inflation risk premia in the euro area and the united states · such premia display remarkably...

47
Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States Peter H¨ ordahl a and Oreste Tristani b a Bank for International Settlements b European Central Bank We use a joint model of macroeconomic and term structure dynamics to estimate inflation risk premia and inflation expec- tations in the United States and the euro area. To sharpen our estimation, we include in the information set macro data and survey data on inflation and interest rate expectations at var- ious future horizons, as well as term structure data from both nominal and index-linked bonds. Our results indicate that, over the post-2004 period when index-linked bond markets were sufficiently developed in both monetary areas, inflation risk premia across various maturi- ties had strikingly similar properties in the United States and in the euro area: their dynamics and their levels, especially over the years until mid-2011, have remained quite close to each other, even if premia appear to be subject to somewhat greater high-frequency volatility in the United States. After correcting for liquidity and inflation risk premia, long-term inflation expectations extracted from bond prices have remained remarkably stable at the peak of the finan- cial crisis and throughout the Great Recession. For the United States, we also document a downward shift in the perceived We would like to thank Greg Duffee, Marc Giannoni, Don Kim, Frank Packer, David Vestin, and seminar participants at the 27th SUERF Colloquium “New Trends in Asset Management: Exploring the Implications,” the 2008 North Amer- ican Summer Meetings of the Econometric Society, the 2009 Econometric Society European Meeting, and the 2009 Federal Reserve Bank of New York confer- ence on “Inflation-Indexed Securities and Inflation Risk Management,” as well as two anonymous referees. The opinions expressed are personal and should not be attributed to the Bank for International Settlements or the European Central Bank. Author contact: H¨ ordahl: Bank for International Settlements, Central- bahnplatz 2, CH-4002, Basel, Switzerland. E-mail: [email protected]. Tris- tani: European Central Bank, DG Research, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311, Frankfurt am Main, Germany. E-mail: [email protected]. 1

Upload: others

Post on 14-Aug-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area andthe United States∗

Peter Hordahla and Oreste TristanibaBank for International Settlements

bEuropean Central Bank

We use a joint model of macroeconomic and term structuredynamics to estimate inflation risk premia and inflation expec-tations in the United States and the euro area. To sharpen ourestimation, we include in the information set macro data andsurvey data on inflation and interest rate expectations at var-ious future horizons, as well as term structure data from bothnominal and index-linked bonds.

Our results indicate that, over the post-2004 period whenindex-linked bond markets were sufficiently developed in bothmonetary areas, inflation risk premia across various maturi-ties had strikingly similar properties in the United States andin the euro area: their dynamics and their levels, especiallyover the years until mid-2011, have remained quite close toeach other, even if premia appear to be subject to somewhatgreater high-frequency volatility in the United States.

After correcting for liquidity and inflation risk premia,long-term inflation expectations extracted from bond priceshave remained remarkably stable at the peak of the finan-cial crisis and throughout the Great Recession. For the UnitedStates, we also document a downward shift in the perceived

∗We would like to thank Greg Duffee, Marc Giannoni, Don Kim, Frank Packer,David Vestin, and seminar participants at the 27th SUERF Colloquium “NewTrends in Asset Management: Exploring the Implications,” the 2008 North Amer-ican Summer Meetings of the Econometric Society, the 2009 Econometric SocietyEuropean Meeting, and the 2009 Federal Reserve Bank of New York confer-ence on “Inflation-Indexed Securities and Inflation Risk Management,” as wellas two anonymous referees. The opinions expressed are personal and should notbe attributed to the Bank for International Settlements or the European CentralBank. Author contact: Hordahl: Bank for International Settlements, Central-bahnplatz 2, CH-4002, Basel, Switzerland. E-mail: [email protected]. Tris-tani: European Central Bank, DG Research, Kaiserstrasse 29, D-60311, Frankfurtam Main, Germany. E-mail: [email protected].

1

Page 2: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

2 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

inflation target, from approximately 3 percent until 2011 tolevels closer to 2 percent following the FOMC announcementof a numerical long-term inflation goal.

JEL Codes: E43, E44.

1. Introduction

As markets for inflation-linked securities have grown in recent years,the prices of such securities have increasingly become an importantsource of information about the state of the economy for marketparticipants as well as central banks and other public institutions.Index-linked bonds, for example, provide a means of measuring exante real yields at different maturities. In combination with nominalyields, observable from markets for nominal bonds, real rates alsoallow us to calculate a “break-even inflation rate,” i.e., the rate ofinflation for which the payoff from the two types of bonds would beequal. Because of their timeliness and simplicity, break-even infla-tion rates are seen as useful indicators of the markets’ expectations offuture inflation. Moreover, implied forward break-even inflation ratesfor distant horizons are often viewed as providing information aboutthe credibility of the central bank’s commitment to maintaining pricestability.

Break-even rates on default-free bonds do not, however, onlyreflect inflation expectations. They also include risk premia, notablyto compensate investors for inflation risk and for differential liquidityrisk in the nominal and index-linked bond markets. At the peak ofthe financial crisis in the last quarter of 2008, for example, ten-yearbreak-even rates fell markedly in both the euro area and the UnitedStates, to a minimum of 1.2 and 0.4 percentage points, respectively.Should such levels be interpreted as correct measures of long-terminflation expectations, or do they rather reflect changes in liquidityand/or inflation risk premia?

The effects of liquidity premia on the price of index-linkedbonds, and specifically their impact on break-even rates in the lastquarter of 2008, have already been studied in the literature—see,e.g., Gurkaynak, Sack, and Wright (2010) and Pflueger and Viceira(2013). In this paper we complement those studies with an analysisof investors’ inflation expectations and inflation risk premia. In so

Page 3: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 3

doing, we adopt a consistent modeling framework across the euroarea and the United States. We can therefore provide a compara-tive analysis of the main features of inflation risk premia for the twolargest world monetary areas.

Our methodology has three distinctive features. First, we modeljointly output, inflation, monetary policy, and term structuredynamics in order to analyze the relationship between inflation riskpremia and the macroeconomy. More specifically, building on Angand Piazzesi (2003), we adopt the framework developed in Hordahl,Tristani, and Vestin (2006), in which bonds are priced based onthe dynamics of the short rate obtained from the solution of aforward-looking macro model and using an essentially affine sto-chastic discount factor (see Duffie and Kan 1996; Dai and Singleton2000; Duffee 2002).

Second, we estimate the model using a broad information set,which includes macro variables, nominal and index-linked yields, andsurvey information on expectations of future inflation and future pol-icy interest rates. Macro variables allow us to identify some stylizedfacts on the cyclical features of inflation risk premia. Survey expecta-tions help us to disentangle expectations dynamics from movementsin risk premia—see Kim and Orphanides (2012).

Finally, to reduce the risk that liquidity factors might distortour estimates, we pre-filter index-linked data based on commonlyused measures of liquidity risk. Our results can therefore provideindications on inflation expectations embodied in bond prices, aftercorrecting for both inflation and liquidity risk premia.

We document that ten-year inflation expectations incorporatedin bond prices in the United States fluctuate around levels slightlybelow 3 percent up until 2011 and then move close to 2 percent overthe course of 2012. This timing is consistent with a realignment oflong-term inflation expectations following the Federal Open Mar-ket Committee (FOMC) press release on January 25, 2012, whichspecified a 2 percent long-run inflation goal. In the euro area, long-term inflation expectations remain very close to levels slightly below2 percent over the whole sample period. These results provide fur-ther support to the view that the availability of an official numericaldefinition of price stability plays an important role in anchoringlong-term inflation expectations.

Page 4: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

4 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

The estimated model-implied expected long-run inflation rateshave been characterized by somewhat greater high-frequencyvolatility in the United States than in the euro area throughout muchof our sample, consistent with the findings of Beechey, Johannsen,and Levin (2011). We find that despite the severe turbulence inbond markets during the financial crisis, long-run inflation expecta-tions remained quite stable at the peak of the crisis and throughoutthe Great Recession in both the United States and the euro area.This stability in inflation expectations during the crisis is in linewith survey-based evidence reported by Galati, Poelhekke, and Zhou(2011) for the crisis period. Financial markets therefore appear tobe similarly confident about the ability of the Federal Reserve andof the European Central Bank (ECB) to deliver a stable inflationrate over medium and long-run horizons.

Concerning inflation risk premia, the broad conclusion of ourinvestigation is that, over the post-2004 period when index-linkedbond markets were sufficiently developed in both monetary areas,such premia display remarkably similar properties in the UnitedStates and in the euro area across various maturities: their dynam-ics and their levels, especially over the years of the financial crisisuntil mid-2011, remain quite close to each other, even if U.S. pre-mia appear to be subject to greater high-frequency volatility. Over2012 and the initial months of 2013, however, there is a decoupling ofinflation risk premia, especially at three- to five-year maturities: suchpremia increase temporarily to higher levels in the United States,while they fall to slightly negative territory in the euro area. In ourmodel these developments are mainly related to differences in growthprospects.

The dynamics of inflation risk premia are positively correlatedwith actual inflation rates in both monetary areas: premia becomehigher when inflation increases. Over the past five years, they arealso somewhat procyclical and, in particular, they fall during theGreat Recession.

The rest of this paper is organized as follows. The next sectiondescribes our model, its implications for the inflation risk premium,and the econometric methodology, while section 3 discusses the dataand our methodology to correct index-linked yields for liquidity pre-mia. The empirical results are presented in section 4, where weshow our parameter estimates and their implications for term premia

Page 5: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 5

and inflation risk premia. In this section, we also relate premia totheir macroeconomic determinants and calculate premium-adjustedbreak-even inflation rates. Section 5 concludes the paper.

2. The Model

We rely on a simple economic model in the New Keynesian tradi-tion and specified directly at the aggregate level. The model includesa forward-looking Phillips curve (e.g., Galı and Gertler 1999) anda consumption-Euler equation (e.g., Fuhrer 2000). Compared withthe alternative of using a microfounded model, the advantage of thisapproach is that it imposes milder theoretical constraints. This flex-ibility allows us to provide descriptive evidence on the dynamics ofrisk premia, conditional on a widely used law of motion for macro-economic variables and on the assumption of rational expectations.The evidence, in turn, can be interpreted as a stylized fact thatsuccessful microfounded models should be able to match. The flex-ibility, however, comes at a price: in the absence of a microfoundedstochastic discount factor, we are unable to explain why certain risksappear to be priced more than others from an empirical viewpoint.

The specification of the model is similar to that in Hordahl,Tristani, and Vestin (2006), and we therefore describe it only verybriefly here. The model includes two equations which describe theevolution of inflation, πt in deviation from its mean π, and the outputgap, xt:

πt =μπ

12

12∑i=1

Et [πt+i] + (1 − μπ)3∑

i=1

δπ,iπt−i + δxxt + επt , (1)

xt =μx

12

12∑i=1

Et [xt+i] +(1 − μx)3∑

i=1

ζx,ixt−i − ζr(rt − Et [πt+1]) + εxt ,

(2)

where rt is the one-month nominal interest rate (in deviation fromits mean r), and inflation is defined as the year-on-year change inthe log-price level. The lead and lag structure reflects the fact thatwe will be using monthly data for the estimations.

In this setup, inflation can be due to demand shocks εxt , which

increase output above potential and create excess demand, and to

Page 6: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

6 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

cost-push shocks επt , which have a direct impact on prices. In addi-

tion, monetary policy can affect inflation by changing the real inter-est rate rt − Et[πt+1] or influencing expectations. Specifically, weassume that the central bank sets the nominal short rate accordingto a forward-looking rule of a type proposed by Taylor (1993):

rt = (1 − ρ) {β (Et [πt+11] − π∗t ) + γxt} + ρrt−1 + ηt, (3)

where π∗t is the perceived inflation target and ηt is a monetary pol-

icy shock. The inflation target is allowed to be time varying to allowfor some evolution in the behavior of monetary policy over time, orat least in the way monetary policy was perceived by market par-ticipants. The coefficient ρ captures interest rate smoothing, reflect-ing the central bank’s desire to avoid making nominal interest ratesexcessively volatile.

Finally, we assume that the monetary policy shock is seriallyuncorrelated, while the other structural shocks may be correlated.1

All shocks are assumed to be normally distributed with constantvariance. The unobservable inflation target is assumed to follow anAR(1) process

π∗t = (1 − φπ∗) π + φπ∗π∗

t−1 + uπ∗,t, (4)

where uπ∗,t is a normal disturbance with constant variance uncorre-lated with the other structural shocks.2

The linear Taylor rule in equation (3) is known to provide agood characterization of monetary policy decisions under normalcircumstances—see, e.g., Hordahl and Tristani (2012), where theTaylor rule is used to describe euro-area policy rates over the Janu-ary 1999 to June 2007 period. A linear policy rule is, however, lesssuitable when interest rates are near the zero lower bound, as it doesnot rule out the possibility of negative interest rates. Ignoring the

1In principle, the monetary policy shock could also be allowed to be seriallycorrelated. We assume instead that the interest rate smoothing component, incombination with the other persistent elements in the policy rule, will be sufficientto capture all of the persistence in the short rate.

2To ensure stationarity of the inflation target process, we impose an upperlimit of 0.99 on the φπ∗ parameter during the estimation process. This restrictionis binding.

Page 7: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 7

zero lower bound constraint is particularly problematic in the UnitedStates, where policy rates have been very close to zero since Decem-ber 2008. It could produce incorrect inference concerning expectedfuture policy rates and, in turn, for the term structure of nominalrisk premia.

These drawbacks are mitigated by our use of survey expectationson future short-term interest rates, which help discipline model-implied interest rate forecasts. In any case, we focus on inflationrisk premia at medium to long-term horizons, which should be lessaffected by the non-linearity induced by the zero bound constraint.

In order to obtain the rational expectations solution to themodel, we write it in state-space form and proceed to solve itnumerically (see the appendix). The result is two matrices Mand C which give the law of motion of the predetermined vari-ables X1,t = [xt−1, xt−2, xt−3, πt−1, πt−2, πt−3, π

∗t , ηt, ε

πt , εx

t , rt−1]′

and which describe how the non-predetermined variables X2,t =[Etxt+11, . . . , Etxt+1, xt, Etπt+11, . . . , Etπt+1, πt]

′ depend on X1,t.Specifically, we obtain

X1,t = MX1,t−1 + Σξ1,t, (5)

X2,t = CX1,t, (6)

where ξ1 is a vector of independent, normally distributed shocks, andwe also get an expression for the equilibrium short-term interest ratein terms of the state variables: rt = Δ′X1,t.

Because the state variables follow a first-order Gaussian VARand the short-term interest rate is expressed as a linear functionof the state vector, we can derive bond prices once we imposethe assumption of absence of arbitrage opportunities and specifya process for the pricing kernel. The appendix describes the pric-ing kernel we choose. One important aspect here is the choice ofthe market prices of risk. Following Duffee (2002), we assume thatthese risk prices are affine functions of the states, or, more pre-cisely, affine functions of a particular transformation of the orig-inal states. Specifically, we define the transformed state vectorZt ≡ [xt−1, xt−2, xt−3, πt−1, πt−2, πt−3, π

∗t , rt, πt, xt, rt−1]′, which is

obtained as Zt = DX1,t for a suitably defined matrix D. Workingwith Zt rather than X1,t facilitates the interpretation of the results

Page 8: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

8 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

later on. Our specification for the market prices of risk therefore hasthe following form:

λt = λ0 + λ1Zt, (7)

so that the risk premium associated with each of the four shocksin ξ1,t can depend on the level of all the state variables. To keepthe number of parameters manageable, we allow only the 4 × 4 sub-matrix in λ1 corresponding to the non-lagged states [π∗

t , rt, πt, xt] inZt to be non-zero.

Given the setup described above, we can write the continuouslycompounded yield yn

t on a zero-coupon nominal bond with maturityn as

ynt = An + B′

nZt, (8)

where the An and B′n matrices can be derived using recursive rela-

tions (see the appendix). Stacking all yields in a vector Yt, we writethe above equations jointly as Yt = A + BZt or, equivalently,Yt = A + BX1,t, where B ≡ BD. Similarly, for real bonds y∗n

t

we obtain

y∗nt = A∗

n + B′∗n Zt, (9)

and Y∗t = A∗ + B∗X1,t, with B∗ ≡ B∗D.

Given the solutions for real and nominal bonds, we can derivethe inflation risk premium as the difference between historical andrisk-adjusted expectations of future inflation rates. In so doing, wefollow closely Hordahl and Tristani (2012)—see also the appendix.

2.1 Estimation

Given the large number of parameters involved in the estimation, wedo not directly maximize the likelihood, but we introduce priors andproceed by relying on Bayesian estimation methods. Specifically, wemaximize the posterior density function obtained by combining thelog-likelihood function with the prior density for the model parame-ters. An advantage of such an approach is that it allows us to exploitprior information on structural economic relationships available fromprevious studies. Moreover, the inclusion of prior distributions brings

Page 9: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 9

an added advantage in that it tends to make the optimization of thehighly non-linear estimation problem more stable.

We evaluate the model likelihood using the Kalman filter. Wefirst define a vector Wt containing the observable contemporaneousvariables,

Wt ≡

⎡⎢⎢⎣Yt

Y∗t

Xo2,t

Ut

⎤⎥⎥⎦ ,

where Yt and Y∗t denote vectors of nominal and real zero-coupon

yields, Xo2,t = [xt, πt]′ contains the macro variables, and Ut denotes

survey expectations that are included in the estimation (see below).The dimension of Wt is denoted ny. Next, we partition the vectorof predetermined variables into observable (Xo

1,t) and unobservablevariables (Xu

1,t) according to

Xo1,t = [xt−1, xt−2, xt−3, πt−1, πt−2, πt−3, rt−1]

′,

Xu1,t = [π∗

t , ηt, επt , εx

t ]′ .

We treat survey expectations of future interest rates and infla-tion as noisy observations of the model-implied forecasts. Surveydata can then be written as suitable linear functions of the statesplus an observation error:

Ut = GX1,t + ut.

For example, for an inflation forecast j periods ahead, we know,based on the model solution, that Et[πt+j ] = CπEt[X1,t+j ] =CπMjX1,t, where Cπ picks the row in C corresponding to theinflation equation. Thus, if Ut contained survey data reflecting thisexpectation, the corresponding row in G would be defined as CπMj .Similar expressions would be derived for the interest rate surveyforecasts included in the estimations (the specific survey data usedis discussed in the next section).

When defining G, we take into account that some of the surveyforecasts refer to average expectations over the future—e.g., over aquarter or over several years. For the exact form of the Kalman filtermatrices, see the appendix. We start the filter from the unconditional

Page 10: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

10 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

mean and the unconditional mean squared error (MSE) matrix (seeHamilton 1994). The Kalman filter produces forecasts of the statesand the associated MSE, which feed into the likelihood function.

Our assumptions regarding the prior distribution of the macroparameters, which are broadly in line with those implied by typi-cal calibrations of the New Keynesian model, are listed in tables 3and 4. For the market prices of risk (the elements in λ0 and λ1),we assume normal priors centered at zero with very large standarderrors, reflecting our lack of prior information regarding these param-eters. We proceed to find the mode of the posterior density using thesimulated annealing algorithm (see Goffe, Ferrier, and Rogers 1994)and simulate the posterior by drawing from a distribution centeredat the mode using the Metropolis-Hastings sampling algorithm (seeAn and Schorfheide 2007).3

3. Data

We estimate the model using monthly data on nominal and realzero-coupon Treasury yields, inflation, a measure of the output gap,and survey expectations of the short-term interest rate and inflation.The model is applied to U.S. and euro-area data. To avoid obviousstructural break issues associated with the introduction of the sin-gle currency, we limit our euro-area sample to the period January1999–April 2013. For the United States, we include more historicaldata and start our sample in January 1990.

We treat the yields on index-linked bonds as reflecting risk-freereal yields, i.e., we assume that the inflation risk borne by investorsbecause of the indexation lag (the fact that there exists a lag betweenthe publication of the inflation index and the indexation of the bond)is negligible. Evans (1998) estimates the indexation-lag premium forUK index-linked bonds and finds that it is likely to be quite small,around 1.5 basis points. Since the indexation lag in the United King-dom is 8 months, while the lag in the United States and the euroarea is only 2.5–3 months, it seems likely that any indexation-lagpremium for these two markets would be even smaller than Evans’sestimate.

3The estimations were performed using modified versions of FrankSchorfheide’s Gauss code for Bayesian estimation of DSGE models. His originalcode is available at http://www.econ.upenn.edu/˜schorf/.

Page 11: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 11

In addition to the aforementioned premium, the indexation lagcan induce deviations in index-linked yields away from the trueunderlying real yield due to inflation seasonality and to “carry”effects. Inflation seasonality matters because index-linked bonds arelinked to the seasonally unadjusted price level, which means thatbond prices will be affected due to the indexation lag, unless theseasonal effect at a given date is identical to that corresponding tothe indexation lag (which is, in general, not the case; see, e.g., Ejsing,Grothe, and Grothe 2012). The carry effect refers to the fact thatindex-linked yields often contain some amount of realized inflation,due to predictable changes in inflation during the indexation-lagperiod (see D’Amico, Kim, and Wei 2008 for a discussion of thecarry effect). While these lag effects can be sizable for short-datedbonds, they tend to be quite small for longer-term bonds. In thispaper, we abstract from such effects, as they are likely to be ofsecond-order importance for our purposes. By excluding short-termreal yields (below three years) in the estimations, we reduce the riskthat index-lag effects might influence our results to any significantextent.

3.1 U.S. Data

The U.S. real and nominal term structure data consists of zero-coupon yields based on the Nelson-Siegel-Svensson (NSS) method,which are available from the Federal Reserve Board.4 For the nom-inal bonds, seven maturities ranging from one month to ten yearsare used in the estimation, while for the real bonds we include fourmaturities from three to ten years (figures 1A and 2A).

While nominal yield data is available from the beginning of thesample, real zero-coupon yields can be obtained only from 1999. Wetherefore treat them as unobservable variables prior to 1999 andinclude them in the measurement equation only thereafter. We alsocorrect real yield for liquidity premia—see section 3.3.

Our inflation data is year-on-year (YoY) CPI (seasonallyadjusted) log-differences, observed at a monthly frequency andscaled by 12 to get an approximate monthly measure, while theoutput gap is computed as the log-difference of real GDP and the

4This data is described in detail in Gurkaynak, Sack, and Wright (2007, 2010).

Page 12: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

12 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Figure 1. Nominal Zero-Coupon Yields

1990 1995 2000 2005 20100

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

8

91−month3−month6−month1−year3−year5−year10−year

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 20140

1

2

3

4

5

6

1−month3−month6−month1−year3−year5−year10−year

A. United States

B. Euro Area

Congressional Budget Office’s estimate of potential real GDP, whichis a quarterly series. Since we estimate the model using a monthlyfrequency, and since the output gap is a state variable, we need amonthly series for the gap. This is obtained by fitting an ARMA(1,1)model to the quarterly gap series, forecasting the gap one quarter

Page 13: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 13

Figure 2. Real Zero-Coupon Yields

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014−3

−2

−1

0

1

2

3

4

5

3−year5−year7−year10−year

2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014−2

−1.5

−1

−0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3−year5−year7−year10−year

A. United States

B. Euro Area

ahead, and computing one- and two-month-ahead values by meansof linear interpolation. This exercise is conducted in “real time,” inthe sense that the model is reestimated at each quarter using dataonly up to that quarter.

Page 14: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

14 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Following Kim and Orphanides (2012), we also use data on sur-vey forecasts for inflation and the three-month interest rate obtainedfrom the Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia’s quarterly Survey ofProfessional Forecasters (SPF).5 As argued by Kim and Orphanides(2012), survey data is likely to contain useful information for pinningdown the dynamics of the state variables that determine the bondyields, which, due to the high persistence of interest rates, is a chal-lenging task. For the United States, we include six survey series: theexpected three-month interest rate two quarters ahead, four quar-ters ahead, and during the coming ten years, and the expected CPIinflation for the same horizons. These survey forecasts are availableat a quarterly frequency, with the exception of the ten-year forecastof the three-month interest rate, which is reported only once peryear. The surveys therefore enter the measurement equation only inthose months when they are released.

3.2 Euro-Area Data

The data setup for the euro area is similar to that for the UnitedStates. We use nominal and real zero-coupon yields for the samematurities as in the U.S. case (figures 1B and 2B). The nominalyields are zero-coupon yields on French government bonds, reportedby Bloomberg. An alternative could have been to instead use Ger-man nominal bond yields, which often are seen as a natural bench-mark for the euro area. However, since our sample includes the mostrecent period when German yields have come under pressure dueto flight-to-safety flows, we view the French government bond yieldsas more likely to reflect underlying macroeconomic fundamentals inthe euro area during this period (and before the crisis, French andGerman yields were virtually indistinguishable).

For the real yields, we estimate zero-coupon rates using NSS,based on prices of government bonds linked to the euro-area HICPissued by France (obtained from Bloomberg). We exclude HICP-linked bonds issued by other countries—e.g., Italy and Greece—toavoid mixing bonds with different credit ratings, a problem that

5D’Amico, Kim, and Wei (2008) discuss at length various survey forecastsavailable for the United States. They conclude that inflation surveys based onthe forecasts of business economists, such as the SPF, are preferable to consumersurveys.

Page 15: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 15

became particularly acute during the euro-area sovereign debt cri-sis. Moreover, the French segment of the market is the largest in theeuro area, which suggests that liquidity conditions in this marketare likely to be relatively good.

The first HICP-linked government bond was issued by the FrenchTreasury in November 2001, and the issuance of additional bondswas very gradual. For this reason, we were able to estimate a euro-area real zero-coupon curve only as of January 2004, which is thedate as of which we include real yields in the estimation of ourmodel.6 The fact that we do not include the first few years of realyield data in the estimation is likely to reduce potential effects on ourestimates arising from initial illiquid conditions in the index-linkedmarket, similar to the U.S. case. Moreover, prior to the introduc-tion of HICP-linked bonds, a market for French bonds linked to theFrench CPI had been growing since 1998, which may have had apositive impact on the overall liquidity situation for the euro-areaindex-linked bond market.

As in the U.S. case, our measure of inflation is monthly YoYHICP log-differences. For the output gap, we rely on the estimatesby the European Commission—see D’Auria et al. (2010).7

The euro-area survey data we include in the estimation consistsof forecasts for inflation obtained from the ECB’s quarterly Surveyof Professional Forecasters and three-month interest rate forecastsavailable on a monthly basis from Consensus Economics. The infla-tion forecasts refer to expectations of HICP inflation one, two, andfive years ahead. The survey data for the short-term interest ratecorrespond to forecasts three and twelve months ahead.

3.3 Correction for Liquidity Premia

Well-known liquidity problems affect both the U.S. TreasuryInflation-Protected Securities (TIPS) and the euro-area index-linked

6Due to data limitations at the beginning of the sample, we included in thecalculation of real zeros one A+ rated bond issued by the Italian Treasury dur-ing the first ten months of our sample. During this period, the yield differencebetween French and Italian government bonds was minimal.

7In a previous version of the paper, we followed Clarida, Galı, and Gertler(1998) and measured the output gap as deviations of real GDP from a quadratictrend. The results are not insensitive to this change of variable.

Page 16: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

16 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

bonds, both during the years when these markets were initially cre-ated and at the peak of the financial crisis in 2008. D’Amico, Kim,and Wei (2008) provide an extensive discussion on the illiquidityof the TIPS market in the early years and argue that it resultedin severe distortions in TIPS yields. Gurkaynak, Sack, and Wright(2010) and Pflueger and Viceira (2013) provide estimates of liquiditypremia during the financial crisis.

For these reasons, we correct real yields for liquidity premia priorto using them in estimation. Specifically, we regress break-even infla-tion rates on proxies for market liquidity and interpret the (negativeof the) fitted values from the regressions as a measure of the timevariation in liquidity premia on index-linked bonds.

For the United States, we follow Gurkaynak, Sack, and Wright(2010) and use two proxies for liquidity: the trading volume amongprimary dealers in TIPS, expressed as a share of total Treasury trad-ing volume, and the spread between Resolution Funding Corporation(Refcorp) strips and Treasury strips. Refcorp-issued bonds are lessliquid than Treasury bonds, but they are guaranteed by the U.S.Treasury. The spreads between these yields can therefore be inter-preted as capturing a liquidity premium, which we use as a proxyfor the liquidity premium on TIPS.

For the euro area, we do not have information on the volume ofindex-linked bonds. We therefore rely solely on the spread betweenKreditanstalt fur Wiederaufbau (KfW) bonds and German bundsas a proxy for the liquidity premium. KfW is a development bankinvolved in supporting public policies, and its bonds have an explicitguarantee from the Federal Republic of Germany. Ejsing, Grothe,and Grothe (2012) argue that this spread is a reliable and timelyindicator of liquidity premia in the euro area.

The regression coefficients are shown in tables 1 and 2. All regres-sors have the expected sign and are significant for the United Statesas well as for the euro area. The U.S. spread regressors are, however,larger in absolute value. An increase in the Refcorp or KfW spreadlowers the break-even inflation rate, but the elasticity at the ten-year maturity is almost −0.8 in the United States, compared with−0.35 in the euro area. In the United States, a higher TIPS vol-ume increases the break-even inflation rate, as it reduces the TIPSliquidity premium and thereby lowers the real yield.

Page 17: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 17

Table 1. Regression Results to Estimate LiquidityPremia in the United States

(Sample Period: January 1999–April 2013)

Regressor Three Year Five Year Seven Year Ten Year

TIPS Relative 0.365 0.299 0.249 0.246Volume (0.134) (0.083) (0.077) (0.053)

Refcorp Spread −2.627 −1.836 −1.531 −0.770(0.709) (0.516) (0.504) (0.296)

R2 0.47 0.45 0.40 0.32

Notes: This table reports the results from regressions of three-, five-, seven- and ten-yearbreak-even inflation rates (in percentage points) onto the TIPS volume as a share of totalTreasury Primary Dealer trading volume (in percentage points), and the spread of ten-yearRefcorp strips over their Treasury counterparts (in percentage points). Newey-West stan-dard errors with a lag truncation parameter of 20 are shown in parentheses. The numberof observations is 172.

Table 2. Regression Results to Estimate LiquidityPremia in the Euro Area

(Sample Period: January 2004–April 2013)

Regressor Three Year Five Year Seven Year Ten Year

KfW Spread −0.814 −0.599 −0.544 −0.358(0.325) (0.183) (0.165) (0.131)

R2 0.15 0.14 0.18 0.13

Notes: This table reports the results from regressions of three-, five-, seven- and ten-yeareuro-area break-even inflation rates (in percentage points) onto the spread of ten-yearKfW bonds over ten-year bunds (in percentage points). Newey-West standard errors witha lag truncation parameter of 20 are shown in parentheses. The number of observationsis 115.

The fitted values from these regressions do not identify the levelof liquidity premia, but only their time variation. As in Gurkaynak,Sack, and Wright (2010), we therefore normalize the U.S. premiumto be zero in April 2005. For consistency, we do the same for theeuro area.

Our estimated liquidity premia are highly correlated across thetwo monetary areas that we study (see figure 3 for the ten-yearmaturity). Their absolute levels, however, are markedly different.

Page 18: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

18 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Figure 3. Estimated Liquidity Premia on Ten-YearIndex-Linked Bonds

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 20140

0.5

1

1.5

United Stateseuro area

Notes: See section 3.3 for the methodology. Sample period: January 1999 (UnitedStates) and 2004 (euro area) to February 2013 (percent per year).

Over the January 2004 to April 2013 sample, liquidity premia onten-year bonds are on average equal to 10 basis points in the euroarea and 37 basis points in the United States. At the peak of the cri-sis, these premia increase to 30 basis points in the euro area and soarto 1.3 percentage points in the United States. These large differencesin liquidity premia are consistent with anecdotal evidence that theflight to safety/liquidity during the financial crisis was mostly a flighttowards U.S. nominal bonds. A temporary spike in TIPS yields wasapparently also due to leveraged investors that had built up hugepositions in U.S. TIPS that needed to be quickly unwound after theLehman bankruptcy (see Bank for International Settlements 2009).

In the rest of our analysis we take these liquidity correctionsat face value and proceed to estimate our model using liquidity-adjusted index-linked yield data.

4. Empirical Results

Tables 3 and 4 report parameter estimates and associated poste-rior distributions for the United States as well as the euro area,

Page 19: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 19Tab

le3.

U.S

.Par

amet

erEst

imat

es(S

ample

Per

iod:Ja

nuar

y19

90–A

pri

l20

13)

Pri

orD

istr

ibuti

onPos

teri

orM

ode

Pos

teri

orD

istr

.

Par

amet

erT

ype

Mea

nSt.

Err

ora

Mode

St.

Err

or5%

Med

ian

95%

ρB

eta

0.9

0.05

0.78

60.

004

0.78

30.

792

0.79

Nor

mal

1.5

0.05

1.74

50.

008

1.69

81.

735

1.77

Nor

mal

0.25

0.05

0.30

90.

009

0.27

80.

306

0.32

πB

eta

0.5

0.05

0.36

50.

005

0.33

40.

343

0.35

1δ x

Gam

ma

0.13

0.02

0.01

80.

001

0.01

60.

017

0.01

xB

eta

0.5

0.05

0.10

20.

007

0.09

20.

103

0.11

4ζ r

Gam

ma

0.09

0.01

0.07

00.

005

0.07

60.

081

0.08

πN

orm

al0.

50.

10.

806

0.00

20.

800

0.80

30.

806

φx

Nor

mal

0.9

0.1

0.97

80.

001

0.97

30.

976

0.97

×12

00B

eta

2.5

0.4

2.75

50.

093

2.59

42.

679

2.75

0r

×12

00B

eta

40.

44.

357

0.18

74.

267

4.39

74.

522

σπ

∗×

103

Inv.

Gam

ma

0.05

40.

076

0.00

50.

062

0.06

90.

078

ση

×10

3In

v.G

amm

a0.

354

0.16

80.

003

0.15

70.

166

0.17

π×

103

Inv.

Gam

ma

0.3

40.

105

0.00

00.

105

0.10

50.

105

σx

×10

3In

v.G

amm

a0.

075

40.

025

0.00

00.

028

0.02

90.

030

λ0(π

∗ )N

orm

al0

100

0.00

00.

005

−0.

083

−0.

052

−0.

025

λ0(η

)N

orm

al0

100

−0.

330

0.00

8−

0.45

1−

0.41

3−

0.37

0(π

)N

orm

al0

100

0.01

00.

001

−0.

026

−0.

022

−0.

019

λ0(x

)N

orm

al0

100

−0.

090

0.00

5−

0.06

0−

0.03

2−

0.00

3aFor

the

inve

rted

gam

ma

dis

trib

uti

on,th

edeg

rees

offr

eedom

are

indic

ated

.N

ote

:B

ased

on50

0,00

0si

mula

tion

s.

(con

tinu

ed)

Page 20: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

20 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Tab

le3.

(Con

tinued

)

λ1

×10

−2:Pos

teri

orD

istr

ibuti

onb

π∗

ηπ

x

π∗

3.60

1(2

.991

,4.

476)

−0.

033

(−0.

135,

0.08

6)−

0.43

6(−

0.53

0,−

0.31

7)0.

412

(0.3

32,

0.51

5)

η0.

058

(−1.

264,

1.44

7)−

4.96

0(−

5.53

5,−

4.55

7)1.

511

(1.0

23,

1.97

8)3.

297

(2.9

98,

3.70

1)

π5.

670

(5.3

96,

5.92

8)1.

364

(1.2

98,

1.45

7)−

4.20

8(−

4.39

4,−

4.00

4)0.

618

(0.5

35,

0.73

9)

x−

4.81

1(−

5.36

9,−

4.15

6)−

0.28

8(−

0.38

9,−

0.15

8)1.

178

(1.0

52,

1.28

5)−

0.79

3(−

0.89

7,−

0.69

0)

bFo

ral

lla

mbda

para

met

ers,

the

prio

rdi

stri

buti

onis

norm

alw

ith

mea

nze

roan

dst

anda

rder

ror

100.

Note

:M

edia

nva

lues

;5%

and

95%

per

cent

iles

inpa

rent

hese

s.

Page 21: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 21Tab

le4.

Euro

-Are

aPar

amet

erEst

imat

es(S

ample

Per

iod:Ja

nuar

y19

99–A

pri

l20

13)

Pri

orD

istr

ibuti

onPos

teri

orM

ode

Pos

teri

orD

istr

.

Par

amet

erT

ype

Mea

nSt.

Err

ora

Mode

St.

Err

or5%

Med

ian

95%

ρB

eta

0.9

0.05

0.97

60.

001

0.97

20.

974

0.97

Nor

mal

1.5

0.05

1.49

70.

008

1.44

81.

500

1.60

Nor

mal

0.3

0.05

0.21

60.

001

0.20

00.

218

0.22

πB

eta

0.75

0.05

0.37

40.

001

0.37

10.

374

0.37

7δ x

Gam

ma

0.13

0.02

0.02

20.

000

0.01

80.

019

0.02

xB

eta

0.5

0.05

0.21

30.

002

0.18

00.

188

0.20

9ζ r

Gam

ma

0.1

0.02

0.05

70.

000

0.06

20.

063

0.06

πN

orm

al0

0.1

0.68

90.

003

0.67

10.

691

0.70

xN

orm

al0.

90.

10.

952

0.00

10.

956

0.95

80.

960

π×

1200

Bet

a2

0.3

1.77

80.

031

1.78

11.

818

1.86

6r

×12

00B

eta

40.

43.

788

0.07

33.

599

3.72

83.

868

σπ

∗×

103

Inv.

Gam

ma

0.01

40.

020

0.00

10.

019

0.02

00.

023

ση

×10

3In

v.G

amm

a0.

14

0.16

40.

004

0.15

10.

157

0.16

π×

103

Inv.

Gam

ma

0.1

40.

091

0.00

10.

089

0.09

80.

112

σx

×10

3In

v.G

amm

a0.

054

0.04

80.

001

0.03

70.

039

0.04

0(π

∗ )N

orm

al0

100

0.50

00.

018

0.48

60.

514

0.53

0(η

)N

orm

al0

100

0.71

00.

001

0.82

70.

832

0.83

0(π

)N

orm

al0

100

−0.

110

0.00

5−

0.14

1−

0.12

4−

0.11

0(x

)N

orm

al0

100

0.45

00.

008

0.49

20.

504

0.51

8

aFor

the

inve

rted

gam

ma

dis

trib

uti

on,th

edeg

rees

offr

eedom

are

indic

ated

.N

ote

:B

ased

on50

0,00

0si

mula

tion

s.

(con

tinu

ed)

Page 22: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

22 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Tab

le4.

(Con

tinued

)

λ1

×10

−2:Pos

teri

orD

istr

ibuti

onb

π∗

ηπ

x

π∗

27.5

58(2

7.13

5,28

.041

)−

0.01

6(−

0.02

5,−

0.01

3)−

0.64

8(−

0.74

7,−

0.56

5)0.

420

(0.2

58,

0.53

5)

η82

.144

(81.

698,

82.4

94)

−2.

264

(−2.

329,

−2.

187)

−1.

581

(−1.

643,

−1.

470)

4.46

7(4

.436

,4.

500)

π−

2.95

2(−

3.10

8,−

2.81

5)−

0.64

1(−

0.70

9,−

0.54

2)−

8.76

2(−

9.52

0,−

8.27

4)1.

642

(1.4

58,

2.07

6)

x52

.619

(52.

436,

52.7

78)

−1.

270

(−1.

310,

−1.

227)

−0.

400

(−0.

440,

−0.

337)

1.82

3(1

.795

,1.

868)

bFo

ral

lla

mbda

para

met

ers,

the

prio

rdi

stri

buti

onis

norm

alw

ith

mea

nze

roan

dst

anda

rder

ror

100.

Note

:M

edia

nva

lues

;5%

and

95%

per

cent

iles

inpa

rent

hese

s.

Page 23: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 23

respectively. The results show that our model seems empiricallyplausible, with estimated macro parameters that are broadly withinthe range of estimates which can be found in the literature (see, e.g.,Rudebusch 2002).

In both sets of estimates, the policy rule is characterized by ahigh degree of interest rate smoothing—however, more so for theeuro area (ρ = 0.97) than in the case of the United States (ρ = 0.79).This might reflect the shorter sample used in the estimation of theeuro-area model, during which the short rate remained relativelystable. The responses to inflation deviations from the objective andthe output gap (β and γ, respectively) are estimated to be similarin the two economies, and also in line with typical values reportedin the literature. The degree of forward-lookingness of the output-gap equation (μx) is somewhat higher for the euro area than for theUnited States. As for the estimated standard deviations of funda-mental shocks, these tend to be higher for the United States than forthe euro area. The only exception is demand shocks, whose standarddeviation is smaller, but the persistence higher, in the United States.These differences are likely to be due to the relatively low macroeco-nomic volatility during the euro sample, compared with the longerU.S. sample. Concerning the λ1 parameters, the prices of inflationtarget, monetary policy, and aggregate demand risk appear to bemuch more sensitive to changes in the perceived inflation target inthe euro area (see the first column of the lower table in tables 3and 4). The other elements of the λ1 matrix appear to be moresimilar across countries in absolute value.

As already mentioned, our assumed perceived policy rule allowsfor a time-varying inflation target. This is an unobservable variablethat needs to be filtered out from available observable data. Panels Aand B of figure 4 display the estimates obtained for the United Statesand the euro area, respectively. From an intuitive viewpoint, theseestimates appear reasonable: in both cases the filtered targets moveslowly and with little variability compared with realized inflation. Inthe euro area, the estimated target fluctuates narrowly around levelsbelow but close to 2 percent over the whole sample period. This isconsistent with the numerical definition of price stability providedby the ECB Governing Council in 1998.

For the United States, we document a slight reduction in theestimated inflation target from levels around 3 percent before

Page 24: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

24 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Figure 4. Inflation and Estimated PerceivedInflation Target

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010−2

−1

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

targetyoy inflation

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014−1

0

1

2

3

4

5

targetyoy inflation

A. United States

B. Euro Area

2011 to levels closer to 2 percent at the end of 2012. This shiftis consistent with the implications of the FOMC announcementof January 25, 2012, which stated as follows: “The Committeejudges that inflation at the rate of 2 percent, as measured by

Page 25: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 25

Figure 5. Estimated Three-Year Inflation Risk Premia

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014−1.5

−1

−0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

United Stateseuro area

the annual change in the price index for personal consumptionexpenditures, is most consistent over the longer run with the Fed-eral Reserve’s statutory mandate.” Our results suggest that theannouncement produced the intended effects. Together with theeuro-area evidence, they provide further support to the view thatthe availability of an official numerical definition of price sta-bility plays an important role in anchoring long-term inflationexpectations.

4.1 Inflation Risk Premia

Given a set of parameters and a specific realization of the state-variable vector, we can compute the model-implied inflation riskpremium.8 The dynamics of our estimated inflation premia are dis-played in figures 5 and 6, with a focus on the three-year and ten-year maturities, respectively, over the sample for which data are

8Our model can also be used to compute nominal and real term premia for anymaturity. We do not report these variables, because our focus is on inflation riskpremia. Note that here we disregard the component due to Jensen’s inequality,which is in the order of only a few basis points.

Page 26: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

26 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Figure 6. Estimated Ten-Year Inflation Risk Premia

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014−1

−0.8

−0.6

−0.4

−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

United Stateseuro area

available for both the United States and the euro area. The overallmagnitude of our estimated inflation premia are comparable, for theUnited States, with recent empirical evidence reported by Chris-tensen, Lopez, and Rudebusch (2010) and Chernov and Mueller(2012) and, for the euro area, with the results in Hordahl andTristani (2012).9

In spite of the different evolution of inflation, of the output gap,and of inflation expectations, inflation risk premia appear to beremarkably close to each other in the United States and in the euroarea. Both at the three-year and the ten-year horizons, their lev-els are broadly comparable and their fluctuations at business-cyclefrequencies are relatively closely aligned. Only at higher frequen-cies are U.S. premia subject to higher volatility. Financial marketparticipants appear to attach very similar prices to inflation risk inthe United States and in the euro area. This suggests that they areequally confident about the ability of the Federal Reserve and the

9Amongst other papers that estimate inflation risk premia on U.S. data, seeDurham (2006) and D’Amico, Kim, and Wei (2008); Garcıa and Werner (2008)study inflation risk premia in the euro area.

Page 27: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 27

European Central Bank to deliver a stable inflation rate over themedium-to-long run.

Nevertheless, temporary divergences between inflation risk pre-mia across the two sides of the Atlantic can occasionally be observedover our sample period. One occurs over 2006 and 2007, but it is con-fined to ten-year premia, which fall to near-zero levels in the UnitedStates, while they remain relatively stable in the euro area. Thisdeviation is linked to a small reduction in the U.S. inflation rate ina period of positive output gap—see section 4.3 for a more detaileddiscussion of the cyclical features of inflation risk premia.

The second period in which U.S. and euro-area inflation riskpremia diverge starts around 2012 and continues until the end ofour sample. Over this period we observe a decoupling of premiaacross the two areas: they fall towards zero or slightly negative lev-els in the euro area, while they tend to increase temporarily in theUnited States. This divergence is visible both at the three-year and,to a lesser degree, at the ten-year maturity—as well as the five-yearmaturity, which is not displayed in the figure.

The model interprets these recent developments in light of thediverging cyclical conditions. Specifically, over the past two yearswe observe an improvement in our output-gap measure and a mildincrease in the inflation rate in the United States. In contrast, theoutput gap falls further in the euro area, and so does the inflationrate.

4.2 Premium-Adjusted Break-Even Inflation Rates

Given our estimates of the inflation risk premium, we can strip outthis component from our measures of the break-even inflation rateswhich have already been corrected for liquidity risk. The results arepremium-adjusted break-even inflation rates, which provide a moreaccurate estimate of inflation expectations over the life of the bonds.

Figure 7 reports raw and premium-adjusted ten-year break-eveninflation rates in the United States and the euro area for the periodover which we have reliable estimates of zero-coupon real rates (seethe data section above).

In the euro area, liquidity risk premia are relatively small overmost of the sample period and the inflation premium is somewhatlarger. The adjusted break-even rate is consequently also lower rel-ative to the raw rate. While the raw euro-area break-even rate has

Page 28: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

28 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Figure 7. Ten-Year Break-Even Inflation Rates andSurvey Inflation Forecasts

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 20141

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

2.2

2.4

2.6

2.8

3

raw BEIadjusted BEIexpected inflationSPF 10y inflation

A. United States

B. Euro Area1990 1995 2000 2005 20100

1

2

3

4

5raw BEIadjusted BEIexpected inflationSPF 10y inflation

Notes: The solid thin line is the unadjusted observed ten-year break-even rate;the solid thick line is the break-even rate adjusted for liquidity and inflation riskpremia; the dashed line is the model-implied average expected inflation over thenext ten years. The diamonds are SPF survey expectations of inflation duringthe next ten years (United States) and five years ahead (euro area). All valuesare expressed in percent per year.

Page 29: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 29

been mostly fluctuating above a level of 2 percent since 2004, thepremium-adjusted measure has generally been below but close to 2percent, suggesting long-term euro-area inflation expectations morein line with the ECB’s price stability objective than what would beconcluded based on the unadjusted break-even rate.

In the United States, liquidity risk premia are very large—larger than inflation risk premia—from 2008 onwards. Over muchof this period, adjusted break-even rates are therefore higher thanthe raw rates, since the positive liquidity premium on TIPS pushesbreak-even rates downward. While the raw U.S. break-even ratereached a minimum of 0.4 percentage points at the end of 2008,the premium-adjusted measure has hovered around 2.5 to 3 per-centage points until mid-2011 and has then fallen slightly towards alevel just above 2 percent. For the period 1999–2008, our estimatesare quite similar to those reported by Gurkaynak, Sack, and Wright(2010) for that period.

Our results suggest that, both in the euro area and in the UnitedStates, long-term inflation expectations have remained remark-ably stable at the peak of the financial crisis and throughout theGreat Recession. Specifically, premium-adjusted break-even rateshave remained stable even over 2009, when our measures record thelargest negative output gap and actual inflation rates temporarilyreached negative territory in both monetary areas.

Figure 7 also displays the estimated model-implied averageexpected inflation over the next ten years for each point in timeduring the sample periods. This is the expected inflation producedby the macro dynamics of the model, which would fully coincidewith the premium-adjusted break-even rate discussed above if allyield measurement errors were always zero. While this is not thecase, the difference is always very small, in the order of a few basispoints, indicating that our model does well in terms of capturingthe dynamics of both nominal and real yields. It also shows that themost recent uptick in the euro-area adjusted break-even rate above2 percent is due to increased yield measurement errors rather thanhigher inflation expectations in the model.

Finally, figure 7 reports measures of long-horizon inflation expec-tations from available survey forecasts: ten-year U.S. inflation expec-tations from the Federal Reserve’s Survey of Professional Forecasters(SPF) and five-year euro-area inflation expectations from the ECB’s

Page 30: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

30 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

SPF. Clearly, inclusion of inflation survey data in the estimation hasbeen useful in getting the model to capture the broad movements ofinvestors’ inflation expectations, as reported by these survey meas-ures. In both monetary areas, the adjusted break-even rate is muchcloser to the survey forecasts than the unadjusted rate.

4.3 The Inflation Risk Premium and the Macroeconomy

In this section, we look closer at the relationship between inflationrisk premia and macroeconomic developments. In essentially affinemodels, movements in risk premia are related to changes in the statevariables. Since the state variables in our model are inflation, theoutput gap, the monetary policy shock, and the perceived inflationtarget, we can relate the dynamics of our estimated inflation riskpremia directly to developments in these variables.

From a descriptive perspective, inflation risk premia are procycli-cal over the past five years. In particular, they fall during the GreatRecession. Inflation risk premia are also positively correlated withactual inflation rates in both monetary areas: premia become higherwhen inflation increases. These patterns are apparent from figures 8–11, which plot movements in ten-year inflation risk premia togetherwith rescaled measures of the output gap and of inflation.

Both in the United States and in the euro area, ten-year infla-tion risk premia fall sharply when output contracts at the end of2008. They then tend to recover, and in the euro area edge downagain, alongside the measured output gaps. Over the longer sam-ple available for the United States, however, inflation risk premiaare on average countercyclical. This result is in line with the widelydocumented countercyclicality of term premia (see, e.g., Stambaugh1988; Hordahl, Tristani, and Vestin 2006).

Figures 8–11 also show that the positive correlation betweenmonth-to-month changes in inflation and the inflation premiumtakes place mostly at a higher frequency. This pattern is againcommon to both the United States and the euro area.

Through the lens of our model, we can also look at how long-terminflation expectations and inflation risk premia react to macroeco-nomic shocks. Figures 12 and 13 compare the impulse responses oflong-term inflation expectations and inflation risk premia, respec-tively, to the four structural shocks in our model. The figures show

Page 31: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 31

Figure 8. U.S. Ten-Year Inflation Risk Premium andOutput Gap

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010−1

−0.8

−0.6

−0.4

−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

110−y inflation premiumoutput gap (rescaled)

Figure 9. U.S. Ten-Year Inflation Risk Premium andYear-on-Year Inflation

1990 1995 2000 2005 2010−1

−0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

10−y inflation premiuminflation (rescaled)

Page 32: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

32 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Figure 10. Euro-Area Ten-Year Inflation Risk Premiumand Output Gap

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014−0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.910−y inflation premiumoutput gap (rescaled)

Figure 11. Euro-Area Ten-Year Inflation Risk Premiumand Year-on-Year Inflation

2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014−0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

10−y inflation premiuminflation (rescaled)

Page 33: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 33

Figure 12. Impulse Responses of Ten-Year InflationExpectations

0 20 40 600

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08Inflation target shock

United StatesEuro area

0 20 40 600

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08Monetary policy shock

0 20 40 600

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08Cost−push shock

0 20 40 600

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08Demand shock

Note: The impulses are equal to one standard deviation for all shocks.

that demand shocks are the most important drivers of long-terminflation expectations (together with target shocks in the UnitedStates case); inflation risk premia are mostly driven by cost-pushshocks.

Specifically, an aggregate demand shock leads to an increase inten-year average inflation expectations in both monetary areas, butthe increase is approximately twice as big in the United States com-pared with the euro area—almost 7 basis points and approximately 3basis points, respectively. This difference is especially striking takinginto account that the standard deviation of the shocks is higher inthe euro area.

Page 34: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

34 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Figure 13. Impulse Responses of Ten-Year InflationRisk Premia

0 20 40 60−0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25Inflation target shock

United StatesEuro area

0 20 40 60−0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25Monetary policy shock

0 20 40 60−0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

Cost−push shock

0 20 40 60−0.05

0

0.05

0.1

0.15

0.2

Demand shock

Note: The impulses are equal to one standard deviation for all shocks.

The cross-country differences in the response of inflation riskpremia to aggregate demand shocks are even larger. At the ten-year horizon, inflation premia increase by almost 10 basis points inthe United States and by 2 basis points in the euro area. All inall, demand shocks have comparable effects on long-term inflationexpectations and long-term inflation risk premia, but these effectsare larger in the United States.

For a given size of the inflation target shock, we observe similareffects on long-term inflation expectations in the United States andin the euro area. A hypothetical 1-percentage-point upward shockto the target would result in a surge in ten-year average inflationexpectations by approximately 0.8 percentage points in both cases.

Page 35: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 35

The estimated average size of inflation target shocks, however, isfour times larger in the United States (0.08 percent) compared withthe euro area (0.02 percent). This result helps explain the highervolatility of inflation expectations conditional on target shocks inthe United States.

The size of monetary policy and cost-push shocks is very similaracross the two monetary areas. A 0.2-percentage-point monetarypolicy shock has negligible effects on ten-year average inflationexpectations and a small impact on ten-year inflation risk premia.

For a given shock size, however, cost-push shocks have a muchlarger impact on long-term inflation expectations and inflation riskpremia in the United States. A positive shock of this type of 0.1percentage point produces an increase in average ten-year inflationexpectations by about 3 basis points in the United States, while thesame expectations only edge up by 1 basis point in the euro area.At the same time, the shock triggers a temporary 25-basis-pointincrease in the ten-year inflation risk premium in the United States,while the premium only increases by 8 basis points in the euro area.

All in all, our results suggest that ten-year inflation expectationsand risk premia are somewhat more volatile in the United Statescompared with the euro area. A distinguishing feature of positiveaggregate demand shocks is to increase long-term inflation expecta-tions and inflation risk premia by comparable amounts. In contrast,cost-push shocks have a much larger impact on inflation risk premia,especially in the United States.

5. Conclusions

Break-even inflation rates are often used as timely measures of mar-ket expectations of future inflation, and are therefore viewed as use-ful indicators for central banks, among others. However, some careshould be exercised when interpreting break-even inflation rates interms of inflation expectations, because they include risk premia,most notably to compensate investors for liquidity and inflationrisks. In this paper we model and estimate the inflation risk pre-mium in order to obtain a “cleaner” measure of investors’ inflationexpectations embedded in bond prices. In addition, we investigatethe macroeconomic determinants of inflation risk premia, in orderto better understand their dynamics.

Page 36: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

36 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

We estimate our model on U.S. and euro-area data. This providesus with an opportunity to examine the main features of inflationrisk premia for the two largest economies, including similarities anddifferences in the determinants of such premia.

Our results suggest that ten-year inflation expectations haveremained quite stable over time in both monetary areas. In theUnited States, since the late 1990s, they have fluctuated aroundlevels slightly below 3 percent up until 2011 when, further to theFOMC announcement of a 2 percent inflation goal, they adjusteddownwards towards this level over the course of 2012. In the euroarea, long-term inflation expectations have generally moved verylittle around levels slightly below 2 percent.

Inflation risk premia at various maturities have remarkably sim-ilar properties in the United States and in the euro area, especiallyover the years of the financial crisis until mid-2011, even if U.S. pre-mia appear to be subject to greater high-frequency volatility. Thehigher volatility in U.S. premia appears to be due to their greatersensitivity to aggregate demand shocks and especially to cost-pushshocks.

These results should provide a useful benchmark for comparisonto further analyses of inflation risk premia based on fully micro-founded models.

Appendix

Solving the Model

In order to solve the model, we write it in the general form[X1,t+1

EtX2,t+1

]= H

[X1,t

X2,t

]+ Krt +

[Σξ1,t+1

0

], (10)

where X1,t = [xt−1, xt−2, xt−3, πt−1, πt−2, πt−3, π∗t , ηt, ε

πt , εx

t , rt−1]′

is the vector of predetermined variables, X2,t = [Etxt+11, . . . , Etxt+1,xt, Etπt+11, . . . , Etπt+1, πt]′ includes the variables which are not pre-determined, rt is the policy instrument, and ξ1 is a vector of inde-pendent, normally distributed shocks. The short-term rate can bewritten in the feedback form

rt = −F[

X1,t

X2,t

]. (11)

Page 37: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 37

The solution of the model can be obtained numerically follow-ing standard methods. We choose the methodology described inSoderlind (1999), which is based on the Schur decomposition. Theresult is two matrices M and C such that X1,t = MX1,t−1 + Σξ1,t

and X2,t = CX1,t.10 Consequently, the equilibrium short-term inter-est rate will be equal to rt = Δ′X1,t, where Δ′ ≡ − (F1+F2C) andF1 and F2 are partitions of F conformable with X1,t and X2,t.

Pricing Real and Nominal Bonds

To build the term structure of interest rates, we first note that thesolution of the macro model is the same as that in standard affineterm structure models. Specifically, the short-term interest rate isexpressed as a linear function of the state vector (X1), which inturn follows a first-order Gaussian VAR.11 To derive the term struc-ture, we therefore only need to impose the assumption of absenceof arbitrage opportunities, which guarantees the existence of a risk-neutral measure, and to specify a process for the stochastic discountfactor, or pricing kernel.

The (nominal) pricing kernel mt+1 is defined as mt+1 =exp(−rt)ψt+1/ψt, where ψt+1 is the Radon-Nikodym derivativeassumed to follow the log-normal process ψt+1 = ψt exp

(−1

2λ′tλt −

λ′tξ1,t+1

), and where λt denotes the market prices of risk. As

described in section 2, we assume that these risk prices are affinefunctions of a transformed state vector Zt ≡ [xt−1, xt−2, xt−3, πt−1,

πt−2, πt−3, π∗t , rt, πt, xt, rt−1]′, defined as Zt = DX1,t for a suitably

defined matrix D. Given this transformation, the solution equationfor the short-term interest rate can be rewritten as a function of Zt,

rt = Δ′Zt. (12)

10The presence of non-predetermined variables in the model implies that theremay be multiple solutions for some parameter values. We constrain the systemto be determinate in the iterative process of maximizing the likelihood function.

11Note, however, that in our case both the short-rate equation and the law ofmotion of vector X1 are obtained endogenously, as functions of the parameters ofthe macroeconomic model. This contrasts with the standard affine setup basedon unobservable variables, where both the short-rate equation and the law ofmotion of the state variables are postulated exogenously.

Page 38: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

38 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

From the macro model solution, we also know that

πt+1 = CπMX1,t + CπΣξ1,t+1

= CπMD−1

Zt + CπΣξ1,t+1,

where Cπ is the relevant row of C.Now assume that the real pricing kernel is m∗

t+1, so that thefollowing fundamental asset pricing relation holds:

Et

[m∗

t+1(1 + R∗

t+1)]

= 1,

where R∗t+1 denotes the real return on some asset.

If we now want to price an n-period nominal bond, pnt , we get

pnt

qt= Et

[m∗

t+1pn−1

t+1

qt+1

],

where qt is the price level in the economy. In terms of inflation rates,πt+1 ≡ ln qt+1 − ln qt, we obtain

pnt = Et

[m∗

t+1pn−1

t+1

exp (πt+1)

].

Notice that this is equivalent to postulating a nominal pricingkernel mt+1 ≡ m∗

t+1/ exp(πt+1), such that

pnt = Et

[mt+1p

n−1t+1

].

Given our assumption on the nominal pricing kernel and on themarket prices of risk, we can postulate that nominal bond prices willbe exponential-affine functions of the state variables, to obtain

pnt = exp

(An + B′

nZt

), (13)

where An and B′n are recursive parameters that depend on the

maturity n in the following way:

An+1 = An − B′nDΣλ0 +

12B′

nDΣΣ′D′Bn, (14)

B′n+1 = B′

nD(MD

−1 − Σλ1

)− Δ

′. (15)

Page 39: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 39

Nominal bond yields are then given by

ynt = − ln (pn

t )n

= −An

n− B′

n

nZt

≡ An + B′nZt. (16)

The definition of the pricing kernel implies

rt = − lnmt+1 − 12λ′

tλt − λ′tξ1,t+1,

which translates into a real pricing kernel

m∗t+1 = exp (−rt + πt+1)

ψt+1

ψt,

or

m∗t+1 = exp

(−Δ

′Zt + CπMX1,t + CπΣξ1,t+1 − 1

2λ′

tλt − λ′tξ1,t+1

).

We postulate again that real bond prices will be exponential-affine functions of the state variables,

pn∗t = exp

(A∗

n + B∗′n Zt

),

where A∗n and B∗

n are parameters that depend on the maturity n,and which can be identified using

pn+1∗t = Et

[m∗

t+1pn∗t+1

]= exp

(A∗

n − Δ′Zt + CπMX1,t + B∗′

n DMX1,t − 12λ′

tλt

)× Et

[exp

((CπΣ − λ′

t + B∗′n DΣ

)ξ1,t+1

)],

where we used

Zt+1 = DMX1,t + DΣξ1,t+1.

Page 40: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

40 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Noting that

Et

[exp

((CπΣ + B∗′

n DΣ − λ′t

)ξ1,t+1

)]= exp

(12

((Cπ + B∗′

n D)

Σ − λ′t

) ((Cπ + B∗′

n D)

Σ − λ′t

)′)

,

and rearranging terms, we obtain

pn+1∗t = exp

(A∗

n +12

(Cπ + B∗′

n D)

ΣΣ′(Cπ + B∗′

n D)′

−(Cπ + B∗′

n D)

Σλ0

+((

Cπ + B∗′n D

) (MD

−1 − Σλ1

)− Δ

′)Zt

).

We can therefore identify A∗n and B∗

n recursively as

A∗n+1 = A∗

n +12

(Cπ + B∗′

n D)ΣΣ′

(Cπ + B∗′

n D)′

−(Cπ + B∗′

n D)Σλ0,

B∗′n+1 =

(Cπ + B∗′

n D) (

MD−1 − Σλ1

)− Δ

′.

For a one-month real bond, in particular, we obtain

p1∗t = Et [mt+1]

= exp((

−Δ′+ Cπ

(MD

−1 − Σλ1

))Zt − CπΣ

(λ0 − 1

2Σ′C′

π

)),

which can be used to start the recursion. Note that the short-termreal rate is

r∗t = CπΣ

(λ0 − 1

2Σ′C′

π

)+

′ − Cπ

(MD

−1 − Σλ1

))Zt.

Derivation of Inflation Risk Premium and Break-EvenInflation Rates

For all maturities, recall that the continuously compounded yield is,for nominal and real bonds, respectively,

yt,n = −An

n− B′

n

nZt

Page 41: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 41

y∗t,n = −A∗

n

n− B∗′

n

nZt.

The yield spread is therefore simply

yt,n − y∗t,n = − 1

n

(An − A∗

n

)− 1

n

(B′

n−B∗′n

)Zt,

where

An+1 − A∗n+1 = An − A∗

n −(B′

n − B∗′n

)DΣλ0 + CπΣλ0

− 12CπΣΣ′C′

π − CπΣΣ′D′B∗n

+12

(B′

nDΣΣ′D′Bn − B∗′n DΣΣ′D′B∗

n

)B′

n+1 − B∗′n+1 =

(B′

n − B∗′n

)D

(MD

−1 − Σλ1

)− Cπ

(MD

−1 − Σλ1

).

Note that the nominal bond equation can be solved explicitly as

An = A1 +n−1∑i=1

(12B

′iDΣΣ′D′Bi − B

′iDΣλ0

),

B′n = −Δ

′n−1∑i=0

[D

(MD

−1 − Σλ1

)]i

.

Similarly, for the real bond A∗n we obtain

A∗n = nCπΣ

(12Σ′C′

π − λ0

)

+n−1∑i=1

(B∗′

i DΣΣ′C′π +

12B∗′

i DΣΣ′D′B∗i − B∗′

i DΣλ0

)

B∗′n =

(Cπ

(MD

−1 − Σλ1

)− Δ

′) n−1∑i=0

[D

(MD

−1 − Σλ1

)]i

.

Page 42: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

42 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Note that the law of motion of the transformed state vector canbe written as Zt+1 = DMD

−1Zt + DΣξ1,t+1, so that the term

D(MD−1 − Σλ1) represents the expected change in Zt under Q.

We can then define a new matrix M = D(MD−1 − Σλ1). Note

also that the sum∑n−1

i=0 Mi can be solved out as∑n−1

i=0 Mi =(I − M)−1(I − Mn) for bonds of finite maturity.12 Note that wecould equivalently write

∑n−1i=0 Mi = (I − Mn)(I − M)−1.

For the state-dependent component of bond prices, it follows that

B′n = −Δ

′ (I − M

)−1 (I − Mn

)B∗′

n =(CπD−1M − Δ

′) (I − M

)−1 (I − Mn

),

and

B∗′n − B

′n = CπD−1M

(I − M

)−1 (I − Mn

).

Note also that

Et [πt+n] = CπMnD−1Zt,

and that expected average inflation up to t + n, πt+n is

Etπt+n =1n

n∑i=1

Etπt+i

= Cπ

∑ni=1 Mi

nD−1Zt,

or, writing this out explicitly,

Etπt+n =1nCπ (I − Mn) (I − M)−1 MD

−1Zt.

12For bonds of infinite maturity, the sum will only be defined if all eigenvaluesof M are inside the unit circle. This is not necessarily true, even if the eigenvaluesof M are within the unit circle by construction.

Page 43: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 43

We are now ready to define the break-even inflation rate as

yt,n − y∗t,n =

1n

(A∗

n − An

)+

1n

(B∗′

n − B′n

)Zt

=1n

(A∗

n − An

)+

1nCπD−1M

(I − M

)−1 (I − Mn

)Zt,

where A∗n and An are defined above.

The inflation risk premium can then be defined as

yt,n − y∗t,n − Etπt+n =

1n

(A∗

n − An

)+

1n

(B∗′

n − B′n

)Zt − Etπt+n,

whose state-dependent component can be written explicitly as

1n

(B∗′

n − B′n

)Zt − Etπt+n =

1nCπ

[D−1M

(I − M

)−1 (I − Mn

)− M (I − Mn) (I − M)−1 D−1

]Zt.

Note that the time-varying component of the inflation risk pre-mium is zero at all maturities when the λ1 prices of risk are zero.To see this, note that for λ1 = 0 we obtain M = DMD

−1, so that

(DMD−1

)n = DMnD−1, and

1n

(B∗′

n − B′n

)Zt − Etπt+n

=1nCπM

[(I − M)−1 D−1

(I − DM

nD−1

)− (I − Mn) (I − M)−1 D−1

]Zt

=1nCπM

[(I − M)−1 (I − Mn) − (I − Mn) (I − M)−1

]D−1Zt

=1nCπM

[n−1∑i=0

Mi −n−1∑i=0

Mi

]D−1Zt = 0.

Kalman Filter Matrices

Given the model solution, the nominal and real bond pricing equa-tions, and the expressions for the survey forecasts, we can proceedto define the observation equation as

Page 44: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

44 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Wt =

⎡⎢⎢⎣AA∗

00

⎤⎥⎥⎦ +

⎡⎢⎢⎣BB∗

CG

⎤⎥⎥⎦X1,t

=

⎡⎢⎢⎣AA∗

00

⎤⎥⎥⎦ +

⎡⎢⎢⎣Bo

Bo∗

Co

Go

⎤⎥⎥⎦Xo1,t +

⎡⎢⎢⎣Bu

Bu∗

Cu

Gu

⎤⎥⎥⎦Xu1,t

≡ K + L′Xo1,t + H′Xu

1,t,

and the measurement equation as

Xu1,t = FXu

1,t−1 + vu1,t,

where F selects the sub-matrix of M corresponding to Xu1 .

Next, the unobservable variables are estimated using the Kalmanfilter. In doing so, we first introduce a vector wt of serially uncor-related measurement errors corresponding to the observable vari-ables Wt. Letting R denote the variance-covariance matrix of themeasurement errors and Q the variances of the unobservable statevariables Xu

1,t, we have

Wt = K + L′Xo1,t + H′Xu

1,t + wt, E [wtw′t] = R

Xu1,t = FXu

1,t−1 + vu1,t, E

[vu

1,tvu′1,t

]= Q.

While we assume that all observable variables are subject to meas-urement error, we limit the number of parameters to estimate byassuming that all yield measurement errors have identical varianceand that all errors are mutually uncorrelated:

R =

⎡⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢⎢⎣

σ2m,y 0 0 0 0 0

0. . . 0 0 0 0

0 0 σ2m,y 0 0 0

0 0 0 σ2m,x 0 0

0 0 0 0 σ2m,π 0

0 0 0 0 0. . .

⎤⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥⎥⎦.

Page 45: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 45

Note also that

Q =

⎡⎢⎢⎣σ2

π∗ 0 0 00 σ2

η 0 00 0 σ2

π 00 0 0 σ2

x

⎤⎥⎥⎦ .

References

An, S., and F. Schorfheide. 2007. “Bayesian Analysis of DSGE Mod-els.” Econometric Reviews 26 (2–4): 113–72.

Ang, A., and M. Piazzesi. 2003. “A No-Arbitrage Vector Autore-gression of Term Structure Dynamics with Macroeconomic andLatent Variables.” Journal of Monetary Economics 50 (4):745–87.

Bank for International Settlements. 2009. “Overview: Investors Pon-der Depth and Duration of Global Downturn.” BIS QuarterlyReview (March): 1–17.

Beechey, M. J., B. K. Johannsen, and A. T. Levin. 2011. “Are Long-Run Inflation Expectations Anchored More Firmly in the EuroArea than in the United States?” American Economic Journal:Macroeconomics 3 (2): 104–29.

Chernov, M., and P. Mueller. 2012. “The Term Structure of InflationExpectations.” Journal of Financial Economics 106 (2): 367–94.

Christensen, J. H. E., J. A. Lopez, and G. D. Rudebusch. 2010.“Inflation Expectations and Risk Premiums in an Arbitrage-FreeModel of Nominal and Real Bond Yields.” Journal of Money,Credit and Banking 42 (s1): 143–78.

Clarida, R., J. Galı, and M. Gertler. 1998. “Monetary Policy Rulesin Practice: Some International Evidence.” European EconomicReview 42 (6): 1033–67.

Dai, Q., and K. J. Singleton. 2000. “Specification Analysis of AffineTerm Structure Models.” Journal of Finance 55 (5): 1943–78.

D’Amico, S., D. Kim, and M. Wei. 2008. “Tips from TIPS: TheInformational Content of Treasury Inflation-Protected SecurityPrices.” BIS Working Paper No. 248.

D’Auria, F., C. Denis, K. Havik, K. McMorrow, C. Planas, R. Raci-borski, W. Roger, and A. Rossi. 2010. “The Production Function

Page 46: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

46 International Journal of Central Banking September 2014

Methodology for Calculating Potential Growth Rates and Out-put Gaps.” European Commission Economic Paper No. 420.

Duffee, G. R. 2002. “Term Premia and Interest Rate Forecasts inAffine Models.” Journal of Finance 57 (1): 405–43.

Duffie, D., and R. Kan. 1996. “A Yield-Factor Model of InterestRates.” Mathematical Finance 6 (4): 379–406.

Durham, J. B. 2006. “An Estimate of the Inflation Risk PremiumUsing a Three-Factor Affine Term Structure Model.” FEDSWorking Paper No. 2006-42, Board of Governors of the FederalReserve System.

Ejsing, J., M. Grothe, and O. Grothe. 2012. “Liquidity and CreditRisk Premia in Government Bond Yields.” ECB Working PaperNo. 1440.

Evans, M. D. D. 1998. “Real Rates, Expected Inflation, and InflationRisk Premia.” Journal of Finance 53 (1): 187–218.

Fuhrer, J. C. 2000. “Habit Formation in Consumption and ItsImplications for Monetary Policy Models.” American EconomicReview 90 (3): 367–90.

Galati, G., S. Poelhekke, and C. Zhou. 2011. “Did the Crisis AffectInflation Expectations?” International Journal of Central Bank-ing 7 (1): 167–207.

Galı, J., and M. Gertler. 1999. “Inflation Dynamics: A StructuralEconometric Analysis.” Journal of Monetary Economics 44 (2):195–222.

Garcıa, J. A., and T. Werner. 2008. “Inflation Risks and InflationRisk Premia.” Mimeo, European Central Bank.

Goffe, L. G., G. D. Ferrier, and J. Rogers. 1994. “Global Optimiza-tion of Statistical Functions with Simulated Annealing.” Journalof Econometrics 60 (1–2): 65–99.

Gurkaynak, R., B. Sack, and J. Wright. 2007. “The U.S. TreasuryYield Curve: 1961 to the Present.” Journal of Monetary Eco-nomics 54 (8): 2291–2304.

———. 2010. “The TIPS Yield Curve and Inflation Compensation.”American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 2 (1): 70–92.

Hamilton, J. D. 1994. Time Series Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Prince-ton University Press.

Hordahl, P., and O. Tristani. 2012. “Inflation Risk Premia in theTerm Structure of Interest Rates.” Journal of the European Eco-nomic Association 10 (3): 634–57.

Page 47: Inflation Risk Premia in the Euro Area and the United States · such premia display remarkably similar properties in the United States and in the euro area across various maturities:

Vol. 10 No. 3 Inflation Risk Premia 47

Hordahl, P., O. Tristani, and D. Vestin. 2006. “A Joint Economet-ric Model of Macroeconomic and Term Structure Dynamics.”Journal of Econometrics 131 (1–2): 405–44.

Kim, D. H., and A. Orphanides. 2012. “Term Structure Estima-tion with Survey Data on Interest Rate Forecasts.” Journal ofFinancial and Quantitative Analysis 47 (01): 241–72.

Pflueger, C. E., and L. M. Viceira. 2013. “Return Predictabilityin the Treasury Market: Real Rates, Inflation, and Liquidity.”NBER Working Paper No. 16892.

Rudebusch, G. 2002. “Assessing Nominal Income Rules for MonetaryPolicy with Model and Data Uncertainty.” Economic Journal112 (479): 402–32.

Soderlind, P. 1999. “Solution and Estimation of RE Macromod-els with Optimal Policy.” European Economic Review 43 (4–6):975–1011.

Stambaugh, R. F. 1988. “The Information in Forward Rates: Impli-cations for Models of the Term Structure.” Journal of FinancialEconomics 21 (1): 41–70.

Taylor, J. B. 1993. “Discretion vs. Policy Rules in Practice.”Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39(December): 195–214.