family firms and high technology mergers and acquisitions

Upload: winda-febriani

Post on 04-Feb-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    1/31

    Family firms and high technology Mergers &

    Acquisitions

    Paul Andre Walid Ben-Amar Samir Saadi

    Published online: 11 May 2012 Springer Science+Business Media, LLC. 2012

    Abstract We examine whether family firms undertake value creating high tech-

    nology M&A. We also examine whether level of ownership, diversification, agency

    issues and CEO type matter. Our sample consists of high-technology M&A

    undertaken by Canadian firms over the period 19972006. Canada offers a setting

    with many family firms and the use of control enhancing mechanisms such as dual

    class shares and pyramid structures. We find a positive relationship between family

    ownership and announcement period abnormal returns. This relationship, however,starts to decrease at higher levels of ownership but remains overall positive. We also

    show that the agency conflict between shareholders and professional managers has a

    detrimental impact on announcement period abnormal returns whereas the conflict

    between controlling and minority shareholders via control enhancing mechanisms

    does not. Finally, we document that founder CEO undertake better high tech M&A

    than descendant or hired CEO.

    Keywords Family firms Family ownership Mergers & Acquisitions

    Corporate governance Control enhancing mechanisms High-technologyfirms Event studies

    JEL Classification G14 G34

    P. Andre (&)ESSEC Business School, Av. Bernard Hirsch, B.P. 50105, 95021 Cergy, France

    e-mail: [email protected]

    W. Ben-Amar

    Telfer School of Management, University of Ottawa, 55 Laurier East,Ottawa, ON K1N 6N5, Canadae-mail: [email protected]

    J Manag Gov (2014) 18:129158DOI 10.1007/s10997-012-9221-x

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    2/31

    1 Introduction

    There is a substantial amount of evidence showing that family firms represent a

    large fraction of public and private firms around the world (e.g. Claessens et al.

    2000; Faccio and Lang 2002; Pedersen and Thomsen 2003; Anderson and Reeb2003a). However, there exists considerable debate as to whether family firms are

    superior or inferior performers (Villalonga and Amit2006; Miller et al. 2007) and

    whether founder CEO matter compared to descendants or hired CEO (Perez-

    Gonzalez2006; He2008). We examine this issue in a specific yet important context

    where family firms pursue risky investments by way of high technology mergers

    and acquisitions (M&A). Formally, our paper aims to answer the following research

    questions: How does the stock market react to the announcement of high technology

    M&A undertaken by family firms? Does the family firms governance character-

    istics (e.g. use of control enhancing mechanisms, family involvement in manage-ment) and strategy affect this reaction?

    Prior M&A studies have mostly focused on managers incentives to undertake

    acquisitions (Miller et al.2010) and few studies (Ben-Amar and Andre2006; Feito-

    Ruiz and Menedez-Requejo2010) have examined the impact of family ownership

    on the value creation from acquisitions. High technology M&A represent a special

    class of M&A given their high growth potential but also high risk (Kohers and

    Kohers 2000, 2001; Hagedoorn and Duysters 2002; Benou and Madura 2005).

    These are often motivated by the acquirers need to obtain highly developed

    technical expertise and cutting-edge technology (Tsai and Wang 2008). Ranft andLord (2000, p. 296) suggest that acquiring firm may not have the ability to develop

    these valuable knowledge-based resources internally or, alternatively, internal

    development may take too long or be too costly. The acquisition of external

    technology should enhance acquirers innovation level and knowledge base

    resulting in better performance.

    High-tech takeover targets are also highly risky because the valuations of these

    companies are based on uncertain information (Kohers and Kohers 2001). Many

    technology firms are young start-ups without any current revenues and whose value

    lies heavily on the future development and commercial success of a new technology

    (Benou and Madura 2005). Therefore, investors may have difficulties in under-

    standing the technological complexity and to adequately evaluate future outcomes.

    High-tech M&A provide an interesting setting to examine the ability of family

    founders and their heirs in choosing high growth but risky investment projects.

    This study contributes to the literature in at least two ways. First, to the best of

    our knowledge, this is one of very few papers to examine how shareholders view the

    effect of family ownership on firm value when the firm undertakes specific

    investments. Second, we investigate the interactions between family firms, the

    nature of the agency problems and their impact on the value creation from high tech

    M&A. Villalonga and Amit (2006) posit that academic research should distinguishbetween ownership, control and management to properly understand their effect on

    130 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    3/31

    We investigate the stock market reaction to high technology M&A undertaken by

    family firms in Canada as it offers a setting with many family firms and use of

    control enhancing mechanisms. Further, Canada offers a corporate governance

    regime that is principles-based rather than rules-based like in the US. These

    features are often considered as a weaker governance setting. Nevertheless,Canada offers a strong legal protection regime for minority shareholders.

    We find a positive relationship between family ownership and announcement

    period abnormal returns. This relationship, however, starts to decrease at higher levels

    of ownership but remains overall positive. Diversifying acquisitions undertaken by

    family firms are not associated with value destruction to their shareholders. We also

    show that the agency conflict between shareholders and professional managers has a

    detrimental impact on announcement period abnormal returns whereas the conflict

    between family block-holders and minority investors via control enhancing

    mechanisms does not. Finally, we document that firms managed by founder CEOearn higher returns than firms managed by the founders descendants or hired CEO.

    The remainder of this paper is organised as follows. The next section reviews the

    related literature and derives our testable hypotheses. The third section describes the

    methodology and Sect. 4 presents and discusses the results. Section5 offers a

    conclusion and suggestions for future research.

    2 Related literature and hypotheses

    2.1 Family firms and value creation in M&A

    The agency literature (Jensen and Meckling1976) discusses the agency costs arising

    from the conflict of interests between shareholders and professional managers

    (agency problem 1). In a M&A setting, managers may undertake acquisitions to

    increase their compensation and private benefits at the expense of dispersed

    shareholders (Shleifer and Vishny 1997). According to the interest alignment

    hypothesis (Jensen and Meckling 1976), family ownership concentration should

    reduce costs associated with this agency problem and therefore should enhance

    value. Large investors such as families have strong incentives and resources to

    collect information and monitor professional managers (Shleifer and Vishny 1997;

    Claessens et al.2002). This active family monitoring should increase the quality of

    the selection of target firms which should result in better acquisition decisions than

    in non-family firms.

    Furthermore, family members often hold the CEO and/or chairperson position in

    the family firm (Anderson and Reeb 2003a). This active involvement should

    improve their knowledge of the firm (firm-specific knowledge) and enhance their

    investment decisions particularly in knowledge-based investments like R&D

    projects or high-tech acquisitions (Chen and Hsu2009; Chang et al. 2010).

    In addition, family blockholders should have a longer investment horizon. Family

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 131

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    4/31

    their firm to the next generation and thus should have a long-term orientation and be

    more efficient in their investment strategies than non family firms.

    However, large family shareholders can also pursue personal objectives that can

    differ from profit maximization and be detrimental to minority shareholders (agency

    problem 2). Prior research suggests that family blockholders impose significantcosts to the firm because they may undertake sub-optimal investments (Zhang

    1998). Given that a large proportion of the family wealth is invested in the firm and

    their active involvement in the management, managers of family firms tend to be

    more risk-averse managers (Chen and Hsu 2009; Chang et al. 2010; Miller et al.

    2010). Therefore, family firms may be reluctant to undertake profitable innovative

    strategies through high-tech acquisitions because it may increase the familys risk

    and threatens the survival of the family firm. Chen and Hsu (2009) report that family

    control is negatively related to the level of R&D investments which suggests that

    family owners may limit risky but profitable R&D investments. Chang et al. (2010)also document a negative association between family ownership and stock market

    reaction to innovation announcements by Taiwanese firms.

    The above effect is likely to be more severe as the amount of family wealth

    invested in the firm increases. At high-levels of ownership, family blockholders

    become entrenched and have sufficient power to undertake investment projects to

    increase their private benefits or to reduce the firms risk (Zhang 1998; Connelly

    et al. 2010). Given the existence of the alignment and entrenchment effects of

    family ownership, prior research (Morck et al. 1988; Sanchez-Ballesta and Garca-

    Meca 2007; Cascino et al. 2010) suggests that family ownership may have a nonlinear effect on firm performance.

    The above arguments lead to the following hypothesis1:

    H1: Family ownership has a positive effect on the stock market reaction to

    high-tech M&A at low levels of family ownership (as a result of the

    monitoring effect), and has a negative effects on the stock market reaction to

    high-tech M&A at high levels of family ownership (as a consequence of the

    expropriation effect)

    Previous studies obtain mixed evidence on the effect of family ownership on firm

    performance (Anderson and Reeb2003a; Maury2006; Villalonga and Amit 2006;

    Miller et al. 2007; Sciascia and Mazzola 2008). Looking to M&A, Ben-Amar and

    Andre (2006) document that family ownership has a positive effect on acquiring

    firm performance in Canada while Feito-Ruiz and Menedez-Requejo (2010) report a

    non linear relationship between family ownership and announcement period

    cumulative abnormal returns in European M&A. Yen and Andre(2007) examine a

    set of deals in English origin countries and find that value creating deals are

    associated with higher levels of ownership concentration consistent with decreasing

    agency costs as the dominant shareholders wealth invested in the acquiring firm

    increases.

    132 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    5/31

    Prior research (Miller et al. 2010; Gomez-Mejia et al.2010; Anderson and Reeb

    2003b) also suggests that family owners priorities should have a significant impact on

    their firms strategic decisions (growth through M&A and diversification decisions).

    Given that family blockholders would like to retain control over the firm for a long

    period to transfer it to future generations (James1999), they invest a large proportionof their wealth in the family firm which increases their financial risk (Anderson and

    Reeb 2003a). Unlike other blockholders, e.g., institutional investors who hold

    diversified portfolios, family owners cannot diversify their personal portfolios

    without diluting their voting rights as well as the socio-emotional wealth derived from

    the control over the family firm (Gomez-Mejia et al. 2007). As a consequence, Miller

    et al. (2010, p. 204) argue that family owners may try to diversify their personal

    investment portfolios through diversifying acquisitions outside the core industry of

    the family firm. These diversifying acquisitions allow them to reduce the familys

    portfolio risk without losing control of the firm. Previous studies obtain mixed resultson the relation between family firms, diversification levels and firm value. Anderson

    and Reeb (2003b) as well as Gomez-Mejia et al. (2010) find that family firms are less

    diversified than non family firms. In contrast, Miller et al. (2010) document a positive

    relation between family ownership and the likelihood of diversifying acquisitions.

    We therefore examine the impact of diversifying acquisitions undertaken by

    family firms. We argue that stock markets may react differently depending on the

    acquisition motives. If family firms are expected to select efficiently their targets in

    diversifying acquisitions to maximize firm value in the long term in order transfer it

    to later generations, we should observe a positive stock market around theannouncement date.

    H2: Diversifying acquisitions undertaken by family firms have a positive

    effect on the stock market reaction to high-tech M&A

    2.2 Family firms, agency problems and value creation in M&A

    The conflict opposing family blockholders and minority shareholders is exacerbated

    when the controlling family maintains control of the voting rights while holding a

    small fraction of cash flow rights through control enhancing mechanisms such asdual class shares and stock pyramids. These ownership structures involve large

    agency costs due to the presence of both entrenchment and incentive problems.

    Since the controlling shareholders have the power to make decisions but do not bear

    the full cost, (Bebchuk et al. 2000) show how these ownership structures distort

    decision making with regard to investment projects choice, firm size and transfer of

    control. Prior studies (Cronqvist and Nilsson 2003; Anderson and Reeb 2003a;

    Villalonga and Amit2006) show that familyuse of control enhancing mechanisms

    has a negative impact on firm performance.2

    Prior studies testing the expropriation hypothesis through M&A obtain mixedresults. Bae et al. (2002) find evidence that controlling shareholders in large Korean

    b i ( h b l ) M&A t t l lth f i it h h ld t

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 133

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    6/31

    themselves. Bigelli and Mengoli (2004) report a negative association between the

    separation of ownership and control and the bidders announcement returns in Italy.

    Holmen and Knopf (2004) as well as Faccio and Stolin (2006) do not find evidence

    supporting the hypothesis of minority shareholders expropriation through mergers

    and acquisitions in Western Europe. Recently, Wong et al. (2010) and Chang et al.(2010) document a negative association between family excess control and stock

    market reaction to corporate venturing and innovation announcements in Taiwan.

    Based on the above discussion, we formulate the following hypothesis:

    H3: The use of control enhancing mechanisms by family firms has a negative

    effect on the stock market reaction to high-tech M&A

    2.3 The effect of family management on value creation in M&A

    Prior research documents mixed results on the relation between family management

    and firm performance. Smith and Amoako-Adu (1999) and Perez-Gonzalez (2006)

    report a negative stock markets reaction to the appointment of founder-descendants

    as CEOs. Villalonga and Amit (2006) and He (2008) report that when the firms

    founder is active in management (either as CEO or board chairperson), family

    ownership has a positive effect on firm performance. In contrast, when founder

    descendants serve as CEO, Villalonga and Amit find that family ownership is

    negatively related to firm performance. Sciascia and Mazzola (2008) document a

    quadratic negative association between the level of family involvement in

    management (measured as the percentage of the firms managers related to thecontrolling family) and firm performance in Italy.

    Agency theory predicts that family management should attenuate agency

    problem 1 opposing a professional manager to dispersed shareholders (Villalonga

    and Amit2006). A family CEO with a long experience within the firm (a founder or

    a descendent) is likely to have a better knowledge about the family firm and should

    pursue value creating acquisition strategies. Thus family management is likely to

    enhance firm value. We test this prediction in the context of high-tech M&A:

    H4: Family management has a positive effect on stock market reaction to

    high-tech M&A

    3 Data and methodology

    3.1 Data

    We obtain our data set of Canadian high tech acquisitions from the Thomson

    Financial Securities Datas SDC PlatinumTM Worldwide Mergers & Acquisitions

    Database (SDC database). We rely on SDC classification for high tech industries

    which include biotechnology & health, communications, computers hardware and

    134 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    7/31

    criteria: (1) Observations are for January 19972006; (2) Acquiring firms are listed

    Canadian companies; (3) Deals are completed and are mergers, exchange offers, or

    acquisitions of majority interest; (4) For companies with more than one merger

    within a 1-year period, we consider only the first merger in order to circumvent the

    contamination effect that results from multiple mergers announcement in theestimation period; (5) Only transactions greater than US$10 million are included;

    (6) Companies have merger announcement dates and others merger-related

    information available from the SDC database, ownership and corporate governance

    data available from company proxies on the SEDAR web site and stock return and

    other financial data available from the CFMRC database and Stock-Guide database,

    respectively. After eliminating observations with missing data and outliers, we end

    up with a sample of 215 mergers undertaken between January 1997 and 2006.4

    3.2 Canadian institutional setting

    The Canadian governance setting is interesting since there is a fairly high level of

    ownership concentration by dominant family shareholdings (Gadhoum 2006; King

    and Santor2008; Bozec and Laurin2008).Recent financial research has shown that a

    high degree of corporate ownership concentration is the norm around the world (La

    Porta et al. 1999; Claessens et al. 2000; Faccio and Lang2002). Further, in many

    countries such as Canada, large publicly listed corporations have family shareholders

    who exercise control over the voting rights with a small fraction of cash flow rights.

    This separation between ownership and control rights is achieved through the use ofmultiple voting shares, stock pyramids and cross-shareholdings (La Porta et al.1999;

    Cronqvist and Nilsson2003). These findings have changed the focus of researchers

    from the traditional conflict of interests between a professional manager and dispersed

    shareholdersAgency problem 1towards another conflict of interests between

    controlling and minority shareholdersAgency problem 2. The presence of separation

    of control and ownership in Canada allows an examination of the effect of family

    control, ownership and management as proposed by Villalonga and Amit (2006).

    In addition, the Canadian approach to corporate governance is significantly

    different from the one adopted in the US. Following the enactment of the Sarbanes

    Oxley Act, the US adopted a rules-based approachthat requires full compliance

    with prescribed corporate governance rules (see section 303A of the NYSE listed

    company manual). In contrast, the Canadian corporate governance regime is still

    largely voluntary. This principles-based approach requires publicly listed firms to

    4 Our sample selection procedure is consistent with prior M&A research using the SDC worldwide M&Adatabase (see for example, Rau and Vermaelen (1998) and Faccio and Stolin (2006)). The first fiveselection criteria resulted in an initial sample of 342 high-tech takeovers. Consistent with the event-studymethodology, 46 observations with less than 100 valid returns over the 200-day estimation period were

    dropped from the sample. We further eliminated 58 observations because their proxy circulars were notavailable on the SEDAR website to code their ownership structure, governance and executivecompensation data. Finally, following normality diagnostic test on our dependent variable CAR (-1, ?1),

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 135

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    8/31

    disclose the extent of their compliance with the a proposed list of best practices

    guidelines orto explain why they did not adopt these suggested practices (Broshko

    and Li2006).5

    3.3 Variables definition

    Table1provides a description of independent and control variables.

    3.3.1 Dependent variable: announcement period abnormal returns

    We use the well established event study methodology (Brown and Warner1985) to

    evaluate the change in wealth of acquiring firms shareholders around the

    announcement of the transactions. The stocks expected return is computed using

    the market model which parameters are estimated during the period of-240 and-40 days from the announcement date.6 We use daily returns of the TSX/S&P

    composite index as a proxy for market returns. Abnormal returns are cumulated

    over 3 days (-1, ?1) around the announcement date.

    3.3.2 Independent variables

    Family ownership, control and management structure

    Family ownershipFollowing prior research (Smith and Amoako-Adu1999; Faccio and Lang2002;

    Maury2006), we define family firms as those in which the founder or a member of

    his or her family by either blood or marriage is the largest shareholder of the firm

    either individually or as a group. The minimum threshold for family blockholding is

    10 % of the voting shares and above, the imposed Toronto Stock Exchange

    reporting requirement. We code a dummy variable for the presence of a family

    blockholder at various levels and a continuous variable capturing the level of

    ownership blockholding of the family.7

    We use the same methodology as La Porta et al. (1999), Faccio and Lang (2002) and

    Claessens et al. (2002) to measure the ultimate voting and ownership rights held by the

    acquiring firms largest shareholder. Ultimate voting rights (family control) are

    measured as the weakest link in the control chain while ultimate ownership (family

    ownership) is measured as the fraction of equity capital held by the family blockholder.

    5 National Policy NP 58-201 Corporate Governance Guidelines and National Instrument NI-58-101Disclosure of Corporate Governance Practices provide a comprehensive description of the Canadiancorporate governance regime. Broshko and Li (2006) discuss also the main differences between corporategovernance regimes in Canada and the US.

    6 Firms with\100 valid returns over the estimation period were excluded from the sample.7 We reran the regressions with a dummy using 20 % threshold, spline dummies at the 1025 % level

    136 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    9/31

    Control enhancing mechanisms and family excess vote-holding

    We code a dummy variable for voting structures that enable the familys voting

    rights (family control) to exceed its cash flow rights (family ownership) via multiple

    share classes with differential voting rights and pyramids where the family holds

    shares in the firm through one or more intermediate entities of which the familyowns less than 100 %. The family excess vote-holding is the difference between the

    voting rights and the cash flow rights.

    Family firm management

    We create a dummy variable to take into account the implication of founding-

    family or professional CEO in the management of the family firm. Professional

    CEO is a dummy variable equals 1 if the acquiring firm prior to the transaction is

    managed by a professional CEO. We further code whether the family CEO is the

    founder or descendant.

    3.3.3 Control variables

    Acquiring firm characteristics

    Institutional ownership in the acquiring firm

    According to the efficiency-augmentation hypothesis, institutional investors have

    strong incentives to effectively monitor managers. This enhances managerial

    efficiency and the quality of corporate decision making including M&A (Duggal

    and Millar1999; Wright et al.2002). On the other hand, according to theefficiency-

    abatement hypothesis, they do not act as effective monitors due to their short term

    vision and passivity. It is argued that they have myopic investment objectives,

    which causes them to sell the stock of an underperforming company rather than to

    have a long term perspective and to pressure managers to favour value-enhancing

    changes. Prior empirical studies (Duggal and Millar1999; Kohers and Kohers2000;

    Wright et al.2002) provide mixed evidence on the relationship between institutional

    ownership and acquiring firm performance. Institutional ownership is measured as

    the level of voting rights held by all institutional investors in the acquiring firm.

    Board composition

    Empirical studies examining the role of independent boards on value creation inthe case of M&A provide mixed evidence. Faleye and Huson (2002)8 find a positive

    relationship while Byrd and Hickman (1992) present evidence that this relation is

    non linear. Subrahmanyam et al. (1997) find a negative relationship in the case of

    announcement date CAR of bank M&A. In a Canadian setting, Ben-Amar and

    Andre (2006) find a significant positive association between the proportion of

    unrelated directors and acquiring firm announcement period excess returns.

    In this study, we rely on the TSX guidelines definition (TSX 1994) of unrelated

    board members which considers a director as unrelated if he-she is not a manager of

    the firm or of its subsidiaries; is not related to the controlling shareholder and doesnot have business dealings with the firm which could create a conflict of interests.

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 137

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    10/31

    Board independence is measured as the ratio of the number of unrelated directors to

    board size.

    Board size

    The governance literature (Jensen 1993; Yermack1996; Eisenberg et al. 1998)

    has also explored the effect of board size on firm value. The increase of board sizeshould enhance its expertise, counterbalance the CEOs dominance of the board and

    enhance board effectiveness. On the other hand, larger boards may encounter

    communication and coordination problems that reduce their effectiveness. Yermack

    (1996) and Eisenberg et al. (1998) confirm this negative relationship between board

    size and firm performance. Looking at M&A, Faleye and Huson (2002) and Ben-

    Amar and Andre (2006) document a negative relationship between board size and

    acquiring firm CAR.

    Leadership structure

    Several studies have examined the effect of CEO duality (i.e., the CEO is also theboard chairman) on firm performance. Duality reduces firm performance because it

    promotes CEO entrenchment, exacerbates CEO power and reduces board

    effectiveness. Scholars from the organization theory argue, however, that duality

    improves firm performance since it provides clear leadership to the firm (Kang and

    Zardkoohi 2005). The empirical evidence does not generally support the idea that

    duality is harmful to firm performance.9 Boyd (1995) finds that duality has a

    positive effect while Baliga et al. (1996) find that it has no impact. In the context of

    M&A, Faleye and Huson (2002) find that duality has no effect on acquiring firm

    announcement period CARs.Managerial incentives (equity based compensation)

    While the issue of managerial incentive pay has been the topic of much

    controversy over the past few years, the agency literature generally considers that

    incentive pay is a useful mechanism to align managers interests with those of the

    shareholders (Core et al.1999). Shleifer and Vishny (1989) predict that equity based

    compensation should reduce agency costs and limit the non-value-maximising

    behaviour of managers of acquiring companies. Prior finance research (Datta et al.

    2001) documents a positive association between equity based compensation and

    acquirers announcement period CARs. Consistent with Bushman et al. (1996), the

    relative importance of the CEOs performance-contingent compensation is

    measured by the ratio of cash bonus plus stock options granted to the total

    compensation earned by the CEO in the same period. The CEOs total

    compensation includes salary, cash bonuses, other compensations and stock options.

    Stock options are valued at 25 % of their exercise price at the time of the grant.10

    US cross-listing

    Charitou et al. (2007, 1282) points out that Canadian firms make up the single

    largest group of foreign firms listed on a US stock exchange. Furthermore, and

    9 See Dalton et al. (1998), Kang and Zardkoohi (2005) for a review of the board leadership structureliterature.10

    138 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    11/31

    unlike firms from other countries, Canadian companies are required to cross-list

    ordinary shares (not ADRs) and submit to all filing and disclosure requirements.

    Prior research (Doidge, Karolyi and Stulz2004) suggests that cross-listing in the US

    is a signal used by these firms to indicate their willingness to accept tougher

    governance rules and further regulatory oversight. Charitou et al. (2007) documentan improvement in the governance practices of Canadian firms in the years

    following their cross-listing in the US. Cross-listing in the US is measured through a

    dichotomous variable that is equal to one if the acquiring firm is listed on a US stock

    exchange and zero otherwise.

    Free cash flows (FCF)

    Jensen (1986) argues that managers of firms with large free cash flows are more

    likely to undertake non-value creating acquisition strategies. In the tradition of Lang

    et al. (1991) and more recent papers such as Gregory (2005), we control for the level

    the acquirers free cash flows. Free cash flows are measured as cash flows fromoperations divided by book value of assets.

    Market-to-book ratio (MarkettoBook)

    Jensen (2005) suggests that firms with high valuations have greater managerial

    discretion which allows their managers to make poor deals once they have run out of

    good ones. Dong et al. (2006) and Moeller et al. (2004) document that high

    valuation firms make poor M&A deals. We measure firm valuation as the ratio of

    market value of equity plus the book value of debt to the book value of assets.

    Acquiring firm industry

    We also control for the acquiring firms industry using the SDC database macroindustry identifier.

    Target firm and deal characteristics

    Public target

    Kohers and Kohers (2000, 42) argue the market may perceive that the growth

    opportunities of privately held high-tech companies are more valuable than those of

    publicly traded high-tech companies. Benou and Madura (2005) and Kohers and

    Kohers (2000) find the acquirers of privately held high-tech targets obtain higher

    returns than the acquirers of public high-tech targets. Looking at Canadian

    acquirers, Yuce and Ng (2005) as well as Ben-Amar and Andre (2006) document

    that the acquisition of private targets is associated with higher announcement period

    abnormal returns.

    Payment method(Cash only)

    Prior research finds that the mode of payment is one of the consistent factors that

    influence the level of value creation in M&A (Andrade et al.2001). In the context of

    high tech acquisitions, Benou and Madura (2005) find that acquirer returns are

    higher in cash offers than in stock or mixed offers. In contrast, Kohers and Kohers

    (2000) find that both stock and cash financing are associated with significantpositive excess returns.

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 139

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    12/31

    synergies are easier to achieve when firms have related business than when creating

    conglomerates. Looking at acquisitions of high tech targets in the US, Kohers and

    Kohers (2000) find that high tech acquirers obtain significantly higher returns than

    non high-tech acquiring firms. Related industries is a dummy variable equal to 1 if

    the acquirer and the target share the same 4-digit SIC code and zero otherwise.Cross-border transactions (cross-border)

    Cross-border transactions should benefit shareholders of both firms when the

    merged firm can exploit market imperfections in outside markets (Eun et al. 1996).

    However, integration costs and cultural problems often undermine these gains.

    Empirical results have been somewhat mixed. Moeller and Schlingemann (2005)

    show that US firms that acquire cross-border targets experience lower abnormal

    performance and that the results are negatively associated with global and industrial

    diversification but positively associated to legal systems offering better shareholder

    protection. Faccio et al. (2006) report a positive association between the acquisitionof foreign targets and acquirer returns for a sample of European M&A. Ben-Amar

    and Andre (2006) document that Canadian bidders involved in cross-border

    transactions obtain higher returns than domestic acquisitions.

    Deal size(log deal value)

    Asquith et al. (1983) argue that bidder returns increase with relative size of the

    target to the acquirer. Kohers and Kohers (2000), as well as Benou and Madura

    (2005), report a positive relation between the relative transaction size and acquirer

    abnormal returns in high-tech acquisitions. We control for transaction size and

    measure deal size as the log of the deal value.Time period

    To control for the high technology wave that occurred in the period 19972000

    we introduce a dummy variable equals to one if the deal occurs in that period.

    4 Results

    4.1 Descriptive statistics

    Our sample consists of 215 transactions between January 1997 and 2006 with an

    annual average value of US $ 352.2 million and total value of over US $ 75.7

    billion. These figures are smaller than those reported in US studies. For example, the

    average transaction value in Benou and Madura (2005) is US $ 433.2 million. The

    largest numbers of deals occurs in the year 2000, the peak of the new economy

    bubble, with 53 deals worth some 27.6 billion dollars, an average deal size of 520

    million. Most acquirers are high-tech firms, followed by telecoms and health

    industry firms. The largest deals were initiated by telecom companies.

    Table2 provides descriptive statistics of variables examined in this study. As

    shown in Panel (i), the average family ownership stake in the acquirer prior to

    merger announcement is 11.5 %, however, this level increases to 25.2 % when

    140 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    13/31

    Table 1 Variable description

    Variable Description

    (i) Family control and family structure

    Family ownership dummy Dummy variable that equals one if the acquirers largest shareholder is a family(the founder or a member of his or her family by either blood or mariage) and

    zero otherwise. A large shareholder is an individual or an entity with a voting

    stake of 10 % or more

    Family ownership stake Percentage of ownership (cash-flow) rights of all classes of the acquiring firms

    shares held by the family as a group prior to the transaction

    Family voting stake Percentage of voting rights of all classes of the acquiring firms shares held by

    the family as a group prior to the transaction

    Control-enhancing

    mechanisms dummy

    Dummy variable equals 1 if there are multiple voting share classes, pyramids or

    cross-holdings in the acquiring firm

    Family excess vote-holding Difference between the percentage of voting rights of the family and cash flow

    rights held by the family in the acquiring firm prior to the transactionProfessional CEO dummy Dummy variable equals 1 if the acquiring firm prior to the transaction is

    managed by a professional CEO, i.e., someone who is not a family member

    (ii) Acquiring firm characteristics

    Institutional ownership

    dummy

    Dummy variable equal 1 if one or more institutional investors own 10 % or

    more of the acquiring firms cash flow rights prior to the transaction

    Institutional ownership stake Percentage of cash flow rights held by institutional investors in the acquiring

    firm prior to the transaction

    Board independence Ratio of unrelated directors to number of board members in the acquiring firm

    prior to the transaction

    Board size Number of board members in the acquiring firm prior to the transactionCEOCOB Dummy variable equals 1 if the acquiring firm CEO is also board chairman prior

    to the transaction

    Incentive compensation The ratio of the market value of options granted to the acquiring firm CEO

    divided by his/her total compensation in the year prior to the deal

    US listing Dummy variable equals 1 if the acquiring firm is listed on a US exchange

    (NYSE, NASDAQ, AMEX) prior to the transaction, and 0 otherwise

    FCF Acquiring firm cash-flow from operations divided by the book value of assets at

    end of year prior to the transaction

    MarkettoBook The ratio of the market value of equity plus the book value of debt to the book

    value of assets at end of year prior to the transaction

    (iii) Target firm and deal characteristics

    Public target Dummy variable equals 1 if target firm is listed on a stock exchange

    Cash only Dummy variable equals 1 if transaction is entirely financed with cash

    Diversification Dummy variable equals 1 if acquirer and target do not share the same 4-digit

    SIC code

    Cross-border Dummy variable equals 1 if target nation is not Canada

    Log deal value Logarithm of the deal total value

    Pre 2001 time Period Dummy variable equals 1 if the transaction is announced between January 1997

    and December 2000

    Governance information is collected from Information Circulars available on SEDAR (sedar.com). Transactioncharacteristics are obtained from the Thomson Financial Securities Datas SDC PlatinumTM Worldwide Mergers

    & Acquisitions Database. Financial information is from Compustat or StockGuide

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 141

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    14/31

    average voting stake for these 98 firms is 47.6 % confirming the presence of control

    enhancing mechanisms. Control enhancing mechanisms (multiple class shares,

    pyramids) are present in 20 % of the sample but represent 43.9 % of family firms.

    The excess vote-holding (difference between voting rights and cash flow rights) is

    10.2 % overall but in fact 51 % when considering only the firms with these

    mechanisms. Looking at management, 74.4 % of firms are run by professionalCEOs, or conversely, 25.6 % of all the sample firms are managed by a family

    Table 2 Descriptive statistics

    Variables Mean Median SD Min. Max.

    (i) Family control and management structure

    Family ownership dummy (10 %) 0.456 0.000 0.499 0.000 1.000

    Family ownership stake 0.115 0.000 0.187 0.000 0.879

    Non zero cases (98) 0.252 0.187 0.206 0.013 0.879

    Family voting stake 0.209 0.000 0.300 0.000 0.925

    Non zero cases (98) 0.476 0.429 0.298 0.106 0.925

    Control enhancing mechanisms 0.200 0.000 0.401 0.000 1.000

    Family excess vote-holding 0.102 0.000 0.218 0.000 0.756

    Non zero cases (43) 0.510 0.536 0.171 0.130 0.756

    Professional CEO 0.744 1.000 0.437 0.000 1.000

    (ii) Acquiring firm characteristics

    Institutional ownership dummy 0.218 0.000 0.414 0.000 1.000

    Institutional ownership stake 0.045 0.000 0.105 0.000 0.703

    Non zero cases (47) 0.207 0.142 0.132 0.102 0.703

    Board independence 0.706 0.750 0.154 0.182 0.938

    Board size 9.690 9.000 3.584 4.000 19.000

    CEOCOB 0.237 0.000 0.426 0.000 1.000

    Incentive compensation 0.290 0.220 0.296 0.000 1.000

    US listing 0.535 1.000 0.500 0.000 1.000

    FCF 0.064 0.081 0.133 -0.633 0.442

    MarkettoBook 2.143 1.680 1.694 0.172 11.778

    (iii) Target firm and deal characteristics

    Public target 0.316 0.000 0.466 0.000 1.000

    Cash only 0.502 0.000 0.501 0.000 1.000

    Diversification 0.665 0.000 0.473 0.000 1.000

    Cross-border 0.591 1.000 0.493 0.000 1.000

    Log deal value 4.205 3.834 1.621 2.302 9.134

    Pre 2001 time period 0.470 0.000 0.500 0.000 1.000

    Sample of 215 mergers and acquisitions by Canadian acquiring firms between January 1997 and 2006 forcompleted transactions over US$ 10 million obtained from the Thomson Financial Securities Datas SDC

    PlatinumTM Worldwide Mergers & Acquisitions Database. See Table1 for variable description

    142 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    15/31

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    16/31

    between all cash deals and those with some stock payment, between cross-border

    and national deals, between deals involving firms in related or non-related

    industries, or across time periods. We do notice that family controlled firms obtain

    announcement period abnormal returns of 1.53 % compared to 0.53 % for non

    family firms. Table4also indicates positive correlation between the presence and

    the level of family control, albeit not significant at conventional levels. Deals

    undertaken by firms managed by professional CEOs generate 0.35 % abnormal

    returns whereas those with family CEOs obtain 2.8 % abnormal returns, the

    difference being significant.

    4.3 Agency problems and announcement period abnormal returns

    Table6offers a first examination of the link between various agency problems and

    acquiring firm announcement period abnormal returns using the Villalonga and

    Amit (2006) framework. The average CARs for the 27 family firms with family

    CEOs and without control enhancing mechanisms (Type I firms: no potential

    agency conflicts) are 3.59 % (median 2.40 %). This contrasts with the average

    CARs of 2.04 % (med. 0.91 %) for the 28 family firms with family CEOs but

    having control enhancing mechanisms (Type II firms: potential conflict between

    large and small shareholders or agency problem 2). The differences become much

    sharper when comparing with the 145 firms having professional CEOs withoutcontrol enhancing mechanisms (Type III firms: potential shareholder-manager

    Table 3 Abnormal returns and cumulative abnormal returns around high-tech M&A announcement

    Period Mean Median t-stat % of Positive CAR

    Cumulative abnormal returns

    Raw returns

    -1 to ?1 0.0152 0.0122 2.451** 58.14

    Market adjusted abnormal returns

    -1 to ?1 0.0136 0.0100 3.198*** 57.67

    Market model abnormal returns

    -1 to ?1 0.0098 0.0037 3.351*** 53.02

    Sample of 215 mergers and acquisitions by Canadian acquiring firms between January 1997 and 2006 forcompleted transactions over US$ 10 million obtained from the Thomson Financial Securities Datas SDCPlatinumTM Worldwide Mergers & Acquisitions Database. AR stands for abnormal return and CAR for

    cumulative abnormal returns. We define the abnormal return for a stockion daytto be the actual returns,Rjt, minus a stocks expected return which is computed using either the market return or the market

    model: ARit Rit ai biRmt

    , where ai and bi were obtained from the ordinary least-squares

    (OLS) regression of stock returns with market returns during an estimation period spanning day -240 today -40, where day 0 (the event day) indicates the day on which the merger was first announced.Abnormal returns are cumulated (CAR) over the 3 day (-1, ?1) windows. **, *** indicate statisticalsignificance at 5 and 1 % levels, respectively

    144 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    17/31

    i.e., Agency problem 1 and 2) having average CARs of-0.90 % (med. -1.67 %).

    Further, tests show that firms with professional CEOs have significantly lower

    CARs both in the absence of control enhancing mechanisms and overall. Type IV

    firms (presence of both agency problems) have significantly lower abnormal returns

    than all other firms. These univariate results suggest that the conflict between

    shareholders and professional managers (agency problem 1) has a detrimental

    impact on announcement period abnormal returns whereas the conflict betweenlarge and small investors via control enhancing mechanisms (agency problem 2)

    Table 4 Partial correlationmatrix: announcement periodabnormal returns on ownership,agency problems, deal andacquiring firm characteristics

    This table reports Spearmancorrelations betweenannouncement period abnormalreturns and independentvariables. Announcement period

    abnormal returns are cumulatedover the 3 day window (-1,?1), where day 0 (the event day)indicates the day on which themerger was first announced,using the market model

    parameters estimated between-240 and -40 days. Sample of215 mergers and acquisitions byCanadian acquiring firmsbetween January 1997 and 2006for completed transactions overUS$ 10 million obtained fromthe Thomson Financial

    Securities Datas SDCPlatinumTM Worldwide Mergers& Acquisitions Database. SeeTable1 for variable description.

    * indicate statistical significanceat 10 % or more

    CAR(-1, ? 1)

    (i) Family control and management structure

    Family ownership dummy (10 %) 0.1164

    Family ownership stake 0.0492

    Control enhancing mechanisms 0.0014

    Family excess vote-holding -0.0247

    Professional CEO -0.1843*

    (ii) Acquiring firm characteristics

    Institutional ownership dummy 0.1500*

    Institutional ownership stake 0.1802*

    Board size -0.1621*

    Board independence -0.0577

    CEOCOB 0.0172

    Incentive compensation -0.0246

    US listing -0.0307

    FCF 0.1355*

    MarkettoBook -0.0822

    Acquirer industry:

    High-tech -0.0393

    Health 0.0725

    Telecoms -0.0163

    Media -0.0029

    Industrial 0.0486

    Other -0.0488

    (iii) Target firm and deal characteristics

    Public target -0.2201*

    Cash only 0.0560

    Diversification -0.0279

    Cross-border 0.0329

    Log deal value -0.1156

    Pre 2001 time period 0.0682

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 145

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    18/31

    Table 5 Announcement period abnormal returns by ownership, governance, deal and acquiring firmcharacteristics (categorical variables)

    CAR (-1, ?1) SD N Ftest Ztest

    (i) Family control and management structureFamily ownership dummy (10 %)

    Yes 0.0153 0.0604 98 1.54 -1.178

    No 0.0053 0.0576 117

    Control enhancing mechanism

    Yes 0.0100 0.0610 43 0.00 0.570

    No 0.0098 0.0585 172

    Professional CEO

    Yes 0.0035 0.0572 160 7.28*** 2.156**

    No 0.0280 0.0604 55(ii) Acquiring firm characteristics

    Institutional ownership

    Yes 0.0265 0.0597 47 4.91** -2.499**

    No 0.0052 0.0581 168

    CEOCOB

    Yes 0.0140 0.0699 51 0.32 -0.224

    No 0.0086 0.0553 164

    US listing

    US listed 0.0078 0.0565 115 0.29 0.000Canadian listed 0.0122 0.0618 100

    (iii) Target firm and deal characteristics

    Target firm listing status

    Listed -0.0092 0.0560 68 10.84*** 3.091 ***

    Private 0.0187 0.0584 147

    Cross-border transaction

    Cross-border 0.0115 0.0605 127 0.23 -1.213

    Domestic 0.0075 0.0569 88

    Payment methodAll cash 0.0131 0.0605 108 0.67 -0.754

    Stock and mixed 0.0075 0.0569 107

    Diversification

    Related 0.0122 0.0698 72 0.17 -0.258

    Diversification 0.0087 0.0529 143

    Pre 2001 time period

    Jan 1997Dec 2000 0.0141 0.0557 101 1.00 -0.936

    Jan 2001Jan 2006 0.0061 0.0617 114

    Announcement period abnormal returns are cumulated over (-1, ? 1), where day 0 (the event day)indicates the day on which the merger was first announced, using the market model parameters estimated

    146 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    19/31

    that agency problem 1 has the most detrimental effect on firm value as measured by

    Tobins Q.

    4.4 Family ownership, agency problems, and announcement period abnormal

    returns

    We use linear regression models to examine the multivariate relationship betweenfamily ownership, agency problems and acquiring-firm announcement period

    abnormal returns. We use Huber/White/Sandwich estimators of variance allowing

    for observations that are not independent within clusters to compute t-statistics to

    control for the significant presence of multiple acquirers (104 unique acquirers for

    the 215 deals). All our regressions include dummies for acquirers industry.

    However, their coefficients are not shown for brevity. Table 7shows the results of

    OLS regressions of CAR on family ownership and control variables. In model 1,

    family ownership is measured with a dummy variable while model 2 introduces

    family ownership levels. Model 3 considers a non linear relationship between familyownership and announcement CAR.

    Table 6 Impact of agency problems on announcement period abnormal returns

    Conflict of interest between largeand minority shareholder(Agency problem 2)

    Conflict of interest between ownersand managers (Agency problem 1)

    Total Test of differences(Ftest &WilcoxonRanksumz test)

    No [FamilyCEO]

    Yes [ProfessionalCEO]

    No [One share, one vote] 27

    0.0359

    0.0240

    (Type I firms)

    145

    0.0049

    0.0024

    (Type III firms)

    172

    0.0098

    0.0056

    6.59**

    2.20**

    Yes [Control-enhancingmechanisms]

    28

    0.0204

    0.0091

    (Type II firms)

    15

    -0.009

    -0.0166

    (Type IV firms)

    43

    0.0100

    -0.0031

    2.44

    1.605

    Total 55

    0.0281

    0.0184

    160

    0.0035

    0.0001

    215

    0.0098

    0.0037

    7.28***

    2.156**

    Test of differences (F test &Wilcoxon Ranksum z test)

    0.90

    1.145

    0.87

    1.308

    0.00

    0.570

    5.59**

    2.481**

    Top number is number of firms of each type, middle number is the mean announcement abnormal returnsand the bottom number is the median announcement period abnormal returns. Announcement periodabnormal returns are cumulated over (-1, ? 1), where day 0 (the event day) indicates the day on which

    the merger was first announced, using the market model parameters estimated between -

    240 and-40 days. See Table1 for variable description. **, *** indicate statistical significance at 5 and 1 %

    levels, respectively

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 147

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    20/31p\0.05). However the results of model 3 show a non linear relation betweenfamily ownership and announcement returns. The coefficient of family ownership

    Table 7 OLS regression of announcement period abnormal returns on family ownership, acquiring firm,target firm and deal characteristics

    Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

    Coefficient t-stat Coefficient t-stat Coefficient t-stat

    (i) Family ownership

    Family ownership dummy

    (10 %)

    0.0265 2.81***

    Family ownership stake 0.0005 2.32** 0.0017 3.06***

    Family ownership stake2 -0.0000 -2.26**

    (ii) Acquiring firm characteristics

    Institutional ownership dummy 0.0173 2.12**

    Institutional ownership stake 0.0634 2.05** 0.0683 2.21**

    Board independence 0.0197 0.75 0.0228 0.87 0.0151 0.61

    Board size -0.0023 -2.11** -0.0024 -2.07** -0.0019 -1.69*

    CEOCOB 0.0067 0.62 0.0102 0.96 0.0052 0.47

    Incentive compensation -0.0029 -0.19 -0.0077 -0.46 -0.0077 -0.48

    US listing -0.0114 -1.31 -0.0106 -1.21 -0.0121 -1.38

    FCF 0.0016 2.62*** 0.0011 1.30 0.0008 0.92

    MarkettoBook -0.0058 2.61*** -0.0053 -2.24** -0.0056 -2.39**

    Acquirer industry H H H

    (iii) Target firm and deal characteristics

    Public target -0.0296 -3.31*** -0.0298 -3.28*** -0.0302 -3.47***

    Cash only 0.0048 1.01 0.0035 0.45 0.0042 0.53

    Diversification -0.0131 -1.23 -0.0146 -1.46 -0.0138 -1.38

    Diversification * family

    ownership

    0.0249 1.19 0.0008 1.64 0.0010 2.27**

    Cross-border -0.0040 -0.46 -0.0024 -0.27 -0.0026 -0.30

    Log deal value 0.0001 0.02 0.0001 -0.02 0.0000 0.01

    Pre 2001 time period 0.0268 3.09*** 0.0281 3.18*** 0.0274 3.11***

    Intercept 0.0055 0.19 0.0087 0.29 0.0063 0.21

    R2 0.1768 0.1687 0.1849

    FStatistic 73.07*** 68.85*** 71.31***

    Sample of 215 mergers and acquisitions by Canadian acquiring firms between January 1997 and 2006 for

    completed transactions over US$ 10 million obtained from the Thomson Financial Securities Datas SDC

    PlatinumTM Worldwide Mergers & Acquisitions Database.Announcement period abnormal returns are cumu-

    lated over (-1, ?1), where day 0 (the event day) indicates the day on which the merger was first announce-

    d,using the market model parameters estimated between -240 and -40 days. Huber/White/Sandwich

    estimators of variance allowing for observations that are not independent within clusters (105 unique acquirers)

    are used to compute t-statistics. All our regressions include dummies for acquirers industry. However, their

    coefficients are not reported for brevity. See Table 1 for variable description. *, **, *** indicate statistical

    significance at 10, 5 and 1 % levels, respectively

    148 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    21/31

    positive relationship starts to decrease at higher levels of ownership but remains

    overall positive. Our results confirm hypothesis 1.

    These results are similar to those of Feito-Ruiz and Menedez-Requejo (2010)

    who find that family ownership has a positive and significant effect on acquirer

    shareholders wealth up to an ownership level of 34 %. Beyond this ownershiplevel, family ownership has a negative effect. Our results suggest that at higher

    levels of ownership, i.e., the family has a higher amount of wealth invested in the

    firm, the market perceives that the family are making deals with less value creation

    potential. One explanation presented in the literature is that family owners may limit

    their risk taking strategies as the level of investment in the firm increases (Miller

    et al. 2010).

    Table7 also presents the results of the effect of diversifying acquisitions

    undertaken by family firms on the announcement period abnormal returns (H2).

    This effect is measured through the interaction term between family ownership andrelatedness dummy (Diversification * Family ownership). The coefficient of the

    interaction variable is positive in the three models and is statistically significant in

    model 3 only although not necessarily economically significant. These results

    suggest that the stock market does not perceive diversifying acquisitions undertaken

    by family owners as value-decreasing. In contrast, our results seem to imply that

    family owners select carefully their target firms in diversifying acquisitions as much

    as in related type deals.

    Table7 also shows that the presence and level of institutional ownership

    positively affects announcement period abnormal returns. Consistent with theefficiency augmentation hypothesis of institutional ownership benefits, our results

    are consistent with Wright et al. (2002) but contrasts with Kohers and Kohers (2000)

    who report a negative relation between institutional shareholdings and high-tech

    acquirers excess returns. These results confirm the effective monitoring role of

    institutional investors. Given their ownership stake and their large resources,

    institutional investors can impact corporate strategy and enhance corporate decision

    making including M&A. We further find a negative relationship between

    announcement date CAR and board size consistent with results by Yermack

    (1996) and Eisenberg et al. (1998). We also document a negative association

    between market-to-book and excess returns earned by acquirer shareholders. This is

    consistent with Jensens (2005) conjecture that firms with high valuations make

    poorer acquirers and confirmed by Moeller et al. (2004) and Dong et al. (2006).

    When we control for variables related to the target firms and deal characteristics,

    we find that acquisitions of public targets are negatively associated to announcement

    period abnormal returns, consistent with prior literature. Deals prior to 2001, i.e.,

    during the high-tech bubble, generate higher abnormal returns to acquiring firm

    shareholders than subsequent deals. The payment method, relatedness, location and

    deal size have no significant effect on acquiring firm performance.11

    11

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 149

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    22/31Turning more specifically to the potential agency problems, multivariate results

    in Table8 support those found in Table6. The coefficient on professional CEO

    Table 8 OLS regression of announcement period abnormal returns on agency problems, acquiring firm,target firm and deal characteristics

    Model 1 Model 2

    Coefficient t-stat Coefficient t-stat

    (i) Agency problems

    Control-enhancing mechanisms ($) 0.0095 0.75

    Family excess vote-holding 0.0004 1.63

    Professional CEO dummy(&) -0.0252 -2.44** -0.0205 -2.06**

    Interaction $ and & -0.0179 -1.05 -0.0007 -2.61**

    (ii) Acquiring firm characteristics

    Institutional ownership dummy 0.0197 2.53**

    Institutional ownership stake 0.0690 2.04**

    Board independence 0.0207 0.84 0.0172 0.67

    Board size -0.0021 -1.82* -0.0025 -2.21**

    CEOCOB 0.0082 0.75 0.0098 0.86

    Incentive compensation -0.0023 -0.15 -0.0025 -0.16

    US listing -0.0072 -0.85 -0.0067 -0.77

    FCF -0.0199 -0.68 -0.0238 -0.82

    MarkettoBook -0.0057 2.37** -0.0056 -2.30**

    Acquirer industry H H

    (iii) Target firm and deal characteristics

    Public target -0.0268 -2.92*** -0.0279 -3.06***

    Cash only 0.0080 1.00 0.0086 1.09

    Diversification 0.0004 0.05 -0.0001 -0.08

    Crossborder 0.0009 0.11 0.0010 0.12

    Log deal value 0.0001 0.03 0.0004 0.11

    Pre 2001 time period 0.0234 2.68*** 0.0235 2.71**

    Intercept 0.0221 0.76 0.0255 0.88

    R2 0.1802 0.1909

    FStatistic 3.71*** 5.85***

    Sample of 215 mergers and acquisitions by Canadian acquiring firms between January 1997 and 2006 forcompleted transactions over US$ 10 million obtained from the Thomson Financial Securities Datas SDCPlatinumTM Worldwide Mergers & Acquisitions Database.Announcement period abnormal returns arecumulated over (-1, ?1), where day 0 (the event day) indicates the day on which the merger was first

    announced, using the market model parameters estimated between -240 and -40 days. Huber/White/Sandwich estimators of variance allowing for observations that are not independent within clusters (105unique acquirers) are used to compute t-statistics. All our regressions include dummies for acquirersindustry. However, their coefficients are not reported for brevity. See Table1 for variable description. *,**, *** indicate statistical significance at 10, 5 and 1 % levels, respectively

    150 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    23/31

    a longer experience within the firm and are likely to have a better knowledge of its

    business than a hired CEO. Hence, they may have superior managerial expertise to

    pursue value creating acquisition strategies particularly in high-technology

    industries.

    As shown in Table8, the coefficients on either the presence of control-enhancingmechanisms or the level of family excess vote holding (agency problem 2) are both

    non significant. H3 is therefore not supported. Family use of controlling enhancing

    mechanisms does not seem to affect the success of major investment projects such

    as high-tech M&A.

    The presence of both agency issues, the interaction term, is negative and

    significant in model 2. Overall, the results of Table 8 suggest that the potential

    agency conflict between shareholders and professional managers (agency problem

    1) has a detrimental impact on announcement period abnormal returns whereas the

    potential agency conflict between large and small investors via control enhancingmechanisms (agency problem 2) does not. The presence of both agency problems

    has a further negative impact on shareholder wealth. It is possible that the market

    expects the presence of family excess control to amplify the agency costs associated

    with the conflict between shareholders and professional managers. When family

    block-holders use control enhancing mechanisms, they hold control over the firm

    with a small fraction of cash flow rights and internalize only a small portion of the

    wealth implications of a non-optimal investment decision. Therefore, stock market

    participants may perceive them as less effective in monitoring professional

    managers acquisition decisions which exacerbate agency costs resulting fromagency problem 1.

    These findings are consistent with arguments made by James (1999) and

    Anderson and Reeb (2003a) who suggest that the sheer amount of wealth families

    have invested in the firm is a sufficient incentive to maximise firm value and restrain

    from extracting private benefits which would make it difficult to establish a long

    term relationship with the investment community, raise additional capital to grow

    the firm and would increase the cost of capital. We can suggest that countries with

    well-developed markets and offering good minority shareholder protection can

    reduce the agency problems between family owners and minority shareholders, to a

    certain extent, as long as the family shareholder continues to play an active role in

    the management of the firm.

    4.5 Do founders matter?

    The results of Tables6and8suggest that family management has a positive effect

    on the market reaction to high-technology M&A. We further examine the impact of

    family management to see whether the positive effect is limited to the firms

    founders or remain with descendant CEO. Similar to Villalonga and Amit (2006)

    and He (2008), we examine the impact of CEO type (founder, descendant or

    professional manager) on the value creation from our risky high tech acquisitions.

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 151

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    24/31

    (median 2.4 %). This result is significantly higher than that from family firms

    managed by the descendants or by professionals. These results confirm the positive

    impact of founders on firm value as reported by Villalonga and Amit (2006) and He

    (2008). These findings suggest that founder CEO may possess specific character-

    istics which may distinguish their acquisition ability, even more so in the context of

    difficult-to-value targets like high-tech firms. Further, founders have a better

    understanding of the business as their long term involvement in having created and

    managed the firm and are often the longest tenured member of the firm, they have a

    significant economic interest in the business and are committed to its success (He

    2008). In contrast, descendant CEO may not possess these inherent characteristics

    or the same drive (Perez-Gonzalez 2006) whereas hired professionals introduce

    agency costs as discussed above.

    5 Conclusion

    We investigate the effect of family ownership, excess control and management onthe stock market reactions to high-tech merger announcements. We find a non linear

    Table 9 Effect of founder CEO on family firms announcement period CARs

    N Mean(t-Stat)

    Median Standarddeviation

    FStatistic

    Professional CEO 43 -0.0010(-0.12)

    0.0001 0.0567 3.28**

    Descendant CEO 12 0.0157

    (0.92)

    -0.0058 0.0618

    Founder CEO 43 0.03152

    (3.50)***

    0.0240 0.0603

    Family firms 98 0.0153 0.0110 0.0604

    Professional CEO Founder CEO

    Comparison of mean differences in CARs by CEO type (Scheffe test)Founder CEO 0.0325**

    p value = 0.042

    Descendant CEO 0.0168

    p value = 0.684

    -0.01577

    p value = 0.716

    Sample of 215 mergers and acquisitions by Canadian acquiring firms between January 1997 and 2006 forcompleted transactions over US$ 10 million obtained from the Thomson Financial Securities Datas SDCPlatinumTM Worldwide Database.Announcement period abnormal returns are cumulated over (-1, ?1),where day 0 (the event day) indicates the day on which the merger was first announced, using the market

    model parameters estimated between -240 and -40 days. **, *** indicate statistical significance at 5

    and 1 % levels, respectively

    152 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    25/31

    reducing strategies leading them to forgo profitable but risky investment projects.

    These findings contribute to a better understanding of how family owners

    preferences and risk attitude affect firm performance. Moreover, the non linear

    association between family ownership and stock market reaction to high-tech M&A

    qualifies the question as to whether family firms are superior or inferior performers.We also show that the conflict of interests between shareholders and professional

    managers (agency problem 1) has the most harmful effect on shareholders wealth

    whereas the conflict between large family owners and minority shareholders via

    control enhancing mechanisms (agency problem 2) does not. To the best of our

    knowledge, our paper is the first to consider the interactions between the two agency

    problems and to test which of the two has the most detrimental effect on the quality

    of an important business decision: high technology M&A. Furthermore, following

    Villalonga and Amit (2006), this paper distinguishes between ownership, control

    and management to better understand the family effect.Adding to the family business literature, we find that family involvement in

    management has a positive effect on the wealth creation of high-tech M&A and that

    founders CEO are associated with better performance than hired CEOs. These

    results confirm the valuable role played by founders in the success of family firms.

    Given their long-term involvement in the firm and their better understanding of the

    business, founders have more expertise in the selection of difficult to value targets

    (such as high-tech firms) which results in value-creating acquisition strategies. Our

    findings do not support the altruism argument (Lubatkin et al. 2005) that family

    firms protect and favour incompetent family CEO who likely lack the expertise toundertake value-creating acquisitions.

    Further, our results contribute to the on-going debate about the impact of control

    enhancing mechanisms, such mechanisms appearing more and more in the

    landscape (e.g. founders of Google and Facebook have retained control enhancing

    mechanisms following their IPO). One explanation for not finding a negative impact

    is that families have such a significant amount of wealth invested in the firm and this

    is a sufficient incentive to maximise firm value and restrain them from extracting

    private benefits which would make it difficult to establish a long term relationship

    with the investment community, raise additional capital to grow the firm and would

    increase the cost of capital (James 1999; Anderson and Reeb2003a).

    Our findings are also of interest to regulatory authorities on the issue of whether

    family blockholders use M&A transactions to expropriate minority shareholders and

    obtain private benefits. Our conclusion does not support the expropriation

    hypothesis and suggests that the current legal protections offered to minority

    shareholders in Canada may limit expropriation and tunnelling opportunities

    through M&A. Our results indicate that a jurisdiction with a well-developed stock

    market and offering good minority shareholder legal protection can reduce the

    agency problems between dominant and minority shareholders.

    As is the case with prior M&A research, this study is not without limitations. We

    examine investors short term reaction to high-technology M&A announcements by

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 153

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    26/31

    also look to the association between agency problems in family firms and post-

    merger performance in different industries and countries to test whether the papers

    conclusions can be extended.

    Further, given that family ownership in publicly listed firms is widely prevalent

    around the world, future research should investigate the effect of family ownership,control and management on other financial and strategic decisions. As suggested by

    Chang et al. (2010), academic research should further explore the channels

    through which family control and management affects firm value. An important

    dimension to explore is family culture and its influence on firm value (see, for

    instance, Chrisman et al. 2002 and Zahra et al. 2004). More specifically, future

    research could examine how the different dimensions of organizational culture

    within a family firm shape its performance following an M&A. Finally, our study

    focuses on high-technology M&A as an example of a high growth but risky

    investment project. A further extension would be to examine the effect of familycontrol and involvement in management on the choice between different forms of

    investments (R&D projects, capital expenditure, M&A) as well as its impact on firm

    performance.

    Acknowledgments We thank seminar participants at the Corporate Governance: An InternationalReviewConference in Birmingham and EFM Athens and comments from colleagues at the University of

    Edinburgh, HEC Montreal, Universitedu Quebec aMontreal and Universitede Paris I and XII. WalidBen-Amar gratefully acknowledges financial support from the University of Ottawas Telfer School ofManagement Research fund. Paul Andregratefully acknowledges support from the Research Alliance in

    Governance and Forensic Accounting funded within theInitiative on the new economy program of theSocial Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Canada (SSHRC). Paul Andre was on honoraryvisiting professor at Cass Business School during some work on this paper.

    References

    Adams, R., & Ferreira, D. (2008). One-share one-vote: The empirical evidence.Review of Finance, 12,5191.

    Anderson, R. C., & Reeb, D. M. (2003a). Founding-family ownership and firm performance: Evidence

    from the S&P 500.Journal of Finance, 58, 13011329.Anderson, R. C., & Reeb, D. M. (2003b). Founding-family ownership, corporate diversification and firm

    leverage.Journal of Law and Economics, 46, 653684.Andrade, G., Mitchell, M., & Stafford, E. (2001). New evidence and perspectives on mergers.Journal of

    Economic Perspectives, 15(2), 103120.Archambeault, D., DeZoort, F. T., & Hermanson, D. (2008). Audit committee incentive compensation

    and accounting restatements. Contemporary Accounting Research, 25, 965992.Asquith, P., Bruner, R. F., & Mullins, D. W., Jr. (1983). The gains to bidding firms from mergers.Journal

    of Financial Economics, 11(14), 121140.

    Bae, K. H., Kang, J. K., & Kim, J. M. (2002). Tunnelling or value addition? Evidence from mergers byKorean business groups.Journal of Finance, 57, 26952740.

    Baliga, B., Moyer, R. C., & Rao, R. S. (1996). CEO duality and firm performance. Strategic Management

    Journal, 17, 4153.Bebchuk, L., Kraakman, R. & Triantis, G. (2000). Stock pyramids, cross-ownership and dual class equity:

    The mechanisms and agency costs of separating control from cash-flow rights. In R. Morck (Ed.),Concentrated Corporate Ownership (pp. 295315), NBER.

    6

    154 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    27/31

    Benou, G., & Madura, J. (2005). High tech acquisitions, firm specific characteristics and the role ofinvestment bank advisors. Journal of High Technology Management Research, 16, 101120.

    Bigelli, M., & Mengoli, S. (2004). Sub-optimal acquisition decision under a majority shareholder system.

    Journal of Management and Governance, 8, 373405.Boyd, B. K. (1995). CEO duality and firm performance: A contingency model. Strategic Management

    Journal, 16, 301312.Bozec, Y., & Laurin, C. (2008). Large shareholder entrenchment and performance: Empirical evidence

    from Canada.Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 35(1 & 2), 2945.Brick, I. E., Palmon, O., & Wald, J. K. (2006). CEO compensation, director compensation, and firm

    performance: Evidence of cronyism?Journal of Corporate Finance, 12, 403423.Broshko, E. B. & Li, K. (2006). Playing by the rules: Comparing principles-based and rules-based

    corporate governance in Canada and the U.S. Canadian Investment Review, 19, 1823.Brown, S. J., & Warner, J. B. (1985). Using daily stock returns: The case of event studies.Journal of

    Financial Economics, 14, 331.Bushman, R. M., Indjejikian, R. S., & Smith, A. (1996). CEO compensation: The role of individual

    performance evaluation.Journal of Accounting and Economics, 21, 161193.

    Byrd, J. W., & Hickman, K. A. (1992). Do outside directors monitor managers? Evidence from tender

    offer bids.Journal of Financial Economics, 32, 195221.Cascino, S., Pugliese, A., Mussolino, D., & Sansone, C. (2010). The influence of family ownership on the

    quality of accounting information.Family Business Review, 23(3), 246265.Chang, S. C., Wu, W. Y., & Wong, Y. J. (2010). Family control and stock market reactions to innovation

    announcements.British Journal of Management, 21, 152170.Charitou, A., Louca, C., & Panayides, S. (2007). Cross-listing, bonding hypothesis and corporate

    governance.Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 34(7 & 8), 12811306.Chen, H. L., & Hsu, W. T. (2009). Family ownership, board independence, and R&D investment. Family

    Business Review, 22(4), 347362.Chrisman, J. J., Chua, J. H., & Steier, L. P. (2002). The influence of national culture and family

    involvement on entrepreneurial perceptions and performance at the state level.Entrepreneurship:

    Theory and Practice, 26(4), 113130.Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J., & Lang, L. H. P. (2000). The separation of ownership and control in

    East Asian corporations.Journal of Financial Economics, 58, 81112.Claessens, S., Djankov, S., Fan, J., & Lang, L. H. P. (2002). Disentangling the incentive and

    entrenchment effects of large shareholders.Journal of Finance, 57, 27412771.Connelly, B. L., Hoskisson, R. E., Tihanyi, L., & Certo, S. T. (2010). Ownership as a form of corporate

    governance.Journal of Management Studies, 47(8), 15611589.Core, J. E., Holthausen, R. W., & Larcker, D. F. (1999). Corporate governance, chief executive officer

    compensation, and firm performance.Journal of Financial Economics, 51, 371406.Cronqvist, H., & Nilsson, M. (2003). Agency costs of controlling minority shareholders. Journal of

    Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 38, 695719.Dalton, D. R., Daily, C. M., Ellstrand, A. E., & Johnson, J. L. (1998). Meta-analytic reviews of board

    composition, leadership structure, and financial performance. Strategic Management Journal, 19,269290.

    Datta, D. K., Pinches, G. E., & Narayanan, V. K. (1992). Factors influencing wealth creation frommergers and acquisitions: A meta-analysis. Strategic Management Journal, 13, 6784.

    Datta, S., Iskandar-Datta, M., & Raman, K. (2001). Executive compensation and corporate acquisitiondecisions.Journal of Finance, 56(6), 22992336.

    Doidge, C., Karolyi, G. A., & Stulz, R. (2004). Why are foreign firms listed in the US worth more?Journal of Financial Economics, 71, 205239.

    Dong, M., Hirschleifer, D., Richardson, S., & Teoh, S. H. (2006). Does investor misevaluation drive thetakeover market?Journal of Finance, 61(2), 725762.

    Duggal, R., & Millar, J. A. (1999). Institutional ownership and firm performance: The case of bidder

    returns.Journal of Corporate Finance, 5

    , 103117.Eckbo, E., & Thorburn, K. (2000). Gains to bidder firms revisited: Domestic and foreign acquisitions inCanada.Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 35(1), 125.

    Family firms and high technology Mergers & Acquisitions 155

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    28/31

    Faccio, M., & Lang, L. H. P. (2002). The ultimate ownership of western European corporations.Journalof Financial Economics, 65, 365395.

    Faccio, M., & Stolin, D. (2006). Expropriation vs. proportional sharing in corporate acquisitions.Journal

    of Business, 79(3), 14131444.Faccio, M., McConnell, J., & Stolin, D. (2006). Returns to acquirers of listed and unlisted targets.Journal

    of Financial Quantitative Analysis, 41, 197220.Faleye, O., & Huson, M. (2002). Understanding acquisition returns: The role of corporate governance.

    Paper presented at the 2002 Financial Management Association Annual Meeting, San AntonioTexas, October 1719.

    Feito-Ruiz, I., & Menedez-Requejo, S. (2010). Family firm mergers and acquisitions in different legalenvironments. Family Business Review, 23(1), 6075.

    Gadhoum, Y. (2006). Power of ultimate controlling owners: A survey of Canadian landscape.Journal ofManagement and Governance, 10, 179204.

    Gomez-Mejia, L. R., Haynes, K., Nunez-Nickel, M., Jacobson, K., & Moyano-Fuentes, J. (2007). Socioemotional wealth and business risks in family controlled firms: Evidence from Spanish olive oilmills. Administrative Science Quarterly, 52, 106137.

    Gomez-Mejia, L. R., Makri, M., & Kintana, M. L. (2010). Diversification decisions in family-controlled

    firms.Journal of Management Studies, 47(2), 223252.Gregory, A. (2005). The long run abnormal performance of UK acquirers and the free cash flow

    hypothesis.Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 32(5&6), 777814.Hagedoorn, J., & Duysters, G. (2002). The effect of mergers and acquisitions on the technological

    performance of companies in a high-tech environment. Technology Analysis and StrategicManagement, 14(1), 6885.

    He, L. (2008). Do founders matter? A study of executive compensation, governance structure and firmperformance.Journal of Business Venturing, 23, 257279.

    Holmen, M., & Knopf, J. D. (2004). Minority shareholder protections and the private benefits of controlfor Swedish mergers.Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 39, 167191.

    James, H. (1999). Owner as manager, extended horizons and the family firm.International Journal of the

    Economics of Business, 6, 4156.Jensen, M. C. (1986). Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance, and takeovers. AmericanEconomic Review, 76, 323329.

    Jensen, M. C. (1993). Modern industrial revolution, exit, and the failure of internal control systems.Journal of Finance, 48, 831880.

    Jensen, M. C. (2005). Agency costs of overvalued firms. Financial Management, 34(1), 519.Jensen, M. C., & Meckling, W. H. (1976). Theory of the firm: Managerial behavior, agency costs and

    ownership structure.Journal of Financial Economics, 3(4), 305360.

    Kang, E., & Zardkoohi, A. (2005). Board leadership structure and firm performance. CorporateGovernance: An International Review, 13(6), 785799.

    King, M., & Santor, E. (2008). Family values: Ownership structure, performance and capital structure ofCanadian firms. Journal of Banking & Finance, 32(11), 24232432.

    Kohers, N. & Kohers, T. (2000). The value creation potential of high-tech mergers.Financial AnalystsJournal, 56, 4050.

    Kohers, N. & Kohers, T. (2001). Takeovers of technology firms: expectations vs. reality, FinancialManagement, 30, 3554.

    La Porta, R., Lopez-De-Silanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (1999). Corporate ownership around the world.Journalof Finance, 54, 471517.

    Lambert, R. A., Larcker, D. F., & Verrecchia, R. E. (1991). Portfolio considerations in valuing executivecompensation.Journal of Accounting Research, 29, 129149.

    Lang, L. H. P., Stulz, R. M., & Walking, R. A. (1991). A test of the free cash flow hypothesis: The case ofbidder returns.Journal of Financial Economics, 29, 315335.

    Lubatkin, M. H., Schultze, W. S., Ling, Y., & Dino, R. N. (2005). Commentary: the effects of parental

    altruism on the governance of family-managed firms. Journal of Organizational Behavior, 26

    ,313330.Maury, B. (2006). Family ownership and firm performance: Empirical evidence from western European

    156 P. Andreet al.

  • 7/21/2019 Family Firms and High Technology Mergers and Acquisitions

    29/31

    Miller, D., Le Breton-Miller, I., & Lester, R. H. (2010). Family ownership and acquisition behavior inpublicly-traded companies. Strategic Management Journal, 31, 201223.

    Moeller, S. B., & Schlingemann, F. P. (2005). Global diversification and bidder gains: A comparisonbetween cross-border and domestic acquisitions.Journal of Banking & Finance, 29, 533564.

    Moeller, S. B., Schlingemann, F. P., & Stulz, R. M. (2004). Firm size and the gains from acquisitions.

    Journal of Financial Economics, 73(2), 201.Morck, R., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1988). Management ownership and market valuation: An

    empirical analysis. Journal of Financial Economics, 20, 293315.Pedersen, T., & Thomsen, S. (2003). Ownership structure and value of the largest European firms: The

    importance of owner identity.Journal of Management and Governance, 7, 2555.Perez-Gonzalez, F. (2006). Inherited control and firm performance. The American Economic Review,

    96(5), 15591588.Ranft, A. L., & Lord, M. D. (2000). Acquiring new knowledge: The role of retaining human capital in

    acquisitions of high tech firms.Journal of High Technology Management Research, 11(2), 295319.Rau, P. R., & Vermaelen, T. (1998). Glamour, value and the post-acquisition performance of acquiring

    firms.Journal of Financial Economics, 49, 223253.

    Sanchez-Ballesta, J. P., & Garca-Meca, E. (2007). A meta-analytic vision of the effect of ownership

    structure on firm performance. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 15(5), 879893.Sciascia, S., & Mazzola, P. (2008). Family involvement in ownership and management: Exploring

    nonlinear effects on performance. Family Business Review, 21(4), 331345.Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1989). Management entrenchment: The case of manager-specific

    investments.Journal of Financial Economics, 25(1), 123139.Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R. W. (1997). A survey of corporate governance. Journal of Finance, 52,

    737783.Smith, B., & Amoako-Adu, B. (1999). Management succession and financial performance of family

    controlled firms.Journal of Corporate Finance, 5, 341368.Subrahmanyam, V., Rangan, N., & Rosenstein, S. (1997). The role of outside directors in bank

    acquisitions.Financial Management, 26, 2336.

    Tsai, K. H., & Wang, J. C. (2008). External technology acquisition and firm performance: A longitudinalstudy. Journal of Business Venturing, 23, 91112.

    Villalonga, B., & Amit, R. (2006). How do family ownership, control and management affect firm value?Journal of Financial Economics, 80, 385417.

    Wong, Y. J., Chang, S. C., & Chen, L. Y. (2010). Does a family-controlled firms perform better incorporate venturing. Corporate Governance: An International Review, 18(3), 175