fareshare_specialissue2014

Upload: hamedarif

Post on 02-Jun-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    1/8

    Celebrating FARE Achievements

    SharWhatsnside

    This special issue ofFARE Shareshowcasesaccomplishments withinhe department in recentmonths. This includesawards bestowedpon FARE faculty andtudents by the Canadian

    Agricultural EconomicsSociety (CAES). TheUniversity of Guelphalso recently named twoew University Research

    Professors from within theFARE department JohnCranfeld and SpencerHenson in recognition ofheir outstanding researchfforts. Some of theirecent work is featuredn this edition. Finally, we

    ighlight developmentsat the Institute for theAdvanced Study of Foodand Agricultural Policy.

    Contact:

    Getu HailuEditor, FARE Share

    [email protected]

    The FARE Share Newslettereatures research and analysis

    rom faculty and students in thenstitute for the Advanced Study of

    Food and Agricultural Policy in theDepartment of Food, Agriculturalnd Resource Economics (FARE).

    Special IssSeptember 2

    FARE Professor Alfons Weersink was recently

    awarded the title Fellow of the Canadian Agricultural

    Economics Society (CAES). This honour recognizes

    his continuous and distinguished contributions to the

    agricultural economics profession and the institutions

    of Canadian agricultural economics.

    Over the past few years, I have written a letter of

    support for individuals selected to be fellows of the

    Canadian Agricultural Economics Society. In myopinion, none of these individuals deserved the honour

    of being selected as a fellow more than Alfons, said

    an external reviewer in a letter of support.

    Weersink joined the University of Guelph in 1989

    after completing his Ph.D. at Cornell University.

    Among other things, his research examines the

    effectiveness of agri-environmental policies. He

    has won several awards for his work, including

    recognition for outstanding articles in the Canadian

    Journal of Agricultural Economics, theReview of

    Agricultural Economics and theAustralian Journal of

    Agricultural Economics.

    While Professor Weersink has been a most prolic

    researcher, he is also one of the departments best

    teachers and has always maintained a full teaching

    load, said Alan Ker, former Chair, FARE. His

    overall evaluation by students has never been less than

    four out of ve on a point scale.

    Of special note, is that much of Weersinks research

    has been done in conjunction with graduate students.

    Alfons has supervised 10 Ph.D. students and 36

    M.Sc. students. Most impressively, almost all of these

    students have produced a publication in a refereed

    academic journal.

    One student commented: Professor Weersink i

    one of the best, if not the best, instructor I have

    in university. He is very approachable and teach

    the course material very well. I would recomme

    his class to anyone who asks.

    Weersink is also commended for his work outsi

    the classroom.Alfons is an outstanding mentor

    younger faculty at FARE in a number of ways,

    says Getu Hailu, Associate Professor, FARE. Hhelps them to establish and further their careers

    and shine. Im absolutely delighted that my

    colleague Alfons has won this award.

    Weersink has made substantial contributions

    in the areas of teaching, research and service.

    The quantity of students that he has mentored

    and impacted over his 25-year career in terms

    of courses taught, membership on student

    committees, and students supervised is impressi

    Weersink has made signicant contributions

    to research on timely and important topics

    in the elds of agri-environmental policies,

    encompassing bioproducts, farm management

    practices, the food versus fuel debate and more.

    Weersink receives honou

    Picture at right:

    Alfons and his

    wife Maureen

    Excerpts from Prof. Alfons Weersink Named CAES Fellow,

    At Guelph, June 6, 2014.

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    2/8

    Canadian Agricultural EconomicSociety (CAES)Award Winners

    Outstanding Masters Thesis AwardWinning thesis: Tor Tolhurst, Department of FARE, University of Guelph, for the thesis

    entitled, Econometric Models of Crop Yields: Two Essays supervised by Alan Ker.

    Award description: Excellence in the Masters program and encourages the study of

    agricultural economics, resource economics and farm management at the Masters level

    Tolhurst received high praise from the review panel, including the following comment: I

    was already very impressed by the quality of the rst essay and that work alone would grant

    rst place among the three works that I read. The second essay by Tolhurst is even better than

    the rst, making Tolhursts thesis a far distant rst place in my opinion. Both essays have the

    potential to be published in good economic journals. In some departments, this work would

    be enough to grant the student a Ph.D. Congratulations to Tolhurst and his advisers.

    Tolhurt describes his award-winning thesis in the following way: This thesis is an

    investigation of econometric crop yield models divided into two essays. In the rst essay,

    I propose estimating a single heteroscedasticity coefcient for all counties within a crop-

    reporting district by pooling county-level crop yield data in a two-stage estimation process.

    In the context of crop insurance where heteroscedaticity has signicant economic

    implications I demonstrate the pooling approach provides economically and statistically

    signicant improvements in rating crop insurance contracts over contemporary methods. In

    the second essay, I propose a new method for measuring the rate of technological change

    in crop yields. To date the agricultural economics literature has measured technological

    change exclusively at the mean; in contrast, the proposed model can measure the rate of

    technological change in endogenously dened yield subpopulations. I nd evidence of

    different rates of technological change in yield subpopulations, which leads to interesting

    questions about the effect of technological change on agricultural production.

    UndergraduateBook PrizeAwardFARE Winner: Rachael Vriezen

    Award description:

    Outstanding undergraduate

    student in agricultural

    economics, farm management

    or a closely related eld

    of study. Each University

    establishes its own criteria.

    The winners receive a cash

    award from CAES in addition to

    a complementary membership.

    FARE Winner: Tor Tolhurst (left)

    2

    FARE faculty and students reached the podium many times

    during the CAES awards ceremony held in Vancouver on

    May 31, 2014.The annual awards recognize and encourage

    excellence in agricultural economics and related elds. FAREs

    own Alan Ker, Alfons Weersink, Rakhal Sarker, Rachael Vriezen

    and Tor Tolhurst were all recognized for their achievements.

    One of the top 50 universities in the worldThe University of Guelph is ranked 24thin agriculture and forestry in

    the world, according to the 2014 QS World University Rankings. In

    fact, the University of Guelph is the only Canadian university to rank

    among the 30 top universities in the world in agriculture and forestry.

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    3/8

    Publication ofEnduring Quality AwardWinning article: Weersink, A., S. Clark, C.G. Turvey, and R. Sarker.

    1999. The Effect of Agricultural Policy on Farmland Values. Land

    Economics 75: 425-39.

    Award description: A publication by a CAES member that has had

    a signicant impact on agricultural, environmental or resource

    economics in Canada and has been available for 10 years or more.

    Entries are judged on the basis of the enduring quality of their effect

    on agricultural, environmental and resource economics in Canada.

    According to nominators Brady Deaton and John Craneld: The

    paper provided the infrastructure for ongoing research and discussionssurrounding the extent to which government payments are capitalized

    into farmland values, and the contemporary debate regarding the extent to

    which the targeted beneciaries of government payments i.e., producers

    capture intended benets.

    Subsequent to its publication, their paper received 101 citations (according

    to Google Scholar). Moreover, these citations have continued unabated

    since publication, including 35 citations since 2010.

    This paper will continue to provide a compass for researchers and policy

    makers trying to measure and understand the effect of government

    payments on farmland values. Weersink et al. (1999) is an article of

    enduring quality and is therefore deserving of the 2014 CAES Publication

    of Enduring Quality Award.

    Outstanding JournalArticle AwardWinning article: Rude, J. and A. Ker. 2013. Transfer

    Efciency of Margin-Based Programs. Canadian

    Journal of Agricultural Economics 61: 509-529.

    Award description: Achievement in agricultural

    economics, resource economics and farm

    management for articles appearing in the Canadian

    Journal of Agricultural Economicsin 2013.

    The abstract of the award-winning article clearly highlig

    the value of the research: AgriStability, Canadas majo

    farm support and business risk management program,has been in place since 2007. As with most agricultural

    insurance programs, AgriStability creates opposing

    incentives where moral hazard and misallocation effects

    discourage production while the risk reduction effects

    encourage production. We investigate the relative size

    of these effects to determine both the degree to which

    production is distorted and the percentage of governmen

    transfer that remains with the producer. Our results

    indicate mild but differential effects across crops. We n

    roughly 45% of program payments remains with primar

    producers. These ndings are of particular interest becau

    of their World Trade Organization implications.

    3

    FARE winners: Associate Professor

    Rakhal Sarker (left) & Professor

    Alfons Weersink (centre)

    FARE Winner:

    Professor Alan Ker (left)

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    4/8

    Paying a premium forspecialty eggsBy: John Craneld, University Research Professor in the Economics oAgri-Food Markets and Policy; Professor and Chair, FARE

    4

    Increasing consumerawareness of animal welfare

    issues is impacting how eggsare produced and marketed.Some jurisdictions have passed legislation prohibiting the use

    of conventional cages and requiring that hens be housed in

    alternative systems, while a growing number of food retailers and

    manufacturers require eggs they sell/use to come from alternative

    housing systems. While the vast majority of eggs sold in Canada arestill produced in conventional cages it is expected that demand for

    eggs from enhanced animal welfare production systems will grow

    in Canada.

    The relative immaturity of this specialty egg market means

    that consumer acceptance and willingness to pay for eggs from

    enhanced animal welfare production systems is still poorly

    understood in Canada. For this reason, we undertook research that

    sought to generate new economic knowledge that helps to inform

    industry stakeholders regarding consumer acceptance and valuation

    of eggs from enhanced animal welfare production systems, and the

    potential size of the market for such eggs.

    The specic objectives of this study were: To understand the socio-demographic and psychographic factors

    associated with consumer acceptance of eggs from animal

    welfare enhanced production systems, including enriched and

    cage-free systems

    To identify and measure the size of consumer segments with a

    high degree of acceptance of eggs from different enhanced animal

    welfare production systems

    To measure consumers stated willingness-to-pay (WTP) for eggs

    from different enhanced animal welfare production systems

    Explore how stated WTP varies across segments of consumers,

    as well as segments of consumers with differing actual

    purchase behaviours of eggs from enhanced animal welfare

    production systems

    Experiments provideeconomic knowledge on

    specialty egg marketTwo choice experiments (CE) were designed. In each CE,

    respondents were presented with a set of choice tasks. In each

    choice task, the respondent was presented with eggs embodying

    different attributes, and they had to indicate which, if any, they

    would purchase. The attributes of eggs in CE I were: price; hou

    systems; organization that veries the housing systems; Omega

    and shell colour. The attributes of eggs in CE II were: price;whether hens had access to the outdoors; whether cages were u

    in the housing system; and the availability of nest boxes, perche

    for roosting and scratch pads for dust bathing.

    The effect of information on consumers purchase behaviour

    towards eggs from enhanced animal welfare production system

    was also investigated by including two information treatments i

    each CE. In treatment 1, a description of the housing systems w

    provided to respondents. In treatment 2, in addition to dening

    the housing system, respondents received scientically based

    information regarding the consequences of each housing system

    on: hens health; hens ability to exhibit natural behaviours;

    affective states; and the impact of housing systems on environm

    Structured this way, the two information treatments will reveal

    whether scientically valid information affects consumer WTP,

    if so, how. Note that WTP is not the price for the product, but ra

    the premium associated with that attribute.

    Providing detailed information aboutthe consequences of the housingsystems on hen health and welfarereduces consumer valuation of eggsfrom free-run and free-range.

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    5/8

    An on-line survey (Ipsos i-Say on-line panel) was conducted

    with a sample representative of the Canadian population in

    terms of demographic characteristics. Respondents were

    generally concerned about animal welfare, but did not consider

    animal welfare among the top issues when purchasing food. Of

    the three aspects of animal welfare, namely basic health and

    functioning, natural behaviour, and affective states, basic health

    and functioning was viewed as most important. Respondents

    knowledge of animal production was limited, and they believed

    that scientic evidence, rather than ethical or moral considerations,

    should be used to determine how farm animals are treated.

    The results from the CE were informative. In CE I treatment 1,respondents were willing to pay a premium of $1.147 ($0.863

    in treatment 2) per dozen for free-range and $0.550 ($0.276

    in treatment 2) per dozen for free-run systems. The premiums

    for these two housing systems were higher than the premiums

    for Omega-3 fatty acid enhanced eggs, or white/brown colour

    attribute. However, eggs from an enriched cage system did not

    induce a positive premium. In fact, eggs from a system labeled

    as enriched cage system had a discount of $0.313 per dozen in

    treatment 1 and $0.331 per dozen in treatment 2. For verication

    attributes, respondents were willing to pay a premium of $0.693 in

    treatment 1 (or $0.599 in treatment 2) if government veries the

    housing systems, $0.156 (or $0.179 in treatment 2) for a third-

    party certier verication and $0.218 (or $0.112 in treatment 2)for industry certier.

    Consumers value absence

    of cagesIn CE II, eggs from systems where hens had access to the outdoors

    yielded the highest WTP ($0.634 in treatment 1 and $0.571 in

    treatment 2) followed by the presence of nest boxes, perches for

    roosting and scratch pads for dust bathing ($0.451 in treatment 1

    and $0.438 in treatment 2), and the cage-free attribute ($0.191 in

    treatment 1 and $0.078 in treatment 2). The latter result suggests a

    premium for the absence of cages in the housing systems; viewedanother way, the presence of cages in the housing system would

    result in a discount. This is an important result and it aligns with

    the results from treatment 1; it suggests that consumers value the

    absence of cages in hen housing. Respondents were willing to pay

    $0.005 in treatment 1 ($0.004 in treatment 2) for every square inc

    increase in a housing system.

    Comparing the WTP results from two information treatments in

    each CE allows one to assess the effect of information. In CE I,

    the provision of additional information in treatment 2 resulted in

    lower (and the difference was statistically signicant) premiums

    for eggs from free-run and free-range housing systems (compared

    to treatment 1). Across the two treatments, there were no other

    signicant differences in WTP for the other attributes in choicetreatment 1. In CE II, the WTP for the cage-free attribute decrease

    in treatment 2, but not for the other attributes. As there were no

    differences in sample characteristics across treatments, we may

    attribute the disparity in WTPs across the treatments to difference

    in the information that was provided. Consequently, it is conclude

    that information on the consequences of each housing system on

    hen health and welfare reduces consumer valuation of eggs from

    free-run and free-range systems (and their valuation of the absenc

    of cages generally).

    Study shows producers need t

    communicate with consumersAlthough consumers have limited knowledge about animal

    production systems and animal welfare, they are sensitive to

    information about housing systems. It is important for egg

    producers to communicate well with consumers. Providing

    detailed information about the consequences of the housing

    systems on hen health and welfare reduces consumer valuation

    of eggs from free-run and free-range. And while respondents

    value the absence of cages (or discount eggs from systems

    that use cages), this value is also reduced when information on

    the consequences of the system on hen health and welfare is

    presented to subjects. An important lesson from this is that use

    of the word cage (e.g., enriched cages) should be avoided lest theprice consumers would pay will be reduced.

    5

    While the vast majority of eggs sold inCanada are still produced in conventionalcages it is expected that demand for eggsfrom enhanced animal welfare productionsystems will grow in Canada.

    This work was completed in collaboration with Yiqing Lu, former M.Sc. student in FARE, and Tina Widowski, Professor in the Department of Animal and Poultry Science at

    the University of Guelph. A version of this report appears in the May 2014 issue of Canadian Poultry Magazine. The nancial support of the Ontario Ministry of Agriculture,

    Food and Rural Affairs and the Poultry Industry Council is gratefully acknowledged.

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    6/8

    The global rise of privatfood safety standardsBy: Spencer Henson, University Research Professor in Economics of Food,Health and Development; Professor, FARE

    The regulation of food safetyhas long been regarded as theresponsibility of government.Thus, countries like Canada have a wide array of acts and regulations

    that lay down requirements on how food is produced, processed

    and distributed with the aim of reducing the microbiological,

    chemical and physical risks that are potentially associated with

    food. Increasingly, however, the private sector nationally and

    internationally is establishing its own food safety standards. For

    some, the rise of these private standards presents a welcome sign that

    the food industry is being proactive in managing food safety. Others,however, have concerns over the ability of the private sector to

    effectively regulate itself, and about the impact of private standards

    on smaller rms and farms. This article looks at why private food

    safety standards have emerged and what they mean for the role of

    government in regulating food safety into the future.

    Three types of privatesafety standardsPrivate standards have become increasingly important in global

    agri-food value chains, progressively pervading both domestic

    business and international trade. One of the dening characteristics

    of private standards, particularly as they relate to food safety, isan increasing focus on the processes by which food is produced

    rather than the end product per se. In this respect, they mirror the

    increasing importance of process standards in public regulations,

    as increasingly seen with requirements for food processors to

    implement Hazard Analysis and Critical Control Point (HACCP)

    under regulations governing food hygiene.

    Within the broad array of private standards relating to food safety, it

    is possible to distinguish between three types of standard based on

    who sets them.Individual company standards are set by particular

    rms, usually large food retailers and food service operators, and

    adopted across their supply chains. The Loblaw Vendor Operating

    Standards and McDonalds Supplier QMS are examples in Canada.Collective national standardsare set by organizations that operate

    within national boundaries, including industry associations and non-

    governmental organizations (NGOs). Some of these standards are

    specically designed to establish claims about food from particular

    countries or regions. The various on-farm food safety programs in

    Canada, such as CanadaGAP, Canadian Quality Milk and Veried

    Beef Production, are examples. A third set of standards, collective

    international standards, are designed to be required or used by

    organizations in different countries. This frequently means that the

    organization setting the standard has international membership.

    GlobalGAP is perhaps the best-known example.

    Food safety standards, public and private, are fundamentally

    about establishing controls and conformance in the production,

    processing and distribution of food. Two questions need to be as

    to understand why private food safety standards have developed

    so rapidly in recent years. First, what are the drivers of increased

    controls along national and global agri-food value chains? Secon

    why is this need for control expressed in the form of a proliferati

    of private standards?

    Drivers for increasing control agri-food value chainsThere are four key drivers for increasing control in agri-food valchains. First, ongoing reforms of food safety regulatory systems

    are a response to real and/or perceived risks in food production,

    processing and distribution, which predominantly reect heighte

    consumer anxiety brought about by high-prole food safety crise

    Second, heightened interest among consumers and businesses in

    food production processes and changes in their conceptions of fo

    safety are reinforced by company competitive strategies around

    food safety and quality. Third, the globalization of food supply a

    increased role of coordination economies in dening competiven

    creates new risks and new challenges for value chain coordinatio

    and control. For example, over 80 per cent of fruit, 55 per cent o

    vegetables and 40 percent of sh and seafood consumed in Cana

    each year is imported. Fourth, responsibility for food safety has

    progressively been devolved from the state towards the private

    sector. Thus, the recently enacted Safe Food for Canadian Act ha

    specic provisions with respect to the responsibility of businesse

    regarding the safety of the food they supply.

    These four drivers combine to create an environment in which

    businesses are under more pressure to deliver food safety and to

    maintain the integrity of their brands. They need to do this in the

    of increasingly globalized and complex food supply chains that c

    across multiple regulatory jurisdictions.

    Going beyond government

    requirementsPrivate standards are frequently characterised as going beyond

    the requirements of government regulations. There are at least

    three different elements to this. First, private standards may set

    a higher standard for particular food product attributes, such as

    levels of pesticide residues or microbial pathogens. In other wor

    private standards may be seen as more stringent than regulations

    Second, private standards may increase the scope of activities th

    are regulated, whether vertically or horizontally. Increased vertic

    coverage means extending the span of control up and down the v

    chain. Increased horizontal coverage relates to including new

    For further information see: Henson, S.J. and Humphrey, J. (2009). The Impacts of Private Food Safety Standards on the Food Chain and on Public Standard-Setting Processes. FAO, 6

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    7/8

    elements that are not subject to government regulations. Third,

    private standards are much more specic about how to achieve the

    desired outcomes than is typical with regulations. In many cases,

    regulations lay down the basic parameters of a food safety system,

    while private standards elaborate on what this system should look

    like in order to be effective.

    In addition to reducing risk, private standards also provide businesses

    with a basis for product differentiation, although this is less common

    in the arena of food safety than with the environment or animal

    welfare, for example. Standards can be adopted to support claims to

    consumers that products have certain extrinsic characteristics that

    reect the way in which they have been produced. Foods producedand labelled using organic methods are an example.

    The legitimacy of privatestandardsAt the heart of the ongoing debate about the role and implications of

    private food safety standards are questions about their legitimacy,

    both in general and in comparison to government regulations.

    Anyone can create a new standard, and businesses can then decide

    whether or not to use it. But when standards begin to have wide

    impact, as with GlobalGAP and national equivalents such as

    CanadaGAP, questions begin to be raised about the extent to which

    these are effective, fair and reasonable.A key concern in ongoing debates about the legitimacy of private

    food safety standards is whether they are science-based and bring

    about safer food. Intuitively, private rms would be unlikely to

    engage in the setting and/or adoption of standards that impose costs

    on the value chains in which they operate unless these brought

    about greater protection than prevailing regulations. At the same

    time, it is clear that there is considerable overlap between regulatory

    requirements and private standards, and that one of the key roles

    of private standards is to dene a coherent and auditable roadmap

    towards regulatory compliance. In this sense, the strict dichotomy

    between government regulations and private standards may be

    somewhat false.

    Cost of food safetymanagementAs with regulations, compliance with private food safety standards

    inevitably imposes costs on agri-food value chains. Thus, we

    observe winners and losers in a world where private standards are

    playing an increasing role in governing food safety. Key concerns

    here relate to the ability of smaller rms and farms to comply,

    and the extent to which private standards are used effectively by

    dominant players, such as large retailers and food service operators,

    to push the cost of food safety management down the value chain.

    Private standards, furthermore, are likely to have profound impactson the structure of agri-food value chains. For example, to the exten

    that there are economies of scale in compliance and/or larger rms

    are better able to access nance and other resources, compliance

    with private food safety standards is likely to induce processes of

    consolidation and concentration.

    Whilst regulations have long been seen as a key way in which

    national governments provide protection to their populations

    against the risks inherent in food, it is also recognised that they can

    impede trade. Thus, the international community has established

    rights and responsibilities for nation states in promulgating food

    safety regulations, which aim to minimise adverse impacts ontrade whilst offering the needed protection for consumers, throughthe Agreement on Sanitary and Phytosanitary Measures under the

    World Trade Organization (WTO). Many argue that private food

    safety standards fall outside of the purview of the WTO.

    Quick response toemerging issuesIt is argued that one of the key advantages of organizations setting

    private standards is their ability to evolve and adapt requirements

    quickly in response to emerging issues. In contrast, regulators are

    often criticised for the slow speed at which they promulgate new

    or revised regulatory requirements. It is important to recognise,however, that regulators are bound to established procedures, the aim

    of which is to ensure accountability and the ability of stakeholders

    to provide input to the regulatory process. Many organizations

    that establish private food safety standards only allow and/or seek

    input from selected (usually industry) stakeholders, with little

    direct voice for consumers and marginalised groups such as smallbusinesses and farms.

    As outlined above, the continued evolution of private food safety

    standards raises important issues for those interested in the safety

    of food, and also for the welfare of those engaged along agri-food

    value chains from consumers back to farmers. More profoundly,

    however, it raises questions over the role of government in regulatin

    the safety of food. Thus, what is the role of public regulators in aworld where the private sector is developing and implementing

    food safety standards that are stricter than regulations? Furthermore

    should regulators embrace private food safety standards, for exampl

    by taking them into account in assessing the risk a particular food

    business poses, or even encouraging compliance? These are difculquestions for government and ones that the Federal government in

    Canada is just beginning to ask. Thus, whilst the various documents

    associated with the Safe Food for Canadian Act demonstrate that the

    Canadian Food Inspection Agency (CFIA) recognises the emergenc

    of private food safety standards, it is not clear that they have a clear

    idea yet as to how to respond.

    What is the role of public regulators in a world where theprivate sector is developing and implementing food safetystandards that are stricter than regulations?

    7

  • 8/10/2019 FAREShare_SpecialIssue2014

    8/8

    http://www.uoguelph.ca/far

    University of Guelph

    Department of Food, Agricultural anResource Economics (FARE)

    J.D. MacLachlan Building

    Guelph, Ontario, Canada N1G 2W1

    Telephone: 519-824-4120 x53625

    Facsimile: 519-767-1510

    uoguelph.ca/fare

    Excerpts from the OAC website

    Institute to co-host CanadianAgriculture Policy ConferenceThe fth annual Canadian Agriculture Policy Conference hosted by the Canadian Agricultural

    Economics Society (CAES) will be co-hosted by the Institute for Advanced Study of Food and

    Agricultural Policy and the Canadian Agri-Food Policy Institute (CAPI). The event will be held from

    January 28-30, 2015 at the Chateau Laurier in Ottawa.

    The conference is considered the premier national policy outlook for the agri-food sector. The gener

    theme for this years event is Keeping Up with Consumers: Understanding the Policy Implications

    of a Changing Landscape. Stay tuned for more details.

    Leading ageconomistsguide InstituteThe Institute for Advanced

    tudy of Food and Agricultural

    Policy is an integral part of

    ARE, bringing together leading

    oices and researchers in

    gricultural economics.What makes the Institute

    nique is that it is built solely on

    cademia, harnessing the brain

    rust of leading agricultural

    conomists. The Institute

    ecently formalized its structure,

    nnouncing FARE Professor

    Alan Ker as Director and FARE

    Research Associate Kenneth

    Poon as Associate Director. They

    re supported by 10 Fellows who

    end signifcant expertise and

    epth to the organization.

    This group includes:

    ohn Craneld,University of Guelph

    Brady Deaton, Jr.,University of Guelph

    effrey Dorfman,University of Georgia

    Barry K. Goodwin,

    North Carolina State University

    Getu Hailu,University of Guelph

    ill E. Hobbs,University of Saskatchewan

    Ken McEwan,University of

    Guelph-Ridgetown Campus

    Michael von Massow,University of Guelph

    ames Rude,University of Alberta

    Alfons Weersink,University of Guelph

    Canadian Agriculture Policy ConferenceJanuary 28-30, 2015

    Chateau Laurier, Ottawa

    John Craneld is new FARE ChairProfessor John Craneld

    has been appointed as

    the new Chair of FARE

    effective September 1,

    2014. I am honoured thatthe department, college and wider communityexpressed its support and condence in me

    serving as Chair in the department, says

    Craneld.FARE has gone through a period

    of considerable growth and renewal in the

    last ve years. My aim is to work to further

    enhance the high quality of our educational

    and research activities, and engagement with

    the broader community.

    Craneld has been a faculty member with

    the department since 2001 and has served as

    the graduate program coordinator since July

    2010. His research focuses on the economics

    of consumer behaviour and demand analysis

    at the individual, household and market level,

    innovation in the agri-food and biotechnology

    sectors and economic history. He has publishe

    over 50 articles in peer-reviewed journals.

    Craneld is an alumnus of the University ofGuelph receiving his Bachelor of Science

    in Agriculture in 1993 and his M.Sc. in

    Agricultural Economics in 1995. He then

    attended Purdue University for his Ph.D.,

    which he completed in 1999.

    I am thrilled to have Professor Craneld

    step into this important leadership role, and I

    look forward to working with him in this new

    capacity, says Robert Gordon, Dean, Ontario

    Agricultural College (OAC). A sincere thank

    you also goes to Professor Alan Ker for his

    considerable contributions as Chair of thedepartment during the last ve years.