fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

10
This article was downloaded by: [University of Illinois Chicago] On: 10 November 2014, At: 10:04 Publisher: Routledge Informa Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House, 37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK Applied Economics Publication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information: http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20 Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk? Vladimir Kühl Teles a & Maria Carolina Leme a a Sao Paulo School of Economics , Getulio Vargas Foundation (EESP-FGV) , Sao Paulo, Brazil Published online: 16 Mar 2009. To cite this article: Vladimir Kühl Teles & Maria Carolina Leme (2010) Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?, Applied Economics, 42:20, 2577-2585, DOI: 10.1080/00036840801964518 To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840801964518 PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) contained in the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make no representations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of the Content. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, and are not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon and should be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable for any losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoever or howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use of the Content. This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematic reproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in any form to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http:// www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Upload: maria-carolina

Post on 14-Mar-2017

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

This article was downloaded by: [University of Illinois Chicago]On: 10 November 2014, At: 10:04Publisher: RoutledgeInforma Ltd Registered in England and Wales Registered Number: 1072954 Registered office: Mortimer House,37-41 Mortimer Street, London W1T 3JH, UK

Applied EconomicsPublication details, including instructions for authors and subscription information:http://www.tandfonline.com/loi/raec20

Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causescountry risk?Vladimir Kühl Teles a & Maria Carolina Leme aa Sao Paulo School of Economics , Getulio Vargas Foundation (EESP-FGV) , Sao Paulo, BrazilPublished online: 16 Mar 2009.

To cite this article: Vladimir Kühl Teles & Maria Carolina Leme (2010) Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causescountry risk?, Applied Economics, 42:20, 2577-2585, DOI: 10.1080/00036840801964518

To link to this article: http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00036840801964518

PLEASE SCROLL DOWN FOR ARTICLE

Taylor & Francis makes every effort to ensure the accuracy of all the information (the “Content”) containedin the publications on our platform. However, Taylor & Francis, our agents, and our licensors make norepresentations or warranties whatsoever as to the accuracy, completeness, or suitability for any purpose of theContent. Any opinions and views expressed in this publication are the opinions and views of the authors, andare not the views of or endorsed by Taylor & Francis. The accuracy of the Content should not be relied upon andshould be independently verified with primary sources of information. Taylor and Francis shall not be liable forany losses, actions, claims, proceedings, demands, costs, expenses, damages, and other liabilities whatsoeveror howsoever caused arising directly or indirectly in connection with, in relation to or arising out of the use ofthe Content.

This article may be used for research, teaching, and private study purposes. Any substantial or systematicreproduction, redistribution, reselling, loan, sub-licensing, systematic supply, or distribution in anyform to anyone is expressly forbidden. Terms & Conditions of access and use can be found at http://www.tandfonline.com/page/terms-and-conditions

Page 2: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

Applied Economics, 2010, 42, 2577–2585

Fundamentals or market sentiment:

what causes country risk?

Vladimir Kuhl Teles* and Maria Carolina Leme

Sao Paulo School of Economics, Getulio Vargas Foundation (EESP-FGV),

Sao Paulo, Brazil

The country risk indicator, as measured by the JP Morgan’s EMBI or

grades of rating agencies such as Standard & Poor’s (S&P’s) or Moody’s,

does not seem to truly reflect the fundamentals of an economy. Countries

that pursue sound economic policies are frequently placed on the same

level as countries with a populist orientation or with a recent history of

default or debt restructuring. Such circumstance generates a feeling of

unease with regard to these ratings. The objective of this article is to

investigate whether these indicators truly reflect market fundamentals or

whether some sort of prejudice, or intolerance towards certain countries,

can be identified. We use the Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition to analyse

the differences in country risk, measured as by EMBIþ, for a group of

emerging markets. This decomposition allows us to separate the ‘justified’

(differences in fundamentals) from the ‘unjustified’ differences (same

fundamental differently evaluated).

I. Introduction

With the recent integration of international capital

markets, country risk has become an important

factor within macroeconomics. The degree of free-

dom of monetary and fiscal policy is, at some level,

constrained by the country risk indicators given

that the economy’s external balance depends on this

variable. The most common ratings used are from

agencies like Standard & Poor’s (S&P’s), Fitch and

JP Morgan (EMBIþ). Ratings are used as a guide

to investors; a low rating is very costly to the

economy since long-term institutional investors are

not allowed to invest in a country not rated as

‘investment grade.’ In this article we use the

indicator EMBIþ by JP Morgan as the measure

of country risk, which reflects the average spread

governments papers pay over the US Treasury Bills.

This spread implies a direct cost to governments

and an indirect cost to firms given that, for most of

the countries, debt repayment depends on the

repayment policy of governments.From the theoretical point of view the determi-

nants of the country risk still are in their early

stages of development. However, there is a con-

sensus view about what determine this indicator: the

economy’s economic fundamentals. Nevertheless,

several countries with fragile fundamentals or with

a history of recent defaults have been rated as less

risky than countries with more solid economic

conditions. As a result, we intend to answer in this

article the following questions: Is country risk

determined by fundamentals or by sentiment? Are

the criteria used to determine country risk equally

applied for all countries or are there countries

treated with a certain level of intolerance? Which

countries suffer the most from discrimination when

their country risk is determined?

*Corresponding author. E-mail: [email protected]

Applied Economics ISSN 0003–6846 print/ISSN 1466–4283 online � 2010 Taylor & Francis 2577http://www.informaworld.com

DOI: 10.1080/00036840801964518

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 3: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

Over the course of the last 20 years, the determi-

nants of emerging markets bonds spreads have been

analysed by a number of authors. The first to do so

was Sebastian Edwards in 1984. Edward analysed the

bond markets for 13 developing countries between

1976 and 1980 – a period when most Lesser

Developed Country (LDC) debt consisted of bank

loans. He found evidence that the debt to Gross

Domestic Product (GDP) ratio had a positive effect

on bond spreads. Recently, studies have benefit from

the much larger bond markets of these countries.Liquidity and solvency indicators play an impor-

tant role in bond spreads. For example, Min (1999)

found that ratios of external debt, international

reserves and debt service to GDP, along with

export and import growth rates were significant for

a group of Latin America and Asian countries

during the period of 1991 to 1995. Additional

macro variables such as inflation rate, terms of

trade, real exchange rate and net foreign asset

accumulation also helped to explain these spreads

in Min’s sample. On much the same lines as Min

(1999), Fiess (2003) separates contagion from

country-specific fundamentals for the joint determi-

nation of capital flows and country risk for four

Latin American countries in the 1990s. Fiess found

that capital flows were driven by both country risk

and global factors while country risk was solely

determined by a number of fundamental variables:

the ratio to GDP of primary balance and public

debt. Furthermore, Beck (2001), when estimating a

panel data, found that during the period immedi-

ately after the Asian crises the spreads were ‘almost

entirely explained by expectations of market funda-

mentals’. On the other hand, for developed

countries, international interest rates also played a

role but stock market volatility did not.Eichengreen and Mody’s (1998) analysis

attempted to separate the impact of changes in

fundamentals from changes in market sentiment

regarding LDC’s bond spreads. They controlled for

selective bias of new issuers and found that changes

in fundamentals explained the change in spreads.

However, the same explanatory variables had a

different impact in different periods of time. For

instance, market sentiment played a stronger role

during the Mexican crises (increasing spreads)

and during subsequent periods (declining spreads)

than during the periods just before the crises.

Moreover, the responses of spread to fundamentals

observed in Latin American countries were different

from the others in the sample.

In a similar way, Reinhart et al. (2003) analysedwhy it is more difficult for some countries to repaytheir debts at levels that would be consideredmoderate for other countries. They built a measureof debt intolerance based on an estimated riskregression, using ratings of the Institutional InvestorRatings as a function of fundamentals and the defaulthistory of the countries.

The present article is along the same lines asEichengreen and Mody’s (1998) and Reinhart et al.’s(2003). The estimated country risk equation is basedon very simple models as in Blanchard (2005) whoassumes that country risk is endogenously determinedby the country’s fiscal policy given that it reflects theprobability of default on the public debt. The debt,derived from the government flow budget constraint,is a function of: real rates of return of bondsdenominated in domestic and in foreign currency,primary surplus and real exchange rate.Correspondingly, the exchange rate is determinedby the relationship between the capital flow, theexchange rate and the trade surplus. That is, if capitalflow declines, the exchange rate must depreciate so asto generate the necessary trade surplus to compensatefor the capital account deficit. The solution to thesethree relationships is highly nonlinear, but a simpli-fied linear equation was estimated for Brazil.1

We also added another dimension to the problemby including the default history of countries inaddition to the fundamentals. We use the coefficientof this regression to compute how much of thedifference in spreads can be attributed to thedifference in country risk and how much tosentiment.

The article is structured as follows. The nextsection discusses some stylized facts regarding theeconomies being analysed. Section III lays out theestimates, and the last section presents the finalconsiderations. In particular, a specification with thenonlinearity of public debt–GDP ratio is included inthe tests of fiscal fundamentals and its significance isrejected.

II. Stylized Facts

JP Morgan’s EMBIþ measures the difference in bondspreads vis-a-vis US Treasury Bills of the samematurity, for countries that are ranked as Baal/BBBþ or below by Moody’s and S&P’s ratingagencies and some liquidity ranking rules. BetweenDecember 1998 and February 2006 a huge difference

1 Tests on a specification of nonlinearity of debt to output ratio in the fiscal fundamental was not significant.

2578 V. K. Teles and M. C. Leme

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 4: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

in the spreads is exhibited by the countries in the

sample2: ranging from 3241 base points (Argentina)

to 111 (Malaysia) (Fig. 1).Looking at the relationship between the EMBIþ

indicator and a number of macro variables, we

observe that correlations are, for the most part, in

the predicted directions. In order to measure the

liquidity/solvency conditions of countries, we use

the ratio between exports and public debt which

measures the number of months of exports necessary

to repay the debt. The average EMBIþ and its

variance declines with this indicator (Fig. 2).In order to capture the fiscal fundamentals we

calculate the ratio of public debt to GDP. The higher

the ratio is the higher the EMBIþ result (Fig. 3).

However, we again observe that this variance also

increases with the debt ratio.For other variables capturing domestic fundamen-

tals there is a slight positive correlation between

domestic interest rates and the country risk, with

a declining variance (Fig. 4) and a negative correla-

tion between this variable and the GDP growth

rate (Fig. 5).The default history can be measured by the number

of times each country has defaulted. In this sample,

we generally find that countries that have never

defaulted (i.e. Korea and Malaysia) had an average

EMBI five times lower than countries which have

repudiated or restructured their debts at least once.

In addition to that, there is a positive relationship

between the number of defaults and the average

EMBI (Fig. 6) in spite of extreme cases such as

Venezuela and Ecuador (with seven registered

defaults each one) which have an average EMBI

lower than Argentina (with six registered defaults).However, as pointed out by Reinhart et al. (2003)

a better measure of the correlation of country risk

would be the length of time since the last default or

restructuring. Figure 7 shows the EMBI figures as of

December 2004 and the number of months since the

last default. Argentina, Ecuador, Russia and Ukraine

are countries with the most recent defaults.Still following Reinhart et al. (2003) approach, we

calculate debt intolerance as measured by the inverse

of the lapse (length) of time since the last default3

multiplied by the ratio of public debt to GDP. The

correlation of this index with the EMBI is highly

positive (Fig. 8). In regard to the bond market there is

a slight positive correlation between the average

spreads and average duration for countries in the

sample and that the variance increases with duration

(Fig. 9).Based on these facts, we can confirm the expecta-

tion that country risk is highly determined by

fundamentals. Nevertheless, some countries are

systematically over the trend line, while others are

frequently above it. Argentina’s EMBI, for instance,

is frequently over it, indicating that its country risk is

higher than the predicted by fundamentals. On the

other hand, Egypt has a country risk lower than the

predicted by its fundamentals given that it is

frequently below the trend lines.

0500

10001500200025003000

Malaysia

South Africa

PolandEgyp

tKorea

Mexico

Panama

Morocco

Ukraine

Bulgaria

Philippines

Peru

ColombiaTurke

yBrazil

Venezuela

Russia

Ecuador

Argentina

Fig. 1. Average EMBI by country

EQ

CO

AG

UK RSBR

EGPOPHPA TK

0

500

1000

1500

2000

2500

3000

0

Exports/Public debt

Embi

Fig. 2. Average EMBI versus average exports/public debt

EQ

CO

AG

UKRS BR

EGPH PA TKPO0

5001000

1500

20002500

3000

0 0 0 0 0 1

Public debt/GDP

Embi

Fig. 3. Average EMBI versus average public debt/product

2 The EMBIþ has been computed from 1993 on and many countries were excluded from the sample because they did not meetthe standards. The countries in Fig. 1, plus Qatar and Nigeria, make up the current sample.3We use the inverse of time since the last default so as not to exclude countries that never defaulted from the analysis.

Fundamentals or market sentiment 2579

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 5: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

III. Estimation and Results

Aiming to measure the impact of fundamentals oncountry risk, we first estimate a panel of 19 countriesusing monthly data between December 1998 andFebruary 2006. Second, we estimate the same modelfor each one of the countries and then, using themethodology proposed by Oaxaca (1973) andBlinder (1973), we decompose the differences incountry risk into two components: one partexplained by fundamentals and another explainedby market sentiment. In Eichengreen and Mody’s(1998) study this methodology was used with theintention to capture the effects of this kind ofsentiment on different spreads over different periods

of time. In the present article we adopt the same

strategy, but with a different purpose, we use it to

compare country risks between economies. The

decomposition is based on a comparison of each

country to the pool of countries in the sample. This

benchmark is particularly opportune to our purpose

given that we are able to capture the differences in

criterion when comparing similar economies in

terms of fragility of their institutions and political

regimes.The decomposition is very simple: let X be the

observed explanatory variables of country risk Y;

therefore for country i we can estimate:

Yi ¼ Xi�i þ ui

EQ

CO

AG

UK BR

EGPHPA TK

PO0500

10001500200025003000

4 8 12 16 20 24

Domestic interest rates

Embi

RS

Fig. 4. Average EMBI versus average domestic interest

rates

CO

AG

UKRSBR

EGPHPA TK

PO0500

10001500200025003000

3 4 5 6 7 8

GDP growth

Embi

Fig. 5. Average EMBI versus average product growth

0

500

10001500

2000

2500

3000

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

Number of defaults

Embi

Fig. 6. Average EMBI by number of defaults

EQ

CO

AG

UKRS BR

EGPH PATK

PO0500

10001500200025003000

5 15 25 35 45 55 65 75

Years

Embi

Fig. 7. Average EMBI versus years since last default

EQ

CO

AG

UKRS BR

EGPHPATK

PO0500

10001500200025003000

2 12 22 32 42 52 62

DI* (PD/GDP)

Embi

Fig. 8. Average EMBI versus default index

Note: *Public debt/GDP.

EQ

CO

AG

UKRSBR

EGPHPATK

PO 0500

10001500200025003000

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

Maturity

Embi

Fig. 9. Average EMBI versus average maturity

2580 V. K. Teles and M. C. Leme

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 6: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

For the pool of countries in the sample we have thesame estimation

Y ¼ X�þ u

Therefore, the difference in averages between eachcountry and the pool of countries is:

�Y� �Yi ¼ �X�� �Xi�i ¼ ð �X� �XiÞ�þ �Xið�� �iÞ

The first term in the right-hand side would be thecomponent explained by fundamentals while thesecond would be explained by market sentiment.Certainly the two effects can be quite differentdepending on which population is chosen as thebase group. Also, as pointed out by Fournier (2005),one can get valuable information by contrasting bothresults. In our analysis we are comparing eachcountry with the pool of countries in the samplethis group is, by construction, our nondiscriminatorybase. This strategy is similar to Neumark’s (1988)who, looking at wage discrimination, estimated thecoefficient of the nondiscriminatory wage structurefor the whole sample.4

We measured country risk by the EMBIþ index.As discussed by Blanchard (2005) the EMBI spreadreflects the probability of default as well as the riskaversion of foreign investor. This last componentprobably varies over time but is not country specific;therefore the difference between the indexes of thecountries is free from it.

The country risk equation was estimated as afunction of: (i) the fiscal fundamentals captured bythe ratio of public debt to GDP (PD/GDP); (ii) thegeneral fundamentals of the economy: the GDPgrowth over the last 12 months (GROWTH), inflationin the last 12 months (INF) and the annual nominalinterest rates (IR) as well as the ratio of internationalreserves to GDP (RES/GDP); (iii) the liquidity andsolvency conditions as captured by the ratio betweenexports and public debt (X/GDP) and (iv) the debtintolerance to defaulters which is obtained by multi-plying public debt to GDP by the index of the inverseof time since the last default (DI). We also controlledfor the debt profile including the average duration ofthe bonds (MAT). The reference currency is theUS dollar and inflation rates were represented bythe Consumer Price Index (CPI). All variables wereobtained from the International Financial Statistics(IFS) and Government Financial Statistics (GFS)of the International Monetary Fund or from theMoody’s database.

Some of the data were only available on an annualbasis. A common approach in the literature is the use

of industrial production to transform the GDP into a

monthly measure (e.g. Mitra, 2007; Teles and

Andrade, 2008). The reason behind this approach is

based on the following factors: (i) within short-term

movements in GDP, output indicators are usually

regarded as being better guides than expenditure

indicators (Mitchell et al., 2005) – industrial produc-

tion is the only monthly output indicator for all

countries in samples with a lot of countries (like

ours); (ii) some studies have found that in several

countries indicators based on industrial activity are

useful when forecasting real GDP growth rates in the

short run (Mourougane and Roma, 2003). We

reconstructed the monthly series for the debt series

using the public deficits/surpluses available in the

IMF/GFS statistics.It can be expected that country risk would increase

with the ratio of public debt to GDP; decrease with

GDP growth and increase with interest rates since

both variables indicate the long-term conditions of

public debt path; and increase with inflation and

decrease with the ratio of international reserves to

GDP. We also expect spreads to increase with the

ratio of exports to public debt and with the inverse of

the amount of time since the last default by PD/GDP

and decline with duration. This variable is itself a

measure of country risk: the riskier the country the

shorter the duration of its bonds and, if a country

wants to issue a bond with a longer duration it will

probably have to pay a higher premium.Before proceeding with the model estimations we

tested the stationarity of the variables used. The null

hypothesis of nonstationarity was tested using the

panel unit root tests of Im et al. (2003), Maddala and

Wu (1999) and Choi (2001). These tests allow each

member of the cross section to have a different

autoregressive root and different autocorrelation

structures under the alternative hypothesis.

Tables A1 and A2 in the appendix show the

hypothesis that all variables considered in the

estimations do not contain a unit root at 5% for at

least one of these tests.We estimated two alternative specifications:

EMBIi¼ �iþ�iPDi

GDPiþ �iMATiþ�i

DI�PDi

GDPi

� �þ’iX

PDii

ð1Þ

The equations were estimated for the entire sample

of countries as well as for each country separately,

using Generalized Least Square (GLS) and

Instrumental Variables (IV) methods (to control for

4 There are other methods to estimate the nondiscriminatory structure such as in Oaxaca and Ramson (1994) and Shresthaand Sakellariou (1996).

Fundamentals or market sentiment 2581

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 7: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

the endogeneity of maturity and interest rates) and

the lagged values of the variables as instruments.For the panel of countries we estimated a fixed

effect model, since the Hausman and redundant

fixed effect tests argue in favour of this model

(Table A3 in the appendix).5 This is the appropriated

model since we want to control for unobserved effects

that capture features of each country possibly

correlated with the explanatory variables and that

can biases their coefficients. The fixed effect model

controls for possible idiosyncratic characteristics of

countries that may affect investors’ risk perceptions.

We assume that these characteristics are time

invariant, a reasonable assumption given the short

interval considered within the analysis. For example,

South Korea may have a higher than expected risk (as

measured by economic fundamentals) based on the

hostility with North Korea, a very unstable regime.As we can see in the first model, the estimated

coefficients exhibited the expected sign and are

significant, except for the ratio of exports to public

debt in both estimations.Omitting the variable X/PD improves the overall

explanatory power of the model without changing

the coefficients of the remaining variables (Model 2).

To test for nonlinearities in the relationship between

country risk and the fiscal variable, the model

was estimated once again including the square of

the public debt to GDP ratio which showed no

significance (Model 3). The results using GLS and IV

are quite similar.The second specification estimated using the IV

method is as follows:

EMBIi ¼ �i þ�iPDi

GDPiþ �iMATi þ �i

DI�PDi

GDPi

� �þ �Z

ð2Þ

where Z is a vector of variables that captures theeconomy’s general fundamentals, as explained above.The ratio of exports to public debt ratio was droppedin the estimation and the results are in Table 2.

The impact of the general fundamentals on countryrisk was first investigated including one variable at atime. We could see that GDP growth is notsignificant, inflation is but collinear with maturityand both, interest rates and the ratio of internationalreserves to GDP are also significant. We can assumethat a model which incorporates all variables, exceptfor the inflation and GDP growth, is the mostparsimonious and was chosen to be used in thedecomposition for the pool of countries – this will beour benchmark.

The first specification and the most parsimoniousversion of the second specification were estimated foreach country separately. To verify the impact of thedifference in coefficients (or discrimination, if youprefer) we used the Oaxaca–Blinder decomposition(Table 3).

The second column of Table 3 shows the actualaverage EMBI for each county. The third and fourthcolumns are the predicted EMBI using coefficientsfrom the panel data estimations in the two specifica-tions with the variables of each country, respectively.In other words, the EMBI that would prevail ifcountries’ fundamentals were evaluated by themarket using the same parameters. The two specifica-tions produce similar results. The last two columnsare the differences between the EMBI’s predicted andthe actual values.

In absolute terms and taking into account onlyfiscal fundamentals, Argentina was the countrymost discriminated against among the countriesof the sample (see fifth column of Table 3). Theaverage EMBI for Argentina was approximately 1500base points higher than the expected considering

Table 1. Effects of debt fundamentals on country risk

1 2 3

Variables GLS IV GLS IV GLS IV

C 133.39 (125.59) 204.52 (128.27) 128.75 (125.34) 200.56 (128.04) �20.91 (188.27) �5.42 (197.24)PD/GDP 311.34 (36.55) 308.62 (36.80) 313.93 (36.31) 311.03 (36.55) 407.54 (95.08) 437.67 (99.04)MAT 249.43 (20.96) 243.90 (21.06) 249.33 (20.95) 243.80 (21.06) �64.94 (14.67) �78.79 (15.79)(PD/GDP) *DI �66.52 (14.56) �78.81 (15.19) �67.07 (14.53) �79.40 (15.16) 249.43 (20.95) 237.76 (21.34)X/PD �0.67 (1.08) �0.62 (1.08)(PD/GDP)2 �12.85 (12.06) �13.73 (12.42)

R2 0.56 0.20 0.56 0.56 0.56 0.56Adj. R2 0.55 0.20 0.55 0.56 0.55 0.56

Note: SDs in parentheses.

5All significant fiscal fundamentals were used to perform the tests (Model 2 in Table 1).

2582 V. K. Teles and M. C. Leme

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 8: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

its fundamentals. At the other extreme is Panama,which received what could be referred to as a ‘VIP’treatment. If only fundamentals were taken intoaccount Panama’s average EMBI would be morethan 1000 base points higher than actually is. Whengeneral fundamental are included major changes takeplace. Argentina, for instance, still receives the mostunfavourable treatment. On the other side, Venezuelabecomes the next in the rank just above Russiaand Ecuador. Malaysia is the most remarkable case.This country has the highest ratio of internationalreserves to GDP (about three times above theaverage ratio of the pool) but is valued at a muchlower rate: its coefficient is about 0.60 of the averagecoefficient. Therefore, the inclusion of this variable

changes completely the predicted EMBI which shouldin fact be negative when compared to the pool ofcountries. Peru and Korea are in the break evenpoint.

It is worth noting that, in some cases, the inclusionof variables like reserves–GDP ratio and interestrates brings the actual EMBI closer to the predicted.As a result, these general fundamentals are useful toexplain country risk only in these cases. For theothers they do not explain intolerance. In somecountries the inclusion of these fundamentalsincreases the difference between actual and predictedEMBIs, indicating an intolerance with respect tothese variables.

Table 4 shows the differences in the country-riskratings as a consequence of market sentiment.The first column is the actual ranking risk. Thesecond and third columns are the predicted rankingsas indicated by the fundamentals. The last twocolumns are the differences between the actual andthe predicted results. A positive value in the last twocolumns means that market sentiment is significantenough to change the country’s ranking position.

Although, in absolute terms, Argentina is the mostdiscriminated country, it remains in the first spot ofthe ranking even when market sentiment is elimi-nated. Argentina is indeed the highest risk country ofthe sample. On the other side, Russia had the thirdhighest average EMBI during the period underanalysis and it was placed in the second spot whenonly fiscal fundamental are taken into account.However, when more general fundamentals areincluded, Russia occupies again the third place.Malaysia is the country with the major change inraking position for the reasons discussed above.

Table 5 shows the relative market sentiment for thetwo specifications. Some changes can be noted regard-ing the previous case of absolute market sentiment.

Table 2. The effects of general fundamentals on country risk

Models

Variables 1 2 3 4 5

C 379.91 (132.59) �600.45 (125.74) �316.97 (167.60) 746.00 (127.57) 889.32 (67.51)PD/GDP 296.66 (38.38) 384.38 (33.74) 400.06 (41.46) 338.29 (34.67) 34.17 (18.59)MAT �104.97 (15.60) 1.38 (14.79) �63.74 (16.80) �23.82 (14.98) �35.43 (7.33)(PD*GDP) *DI 200.71 (21.89) 52.20 (20.57) 187.29 (24.58) 207.69 (20.03) 311.64 (25.37)GDP GROWTH 17.21 (24.51)INFLATION 28.00 (1.43)INTEREST RATES 23.00 (4.94) 13.65 (1.32)RESERVES/GDP �1156.44 (87.97) �436.18 (41.64)

R2 0.59 0.68 0.53 0.61 0.64Adj. R2 0.59 0.68 0.52 0.61 0.64

Note: SDs in parentheses.

Table 3. Actual EMBI and EMBI predicted by market

fundamentals

Actual Predicted 1 Predicted 2

(A) (B) (C) B�A C�A

Argentina 3023 1499 1475 �1524 �1549

Russia 1084 381 816 �703 �268

Ecuador 1484 1152 1246 �332 �238

Ukraine 548 265 874 �282 327

Venezuela 979 739 506 �240 �473

Philippines 468 281 632 �186 165

Colombia 536 367 710 �169 174

Mexico 350 188 655 �162 305

Peru 495 553 487 57 �8

Korea 184 255 185 70 1

Poland 171 319 533 148 362

Bulgaria 474 698 528 224 54

South Africa 148 427 825 279 676

Brazil 819 1105 1050 286 231

Malaysia 113 507 �129 394 �242

Egypt 239 704 694 465 454

Turkey 569 1071 1275 501 705

Morocco 398 1192 691 794 293

Panama 387 1536 748 1149 362

Fundamentals or market sentiment 2583

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 9: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

Now, in terms of fiscal fundamental, Russia is themost

discriminated against: its EMBI should be roughly

65% lower than actually is. Meanwhile Panama and

Malaysia remain as themost privileged countries in our

sample. When other macro variables are included, this

scenario changes a bit:Malaysiamoves from the last to

the first position in the ranking.

IV. Conclusions

An analysis of country risk for a pool of emergingmarkets shows that its determinants reflect bothfundamentals and sentiment features. If the onlyfactors taken into consideration were economicfundamentals and past behaviour in relation to debtrepayment then a number of countries would exhibit adifferent level of risk than they actually do. Based onour analysis, the only country in the sample receiving a‘fair evaluation’ is South Korea, but, this is so, onlywhen macro variables are included. In absolute terms,Argentina is the most discriminated country in thesample and even after correcting for such tendency it isstill the riskiest country. Ecuador, Venezuela andRussia change positions but are always placed in thetop five of the ranking of risky countries. Turkey andBrazil considerably drop positions and are negativelyaffected and impacted by such ratings. After correct-ing for market sentiment, Brazil drops from the fifthto the 14th place of the riskiest countries in terms offiscal fundamentals or to 11th place in more generalterms. On the other hand, Turkey drops from the sixthto the 17th and 19th place, respectively. Malaysia is aspecial case given that in terms of fiscal fundamentalsit has a better position than it really should; but whenthe ratio of international reserves to GDP is included,Malaysia is severely discriminated and occupies theworst relative position.

References

Blanchard, O. (2005) Fiscal dominance and inflationtargeting: lessons from Brazil, in Inflation Targeting,Debt, and the Brazilian Experience, 1999 to 2003 (Eds)F. Giavazzi, I. Goldfajn and S. Herrera, MIT Press,Cambridge, MA, pp. 49–84.

Beck, R. (2001) Do country fundamentals explain emergingmarket bond spreads?, CFS Working Paper No.2001/02, Centre for Financial Studies, Frankfurt.

Choi, I. (2001) Unit root tests for panel data, Journal ofInternational Money and Finance, 20, 249–72.

Edwards, S. (1984) LDCs’ foreign borrowing and defaultrisk: an empirical investigation, 1976–1980, AmericanEconomic Review, 74, 726–34.

Eichengreen, B. and Mody, A. (1998) What explainschanging spreads on emerging-market debt:fundamentals or market sentiment?, NBER WorkingPaper Series W6408.

Fiess, N. (2003) Capital flows, country risk and contagionpolicy, #Research Working Paper No. 2943, TheWorld Bank.

Fournier, M. (2005) Exploiting information from pathdependency in Oaxaca–Blinder decompositionprocedures, Applied Economics Letters, 12, 669–72.

Im, K. S., Pesaran, M. H. and Shin, Y. (2003) Testing forunit roots in heterogeneous panels, Journal ofEconometrics, 115, 53–74.

Table 5. Relative market sentiment

Country Rel. 1 Rel. 2

Russia �0.65 �0.25Ukraine �0.52 0.60Argentina �0.50 �0.51Mexico �0.46 0.87Philippines �0.40 0.35Colombia �0.32 0.33Venezuela �0.25 �0.48Ecuador �0.22 �0.16Peru 0.12 �0.02Brazil 0.35 0.28Korea 0.38 0.00Bulgaria 0.47 0.11Poland 0.86 2.12Turkey 0.88 1.24South Africa 1.88 4.56Egypt 1.94 1.90Morocco 2.00 0.74Panama 2.97 0.94Malaysia 3.49 �2.14

Table 4. Rank

Actualrank

RankEMBI 1

RankEMBI 2

Country A B C B–A C–A

Argentina 1 1 1 0 0Ecuador 2 3 5 1 3Russia 3 2 3 �1 0Venezuela 4 5 2 1 �2Brazil 5 14 11 9 6Turkey 6 17 19 11 13Ukraine 7 4 14 �3 7Colombia 8 7 10 �1 2Peru 9 9 6 0 �3Bulgaria 10 12 8 2 �2Philippines 11 6 9 �5 �2Morocco 12 18 12 6 0Panama 13 19 15 6 2Mexico 14 8 13 �6 �1Egypt 15 16 17 1 2Korea 16 10 7 �6 �9Poland 17 11 16 �6 �1South Africa 18 13 18 �5 0Malaysia 19 15 4 �4 �15

2584 V. K. Teles and M. C. Leme

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14

Page 10: Fundamentals or market sentiment: what causes country risk?

Maddala, G. S. and Wu, S. (1999) A comparative studyof unit root tests with panel data and a new simple test,Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 61, 631–52.

Min, H. G. (1999) Determinants of emerging market bondspread: do economic fundamentals matter?, WorkingPaper Series, The World Bank.

Mitchell, J., Smith, R. J., Weale, M. R., Wright, S. andSalazar, E. J. (2005) An indicator of monthly GDP andan early estimate of quarterly GDP growth, TheEconomic Journal, 115, 108–29.

Mitra, S. (2007) Is the quantity of government debt aconstraint for monetary policy?, IMF Working PaperNo. WP/07/62.

Mourougane, A. and Roma, M. (2003) Can confidenceindicators be useful to predict short term real GDPgrowth?, Applied Economics Letters, 10, 519–22.

Neumark, D. (1988) Employers discriminatory behaviorand estimation of wage discrimination, Journal ofHuman Resources, 23, 279–95.

Oaxaca, R. (1973) Male–female wage differentials in urbanlabor markets, International Economic Review, 14,693–709.

Oaxaca, R. and Ramson, M. R. (1994) On discriminationand decomposition of wage differentials, Journal ofEconometrics, 61, 5–21.

Reinhart, C., Rogoff, K. and Savastano, M. (2003) Debtintolerance, NBER Working Paper No. W9908.

Shrestha, K. and Sakellariou, C. (1996) Wagediscrimination: a statistical test, Applied EconomicsLetters, 3, 649–51.

Teles, V. K. and Andrade, J. (2008) Monetary policy andcountry risk, Applied Economics, 40, 2021–8.

Appendix

Table A1. Unit root tests

Levin, Lin and Chu t* Im, Pesaran and Shin W-stat** ADF-Fisher �2** PP-Fisher �2**

Variables Statistic Prob. Statistic Prob. Statistic Prob. Statistic Prob.

EMBI �2.37 0.01 �1.93 0.03 50.61 0.05 104.22 0.00Public debt/GDP �3.67 0.00 �2.34 0.01 63.94 0.00 67.27 0.00Maturity 2.41 0.99 0.87 0.81 46.76 0.11 56.70 0.02Default index*(PD/GDP) 0.67 0.75 �2.19 0.01 61.17 0.00 61.81 0.00Public debt/exports �4.44 0.00 �6.61 0.00 185.54 0.00 242.99 0.00GDP growth 0.02 0.51 �3.94 0.00 79.46 0.00 103.17 0.00Inflation �3.47 0.00 �4.60 0.00 89.27 0.00 89.76 0.00

Notes: *Assumes common unit root process. **Assumes individual unit root process.

Table A2. Unit root tests with trend

Levin,Lin and Chu t*

Breitungt-stat*

Im, Pesaran andShin W-stat** ADF-Fisher �2** PP-Fisher �2**

Variables Statistic Prob.** Statistic Prob.** Statistic Prob.** Statistic Prob.** Statistic Prob.**

Public debt/GDP 2.37 0.99 �1.32 0.09 �4.83 0.00 98.66 0.00 82.87 0.00Maturity 0.38 0.65 1.01 0.84 �3.57 0.00 76.31 0.00 105.55 0.00

Notes: *Assumes common unit root process. **Assumes individual unit root process.

Table A3. Fixed versus random effects tests

Test Statistic p-value

Hausman test 44.4076 0.0000Redundant fixed effectsCross-section F 35.5863 0.0000Cross-section chi-square 536.7126 0.0000

Fundamentals or market sentiment 2585

Dow

nloa

ded

by [

Uni

vers

ity o

f Il

linoi

s C

hica

go]

at 1

0:04

10

Nov

embe

r 20

14