improving the investment climate in china€¦ · improving the investment climate in china david...

90
Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin Colin Xu March 2003 This report is based on an investment climate survey conducted in 2002 in five Chinese cities (Beijing, Chengdu, Guangzhou, Shanghai, and Tianjin). We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the United Kingdom’s Department for International Development (DFID). A grant from DFID supported the collaboration of the Enterprise Survey Organization in this survey and fellowships for two ESO staff, Mr. Yang Yumin and Ms. Li Hui, to visit Washington, DC, for analysis and preparation of this report. This project is part of a larger effort in the World Bank Group to help countries assess their investment climates and to identify reforms that will lead to higher productivity, more efficient investment, and ultimately more job creation and growth.

Upload: others

Post on 21-Jun-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

Improving the Investment Climate in China

David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin Colin Xu

March 2003

This report is based on an investment climate survey conducted in 2002 in five Chinese cities (Beijing, Chengdu, Guangzhou, Shanghai, and Tianjin). We gratefully acknowledge financial support from the United Kingdom’s Department for International Development (DFID). A grant from DFID supported the collaboration of the Enterprise Survey Organization in this survey and fellowships for two ESO staff, Mr. Yang Yumin and Ms. Li Hui, to visit Washington, DC, for analysis and preparation of this report. This project is part of a larger effort in the World Bank Group to help countries assess their investment climates and to identify reforms that will lead to higher productivity, more efficient investment, and ultimately more job creation and growth.

Page 2: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

2

Table of Contents Chapter 1. Investment Climate Matters

1.1 What do we mean by “investment climate” 1.2 …and why does it matter

Chapter 2. China’s Investment Climate in International Perspective 2.1 International Integration 2.2 Infrastructure 2.3 Regulatory burden, governance, and corruption 2.4 Entry and Exit 2.5 Human Resources, Skills, and Technology Endowment 2.6 Access to Finance 2.7 Conclusion

Chapter 3. Measuring the Investment Climate and its Consequences in China 3.1 Introduction 3.2 Regional Variation In Investment Climate

3.2.1 International Integration 3.2.2 Private Sector Development 3.2.3 Domestic Entry and Exit Barrier 3.2.4 Labor Flexibility 3.2.5 Skills and Technology 3.2.6 Financial Services 3.2.7 Government Effectiveness 3.2.8 A brief Summary: A Score Card for the Cities

3.3 Impact of the Investment Climate 3.3.1 Methodology 3.3.2 Investment Rates 3.3.3 Sales Rates 3.3.4 Productivity

3.4 Policy Implications

Page 3: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

3

ANNEXES

1. Technical appendix 2. References

Page 4: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

4

Macro environment1995 2000/1 1995 2000/1 1995 2000/1

GNI per capita (US$, PPP) 2650 3940 1860 2390 6180 6330Population, mid year (millions) 1205 1261 929 1016 59 61GDP growth (1991-95 and 1996-2000,avg %) 12.1 8.2 5.2 6.1 8.7 0.4Openness (Imports+Exports/GDP) 45.7 47.1 25.7 28.2 90.2 124.5Private Investment (% GDP) 15.8 16.7 16.9 16.6 32.1 13.6Public Investment (% GDP) 18.9 19.2 7.7 7.1 8.8 6.5FDI inflows (net, % GDP) 5.1 3.9 0.6 0.5 1.2 5.1

Micro environment Inputs

Labor force education (avg yrs educ, manufact.) 10 10 11Excess labor force, % -- 17.3 --Suppliers availability (used for main input), median 20 4 --Stock of inventories of inputs (days of production) -- 28 --R&D (% sales) 2 -- 5.6

GovernanceControl of corruption2 -0.29 -0.31 -0.17Rule of law2 -0.20 0.23 0.44Political Stability2 0.40 -0.05 0.21Number of visits by gvnt officials, avg per year -- 10.5 --% of senior manager time with gvnt officials 9.2 16.0 --

InfrastructureShare of firms with own generator,% 30 69 --Excess cost of private electricity, % of public -- 24 --Days to clear imports, longest in last year3 12 21 24Cost of shipping4, % 5.4 8.5 6.7Telephone lines in largest city (per 1000 people) 294 131 371Personal computers (per 1,000 people) 12 3 23Paved roads, % of total 88 56 97

Finance

Cost of capital (lending interest rate, %) 5.85 12.29 7.83Share of credit from financial institutions, % 25 36 47 Credit to private sector (stock, % GDP) 125 25 109

Entry/Exit and Operation Cost of labor5 0.23 0.21 0.30Import duty on capital equipment6 -- 10 24Median number of days to start a business 30 90 30Number of permits to start business 6 10 3Bankruptcy rate, % of total firms -- 0.04 0.14Uncertainty of expectations in sales7, % -- 14 --

Source: WDI, ICU firm surveys1/ or most recent available year

2 Scale of -2.5 to 2.5. Higher values correspond to better outcomes

3 Average for Thailand

4 Transport cost as share of value of export to US, textiles, 1998.

5 Ratio of average wage to average value added, median value

6 On all imports for Thailand

7 % variation of avg expectations

India

Investment Climate at a glanceChina, India, and Thailand

China Thailand GNI per cap, PPP $

1000

3000

5000

7000

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

India Thailand China

Credit to Priv. Sector (% gdp)

0

60

120

180

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

India Thailand China

PC per 1,000 people

0

5

10

15

20

25

1995 1996 1997 1998 1999

India Thailand China

Page 5: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

5

Chapter 1. Investment Climate Matters

During the last decade, major developing countries including China have begun to

integrate much more with the global economy. The countries that are aggressively

integrating have grown significantly faster than those that are not. In the 1990s, the more

rapidly globalizing developing countries (measured in terms of increased trade

participation) grew at 5.0 percent per capita, while the rest of the developing world

posted negative growth of 1.1 percent.1 Among the more aggressive globalizers were

Brazil, China, Mexico, Philippines, Thailand, and India.

That globalizing developing countries are doing well on average is good news. But

these averages disguise considerable variation in performance within this group. China

has done spectacularly well, and is the unchallenged leader of the pack. The country has

doubled its ratio of trade to GDP over the past two decades (to 41 percent of GDP in

1999), and has had per capita GDP growth of nearly 8 percent during 1990-99. Malaysia

was another winner: in spite of the temporary income compression due to the Asian

crisis, it could still enjoy per capita GDP growth of 3.8 percent during the 1990s. Again,

despite the crisis, Thailand’s per capita GDP growth in the 1990s averaged 3.8 percent.

However, the per capita GDP growth of another relatively aggressive globalizer, Brazil,

has only been around 1 percent for 1990-99; and growth in the Philippines was only 0.4

percent. India, with per capita GDP growth of 3.3 percent during 1990-99 is in the middle

of the pack (figure 1.1).

1 During the same period, the rich countries grew at about 2 percent per capita.

Page 6: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

6

The implication of these variations is striking. Such differences in growth rates

sustained for one or two decades make a huge difference in living standards and the

extent of poverty. While China and India had comparable levels of GDP per capita

(measured at purchasing power parity) in 1990 (approximately $1400), over the

following decade India’s per capita income nearly doubled, while China’s nearly tripled.

Thus, today, China’s per capita income is about 50 percent higher than that of India.

Together with its faster growth, China has also had significantly faster poverty reduction

(figure 1.2).

Figure 1.1 Per capita GDP growth rates in globalizing developing countries

(average 1990-99)

0

2

4

6

8

China Malaysia India Thailand Mexico Brazil Philippines

Page 7: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

7

Figure 1.2 Poverty reduction in India and China is closely related to the growth rate

* India poverty reduction figure is for 1993-99

Percent per annum (1992-98)

8.4

China

9.9

India

4.4

5.4*

0

2

4

6

8

GDP per capita

growth ratePoverty

reduction

10

The purpose of our paper is to examine some of the reasons for such performance

variations across countries. We argue that openness to foreign trade and investment is an

important, but not sufficient, condition for sustained GDP growth. For China and other

developing countries to do well, good macro and trade policies need to be complemented

with a host of other institutional factors and policies that can be classified under the broad

heading ‘investment climate’.

In the next section we define in more detail what we mean by investment

climate. Section 2 then briefly reviews some of the macro evidence that shows the

importance of investment climate for sustained growth and poverty reduction. While

illuminating about the importance of the investment climate, the macro literature does not

really provide much specific guidance about what aspects of the investment climate are

important and what specific reforms are needed in particular countries. For this reason

Page 8: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

8

we go down to a more micro level in chapters 2 and 3. Chapter two looks at China in

international perspective. The source of information includes surveys conducted by the

World Bank with the Enterprise Survey Organization of China’s National Statistical

Bureau, comparable surveys conducted in other countries, and various cross-country

databases. In general, China compares favorably in areas such as macro and political

stability, integration into the world market, and infrastructure. Abundance of cheap labor

associated with rural-urban migration has been and continues to be a comparative

advantage of China. Not everything is rosy, however. The financial sector is not

operating efficiently—the vast majority of credit has been provided to state-owned

enterprises, which often cannot service their debts, and small- and medium enterprises

have to rely mainly on retained earning and personal wealth (or parent company

financing) to finance their investment. Moreover, China also lags its more developed East

Asian neighbors in terms of education level and infrastructure. Another important caveat

is that our survey covers five major cities – Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Guangzhou, and

Chengdu. So, the results should be interpreted as showing something about the

investment climate in these cities. There remains an important question about the

investment climate in smaller cities and in more interior locations, which we plan to take

up in future surveys and analysis.

Chapter three compares the investment climate in the five cities (Beijing, Tianjin,

Shanghai, Guangzhou, and Chengdu), using the ESO-WB survey of 1500 firms. The

main findings are the following: First, investment climate shows large variations across

the five cities. In particular, Shanghai is characterized by the best international

integration, financial services, good entry and exit conditions and labor market flexibility,

Page 9: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

9

but has the lowest level of domestic private sector participation. Guangzhou is the best in

labor market flexibility, entry and exit fluidity, government efficiency, and private sector

participation; good in international integration and financial services; but relatively low

in skills and technology. Beijing is largely in the middle of the pack, with no especially

strong advantage or disadvantage. Tianjin is good in private sector participation, in the

middle of the pack in terms of entry and exit fluidity and labor market flexibility, poor in

international integration and government efficiency, and worst in skills and technology

and financial services. Chengdu, the only inland city we have surveyed, lags the farthest

in almost everything, with the following exceptions: a good level of private sector

participation, with reasonable skills and especially technology.

Second, the growth potential from improving the investment climate could be

quite large. For instance, we consider what gain Chengdu would get from attaining the

level of investment climate indicators that we observe in the better cities of Guangzhou or

Shanghai. We estimate that in this scenario firm productivity could be increased by

about 30 percent and that the investment rate of the typical firm would increase from the

14 percent that we actually observe in the Chengdu sample to about 19 percent. The

specific point estimates inevitably have some uncertainty around them, but the general

point is that firm productivity, investment, and growth are related to aspects of the

investment climate and that addressing weaknesses identified in this analysis should lead

to substantially better firm performance. Third, within the categories of investment

climate we have found the extent of international integration and the extent of

development of the private sector to be especially important. Other issues such as entry

Page 10: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

10

and exit barriers, labor market flexibility, and financial services are important as well.

Each city has specific areas that could be improved.

A. What do we mean by “investment climate”?

The quantity and quality of investment flowing into China or any specific region

depend upon the returns that investors expect and the uncertainties around those returns.

These expectations can be usefully categorized as the following broad yet interrelated

components:

• First, there are a set of macro or country-level issues concerning economic and

political stability and national policy towards foreign trade and investment. By these,

we generally refer to macroeconomic, fiscal, monetary, and exchange rate policies as

well as political stability. As far as these macro indicators go, China performs quite

well, as will be documented in chapter two.

• Second, there is the issue of efficacy of a country’s regulatory framework. As far as

firms are concerned, these relate to the issues of entry and exit, labor relations and

flexibility in labor use, efficiency and transparency of financing and taxation, and

efficiency of regulations concerning the environment, safety, health, and other

legitimate public interests. The question is not whether to regulate or not, but whether

such regulations are designed in incentive compatible ways, avoid adverse selection

and moral hazard, serve the public interest, are implemented expeditiously without

harassment and corruption, and facilitate efficient outcomes. While such variables are

hard to measure, our surveys clearly suggest that regulatory efficacy varies widely

across countries and, as far as China is concerned, across provinces.

Page 11: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

11

• Third, and no less important, is the quality and quantity of available physical and

financial infrastructure, such as power, transport, telecommunications, and banking

and finance; and given the imperfect mobility of skilled workers and the clustering of

technology, the endowment of skills and technology. When one surveys entrepreneurs

about their problems and bottlenecks, they will often cite infrastructure issues such as

power reliability, transport time and cost, and access and efficiency of finance, along

with the lack of skilled workers and the difficulty of access to advanced technologies

as key determinants of competitiveness and profitability.

China’s success in the 1990s suggests that it has many positive features in its

investment climate, and one objective of our study is to understand what has contributed

to China’s success – which can provide useful lessons to other developing countries. The

evidence also shows that there is still room for significant improvement in the investment

climate. To be sure, China has been excellent in the first dimension of the investment

climate (i.e., macro environment), as characterized by political and macro policy stability.

However, some recent changes in the structure of the Chinese economy require further

structural reforms. The WTO accession, for instance, requires China to shift from a

discretion-based governance system to a rule-based one, which requires the reduction of

the role of the government in how firms operate. Financing also should be less favorable

to one particular type of ownership. Another challenge has been the migration of rural

residents to cities, and the pressure of job creation due to both migration and Xia-Gang

workers (i.e., laid-off workers from SOEs). This challenge also imposes demand for

regulatory reforms to reduce entry barriers for new, and small- and medium-sized

enterprises, which have been shown to be the most important force behind job creation;

Page 12: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

12

and it also pushes for reforms in financial institutions in order to allow SMEs more ready

access for credit. This paper hopes to shed light on what would be some fruitful areas for

further reforms.

Two caveats are in order at this stage. First, we are not interested in the quantity

of investment per se. Indeed, recent work on economic growth [Easterly 1999] has shown

that there is surprisingly little relationship between the quantity of investment and the rate

of economic growth. In many instances, this is due to a distorted and dysfunctional

institutional and policy milieu — where neither public nor private investments produce

the benefits that they should. Our focus, therefore, is not on the quantity of investment,

but on the overall institutional and policy environment — the ‘investment climate’ —

that determines whether or not investments pay off in terms of greater competitiveness of

firms and sustained growth.

Second, while we recognize that social infrastructure is no less important than its

physical and financial counterparts, we have chosen to exclude from our definition of the

investment climate such issues as the provision of basic education and health services. It

is a deliberate choice. The reforms needed to improve social services are quite different

from the issues of infrastructure and regulation of industry on which we concentrate.

B… and why does it matter

Spurred by the endogenous growth theories of Romer (1986) and Lucas (1986), there is

now a vast empirical literature that investigates the determinants of growth. Some of the

empirical results are fairly robust and provide macro evidence about the importance of

Page 13: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

13

the investment climate. Fischer (1993), for example, found that high inflation is bad for

growth. This commonsense result is hard to dispute. To an extent, inflation reflects

exogenous shocks that are beyond the government’s control. But truly high inflation

typically reflects serious monetary mismanagement. There is also a clear negative

relationship between government consumption and growth, which was first noted by

Easterly and Rebelo (1993). No doubt, some government expenditures are socially

productive, but developing countries with very high government spending usually have

inefficient bureaucracies and high levels of corruption.

A number of studies, most recently Frankel and Romer (1999) and Dollar and Kraay

(2001), find that openness to trade and direct foreign investment accelerates growth.

These findings are in the spirit of the new growth models, and emphasize the importance

of market size for creating a finer division of labor and stronger incentives to innovate. In

addition to macro and trade policies, financial development is also a catalyst for growth

[Levine, Loayza and Beck (2000)]. All else being controlled for, countries that have more

developed stock markets and/or deeper banking systems tend to grow faster.

Investment climate measures such as the strength of property rights, rule of law, and

level of corruption are also well correlated with growth [Kaufmann, Kraay, and Zoido-

Lobatón (1999); Knack and Keefer (1995)]. These studies typically use data generated

from surveys of private businesses, and reflect the extent to which investors and/or firms

perceive problems with harassment, corruption, and inefficient regulation. A problem of

these measures, however, is that they are often based on a small sample of very large

entrepreneurs and hence do not provide a robust assessment of how rule of law and

Page 14: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

14

corruption are experienced by small and medium enterprises, which form the backbone of

the economy.

Thus, the empirical cross-country literature provides evidence that growth and

poverty reduction are promoted by a good investment climate — an appropriate policy

package of private property rights, sound rule of law, macroeconomic stability,

government spending that is not excessive and well focused on public goods, and

openness to foreign trade and investment. However, most of the macro-indicators of

policy and investment climate used in these studies are quite crude, and are of little help

to countries in identifying what specifically needs to be done to create a better climate.

For instance, the existing cross-country macroeconomic measures are quite similar for

China and India (e.g. rankings on rule of law, corruption, or overall infrastructure quality

from different international sources) (ICU, World Bank, 2002). Both countries ‘fit’ the

empirical growth studies in that both have done relatively well. India has grown at about

twice the rate of the OECD countries in the 1990s. Yet, China has grown much faster and

had much greater poverty reduction. Macro-indices fail to explain such differences. Thus,

while the macro evidence is useful as background and motivation for the rest of our work,

it suggests the need to delve at a much more micro level, and to survey large numbers of

producers, including SMEs, to understand the rich differential relationship between

investment climate and growth.

Page 15: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

15

Chapter 2: China’s Investment Climate in International Perspective

China’s solid macroeconomic performance over the past decade is

unquestionable. Moreover, this growth remained relatively stable even during the East

Asia crisis, when other countries in the region saw large GDP decreases (figure 2.1).

Figure 2.1 Growth remains strong through the East Asian crisis

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

15

1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001

Percent GDP growth

ChinaKorea, Rep.

MalaysiaIndonesia

Thailand

Philippines

Other macroeconomic indicators are also consistent with this long-running

economic growth. Low inflation, for example, tends to be an important factor in

sustainable economic growth, though moderate inflation may not be harmful (Barro,

1997).2 Inflation in China was relatively low through the 1990s. Moreover, it remained

2 Spurred by the endogenous growth theories of Romer (1986) and Lucas (1986), there is now a vast empirical literature that investigates the relationship between inflation and growth. Fischer (1993), for example, found that high inflation is bad for growth. This commonsense result is hard to dispute. To an extent, inflation reflects exogenous shocks beyond the government’s control. But truly high inflation, however, typically reflects serious monetary mismanagement.

Page 16: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

16

low during the East Asian crisis, unlike other Asian countries which saw higher inflation

(figure 2.2).3

Figure 2.2 Low inflation, even during the East Asian crisis

0

20

40

60

China India S. Korea Malaysia Indonesia Thailand Philippines

CPI percent change

Average1990-2000

1998

Strong macroeconomic performance, however, masks the underlying components

of the investment climate, described in chapter 1, that affect (and are affected by) the

macroeconomy. While chapter 3 will explore the microeconomic foundations of China’s

investment climate, this chapter will compare China’s aggregate performance in certain

investment climate measures to the rest of the world. Broadly speaking, these factors

include international integration, governance, infrastructure, entry and exit of businesses,

human resources, and finance. While macroeconomic indicators present only good news,

as we will see the investment climate analysis reveals both strengths and serious

weaknesses.

3 Some debate these inflation figures, suggesting that enterprises have systematically understated inflation (Young, 2000).

Page 17: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

17

1. International Integration

The strong macroeconomic environment has brought—and has been encouraged

by—China’s increased integration in the world economy. Indeed, China’s entry into the

WTO is a major signal of China’s international outlook. The important role that trade

plays in promoting productive investment and growth has long been recognized. Using

different measures of “openness” to trade, including both its relative size (as measured by

import and export shares) and degree of distortion (as measured by average tariff rates

and dispersion), research strongly suggests that greater openness is associated with higher

growth in both industrialized and developing nations. Sachs and Warner (1995) find that

openness is a highly significant determinant of growth, and combined with property

rights may even represent sufficient conditions for growth in poor economies. Kang and

Sawada (2000) find a similar effect of openness on growth, arguing that combined with

financial development it increases growth rates in developing economies by decreasing

the cost of human capital investment.4

Foreign direct investment (FDI) and trade are good indicators of this integration.5

Net FDI increased dramatically in the last decade, from $2.7 billion in 1990 to $37 billion

in 2000. This growth is impressive, and as a share of GDP, net FDI into China is higher

than many other Asian countries, though not as high as some in Latin America (figure

4 Rodriguez and Rodrik (1999) argue that some indicators of openness are highly correlated with other indicators of economic performance, including macroeconomic policy, or that they imperfectly reflect a country’s trade policy regime. The high correlation of components of the Sachs and Warner index with policy and institutional variables yields an upward bias in the estimation of trade restriction effects, while tariff and non-tariff barriers, the two variables that directly measure trade openness, have little explanatory power when considered separately in cross-country regression studies. 5 A number of studies, most recently Frankel and Romer (1999) and Dollar and Kraay (2002), find that openness to trade and direct foreign investment accelerates growth. These findings are in the spirit of the new growth models, and emphasize the importance of market size for creating a finer division of labor and stronger incentives to innovate.

Page 18: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

18

2.3). FDI as a share of GDP has come down somewhat in the second half of the 1990s

(figure 2.4), but in absolute terms China is still the largest recipient in the developing

world.

In regards to trade, meanwhile, China has reduced tariff rates to about one-third of

what they were two decades ago: from 49.5 percent in 1982 to 16.8 percent by 1998

(World Bank 2002). Partly as a result, trade increased from 15 percent of GDP in 1980

to nearly 50 percent of (a much larger) GDP by 2000. Imports increased from about $US

36 billion in 1980 to $US 192 billion in 2000 (in constant 1995 US dollars). Likewise,

exports increased from $US 27 billion in 1980 to $US 239 billion in 2000.

Figure 2.3 FDI as a share of GDP, 2000

-2

0

2

4

6

China India S. Korea Malaysia

Indonesia

Thailand Philippines Brazil Argentina

Page 19: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

19

Figure 2.4 FDI as a share of GDP in China is high, but declining

0

2

4

6

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

2. Infrastructure

One component of the investment climate is a country’s infrastructure.

Businesses in countries with poor infrastructure must spend more effort to, for example,

acquire information, receive inputs, and get their products to market. The costs of poor

infrastructure can easily undermine any cost-competitiveness that a business would

otherwise have, at best making it more costly for a given firm to operate and at worst

deterring entry in the first place by making it uneconomic. Infrastructure in China

appears to do relatively well compared to other developing countries.

Two separate surveys suggest that businesses do not perceive infrastructure to be

a tremendous obstacle. Figure 2.5 reports the share of firms in the World Business

Environment Survey reporting that infrastructure posed “no obstacle” for “the operation

and growth of [their] business.” Approximately 42 percent of Chinese firms responded

that infrastructure posed no obstacle, much better than Brazil or India, but about average

Page 20: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

20

for East and South Asia. Figure 2.6, meanwhile, reports the average responses of

business executives surveyed in the World Economic Forum’s Global Competitiveness

Report (GCR), which asks respondents to rate “the overall infrastructure quality of their

country” on a scale of 1 to 7, with one being the worst ranking and seven the best.6

While China ranks slightly ahead of India, it falls below Brazil, Malaysia, and Thailand.

Figure 2.5 Share of firms reporting that infrastructure was “no obstacle” to doing business

Source: World Business Environment Survey

0

20

40

60

Thailand India Brazil East Asia China South Asia Malaysia OECD

6 There are serious problems with simply averaging responses. For example, it assumes that a response of “2,” for example, means the same thing for each respondent, a notion that research on surveys contradicts (see, for example (Recanatini, et al., 2000). At least one study has criticized the Global Competitiveness Report on the grounds that it is methodologically flawed and theoretically weak (Lall, 2001).

Page 21: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

21

Figure 2.6 Overall quality of infrastructure, average response

(1=poorly developed and inefficient, 7= among the best in the world)

0

2

4

6

India China Brazil Thailand Malaysia OECDSource: World Economic Forum, 2002

These two figures are illustrative, but also show the limitations of such surveys:

for example, the GCR suggests that infrastructure, overall, is better in Brazil than in

China, while the WBES suggests that fewer firms in China believe that infrastructure is

an obstacle to their doing business. Several factors could be driving this seemingly

anomalous result. First, neither survey is random or representative, making it difficult to

compare one country to another. Second, firms surveyed in Brazil could be more

technologically advanced than those in China, meaning that Brazilian firms might

demand higher quality infrastructure. If so, infrastructure quality in Brazil could be

higher than in China, but still pose a relatively greater obstacles to firms there. Because

of the imprecision inherent in such surveys, it is worth exploring more factual indicators.

Below we compare data on shipping costs and ports, telecommunications development,

and power provision.

Page 22: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

22

Shipping and ports

China is relatively well integrated into the world market through efficient

shipping and relatively well functioning ports. Data from U.S. customs concerning all of

the containerized shipments into U.S. ports allow for a comparison of the shipping costs

for a particular product such as textiles from different ports around the world. China has

a large shipping cost advantage over India and significant cost advantages over Thailand,

Indonesia, and Brazil (figure 2.7).

Figure 2.7 Shipping cost advantages

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

Thailand Indonesia China S. Korea Brazil

Cost advantage compared to IndiaE. CoastW. CoastUSA

Textiles

This reflects the large volume of exports from China as well as relatively efficiency of its

ports. On the related issue of bottlenecks in customs clearance, China is good compared

to India and a bit behind Asian neighbors such as Korea and Thailand. In large samples

of manufacturing firms the average clearance time for imported inputs was 8 days in

China, compared to 11 for India, and 7 for Korea and Thailand. In more recent surveys

we have been asking firms their worst customs experience in the past six months, which

Page 23: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

23

highlights whether firms operate in an uncertain environment. In the Indian sample the

typical firms worst experience was a three-week delay, compared to only 9 days in

Shanghai (figure 2.8).

6.7

21.0

9.210.6

0

10

20

India Shanghai

Last timeLongest

0

4

8

1210.6

7.0 7.0

India Korea Thailand

7.8

China

Figure 2.8 Days to clear imported inputs through customs

c

The reasonably good port and customs facilities help Chinese firms connect effectively

to the world market.

Telecommunications

Telecommunications is an increasingly important component of a nation’s

infrastructure. There has been a steady increase in the number of telephones per capita in

China, from less than one telephone line per hundred people in 1990 to nearly 14 by

2001, though the telephone penetration rate is still lower than many other developing

countries. Among seven Asian countries, China has fewer telephone lines per capita than

Page 24: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

24

South Korea and Malaysia, but more than India, Thailand, Indonesia, and the Philippines

(figure 2.9).

Figure 2.9 Telephones per hundred people

0

10

20

30

40

50

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000

Korea

Malaysia

Brazil

China

Thailand

India

Source: International Telecommunications Union

The number of telephone mainlines is only a part of the telecommunications

infrastructure. Much telecommunications growth in developing countries now comes

from mobile telephone providers, and China is no exception. By 2001 China had more

mobile telephone subscribers than any country in the world. Of course, China is also the

most populous country in the world, and mobile penetration has exploded throughout the

world, so the number of mobile phones per capita paints a slightly different picture. By

2001 China boasted just over 11 mobile subscribers per hundred people—better than

India or Indonesia, but trailing far behind Korea, Malaysia, and the Philippines (figure

2.10).

Page 25: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

25

Figure 2.10 Mobile phone users per hundred people, 2001

0

20

40

60

China

India Indonesia

S. Korea

Malaysia

Philippines

Source: International Telecommunications Union

Power

Access to reliable power at a reasonable cost is a prime concern for most

manufacturing firms. Figure 2.11 shows electricity generation capacity in China and

selected countries. While generation has clearly been growing, generation capacity has

only just managed to stay above population growth. Moreover, China lags several

countries in this measure. Thailand, Brazil, and Malaysia all have more generation

capacity per capita than does China, though the Philippines and two states in India for

which there are data lag behind. China has a number of big projects in the pipeline that

will boost generating capacity substantially.

Page 26: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

26

Figure 2.11 Electrical generation capacityMW/thousand people)

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 19990

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1Korea

Malaysia

Orissa (India)

BrazilThailand

ChinaPhilippines

Punjab (India)

Source: US Energy Information Agency

Generation capacity, of course, is only part of the story. Reliable power means

electricity delivered with few interruptions. Low prices for electricity from the grid are

not helpful to firms if electricity is frequently unavailable. Our surveys of firms contain

some illuminating information. For example, 30 percent of firms in China have backup

generators compared to 69 percent in India, where electricity is less reliable. Chinese

firms report, on average, losing about 2 percent of their output as a result of power

problems, compared to 6 percent in Pakistan.

Regulatory burden, governance, and corruption

A country’s general governance structure and business-government interactions

are an important component of the investment climate. Broadly speaking, these include

the burden firms face in complying with regulations, the quality of the services provided

by these regulations and the extent to which corruption is associated with the

procurement of such services. Five composite indicators from Kaufman, Kraay, and

Page 27: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

27

Zoido-Lobaton (1999; 2002) capture the dimensions of interest.7 These categories

include:

• Government effectiveness measures bureaucratic delays, competence of officials,

the quality of public service delivery and the independence of the civil service

from political pressures. This grouping of indicators covers the elements needed

for the government to design and implement good policies.

• Regulatory burden includes the number of regulations within a market, the

number of markets that are regulated, competition policy measures, and price

controls. This captures more of the outcomes of the policies and provides a sense

of how market friendly the business environment is.

• Rule of law captures the extent of crime, property rights, tax evasion and the legal

system’s effectiveness. It indicates the enforceability of contracts and the

predictability of rules.

• Corruption measures include the frequency and size of irregular payments.

7 These governance indices are the compilations of up to 60 sub-indices from various sources. Some qualifications should be noted when using these subjective measures to compare competitive environments. They revolve around the issue of the yardstick used in judging a country’s performance. First, the point of reference itself can vary across country. In one study, Korean entrepreneurs rankings of problems were consistently higher than those of Indonesia. Few would believe the business environment in Indonesia to be superior to that of Korea. Rather, a more plausible explanation is that the Korean entrepreneurs had relatively high expectations of services their government should provide and shortfalls were readily registered. In contrast, if there are few expectations that a service will be performed, its failure is not seen as particularly problematic. Controlling for differences in country mean responses offers at least a partial solution. Another shortcoming of these measures is that they register very little change over time, and do not necessarily reflect that substantial improvements have been made in the substantive area over time. Again, this may be due to changes in the subjective yardstick against which they are being measured. For example, as the judicial system is reformed, expectations will rise as to what role the courts should play. Failure to meet expectations could lead to low rankings, even as the system improves These subjective rankings are more useful for making comparisons within a single country than for attaching great significance to the international ranking. Thus, one can look among Indian entrepreneurs to see the relative rankings of problems, for example infrastructure versus corruption, rather than looking at perceptions of corruption between India and its neighbors. Unfortunately these indictors are rarely used in this fashion.

Page 28: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

28

• Political instability and violence measures the incidence of coups, assassinations,

riots, armed conflicts and provides a measure of the likelihood of a violent

overthrow of a governing party.

The individual measures of governance are plotted on ‘governance

pentagons’ for China and selected countries (figure 2.12).

The outer web indicates the best performance, and the inner web the

median measure for the 174 countries for which measures were available.

Thus, the larger the country’s web, the better its governance is measured

to be. China scores very high on political stability, near the median for

government effectiveness, regulations, and rule of law, but below the

median for corruption.

IndiaPolitical stability

Government effectiveness

RegulationsRule of law

Corruption

ChinaPolitical stability

RegulationsRule of law

Corruption

BrazilPolitical stability

RegulationsRule of Law

Corruption

ThailandPolitical stability

RegulationsRule of Law

Corruption IndonesiaPolitical stability

RegulationsRule of Law

Corruption

Government effectiveness

Government effectiveness

Government effectiveness

Government effectiveness

Figure 2.12 Governance ‘pentagons’

Source: Kaufman, Kraay and Zoido-Laboton, 1999

Page 29: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

29

Some additional measures support the information presented in the pentagons.

There is both good, bad, and conflicting news on the regulatory burden facing firms in

China. The World Business Environment Survey, for example, found that managers in

China spend about nine percent of their time dealing with public officials, far less than in

India, and about the same as in transition European countries, Latin America, and even

OECD countries (figure 2.13).

The Global Competitiveness Report, on the other hand, ranked China significantly worse

than the median on the same measure, and far worse than India. In terms of corruption,

the Global Competitiveness Report ranked China among the worst in terms of business

costs of corruption, worse even than, for example, Thailand and India. Likewise, China

was worse than the median country on the frequency of “irregular” payments by firms,

though in this case Thailand and India scored even more poorly (figure 2.14).

Figure 2.13Management time spent dealing with public officials on

regulations, administrationPercent of management time

0

5

10

15

20

IndiaChina Transitional Europe

LAC OECD

Source: World Business Environment Survey (WBES) ©2000 The World Bank Group

Page 30: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

30

Figure 2.14 Corruption measuresRanking out of 75 countries surveyed in the Global Competitiveness Report, 2001

0 15 30 45 60 75

Frequency of irregular payments

Time senior management spends with government agencies/regulators

Business costs of corruption

Strongest

ChinaIndia

Weakest

Entry and Exit

Free entry and exit of firms is important to a healthy economy. Barriers to entry

and exit block new, more productive and innovative firms from emerging. A growing

body of literature documents the difficulty entrepreneurs face in establishing firms in

developing countries (e.g., Djankov, et al., 2002; Emery, et al., 2000; Friedman, et al.,

2000). Djankov, et al. (2002) compiled data on entry regulations in 85 countries, and

discovered enormous variation in the number of procedures required to start firms across

countries, ranging from a low of two in Canada, to as many as 21 in the Dominican

Republic (with Bolivia and Russia a close second at 20). Likewise, the time required to

establish a firm ranged from two to 152 business days. These procedures can be

extremely costly to the economy—the cost of official procedures (that is, not including

bribes) for setting up a new business was 266 percent of per capita income in Bolivia.

They find that stricter regulation of entry is correlated with more corruption and a larger

informal economy.

Page 31: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

31

Figure 2.15 Number of procedures and days to complete them to start a new business

Source: Djankov 2000

0

4

8

12

16

China Malaysia Thailand India S. Korea Philippines 85 country average

0

20

40

60

80

100

Days

Days to complete

Number of proceduresNumber of procedures

Using Djankov’s measure of business entry, China required 12 procedures to start

a firm, more than the sample average of 10, and far more time was required to complete

them at 92 days, versus a sample average of 47 days. These estimates suggest that it

takes more time to start a business in China than in, for example, India, Thailand, or

Malaysia (figure 2.15). These data, however, are somewhat contradicted by survey

responses in the Global Competitiveness Report (figure 2.16). This measure places

China at worse than the median in terms of the number of permits to start a business—

which they estimate at six—but also suggests that the median number of days to start a

business is only 30. In this case China does better than the median, and much better than

India, which is near the bottom. Another way to determine the difficulty of entry and exit

is to examine outcomes that are associated with these factors. In particular, entry and exit

are crucial to a competitive economy, and one of the most telling indicators of whether

Page 32: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

32

markets are competitive in a country is the productivity dispersion of firms within an

industry.

In a competitive market, with reasonably free entry and exit, dispersion should be

low as unproductive firms either improve or leave the market. Higher dispersion

indicates that less efficient producers are not being forced to improve their productivity

or exit the market. Firm-level studies in a number of countries bear this out.8 Subsidies

or strict regulations that impede entry or exit can ultimately bolster high cost producers.

When such firms remain in the market, more productive firms may not have adequate

incentives or the ability to increase productivity or to grow. However, as competition

increases, firms face greater incentives to innovate and greater penalties for failure to do

so.

Figure 2.16 Entry and exit

China

0 15 30 45 60 75

Hiring and firing of workers

Administrative burden for startups

Median number of days to start a firm

Number of permits to start a firm(6 permits)(10 permits)

(30 days)(90 days)

Strongest Weakest

India

Ranking out of 75 countries surveyed in the Global Competitiveness Report, 2001

Loss of protection and greater competition from foreign firms can drive

inefficient domestic producers to better exploit scale economies, eliminate waste, reduce

managerial slack, adopt better technologies, or shut down. As a result, productivity

dispersion should shrink as productivity levels rise in the face of greater competition.

8 See Hallward-Driemeier (2001) for a longer discussion; Levinsohn (1993), Haddad and Harrison (1994).

Page 33: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

33

Productivity dispersion—a measure of inefficiency—tends to be associated with

barriers to competition, such as administrative barriers to start a business or trade barriers

to competition for India, China, Philippines, Thailand, Malaysia and Korea (figure 2.17).

Figure 2.17 Dispersion of value added by workerRatio of 75th percentile to 25th

0

2

4

6

8

Garments Electronics

India

PhilippinesThailandMalaysiaKorea

China

In Chinese garments and electronics, the higher performers have value added per worker

that is 5 times that of lower performers. In electronics, productivity dispersion is lower in

four East Asian countries where the World Bank has conducted similar surveys, while in

garments only India performs worse than China on this measure. In Malaysia and

Thailand the ratios are just below 3, and in Korea not much more than 2. Thus, more

competitive countries in the group (as proxied by weeks to start a business and average

tariff rates) have lower levels of productivity dispersion than do the less competitive

countries.

Page 34: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

34

Human Resources, Skills, and Technology Endowment

The availability of inputs is a crucial component of the investment climate. In

terms of human resources, this does not mean simply an abundant labor force—which

China certainly possesses—but also skill levels and technological know-how. In this

section we explore how educated the Chinese labor force is compared to other countries

at the most basic level and in terms of higher education. We also explore measures of

technological know-how and endowments in the country.

Close to 16 percent of the Chinese population is illiterate. This is considerably

better than India, and only slightly worse than Malaysia and Indonesia, but is much worse

than the Philippines, Thailand, or South Korea (figure 2.18).

Figure 2.18 Illiteracy and school enrollment, 1999-2000

*Philippines data is for 1998-1999 ** No data for India and IndonesiaSource: UNESCO, through SIMA

0

20

40

60

80

100

Illiteracy rate Secondary enrollment Tertiary enrollment**

ChinaIndiaIndonesiaKorea, Rep.MalaysiaPhilippines*Thailand

Similarly, nearly 63 percent of the relevant population in China is enrolled in secondary

school, better than the 50 percent in India, but below the other countries in the sample.

Page 35: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

35

Even worse, China’s tertiary enrollment rate is only 7.5 percent, which is extremely low

compared to other Asian countries.

Nonetheless, these relatively low figures still represent improvements over time.

China’s educational infrastructure, especially with respect to science and technology, has

developed mostly since the 1978 reforms. Since then China has rapidly built higher

educational institutions and sent tens of thousands of students to study abroad.

Postgraduate enrollment in Chinese institutions has increased from nearly nothing prior

to 1978 to more than 300,000 by the year 2000. Some recent research has begun to

account for this vast increase in human capital, finding that it has contributed

significantly to growth and welfare (Wang and Yao, 2001).

An ongoing concern in China, however, is the large number of students who leave

to study abroad and then do not return. In response to this concern in 1992 the

government began to send delegations abroad to entice Chinese degree holders to return

(Guo, 2000). While it is true that increasing numbers of students leave to study abroad, it

is also true that an increasing number of students are returning to China once they have

their degree (see figure 2.19).

Page 36: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

36

Figure 2.19 Chinese students abroad

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

1952 1980 1990 1995 2000

Number students studying abroad

Number students returned

Source: Chinese Statistical Yearbook

Data compiled by the U.S. National Science Foundation (NSF) sheds additional light on

this phenomenon. The NSF collects information on, among other things, students from

outside the US who received science and engineering PhDs from US institutions. The

data includes numbers of students and those with “firm plans to stay,” where firm plans

means the students have job offers in the United States.

Page 37: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

37

Figure 2.20 Number of science and engineering PhDs received in the US, by citizenship

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997

China

Taiwan,China

Korea

India

Brazil

Source: US National Science Foundation

Figure 2.20 shows the number of students from China and other countries that

received science and engineering PhDs in the United States in the 1990s. The figure

shows a steadily increasing trend for China (except in 1997), which has far better

representation than any other country, while the number of students from other countries

remained fairly flat. The share of students from China that plan to stay in the US is

exceeded only by students from India (figure 2.21). Moreover, the share of students with

plans to stay remained relatively stable until 1995, when it began to increase. Whether

this trend continued with the contraction of the US high-tech economy is unclear.

Page 38: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

38

Figure 2.21 Share of science and engineering PhDs with firm plans to stay in U.S.

0

20

40

60

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997

India

China

Korea

Brazil

Taiwan,China

Some see the increasing numbers of students abroad and large share of students

staying in the US as evidence of brain drain. On the other hand, ever increasing numbers

of students are returning to China after studying abroad, suggesting more of a brain

circulation. There is likely some truth to both sides. New research, however, is

beginning to document gains to developing countries that emerge over a long period of

time when large numbers of students at first remain abroad but then gradually return.

Saxenian (1999; 2000) found that large numbers of people from India and Taiwan

province came to the US as students and remained to work in Silicon Valley, learning US

high-tech business and management models. Eventually, many of them began to return

home, bringing those skills and education with them. Those re-patriats are largely

responsible for new high-tech firms and success of new technology areas. Moreover,

there is increasing evidence of a similar phenomenon beginning to take place in China.

Page 39: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

39

R&D and Technology

Xioajuan (1997) notes three major changes in Chinese science and technology

policy since 1978:

• The government no longer controls all science and technology projects.

• Science and technology no longer takes place only in free-standing research

institutes—enterprises and other non-governmental organizations conduct

research.

• Research results can be transferred to markets as commodities.

Some of these changes can be seen in aggregate statistics.

Figure 2.22 Research and development expenditures in China

0

10,000

20,000

30,000

40,000

1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 19990

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

Total R&D expenditure (left axis)

As percent of GDP(right axis)

PPP $

Figure 2.22 shows the change in R&D spending in the Chinese economy over the last

decade. Even with the dramatic growth in China’s GDP, the share of R&D in the

economy is growing.

Page 40: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

40

Figure 2.23 Research and development as share of GDP, latest year available

0

1

2

3

China India Brazil Korea Malaysia Thailand

1997 1994 1996

1996

19961996

Though this bodes well, figure 2.23 shows that China spends only about as much on

R&D as a share of GDP as does India and Brazil, more than countries like Malaysia and

Thailand, but far less than more developed countries like Korea.

Access to Finance

Economic theory holds that businesses will invest in projects where the expected

benefits exceed the costs of the investment. This efficient investment can happen,

however, only when businesses do not face credit constraints unrelated to their own

performance. Such credit constraints are less likely to occur in countries with better-

developed financial systems. Indeed, a great deal of research has demonstrated the

importance of well-functioning financial systems to growth (World Bank, 2001). In

general, countries with deep financial systems (banks, stock, and bond markets) tend to

grow faster than countries with more shallow systems. A properly-functioning financial

Page 41: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

41

system contributes to growth by allocating financing to high-productivity investments,

which will be more effective than simply increasing overall investment.

Chinese firms have much less access to formal finance than do firms in any other

Asian country surveyed thus far. Approximately 29 percent of working capital for large

Chinese firms comes from bank loans, less than firms in Indonesia, Malaysia, the

Philippines, Thailand, or Korea (figure 2.24).

Figure 2.24 Access to capital, large firms(Share of working capital from various sources)

0%

20%

40%

60%

Retained earnings Bank loans Other (family, informal markets)

ChinaKorea

Thailand

The situation appears even worse for small and medium-size firms (SMEs) (figure 2.25).

On average, only 12 percent of SME’s working capital comes from bank loans. By

comparison, 21 percent of SME’s capital in Malaysia comes from loans, 24 percent in

Indonesia, 28 percent in the Philippines, and 26 percent in Thailand and Korea. The lack

of formal finance among small firms becomes starkly worse as firm size decreases (figure

2.26).

Page 42: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

42

Firms with at least 100 employees finance 27 percent of their capital through bank loans,

compared to 39 percent in India. Firms with between 20 and 100 employees finance 13

percent of their capital through bank loans, compared to 38 percent in India. Firms with

fewer than 20 employees finance only 2.3 percent of their capital, on average, through

bank loans, compared to 29 percent in India.

Figure 2.25 Access to capital, SMEs(Share of working capital from various sources)

0%

20%

40%

60%

Retained earnings Bank loans Other (family, informal markets)

ChinaKorea

Thailand

One would expect that, on average, less capital would come from formal sources of

finance in smaller firms. Smaller firms tend to be younger and have a more uncertain

future, making formal financiers more hesitant to lend to them and making loans more

costly to the firm to incorporate this risk premium. On the other hand, the share of

capital financed through loans in China is lower than other countries even among large

firms, and the gap between China and other Asian countries increases as firm size

decreases. These figures strongly suggest that firms may be facing credit constraints

completely unrelated to a firm’s expected probability of being successful in the market.

Page 43: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

43

The consequences of real credit constraints could be severe. Large firms

may have difficulty expanding or upgrading. Entrepreneurs may be unable to enter the

market at all. Such a deterrent to entry could be especially costly to the economy as

entrepreneurship—individuals taking risks to bring innovative products and services to

the market—is a key component of economic growth (McMillan and Woodruff, 2002).

Gaining access to the financial credit entrepreneurs need to launch new ideas and

businesses is an issue all over the world. But the formal financial sector should not make

the problem worse by denying access to firms by virtue of their size alone.

Conclusion

Aggregated macroeconomic indicators, while useful, mask underlying issues

facing the economy, making it difficult for policymakers to see the economy’s particular

strengths and weaknesses. Such knowledge can help devise policies targeted at

Fig.2.26 Sources of finance

India

Retained earnings

Parent Bank loan

Equity Other(largely

other loans)

<20 20-100 100 plus

China

Retained earnings

Parent Bank loan

Equity Other (largely other loans)

0

20

40

60Percent

0

20

40

60Percent

Page 44: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

44

mitigating specific problems. This chapter explored factors that comprise China’s

investment climate, namely international integration, infrastructure, governance, entry

and exit, human resources and skills, and access to finance.

Overall, international integration increased significantly in the past decade,

culminating, of course, with China’s entry into the WTO. On this measure China

compares well to other Asian countries. Infrastructure, too, compares well to other

countries and seems to be improving rapidly. Most elements of governance compare

favorably to other countries. Human resources and skills are, despite high illiteracy rates

and low tertiary school enrollment, largely comparable to several other Asian countries

and appear to be improving.

Not all investment climate measures were positive, however. Different measures

of entry and exit were mixed, though they seemed to put China somewhat below the

median of developing countries. Moreover, the high productivity dispersion in our firm

survey suggests that entry and exit are less common than elsewhere. The clearest

problem was access to finance, which was worse than every other country in the sample.

Moreover, the gap between China and other Asian countries increased as firm size

decreased.

While this analysis takes us beneath the macroeconomic level, it still requires

aggregating lots of information into single (or just a few) indicators. Microeconomic

analysis at the business level can shed further light on these issues. We take up that

matter in the next chapter.

Page 45: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

45

Chapter 3

Measuring the Investment Climate and its Consequences in China

3.1. Introduction.

In international comparison, China’s investment climate is reasonably strong,

with impressive improvements having been realized in the last fifteen years. Within

China, however, the investment climate is not uniform; national indicators can mask

important variations across regions. This chapter addresses the differences in the

investment climate within China, focusing on the variation across five regions. The aim

is two-fold. First, new quantitative measures of the investment climate are presented,

allowing for objective comparisons across the regions. Second, these measures are then

linked to firm performance to illustrate how improvements in different dimensions of the

investment climate can spur additional investment, sales growth and productivity. The

counterfactual analysis indicates that investment rates could be increased by up to one

quarter, sales growth could be increased by up to one half and productivity by up to one

third if the weakest cities had the investment climate indicators of the leading city.

Variation across regions in China is quite considerable, with eastern and coastal

areas generally having developed more quickly and attracted more investors than the

mid- and Western areas. There are two broad sources of factors that help explain this

phenomenon. The first is differences in natural endowments, such as access to ports and

labor endowments. The second source is the particular nature of how the Chinese

economy and policy making has been decentralized. For years, regional governments

Page 46: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

46

have been given different degrees of discretion in setting economic policy. Thus, some

experimental provinces and cities were given greater freedom to choose more liberal

policies to attract foreign capital. Furthermore, the central and regional tax arrangements

were negotiated province by province, giving regional governments different incentives

for economic performance (Gordon and Li, 2002). These differences have also given rise

to strong regional protectionism (Poncet, 2002), as carefully documented by the State

Planning Commission (2000). Together, the differences in initial endowments, regional

discretion in policy making, tax arrangements, as well as leadership turnover patterns

have led to strong regional variations in the investment climate. This chapter seeks to use

this regional variation to understand the relative importance of different dimensions of

the investment climate and to explore the potential gains that could be realized by

improvements in investment climate indicators.9

Instead of a one-dimensional indicator of “goodness of investment climate”, we

shall offer a series of measures on the different aspects of investment climate. This

approach highlights not only the complex nature of how the investment climate affects

firms, but also emphasizes that a region can excel in some areas, while lagging in others.

To facilitate discussion, the broad array of indicators is grouped into seven categories.

The final selection of the indicators presented here is based on our empirical investigation

of the most important determinants of firm-level performance and by findings of other

researchers in the literature. In particular, we shall focus on the following areas:

integration into international markets, the pace of private sector participation, entry and

9 In this study the five regions included are among some of the stronger performers so that the differences would be even starker should less industrialized or integrated regions be included in the comparison.

Page 47: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

47

exit barrier for firms, financial services, government efficiency, labor market flexibility,

and human capital and technology.

The measurements of the investment climate are based on a new survey of

Chinese firms. With the collaboration of the Enterprise Survey Organization (ESO) of

Chinese National Bureau of Statistics, the World Bank surveyed 1500 firms in 2001 and

2002 in five cities: Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Guangzhou, and Chengdu. The survey

asks in-depth objective questions related to firm performance, production, labor,

governance, financing and technology. Rather than asking subjective questions on how

much of a problem something is perceived to be, objective quantitative data is collected.

Thus, instead of asking if red tape is an obstacle, managers are asked the amount of time

they spend with officials to meet regulation requirements. Or, rather than asking if labor

laws are restrictive, information is gathered on the share of temporary workers and the

extent to which firms have excess workers. (For more details, see the data appendix.)

This rich database provides information over three years, with large variations both in

performance over time and the investment climate across firms and regions.

After presenting the regional variations in the investment climate, the goal of the

second half of the paper is to answer the following questions: Do investment climate

indicators affect firm-level performance? If so, how important are they? How much can

we expect the cities to gain from improving their investment climate? To answer the first

question, we conduct empirical analysis relating firm-level performance (both technical

efficiency and dynamic aspects such as sales growth and investment rate) to indicators of

investment climate. To answer the second and third questions, we conduct some counter-

factual exercises, allowing cities to achieve the investment climate levels of better

Page 48: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

48

performing cities and asking how much the typical firm in the city would gain in terms of

investment, sales growth or productivity. These exercises should be treated with some

caution; for some cities, the hypothetical improvements are substantial. The exact

predictions of the extent of benefits are less significant than the general magnitude of

potential gains and the priorities given to the different dimensions of the investment

climate.

3.2. Regional Variations in Investment Climate

The survey has a rich set of measures that could be included in this analysis. We

have restricted the presentation to those measures that were the most significant

determinants of firm performance. In our discussion of investment climate we have

usefully classified a larger list of indicators into the following categories:

1. international integration;

2. pace of private sector participation;

3. domestic entry and exit barriers for firms;

4. labor market flexibility;

5. skills and technology endowment

6. the working of financial markets;

7. government effectiveness of regulation (include physical infra);

We shall discuss how we go about measuring each category, and how the five cities differ

in these aspects.

Page 49: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

49

1. International Integration

As noted in the earlier chapters, there is general consensus that greater openness

to international markets facilitates growth. This is true not just in the macroeconomic

level but is confirmed with micro-evidence. Many firm-level studies have found that

firms with foreign partners, firms that participate in international markets and those

facing greater import competition are more productive – particularly in developing

countries.10 Foreign entry encourages technological and managerial know-how transfers

and helps integrate the domestic market with the international market. A higher

proportion of market share accounted for by imports also puts greater pressure on

domestic competitors to improve their productivity and expands the range of available

inputs for use in domestic production. Thus a friendly investment climate would

encourage foreign entry and openness to foreign made goods.

Three measures are used here to capture the extent of international integration.

The first measures the extent of foreign ownership. It is the share of total ownership

accounted for by foreigners and is a clear indicator of the presence of foreign capital.

However, it has long been recognized that the potential for spillovers is often greater if

foreigners partner with local firms rather than enter with a wholly owned subsidiary. The

second indicator is thus the share of firms in each city that report having a foreign

partner. This partnership does often take the form of a joint venture, but this measure has

the advantage of including other types of significant collaborations beyond ownership,

including joint research and development, training and marketing.

10 For a more detailed discussions, see: Roberts and Tybout, 1996, Clerides, Lach and Tybout, 1998, Hallward-Driemeier, Iarossi, and Sokoloff, 2002, Pavcnik, 2000.

Page 50: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

50

The inter-city comparison on international integration is featured in figure 3.1.

Figure 3.1 Difference in international integration

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4Share of foreign ownershipShare of firms with foreign partShare of import in the product market

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Shanghai Tianjin

The front runners on international integration are Shanghai and Guangzhou. In

Shanghai, almost 40 percent of firms have foreign partners and foreign ownership

accounts for almost a third of the value of surveyed firms in that city. Guangzhou has

roughly 28 percent of firms having foreign partners, although overall foreign ownership

is higher, at 35 percent. Beijing and Tianjin are in the middle of the pack. Chengdu, the

only inland city in our sample, not surprisingly, is the laggard, with only 10 percent of

firms having foreign partners and an even lower share of foreign ownership.

The third indicator from the CICS is the market share of the main product of the

surveyed firm accounted for by imports. The higher the import share, the greater is the

exposure to international competition. Based on this measure, Guangzhou and Shanghai

have greater exposure to international competition, with the market shares accounted for

Page 51: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

51

by imports being 11.7 and 8.8 percent, respectively. Chengdu and Tianjin have lower

openness scores, with their shares being 5.9 percent and 7.4 percent.

2. Private sector participation

In conjunction with increased competition from international sources, China has

allowed greater private sector participation domestically. As private ownership has

increased in China, growth and productivity have accelerated. Without a soft budget

constraint or guaranteed sales, private firms face greater incentives to innovate and to

respond to market signals. In the CICS sample, the private firms have significantly

higher productivity levels and investment rates than the state-owned ones. Competition

among privately owned firms is also more likely to be on a level playing field, with

resources flowing to the most productive users. SOEs can continue to operate despite

their lower efficiency due to preferential access to finance and the possibilities of bailouts

– thereby taking up resources and distorting competition among firms. Cities with strong

private participation are likely to be more dynamic and to bolster the investment climate.

In measuring the extent of private sector participation, the CICS differentiates

between three types of private owners: managerial ownership, private individual

ownership, and foreign ownership. Figure 3.2 would focus on all three types of private

ownership.

Page 52: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

52

Share of non-managerial private

0

0.2

0.4

0.6Share of managerial ownership

Share of foreign ownershipThree types combined

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Shanghai Tianjin

Figure 3.2 Difference in private ownership

The foreign ownership share is repeated from the previous figure, to illustrate the

importance of the role foreigners have played in increasing the private participation in

these cities and to highlight the complementary nature of this and previous categories of

the investment climate. Including all three types of private ownership also allows for a

test if there are significant differences between them – or whether the real difference is

between private ownership and government ownership.

Figure 3.2 depicts the distribution of private ownership among the cities. To

facilitate interpretation, the last bar sums up the total share of private ownership.

Guangzhou is the front runner in terms of private sector participation, followed by

Tianjin and Chengdu. Shanghai is the laggard. The distribution among the alternative

types of private sector participation differs, however. Chengdu is characterized by the

largest managerial ownership and non-managerial private ownership, but the lowest share

of foreign ownership. In fact, the deficit in foreign ownership for firms in Chengdu is so

Page 53: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

53

large as to completely offset the surplus in the other two types of private ownership. The

case of Chengdu highlights the potential problems faced by inland firms: the difficulty to

attract foreign participation. Shanghai is characterized by a reasonable level of foreign

ownership (ranked just behind Guangzhou) but a lackluster pace in domestic private

ownership.

3. Domestic entry and exit barrier

Both policy makers and economic researchers have noted the strong domestic

barriers to entry and exit in China. The State Development Planning Commission, for

instance, has organized an ad hoc team to study this issue, and published a book on this

topic in 2000 (SPC, 2000). The World Bank country team has also called for further

study on regional protectionism. Here we thus try to measure the entry and exit barriers

in the five cities from a number of perspectives.

The first measure of regional entry and exit barriers is a measure of border effects

constructed recently by Poncet (Poncet, 2002). She directly analyzes trade in goods to

obtain estimates of “border effects”—how much provincial borders deter trade.

Comparing trade across borders with trade within borders -- taking into account factors

like transport costs and geographical barriers – she calculates what would be the

necessary tariff rate to produce the same pattern of trade if all the markets were perfectly

integrated. (Gilley, 2001). The imputed tariff level is the “border effects”. Thus, the

higher the border effect, the greater the trade barrier erected by a province. For the year

1997, the most recent year for which the data is available, this measure (called “regional

protection” in figure 3.2) was highest for Chengdu, followed by Beijing, Tianjin and

Page 54: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

54

Shanghai.11 The least protectionist was Guangzhou, at less than half the level of

Chengdu.

Three other measures of entry and exit barrier come from the CICS. First, CICS

inquires about the market share claimed by the main product of the surveyed firm. This

is not a perfect measure of market competition because, on one hand, a higher figure

could mean a higher entry barrier, and on the other hand, it could imply more efficient

firms in that location. Figure 3.3 suggests that Guangzhou firms have the lowest market

share, at 7.9 percent, followed by Chengdu at 11.1 percent. The firms claimed the

highest market share in Beijing (16.7 percent) and Shanghai (16.5 percent).

Figure 3.3 Difference in entry and exit barriers

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Shanghai Tianjin

Regional protectionMarket shareExcess capacityShare of subcontracting

0

0.1

0.2

A second measure is based on the share of costs used to hire subcontracting firms. The

more flexible the market, the less need there is for firms to keep all their activities in- 11 We assume the level of protection is the same within a province.

Page 55: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

55

house. The availability of sub-contractors indicates a greater ease of entry for firms, a

greater specialization of production and would be expected to be an attractive feature of a

location. Shanghai leads on this measure, following by Beijing. Chengdu has a

significantly lower share of subcontracting services.

Finally, a nice measure of exit barriers is provided by the excess capacity of the

firm reported in the CICS. Firms often continue to operate with a certain amount of

excess capacity given adjustment costs associated with investment and the hiring and

firing of workers. However, larger shares of excess capacity indicate that the barriers to

exit can be substantial. Chengdu and Beijng top this measure of exit barriers, with their

ratios being 22.1 and 20.5 percent, respectively. Guangzhou and Shanghai are again

better, at 16.9 and 17.2 percent, respectively. Thus the overall impression is that

Guangzhou and Shanghai have lower entry and exit barrier, and Chengdu has the higher

barriers, with Beijing and Tianjin in between.

4. Labor Flexibility

Besides product markets, an important ingredient for a healthy investment climate

is the functioning of labor market. A healthy labor market is characterized by flexibility,

including low exit barriers. While these variables could have been incorporated into the

general category on entry and exit barriers, the particular importance of such features in

the labor market warranted its own category. Exit barriers shows up in forms such as

specific requirement not to fire workers, government interference in shedding redundant

workers, rules or regulations that restrict hiring seasonal and contract workers, or

requirements on firms to provide insurance, medical care and pensions. The CICS data

Page 56: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

56

provide two measures of exit barriers for labor. The first is the share of workers or staff

that is non-permanent. Since it is much easier to shed temporary or seasonal workers, a

higher share of non-permanent staff represents a lower exit barrier.12 In addition, firms

were asked directly whether they were overstaffed – i.e. what share of their workforce

would they consider redundant if there were no penalties associated with laying-off

workers. Thus, more flexible labor markets would be characterized by higher non-

permanent labor ratios and lower overstaffing-ratios.

Figure 3.4 shows clearly that Guangzhou leads other cities in terms of reducing

exit barrier in the labor market. Firms in Guangzhou on average only have 6 percent of

redundant workers, yet almost 21 percent of non-permanent workers. Shanghai likely

ranks the second. Its share of non-permanent workers is 14 percent, slightly lower than

that of Tianjin (14.7 percent), but its overstaffing ratio is only 7.5 percent, more than 10

percentage points lower than the other three cities. Chengdu is the laggard, with 12

percent of workers being non-permanent, yet a overstaffing ratio of 20 percent. Beijing

and Tianjin are once again in the middle of the pack.

12 It is true that in some instances the reliance on a large temporary staff is an indication of high exit barriers (i.e. firms hire temporary workers as a way to get around the burdens imposed by regulations). However, we argue that given the nature of China’s migratory labor and residency requirements, allowing the hiring of temporary workers is actually a sign of greater flexibility and a loosening of labor requirements.

Page 57: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

57

Figure 3.4 Differences in labor flexibilityOver-staffing ratioNon-permanent labor

0

0.1

0.2

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Shanghai Tianjin

5. Skills and technology

Investors are likely to be pulled to locations with abundant skilled workers and

advanced technology. To gauge the skill and technology position of each city, we use

CICS information to construct three indicators. The first is the share of workers with

formal training. Training enhances workers’ skills and productivity. The second is an

index of worker quality, which increases with the shares and schooling levels of technical

personnel and of managerial and sales personnel. We focus on the technical and

managerial (and sales) personnel because they are likely more skilled than the other types

of employees (such as production workers and auxiliary workers). A final measure is an

index of R&D intensity, which increases in R&D expenditure per worker, the ratio of

R&D staff (in all the staff), and an indicator of the extent of reliance of outsider R&D

services.

Page 58: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

58

Figure 3.5 suggests that no city is an unambiguous leader in all departments.

Indeed, Shanghai, Beijing and Chengdu appear to be significantly stronger in terms of

skills and technology endowment. Firms in the Shanghai sample have 57 percent of their

workers trained (ranking behind Guangzhou), rank the highest in staff quality, and second

highest in R&D intensity. Firms in Chengdu have roughly half of their workers trained,

ranks the third in staff quality, but the highest in R&D intensity. Firms in Beijing have

48 percent of their workers trained (ranking the fourth), the second best ranking in staff

quality, and the third best ranking in R&D intensity. In contrast, although Guangzhou

has the highest ratio of trained staff, it ranks lowest in staff quality and R&D intensity.

This may reflect the high ratio of migrants in Guangzhou’s workers, and the low-tech

nature of firms in Guangzhou. Tianjin features the lowest ratio of trained staff, the

lowest intensity of R&D, and the second lowest quality of staff.

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8Share of workers trainedIndex of quality of staffR&D intensity index

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Shanghai Tianjin

Figure 3.5 Difference in skills and technology

Page 59: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

59

6. Financial services

A healthy financial service industry is vital for firms. It frees firms from financial

constraints, allowing firms short of internal funds to expand beyond their own capacity.

In the CICS data we have a number of indicators about the ability to obtain financial

services including funding. For a parsimonious specification of how financial services

differ among regions we constructed a index of availability of financial services. The

index increases in the availability of external financing such as the availability of foreign

loans, bank financing, parent company financing and the availability and amount of trade

credit. The index decreases with the extent that the firm has to rely on own retained

earning or own family financing.(See appendix 1 for more information on the

construction of this index). Figure 3.6 shows that Shanghai is clearly the leader in

availability of financing. Guangzhou is second. Beijing and Chengdu are in the middle,

while Tianjin lags behind.

0

1

2

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Shanghai Tianjin

Figure 3.6 Differences in financing availability

Page 60: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

60

7. Government effectiveness

Over the last decade, economists have increasingly paid attention to the role that

the state plays for a healthy economy. Indeed, an economy is expected to work much

better when the state sets up a level playing field, when bureaucrats are more interested in

enforcing efficient rules rather than maximizing bureaucratic budgets, when the

government provides sufficient resources to set up an environment characterized by an

adequate supply of public goods (i.e., public safety, infrastructure) (Shleifer and Vishny,

1999).

To measure the effectiveness with which the government provides public goods

and plays the role of “helping hand” rather than “grabbing hand”, we construct three

measures. The first is a measure of informal payment, constructed as the share of sales

spent on gift or bribes to government and regulatory agencies (or called “informal

payment”). The second measure captures the costs to the firm in terms of the share of

time that senior managers spend receiving government officials. This reflects the

cumbersome nature of meeting extensive regulatory requirements, can be a further

indication of corruption and represents an important opportunity cost on the part of

CEOs. The third measure is the share of shipments lost due to theft, breakage or spoilage.

Since pubic safety and ports are largely the business of the government. The losses

occurred should reflect the lack of efficiency associated with government services and

poor infrastructure.

Figure 3.7 suggests that the relative ranking for the three indicators differs a lot

among the cities. For instance, cities with relatively lower informal payments to

government regulators are Shanghai, Guangzhou and Beijing. Yet if you look at

Page 61: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

61

managerial share of time on regulation requirements, the lowest are Chengdu,

Guangzhou, and Shanghai. When examining the share of shipment loss due to theft and

other factors, the ranking differs again from the other two. Various aspects of

government efficiency thus do not necessarily agree with one another. Not surprisingly,

we shall later find that for these five cities inter-city performance differences do not

strongly hinge on measures of government efficiency.

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

Figure 3.7 Difference in government effectiveness

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Shanghai Tianjin

Payment to regulators as percent of sales x 100Share of managerial time on regulationsShare of loss due to theft x 10

A brief summary: A score card for the cities

Table 3.1 present a summary table about the key ingredients of investment

climates. It is apparent that Guangzhou and Shanghai are clear leaders in investment

climate, while Chengdu and Tianjin lags the farthest. Beijing is in the middle of the

pack. We next investigate whether the relative rankings in terms of investment climate

carry through to economic performance, what are the key investment climate ingredients,

Page 62: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

62

and what are the expected gains for each city if it achieves high standards in investment

climate.

Table 3.1 Cities vying for the best investment climate: a report card

Shanghai TianjinGuangzhouSecond

Best

Best

Second

Tied at the middle, but with worst staff quality

Best

Low in informal payment & regulatory burden, high in shipment loss.

International integration

Fourth

Domestic entry and exit barrier

Third

Labor flexibility Tied at third

Financial services

Worst

Skills and technology

Worst: worst in both training and R&D intensity

Private sector participation

Tied at second: a high share of foreign ownership

Government efficiency

Second

Second

Best

Best

Worst

Low shipment loss & informal payment, middle in regulatory burden

Relatively high informal payment; middle in regulatory burden and shipment loss

ChengduWorst

Worst

Worst

Fourth

Tied at the middle

Tied at second: a high share of outside private ownerships

High informal payment; middle in shipment losses, low regulatory burden

Beijing Third

Fourth

Tied at third

Third

Tied at the middle: good staff quality, but little training of staff

Third

middle in informal payment, but bureaucratic, with significant shipment losses

3.3. Impact of the Investment Climate

To investigate whether the various ingredients of investment climate really

matter, we investigate how they affect some common measures of economic

performance. In particular, we focus on three variables: sales growth, investment rates,

and productivity. The first is the annual growth rate of sales. The investment rate is

measured as new investment over the original value of fixed assets. Productivity is

measured as the relative efficiency in generating value added holding constant the

Page 63: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

63

amount of labor (as measured by the number of employees) and capital stock (see the

technical appendix for the details of estimating total factor productivity, abbreviated as

productivity). Sales growth and investment rate measure the dynamism of the firms, the

pace at which their businesses are expanding, and productivity measures the relative

efficiency of firms in generating value.

The key questions that this section aims to answer are: Does the investment

climate matter? If so, what are some of the key ingredients? What magnitudes of gains

are expected with a significant improvement in investment climate? What are some of

the key areas that each city can work on to expect important gains in performance?

In what follows, we shall first briefly introduce the background of our

methodology. Then we conduct counterfactual exercises to see how firms in each city

would perform if they could operate in a better environment.

Methodology

Our exercises are based on the empirical investigation of how the three

performance measures (i.e., sales growth, investment rate, and productivity) are affected

by the investment climate, holding constant some basic characteristics such as macro

shocks, industry affiliations, firm size (including both the number of employees and

initial revenue). The set of investment climate indicators presented here reflect those

elements that: (1) the government can do something about, (2) are widely viewed as

important, and (3) have important explanatory power.

Page 64: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

64

The statistical relationship between the performance measures and investment

climate are reported in the technical appendix. The main findings can be summarized

succinctly as follows:

1. Overall, international integration affects performance significantly. Firms with a

foreign partner or that have foreign ownership have significantly higher growth

rates and productivity levels. However, somewhat surprisingly, the effect on

investment rates is less. This may be due to foreign owned firms generally being

newer (the average age of a foreign owned firm is 5 years versus 15 years for

those without foreign ownership) so that they are already operating with more up

to date equipment.

2. The development of the private sector also improves firm performance. Including

all three types of private ownership allows for a test of whether there is a

difference in the type of private ownership for firm performance. While

managerial owned and foreign owned have the strongest association with better

performance, the differences between any one of the private ownership measures

and SOEs dwarves the differences between the three ownership types. This

finding echoes another that is based on an entirely different data set of Chinese

firms (Xu, Zhu, and Lin, 2002).

3. The reduction of entry and exit barriers explains a significant part of all three firm

performance measures, although the importance of the specific sub-indicators

varies across them. For instance, firms in provinces with higher protectionism

have lower investment rate and productivity. Firms with higher excess capacity

had lower sales growth rate and productivity. Firms with higher market share also

Page 65: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

65

have better performance when being judged by all three measures, supporting the

idea that market share is not a proxy for entry barriers but rather greater

efficiency. Finally, a higher share of sub-contracting contributes to higher sales

growth, investment, and productivity.

4. Labor market flexibility can have important consequences, particularly for

productivity. The percent of non-permanent (or flexibly-deployed) workers is

positively associated with all three performance measures, while the percent of

overmanning is negatively correlated with productivity.

5. Skills and technology availability contribute in positive ways. The training of

employees is associated with better performance based on all three measures; so is

a higher quality of employees. Research and development intensity improves

firms’ investment rate and productivity.

6. The availability of financial services has an impact. When firms have better

access to financial services, their sales growth rates and productivity are both

higher. This finding is consistent with cross-country evidence that financial

development is associated with a significantly higher growth rate of GDP (King

and Levine, 1993).

7. There is also some evidence that governance affects performance. Firms in a city

characterized by a higher level of informal payments had lower sales growth and

productivity. Moreover, managerial time spent dealing with regulatory officials

have a negative effect on sales growth.

Page 66: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

66

A number of caveats should be kept in mind in interpreting these findings. First,

these relationships indicate correlation, not causation. For a number of measures there is

potential endogeneity problems (e.g. productive firms could have better access to finance

and not just that better access to finance boosts productivity) that can bias coefficients

upward. On the other hand, there is likely collinearity between a number of the different

investment climate indicators that could reduce the significance of some variables. Also,

the cities included in the study are all relatively strong performers within China. A

number of potential bottlenecks in other regions may not appear as constraining in this

study. Overall, that the results are robust across the different performance measures

bolsters confidence in the findings. The direction and general magnitude of the findings

are informative, but too much emphasis should not be placed on the exact coefficients.

What remains to be seen are what the key determinants of inter-regional

variations in firm performance are, and what is the potential gain that a city can expect

from improving its investment climate. To these ends, we conduct a counterfactual

analysis. First, we identify a leading city for each performance measure. For sales

growth and investment, Guangzhou is the leading city, while for productivity, Shanghai

is the leading city. The leading city is taken as the benchmark and compared to each of

the other remaining cities. The exercise is to see how the comparator’s performance

would change if its investment climate indicators were at the levels of those of the

leading city. We can then infer the contribution of each category of investment climate to

the performance differential between the two cities.

It should be noted that the leading city on performance does not necessarily have

the leading investment climate indicators in all categories – so for some dimensions in

Page 67: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

67

some cities the counterfactual could actually detract from performance. The

counterfactual aims to be realistic; that the level of reform that is hypothesized is within

the reach of the cities being studied. It allows for each category of investment climate

indicators to be improved individually – as well as indicating the overall impact if all

indicators were changed simultaneously. This latter exercise is clearly more of an upper-

bound estimate, but remains within plausible bounds.13

Investment Rate

Guangzhou is the leading city in terms of investment, with a rate of 19.4 percent.

The counterfactual compares other cities with Guangzhou, reporting how their

investment rates would change if each category of investment climate indicators were

changed to the level enjoyed in Guangzhou. Figure 3.8 presents the average level of

actual investment rates. They are 15.9 percent for Beijing, 15.6 percent for Shanghai,

14.2 percent for Chengdu, and 13.6 percent for Tianjin. The second bar then reports the

potential investment rates each city could experience if all its investment climate

indicators were at the same level as Guanzhou’s. Thus Tianjin and Chengdu, the cities

with the lowest investment rates would experience the greatest improvements to the

investment climates and would reap the greatest increase in investment. Under this

counterfactual, Beijing would marginally have the highest overall potential rate of

investment.

13 To the extent that this is the local maximum among only the five cities, there could be even greater potential to improve for our sample cities.

Page 68: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

68

Figure 3.8 Investment rate: actual versus realistic potential

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2Investment ratePotential investment rate

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Tianjin

Figure 3.9 looks at the contribution made by each category of investment climate

indicators individually. Overall, lowering entry and exit barriers, greater international

integration and better skills and technology are the most important sources for reform to

boost investment rates. However, there are clear differences across cities.

For Beijing, the overall increase in investment would be about 3.4 percentage

points. Entry and Exit plus labor market flexibility are the two most important sources of

gain. These are followed by skills and technology plus international integration. The

effects of greater private participation’s contribution is marginal. For Chengdu, the total

contributions are larger, an increase in investment rate by 3.9 percentage points.

Improvements in entry and exit barriers alone would increase investment by almost 3

percent. Greater integration and labor flexibility would together increase investment a

further 2 percent. One striking feature is that changing private sector participation would

actually lower investment rates. Referring back to figure 3.1 explains why. While

Page 69: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

69

Chengdu overall ranks in the middle with regard to private participation, its composition

is heavily skewed away from foreign private ownership (the category that enters in

international integration.) Thus, relative to Guangzhou its non-managerial and

managerial domestic private participation is higher – lowering the levels to those of

Guangzhou would hurt Chengdu.

Figure 3.9 Investment rate gains with Guangzhou’s IC

Beijing Chengdu Shanghai Tianjin

International integrationEntry and exitLabor market flexibilityFinanceSkills and technologyPrivate sector participation

-0.02

0

0.02

0.04

The improvement in Shanghai’s investment rate is relatively small (2.5

percentage points). This is largely due to Shanghai’s investment climate indicators not

differing too substantially from the benchmark of Guangzhou. On those dimensions

where Shanghai is stronger, the change due to the counterfactual actually serves to reduce

the measured potential investment rate. Four areas where improvement would assist

Shanghai are greater private sector participation, international integration, labor market

flexibility, and lower entry and exit barriers.

Page 70: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

70

Tianjin has the lowest investment rate among the five cities and sees the largest

improvement (4.1 percentage points) coming from all indicator categories. The dominant

source of improvement comes from better skills and technology. Lower entry and exit

barriers, including those in the labor market, are also important.

Sales Growth

The four other cities trail Guangzhou significantly in sales growth rate. The

average sales growth rates, from the highest to the lowest, are 30 percent for Guangzhou,

22 percent for Beijing, 21.8 percent for Shanghai, 20.3 percent for Chengdu, and 18

percent for Tianjin (see figure 3.10).

Figure 3.10 Sales growth: actual versus realistic potential

0

0.1

0.2

0.3Sales growthPotential sales growth

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Tianjin

The counterfactual exercise would raise sales growth the most in Chengdu, an

increase of 10.7 percentage points. Beijing and Tiajin would realize increased growth of

around 8 percentage points, while Shanghai would only gain about 2 percentage points.

Page 71: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

71

The difference is not so much due to Shanghai having that much higher a sales growth

rate (it doesn’t), but that the improvements in the investment climate proposed in the

counterfactual are not that large.

Figure 3.11 Sales growth gain with Guangzhou’s IC

-0.05

0

0.05

0.1International integrationEntry and exitLabor market flexibilityFinanceSkills and technologyPrivate sector participation

Beijing Chengdu Shanghai Tianjin

As illustrated in figure 3.11, the lagging of Beijing behind Guangzhou in sales

growth can largely be explained by the lower degree of international integration,

followed by labor market flexibility, skills and technology, and entry and exit barrier.

Using the assumptions of the counterfactual, growth could be increased by as much as 8

percentage points.. As with Beijing, greater international integration is also the largest

source of increased sales growth for Chengdu. However, in this case the expected benefit

is 7 percent points of growth rather than 2.5 points for Beijing as the gap in integration

measures is considerably larger for Chengdu than for Beijing. Entry and exit barriers are

the next most important factor for Chengdu’s growth performance. As with the

Page 72: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

72

investment counterfactual, Chengdu has a negative contribution from changing its private

sector participation.

For Shanghai, there is only a very little gained in terms of increased growth. This

is largely due to the relative strength of Shanghai’s own investment climate indicators;

changing the indicators to the levels realized by Guangzhou does introduce some

improvements, but in other areas it weakens Shanghai’s position. Thus, greater private

participation, international integration, and labor flexibility would increase growth, but it

is almost offset by the greater entry barriers and reduced access to finance. Under the

assumptions of the analysis, if only those categories that improved were included,

Shanghai could realize higher growth on the order of 4 to 5 percent.

For Tianjin the most important source of improvement in sales growth is skills

and technology, followed by integration, finance and labor flexibility. Private

participation has virtually no effect.

Page 73: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

73

Productivity

Figure 3.12 Productivity: actual versus realistic potential

ProductivityPotential productivity

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Tianjin-0.4

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

For productivity, the leading city used in the counterfactual is now Shanghai. Its

performance on this dimension is particularly impressive; the productivity gap appears to

be quite large. The average productivity of Shanghai exceeds those of Beijing, Chengdu,

and Tianjin firms by a significant margin. Tianjin appears to have the lowest

productivity, with Beijing and Chengdu immediately following, and the differences

between Beijing and Chengdu are quite small. Firms in Guangzhou have the second

highest level of productivity, not too far behind Shanghai. Plotting the relative

productivity levels on figure 3.12, the y-intercept is at the overall average level of

productivity (as TFP is an index, centered on zero). Thus, positive bars indicate above

average performance and negative bars indicate below average performance. Bringing

the investment climate indicators to the level of Shanghai’s would lead to substantial

Page 74: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

74

productivity gains for Beijing and Tianjin, but the city that would experience by far the

largest gain would be Chengdu. Guangzhou, on the other hand, would experience

virtually no change in productivity as it is close to Shanghai in overall investment climate

(and in productivity). Thus the lagging of productivity of Guangzhou behind Shanghai is

largely explained by non-investment-climate factors such as industry composition.

Figure 3.13 Productivity gains with Shanghai’s IC

-0.1

0.1

0.2

International integrationEntry and exitLabor market flexibilityFinanceSkills and technologyPrivate sector participation

Beijing Chengdu Guangzhou Tianjin

0

Figure 3.13 sheds light on why the three cities trail Shanghai so far in productivity. For

Beijing, entry and exit barriers, integration, skill and technology, and finance are all

important. Overall, its productivity would increase almost 26 percent,14 with integration

and entry and exit each explaining increases of 8 percent.

For Chengdu, greater integration and the removal of entry barriers is impressive,

improving productivity each by roughly 20 percent. Labor market flexibility, finance,

14 That is, 123.0 −e

Page 75: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

75

and skills and technology are important in similar magnitudes, each contributing another

3 percent to productivity gains. Private participation shows up as a negative in the

counterfactual because Chengdu has higher private participation than Shanghai to begin

with so that becoming more like Shanghai in this dimension is a negative. The total

expected gain in productivity could be 56 percent.

Guangzhou overall would not gain anything in terms of improved productivity by

being more like Shanghai. On the one hand, improvements would be observed with

Shanghai’s skills and technology and access to finance. On other hand, these gains are

offset because Guangzhou was found to be better than Shanghai in the important areas of

entry and exit barriers, labor market flexibility, and private sector participation.

The improvement in skills and technology would boost Tianjin’s productivity by

more than 10 percent. Integration is the second largest source of improvements, with

finance and entry and exit barriers the next most important sources. Overall, Tianjin

could improve productivity by 31 percent by reforms that brought its investment climate

to the level experienced in Shanghai.

3.4. Policy Implications

We have focused on three tasks: (1) constructing measures of the investment

climate; (2) demonstrating that the investment climate matters for sales growth,

investment rates, and productivity; (3) investigating the reasons for performance

differences among cities, the contribution of each category of the investment climate, and

the performance potential from improved investment climate indicators. What policy

implications can we draw from this investigation?

Page 76: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

76

The first policy implication is that local government can improve regional growth

potential significantly. We have demonstrated that the five large cities differ greatly in

the three performance measures, and that the growth potential of improving the

investment climate could be huge. For instance, sales growth could increase up to ten

percentage points and productivity could increase by a half from improving the key

investment climate obstacles for cities such as Chengdu or Tianjin – and keep in mind

that these cities are likely among the better performers in the larger scheme of China’s

numerous cities. Another important implication from the regional variations is that

market segmentation in China is likely quite severe, otherwise free flow of resources

among regions would narrow down the differences.

Starting from a longer initial list, the empirical investigation found the following

categories of investment climate to be especially important: international integration,

private sector participation, entry and exit barriers, skills and technology, labor market

flexibility, and financial services.15 Within the category of labor market flexibility, we

find that it is particularly important to create conditions to allow for flexible labor force.

Another interesting finding is that cities have their distinct advantages and

disadvantages:

�� Shanghai shines as the most productive city and is clearly the center of higher

value added activities. The city is characterized by a strong degree of international

integration as viewed by the share of firms with foreign partners, although overall

15 Government efficiency was included in the analysis, but the significance of the effects were small enough that they were excluded from the counterfactual graphs and discussion. The lack of significant differences in performance on these measures across cities accounts for why this category is not particularly relevant in understanding differences within China – it does not imply that the topic is not important looking at China vis a vis other countries, or potentially if the regional coverage within China were extended.

Page 77: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

77

foreign ownership and import penetration are lower than in Guangzhou. It also

has the strongest financial services, and has good entry and exit conditions and

labor market flexibility. Shanghai’s top issue for reform would be to improve its

domestic private sector participation. Secondary areas for reform would be to

encourage greater foreign ownership and import penetration to boost its sales and

investment, as well as greater flexibility in the use of temporary workers.

�� While Guangzhou does not produce as sophisticated products at Shanghai, it

nonetheless uses its advantages to claim the highest sales growth rate and investment

rate. It has the most flexible labor market, fluidity of entry and exit, government

efficiency, and private sector participation. Its international integration is also

reasonably strong. For Guangzhou, upgrading skills and finance would be the top

issues to consider for reform.

�� Beijing is largely in the middle of the pack, with no especially strong advantage or

disadvantage. It could benefit from some focus on greater labor market flexibility,

entry and exit, and international integration.

�� Tianjin is good in private sector participation, and in the middle of the pack in terms

of entry and exit fluidity and labor market flexibility. For Tianjin, reforms in skills

and technology should dominate the reform agenda, with improvements in

international integration and government efficiency as secondary areas of focus.

�� Chengdu, the only inland city we have surveyed, lags the farthest in most

performance measures as well as in investment climate indicators. However, it does

have a good level of private sector participation, with reasonable skills and especially

Page 78: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

78

technology. For Chengdu, the top priorities for reform should be to foster greater

international integration and to lower entry and exit barriers.

While we have answered some of the questions posed earlier, it is important to

keep in mind some of the limitations associated with the survey work and the questions

that it can address. First of all, the results need to be treated with some caution. The

estimates should be seen as indicative of the relative importance of different dimensions

of the investment climate rather than exact predictors of how performance will change

should reforms be enacted. Still, the consistency in the regression results across the three

performance measures and that the levels considered in the counterfactual are based on

those actually achieved by the leading city, reinforces the credibility of this analysis.

Second, some dimensions of the investment climate did not receive much attention in this

study. This could be due to all cities having relatively strong performances on that

dimension or because there was little variation across cities for that measure. Given the

nature of the counterfactual, if all cities receive close to the same measure on an

indicator, the scope for improvement in the exercise is limited. Thus, physical

infrastructure does not get much attention here; all five have good indicators, certainly

against the rest of the country. Likewise, the government efficiency indicators do not

vary as much across cities, leaving little scope of its importance to be demonstrated in the

counterfactual analysis. The lack of attention on these issues here does not imply that

they are not potentially constraining factors for other areas within China or for explaining

China’s performance relative to other countries. Third, some important consequences of

the investment climate cannot be captured by survey data. For instance, the survey

Page 79: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

79

cannot address some issues surrounding entry and exit as firms that did not enter the

market or those firms that did exit could not be included in the sample. Fourth, there are

no doubt other important aspects that are left out in the categories of our investment

climate. One example is the effect of tax rates and special incentives – topics that are

certainly of interest but were deemed too difficult to get reliable responses on. Finally,

the current survey does not represent enough variation for inland cities. Future surveys

covering diverse inland locations are keenly needed, and currently under discussion

between the Enterprise Survey Organization and the World Bank team.

Page 80: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

80

Technical Appendix

Data

The data on investment climate are based on two surveys that the World Bank

conducted with the Enterprise Survey Organization of Chinese National Bureau of

Statistics. The first survey was done in 2001, covering 300 firms in each of five cities:

Beijing, Tianjin, Shanghai, Guangzhou, and Chengdu, for a total of 1500 firms. The

survey collected detailed information on financial statements, and different aspects of

corporate governance, financing, firm-government relationship, innovation, technology,

labor, and so on. Most quantitative questions cover the period 1997 to 2000, and most

qualitative questions cover only the time of the survey.

The second survey covers the same set of firms, with a small percentage of firms

having disappeared between the first and the second survey. The questionnaire covers

the following aspects: investment climate constraints to the establishment, infrastructure

and services, finance, labor relations, sales and supplies, business-government relations,

conflict resolution and legal environment, crime, capacity, innovation and learning.

The sample firms consist of both manufacturing and service firms. The industries

covered include: clothing and leather products (14.1 percent); electronic and

communication equipment making (12.5 percent); electronic components (14.7 percent));

household electrical goods (11 percent); auto and auto parts (14.4 percent); information

technology services (8.9 percent); communication services (4.6 percent); accounting,

auditing and nonblank financial services (7.1 percent); advertising and marketing services

(5.8 percent); business logistics services (7 percent). Within the sample, firms vary

Page 81: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

81

substantially by size and by ownership type. The samples are randomly chosen given

pre-determined distribution by city and broad industry and size strata.

Construction of TFP

The total factor productivity is estimated using a production function as follows:

iti

J

jitjKitjLijtit eKLDV εααβ ++++= �

=10 )lnln(ln (A.1.)

where itV is value added for firm i and period t. itL and itK are the number of

employees and the capital stock, respectively. The capital stock is proxied by the original

value of fixed assets, the only time-varying measure we have for capital stock. ijtD is a

dummy variable that is one if firm i is affiliated with sector j. In total we have ten

industries as mentioned above. So equation (A.1.) essentially allows sector-specific

shares of labor and capital. The total factor productivity is then constructed as the

estimate of itie ε+ , the part of value added that is not explained by capital and labor.

Regressions framework

To examine how various elements of investment climate affect performance, we estimate

the following regressions:

itiit ICXY εβββ +++= 210 (A.2)

where Y could be sales growth rates, investment rate, or total factor productivity as

constructed above. X are a set of control variables, including industry dummies (to allow

the performance to have an industry-specific mean), year dummies (to capture macro

shocks, changes in macro policies, and technological changes over time), the logarithm of

Page 82: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

82

the number of employees, and the logarithm of initial sales. The last two measures are

intended to capture things such as economies of scale or any other aspects related to scale

(market power and so on). IC is a vector of indicators related to investment climate. The

results, along with some notes concerning the construction of some of the used measured,

are reported in Table A.1.

Page 83: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

83

Table A.1. The Impact of Investment Climate

(1) Sales growth rate (2) Investment rate (3) Total factor productivityForeign ownership 0.211 0.045 0.363 (0.045)*** (0.017)*** (0.102)*** Has a foreign partner 0.045 -0.017 0.369 (0.026)* (0.010)* (0.060)*** Import share for the most -0.077 -0.025 0.231 important product of the firm (0.071) (0.026) (0.156) Index of provincial price -0.109 -0.120 -0.630 segmentation (0.141) (0.053)** (0.324)* Market share of the most 0.146 0.048 0.264 important product of the firm (0.051)*** (0.019)** (0.117)** Excess capacity ( percent) -0.272 -0.029 -0.944 (0.053)*** (0.020) (0.120)*** Subcontracting (percent) 0.228 0.119 0.462 (0.105)** (0.039)*** (0.234)** Overmanning (percent) -0.025 -0.008 -0.163 (0.019) (0.007) (0.069)** Non-permanent workers (percent) 0.168 0.102 0.662 (0.041)*** (0.015)*** (0.093)*** Share of labor with formal 0.106 0.041 0.143 training (0.023)*** (0.009)*** (0.054)*** Quality of labor staff 0.075 0.020 0.315 (0.012)*** (0.004)*** (0.026)*** Index of RD intensity 0.003 0.019 0.093 (0.011) (0.004)*** (0.023)*** Managerial ownership 0.237 0.104 0.076 (0.080)*** (0.029)*** (0.176) Private individual 0.153 0.065 0.233 ownership (0.040)*** (0.015)*** (0.090)*** Index of corruption -4.167 0.644 -32.897 (2.931) (1.043) (7.029)*** Manager’s time on meeting (percent) -0.155 -0.000 0.021 regulation requirements (0.085)* (0.032) (0.197) Shipment costs lost due to theft, -0.152 -0.067 -0.456 breakage, and spoilage (percent) (0.180) (0.067) (0.415) Index of financial services 0.027 0.001 0.039 (0.009)*** (0.003) (0.018)** Log (number of employees) 0.067 0.005 (0.011)*** (0.004) log (initial sales) -0.083 -0.009 (0.008)*** (0.003)*** Year, industry indummies yes yes yes Observations 3128 3116 2818 R-squared 0.10 0.12 0.79

Page 84: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

84

Notes.

1. *, **, *** represent statistical significance in the 10, 5, and 1 percent levels. The

model specification is ordinary least squares.

2. Sales growth rate is winsorized at 5 and 95 percentiles to make sure that the results

are not driven by outlier: that is, replaced the lowest 5th percent observations with

the 5th percentile, and the 95th to 100th percentile with the 95th percentile values. The

sales growth rate is much more skewed than other variables such as investment rate.

For investment rate, we replaced negative number and number greater than 1 with 0

or 1; only fewer than 10 observations are affected. Similarly, total factor productivity

is winsorized at 1 and 99 percentiles.

3. The construction of some measures involved the following details:

1) Percent subcontracting: assumed to be zero if the answer is not applicable.

2) Excess capacity, not asked by service firms, and is assumed to be zero given the

relatively low excess capacity and the lower need for fixed assets investment.

3) The informal payment variable is cleaned as follows. Upon examining its

distribution, we find that there are 12 observations that are clearly outliers (i.e.,

those greater than 0.07), ranging from 0.49 to 28.57. The mean of this variable is

only 0.02 (including these outliers). In empirical implementation, we drop these

outliers.

Page 85: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

85

4) The index of financial services is constructed as a principal component of the

following variables as follows:16

0.31 * share of input bought on trade credit + 0.44 * log(1+number of banks to do

business with) + 0.28 * share of loans denominated in foreign currencies + 0.50 *

the dummy variable of having overdraft facility or line of credit + 0.52 * the

dummy variable of having a bank loan + 0.004 * share of financing from parent

company or other partner companies + 0.13 * share of financing from trade credit

+ 0.13 * share of financing from “other sources” - 0.17 * share of financing from

retained earning or funds - 0.22 * share of financing from managerial families.

5) The index of staff quality is a principal component index of a number of

indicators of the human capital level of firm staff, constructed as 0.51 * share of

technical personnel + 0.36 * share of management and sales personnel + 0.54 *

average schooling of technical personnel + 0.57 * average schooling of

management and sales personnel. For graphing purposes, this variable is

renormalized by the addition of a constant, 0.50.

6) The index of RD intensity. A principal component of the following RD variables,

including log(1+ real RD expenditure per worker), percent of staff as RD staff, a

index of whether buying RD services outside. A constant of 0.50 is then re-

normalized into this index for graph presentation purposes.

Note that most of these variables are observed only for the year 2001. In our

empirical analysis we assume the prior years to have the same value.

16 For graphing purpose but without affecting any of our analyses, a constant of 1 is added to this variable.

Page 86: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

86

References

Barro, Robert. 1997. Determinants of Economic Growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.

Djankov, Simeon, Rafael La Porta, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes, and Andrei Shleifer.

2002. "The Regulation of Entry." Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117:1, pp. 1-37.

Dollar, David and Aart Kraay. 2002. "Institutions, Trade, and Growth." Carnegie

Rochester Series on Public Policy.

Emery, James, Melvin T. Spence, Louis T. Wells, and Timothy Buehrer. 2000.

"Administrative Barriers to Foreign Investment: Reducing Red Tape in Africa." The

International Finance Corporation: Washington.

Fischer, Stanley. 1993. "The Role of Macroeconomic Factors in Growth." Journal of

Monetary Economics, 32:3, pp. 485-512.

Frankel, Jeffrey and David Romer. 1999. "Does Trade Cause Growth?" American

Economic Review, 89:3, pp. 279-96.

Page 87: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

87

Friedman, Eric, Simon Johnson, Daniel Kaufmann, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton. 2000.

"Dodging the Grabbing Hand: the Determinants of Unofficial Activity in 69 Countries."

Journal of Public Economics, 76:3, pp. 459-93.

Gilley, Bruce. “Provincial Disintegration: Reaching your market is more than just a

matter of distance.” November 22, 2001.

Gordon, Roger, and Wei Li. “Taxation and Economic Growth in China,” mimeo,

University of Virginia.

Guo, Yugui. 2000. "Graduate Education Reforms and International Mobility of Scientists

and Engineers in China." Graduate Education Reform in Europe, Asia and the Americas.

National Science Foundation: Washington.

Jiang, Xiaojuan. 1997. "Chinese Government Policy Towards Science and Technology

and its Influence on the Technical Development of Industrial Enterprises," in Chinese

Technology Transfer in the 1990s: Current Experience, Historical Problems, and

International Perspectives. Charles Feinstein and Christopher Howe eds. Cheltenham:

Edward Elgar.

Kang, Sung Jin and Yasuyuki Sawada. 2000. "Financial Repression and External

Openness in an Endogenous Growth Model." Journal of International Trade and

Economic Development, 9:4, pp. 427-43.

Page 88: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

88

Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton. 1999. "Governance Matters."

World Bank Policy Research Working Papers: Washington.

Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Kraay, and Pablo Zoido-Lobaton. 2002. "Governance Matters II:

Updated Indicators for 2000/01." World Bank Policy Research Working Papers:

Washington.

King, Robert G., and Ross Levine. 1993. “Finance and Growth: Schumpeter Might be

Right,” Quarterly Economics of Economics 108(3), 717-737.

Lall, Sanjaya. 2001. "Competitiveness Indices and Developing Countries: An Economic

Evaluation of the Global Competitiveness Report." World Development, 29:9, pp. 1501-

25.

Lucas, Robert. 1986. "Principles of Fiscal and Monetary Policy." Journal of Monetary

Economics (Netherlands), 17:117-134.

McMillan, John and Christopher Woodruff. 2002. "The Central Role of Entrepreneurs in

Transition Economies." Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16:3, pp. 153-70.

Page 89: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

89

Poncet, Sandra. 2002. “Domestic Market Fragmentation and Economic Growth in

China,” mimeo, CERDI, France.

Recanatini, Francesca, Scott Wallsten, and Lixin Colin Xu. 2000. "Surveying Surveys

and Questioning Questions: Learning from World Bank Experience." World Bank Policy

Research Working Paper Series: Washington.

Rodriguez, Francisco and Dani Rodrik. 1999. "Trade Policy and Economic Growth: A

Skeptic's Guide to the Cross-National Evidence." National Bureau of Economic Research

Working Paper: Cambridge.

Romer, Paul. 1986. "Increasing Returns and Long-Run Growth." Journal of Political

Economy, 94, pp. 1002-10037.

Sachs, Jeffrey and Andrew Warner. 1995. "Economic Convergence and Economic

Policies." NBER Working Paper: Cambridge.

Saxenian, AnnaLee. 1999. "Silicon Valley's New Immigrant Entrepreneurs." The Public

Policy Institute of California: San Francisco.

Saxenian, AnnaLee and Jinn-Yuh Hsu. 2000. "The Silicon Valley-Hsinchu Connection:

Technical Communities and Industrial Upgrading."

Page 90: Improving the Investment Climate in China€¦ · Improving the Investment Climate in China David Dollar, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Anqing Shi, Scott Wallsten, Shuilin Wang, and Lixin

90

Wang, Yan and Yudong Yao. 2001. "Sources of China's Economic Growth, 1952-1999:

Incorporating Human Capital Accumulation." Washington.

World Bank. 2002. "World Development Indicators." Washington.

Young, Alwyn. 2000. "Gold Into Base Metals: Productivity Growth in the People's

Republic of China During the Reform Period." NBER Working Paper Series: Cambridge.

State Planning Commission. 2000. Strategies for Overcoming Regional Market

Segmentation and Establishing National Market, Beijing, SPC.

Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny. The Grabbing Hand, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard

University Press.

World Bank. Improving the investment climate in India, a product of the Private Sector

Development team, South Asia Region and Investment Climate Unit (PSI-DEC),

the World Bank.

Xu, Lixin Colin, Tian Zhu, and Yi-min Lin. 2002. “Politician control, Agency problems,

and Firm Performance: Evidence from a National Survey of Ownership

Restructuring in China,” mimeo, the World Bank.