gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality jonathan gershuny...

22
Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology University of Oxford For GENET Conference, December 2009

Upload: megan-cameron

Post on 28-Mar-2015

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality

Jonathan Gershuny

Centre for Time Use Research

Department of Sociology

University of Oxford

For GENET Conference, December 2009

Page 2: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

This Talk• Proposition:

– National systems of regulation of access to work have effects on life chances which differ markedly by gender and class-of origin.

• Based on two unpublished papers: – Man-Yee Kan, Oriel Sullivan, JG; “Gender Convergence

in Domestic Work” (2009)– JG; “Dynamics of Social Position” (2008)

Kan, Sullivan and Gershuny are in the Sociology Department and Centre for Time Use Research, University of Oxford.

Page 3: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Definitions• Portable or Embodied (vs Fixed) capitals:

• “human” (Becker, Mincer) or• (1) “economic”, (2) social, (3) cultural (Bourdieu)

• Embodied capitals formed: – In household of origin…– …then through the formal educational system…– …and recursively through practices of daily life.

• time-use gives empirical estimates of practices

• Embodied capital dynamics life chances• Good/bad outcomes result from current capitals• Capitals indicate advantages and outcomes• Hence, new approach to intergenerational social mobility.

Page 4: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

The day and the lifecourse

Theoretical intuition:

Daily choices among paid work, unpaid work, leisure/consumption

capitals form at differential rates

differentiate individual life-chancesconsequences for transmission of

position to children

Page 5: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Two steps (two data sources)

• STEP 1 (Multinational Time Use Study)– Typologies of national systems of work

regulation and gender ideologies…– …are strongly associated with different

historical changes in work patterns

• STEP 2 (British Household Panel Study) – Lifecourse changes in gender work-sharing…– …polarise class mobility and life-chances

Page 7: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

The Multinational Time Use Study @ December 2009 N of Days 1970 -74 1975 -84 1985 -89 1990 -94 1995 -99 2000 -04 total

Canada 2138 2682 9618 8936 10726 34100 Denmark 4173 3584 7757

France 2898 4633 14631 22162 Netherlands 4019 3263 3158 3227 11851 25518 Norway 6516 6068 6129 7904 26617 UK 9292 14898 9206 1962 17248 52606 USA 2021 7010 4935 9386 1151 20340 44843 Finland 11908 15219 8354 1686 37167

Italy 37764 51206 88970 Australia 1491 3181 13937 14315 32924 Israel 3126 3126 Sweden 7065 7747 14812 Germany 3687 22554 35813 62054 Austria 25162 25162

South Africa 14217 14217 Slovenia 12273 12273 Spain 46774 46774 Column total 22071 14778 46585 86770 99453 54366 227059 551082 N of surveys 5 4 6 8 9 7 11 50

Page 8: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

all unpaid work, men 20-59

60

80

100

120

140

160

180

1961-69 1970-74 1975-84 1985-89 1990-94 1995-99 2000-04

mins per day

Canada

Denmark

France

Netherlands

Norway

UK

USA

Finland

Italy

Australia

Israel

Sweden

Germany

Austria

South Africa

Slovenia

Spain

all unpaid work, women 20-59

200

250

300

350

400

450

1961-69 1970-74 1975-84 1985-89 1990-94 1995-99 2000-04

mins per day

Canada

Denmark

France

Netherlands

Norway

UK

USA

Finland

Italy

Australia

Israel

Sweden

Germany

Austria

South Africa

Slovenia

Spain

Page 9: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Welfare Regimes and Gender Ideologies• liberal market regimes:

– UK, the USA, Canada and Australia – modified breadwinner gender ideology, women both paid

work & caring roles

• social democratic nordic regimes: – Denmark, Norway, Finland, Sweden – dual earner family model, high employment rate of both

women and men

• conservative/corporatist regimes: – Netherlands, France, Germany, Austria– weak familist gender ideology, men primary breadwinners,

women carers

• southern regime: (later addition to typology) – Spain, Italy and Israel– traditional familist gender ideology, stronger emphasis on

women’s family role

Page 10: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Women’s proportion of all unpaid work (men and women age d 20-59)

a. Nordic women's proportions of

all unpaid work

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

1961-69 1970-

74

1975-

84

1985-

89

1990-

94

1995-

99

2000-

04

%

Denmark

Norway

Finland

Sweden

modelednordic

ew

b. Liberal women's proportions of all unpaid work

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

1961-

69

1970-

74

1975-

84

1985-

89

1990-

94

1995-

99

2000-

04

%

Canada

UK

USA

Australia

modeledliberal

e

c. Corporatist women's prop. of all unpaid work

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

1961-

69

1970-

74

1975-

84

1985-

89

1990-

94

1995-

99

2000-

04

%

France

Netherlands

Germany

Austria

Slovenia

modeledcorporatist

d. Southern women's prop. of all unpaid work

55

60

65

70

75

80

85

1961-

69

1970-

74

1975-

84

1985-

89

1990-

94

1995-

99

2000-

04

%

Italy

Spain

modeledsouthern

Page 11: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Step 1. Public regulation matters

Note:– corporatist, liberal and nordic groups all start

out rather similar in the 1960s– Gender equality in total work (“isowork”)

Implications:

1. Public policy has a real effect on gendered balance between paid and unpaid work

2. Gender differentials in rates of accumulation of economic capital affected by regime choices.

Page 12: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Human capital: the “Essex Score”Data from British Household Panel Study

– 5000 UK households, 1991—present

Variables in the model:• Age, age squared, Education dummies• MOW scores (mean occupational wage, 2 digit

categories, standardised to 0-100)• Work, family care months over past 4 years• Dummies for top MOW decile and deciles 7 to 9 • Product of MOW dummies and age, age squared• Sex only in selection equation

Kan and Gershuny ISER WP 2006-03

Page 13: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

BHPS longitudinal evidence

all couples, human capital before and after first birth

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

before

2 4 6 8 10

human capital score

woman

man

Page 14: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Contrasting “leavers” and “stayers”

• Consider all women in employment at time of BHPS interview before first birth:

– “leavers”—women not in employment the year after first birth.

– “stayers”—women in employment at all of six subsequent annual interviews.

– Note third intermediate category: non-leavers with various other post-birth strategies.

(details of regression modelling available on request)

Page 15: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Alternative household work strategies

all couples, w ife not in employment year after first birth

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

before

2 4 6 8 10

human capital score

woman

man

all couples, w ife employed first 6 years after first birth

5

6

7

8

9

10

11

before

2 4 6 8 10

human capital score

woman

man

Page 16: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

all women, parents in top human capital quintile

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

before

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years before/after first childbirth

human capital score

born in1920sborn in1930sborn in1940sborn in1950s

all women, parents in bottom human capital quintile

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

before

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years before/after first childbirth

humasn capital score

born in 1920s

born in 1930s

born in 1940s

born in 1950s

Page 17: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

top parental human capital quintiles: stayers vs leavers

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

beforeafter

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years before/after birth of first child

modelled human capital score

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

Page 18: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

top parental human capital quintiles: stayers vs leavers

stayer 1920s

leaver 1920s

stayer 1930s

leaver 1930s

stayer 1940s

leaver 1940s

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

beforeafter2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years before/after birth of first child

modelled human capital score

stayer 1920s

leaver 1920s

stayer 1930s

leaver 1930s

stayer 1940s

leaver 1940s

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

Page 19: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

top parental human capital quintiles: stayers vs leavers

stayer 1920s

leaver 1920s

stayer 1930s

leaver 1930s

stayer 1940s

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

beforeafter2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years before/after birth of first child

modelled human capital score

stayer 1920s

leaver 1920s

stayer 1930s

leaver 1930s

stayer 1940s

leaver 1940s

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

bottom parental human capital quintiles, stayers vs leavers

stayer 1920s

leaver 1920s

stayer 1930s

leaver 1930s

stayer 1940s

leaver 1940s

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

2.00

3.00

4.00

5.00

6.00

7.00

8.00

before after2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years before and after first birth

modelled human capital score

stayer 1920s

leaver 1920s

stayer 1930s

leaver 1930s

stayer 1940s

leaver 1940s

stayer 1950s

leaver 1950s

Page 20: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Leaving-vs-staying penalties,women with parents in the top human capital quintile

born in 1920s

born in 1930s

born in 1940s

born in 1950s

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

0.35

0.40

year after

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years after first childbirth

stayer hc/leaver hc -1

born in1920sborn in1930sborn in1940sborn in1950s

Leaving-vs-staying penalties, women with parents in the bottom human capital quintile

born in 1920s

born in 1930s

born in 1940s

born in 1950s

0.10

0.20

0.30

0.40

0.50

0.60

0.70

0.80

year after

2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9

years after first birth

stayer hc/leaver hc -1

born in 1920s

born in 1930s

born in 1940s

born in 1950s

Page 21: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

Step 2. Gender balance matters

UK as example of liberal regime lacking strong childcare & paternity leave regulations:

• For women with parents in top quintile: – Income (humcap) penalties falling from the

1930s to 1950s birth cohorts, to around 20%.• For women with parents in bottom quintile:

– penalties rising from 1920s to 1950s birth cohorts, from 40% to 70% 7 yrs after birth.

Page 22: Gendered divisions of labour and the intergenerational transmission of inequality Jonathan Gershuny Centre for Time Use Research Department of Sociology

L/S penalties interact with parents’ class situation and regimes

Conclude: gendered polarisation

in intergen. transmission of life chances…

• … results from choices made under constraints of national system of regulation

• …and this effect is intensified by concurrent rise in marital dissolution:

• He leaves with the human capital• She’s left with the baby…• …and another child grows up in poverty.