h3 economics papers

30
The significance of economics “What is my advice for students worried about the recent financial crisis? Learn some economics,” said Greg Mankiw. It may seem counterintuitive to rely on the subject which has gotten so much so wrong—as exemplified by the financial crisis itself, in which theories such as the Efficient Markets Hypothesis led to excessive deregulation and the falsely propagated ‘Great Moderation’. Yet abandoning economics, either as a predictive tool or a policy science, would be an unhelpful overreaction. Indeed, economics has progressed much from crises, and even if its prescriptions may sometimes be wrong, as Anatole Kaletsky argued, economics can explain and describe what went wrong, how it went wrong, and how we may avoid such a situation in the future. For the individual: 1. Economics helps people understand the whirlwind of forces swirling around them. 2. Develops rigorous analytic skills 3. Makes students better citizens 4. Joan Robinson: The purpose of studying economics is not to acquire a set of ready-made answers to economic questions, but to learn how to avoid being deceived by economists 5. (Statistics) Interpreting data 6. (Finance) Managing own finances e.g. diversification, going to college How economics is progressing from the crisis 1. Behavioural economics—people are 2. Ignoring advice: the future is far from certain a. Black Swan events have such huge impacts precisely because they are unpredictable 3. Renewed role of Keynesian fiscal policy a. Is this just a temporary swing? Or are we finally recognising that governments can and should play an important role in their economies? i. “Governments need the capability to step in when they can make things better, the humility to pull out when they are making things worse, and most of

Upload: davidboh

Post on 19-Jan-2016

87 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

H3 Economics Papers

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: H3 Economics Papers

The significance of economics

“What is my advice for students worried about the recent financial crisis? Learn some economics,” said Greg Mankiw. It may seem counterintuitive to rely on the subject which has gotten so much so wrong—as exemplified by the financial crisis itself, in which theories such as the Efficient Markets Hypothesis led to excessive deregulation and the falsely propagated ‘Great Moderation’. Yet abandoning economics, either as a predictive tool or a policy science, would be an unhelpful overreaction. Indeed, economics has progressed much from crises, and even if its prescriptions may sometimes be wrong, as Anatole Kaletsky argued, economics can explain and describe what went wrong, how it went wrong, and how we may avoid such a situation in the future.

For the individual:

1. Economics helps people understand the whirlwind of forces swirling around them. 2. Develops rigorous analytic skills3. Makes students better citizens4. Joan Robinson: The purpose of studying economics is not to acquire a set of ready-made

answers to economic questions, but to learn how to avoid being deceived by economists5. (Statistics) Interpreting data6. (Finance) Managing own finances e.g. diversification, going to college

How economics is progressing from the crisis

1. Behavioural economics—people are2. Ignoring advice: the future is far from certain

a. Black Swan events have such huge impacts precisely because they are unpredictable3. Renewed role of Keynesian fiscal policy

a. Is this just a temporary swing? Or are we finally recognising that governments can and should play an important role in their economies?

i. “Governments need the capability to step in when they can make things better, the humility to pull out when they are making things worse, and most of all, the wisdom to know the difference.” Ravi Menon, from Singapore’s Ministry of Trade and Industry

The crisis has prompted a fundamental re-think of the relationship between markets and governments. The contest is not just between economic theories but between competing systems of political economy and models of governance.

- Barry Eichengreen: The crisis has “cast into doubt much of what we thought we knew about economics.”

- Paul Krugman: much of the past 30 years of macroeconomics was “spectacularly useless at best, and positively harmful at worst.”

- Gary Becker: “free markets sometimes don't do a very good job ... but if I take the first proposition of Chicago economics - that free markets generally do a good job - I think that still holds”.

- Blaug: “Economics emphasizes technical puzzle-solving abilities at the expense of knowledge of the economic system”

Page 2: H3 Economics Papers

Economists know a lot about how the economy works, and can offer some useful advice on things like how to avoid hyperinflations (for sure) and depressions (usually). But there’s a lot that they can’t cure. Above all, they don’t know how to make a poor country rich, or bring back the magic of economic growth when it seems to have gone away. These limitations are a big problem for politicians…and a different group, the policy entrepreneurs, has arisen to fill the gap. (Krugman)

Market failure revealed by the crisis

1. Information asymmetry2. Moral Hazard3. Systemic risks4. Behavioural or non-rational motivators of choice5. Inherent limitations of government in a globalised and complex economy

Monetarism vs Keynesianism

- Monetarists argue that keeping the money supply steady is sufficient - Friedman: monetary and fiscal policy work with “long and variable lags”, and thus instead of

smoothing out the business cycle, would make things worse- Advocated rules not discretion- Fiscal policy would result in the crowding out of productive investment

The usefulness of economics in predictions

- Friedman : The usefulness of a theory is judged not by its realism, but by its predictive power “Economics is to be judged by the precision, scope, and conformity with experience of the predictions it yields. In short, positive economics is, or can be, an ‘objective science, in precisely the same sense as any of the physical sciences.”

- Solow : A good theory is always trying to tell us something even if it is not the literal truth- Marshall : Economic science is but the working of common sense aided by appliances of

organised analysis and general reasoning - Anatole Kaletsky : Economics should recognise that, as a discipline, it cannot be about

predicting, but is instead about explaining and describing - Galbraith : The only function of economic forecasting is to make astrology look respectable- John Kay : A fiscal watchdog should not need a crystal ball… Anyone confident in predicting

either a strong recovery or a collapse in business confidence is a fool. There will always be a demand for forecasts, so there will always be a supply. But the reputation of economic forecasters, like other quacks and charlatans, depends more on the slickness of their presentations than the value of their work.

Unrealistic models are termed the Ricardian Vice; implausible assumptions may yield fascinating results, but the fact remains that the model’s conclusions may hardly apply at all in real life. A model tries to turn the normative into the positive.

John Milton: By misdirection we arrive closer at the truth

Blaug: When theories face empirical difficulties, as they always do, one attempts to modify them. If some of the new predictions are confirmed, then the modification is “empirically progressive,” and

Page 3: H3 Economics Papers

one has reason to reject the unmodified theory and to employ the new theory, regardless of how unsuccessful in general either theory may be. What matters is empirical progress or retrogression rather than empirical success or failure. This causes paradigm shifts (Kuhn), a result of the intellectual competition between theories, and the challenge of conventional wisdom.

Economics as a science

1. Not scientific in the sense of predictive power (anyway, most natural sciences except astronomy only work in controlled experiments)

2. Scientific in the sense of providing a causal mechanism3. Cannot exist in isolation: social phenomena are constituted in relation to each other4. No stability: economies are continually changing

a. Moreover, the study of economics itself affects economies and economic behaviouri. E.g. game theory, profit/revenue maximisation

Lawson: If science is the move from phenomena of interest to underlying causes then this move is a feasible in economics as in natural science. However, in some special cases natural scientists can successfully carry out controlled experimentation. In such conditions, event regularities may be produced in the course of their evaluating a theory about an underlying causal mechanism.

Economists, though, have typically not only restricted their focus to this special case, but also universalized the wrong aspect of it. Instead of seeing the central moment as furthering our understanding of some underlying causal mechanism, economists have focused on the experimental production of event regularities. And they have generalized this inessential feature of science to a context, namely the social realm, where typically the conditions are such that event regularities do not occur.

Although a science of social phenomena remains entirely feasible, the reliance on methods of mathematical modeling in economics, presupposing as it does a ubiquity of even regularities, mainly serves as an obstacle to the discipline’s realizing its scientific potential

- Marshall : The forces of which economics has to take into account are more numerous, less definite, less well known, and more diverse in character than those of mechanics; while the material on which they act is more uncertain and less homogeneous

- Keynes : Due to the nature of economic material, a generalisation to cover everything is impossible and impracticable

Keynes: The master-economist... must be mathematician, historian, statesman, philosopher... He must study the present in the light of the past for the purposes of the future.

- “Unlike physics, economics yields no natural laws or universal constants” Kagel and Rotho However, Roth later clarified that economics could still be a science: laboratory

experiments, such as Kagel and Roth’s studies of market organizations, complement

Page 4: H3 Economics Papers

other forms of investigation. Experiments in biology do not reveal universal constants either, but biology is still as much of a science as physics.

o Then again it is difficult to conduct controlled laboratory experiments, and we want to see whether theories apply in real life, not in controlled settings

- Can try to find natural experiments e.g. Angrist and Kruger’s study of whether education increased people’s incomes

o However, there are only so many things that natural experiments can tell you may end up avoiding big questions

- Need to use econometrics and data analysis to judge the accuracy of theories; otherwise, sensible policy prescriptions are impossible

Economic methods

Both inductive and deductive methods in economics are problematic: Mill maintains that direct inductive methods can study only phenomena with few causal factors in play (ceteris paribus).

Black Swan problem of inductive reasoning: a turkey that has not been killed for the past 100 days may inductively conclude that it will not die on the 101st—but the 101st day may be Thanksgiving.

Inductive and deductive reasoning may be used in combination: Economists believe that demand curves slope down because of statistical evidence accumulating in journals. Yet more beliefs in the hypotheses come from other sources: deduction (a higher price leaves less disposable income), introspection (what would I do), and extrapolation (if the demand curve for iron slopes down, why not for love?)

All historical explanations are pseudo-explanations, they may be true or false but we will rarely know the case (Hempel)

Falsifiability

Popper holds that hypotheses are scientific only if their predictions are in principle falsifiable – this is the only way we can know if a theory is true: that it makes definite predictions about economic events.

Theories have been falsified include:

The Philips Curve, which supposes a stable trade-off between inflation and unemployment, and broke down in the stagflation of the 1970s

There is a stable velocity of circulation of money

However, empirical testing is difficult and ambiguous, given the near-impossibility of experiments, and the lack of ceteris paribus conditions. The Duhem-Quine thesis in fact states that it is logically impossible to decisively refute any theory, since a refutation can always be blamed on inappropriate initial conditions. And in economics, subsidiary assumptions are often dubious or patently false.

Page 5: H3 Economics Papers

Only 3 out of 500 empirical articles in top journals attempted to falsify the proposed hypotheses (Canterbery), and 50% of American Economic Review articles had models but no data (Leontief).

Empirical testing is a safety valve protecting economics from falling prey to dogmatism. Blaug: “To predict and prescribe policy, economics must be first and foremost an empirical science.”

Krugman: “Economists have mistaken beauty for truth.”“To succeed, an idea need not be true or even useful, as long as it has what it takes to propagate itself”

Statistics in economics

Statistical inference can be too stringent or too lax (Type 1/2 errors), and ‘fudge factors’ are often introduced into econometric models

- Epstein : Math is descriptive and not explanatory: we may accurately describe behaviour in mathematical terms, but what happens inside the system remains unknown

- Kaletsky : “Smith, Ricardo and Keynes produced no mathematical models. Their work lacked the “analytical rigour” and precise deductive logic demanded by modern economics. If any of these giants of economics applied for a university job today, they would be rejected. As for their written work, it would not have a chance of acceptance in the Economic Journal or American Economic Review.”

- Krugman : The profession’s failure was the desire for an all-encompassing, intellectually elegant approach that also gave economists a chance to show off their mathematical prowess

- Hahn : Not only will our successors have to be far less concerned with general laws than we have been, they will have to study complexity. Not for them the pleasure of theorems and proofs. Instead, the uncertain embrace of history, sociology and biology

- Marshall : The most helpful applications of mathematics to economics are those which are short and simple, which employ few symbols; and which aim at throwing a bright light on some small part of the great economic movement rather than at representing its endless complexities

o In line with Occam’s Razor, simpler theories should be preferred

Roosevelt: Economic laws are not made by nature. They are made by men and we decide how the economy is to work

Assumptions

Assumptions may not have to be realistic; what matters may be the robustness of a theory—that its predictions hold even if the assumptions are violated. There may be robustness to changes in the model’s idealisations, changes in background conditions, or changes in the causal mechanism.

One major assumption is that of rational economic man. This removes the differences caused by irrationality, so theorists need not worry about what people’s beliefs are. However, there are

Page 6: H3 Economics Papers

limitations of human rationality due to imperfect information and ‘herd’ mentality, as seen by the formation of bubbles that disprove the Efficient Markets Hypothesis. Moreover, choices depend on expectations: the ‘true’ value of a stock depends on future profits, but what matters in the short run is what people believe.

Bounded rationality may be a suitable alternative: economic actors display inertia in their reaction to new information and are strongly influenced by emotional and hormonal reactions

The risk management models that underlay financial instruments were highly flawed, failing to take into account tail-end risks, leverage, interconnectedness, and foreign currency exposure (IMF)

Fallacies

1. Fallacy of composition/aggregation: what is true for one person may not be true for the economy as a whole

a. E.g. Nash equilibrium, systemic risk2. Post-hoc fallacy: just because two events occur together doesn’t mean one caused the other

a. E.g. Money supply growth and inflation3. Other-conditions fallacy: even if two events always occurred in together in the past, they

may not always occur together in the future a. E.g. Philips curve

4. Misleading comparison: comparing things in a way that does not reflect their true difference5. Selection bias

a. Coase: If you torture the data long enough, it will confess

Industrial policy

Dani Rodrik: “the proverbial road to hell is paved with well-meaning industrial development plans.”

But Michael Porter argues that “national prosperity is created, not inherited”

Governments’ roles:

1. Enable markets by ensuring the rule of law, property rights, and public infrastructurea. Going further: capability developmentb. Agglomeration benefits (high growth industries e.g. previously chemicals, now

biomedical)c. Positive externalities from information and learning spill-overs

2. Regulate markets, including supervising the financial sector, ensuring competition, and taxing negative externalities.

a. Shift towards lighter regulation accompanied by risk-based supervision3. Stabilise markets: macroeconomic management

Page 7: H3 Economics Papers

a. In the recent financial crisis, economists advocated loose monetary policy and expansionary fiscal policy; this was largely successful and much of the world is rebounding, and the effects of what was once proclaimed the second Great Depression have been comparatively muted

4. Legitimise markets by facilitating difficult transitions, redistributing incomes, or providing social safety nets, so as to maintain public support for market-oriented policies

Ricardo Hausmann: “What distinguishes a good industrial policy is not the ability to pick winners, but the guts to let losers go.”

In Paul David’s article, ‘Clio and The Economics of QWERTY’, he explained how historical factors can lead to an inefficient allocation of resources becoming “locked in”.

The collective results of free choices may ‘lock in’ a bad result. We may end up producing an inferior technology, locating an industry in a congested metropolis when it could function better elsewhere, or seeing another country ‘lock in’ an advantage with timely government intervention, and thereby be locked out ourselves.

Government failure

Japan’s attempts at fiscal policy have failed to pull it out of a nearly twenty-year depression. It is also facing a liquidity trap. Japan has supply-side problems which are much more difficult to address: structural unemployment and a mismatch of industries, with excess capacity in the property sector, and a hollowing out of the manufacturing sector.

Lags in recognition, analysis, implementation, and effect

Friedman argued that discretionary policy would not only be ineffective but destabilising ‘’

There is no such thing as favouring producers over consumers. Each of us is a producer, typically from nine to five, and a consumer the rest of the day (Krugman)

Nature of Economics

Krugman: Because the exchange of goods and services is a less complex, perhaps less human activity than other social interactions, economics lends itself both to the development of theory and the testing of that theory to a greater extent than other social sciences.

However, economics has a direct impact on government policies that affect almost everyone, and therefore change the nature of the subject itself. Moreover, people care about economics only enough to know what they want to believe.

Page 8: H3 Economics Papers

International Trade and Globalisation

Ricardian model of comparative advantage

Countries should specialise in producing what they can produce at a lower opportunity cost.

Hecksher-Ohlin Theorem

(expanded on the theory of CA by introducing capital as a factor of production)Countries will export products that use their abundant factors of production, and import products that use their scarce factors of production. This is because the profitability of goods is determined by input costs.

Expansions:

1. Rybczynski theorem: When the amount of one factor of production increases, the production of the good which uses that particular factor of production intensively increases relative to the increase in the factor of production

2. Stolper-Samuelson theorem: Relative changes in the prices of output goods will drive the relative prices of the factors used to produce them

3. Factor-Price equalisation theorem: Free trade will make factor prices converge along with traded goods prices.

a. For example, after NAFTA was signed, the wages of unskilled labour fell in the US, and rose in Mexico

However, the assumption of factor-intensity reversal, that a commodity is always intensive in a given factor regardless of relative factor prices, may not hold. Commodities may have different relative factor intensity at different relative factor prices. This may explain why a labour-intensive country such as India and a capital-intensive country like the US can export the same commodity. The H-O theorem also assumes that production functions are identical, which is unrealistic, as the technological gap between developed and developing countries is the main concern for the development of poor countries.

Factor-price equalisation also does not prove that trade will pull up wages in developing countries, due to the fallacy of aggregation of goods: trade economists ignore the impact of non-traded goods on factor prices. Trade liberalisation may lower the price of the unskilled-labour intensive good produced in a country, and thus hurt the wages of those at the very bottom.

Refutations:

1. Leontief’s paradox: the US exported more labour intensive products even though its abundant factor of production was capital

a. However, this may possibly be explained by ‘demand reversal’: if demand in two countries is so different such that the price of a good that uses the abundant factor of production is higher, trade can flow in the opposite direction.

2. Vernon’s Product Life Cycle theory: production moves away from the point of origin as the product matures

3. Keesing Human Skills Theory of Trade: based on human factor endowments

Page 9: H3 Economics Papers

4. Dynamic comparative advantage: nations create their own comparative advantages (Singapore especially; most recently in the biotechnology sector)

a. Michael Porter: “nations succeed in industries where they are particularly good at factor creation”

New Trade Theory

Krugman (1985) propounded the theory of economic geography, which focuses on the role of historical accident in determining patterns of trade. Increasing returns to scale lead to agglomeration effects that governments can and should help to create, to promote major industries, because a large industrial concentration may be needed to facilitate the flow of information. Governments have the largest role in promoting external economies of scale, such as in Silicon Valley, which prospered precisely because of a large pool of skilled labour, specialised suppliers, and the flow of knowledge. Industry localisation demonstrates path dependence: the role of historical accident in determining the shape of the economy

The theory of comparative advantage explains a lot of international trade, but fails to explain why increasingly similar advanced nations began to trade so much with each other, especially after WWII. By 1990, 76% of advanced country exports went to other advanced nations.

Exports from one industrial country to another don’t give us much indication that they are based on any underlying national resource of characteristic (Krugman) At a broad level, trade reflects resources: a country with a highly skilled labour force will, in general, export goods whose production requires a high ratio of skilled to unskilled labour, and import goods for which the reverse is true. But precisely which goods the country exports cannot be determined from its resources alone. That final determination rests in the realm of chance and history, in the land of QWERTY.

Strategic Trade Theory

In the Brander-Spencer Model, a government subsidy for one firm could give that firm a strategic advantage over its rival.

Initial conditions BoeingEnter Don’t Enter

Airbus Enter -10, -10 100, 0Don’t enter 0, 100 0, 0

With subsidy of 20 for Airbus BoeingEnter Don’t Enter

Airbus Enter 10, -10 120, 0Don’t enter 0, 100 0, 0

Regardless of Boeing’s actions, it is profitable for Airbus to enter, but Boeing will lose money if it enters along with Airbus. Thus, Airbus will enter, and Boeing won’t. Airbus’ profits have gone from 0

Page 10: H3 Economics Papers

to 120, despite the fact that the subsidy was only 20—the extra 100 represents a shift of wealth from Boeing to Airbus.

Yet Brander and Spencer never claimed they had offered a general argument for aggressive trade policies: what they provided was only an example of how such a policy could work. As soon as the idea of strategic trade began circulating, aggressive trade policies would begin to backfire. Moreover, it is difficult to choose which industries to encourage, and infant industries might never grow up.

Economists who take the theory of comparative advantage seriously, however, do not see the international trade as a competitive sport. Import quotas, for example, may seem to create jobs, but the jobs gained in the protected industry are lost by the crowding out of employment, leaving us with nothing but higher prices and reduced competition, e.g. jobs saved in the American steel industry are at the expense of American dock workers, etc. An export subsidy normally costs the government and domestic consumers far more than it benefits producers in that industry (Harberger triangles)

The nineteenth-century French economist Bastiat once said: “Saying that our country should be protectionist because other countries do not practice free trade is like saying that we should block up our harbours because other countries have rocky coasts.”

The statements, ‘I understand the principle of comparative advantage,’ and ‘I support free trade,’ have become part of the economists’ credo. (Krugman)

The Thurow-Reich industrial policy prescribed that govts should help sunrise industries, in which you have a high market share and the industry is expected to grow quickly; and bring ‘sunset’ industries to a soft landing. Yet this was based on the belief that there were strong, predictable ‘learning curves’ that would allow a firm to translate a dominant market share into a cost advantage over its rivals; and in practice, these learning curves were much less reliable.

Gravity Model of World Trade (Krugman)

What determines the volume of trade between two countries are the size of their GDPs and the distance between the countries

- Large countries spend more on imports and attract large shares of other countries’ spending because they produce a wide range of products

Linder Hypothesis: Focuses on the pattern of demand. International trade in manufactured goods will be more intense between countries with similar per capita income levels. Tastes of representative consumers in a country yield product demands, and in turn generate a production response. Trade occurs in goods that have overlapping demand.

This has empirically, proven to be right. However, countries with similar per capita incomes tend to be geographically close, so intense trade may also reflect low transport costs and cultural similarity. Also, this theory does not specify the direction of trade—goods may be sent in both directions, in light of product differentiation.

Page 11: H3 Economics Papers

Intra-Industry trade is also not based on comparative advantage

- Economic geography may be due to economies of scale created by historical accident (Krugman)

- Ruffin: “Intra-Industry trade enhances the gains from trade through better exploitation of economies of scale, leading to a world expansion of output because of the savings on fixed costs”

- Ruffin’s Endogeneous Theory of Growth: Intra-Industry trade encourages monopolistic competition, trade stimulates innovation

- Marvel and Ray (1987): “Intra-industry trade reduces the demands for protection because there are both exports and imports, making it difficult to achieve unanimity among those demanding protection.”

- Trade need not cause the dislocations associated with inter-industry trade. Intra-industry trade beneficial because it stimulates innovation and exploits economies of scale

o Allows countries to benefit from larger markets: Study of the North American Auto Pact in 1964 indicated that the gains from intra-industry trade can be substantial

Trade policy

Tariffs: transfer consumer surplus to producer surplus; efficiency loss in terms of Harberger triangles

The impact of a tariff depends on the effective rate of protection (which is not necessarily the same as the tariff rate). Tariffs often have different impacts on different stages of production, e.g. the assembly industry and parts industry in automobile manufacturing. American steel tariffs, for example, may have caused even more job losses in industries depending on steel imports; steel-using industries account for 57 times as many jobs as steel-producing industries.

Export subsidies: Same production and consumption losses, but export subsidies worsen a country’s terms of trade by raising prices in the exporting country while lowering them in the importing country

E.g. The EU’s Common Agricultural Policy costs $60 billion per year to European taxpayers, not including indirect costs to food customers (Krugman-Obstfeld)

Import quotas: always raise the domestic price of the imported good. This is an extreme case of concentrated gains to favoured producers, diffuse costs to other producers and all consumers. The transfer of quota rents to holders of import licenses can make the costs of a quota higher than an equivalent tariff, but governments receive no revenue

E.g. US sugar quotas lead to a net loss of $883 billion per year to the US. Sugar producers, however, have very strong lobbies, as they gain a subsidy of about $20 000 per employee. It is estimated that with free trade, the consumer cost per job saved will be over $200 000 (Figures from US International Trade Commission, 2007)

Page 12: H3 Economics Papers

Voluntary Export Restraints: have political and legal advantages, but from an economic point of view, VERs simply act like import quotas.

E.g. US asked the Japanese government to voluntarily limit its exports, and the Japanese agreed. However, Japanese and US cars were not perfect substitutes, and the Japanese industry responded to the quota by upgrading its quality and selling larger automobiles with more features. Most importantly, the price of Japanese cars in the US rose significantly, with the rent captured by Jap firms. The US government estimates the total costs to the US as $3.2 billion in 1984, primarily in transfers to Japan.

Page 13: H3 Economics Papers

Globalisation

Definition: (Peter Nolan) “The era of capitalist globalisation witnessed an unprecedented pace of technological progress [and reductions in trade barriers.] It witnessed an ever-deeper intermeshing of national economies, drawn together by the bonds of trade and, even more, by cross-border investment by international firms.” To a lesser extent it also resulted in the freer flow of labour and people around the world.

Jagdish Bhagwati, In Defence of Globalisation

Globalisation first became a buzzword. Davos and Thomas Friedman celebrated its virtues and its inevitability; but economists such as Joseph Stiglitz were more wary, warning of its vices and its vincibility.

Brazilian sociologist Cardoso invented the dependencia thesis, arguing that poor countries would be relegated to a dependent status in the international economy. When he became President Cardoso of Brazil, however, he sought to take Brazil into more, not less, globalisation.

According to a 2006 World Economic Forum survey, fears of ‘malign impact’ have been more prominent amongst richer nations, especially America

Rapid technological change has dramatically reduced costs of transport and communication: the telegraph reduced communication time by 2500x, and the internet reduced it by a further 5x

The sense of vulnerability or economic insecurity is greater today because of intensified competitive pressures from actual and potential rivals. The novel fear today is that globalisation places limits on the ability of the state to provide for the welfare of their citizens.

David Hume’s concentric circles of reducing loyalty and empathy

Adam Smith wrote that ‘The destruction of that immense multitude seems…less interesting to him than this paltry misfortune of his own. To prevent, therefore, this paltry misfortune to himself would a man of humanity be willing to sacrifice the lives of a hundred million of his brethren, provided he had never seen them?’

Capitalism and globalisation are not such an inexorable force that they propel society into a headlong rush away from traditional communitarian values and ways

Throwing sand into the gears of globalisation is seen as a way to spit upon American hegemony, if not to limit the exercise of it in the political, cultural and economic domains.

While globalisation may be economically benign (in the sense of increasing the pie), it may be socially malign

If there was no way to significantly affect the share of the pie going to the bottom 30%, the most important thing was to grow the pie. (Therefore, growth was not a “passive, trickle-down strategy”; it was an “active, pull-up strategy”)

Page 14: H3 Economics Papers

NB: Fallacy of aggregation! Globalisation does not have to come with both trade liberalisation and financial liberalisation. While trade liberalisation may benefit an economy greatly, the reckless freeing up of capital may be far more detrimental.

Gresham’s Law: Bad money drives out the good (especially when the exchange rate is fixed)

“The reason why capital inflows are tricky is simply because when confidence is shaken, the fact that the situation is inherently one of imperfect information implies that the actions of a few can initiate herd action by others” (Bhagwati)

The Economist: “It seems natural to suppose that what goes for trade in goods must go for trade in capital, in which case capital controls would offend us as violently as say, an import quota on bananas. The issues have much in common, but they are not the same. Untidy as it may be, economic liberals should acknowledge that capital controls—of a certain restricted sort, and in certain cases—have a role.”

Asian Financial Crisis highlights the potential vulnerabilities from unfettered financial liberalization, and overexposure to ‘hot’ money. The IMF’s unrealistic demands for austerity helped to prolong and worsen Indonesia’s recession (-13%), and when the Suharto government could not meet requirements, investors panicked even further. Mahathir, on the other hand, ignored the IMF’s recommendations, and to its horror, imposed short-term capital controls. To its even greater horror, Mahathir’s capital controls were successful, and in 2002 the IMF changed tact and admitted that “capital controls might be necessary in times of severe panic”

However we must not forget that the Asian economic miracle can be largely attributed to trade liberalization in the first place. Significantly, after the AFC, countries did not close themselves off from trade, but instead liberalized further and embarked on greater efforts at regional cooperation e.g. ASEAN+3, Asian Development Bank, ASEAN Finance Ministers Work Plan

Terms of Trade between the Uruguay Round and 1995 establishment of the WTO saw the net effect of tariff reductions to lower the prices some of the poorest countries in the world received relative to what they paid for the imports (Stiglitz) Failure of negotiations at Cancun, Mexico further demonstrate the developing nations’ lack of bargaining power.

Currently, however, developing countries are growing at much faster rates (10%) than the stagnating rich world. Productivity in the developing world is rising significantly, boosted by technology and globalisation. In 2002-08 more than 85% of developing economies grew faster than America’s, compared with less than a third between 1960 and 2000, and virtually none in the century before that. (The Economist)

Other issues:

Poverty

Free trade results in concentrated costs to competitors, but creates diffuse gains for millions of workers in China and India

Page 15: H3 Economics Papers

Opening up the Jamaican milk market to US imports in 1992 may have hurt local dairy farmers, but it also meant poor children could get milk more cheaply (Stiglitz)

Sweatshops: Working in a dark, cramped factory is often better than slaving over backbreaking farm work in the sweltering sun

Inequality

Globalisation may have increased the gap between skilled and unskilled workers, but it has reduced wage differentials by gender, race, and citizenship. Bhagwati: “The women and children who returned to Japan became agents for change” Women working in Bangladeshi garment factories were provided with “a degree of autonomy, self-respect, and freedom from traditional gender work”

• Munch and Skaksen (2008) find that wages are higher in Danish firms with high export intensity and highly educated workers but lower in high-export-intensity Danish firms with workers who have lower levels of education.

• Schank et al. (2007) estimate separate regressions for blue-collar and white-collar German manufacturing workers while controlling for a range of individual characteristics including age, gender, level of education, and nationality. In contrast with much of the other literature, they find a higher export wage premium for blue-collar workers than for white-collar workers.

Moser and Urban find that there is a significant export wage premium for workers in the two highest skill categories and evidence of an export wage discount for lower-skilled workers. Their research shows that the links between trade and inequality are subtle. An increase in the average export share of the German economy raises wage inequality along the dimension of skill. But this same shift in the economic profile of the economy lowers wage inequality along the dimensions of gender and citizenship.

Lester Thurow in The Future of Capitalism (1996, pp. 69, 70) explains the "theory of comparative advantage" and describes the assumptions required for it to hold:

"The classical theory of comparative advantage is often taught as if everyone benefits from trade. Technically that is not true. The total income of every country that takes advantage of comparative advantage grows, but there will be individuals within each country who lose. What the theory holds is that those who gain from international trade receive enough extra income from their activities that they could compensate those who lose when international trade commences. If that compensation isn't actually paid (and it almost never is), then those who lose are quite rational to oppose international trade.

"But in the classical theory the losses usually will be quite small. First, full employment is assumed to exist. Free trade does not push anyone into unemployment. Second, transition costs are assumed to be zero. There is no region-, industry-, or firm-specific physical or human capital that is destroyed when workers are forced to shift between regions, industries, or firms. Third, returns are assumed to be everywhere equal. Each industry has the same rate of return on human or physical capital. Each firm and industry pays the same wage rate for a worker's being willing to give up an hour of leisure. As a consequence, being forced to shift jobs doesn't change wages very much, if at all."

Possible democratic deficit

Ann Pettifor: Globalisation has undermined democracy by making leaders accountable to nameless Washington-based institutions rather than their own people

Page 16: H3 Economics Papers

Bhagwati: Globalisation promotes democracy while constraining it at the same time

E.g. ITT’s intervention in overthrowing Salvador Allende; United Fruit Company lobbied for the US government to force Colombia to grant Panama independence even though it wasn’t ready

- Guerillas in the Philippines were provided jobs by World Bank financed projects as they laid down their arms (Stiglitz)

Technology

FDI provides access to technology: e.g. Japan forced IBM to share technology with local Jap firms in return for market access

Intellectual Property rights

- Incentive to innovate; without IP rights, companies would not be able to make profits, and thus would not develop the drugs in the first place

- However Stiglitz argues that the increased profits from sales in the developing world was small, since few could afford the drugs, making the incentive effect limited. In the case of AIDS, the fact that thousands were effectively condemned to death sparked international outrage and forced drug companies to agree to sell the drugs at cost in 2001.

NB: Globalisation is not a new phenomenon.

Keynes (1919): What an extraordinary episode in the economic progress of man that age was which came to an end in August 1914! … The inhabitants of London could order by telephone, sipping his morning tea in bed, the various products of the whole earth, in such quantity as he might see fit, and reasonably expect their early delivery upon his doorstep

Transitions to market economies

Importance of managed transitions to market economies—while in 1990 China’s GDP was 60% that of Russia’s, by the end of the decade the numbers had been reversed (Stiglitz). While Russia saw an unprecedented increase in poverty, massive capital flight, and asset stripping, China managed to pull over 800 million people out of poverty and gradually liberalized sectors (Special Economic Zones) while maintaining political stability by using existing institutions (Town and Village Enterprises)

Page 17: H3 Economics Papers

Behaviour of firms

Strategic competition

- Making credible early commitments to enter the market, or dropping out if it becomes convinced that the other firm will enter

- Signalling: o Investing in capacity it doesn’t need to convince rivals that they will face a price war

if they challenge its positiono Charging a lower price than the market will bear, to signal to rivals that its costs are

too low for them to challenge

- Klemperer (1987): Large switching costs- Fudenberg’s “Fat Cat” (1986): a firm that invests in goodwill (out of advertising) to its

customers, and thus consumers will not switch- Advertising to raise entrants’ sunk costs of entry (Farrell 1986)

Bureaucratic power

JKG’s Economics and the Public Policy discusses the “unequal deployment of power” in the corporation, and argues that the quality of life would suffer with bureaucratic power as the decisive force in economic and political life.

Organization goes hand in hand with technological advanceThe management of equipment requires specialists and more organization

Decisions to save and invest are concentrated at the hands of a few thousand firmsIf investment is insufficient, the system will be subject to a downward spiral of prices

As income increases, needs continue to preempt all energy and eliminate all choice. This is the artifice of the planning system

The prime purpose of improving income should be to increase the no of ppl who are removed from the pressures of physical need or its equivalent and who are able, in consequence, to exercise choice as to their style of economic life

Self-exploitation: workers may end up working for less than the economy usually pays for such effort due to his lack of economic power

We only need look at IBM, Microsoft, Kodak and Fuji, the Wellcome Foundation in drug research etc. to find evidence of large firms investing much more in R&D. Evidence from the US in 1988 showed only 7% of manufacturing firms employing less than 1000 workers had a formal R&D programme compared to 91% of large firms with >25000 employees.

However lest we get carried away on a wave of oligopoly enthusiasm evidence from John Jewkes et al demonstrates how less than half of the most important inventions this century came from the laboratories of large firms.

Page 18: H3 Economics Papers

Efficiency

Tobin “The most difficult issues of public policy are those where the goals of equality, freedom of choice and efficiency conflict.”

Okun “You cannot have your market efficiency and distribute it fairly.”

Kaldor-Hicks : if the amount that winners gain is more than sufficient to compensate losers, or the amount that losers are willing to pay is less than what winners are willing to accept

However it does not take into account whether the compensation is actually paid—this is seldom the case

Also it assumes constant marginal utility—bastardising Benthamite utilitarianism

John Rawls’ theory of justice (each person has an equal claim to basic rights and liberties, and that inequality should only be permitted to the degree that it helps the people on the bottom)

Nozick’s entitlement theory (justice in acquisition, transfer, redressing injustice. historical basis for claims)

Amartya Sen: governments need to develop people’s capabilities"Justice," Sen writes, "is ultimately connected with the way people's lives go, and not merely with the nature of institutions surrounding them."

Arrow’s impossibility theorem: No voting system can represent all the preferences of individuals if there is non-dictatorship, irrelevance of independent alternatives, and an unrestricted domain Social welfare function is either democratic or consistenti.e. voting systems are not fair. Game theory might be used to predict outcomes.

Inequality

Lipsey: Governments run into trouble when they try to eliminate equilibrium differentials, i.e. wage differentials that arise out of differences in ability or skill

In Britain the richest 10% of the population are more than 100 times as wealthy as the poorest 10% of society

Emmanuel Saez found that in 2007 the top .01 percent of American earners took home 6 percent of total U.S. wages, a figure that has nearly doubled since 2000.

2007, the top decile (10%) of American earners, Saez writes, pulled in 49.7 percent of total wages, a level that's "higher than any other year since 1917 and even surpasses 1928, the peak of stock market bubble in the 'roaring" 1920s.'"

Page 19: H3 Economics Papers

The top 1 percent incomes captured half of the overall economic growth over the period 1993-2007," Saes writes.

Inequality contributed to the Great Recession- Middle class incomes stagnated, higher demand for debt- Richest ppl sought higher returns for their savings- Poorest have highest MPC but their real incomes rose much less

Robert Frank: “Expenditure cascade”'Even if envy and jealousy were non-existent, there would still be perceptions of quality that depend on context. And so everybody would have a tendency to spend more when others spend more. 'When everybody spends more on high quality things, the things that used to seem high quality don't seem so any more.'

Before 1991, elite American universities agreed among themselves not to compete for the best students through merit-based scholarships in order to channel their money to truly needy students. But the US Justice Department charged them with violating anti-trust legislation, prompting them to end such cooperation. What ensued was a free for all as universities tried to match each other's scholarship offers to attract the highest-scoring students, which drained funds available for financial aid

However, Bhagwati: “The preoccupation with inequality measures is ludicrous unless the economist has bothered to put them into social and political context”…Inequality might be paradoxically benign, if the extremely rich, such as Bill Gates, spend more money on the social good

The Tragedy of the Commons

The commons is a term for a shared resource in which stakeholders have equal interest

Common-pool resources (CPRs) are natural or human-made resources where one person's use subtracts from another's use and where it is often necessary, but difficult and costly, to exclude other users outside the group from using the resource.

- Acting in self-interest- Externality- Dominant strategy- Deplete common pool resource

E.g. Overfishing or global warming

Coase Theorem

- Allocate property rightso Private bargaining e.g. radio frequency

- Zero transaction costs (Coase: “nothing further from the truth”)o Search, bargaining, policing and monitoring costs

Page 20: H3 Economics Papers

o E.g. Paying Indonesians to stop slash-and-burn- Property rights may not be well-defined- Incentive to lie—underdeclare or overdeclare costs

o Possible solution: pay what the other person bargains, e.g. if you value it at $8, you would hope that your partner wins if the bid was more than $8, and hope that your partner loses if the bid is under $8

- Tragedy of the Anticommons—underusage or overusage of resources e.g. Singapore, kids cannot play football

- Property rights lie at the heart of our market need to define property rights in places like China and India

Tragedy of the Anticommons (Michael Heller): underutilisation of resources because of numerous right holders

Elinor Ostrom’s governing the commons

People are trapped by the Prisoner's Dilemma only if they treat themselves as prisoners by passively accepting the suboptimum strategy the dilemma locks them into, but if they try to work out a contract with the other players, or find the ones most likely to cooperate, or agree on rules for punishing cheaters, or artificially change the incentive ratios - they can create an institution for collective action that benefits them all. This resonates with Peter Kollock's taxonomy of strategies for dealing with social dilemmas - one strategy is to change the rules of the game.

Changing the rules of the game to turn zero-sum games into non-zero-sum games:Groups can create contracts, agreements, incentives, constitutions, signals, media to enable cooperation for mutual benefit.

However there may be a lack of information about the system. o E.g. In water-sharing agreements in California, individual water-users knew whether

their wells were pumping salt, but none of them knew the overall pattern in the watershed, and no one was willing to pay the price of gathering it.In this case, the US Geographic Survey had the data, thus overcoming this obstacle.

Another obstacle is free-riding In comparing the communities, Ostrom found that groups that are able to organize and

govern their behavior successfully are marked by the some basic design principles: o Group boundaries are clearly defined.o Rules governing the use of collective goods are well matched to local needs and

conditions.o Most individuals affected by these rules can participate in modifying the rules.o The rights of community members to devise their own rules is respected by external

authorities.o A system for monitoring member's behavior exists; the community members

themselves undertake this monitoring.o A graduated system of sanctions is used.o Community members have access to low-cost conflict resolution mechanisms.

Page 21: H3 Economics Papers

o For CPRs that are parts of larger systems: appropriation, provision, monitoring, enforcement, conflict resolution, and governance activities are organized in multiple layers of nested enterprises.

Studied management of pastures in Africa and irrigation systems in NepalThe Great Recession

David Blanchflower: Past recessions may have led to adverse effects on the supply potential of theeconomy. Long-term unemployment, particularly at a young age, is damaging tofuture labour market prospects both for the individuals involved and the economy as awhole. Workers may lose their skills, causing a loss of human capital. High rates ofunemployment may mean there is a mismatch between those skills that workerspossess and those for which there is demand within the economy. People may also beless likely to participate in the labour market the longer their spell of unemploymentpersists.

Sustained unemployment while young, especially of long duration, has particularlynasty effects. By preventing labour market entrants from gaining a foothold inemployment sustained youth unemployment may reduce their productivity. A rangeof evidence indicates those that suffer youth unemployment have lower incomes andpoorer labour market experiences decades later4. These are important lessons for anymeasures that may be taken to address higher unemployment in the near future.

Krugman: "We weren't supposed to find ourselves in this situation. For manyyears most economists believed that preventing another GreatDepression would be easy... It turns out, however, that preventingdepressions isn't that easy after all..... Friedman’s claim that monetarypolicy could have prevented the Great Depression was an attempt torefute the analysis of John Maynard Keynes, who argued that monetarypolicy is ineffective under depression conditions and that fiscal policy— large-scale deficit spending by the government — is needed to fightmass unemployment. The failure of monetary policy in the currentcrisis shows that Keynes had it right the first time".

Some economists have celebrated the triumph of economic theory in modernmacroeconomic research.“Over the last three decades, macroeconomic theory and the practice ofmacroeconomics by economists have changed — for the better.Macroeconomics is now firmly grounded in the principles of economictheory.” Chari and Kehoe (2006).