fiscal consolidation in a disinflationary environment: price...

42
Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price- vs. Quantity-Based Measures Evi Pappa Rana Sajedi Eugenia Vella § January 2016 PRELIMINARY DRAFT Abstract An important feature of the current economic conditions in the EU, which challenges the design and implementation of macroeconomic policy, is inflation uncertainty. With monetary policy at the zero lower bound, and inflation well below its target, a key issue for policy makers is the eect this has on the transmission of fiscal policy. We aim to address this question, in particular comparing the eects of price-based and quantity-based fiscal instruments. In this paper we focus on the public wage bill, and consider a DSGE model in which the government can consolidate their debt through reductions in the public wage or public employment. We find that the low-inflation environment eliminates the expansionary eects of the reduction in the public wage bill in both cases, with increased debt-to GDP levels during the consolidation process. Our results also indicate that consolidation through cuts in public wages takes less time than through cuts in public employment. JEL classification: E32, E62 Keywords: fiscal consolidation, public wage bill, zero lower bound, un- employment Acknowledgements. The views expressed here in no way reflect those of the Bank of England. Corresponding author: Department of Economics, European University Institute, Via della Piazzuola 43, 50133 Florence, Italy, Tel: (+39) 055 4685 908, e-mail: [email protected] European University Institute and Bank of England. e-mail: [email protected] § Department of Economics, University of Sheeld. e-mail:e.vella@sheeld.ac.uk 1

Upload: others

Post on 18-Sep-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary

Environment: Price- vs. Quantity-Based Measures

Evi Pappa† Rana Sajedi‡ Eugenia Vella§

January 2016

PRELIMINARY DRAFT

Abstract

An important feature of the current economic conditions in the EU, whichchallenges the design and implementation of macroeconomic policy, is inflationuncertainty. With monetary policy at the zero lower bound, and inflation wellbelow its target, a key issue for policy makers is the e↵ect this has on thetransmission of fiscal policy. We aim to address this question, in particularcomparing the e↵ects of price-based and quantity-based fiscal instruments.In this paper we focus on the public wage bill, and consider a DSGE modelin which the government can consolidate their debt through reductions in thepublic wage or public employment. We find that the low-inflation environmenteliminates the expansionary e↵ects of the reduction in the public wage bill inboth cases, with increased debt-to GDP levels during the consolidation process.Our results also indicate that consolidation through cuts in public wages takesless time than through cuts in public employment.

JEL classification: E32, E62

Keywords: fiscal consolidation, public wage bill, zero lower bound, un-employment

⇤Acknowledgements. The views expressed here in no way reflect those of the Bank of England.†Corresponding author: Department of Economics, European University Institute, Via della

Piazzuola 43, 50133 Florence, Italy, Tel: (+39) 055 4685 908, e-mail: [email protected]

European University Institute and Bank of England. e-mail: [email protected]

§

Department of Economics, University of She�eld. e-mail:e.vella@she�eld.ac.uk

1

carpeni
Typewritten Text
Copyright with the authors, 2016. Preliminary – please do not quote
carpeni
Typewritten Text
carpeni
Typewritten Text
Page 2: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

1 Introduction

An important feature of the current economic conditions in the EU, which challenges

the design and implementation of macroeconomic policy, is inflation uncertainty.

With monetary policy constrained by the zero lower bound (ZLB henceforth), in-

flation in the euro area has remained below the ECB’s medium-run objective for

some time. While some recent studies have looked at the impact of the ZLB on

fiscal policy, research on the di↵erential impact of inflation on di↵erent budgetary

items is limited. In this context, the aim of this paper is to examine the e↵ects

of alternative fiscal consolidation strategies to reduce the public wage bill, specifi-

cally comparing price-based measures and quantity-based measures, under di↵erent

inflation environments.

As seen in Figure 1, since 2012, the inflation rate across the euro area has been

trending downwards and still remains below the ECB’s 2% target. At the same

time, monetary policy easing has been subdued, with nominal interest rates at the

ZLB, and the e↵ects of unconventional measures, such as the recent asset purchases,

remaining uncertain.

This environment has important implications for fiscal policy. Firstly, low in-

flation is generally considered to make fiscal consolidation more di�cult. Indeed,

historically, periods of high inflation have been used to reduce debt-to-GDP ratios,

for example in many western countries following both the First and Second World

War (see Reinhart et al. 2015). From a theoretical point of view, low inflation re-

duces the growth in nominal GDP and, all else equal, raises deficit- and debt-to-GDP

ratios. Debt dynamics would be left unchanged if nominal interest rates fall by the

same magnitude as inflation, thus leaving real rates unchanged. Instead, when nom-

inal rates have hit the ZLB, falling inflation leads to rising real interest rates, making

it more di�cult to reduce government debt-to-GDP ratios.

Moreover, much of the literature, both theoretical and empirical, has found that

2

Page 3: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Figure 1: Inflation and Interest Rates in the Euro Area Source: ECB, Eurostat

fiscal multipliers are higher when monetary policy is constrained. In particular,

Eggertsson (2011) found that the government spending multiplier goes from below

0.5, to around 2.3 at the ZLB, and that tax multipliers even change sign and become

negative at the ZLB. Similar results are found in the studies of Christiano et al.

(2011), Coenen et al. (2012) and De Long and Summers (2012). Empirically, Ilzetzki

et al. (2013) corroborate these results, finding that government spending multipliers

are substantially higher in countries operating under fixed exchange rates. Nakamura

and Steinsson (2014) draw similar conclusions regarding the multiplier of military

spending, although their analysis is not a direct comparison of di↵erent monetary

regimes. Based on these principles, several papers discuss the potential role of fiscal

stimulus in alleviating a ZLB crisis: Correia et al. (2013) suggest an alternative

stimulus strategy to the use of government spending, based on consumption taxation,

and Rendahl (2015) focuses on amplification e↵ects in the labour market due to the

ZLB and how an expansionary fiscal policy can best exploit these. The converse of

these arguments is that attempting to carry out fiscal consolidation in a liquidity

trap can be very costly, and even self-defeating.

Another important way in which low inflation a↵ects fiscal policy is the fact that

3

Page 4: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

inflation shocks can be expected to have a di↵erent impact, both in terms of size

and timing, across di↵erent government revenue and expenditure categories. In line

with the research highlighted above, Jalil (2012) finds that the di↵erences between

the estimated multipliers of government spending and taxation can be explained

by the di↵erential response of monetary policy. Erceg and Linde (2013) find that

the magnitude of the output contraction induced by spending-based consolidation

is roughly three times larger when monetary policy is constrained by the ZLB than

when it is unconstrained. They also find that a tax-based consolidation is less costly

in the short-run than a spending-based consolidation, while the opposite is true

when monetary policy is unconstrained. McManus et al. (2014) find that the ZLB

has di↵erent e↵ects on di↵erent fiscal consolidation instruments, and should therefore

be considered when designing austerity packages.

One aspect of this comparison which has been overlooked is that the e↵ectiveness

of consolidation packages that focus on quantity-based measures instead of price-

based measures may be di↵erent depending on the inflation environment. Recent

austerity packages implemented in many European countries, like Greece and Spain,

have placed special emphasis on the reduction of the public wage bill. In that con-

text, reducing the wage bill via cutting wages (price-based measure) or reducing

public employees (quantity-based measure) may have a di↵erent budgetary impact

depending on the inflation environment. This paper aims to uncover the potential

e↵ect of a low-inflation environment on these alternative consolidation strategies.

To this end, we develop a DSGE model through which we can study the di↵eren-

tial e↵ects of quantity-based and price-based consolidation measures. In particular,

we consider a New-Keynesian model with nominal rigidities in the form of monopolis-

tic retailers facing price-stickiness. In order to build a complete model of the labour

market, we incorporate both search and matching frictions, leading to involuntary

unemployment, and an endogenous labour force participation decision, leading to

4

Page 5: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

voluntary unemployment. Finally, to study the e↵ects of the public wage bill, we

allow the government to hire public employees to produce a public good that is used

by private firms.

Following Erceg and Linde (2013) and Pappa et al. (2015), fiscal policy responds

to the deviation of the debt-to-GDP ratio from a target value, and fiscal consolidation

occurs when this target is hit by a negative shock. We focus attention on two fiscal

consolidation instruments on the part of the government: public wage cuts and public

vacancy cuts. We consider each instrument separately, assuming that if one is active,

the other remains fixed at its steady state value. We then repeat this experiment

when the economy faces low inflation due to a liquidity trap. This setup allows us to

compare, for a given consolidation volume, the e↵ects of the alternative consolidation

strategies in di↵erent environments.

In a low inflation environment, induced by a positive shock to the discount rate,

a much larger cut in the public wage bill is required to bring the debt-to-GDP ratio

to the desired level. The rise in the real interest rate when the ZLB constraint is

binding leads to a rise in public debt and, as a result, makes consolidation more

costly. The fall in demand following the discount rate shock creates a drag on the

private sector, meaning that the consolidation in this environment has large negative

e↵ects.

The remainder of the paper is organised follows. In Section 2, we provide the de-

tails of the model. Section 3 discusses the results of the di↵erent policy experiments.

Section 4 concludes.

2 The Model

We consider a DSGE model with search and matching frictions, endogenous labour

participation choice, and sticky prices in the short run. There are three types of firms

in the economy: (i) a public firm that produces a good that is used for productive

5

Page 6: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

and utility enhancing purposes, (ii) private competitive firms that use private inputs

and the public good to produce an inermediate good, and (iii) monopolistic retailers

that use the intermediate good to produce a final good. Price rigidities arise at the

retail level, while labour market frictions occur in the intermediate goods sector.

The representative household consists of private and public employees, unemployed,

and labour force non-participants. The government collects taxes and uses revenues

to finance the wages of public employees, the costs of opening new vacancies in the

public sector and the provision of unemployment benefits.

2.1 Labour markets

We consider search and matching frictions in both the private and public labour mar-

kets. In each period, jobs in each sector, j = p, g, are destroyed at a constant fraction

j and a measure m

j of new matches are formed. The evolution of employment in

each sector is thus given by:

n

jt+1 = (1� �

j)njt +m

jt (1)

We assume that �p> �

g in order to capture the fact that, in general, public employ-

ment is more permanent than private employment.

The new matches are given by:

m

jt = ⇢

jm(�

jt )↵(uj

t)1�↵ (2)

where the matching e�ciency, ⇢jm, can di↵er in the two sectors. From the match-

ing functions specified above we can define, for each sector j, the probability of a

jobseeker being hired, hjt , and of a vacancy being filled, fj

t :

hjt ⌘

m

jt

u

jt

(3)

6

Page 7: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

fjt ⌘

m

jt

jt

(4)

2.2 Households

The representative household consists of a continuum of infinitely lived agents. The

members of the household derive utility from leisure, which corresponds to the frac-

tion of members that are out of the labour force, lt, and a consumption bundle, cct,

defined as:

cct = [↵1(ct)↵2 + (1� ↵1)(y

gt )↵2 ]

1↵2

where ygt denotes a public good, taken as exogenous by the household, and ct is private

consumption. Following Neiss and Pappa (2005), we also allow for variable labour

e↵ort, et, which leads to separable disutility. The instantaneous utility function is

thus given by:

U(cct, lt) =cc

1�⌘t

1� ⌘

+ �l

1�'t

1� '

� �2e

1+'2t

1 + '2

where ⌘ is the inverse of the intertemporal elasticity of substitution, � > 0 is the

relative preference for leisure, and ' is the inverse of the Frisch elasticity of labour

supply. The elasticity of substitution between the private and public goods is given

by ⌘1�↵2

.1

At any point in time, a fraction n

pt (ng

t ) of the household members are private

(public) employees. Campolmi and Gnocchi (2014) and Bruckner and Pappa (2012)

have added a labour force participation choice in New Keynesian models of equilib-

rium unemployment. Following Ravn (2008), the participation choice is modelled as

a trade-o↵ between the cost of giving up leisure and the prospect of finding a job. In

particular, the household chooses the fraction of the unemployed actively searching

for a job, ut, and the fraction which are out of the labour force and enjoying leisure,

1When this elasticity is greater than one, ct and ygt are substitutes, and when it is below onethey are complements. The Cobb-Douglas specification is obtained when it is equal to zero.

7

Page 8: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

lt, so that:

n

pt + n

gt + ut + lt = 1 (5)

The household chooses the fraction of jobseekers searching in each sector: a share st

of jobseekers look for a job in the public sector, while the remainder, (1 � st), seek

employment in the private sector. That is, ugt ⌘ stut and u

pt ⌘ (1� st)ut.2

The household owns the private capital stock, which evolves according to:

k

pt+1 = i

pt + (1� �

p)kpt �

!

2

k

pt+1

k

pt

� 1

◆2

k

pt (6)

where ipt is private investment, �p is a constant depreciation rate and !2

kpt+1

kpt� 1⌘2

k

pt

are adjustment costs.

The intertemporal budget constraint is given by:

(1+⌧c)ct+i

pt+

Bt+1⇡t+1

Rt

[rpt�⌧k(rpt��

p)]kpt+(1�⌧n)(w

ptn

pt et+w

gtn

gt )+$ut+Bt+⇧

pt�Tt

(7)

where ⇡t ⌘ pt/pt�1 is the gross inflation rate, wjt , j = p, g, are the real wages in the

two sectors, rpt is the real return on capital, $ denotes unemployment benefits, Bt is

the real government bond holdings, Rt is the gross nominal interest rate, ⇧pt are the

profits of the monopolistic retailers, discussed below, and ⌧c,⌧k, ⌧n, and T represent

taxes on private consumption, private capital, labour income and lump-sum taxes

respectively.

Thus the problem of the household is to choose ct, ut, st, npt+1, n

gt+1, k

pt+1and Bt+1

to maximise lifetime utility subject to the budget constraint, (7), the law of motion of

employment in each sector, (1), the law of motion of capital, (6), and the composition

of the household, (5). Details of the household’s optimisation, and the resulting first

order conditions, is provided in Appendix A.1. For use below, we define the marginal

2For simplicity, we will abstract from variable labour e↵ort in the public sector.

8

Page 9: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

value of an additional private sector employee as:

V

Hnpt = �ctw

pt et(1� ⌧n)� �l

�'t + (1� �

p)�npt (8)

= �ctwpt et(1� ⌧n)� �l

�'t + (1� �

p)�Et(VHnpt+1)

where �ct and �npt are the lagrange multipliers on the budget constraint and the law

of motion of private employment respectively.

2.3 Production

2.3.1 Intermediate goods firms

Intermediate goods are produced with a Cobb-Douglas technology:

y

pt = (Atn

pt et)

1��(kpt )�(ygt )

⌫ (9)

where At is a labour augmenting productivity factor, kpt and n

pt are private capital

and labour inputs, et is the e↵ort intensity of labour, and y

gt is the public good used

in productive activities, taken as exogenous by the firms. The parameter ⌫ regulates

how the public input a↵ects private production: when ⌫ is zero, the government good

is unproductive.

Since current hires give future value to intermediate firms, the optimization prob-

lem is dynamic and hence firms maximize the discounted value of future profits. The

number of workers currently employed, npt , is taken as given and the employment

decision concerns the number of vacancies posted in the current period, �pt , so as

to employ the desired number of workers next period, n

pt+1.

3 Firms also decide

the amount of the private capital, kpt , to be rented from the household at rate r

pt .

3Firms adjust employment by varying the number of workers (extensive margin) rather than thenumber of hours per worker. According to Hansen (1985), most of the employment fluctuationsarise from movements in this margin.

9

Page 10: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

The problem of an intermediate firm with n

pt currently employed workers consists of

choosing k

pt and �pt to maximize:

Q

p(npt ) = max

kpt ,�pt

xt(Atnpt )

1��(kpt )�(ygt )

⌫� w

ptn

pt et � r

pt k

pt � �

pt + Et

⇤t,t+1Qp(np

t+1)⇤

(10)

where xt is the relative price of intermediate goods, is a utility cost associated with

posting a new vacancy, and ⇤t,t+1 = �

�ct+1

�ctis the discount factor. The maximization

takes place subject to the private employment transition equation, where the firm

takes the probability of the vacancy being filled as given:

n

pt+1 = (1� �

p)npt +

fpt �

pt (11)

The first-order conditions are:

xt�y

pt

k

pt

= r

pt (12)

fpt

= Et⇤t,t+1[xt+1(1� �)y

pt+1

n

pt+1

� w

pt+1et+1 + (1� �

p)

fpt+1

] (13)

According to (12) and (13) the value of the marginal product of private capital should

equal the real rental rate and the marginal cost of opening a vacancy should equal the

expected marginal benefit. The latter includes the marginal productivity of labour

minus the wage plus the continuation value, knowing that with probability �p the

match can be destroyed.

The expected value of the marginal job for the intermediate firm, V Fnpt is:

V

Fnpt ⌘

@Q

p(npt )

@n

pt

= xt(1� �)y

pt

n

pt

� w

pt et +

(1� �

p)

fpt

(14)

10

Page 11: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

2.3.2 Retailers

There is a continuum of monopolistically competitive retailers indexed by i on the

unit interval. Retailers buy intermediate goods and di↵erentiate them with a tech-

nology that transforms one unit of intermediate goods into one unit of retail goods,

and thus the relative price of intermediate goods, xt, coincides with the real marginal

cost faced by the retailers. Let yit be the quantity of output sold by retailer i. The

final consumption good can be expressed as:

yt =

ˆ 1

0

(yit)✏�1✏di

✏✏�1

where ✏ > 1 is the constant elasticity of demand for each variety of retail goods. The

final good is sold at a price pt =h´ 1

0 p

1�✏it di

i

11�✏

. The demand for each intermediate

good depends on its relative price and on aggregate demand:

yit =

pit

pt

◆�✏

yt (15)

Following Calvo (1983), we assume that in any given period each retailer can reset

its price with a fixed probability (1 � �). Firms that are able to reset their price

choose p

⇤it so as to maximize expected nominal profits given by:

Et

1X

s=0

s⇤t,t+s(p⇤it � pt+sxt+s)yit+s

subject to the demand schedule, (15), in each period. Since all firms are ex-ante

identical, p⇤it = p

⇤t for all i. The resulting expression for p⇤t is:4

p

⇤t =

✏� 1

Et

P1s=0 �

s⇤t,t+syt+sxt+sp✏t+s

Et

P1s=0 �

s⇤t,t+syt+sp✏�1t+s

(16)

4See Appendix A.3 for the derivation of this condition.

11

Page 12: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Under the assumption of Calvo pricing, the price index is given by:

pt =⇥

(1� �)(p⇤t )1�✏ + �(pt�1)

1�✏⇤ 11�✏ (17)

2.4 Government

The government sector produces the public good using public capital and labour:

y

gt = (Atn

gt )

1�µ(kgt )

µ (18)

where we assume that productivity shocks are not sector specific and µ is the share

of public capital. The public good, which is provided for free, provides productivity

and utility enhancing services.

The government holds the public capital stock. Similar to the case of private

capital, the government capital stock evolves according to:

k

gt+1 = i

gt + (1� �

g)kgt �

!

2

k

gt+1

k

gt

� 1

◆2

k

gt (19)

Government expenditure consists of public investment, public wages, public vacancy

costs and unemployment benefits, while revenues come from the consumption, capital

income, labour income and lump-sum taxes. The government deficit is therefore

defined by:

DFt = i

gt + w

gtn

gt + v

gt +$ut � TRt

where TRt ⌘ ⌧n(wptn

pt et + w

gtn

gt ) + ⌧k(r

pt � �

p)kpt + T + ⌧cct denotes tax revenues.

The government budget constraint is given by:

Bt +DFt = R

�1t Bt+1⇡t+1 (20)

We assume that tax rates are constant and fixed at their steady state levels, and

12

Page 13: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

we do not consider them as active instruments for fiscal consolidation. Similarly we

assume that government investment is held fixed at it’s steady state value, ig = �

gk

g,

keeping the public capital stock constant. Thus the government has two potential

fiscal instruments, vg and wg. We consider each instrument separately, assuming that

if one is active, the other remains fixed at its steady state value. For 2 {vg,wg},

we assume fiscal rules of the form, following Erceg and Linde (2013) and Pappa et

al. (2015):

t = (1�� 0) � 0

t�1

"

bt

b

⇤t

◆� 1✓

�bt+1

�b

⇤t+1

◆� 2#(1�� 0)

where bt =BtYt

is the debt-to-GDP ratio and b

⇤t is the target debt-to-GDP ratio, given

by the AR(2) process:

log b⇤t � log b⇤t�1 = µb + ⇢1(log b⇤t�1 � log b⇤t�2)� ⇢2 log b

⇤t�1 � "

bt

where "bt is a white noise shock representing a fiscal consolidation.5

2.5 Closing the model

2.5.1 Monetary policy

There is an independent monetary authority that sets the nominal interest rate to

target zero net inflation, subject to the ZLB:

Rt = max(1, R⇡⇣⇡t ) (21)

5Notice that public wage cuts reduce the wage bill in the public sector in the same period, whilepublic vacancy cuts reduce it with a lag from next period.

13

Page 14: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

2.5.2 Resource constraint

Private output must equal private and public demand. The resource constraint is

given by:

y

pt = ct + i

pt + i

gt + (�pt + �

gt ) (22)

Following Gomes (2015), we define total output, Yt, as private output plus the public

wage bill: Yt = y

pt + w

gtn

gt .

2.5.3 Wage bargaining

Private sector wages are determined by ex post (after matching) Nash bargaining.

Workers and firms split rents and the part of the surplus they receive depends on

their bargaining power. If we denote by # 2 (0, 1) the firms’ bargaining power, the

Nash bargaining problem is to maximize the weighted sum of log surpluses:

maxwp

t

(1� #) lnV Hnpt + # lnV F

npt

where V Hnpt and V

Fnpt have been defined above. The optimization problem leads to the

following solution for wpt :

6

w

pt et = (1� #)xt(1� �)

y

pt

n

pt

+#

(1� ⌧n)�c,t�l�'t (23)

Hence, the equilibrium wage is a weighted average of the marginal product of em-

ployment and the disutility from labour, with the weights given by the firm and

household’s bargaining power respectively.

6See Appendix A.2 for the full derivation.

14

Page 15: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Table 1: Calibration of Parameters and Steady-State ValuesParameter/Variable Description Value

Preferences:

� Household discount factor 0.99↵1 Share of public good in consumption 0.85↵2 Private/public elasticity of substitution �1.25

Labour Market:

(1� l) Labour force participation 65%u/(1�l) Unemployment rate 10%ng/n Share of public employment 18%

/wp Vacancy costs as a share of wages 4.5%

Production:

⌫ Productivity of public good 0.15�, µ Share of capital in production 0.36kg/kp Public-private capital ratio 0.31� Price-stickiness 0.75

Policy Parameters:

⇣⇡ Taylor-rule inflation targeting parameter 1.1⇢1, ⇢2 Debt-target law of motion 0.85, 0.0001b Steady-state debt-to-GDP ratios 103%

2.6 Model Solution and Calibration

We solve the model by linearising the equilibrium conditions around a non-stochastic

steady state in which all prices are flexible, the price of the private good is normalized

to unity, and inflation is zero. When considering the ZLB, which is a non-linear

constraint, we use the Occbin toolkit provided by Guerrieri and Iacoviello (2015).

Table 1 shows some of the key parameters and steady-state values targeted in

our calibration. In particular, note that we allow the public good to be both utility

enhancing, as a complementary good to the private consumption good, and produc-

tive in the private production function. Full details of the calibration strategy are

provided in Appendix C.

15

Page 16: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

3 Results

We begin by considering a shock to the debt-to-GDP target which drives this ratio

around 5% below its steady state after 3 years. We simulate the response to this

shock under the two alternative policy instruments, �gand w

g. We then consider the

same shock in a low inflation environment. Following the literature, this environment

is induced by assuming a positive shock to the household’s discount rate, �, which

causes inflation to fall, driving the nominal interest rate to its lower bound.7 For

ease of exposition, we consider the cases of the two policy instruments in turn, and

compare the simulations with and without the shock to the discount rate in each

case.

3.1 The E↵ects of Quantity-Based Measures: A Cut in Pub-

lic Vacancies

Figure 2 shows the responses when public vacancies are the active consolidation

instrument. The blue line shows the baseline simulations in response to the fiscal

consolidation shock.8 We see that the cut in public vacancies causes a fall in public

employment, and hence both the public wage bill and public output, with a lag. Some

of the jobseekers leaving the public sector move towards the private sector, causing

a rise in private employment. At the same time, the reduction in expenditure on

the public wage bill creates a positive wealth e↵ect for the household, causing a rise

in private consumption and investment, which leads to a rise in capital. The rise in

both private employment and capital lead to a rise in private output, despite the fall

in public output, which also serves as an input in private production.

The green line depicts the responses in a low inflation environment induced by

the shock to the household’s discount rate, without yet imposing the ZLB constraint.

7We assume that the shock decays with auto-regressive parameter 0.5.8The dotted line in the debt-to-GDP ratio graph shows the path of the exogenous debt target.

16

Page 17: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Figure

2:FiscalCon

solidationwithPublicVacan

cyCuts

24

68

1012

-0.50

0.5

PAR

TIC

IPA

TIO

N R

ATE

24

68

1012

-4-20PRIV

ATE

CO

NSU

MPT

ION

24

68

1012

123PRIV

ATE

INVE

STM

ENT

24

68

1012

0

0.51

1.5

GR

OSS

REA

L IN

TER

EST

RA

TE

24

68

1012

0

0.050.1

PRIV

ATE

CA

PITA

L

24

68

1012

-15

-10-505

PRIV

ATE

VA

CA

NC

IES

24

68

1012

-10-50

PRIV

ATE

WA

GES

24

68

1012

-50510PR

IVA

TE J

OB

SEEK

ERS

24

68

1012

012PRIV

ATE

EM

PLO

YMEN

T

24

68

1012

-3-2-1

PRIV

ATE

OU

TPU

T

24

68

1012

-80

-60

-40

-20

PUB

LIC

VA

CA

NC

IES

24

68

1012

-15

-10-50

PUB

LIC

WA

GE

BIL

L

24

68

1012

-2002040

PUB

LIC

JO

BSE

EKER

S

24

68

1012

-15

-10-50PU

BLI

C E

MPL

OYM

ENT

24

68

1012

-10-50

PUB

LIC

OU

TPU

T

24

68

1012

-2-10G

RO

SS N

OM

INA

L IN

TER

EST

RA

TE

24

68

1012

-2-10IN

FLA

TIO

N

24

68

1012

246UN

EMPL

OYM

ENT

RA

TE

BA

SELI

NE

UN

CO

NST

RA

INED

CO

NST

RA

INED

24

68

1012

-4-2024D

EBT-

TO-G

DP

RA

TIO

17

Page 18: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Here we see that the nominal and the real interest rates fall sharply. Since agents

become more patient, we observe a fall in private consumption and a larger increase

in private investment compared to the baseline case. The latter leads to a higher

accumulation of private capital. However, despite the rise in capital, the demand

contraction leads to a fall in private labour demand and hence private employment.

Notice that the contraction in the private sector leads to a rise in public debt despite

the consolidation shock. This means that public vacancies fall by much more than

the baseline case, contraction public employment and output by more. This further

reinforces the fall in private output.

We next impose the ZLB constraint on the nominal interest rate and examine

again the responses to the combination of the consolidation and discount factor

shocks, as shown by the red lines. As we can see, the nominal interest rate now

cannot fall to the necessary level. The fall in inflation therefore translates to a large

rise in the real interest rate, putting upwards pressure on the debt-to-GDP ratio,

which rises by even more in the short run. In this case, a much larger cut in public

vacancies is required. The e↵ects of the shock are amplified accordingly, with a larger

fall in public, and hence private, output.

3.2 The E↵ects of Price-Based Measures: A Cut in Public

Wages

Figure 3 shows the responses when public wages are the active consolidation instru-

ment. Again, the blue lines depict the baseline simulations with the consolidation

shock only. We see that the public wage cut causes a fall in the fraction of jobseek-

ers in the public sector, and hence public employment and public output are again

reduced. As before, this causes a movement of jobseekers towards the private sector,

and boosts private employment. Despite the fall in income, we see that again the

consolidation causes a positive wealth e↵ect for the household, raising consumption

18

Page 19: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Figure

3:FiscalCon

solidationwithPublicWageCuts

24

68

1012

-0.4

-0.200.2

PAR

TIC

IPA

TIO

N R

ATE

24

68

1012

-4-20PRIV

ATE

CO

NSU

MPT

ION

24

68

1012

0123PRIV

ATE

INVE

STM

ENT

24

68

1012

012G

RO

SS R

EAL

INTE

RES

T R

ATE

24

68

1012

0

0.050.1

PRIV

ATE

CA

PITA

L

24

68

1012

-202468PR

IVA

TE V

AC

AN

CIE

S

24

68

1012

-10-50

PRIV

ATE

WA

GES

24

68

1012

051015

PRIV

ATE

JO

BSE

EKER

S

24

68

1012

0

0.51

1.5PR

IVA

TE E

MPL

OYM

ENT

24

68

1012

-3-2-10PR

IVA

TE O

UTP

UT

24

68

1012

-12

-10-8-6-4-2

PUB

LIC

WA

GES

24

68

1012

-15

-10-5

PUB

LIC

WA

GE

BIL

L

24

68

1012

-60

-40

-200

PUB

LIC

JO

BSE

EKER

S

24

68

1012

-6-4-20PUB

LIC

EM

PLO

YMEN

T

24

68

1012

-4-20PU

BLI

C O

UTP

UT

24

68

1012

-2-10G

RO

SS N

OM

INA

L IN

TER

EST

RA

TE

24

68

1012

-3-2-10IN

FLA

TIO

N

24

68

1012

-4-202UN

EMPL

OYM

ENT

RA

TE

BA

SELI

NE

UN

CO

NST

RA

INED

CO

NST

RA

INED

24

68

1012

-4-2024D

EBT-

TO-G

DP

RA

TIO

19

Page 20: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

and investment, and reducing labour force participation. Hence, despite the fall in

public output, we again see a rise in private output. It is also important to note that

the consolidation is much more successfull in the case of public wage cuts, with the

debt-to-GDP ratio falling to its new target after 3 years.

We turn next to the e↵ects of fiscal consolidation in the presence of the positive

shock to the household’s discount rate. The fact that inflation remains below the

steady state level so persistently implies that the government debt-to-GDP rises

dramatically above the steady state level, despite the deep fall in public wages. In

other words, in order for debt to be lowered to the new target level, a much deeper

cut in the public wage bill is required in the presence of the ZLB. This depresses

public employment and public output by far more than the baseline case. Hence,

despite the rise in private employment and capital, we see a fall in private output.

When the ZLB is imposed, the rise in the real rate again puts upward pressure on

public debt, further amplifying the required fall in public wages and hence the impact

of the shock.

3.3 The Productivity of the Public Sector Output

The results we present are, of course, very sensitive to the assumed value for the

productivity of the public good (⌫), as this is crucial in determining the e↵ects of

cuts in public wages or vacancies even in the baseline model when the ZLB does not

bind. Take, for example, the e↵ect of the vacancy cut: the fall in public employ-

ment generates a fall in public output and at the same time an increase in private

employment given that workers shift their supply away from public jobs. Whether

private output increases or not, and whether the consolidation is actually successful

or not, depends crucially on the productivity of the public good. If the public good

is productive, the cut in public vacancies reduces public output and, as a result,

besides the increase in private employment, for some parameterizations of ⌫, private

20

Page 21: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

output could decreases after the consolidation shock.

In the case of wage cuts, the subsequent decrease of the private wage decreases

marginal costs of firms in the private sector and this increases the demand for labour

and boosts private employment. Due to the fall in public wages and the increase in

demand in the private sector, unemployed shift their supply of labour to the private

sector and, hence, public employment is also decreasing, as in the case of vacancy

cuts, but for di↵erent reasons. Again, the productivity of the public good is crucial.

The more productive is the public good, the more private firms will increase vacancies

and the smaller the impact of the consolidation in unemployment will be, generating

a smaller impact of the consolidation in the private sector.

Now in a low inflation environment the demand e↵ect from the consolidation

shock coupled with the negative demand e↵ect from the discount factor shock will

crucially interplay with the e↵ects coming from the fall in public output. Whether

public output is productive or not will crucially a↵ect the transmission of consolida-

tion shocks in a low inflation environment. Figures 4 and 5 compare the responses

using the previous calibration, in which public output is assumed to be somehow

productive, ⌫ = 0.15, with the case in which ⌫ is reduced by half. As it is clear from

the figures, making the public sector less productive implies a need for a smaller

fiscal consolidation after the discount factor shock, and a smaller and less persistent

fall in private output.

3.4 The Taylor Rule Coe�cient on Inflation

Given the focus of the paper on the e↵ects of fiscal consolidation when monetary pol-

icy is constrained, the fiscal and monetary policy interactions become very important

in our context. We therefore turn next to examining the e↵ects of fiscal consolidation

in an economy constrained by the ZLB when the response of the nominal interest

rate to inflation through the Taylor rule is higher. In Figures 6 and 7 the blue lines

21

Page 22: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Figure

4:FiscalCon

solidationwithPublicVacan

cyCuts

under

theZLB

-Di↵erentProductivityof

PublicGoo

d

05

10

-0.50

0.5

PAR

TIC

IPA

TIO

N R

ATE

05

10-4-20PR

IVA

TE C

ON

SUM

PTIO

N

05

100.51

1.5PR

IVA

TE IN

VEST

MEN

T

05

100

0.51

1.5

GR

OSS

REA

L IN

TER

EST

RA

TE

05

100

0.1

0.2

PRIV

ATE

CA

PITA

L

05

10

-15

-10-505

PRIV

ATE

VA

CA

NC

IES

05

10

-10-8-6-4-2

PRIV

ATE

WA

GES

05

10

0510PR

IVA

TE J

OB

SEEK

ERS

05

10

012PRIV

ATE

EM

PLO

YMEN

T

05

10-3-2-10

PRIV

ATE

OU

TPU

T

05

10-80

-60

-40

-20

PUB

LIC

VA

CA

NC

IES

05

10

-15

-10-50

PUB

LIC

WA

GE

BIL

L

05

10

-2002040

PUB

LIC

JO

BSE

EKER

S

05

10

-15

-10-50PU

BLI

C E

MPL

OYM

ENT

05

10

-10-50

PUB

LIC

OU

TPU

T

05

10-1

-0.8

-0.6

-0.4

GR

OSS

NO

MIN

AL

INTE

RES

T R

ATE

05

10

-2.5-2

-1.5-1

-0.5

INFL

ATI

ON

05

10246U

NEM

PLO

YMEN

T R

ATE

BA

SELI

NE

CA

LIB

RA

TIO

N

LOW

ER P

RO

DU

CTI

VITY

YG

05

10

-4-2024D

EBT-

TO-G

DP

RA

TIO

22

Page 23: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Figure

5:FiscalCon

solidationwithPublicWageCuts

under

theZLB

-Di↵erentProductivityof

PublicGoo

d

05

10-0.6

-0.4

-0.200.2

PAR

TIC

IPA

TIO

N R

ATE

05

10

-4-3-2-1PRIV

ATE

CO

NSU

MPT

ION

05

10

0

0.51PR

IVA

TE IN

VEST

MEN

T

05

10012

GR

OSS

REA

L IN

TER

EST

RA

TE

05

100

0.050.1

PRIV

ATE

CA

PITA

L

05

10-4-20246

PRIV

ATE

VA

CA

NC

IES

05

10-12

-10-8-6-4-2

PRIV

ATE

WA

GES

05

1001020PR

IVA

TE J

OB

SEEK

ERS

05

100

0.51

1.5PR

IVA

TE E

MPL

OYM

ENT

05

10

-3-2-10PR

IVA

TE O

UTP

UT

05

10

-12

-10-8-6-4-2

PUB

LIC

WA

GES

05

10-20

-15

-10-5

PUB

LIC

WA

GE

BIL

L

05

10-80

-60

-40

-20020

PUB

LIC

JO

BSE

EKER

S

05

10-8-6-4-20PU

BLI

C E

MPL

OYM

ENT

05

10-5-4-3-2-1

PUB

LIC

OU

TPU

T

05

10-1

-0.50

GR

OSS

NO

MIN

AL

INTE

RES

T R

ATE

05

10

-3-2-10IN

FLA

TIO

N

05

10

-4-202UN

EMPL

OYM

ENT

RA

TE

BA

SELI

NE

CA

LIB

RA

TIO

N

LOW

ER P

RO

DU

CTI

VITY

YG

05

10

-4-2024D

EBT-

TO-G

DP

RA

TIO

23

Page 24: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

correspond to our baseline calibration (⇣⇡ = 1.1), while the red lines correspond to

the case in which the inflation coe�cient in the Taylor rule is higher (⇣⇡ = 1.5).

As we see in both figures, the tighter is monetary policy the less significant are

the e↵ects of the fiscal consolidation. The drop in private wages and inflation is

smaller. Consequently, the fall in the nominal interest rate is smaller, while the real

interest rate falls by more. The debt-to-GDP ratio increases by much less and as a

result the required cut in the fiscal instrument for debt consolidation is smaller. In

the labour market the e↵ects appear generally mitigated.

4 Conclusions

In this paper, we have set up a DSGE model with search and matching frictions,

nominal rigidities, and public employment. This rich model allows us to study non-

trivial reallocation of agents in and out of the labour force, and between the public

and private sector. In the baseline case, a fiscal consolidation through a cut in public

wages is able to reduce the public debt-to-GDP ratio faster than public vacancy

costs, although both have similar e↵ects on private output. Hence, public wage cuts

are a preferable consolidation strategy.

In a low inflation environment, induced by a positive shock to the discount rate,

a much larger cut in the public wage bill is required to bring the debt-to-GDP ratio

to the desired level. The rise in the real interest rate when the ZLB constraint is

binding leads to a rise in public debt and, as a result, makes consolidation more

costly. The fall in demand following the discount rate shock creates a drag on the

private sector, meaning that the consolidation in this environment has large negative

e↵ects.

24

Page 25: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Figure

6:FiscalCon

solidationwithPublicWageCuts

under

theZLB

-Di↵erentTaylorRule

Coe�cient

05

10

-0.4

-0.200.2

0.4

PAR

TIC

IPA

TIO

N R

ATE

05

10

-4-3-2-1PRIV

ATE

CO

NSU

MPT

ION

05

10012PR

IVA

TE IN

VEST

MEN

T

05

10

012G

RO

SS R

EAL

INTE

RES

T R

ATE

05

100

0.050.1

0.15

PRIV

ATE

CA

PITA

L

05

10

-2024

PRIV

ATE

VA

CA

NC

IES

05

10

-10-8-6-4-2

PRIV

ATE

WA

GES

05

10051015

PRIV

ATE

JO

BSE

EKER

S

05

100

0.51

1.5PR

IVA

TE E

MPL

OYM

ENT

05

10-3-2-10

PRIV

ATE

OU

TPU

T

05

10-12

-10-8-6-4-2

PUB

LIC

WA

GES

05

10

-15

-10-5

PUB

LIC

WA

GE

BIL

L

05

10

-60

-40

-200

PUB

LIC

JO

BSE

EKER

S

05

10

-6-4-20PUB

LIC

EM

PLO

YMEN

T

05

10

-4-20PU

BLI

C O

UTP

UT

05

10-1

-0.50

GR

OSS

NO

MIN

AL

INTE

RES

T R

ATE

05

10-3-2-10

INFL

ATI

ON

05

10-4-202U

NEM

PLO

YMEN

T R

ATE

BA

SELI

NE

CA

LIB

RA

TIO

N

HIG

HER

TA

YLO

R C

OEF

FIEC

IEN

T0

510

-4-2024D

EBT-

TO-G

DP

RA

TIO

25

Page 26: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Figure

7:FiscalCon

solidationwithPublicVacan

cyCuts

under

theZLB

-Di↵erentTaylorRule

Coe�cient

05

10

-0.50

0.5

PAR

TIC

IPA

TIO

N R

ATE

05

10-4-3-2-1PR

IVA

TE C

ON

SUM

PTIO

N

05

100.51

1.52PR

IVA

TE IN

VEST

MEN

T

05

10

0

0.51

1.5

GR

OSS

REA

L IN

TER

EST

RA

TE

05

100

0.1

0.2

PRIV

ATE

CA

PITA

L

05

10

-15

-10-505

PRIV

ATE

VA

CA

NC

IES

05

10

-10-8-6-4-2

PRIV

ATE

WA

GES

05

10

0510PR

IVA

TE J

OB

SEEK

ERS

05

10

012PRIV

ATE

EM

PLO

YMEN

T

05

10-3-2-10

PRIV

ATE

OU

TPU

T

05

10-80

-60

-40

-20

PUB

LIC

VA

CA

NC

IES

05

10

-15

-10-50

PUB

LIC

WA

GE

BIL

L

05

10

-2002040

PUB

LIC

JO

BSE

EKER

S

05

10

-15

-10-50PU

BLI

C E

MPL

OYM

ENT

05

10

-10-50

PUB

LIC

OU

TPU

T

05

10-1

-0.50

GR

OSS

NO

MIN

AL

INTE

RES

T R

ATE

05

10

-2-10IN

FLA

TIO

N

05

10

246UN

EMPL

OYM

ENT

RA

TE

BA

SELI

NE

CA

LIB

RA

TIO

N

HIG

HER

TA

YLO

R C

OEF

FIEC

IEN

T0

510

-4-2024D

EBT-

TO-G

DP

RA

TIO

26

Page 27: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

References

Bruckner, M. and Pappa, E.: 2012, Fiscal expansions, unemployment, and labor force

participation: theory and evidence, International Economic Review 53(4), 1205–

1228. 2.2, C.2

Calvo, G.: 1983, Staggered prices in a utility maximizing framework, Journal of

Monetary Economics 12(3), 383–398. 2.3.2

Campolmi, A. and Gnocchi, S.: 2014, Labor market participation, unemployment

and monetary policy, Bank of Canada Working Paper No. 2014/9 . 2.2

Christiano, L., Eichenbaum, M. and Rebelo, S.: 2011, When Is the Government

Spending Multiplier Large?, Journal of Political Economy 119(1), 78–121. 1

Coenen, G., Erceg, C. J., Freedman, C., Furceri, D., Kumhof, M., Lalonde, R., ...

and Trabandt, M.: 2012, E↵ects of Fiscal Stimulus in Structural Models, American

Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 4(1), 22–68. 1

Correia, I., Farhi, E., Nicolini, J. and Teles, P.: 2013, Unconventional Fiscal Policy

at the Zero Bound, American Economic Review 103(4), 1172–1211. 1

De Long, J. and Summers, L.: 2012, Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy, Brookings

Papers on Economic Activity pp. 233–297. 1

Eggertsson, G.: 2011, What Fiscal Policy is E↵ective at Zero Interest Rates?, NBER

Macroeconomics Annual 2010 25, 59–112. 1

Erceg, C. and Linde, J.: 2013, Fiscal Consolidation in a Currency Union: Spending

Cuts vs. Tax Hikes, Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 37(2), 422–445.

1

Gomes, P.: 2015, Heterogeneity and the public sector wage policy, Manuscript . 2.5.2

27

Page 28: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Guerrieri, L. and Iacoviello, M.: 2015, OccBin: A toolkit for solving dynamic mod-

els with occasionally binding constraints easily, Journal of Monetary Economics

70(C), 22–38. 2.6

Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E. and Vegh, C.: 2013, How Big (Small?) Are Fiscal Multi-

pliers?, Journal of Monetary Economics 60(2), 239–254. 1

Jalil, A.: 2012, Comparing Tax and Spending Multipliers: It’s All About Controlling

for Monetary Policy, Available at SSRN 2139855 . 1

McManus, R., Ozkan, F. G. and Trzeciakiewicz, D.: 2014, Self-defeating austerity at

the zero lower bound, Department of Economics, University of York . 1

Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J.: 2014, Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union: Evi-

dence from US Regions, American Economic Review 104(3), 753–792. 1

Neiss, K. S. and Pappa, E.: 2005, Persistence without too much price stickiness: the

role of variable factor utilization, Review of Economic Dynamics 8(1), 231–255.

2.2, C.3

Pappa, E., Sajedi, R. and Vella, E.: 2015, Fiscal Consolidation with Tax Evasion

and Corruption, Journal of International Economics 96(S1), 56–75. 1

Ravn, M.: 2008, The consumption-tightness puzzle, NBER International Seminar

on Macroeconomics 2006 pp. 9–63. 2.2

Reinhart, C., Reinhart, V. and Rogo↵, K.: 2015, Dealing with Debt, Journal of

International Economics 96(S1), 43–55. 1

Rendahl, P.: 2015, Fiscal Policy in an Unemployment Crisis, Review of Economic

Studies (forthcoming). 1

28

Page 29: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Appendices

A Derivations

A.1 Household’s maximisation problem

We can write in full the Lagrangean for the representative household’s maximisation

problem. Firstly, we can incorporate the composition of the household, as well as

the definition of the total consumption bundle, directly into the utility function of

the household. Then, we can plug the definition of the matches m

jt =

hjt u

jt into

the law of motion of employment in each sector, and also replace i

pt in the budget

constraint using the law of motion of private capital. We are left with 3 constraints,

and the following Lagrangean:

L = E0

1X

t=0

t{

[↵1(ct)↵2 + (1� ↵1)(ygt )↵2 ]

1�⌘↵2

1� ⌘

+ �[1� ut � n

pt � n

gt ]

1�'

1� '

� �2e

1+'2t

1 + '2

��ct[(1 + ⌧

ct )ct +

p

gt

pt

y

gt + k

pt+1 � (1� �

p)kpt +

!

2

k

pt+1

k

pt

� 1

◆2

k

pt

+Bt+1⇡t+1

Rt

� [rpt � ⌧

k(rpt � �

p)]kpt � [rpt � ⌧

k(rpt � �

p)]kpt �

(1� ⌧

nt )(w

ptn

pt et + w

gtn

gt )�$ut � Bt � ⇧

pt + Tt]

��npt

h

n

pt+1 � (1� �

p)npt �

hpt (1� st)ut

i

��ngt

h

n

gt+1 � (1� �

g)ngt �

hgt stut

i

}

The controls are ct, ut, st, npt+1, n

gt+1, k

pt+1and Bt+1. The first order conditions are:

[wrt ct]

cc

(1�⌘�↵2)t ↵1c

(↵2�1)t � �ct(1 + ⌧

ct ) = 0 (24)

29

Page 30: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

[wrt kpt+1]

�ct

1 + !

k

pt+1

k

pt

� 1

◆�

��Et�ct+1[1��p+r

pt+1�⌧k(r

pt+1��

p)+!

2(

k

pt+2

k

pt+1

◆2

�1)] = 0

(25)

[wrt Bt+1]

� �ct1

Rt

+ �Et�ct+11

⇡t+1= 0 (26)

[wrt n

jt+1]

� �njt � �Et[�l�'t+1 � �ct+1(1� ⌧n)w

jt+1e

jt+1 � �njt+1(1� �

j)] = 0 (27)

[wrt st]

�npt hpt = �ngt

hgt (28)

[wrt ut]

� �l�'t + �ct$ + �npt hpt (1� st) + �ngt

hgt st = 0 (29)

[wrt et]

� �2e'2t � �ctw

ptn

pt = 0 (30)

Equations (24)-(26)are standard and include the arbitrage conditions for the returns

to private consumption, private capital and bonds. Equation (27) relates the ex-

pected marginal value from being employed to the after-tax wage, the utility loss

from the reduction in leisure, and the continuation value, which depends on the

separation probability. Equation (29)states that the marginal utility of the unem-

ployment benefit, minus the marginal utility from leisure should equal the expected

marginal values of being employed, given te share of unemployed searching in each

sector. Equation (28) is an arbitrage condition according to which the choice of the

share, st, is such that the expected marginal values of being employed are equal

across the two sectors.

30

Page 31: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

We can define the marginal value to the household of having an additional member

employed in the private sector, as follows:

V

hnpt ⌘

@L

@n

pt

= �ctwpt et(1� ⌧n)� �l

�'t + (1� �

p)�npt (31)

= �ctwpt et(1� ⌧n)� �l

�'t + (1� �

p)�Et(Vhnpt+1)

where the second equalities come from equation (27) for each j respectively.

A.2 Derivation of the private wage

The Nash bargaining problem is to maximize the weighted sum of log surpluses:

maxwp

t

n

(1� #) lnV hnpt + # lnV f

npt

o

where V

hnjt and V

fnjt

are defined as:

V

hnpt ⌘

@L

@n

pt

= �ctwpt et(1� ⌧

nt )� �l

�'t + (1� �

p)�npt (32)

V

Fnpt ⌘

@Q

p

@n

pt

= xt(1� �)y

pt

n

pt

� w

pt et +

(1� �

p)

fpt

(33)

The first order conditions of this optimization problem is:

#V

hnpt = (1� #)�ct(1� ⌧

nt )V

fnpt (34)

Plugging the expressions for the value functions into the FOC, we can rearrange to

find the expression for the private wage. Using (32),(33) and (34) we obtain:

w

pt et = (1� #)[xt(1� �)

y

pt

n

pt

+(1� �

p)

fpt

] +#

(1� ⌧n)�c,t(�l�'t � (1� �

p)�npt) (35)

Finally, taking the time t expectation of34 evaluated at time t+1, and using the

31

Page 32: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

FOCs of the household and firm, we obtain

#�npt = (1� #)�ct(1� ⌧

nt )

fpt

which allows us to simplify 35 to obtain the final expression for the private wage

w

pt et = (1� #)xt(1� �)

y

pt

n

pt

+#

(1� ⌧n)�c,t�l�'t (36)

A.3 Derivation of the optimal price condition

An optimising retailer will choose the optimal price, p⇤it to maximise:

Et

1X

s=0

s⇤t,t+s(p

⇤it

pt+s

� xt+s)yit+s

subject to

yit+s =

p

⇤it

pt+s

◆�✏

yt+s

We can rewrite the objective function, plugging in this constraint, as follows:

Et

1X

s=0

s⇤t,t+syt+s

p

⇤it

pt+s

◆�✏✓p

⇤it

pt+s

� xt+s

= Et

1X

s=0

s⇤t,t+syt+s

p

⇤it

pt+s

◆1�✏

p

⇤it

pt+s

◆�✏

xt+s

!

For simplicity, let ✓s ⌘ �

s⇤t,t+syt+s. We can multiply out the terms in the

objective function to get:

Et

1X

s=0

✓s

p

⇤it

pt+s

◆1�✏

� Et

1X

s=0

✓sxt+s

p

⇤it

pt+s

◆�✏

= (p⇤it)1�✏

Et

1X

s=0

✓sp✏�1t+s � (p⇤it)

�✏Et

1X

s=0

✓sxt+sp✏t+s

32

Page 33: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

Taking the derivative with respect to p

⇤it, we have the following first order condi-

tion:

(1� ✏)(p⇤it)�✏Et

1X

s=0

✓sp✏�1t+s + ✏(p⇤it)

�✏�1Et

1X

s=0

✓sxt+sp✏t+s = 0

(1� ✏)(p⇤it)Et

1X

s=0

✓sp✏�1t+s = �✏(p⇤it)

�✏�1Et

1X

s=0

✓sxt+sp✏t+s

(p⇤it)�✏

(p⇤it)�✏�1

=�✏

(1� ✏)

Et

P1s=0 ✓sxt+sp

✏t+s

Et

P1s=0 ✓sp

✏�1t+s

(p⇤it)�✏+✏+1 =

✏� 1

Et

P1s=0 ✓sxt+sp

✏t+s

Et

P1s=0 ✓sp

✏�1t+s

p

⇤it =

✏� 1

Et

P1s=0 ✓sxt+sp

✏t+s

Et

P1s=0 ✓sp

✏�1t+s

Note that the right hand side no longer depends on i, so that we have p

⇤it = p

⇤t .

Reinserting ✓s ⌘ �

s⇤t,t+syt+s, we have the expression for the optimal price level

p

⇤t =

✏� 1

Et

P1s=0 �

s⇤t,t+syt+sxt+sp✏t+s

Et

P1s=0 �

s⇤t,t+syt+sp✏�1t+s

B Model Equations

B.1 Dynamic Equations

We write the model as 38 equations in 38 unknowns:

nt + ut + lt = 1 (37)

n

pt+1 = (1� �

p)npt +m

pt (38)

33

Page 34: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

n

gt+1 = (1� �

g)ngt +m

gt (39)

nt = n

pt + n

gt (40)

m

pt = ⇢

pm(�

pt )↵ (up

t )1�↵ (41)

m

gt = ⇢

gm(�

gt )↵(ug

t )1�↵ (42)

ut = u

pt + u

gt (43)

fpt =

m

pt

pt

(44)

hpt =

m

pt

u

pt

(45)

hgt =

m

gt

u

gt

(46)

fgt =

m

pt

gt

(47)

k

pt+1 = i

pt + (1� �

p)kpt �

!

2

k

pt+1

k

pt

� 1

◆2

k

pt (48)

cct = [↵1(ct)↵2 + (1� ↵1)(y

gt )↵2 ]

1↵2 (49)

cc

(1�⌘�↵2)t ↵1c

(↵2�1)t = �ct(1 + ⌧

ct ) (50)

� �ct1

Rt

+ �Et�ct+11

⇡t+1= 0 (51)

34

Page 35: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

�ct

1 + !

k

pt+1

k

pt

� 1

◆�

��Et�ct+1[1��p+r

pt+1�⌧k(r

pt+1��

p)+!

2(

k

pt+2

k

pt+1

◆2

�1)] = 0

(52)

� �npt � �Et[�l�'t+1 � �ct+1(1� ⌧n)w

pt+1 � �npt+1(1� �

p)] = 0 (53)

� �ngt � �Et[�l�'t+1 � �ct+1(1� ⌧n)w

gt+1 � �ngt+1(1� �

g)] = 0 (54)

� �l�'t + �ct$ + �npt hpt = 0 (55)

�npt hpt = �ngt

hgt (56)

�2e'2t = ��ctw

ptn

pt (57)

y

pt = (Atn

pt )

1��(kpt )�(ygt )

⌫ (58)

xt�y

pt

k

pt

= r

pt (59)

fpt

= �Et�c,t+1

�c,t

"

xt+1(1� �)y

pt+1

n

pt+1

� w

pt+1 + (1� �

p)

fpt+1

#

(60)

w

pt = (1� #)[xt(1� �)

y

pt

n

pt

+(1� �

p)

fpt

] +#

(1� ⌧n)�c,t(�l�'t � (1� �

p)�np,t) (61)

y

pt = ct + i

pt + i

gt + (�pt + �

gt ) (62)

y

gt = (Atn

gt )

1�µ(kgt )

µ (63)

k

gt+1 = i

g + (1� �

g)kgt �

!

2

k

gt+1

k

gt

� 1

◆2

k

gt (64)

yt = y

pt + w

gtn

gt (65)

35

Page 36: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

TGt = i

g + w

gtn

gt + v

gt +$ut (66)

TRt = ⌧n(wptn

pt + w

gtn

gt ) + ⌧k(r

pt � �

p)kpt + ⌧cct (67)

DFt = TGt + T � TRt (68)

Bt +DFt = R

�1t Bt+1⇡t+1

Rt = R⇡

⇣⇡t (69)

t = (1�� 0) � 0

t�1

"

bt

b

⇤t

◆� 1✓

�bt+1

�b

⇤t+1

◆� 2#(1�� 0)

(70)

log b⇤t � log b⇤t�1 = µb + ⇢1(log b⇤t�1 � log b⇤t�2)� ⇢2 log b

⇤t�1 � "

bt (71)

1 = (1� �) (p⇤t )1�✏ + �⇡

✏�1t (72)

⌦1,t = �ctytxt + �Et⇡✏t+1⌦1,t+1 (73)

⌦2,t = �ctyt + �Et⇡✏�1t+1⌦2,t+1 (74)

p

⇤t =

✏� 1

⌦1,t

⌦2,t(75)

C Calibration Strategy

C.1 Labour market variables

We calibrate e = 1, such that it does not e↵ect the rest of the steady state. We

calibrate the labour-force participation rate, the unemployment rate, and the share

36

Page 37: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

of public employment in total employment to match the observed average values

from the Italian data (1� l = 0.65, urate = u1�l

= 0.1, ng

n= 0.18). Then we get u, n,

np

n, n

p, n

g as follows:

u = u

rate(1� l)

n = 1� l � u

n

p

n

= 1�n

g

n

n

j =n

j

n

n

We set the following values for the separation rates, �p = 0.063 and �g = 0.06. Then

we get mj from (1) at the steady state:

m

j = �

jn

j

We calibrate the ratio of unemployed searching in two sectors as up/ug = 4. Then, it

holds by definition:

u

p =u

1 + up/ug

u

g = u� u

p

hj =m

j

u

j

Since there is no exact estimate for the value of the private vacancy-filling prob-

ability, fp, in the literature, we use what is considered as standard by setting it

equal to 0.1 and then we assume that fp =

fg. Hence, we get:

j =m

j

fj

The elasticity in the matching functions, ↵, is set equal to 5. Then the e�ciency

37

Page 38: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

parameter for private matches, ⇢pm, is given by inverting the matching function:

jm =

m

j

(�j)↵ (uj)1�↵

C.2 Production

We set the capital depreciation rates, �j, equal to 0.025. Following the literature, we

set the discount factor, �, equal to 0.99. The tax rates on capital and labour income

are calibrated to 30%. Next, we get rp and R from (25) and (26), respectively:

r

p =1

(1� ⌧k)

1

� 1

+ �

p

R =1

The elasticity of demand for intermediate goods, ", is set equal to 10, which implies

a gross steady-state markup, ""�1 , equal to 1.11. The price of the final good is

normalized to one, meaning that x is determined from (16):

x ="� 1

"

We set the capital share in the production function of the private good equal to 0.36.

Then we obtain yp

kpfrom (12):

y

p

k

p=

r

p

�x

We set the shares of public capital in public production, µ, equal to 0.36, of the

public good in private production, ⌫, equal to 0.12. Further, using data from Kamps

(2006) we set kg

kp= 0.31, close to the mean value for 1970-2002. Since we restrict

our case to a deterministic steady state, we normalize At to one. Then from (9) and

38

Page 39: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

(18), kp is determined by:

k

p =

"

y

p

k

p(np)

�(1��)

(ng)µ⌫�⌫✓

k

g

k

p

◆�µ⌫#

1�+µ⌫�1

and then we get ypand k

gby definition:

y

p =y

p

k

pk

p, kg =k

g

k

pk

p

and i

p and i

g from (6) and (19) at steady state:

i

p = �

pk

p, i

g = �

gk

g

and y

g from (18):

y

g = (ng)1�µ(kg)µ

Following Hagedorn and Manovskii (2008), Galı (2011), and Bruckner and Pappa

(2012), we calibrate the cost of posting a vacancy, , by targeting vacancy costs per

filled job as a fraction of the real private wage, wp , choosing 0.045 as a target as in

Galı (2011). Also, we set the replacement rate, $wp , equal to 0.4 (in accordance with

the range [0.2, 0.4] in Petrongolo and Pissarides, 2001). Then, we can get wp from

(13):

w

p = x(1� �)y

p

n

p

1 +�

p

fp

w

p

◆�1

and it follows that and b are given by:

=

w

pw

p

b =b

w

pw

p

39

Page 40: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

C.3 Households

We derive private consumption from the resource constraint (22)

c = y

p� i

p� i

g� (�p + �

g)

We set the consumption tax rate to 15%, the intertemporal elasticity of substi-

tution, 1⌘, equal to 1, the Frisch elasticity of labour supply, 1

, equal to 0.25 (in the

range of Domeij and Floden, 2006). We set the share of private consumption in the

consumption bundle, ↵1 = 0.85, and the elasticity of substitution between the two

goods, ↵2 = �1.25, such that the two goods are complements. This gives us the

total consumption bundle by definition:

cc = [↵1(c)↵2 + (1� ↵1)(y

g)↵2 ]1↵2

We derive the two lagrange multipliers from the household’s first order conditions,

(24) and (27) for j = p, respectively:

�c = (1 + ⌧

c)�1↵1cc

(1�⌘�↵2)c

(↵2�1)

�np =��c(wp(1� ⌧n)�$)

1� �(1� �

p) + �

hp

This allows us to derive � from (29), after substituting in (28):

� = l

'(�c$ +

hp�np)

and the firm’s bargaining power from (23):

40

Page 41: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

# =x(1� �)(yp/np) + (1� �

p)/ fp� w

p

x(1� �)(yp/np) + (1� �

p)/ fp� (�l�' � (1� �

p)�np)/�c(1� ⌧n)

Following Neiss and Pappa (2005)we set '2 = 0.5, and we use (30) to calibrate

�2 such that e = 1:

�2 = ��cwpn

p

Finally, we derive the lagrange multiplier from (28), and the public wage from

(27) for j = g:

�ng =�np

hp

hg

w

g =�l�' + �ng(R� 1 + �

g)

�c(1� ⌧n)

This also allows us to define total output, Y = y

p + w

gn

g.

C.4 Fiscal Policy

We set the steady-state debt to GDP ratio, b, equal to 103%, so that by definition:

B = bY

and using the government’s budget constraint, (20), in steady state, we have:

DF = (� � 1)B

Next, we calibrate the steady state value for lump-sum transfers, T , from the

41

Page 42: Fiscal Consolidation in a Disinflationary Environment: Price ...ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/events/2016/20160119-fiscal...2016/01/19  · comparing the e ects of price-based and

definition of the deficit:

T = i

g + w

gn

g +$u+ �

g� ⌧k(r

p� �

p)kp� ⌧n(w

pn

p + w

gn

g)� ⌧cc�DF

C.5 Other parameters

Finally, the model’s steady state is independent of the degree of price rigidities, of

the monetary policy rule, the debt-targeting rule for lump-sum taxes, and of the size

of the capital adjustment costs. We set the probability that a firm does not change

its price within a given period, �, equal to 0.75, the Taylor rule coe�cient, ⇣⇡, equal

to 1.1, and the adjustment costs parameter, !, equal to 150. Finally, we set the

parameters for the persistence of the debt-target shock,⇢1 and ⇢2, equal to 0.85 and

0.0001, respectively.

42