housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... ›...

29
* *

Upload: others

Post on 06-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and

�nancial literacy among the European elderly∗

Agnese Romiti† Mariacristina Rossi‡

September 2012

Very preliminary - please do not quote

Abstract

This paper analyses the role played by �nancial literacy on saving decisions and

wealth decumulation. Broad evidence shows that (elderly) households do not decu-

mulate their assets as they age contradicting the standard life-cycle theory which

predicts that households should decumulate their asset in order to keep consump-

tion smooth. In particular older people seem to be very attached to illiquid asset,

such as housing wealth, far more di�cult to be liquidated and used to face unex-

pected shocks and to smooth consumption. By using the SHARE (Survey of Health,

Ageing, and Retirement in Europe) survey we try to detect whether more �nancial

literacy brings about a more optimal behaviour from a life-cycle perspective, and we

look at the impact of �nancial literacy on three di�erent dimensions of saving deci-

sions: unbalance portfolio with excessive weight assigned to illiquid assets, optimal

consumption path and housing wealth decumulation. According to our �ndings �-

nancial literacy substantially reduces portfolio imbalance of 50+ people, by reducing

the weight of housing wealth over total net worth, at the same time it is responsible

of a more optimal consumption path, despite not exerting any impact on housing

wealth decumulation.

Keywords: Financial literacy, savings, wealth decumulation, housing, portfolio

JEL codes: D91, G11

∗Acknowledgements: We acknowledge Observatoire de l'Epargne Europeenne for funding the project

`Is housing an impediment to consumption smoothing?'†University of Turin, CeRP and CHILD. Email: [email protected].‡University of Turin and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email: [email protected].

1

Page 2: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Introduction

A large strand of the literature on savings focuses on the pivotal factors ruling wealth

accumulation. Being able to accumulate wealth constitutes �nancial stability for a house-

hold. A bu�er stock of wealth might immunize households against bad shock realizations,

thus constituting a crucial factor of �nancial protection. From a policy standpoint, a high

level of household wealth generates less pressure for welfare policy interventions in time

periods of �nancial crisis. What if households do not resort to their wealth in times of

instability and income drops? Whether households decide not to use their assets might

be an individual reason. However, it is hard to agree on that public resources should be

the sole response to economic downturns in presence of unused consistent asset.

On one hand, Italian GDP growth has shown a poor trend, on the other one Italian

per capita assets are at consistent levels compared to other European countries.

The asset of Italian households is mainly constituted by housing. Italian households

exhibit a high home ownership rate, and the value of housing asset constitutes more than

half of the total assets. The wellness of Italian households is tied to illiquid asset, di�cult

to be liquidated when hard economic times hit. Italian households are rich but their asset

being mainly illiquid they are unable to use it e�ciently. Why is the portfolio of Italian

households so much imbalanced in favour of illiquid asset? Do the elderly bear strong

consequences for the inability to e�ciently use their asset?

In this paper we want to investigate an innovative research question. Does �nancial

sophistication play a role in the ability to use e�ciently household wealth? The role of

�nancial literacy on the ability to save has been intensively explored. However, after

retirement, the decumulation phase should start. However, very little decumulation is

observed along the after-retirement path. Is �nancial literacy responsible for the little

decumulation in the old age? Moreover, is the portfolio allocation a�ected by the de-

gree of �nancial knowledge? Our ex-ante expectation is that more �nancial sophisticated

households should be more active in their decumulation phase as well as show a more

balanced portfolio. Our paper also wants to investigate somehow on the consequences of

the shadow illiquid asset. We thus test whether having problems in making ends-meet

can be dependent on the degree of portfolio illiquidity. Our results show that whether

�nancial literacy might be responsible for portfolio imbalance, the same does not hold

for asset decumulation. More �nancial literate people are as distant from the life cycle

optimal path as their less �nancial literate peers.

The rest of the paper is laid out as follows. In section two we revisit the related

literature, in section three and four we describe the asset decumulation and composition

and their relationship to �nancial literacy. Section �ve and six describe the data and the

empirical strategy and �nally Section seven concludes the paper.

2

Page 3: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Literature review

There is poor evidence of housing wealth decumulation as individual ages: in a cross-

section framework Chiuri and Jappelli (2010) recently document how the ownership rates

decline after age 60 but this decline turns out to be almost entirely explained by cohort

e�ects. Once cohort e�ects are controlled for, the ownership rate follows a slow decline as

individuals get older, reaching a rate of about 1 percentage point per year after age 75.

Similar �ndings have been shown by other studies (Venti and Wise, 1989, 2002, 2004):

house equity and home ownership do not decrease as individuals reach older ages. Elderly

people could exploit other tools in order to face the drop in income occurring at retire-

ment and �nance their general consumption: they could move to another smaller unit

by downsizing or they could exploit �nancial services such as reverse mortgage. However

the evidence does not support a wide-spread use of the latter, whereas the large reduc-

tions in home equity are typically associated with exogenous factors such as the death

of a spouse, the movement to a nursing home or a worsening in the health status rather

than to individual choices (Venti and Wise, 2002, 2004). Since real (housing) wealth

represents the overwhelming share of total wealth, in particular for the elderly, all those

aforementioned factors contradict clearly the standard life-cycle theory which states that

individuals should use their accumulated wealth in order to �nance their consumption

after retirement. In addition Angelini et al. (2010) provide evidence that the decision to

downsize and to move to a smaller house are negatively correlated to the poor develop-

ment of the mortgage market, which in turn is responsible for higher �nancial distress

among elderly people.

The impact of health status on consumption and saving behaviour at old age has been

already documented by a few studies (Lillard and Weiss, 1997, Palumbo, 1999, Rosen and

Wu, 2004).

On the other hand there has been recently an increasing interest in the role of �nancial

literacy in explaining wealth and savings decisions. Being �nancially �literate� can help

explaining the reluctance to use debt instruments or the failure to use them properly;

being able to understand instruments allowing equity release (e.g. reverse mortgages)

would allow people to avoid becoming �house-rich, cash-poor�, thus helping in solving the

puzzle of why many elderly people end up dying with a portfolio almost entirely made

up of illiquid assets, such as real (housing) wealth, which are more di�cult to be used

in order to face hardship such as di�cult health conditions. Understanding which is the

role played by (the lack of) �nancial literacy could ultimately help in fostering strategies

aimed at making elderly people more con�dent with using instruments allowing equity

release.

The relationship between �nancial literature and saving decisions has been explored

so far mainly pointing out to the positive impact of the former on wealth, arguing that

3

Page 4: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

a higher level of �nancial literacy fosters the accumulation of wealth (Behrman et al.,

2010, Jappelli and Padula, 2011). In a recent study Jappelli and Padula (2011) analyzed

the impact of �nancial literacy on saving decisions of elderly people. Accounting for the

endogeneity of the variable of interest, they found that rising �nancial literacy fosters sav-

ings in a cross-country setting. Financial literacy has been also found to be responsible

for higher participation in the stock market (van Rooij et al., 2011). In addition poor

�nancial literacy has been also found to bring about a failure of planning for retirement

(Lusardi and Mitchell, 2007a,b, 2008, 2011, Hung A. and Yoong, 2009, van Rooij et al.,

2012).

Our study looks at the relationship between �nancial literacy and wealth from a dif-

ferent perspective, moving from the existing literature which looks at the relationship

between wealth and �nancial literature, and answers the question of how better informed

individuals in terms of �nancial literacy tend to have higher wealth and to save more.

Our analysis instead aims at detecting how higher level of �nancial literacy allows

elderly people to make better decisions regarding their wealth accumulation, especially in

a life-cycle perspective. As has been found that a higher endowment of �nancial literacy

allows elderly people to set better plans for their retirement, in a similar perspective we

would expect that the former should prevent elderly from getting to the end of their life

with too much (illiquid) wealth, out of the wealth that has been set apart for bequest

motives. Therefore our main question �rst looks at whether any wealth decumulation

occurs among elderly people, then we consider the role played by �nancial literacy on the

following dimensions: (housing) wealth decumulation, potential imbalance in portfolio al-

location, and potential deviations in the optimal consumption behaviour. It might be the

case that individual better endowed with more �nancial literacy can invest their wealth

in more liquid assets, or can have a consumption path with better resemble the optimal

one in a life-cycle perspective.

To the best of our knowledge there are no existing studies looking at the relation-

ship between �nancial literature and portfolio imbalance or optimal consumption path,

whereas Hung A. and Yoong (2009) represents the only previous example trying to answer

the question of whether �nancial literacy has any impact on �decumulation planning�. The

authors analyse how �nancial literacy a�ects three di�erent measures related to planning

and decumulation after retirement. Individuals are asked if they have tried to �gure out

how much to withdraw from their savings after retirement, by spending down De�ned

Contribution plan assets, if they have made a plan in order to do so and if they are con-

�dent that their retirement spending plans will meet their needs. By adopting a linear

probability model their �ndings are in favour of a positive impact of �nancial literacy on

all these indicators of decumulation planning, however their estimation strategy is �awed

since there is no account for the endogeneity of the �nancial literacy which is well-known

to be strongly correlated to other third factors a�ecting decumulation.

4

Page 5: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Asset Decumulation

One of the main intuitions of the life cycle is that asset accumulation is not a goal per sè,

but, rather, it is ancillary to the accomplishment of the consumption smoothing principle.

Irrespectively of income �uctuations, consumption is kept constant. Asset does not enter

directly the utility function as what matters for consumers is the amount of consumption

they are able to achieve. It is certainly hard to reconcile this strong prediction with

what the empirical evidence shows. Looking at the European scenario, it is evident how

household decumulation does not occur as individuals age (Figure 1).1 Controlling for

both cohort and age e�ects the average net worth increases for individuals aged up to 80,

whereas only for the age bracket 80-95 there is a very slow decline.2 Housing wealth follows

quite a similar patter over age and by cohort and it is stable throughout the life-cycle

apart from the increasing trend between age 50 and 60 (Figure 2). Household �nancial

wealth is even more stable and also slightly increasing for the youngest cohort (Figure 3).

Why are the elderly so much attached to their assets? Is it the fear of outliving asset?

If this were the reason it is not understandable why people do not, at least partially,

annuitize their wealth. In his seminal paper Yaari (1965), and, more recently, with much

less restrictive hypothesis Davido� (2005), proved that all wealth should be annuitized at

some point. The reason is that annuities return incorporates survival probabilities and

thus, if the price is fair, their return will always be superior to any bond, which does

not incorporate longevity risk. This condition obviously holds in absence of bequest, as

no utility is associated to time after death. Even if bequests are taken into account, and

markets for annuities are distant from fairness, there is still room for a substantial demand

for annuities. Despite the strong rationale claiming for annuities, the market of annuities

is very thin, not only in countries with very limited range of �nancial products, such as

Italy, but also in countries such as the UK and the US (see, among others Mitchell, 1999).

Moreover, bequests, despite being cited as the most likely explanation for the lack of

annuities (Lockwood, 2012), are very di�cult to be e�ectively detected in the intentions of

respondents for savings. Little evidence, in fact, points in favour of this direction (Altonji

et al., 1997, Laitner and Juster, 1996, Poterba, 2001, Gan et al., 2004), more likely positive

asset at death seems to be associated with unintended bequests. In our sample respondents

are asked about the chance they will leave any inheritance, the question being asked is the

following: �Including property and other valuables, what are the chances that you or your

husband/wife/partner will leave an inheritance totalling 50,000 euro (in local currency)

or more?�. 51 percent of our sample members answer with a probability higher than 50.

1We consider a sample of all individuals 50 aged and older, and accordingly we de�ne 4 cohorts, given

by the following intervals in terms of year of birth: 1902-1925, 1926-1935, 1936-1945, and 1946-1957.2The big jumps and noisy pattern after age 90 are due to the small magnitude of the sample for this

age bracket, as such the underlying trend is not reliable to be considered as representative of the relevant

population.

5

Page 6: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

However other studies have found no strong support for a bequest motive. In this paper

we want to explore whether in households where �nancial literacy is more present wealth

is depleted more easily, as individuals do not attach a utility to asset per sè, but, rather,

they attach a value to consumption that asset could generate.

We �rst derive a benchmark for asset depletion rate in order to have the optimal

behaviour according to which people would like to decumulate. Our prediction is that

more knowledgeable people dislike the idea of dying with �too much� asset and therefore

would be closer to the optimal depletion rate. Conversely, people less �nancial literate

are less conscious of the welfare loss of not disposing of their asset optimally.

We derive the optimal decumulation path as follows. Consider the sum of lifetime resources

at time t

At + Pt−1 + (1 + r)T−t

−1 + (1 + r)= ct−1 + (1 + r)T−t

−1 + (1 + r)(1)

where T is the expected end of life, r is the real interest rate, At is wealth, P are pensions

bene�ts, and c is current consumption, assuming that pension bene�t and consumption

are both constant over time as it is the real interest rate, r. Computing equation (1) at

t+1, dividing At+1 by At and taking logs, we obtain the simpli�ed version of the optimal

decumulation path as follows3

log

(At+1

At

)' − r

1− (1 + r(T − t))(2)

From our theoretical framework thus follows that asset depletion rate should just

depend upon the life expectancy and the interest rate and not be reactive to other factors.

However, given the small values taken by r, equation (2) simpli�es as follows

log

(At+1

At

)' − 1

T − t(3)

thus asset depletion turns out to be only a function of individual life expectancy. 4

3See the Appendix for details on how we derive equation (2)4In the empirical implementation we adopt a further simpli�cation, driven by our measure of life

expectancy. Since our measure for life expectancy is the self-reported probability of being alive at a given

future age, and 5 percent of the sample reports a probability equal to zero, we approximate the factor

k=−1/(T − t) with k=−1/(1 + (T − t)) in order not to lose the observations with probability equal to

6

Page 7: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

We claim that the degree of �nancial literacy might play a role in this decumulation plan-

ning. In particular, those households less �nancial literate might be less aware of �nancial

instruments to e�ciently decumulate wealth and also less able to plan e�ciently their

welfare during retirement. In the empirical analysis we test this hypothesis introducing as

regressors in the regression modelling (housing) wealth decumulation the constant term

(k=-1/(1+lifeexp)) and its interaction with the �nancial literacy indicator. According to

our prior, we would expect that the sum of the k coe�cient and the coe�cient of its inter-

action with �nancial literacy should correspond to the optimal behaviour, thus it should

be equal to one, the coe�cient relevant to the constant as in (1). More �nancial literacy

should help individuals to take decisions which are closer to the optimal behaviour from

a life-cycle perspective. The intertwining between decumulation and asset composition is

of crucial relevance. The majority of asset is tied to housing, and, moreover, the housing

asset is represented by the home residence in the majority of cases. People have accumu-

lated housing wealth during lifetime which is a probably easy and e�ciently way to save.

However, after retirement, they do not know how to make the capital embedded in the

house liquid and therefore consumes much less than their potential level.

Asset composition

There is a vast strand of literature on portfolio decisions of households and how e�ciently

households allocate their savings among risky and riskless assets (see, among others, van

Rooij et al., 2011). The general conclusion of this line of research is that households,

particularly those with poor �nancial literacy background, tend to under invest in the

stock market (van Rooij et al., 2011, 2012). Using a simple framework of expected utility

maximisation, it is shown that the households maximize their expected utility by having

a diversi�ed portfolio that mixes riskless with risky assets. Particularly the ratio of risky

asset out of total asset should always be positive and its amount positively correlated to

the excess return rate (to the riskless return rate) and inversely related to the variance of

the risky return rate shock (Viceira, 2001). In all circumstances, every portfolio should

contain some share of stocks. Observing zero asset in the stock market hence comes as a

contradiction to the agents' rational behaviour.

However, if risky and riskless assets have always been identi�ed as stocks and bonds,

housing investment role has largely been ignored. Housing investment is di�cult to deal

with as housing contains both and element of consumption and of investment. However,

when housing has been incorporated into the picture, rarely it has been considered as

risky.

In this paper we want to concentrate on the share of housing out of total wealth, to

understand whether more literate households do show a more balanced portfolio by being

zero.

7

Page 8: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

less imbalanced in favour of housing. If housing is rightly perceived as risky, it should be

considered as such by households, whose wealth disproportionately is tided up to housing

prices. In our empirical analysis we thus show whether more �nancially sophisticated

households have a less pronounced share of their assets in housing.

As we mentioned in the introduction, we also want to provide a measure of the con-

sequences of portfolio imbalance. Do the elderly bear heavy costs for their choices of not

using their tied up into housing wealth? Does �nancial literacy help in smoothing shocks

and bear less negative consequences of portfolio imbalance? In order to do so, in the

empirical analysis we try to detect the role of �nancial literacy on another dimension of

the optimal behaviour, measured by the optimal consumption path. The ideal empirical

implementation would be to use total household consumption and look at the role of �nan-

cial literacy on the consumption drop, assuming that in the optimal scenario consumption

should be kept constant over the life-cycle, thus no consumption drop should occur.

Data

For our empirical analysis we use the SHARE dataset, a survey which in 2004 has started

collecting data on the individual life circumstances of a representative sample of persons

aged 50 and over in 12 European countries: Austria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany,

Greece, Israel, Italy, the Netherlands, Spain, Sweden, and Switzerland. In addition, three

new countries joined the survey in wave 2 which was released between 2006 and 2007:5

the Czech Republic, Poland, and Ireland. The survey covers 19,286 households and 32,022

individuals, and its main purpose is to collect comparable information about health sta-

tus, income, wealth and household characteristics of elderly people for di�erent European

countries, following the example initiated by the US Health and Retirement Study (HRS)

and the English Longitudinal Survey on Ageing (ELSA).

Since we want to exploit the longitudinal dimension of the survey we restrict the anal-

ysis to the 11 countries which are present in both waves thus excluding Israel, the Czech

Republic, Poland, and Ireland, therefore we are left with the following 11 countries: Aus-

tria, Belgium, Denmark, France, Germany, Greece, Italy, Netherlands, Spain, Sweden,

and Switzerland. Our aim is to analyse di�erent measures of household wealth and how

the decisions about the latter are related and shaped by the stock of �nancial literacy

other than by other observed and unobserved individual characteristics of those in charge

of dealing with household �nances, therefore we ideally need to identify the individual who

is responsible for them. Wealth-related survey questions refer to the household whereas

5The �rst wave of the SHARE survey is related to 2004 for most countries, for France, Greece and

Belgium the data have been collected between 2004 and 2005, whereas the second wave is relevant to the

period 2006-2007 with the exception of the Netherlands and Greece whose data have been collected in

2007.

8

Page 9: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

other questions such as all questions related to cognitive abilities (thus to �nancial liter-

acy) are asked to each respondent. We need to match the household related variables to

the individual characteristics of one person per household, ideally to the person who is

most in charge of household �nances. The survey is well suited to this purpose because

at the beginning of the questionnaire individuals are asked about who is the household

�nancial respondent, the person responsible for the family �nances, therefore we select

the latter when he/she is uniquely identi�ed, whereas when there are more than one �-

nancial respondent because both members of the couple manage the �nances separately,

we consider the one with the highest income, or, in case of couples with no income, the

oldest one. Individual income is computed as the sum of earnings, public and private

pensions, life insurance payment received, private annuity, alimony, regular payment from

charities, and income from rent. Interest from bank accounts, stocks, bonds, and mutual

funds are not included because the asset questions in wave 2 refer to the household and

not to individuals therefore the relevant variable are only available for wave 1.

We analyse household �nancial behaviour and its relationship with �nancial literacy

under three di�erent perspectives: housing wealth decumulation, portfolio's imbalance,

and consumption path. Accordingly we thus consider the following three main dependent

variables: the growth rate of household housing wealth (equivalent to the �rst di�erence

of the log value), the ratio between housing wealth and total net worth (log), and a proxy

for the optimal consumption path. The dataset does not provide a proper measure of con-

sumption since the information on total household consumption is only available for the

�rst wave, whereas the only measure of consumption available for the two waves consists

in the amount spent on food at home or outside home plus the amount spent on tele-

phone. Thus we consider as a proxy for the optimal consumption path an indicator for

the self-reported household ability of making ends meet. The relevant question is asked

to respondents in charge of answering household-related questions: �Is household able to

make meets end? Thinking of your household's total monthly income, would you say that

your household is able to make ends meet�. From this question we built an indicator set

equal to one if the answer falls into one of the following categories: �fairly easily� or �eas-

ily� and equal to zero if the answer is �with some di�culties� or �with great di�culties�.

After excluding all observations with missing information on the variables of interest

we are left with a sample of 18,435 observations. The summary of descriptive statistics is

shown in Table 1. Following Jappelli and Padula (2011) we adopt the variable numeracy

provided by the survey as a proxy for our measure of �nancial literacy. The variable

numeracy is derived from four questions which are combined into a single indicator taking

values from 1 to 56 with 5 corresponding to the highest level of numeracy and it is meant

to measure the ability to perform basic numerical operations. Three questions test the

6As for the details on how the indicator is constructed see the Appendix.

9

Page 10: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

ability of playing with numbers, such as the ability of computing a percentage (�If the

chance of getting a disease is 10 per cent, how many people out of one thousand would be

expected to get the disease?�), computing the �nal price of a discounted good from the

original price (�In a sale, a shop is selling all items at half price. Before the sale a sofa costs

300 euro. How much will it cost in the sale?�), and the price of a second hand car sold

at two-third of its original price (�A second hand car dealer is selling a car for 6,000 euro.

This is two-thirds of what it costs new. How much did the car cost new?�). The fourth

question is instead related to interest rate compounding in a savings account (�Let's say

you have 2,000 euro in a saving account. The account earns ten per cent interest each

year. How much would you have in the account at the end two years?�). In the SHARE

dataset the original variable name is �numeracy�, for simplicity we use instead the name

�nancial literacy.

Using housing wealth we need to take into account two di�erent model speci�cations

for those with housing wealth equal or di�erent from zero, since the determinants of the

two groups might di�er, in addition, since we work with the log transformation of the

variable, all observations with zero value are dropped from the sample therefore we end

up with a censored sample. The original (uncensored) sample size would be cut by 30

percent (12,763), thus we address potential selection concerns by estimating a Heckman

selection model, in order to make sure that the estimates on the censored sample are not

biased due to the selection process. Lack of decumulation is evident from the pattern of

both real and housing wealth (Tables 2 and 3) which does not seem to follow an optimal

path from a life-cycle perspective, since di�erent cohorts do not decumulate as they age.

Moreover, within each cohort, higher level of �nancial literacy corresponds to higher

level of both real and housing wealth (Table 4), and this can be easily interpreted as

due to both variables being correlated to third common factors. Households endowed

with higher level of wealth can also have higher incentives to invest in �nancial literacy

provided that �nancial literacy is in turn positively correlated to education and income.

On the contrary with respect to our priors, from the raw descriptive statistics (Table

4) it is also clear how households with a higher endowment of �nancial literacy do not

decumulate to a greater extent their illiquid assets than those with a lower level, in fact

splitting the sample according to having a level of �nancial literacy higher than the mean

sample value, there is no di�erence in the respective decumulation behaviour. However

this evidence is only indicative of a pure correlation and in order to have a better picture

of the causal relationship between �nancial literacy and wealth decumulation we need to

rely on model estimation.

At the same time there is not a clear-cut relationship between household portfolio im-

balance and the stock of �nancial literacy (Table 5) since having a higher stock of �nancial

literacy is neither positively nor negatively correlated to having a higher portfolio imbal-

ance. On the contrary there is strong positive correlation between increasing �nancial

10

Page 11: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

literacy and an optimal consumption behaviour, which is proxied by our indicator of be-

ing able to make ends needs (Table 6) and this correlation is not driven by income e�ects

since the pattern remains also if we control for income replicating the cross-tabulation by

quintiles of income.

Empirical strategy

In order to estimate the impact of �nancial literacy on di�erent dimensions of wealth

and saving decisions, we use the three dependent variables as described above: the ratio

of housing wealth over net worth (in logs) which we consider as a measure of portfolio

imbalance, an indicator equal to one for households being able to make ends meet which

is our proxy for optimal consumption, whereas the third dependent variable representing

housing wealth decumulation is the growth rate of housing wealth. Financial literacy is

likely to be endogenous for all these dependent variables since individual unobserved char-

acteristics such as individual preferences, innate ability, or the household socio-economic

environment are all correlated to both investments in �nancial literacy and to decisions

about savings and portfolio. As a consequence the relevant coe�cient is biased if this

source of endogeneity is not taken into account. Therefore we need to adopt an IV ap-

proach for all the speci�cations. Our instrument for �nancial literature is an indicator

for the last job or occupation held by the father; we set this indicator equal to one if the

father was employed in high skilled occupations, which we de�ne as manager, professional,

or technician and associate. The intuition driving this choice is due to the fact that �rst

of all, within the family, it is often the father in charge of dealing with �nance and then

awarer of the role played by �nancial literacy as opposed to the mother. In addition,

being employed in a high skilled occupation is certainly positively correlated to investing

in children �nancial literacy because of the awareness that higher �nancial literacy can

have a positive and importance impact on children subsequent planning for retirement

other than on dealing with household �nances. As a consequence, father employed in

higher skilled jobs can a�ect and in�uence the past stock of children's �nancial literacy at

the same time without having any impact on the children's future decisions about wealth

and consumption assuming that a su�cient time lag can dissipate the potential common

socio-economic context shared by both the young children and the father. That is to say

that the past father's occupation should not be related to current (un)observed character-

istics a�ecting current decisions about household �nances (in particular if we also control

for household income, another potential channel through which the children can be af-

fected by the past parental occupation if we assume low socio-economic intergenerational

mobility). The drawback with this instrument's choice is that it is time-invariant by its

nature, since it is derived by a question (�What is or was the last job your father had?�)

only asked in the �rst wave. Therefore we are forced to consider only respondents who

11

Page 12: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

were present in the �rst wave and we attribute the same value of this variable also to the

second wave assuming that given the old age of the sample (50+) last parental job would

not probably change in the second wave, the large majority of parents would be already

retired and also the very few not yet retired would probably do not shift from a skilled to

an unskilled category of occupation at the end of their working career. As a consequence

the instrument cannot be used in a longitudinal setting such as a FE estimator. Our

strategy is therefore to run �rst two separated regressions one per each wave, then to

compare the endogenous estimates obtained per each wave with FE estimates in order to

evaluate the potential incidence of the unaccounted individual unobserved heterogeneity.

If the di�erence between the two estimators is not signi�cant we can consider the cross-

sectional IV estimates per wave as the benchmark.

We use three dependent variables of di�erent type; therefore we need to use di�erent

models' speci�cations. The measure of portfolio imbalance is a continuous variable which

we model by using two OLS regressions and the relevant IV regressions, one per each

wave. Thus we compare the OLS results with a FE linear model. In addition to that

this dependent variable is censored because of the log transformation which drops the

zero values therefore we also control for potential selection bias by adopting a standard

Heckman selection model with its control function version, in order to account for the

endogeneity of �nancial literacy (Tables 7 and 8-various columns).

The second dependent variable of interest is a dichotomous variable representing an

indicator for being in a (self-reported) good �nancial situation, thus we need to adopt a

non linear model, such as a logit regression with a control function approach, and then we

contrast the results from the logit speci�cations with a FE non linear estimation model,

such as a conditional logit model (Table 9). The third dependent variable is the growth

rate of housing wealth, a continuous variable, which we treat with OLS and IV speci�-

cations, and it is available for one wave only since we only have two waves from which

we can compute the growth rate (Table 10). For all the three dependent variables we use

the same vector of individual regressors given that the determinants underlying each of

them are similar and all related to saving decisions. The individual regressors consist in

the following: the proxy for �nancial literacy, three categorical indicators corresponding

to being in the following age brackets: 50-64, 65-85, and 85-100 which should account for

the fact that three distinct age-speci�c phases exist according to the standard life-cycle

model, each of them describing di�erent saving behaviour. The younger age when indi-

viduals decumulate because they are in the initial stage of their working life, afterwards

the accumulation period starts and workers face a steeper earning pro�le and eventually

they enter the retirement period where they should start to decumulate due to the less

than unitary pension bene�t replacement rate. Since the dataset only involves individuals

50 aged and older, we divide the two left conventional phases in three brackets in order

to account for the additional variability due to the oldest-old phase (85-100). In addition

12

Page 13: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

we include the self-reported probability of being alive which we assume as a proxy for

expected life expectancy assuming that the perceived longevity should have an impact on

saving behaviour. Individuals are asked the following question: �What are the chances

that you will live to be age [75/80/85/90/95/100/105/110/120] or more?� Each respon-

dent can answer by choosing a certain age among the list and then provide the probability

of being alive up to the chosen age. We then control for gender, immigration status (based

on country of birth), and education level including an indicator for being highly educated

where higher education corresponds to a post-secondary, non tertiary education level. We

also control for household income per capita (in logs) and its squared value. Additional

information is included in order to account for potential determinants or shocks to sav-

ing decisions: an indicator for being retired, for being widow/er, and for good subjective

health status. From the question �Would you say your health is� with the following pos-

sible answers: excellent, very good, good, fair, and poor, an indicator is set equal to one

if the respondent's answer is excellent, very good, or good. We also control for potential

bequest motives by including the number of children.7 Additional information included

is: country �xed e�ects and time �xed e�ects in case of the FE speci�cations.

We start commenting the results on �nancial literacy and portfolio imbalance (Table

7 and 8). The �rst and second columns report the results obtained for both OLS and

IV estimations. Concentrating on the impact of �nancial literacy, both OLS and IV re-

sults show that having a higher endowment of �nancial literacy brings about a reduction

in household portfolio imbalance: a lower proportion of household wealth will consist of

housing wealth and this result is consistent in both waves. We also replicate the analysis

by controlling for potential selection bias, since 30 percent of the uncensored sample has

zero housing wealth therefore it is dropped out because of the log transformation. We

adopt the standard likelihood Heckman selection model, and we also account for the po-

tential endogeneity of the �nancial literacy variable by using a control function approach

(columns 3 and 4 in Tables 7 and 8). Despite the LR test for independent equations

signals that the selection mechanism is not ignorable (p-value=0.001), the coe�cients rel-

evant to �nancial literacy are substantially unchanged with respect to the ones obtained

on the censored sample. The selection mechanism is instead ignorable in case of wave 2

where we cannot reject the null hypothesis of independent equations (p-value=0.6). As

it is reported in column 4, the signi�cance of the residuals' coe�cient reports the endo-

geneity of the �nancial literacy variable in both waves. We consider the results reported

in column 4 as our benchmark estimates because they account for both endogeneity and

potential selection bias. According to these results increasing the stock of �nancial lit-

7The dataset also provides with the information about the intention to leave inheritance by asking the

following question: �Within the next ten years, what are the chances that you will leave an inheritance

worth more than 50,000 euro (in local currency)?� Instead of using this information we opt for using a

more exogenous proxy given by the number of living children.

13

Page 14: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

eracy by one point brings about a signi�cant reduction in household portfolio imbalance

equal to 23 percentage points, which is a substantial e�ect given that the average value

of the dependent variable is about .71. We then compare the results obtained from the

Heckman speci�cation to those of the FE linear model, since this allows us to control

for time-invariant unobserved factors a�ecting saving decisions and also correlated to the

stock of �nancial literacy. The results, shown in column 5, are consistent with those

found for both the OLS and Heckman speci�cations, suggesting that the unobserved het-

erogeneity is only in part responsible for our main coe�cient of interest; we can argue that

the endogeneity might be due to other time-varying factors which we control for in the

cross-sectional IV speci�cation. Unfortunately we cannot compare the IV-FE estimator

with the cross-section one because our instrument is time-invariant therefore it would be

dropped from the estimation. As for the other coe�cients, surprisingly individual factors

such as immigration status, gender, being widow/er or retired, and also the number of

children do not seem to have an impact on saving decisions, as it is clear from column

4 in Tables 7 and 8, with the only exception for being retired which increases portfolio

imbalance (only for the �rst wave). From the selection equation, which we identify by

functional form instead of using any exclusion restriction, we can argue which individual

factors mostly increase the probability of having no zero housing wealth. Immigrants are

much less likely to own housing wealth, whereas the opposite is true for being a widow/er

which can be interpreted as due to the fact that the widows/ers inherit the spouse's hous-

ing wealth, moreover a self-perceived longer life is positively correlated to having housing

wealth, even though the latter does not exert any impact on portfolio imbalance. The

chosen instrument seems not to su�er from any weakness throughout all the speci�cations,

either when we consider the IV estimates or the control function approach (see the bottom

panel of Tables 7, 8, 9, and 10), both the �rst stage F statistics and the t-test in the �rst

stage of the control function speci�cations are highly above any standard critical values.

The results for the impact of �nancial literacy on consumption patterns, proxied by

the likelihood of making meets end are shown in Table 9, which reports the cross-section

logit and its control function version by wave (wave 1 in columns 1 and 2, and wave 2

in columns 3 and 4), whereas the FE results are reported in column 5 where we use a

conditional logit model. Both the OLS and the control function speci�cations report a

positive coe�cient for �nancial literacy, thus suggesting the positive impact of the latter

on the probability of making meets end, having a higher endowment of �nancial literacy

increases the likelihood of optimal consumption behaviour. And this pattern remains

stable and signi�cant (even if with a lower magnitude) also controlling for unobserved

individual heterogeneity in the FE estimation. Several individual factors a�ect the proba-

bility of an optimal consumption pattern, but once we control for individual �xed e�ects,

we observe a signi�cant positive impact of only higher life expectancy and a negative im-

pact of being a widow/widower. Commenting on the IV speci�cations, our estimates show

14

Page 15: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

that increasing the numeracy score by one point increases the probability of following an

optimal consumption pattern of around 30 percent. As a robustness check we also control

for unobserved individual heterogeneity which might explain part of the �nancial literacy

endowment and be responsible for the endogeneity, and in case of the FE speci�cation

the impact is lower in magnitude corresponding to a 2 percent increase, and loses a bit of

signi�cance (10 percent level) but still maintains the same positive sign. As for the role

played by �nancial literacy, since the FE estimates are very similar to the cross-section

logit ones, we argue that individual time-invariant unobserved heterogeneity plays a minor

role, whereas the endogeneity seems to be an issue as it is clear from the strong signi�cance

of the residuals in the cross-section estimates, hence our preferred estimate are the latter

which control also for the endogeneity of �nancial literacy. The direction of the bias in

the OLS estimates is not so clear-cut and it cannot be known a priori since it depends on

many di�erent factors. Innate abilities can be responsible for an upward bias in OLS esti-

mates, assuming that they are positively correlated to both the stock of �nancial literacy

and the optimal consumption behaviour. However OLS estimates can also be downward

biased in case of measurement errors in the �nancial literacy indicator. Therefore the

direction of the bias is an empirical question. Underestimation of the OLS coe�cient has

also been found by Jappelli and Padula (2011) use the same SHARE dataset to estimate

the impact of �nancial literacy on saving rate. Taking the math test score at the age of

10 as the instrument for the �nancial literacy indicator, they also found that the OLS

coe�cient of �nancial literacy was an underestimation of the IV one.

The last model is related to the impact of �nancial literacy on housing wealth decu-

mulation, and the relevant results are shown in Table 10. Housing wealth decumulation

is measured by its growth rate, our dependent variable. From both the OLS and the IV

results we argue that �nancial literacy does not play any role on wealth decumulation, and

also its interaction with the constant k factor � as derived from the theoretical framework

in the above section and it is computed as an inverse function of life expectancy8 - is only

signi�cant in the OLS estimates (column 1), despite maintaining the expected negative

sign also in the IV but becoming not signi�cant. Even trying to isolate subgroups of indi-

viduals which should potentially be more subject to wealth decumulation, such as elderly

or retired people, the role of �nancial literacy is consistent with these results and remains

insigni�cant. This lack of evidence about the role of �nancial literacy on housing wealth

decumulation can be explained by the extremely poor evidence of overall (housing) wealth

decumulation in the sample as provided by the above descriptive statistics.

8Life expectancy is represented by the same variable also included in all the regressions.

15

Page 16: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Discussion and conclusions

This paper analyses the role played by �nancial literacy on optimal saving decisions and

potential household portfolio imbalance. From a life-cycle perspective having a large

share of wealth invested in illiquid asset, in particular at the late stage of the life-cycle,

is highly sup-optimal, since illiquid assets such as housing wealth are di�cult to be used

in order to face unexpected shocks or also to keep consumption levels smooth during the

retirement period where the income from pension bene�t is substantially lower. Despite

the theoretical guidance, the empirical evidence largely shows that households do not

decumulate as they age and also have large part of their wealth invested in housing wealth,

this despite not having string bequest intentions which could motivate and justify the

nature of an unbalance portfolio. Motivated by this puzzle we analyse whether individuals

endowed with a bigger stock of �nancial literacy may behave in a way which is more

consistent with an optimal saving pattern, assuming that higher �nancial literacy also

helps dealing with more complex �nancial instrument thus it should increase the share of

the portfolio devoted to �nancial assets. By using the SHARE survey on 50+ individuals

we empirically investigate the role played by �nancial literacy on the following dimensions

of saving decisions: unbalance portfolio, optimal consumption pattern, and housing wealth

decumulation.

Our results are robust to the endogeneity of �nancial literacy through the adoption

of a IV strategy, based on father's past occupation. According to our �ndings we show

that �nancial literacy helps household to have a more balanced portfolio, characterized

by a lower weight assigned to illiquid assets (such as housing wealth), at the same time

a higher stock of �nancial literacy helps individual to follow a more optimal consumption

path which is proxied by the likelihood of making ends meet. However we do not �nd

any role played by �nancial literacy on another dimension of optimal saving behaviour,

represented by housing wealth decumulation, which is totally una�ected by the stock of

�nancial literacy the individuals are endowed with.

16

Page 17: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Appendix

A.1. Theoretical framework

The sum of lifetime resources at time t with constant pension bene�t, P, and consumption,

C can be expressed as

At + PT∑x=t

1

(1 + r)x−t= c

T∑x=t

1

(1 + r)x−t(4)

which simpli�es to

At + P1− (1 + r)T−t

1− (1 + r)= c

1− (1 + r)T−t

1− (1 + r)(5)

Dividing equation (5) computed at t+1 by equation (5) computed at t and simplifying,

we obtain

At+1

At

= 1 +r

1− (1 + r)T−t(6)

Taking logs and simplifying further yields result (3)

log

(At+1

At

)' r

1− (1 + r)T−t' − 1

T − t(7)

A.2. Numeracy

The 4 questions relevant to the variable numeracy are the following. Possible answers are

shown in a card while the interviewer is instructed not to read them out to the respondent:

1.If the chance of getting a disease is 10 per cent, how many people out of one

thousand would be expected to get the disease? The possible answers are 100, 10,

90, 900 and another answer.

2.In a sale, a shop is selling all items at half price. Before the sale a sofa costs 300

euro. How much will it cost in the sale? The possible answers are 150, 600 and

another answer.

17

Page 18: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

3.A second hand car dealer is selling a car for 6,000 euro. This is two-thirds of what

it costs new. How much did the car cost new? The possible answers are 9,000,

4,000, 8,000, 12,000, 18,000 and another answer.

4.Let's say you have 2,000 euro in a saving account. The account earns ten per

cent interest each year. How much would you have in the account at the end two

years? The possible answers are 2,420, 2,020, 2,040, 2,100, 2,200, 2,400 and another

answer.

The variable numeracy has been built as follow. If a person answers (1) correctly she is

then asked (3) and if she answers correctly again she is asked (4). Answering (1) correctly

results in a score of 3, answering (3) correctly but not (4) results in a score of 4 while

answering (4) correctly results in a score of 5. On the other hand if she answers (1)

incorrectly she is directed to (2). If she answers (2) correctly she gets a score of 2 while if

she answers (2) On the basis of these four questions Dewey and Prince (2005) construct

a numeracy indicator, which ranges from 1 to 5.

18

Page 19: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

References

Altonji, J. G., Hayashi, F., and Kotliko�, L. J. (1997). Parental altruism and inter vivos

transfers: Theory and evidence. Journal of Political Economy, 105(6):1121�66.

Angelini, V., Brugiavini, A., and Weber, G. (2010). Does downsizing of housing equity

alleviate �nancial distress in old age? MEA discussion paper series 10217, Munich

Center for the Economics of Aging (MEA) at the Max Planck Institute for Social Law

and Social Policy.

Behrman, J. R., Mitchell, O. S., Soo, C., and Bravo, D. (2010). Financial literacy, school-

ing, and wealth accumulation. Working Paper 16452, National Bureau of Economic

Research.

Chiuri, M. and Jappelli, T. (2010). Do the elderly reduce housing equity? an international

comparison. Journal of Population Economics, 23:643�663.

Davido�, T. (2005). Annuities and individual welfare. American Economic Review,

95(5):1573�1590.

Gan, L., Gong, G., Hurd, M., and McFadden, D. (2004). Subjective mortality risk and

bequests. Working Paper 10789, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Hung A., Meijer E., M. K. and Yoong, J. (2009). Financial literacy, retirement saving

management, and decumulation. RAND Working Paper 712.

Jappelli, T. and Padula, M. (2011). Investment in �nancial literacy and saving decisions.

CSEF Working Paper 272.

Laitner, J. and Juster, F. T. (1996). New evidence on altruism: A study of tiaa-cref

retirees. The American Economic Review, 86(4):893�908.

Lillard, L. and Weiss, Y. (1997). Uncertain health and survival: E�ects on end-of-life

consumption. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 15:254�268.

Lockwood, L. M. (2012). Bequest motives and the annuity puzzle. Review of Economic

Dynamics, 15(2):226�243.

Lusardi, A. and Mitchell, O. S. (2007a). Baby boomer retirement security: The roles

of planning, �nancial literacy, and housing wealth. Journal of Monetary Economics,

54(1):205�224.

Lusardi, A. and Mitchell, O. S. (2007b). Financial literacy and retirement planning: New

evidence from the rand american life panel. Working Paper 2007-157, MRRC.

19

Page 20: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Lusardi, A. and Mitchell, O. S. (2008). Planning and �nancial literacy: How do women

fare? American Economic Review, 98(2):413�17.

Lusardi, A. and Mitchell, O. S. (2011). Financial literacy and planning: Implications for

retirement wellbeing. Working Paper 17078, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Mitchell, O. S. (1999). New evidence on the money's worth of individual annuities. Amer-

ican Economic Review, 89(5):1299�1318.

Palumbo, M. G. (1999). Uncertain medical expenses and precautionary saving near the

end of the life cycle. The Review of Economic Studies, 66(2):395�421.

Poterba, J. (2001). Estate and gift taxes and incentives for inter vivos giving in the us.

Journal of Public Economics, 79(1):237 � 264.

Rosen, H. and Wu, S. (2004). Portfolio choice and health status. Journal of Financial

Economics, 72:457�484.

van Rooij, M. C., Lusardi, A., and Alessie, R. (2011). Financial literacy and stock market

participation. Journal of Financial Economics, 101(2):449�472.

van Rooij, M. C., Lusardi, A., and Alessie, R. (2012). Financial literacy, retirement

planning and household wealth. The Economic Journal, 122(560):449�478.

Venti, S. F. andWise, D. A. (1989). Aging, moving, and housing wealth. In The Economics

of Aging, NBER Chapters, pages 9�54. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

Venti, S. F. and Wise, D. A. (2002). Aging, moving, and housing wealth. In Innovations

in retirement �nancing. Z. Bodie, P. Hammond, and O. eds., University of Pennsylvania

Press, Philadelphia.

Venti, S. F. and Wise, D. A. (2004). Aging and Housing Equity: Another Look, pages

127�180. University of Chicago Press.

Viceira, L. M. (2001). Optimal portfolio choice for long-horizon investors with nontradable

labor income. Journal of Finance, 56(2):433�470.

Yaari, M. E. (1965). Uncertain Lifetime, Life Insurance, and the Theory of the Consumer.

The Review of Economic Studies, 32(2):137�150.

20

Page 21: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Table 1: Summary statisticsVariable Mean Std. Dev. Min. Max. N

Age 66.058 9.994 50 100 18435

Life exp 60.239 29.123 0 100 18435

Financial literacy 3.443 1.104 1 5 18435

Women 0.526 0.499 0 1 18435

Immigrant 0.072 0.258 0 1 18435

High Edu 0.224 0.417 0 1 18435

Housing w over net w (log) -0.176 0.471 -4.541 5.606 12763

Housing w over net w 0.718 3.465 0 272.072 18435

Prob making ends meet 0.632 0.482 0 1 18435

HH net worth 210352.01 276937.306 -88297.815 2750285.065 18435

HH Housing w 159364.317 209258.224 0 2031137.375 18435

Income_pc (log) 6.299 2.677 0 12.163 18435

Subjective Health 0.695 0.46 0 1 18435

Retired 0.545 0.498 0 1 18435

Widow/er 0.233 0.423 0 1 18435

Numb children 1.985 1.18 0 4 18435

Table 2: Household Net Real wealthCohort

Age 1904-1925 1926-1935 1936-1945 1946-1957 |Total

50-54 185, 247.51 185, 247.51

55-59 149, 912.75 197, 504.18 194, 610.87

60-64 178, 805.42 209, 490.65 184, 192.23

65-69 142, 852.13 169, 173.24 167, 059.17

70-74 140, 915.03 186, 645.34 149, 122.05

75-79 99, 112.33 138, 353.84 134, 983.40

80-84 108, 203.30 160, 876.63 118, 356.73

85-100 88, 752.47 88, 752.47

Total 100, 065.91 141, 173.27 173, 922.70 193, 782.80 164, 774.84

21

Page 22: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Table 3: Household housing wealthCohort

Age 1904-1925 1926-1935 1936-1945 1946-1957 |Total

50-54 169, 276.24 169, 276.24

55-59 146, 734.66 182, 644.47 180, 468.44

60-64 172, 684.47 202, 780.97 177, 973.12

65-69 144, 287.00 167, 546.01 165, 676.98

70-74 143, 551.04 184, 948.43 150, 988.42

75-79 103, 987.00 138, 804.33 135, 818.47

80-84 109, 151.44 164, 817.65 119, 873.86

85-100 90, 626.05 90, 626.05

Total 101, 693.61 142, 900.81 170, 301.51 179, 234.19 159, 364.32

Table 4: Housing wealth and Financial Literacy by cohort-ageCohort 1904-1925 1926-1935 1936-1945 1946-1957

Fin Lit No Yes No Yes No Yes No Yes

50-54 159401.15 175122.56

891 1505

55-59 119682.67 167490.07 155604.34 200338.08

89 116 1257 1921

60-64 142051.06 197310.50 181560.62 217557.10

1156 1438 227 326

65-69 126134.50 170690.62 139147.19 196211.59

144 99 1397 1384

70-74 125019.06 166891.55 164855.79 207099.33

1097 871 226 205

75-79 97617.95 114602.07 123096.18 163810.07

105 63 1100 691

80-84 101156.95 126289.05 134406.76 226700.27

746 348 175 86

85-100 88973.04 95450.81

575 197

Table 5: Share of housing wealth over net worth by Financial LiteracyFinancial literacy

1 0.59

2 0.76

3 0.68

4 0.77

5 0.69

Total 0.72

22

Page 23: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Table 6: Making ends meet and Financial Literacy5 quintiles of HH income

Financial literacy 1 2 3 4 5 Total

1 0.30 0.45 0.53 0.60 0.51 0.41

2 0.31 0.50 0.54 0.62 0.68 0.47

3 0.37 0.54 0.65 0.73 0.76 0.59

4 0.46 0.60 0.69 0.79 0.85 0.70

5 0.47 0.60 0.75 0.80 0.88 0.76

Total 0.37 0.55 0.66 0.75 0.82 0.63

23

Page 24: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Table 7: Wave 1. Portfolio ImbalanceOLS IV Heck-ll Heck-ll-IV FE

Financial literacy −0.033∗∗∗ −0.228∗∗ −0.021∗∗∗ −0.165∗ −0.020∗∗∗(0.006) (0.102) (0.007) (0.089) (0.007)

Residuals 0.145

(0.089)

Age 65-84 0.007 −0.045 0.015 −0.020 0.018

(0.014) (0.032) (0.017) (0.028) (0.025)

Age 85-100 −0.032 −0.151∗∗ −0.058∗∗ −0.137∗∗ −0.019

(0.026) (0.068) (0.028) (0.056) (0.039)

Life exp −0.000 −0.000 0.000 0.000 −0.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Women 0.034∗∗ −0.042 0.032∗∗ −0.023

(0.014) (0.043) (0.014) (0.037)

Immigrant 0.053∗ 0.035 −0.011 −0.040

(0.031) (0.034) (0.029) (0.034)

hs −0.025 0.072 0.013 0.093∗(0.017) (0.053) (0.016) (0.051)

loginc_pc −0.019 −0.028∗∗ −0.008 −0.010 −0.027∗∗(0.013) (0.014) (0.014) (0.014) (0.011)

loginc_pc2 0.001 0.002 −0.001 −0.000 0.001

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

Subjective Health −0.032∗∗ 0.018 −0.012 0.028 −0.012

(0.013) (0.030) (0.016) (0.029) (0.013)

Retired 0.022 0.026∗ 0.019 0.021 −0.003

(0.014) (0.015) (0.016) (0.016) (0.019)

Widow/er 0.029 −0.012 0.049∗∗ 0.029 0.078

(0.020) (0.030) (0.020) (0.024) (0.061)

Selection eqn

Financial literacy 0.114∗∗∗ 0.519∗∗∗(0.014) (0.198)

Residuals −0.408∗∗(0.199)

Age 65-84 0.038 0.139∗∗(0.038) (0.062)

Age 85-100 −0.208∗∗∗ 0.012

(0.057) (0.122)

Life exp 0.003∗∗∗ 0.002∗∗∗(0.001) (0.001)

Women −0.029 0.127

(0.030) (0.082)

Immigrant −0.472∗∗∗ −0.386∗∗∗(0.051) (0.066)

hs 0.376∗∗∗ 0.153

(0.036) (0.115)

loginc_pc 0.071∗∗ 0.078∗∗(0.032) (0.032)

loginc_pc2 −0.011∗∗∗ −0.011∗∗∗(0.002) (0.002)

Subjective Health 0.175∗∗∗ 0.063

(0.032) (0.063)

Retired −0.030 −0.038

(0.036) (0.036)

Widow/er 0.180∗∗∗ 0.237∗∗∗(0.042) (0.050)

lambda 0.232 0.233

se (lambda) 0.070 0.069

LR (ρ = 0) p-value: 0.001 0.001

First stage

IV 0.165∗∗∗ 0.1719∗∗∗(0.028) (0.0233)

F-stats 35.611

Obs 6475 6475 10085 10085 12763

Robust standard errors in parentheses

* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01

24

Page 25: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Table 8: Wave 2. Portfolio ImbalanceOLS IV Heck-ll Heck-ll-IV FE

Financial literacy −0.021∗∗∗ −0.195∗∗ −0.021∗∗∗ −0.183∗∗ −0.020∗∗∗(0.006) (0.091) (0.006) (0.082) (0.007)

Residuals 0.163∗∗(0.082)

Age 65-84 0.054∗∗∗ 0.006 0.054∗∗∗ 0.011 0.018

(0.013) (0.028) (0.013) (0.025) (0.025)

Age 85-100 0.011 −0.089 0.010 −0.082 −0.019

(0.019) (0.056) (0.019) (0.050) (0.039)

Life exp −0.000 −0.000 −0.000 −0.000 −0.000

(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)

Women 0.037∗∗∗ −0.031 0.036∗∗∗ −0.026

(0.012) (0.038) (0.012) (0.034)

Immigrant 0.014 0.010 0.011 −0.007

(0.024) (0.026) (0.024) (0.026)

hs −0.058∗∗∗ 0.024 −0.056∗∗∗ 0.027

(0.015) (0.046) (0.015) (0.045)

loginc_pc −0.015∗ −0.020∗ −0.015 −0.016∗ −0.027∗∗(0.009) (0.010) (0.009) (0.009) (0.011)

loginc_pc2 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

Subjective Health −0.026∗∗ 0.018 −0.026∗∗ 0.017 −0.012

(0.012) (0.027) (0.012) (0.025) (0.013)

Retired 0.031∗∗ 0.035∗∗ 0.031∗∗ 0.039∗∗∗ −0.003

(0.013) (0.014) (0.013) (0.013) (0.019)

Widow/er 0.019 −0.015 0.020 −0.008 0.078

(0.016) (0.024) (0.016) (0.021) (0.061)

Selection eqn

Financial literacy 0.112∗∗∗ 0.625∗∗∗(0.017) (0.232)

Residuals −0.516∗∗(0.233)

Age 65-84 −0.015 0.121

(0.045) (0.077)

Age 85-100 −0.148∗∗ 0.142

(0.062) (0.145)

Life exp 0.002∗∗∗ 0.002∗∗∗(0.001) (0.001)

Women −0.082∗∗ 0.115

(0.036) (0.095)

Immigrant −0.433∗∗∗ −0.373∗∗∗(0.061) (0.066)

hs 0.377∗∗∗ 0.116

(0.043) (0.125)

loginc_pc 0.047 0.051

(0.039) (0.039)

loginc_pc2 −0.010∗∗∗ −0.010∗∗∗(0.003) (0.003)

Subjective Health 0.149∗∗∗ 0.014

(0.036) (0.071)

Retired 0.065 0.039

(0.042) (0.044)

Widow/er 0.158∗∗∗ 0.250∗∗∗(0.050) (0.065)

lambda 0.017 0.020

se lambda 0.014 0.015

LR (ρ = 0) p-value 0.227 0.191

First stage

IV 0.170∗∗∗ 0.1773∗∗∗(0.029) (0.0252)

F-stats 35.350

Obs 6288 6288 8350 8350 12763

Robust standard errors in parentheses

* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01

25

Page 26: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Table 9: Probability HH making ends meet-LogitWave 1 Wave 2

Logit Logit-cf Logit Logit-cf Logit-FE

Financial literacy 0.054∗∗∗ 0.265∗∗∗ 0.049∗∗∗ 0.336∗∗∗ 0.027∗(0.005) (0.080) (0.006) (0.086) (0.016)

Residuals −0.212∗∗∗ −0.288∗∗∗(0.080) (0.086)

Life exp 0.001∗∗∗ 0.001∗∗ 0.001∗∗∗ 0.001∗∗∗ 0.001∗∗∗(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001)

Age 65-84 (d) 0.034∗∗ 0.085∗∗∗ 0.032∗∗ 0.106∗∗∗ 0.010

(0.014) (0.023) (0.015) (0.027) (0.055)

Age 85-100 (d) 0.154∗∗∗ 0.234∗∗∗ 0.097∗∗∗ 0.218∗∗∗ 0.062

(0.018) (0.030) (0.020) (0.034) (0.098)

Women (d) −0.043∗∗∗ 0.037 −0.062∗∗∗ 0.047

(0.012) (0.033) (0.013) (0.035)

Immigrant (d) −0.118∗∗∗ −0.070∗∗∗ −0.098∗∗∗ −0.061∗∗(0.020) (0.027) (0.025) (0.027)

hs (d) 0.121∗∗∗ 0.011 0.119∗∗∗ −0.020

(0.013) (0.045) (0.014) (0.047)

loginc_pc 0.066∗∗∗ 0.070∗∗∗ 0.058∗∗∗ 0.060∗∗∗ −0.047

(0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.012) (0.038)

loginc_pc2 −0.005∗∗∗ −0.006∗∗∗ −0.005∗∗∗ −0.005∗∗∗ 0.005

(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.003)

Subjective Health (d) 0.144∗∗∗ 0.083∗∗∗ 0.126∗∗∗ 0.048∗ 0.028

(0.013) (0.026) (0.013) (0.026) (0.032)

Retired (d) 0.018 0.014 0.015 0.001 −0.063

(0.014) (0.014) (0.015) (0.015) (0.045)

Widow/er (d) 0.033∗∗ 0.061∗∗∗ 0.027 0.075∗∗∗ −0.285∗∗(0.016) (0.019) (0.018) (0.022) (0.141)

Numb children −0.013∗∗∗ −0.007 −0.022∗∗∗ −0.017∗∗∗ −0.002

(0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.005) (0.037)

First stage

IV 0.1719∗∗∗ 0.1773∗∗∗(0.0233) (0.0252)

Obs 10085 10085 8350 8350 2030

Marginal e�ects; Robust standard errors in parentheses

(d) for discrete change of dummy variable from 0 to 1

* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01

26

Page 27: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Table 10: Growth rate in housing wealthOLS IV

Financial literacy 0.025 1.047

(0.053) (0.769)

k 0.767 2.563

(0.469) (2.218)

kx�n lit −0.216∗ −0.763

(0.130) (0.702)

Life exp 0.003∗ 0.003

(0.002) (0.002)

Age 65-84 0.120 0.400

(0.126) (0.250)

Age 85-100 0.118 0.672

(0.164) (0.454)

Women −0.041 0.342

(0.078) (0.281)

Immigrant −0.105 −0.073

(0.122) (0.133)

hs 0.135 −0.328

(0.124) (0.302)

loginc_pc 0.031 0.058

(0.075) (0.087)

loginc_pc2 −0.002 −0.005

(0.005) (0.007)

Subjective Health −0.032 −0.280

(0.068) (0.200)

Retired −0.204∗ −0.213∗(0.114) (0.121)

Widow/er 0.214∗ 0.396∗(0.129) (0.227)

Numb children 0.004 0.017

(0.035) (0.037)

First stage

IV 0.166∗∗∗

(0.030)

F-stats 17.936

Obs 6288 6288

Robust standard errors in parentheses

* p<0.10, ** p<0.05, *** p<0.01

27

Page 28: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Figure 1:

0

50000

100000

150000

200000

250000

300000

350000

50 60 70 80 90Age

1904-1925 1926-19351936-1945 1946-1957

Net worth wealth by cohort

Source: SHARE, waves 1 and 2.

Figure 2:

0

50000

100000

150000

200000

250000

300000

350000

50 60 70 80 90Age

1904-1925 1926-19351936-1945 1946-1957

Housing wealth by cohort

Source: SHARE, waves 1 and 2.

28

Page 29: Housing wealth decumulation, portfolio composition and ...fileserver.carloalberto.org › ... › Romiti_Rossi.pdf · zUniversity of urinT and CeRP-Collegio Carlo Alberto. Email:

Figure 3:

0

25000

50000

75000

100000

125000

150000

50 60 70 80 90Age

1904-1925 1926-19351936-1945 1946-1957

Financial wealth by cohort

Source: SHARE, waves 1 and 2.

29