information sharing by competitors: minimizing antitrust

47
Presenting a live 90minute webinar with interactive Q&A Information Sharing by Competitors: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust Liability Avoiding GunJumping in Mergers and Competitor Collaborations T d ’ f l f 1pm Eastern | 12pm Central | 11am Mountain | 10am Pacific TUESDAY, DECEMBER 14, 2010 T odays faculty features: William Blumenthal, Partner, Clifford Chance, Washington, D.C. Joseph G. Krauss, Partner, Hogan Lovells, Washington, D.C. Alan Ryan, Partner, Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer, Brussels The audio portion of the conference may be accessed via the telephone or by using your computer's speakers. Please refer to the instructions emailed to registrants for additional information. If you have any questions, please contact Customer Service at 1-800-926-7926 ext. 10.

Upload: others

Post on 06-Oct-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Presenting a live 90‐minute webinar with interactive Q&A

Information Sharing by Competitors: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust LiabilityAvoiding Gun‐Jumping in Mergers and Competitor Collaborations

T d ’ f l f

1pm Eastern | 12pm Central | 11am Mountain | 10am Pacific

TUESDAY, DECEMBER 14, 2010

Today’s faculty features:

William Blumenthal, Partner, Clifford Chance, Washington, D.C.

Joseph G. Krauss, Partner, Hogan Lovells, Washington, D.C.

Alan Ryan, Partner, Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer, Brussels

The audio portion of the conference may be accessed via the telephone or by using your computer's speakers.Please refer to the instructions emailed to registrants for additional information. If you have any questions,please contact Customer Service at 1-800-926-7926 ext. 10.

Page 2: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Continuing Education Credits FOR LIVE EVENT ONLY

For CLE and/or CPE purposes, please let us know how many people are listening at your location by completing each of the following steps:

• Close the notification box

• In the chat box, type (1) your company name and (2) the number of attendees at your location

• Click the blue icon beside the box to send

Page 3: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Tips for Optimal Quality

S d Q litSound QualityIf you are listening via your computer speakers, please note that the quality of your sound will vary depending on the speed and quality of your internet connection.

If the sound quality is not satisfactory and you are listening via your computer speakers, you may listen via the phone: dial 1-866-873-1442 and enter your PIN when prompted Otherwise please send us a chat or e mail when prompted. Otherwise, please send us a chat or e-mail [email protected] immediately so we can address the problem.

If you dialed in and have any difficulties during the call, press *0 for assistance.

Viewing QualityTo maximize your screen, press the F11 key on your keyboard. To exit full screen, press the F11 key againpress the F11 key again.

Page 4: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

InformationInformation Sharing Between Competitors

December 14, 2010 Strafford CLE Webinar

William Blumenthal

Page 5: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

This Presentation

Focus on mergers, joint ventures, and other legitimate collaborationslegitimate collaborations

Limited to arrangements between competitorscompetitors Standards generally more permissive when

arrangements do not involve competitorsarrangements do not involve competitors

Excludes issues arising from cartels and naked restraintsnaked restraints Important, but not today’s presentationDistinction from today’s issues sometimes blurs

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 5

Distinction from today s issues sometimes blurs

Page 6: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Two Broad Families of Issues

“Gunjumping” before merger closing or JV formationformation “Information sharing / diligence” strandDistinct from “premature control” strandDistinct from premature control strand

Ancillary restraints and collateral effects in the context of ongoing cooperationthe context of ongoing cooperation Examples on next slide

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 6

Page 7: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Ongoing Cooperation: Examples

Joint venturesWhere co venturers compete with each otherWhere co-venturers compete with each other outside the venture

Where a co-venturer competes with the ventureWhere a co venturer competes with the venture

Joint activity often not performed through entitiesentities Joint development arrangements Joint marketing and promotiong p Joint purchasing

Standard-setting organizations

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 7

S a da d se g o ga a o s

Page 8: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Ongoing Cooperation: Examples 2

Distribution by vertically integrated firmsWhere a manufacturer sells through independentWhere a manufacturer sells through independent distributors and through own distribution arm

Where a component manufacturer sells toWhere a component manufacturer sells to independent downstream firms and transfers in internal manufacturing operations

Trade association data collection and dissemination

Benchmarking activities

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 8

Page 9: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Some Key Authority on Jointness

Leading historical Supreme Court cases on price informationprice informationMaple Flooring (1925)Cement Manufacturers Protective Ass’n (1925)Cement Manufacturers Protective Ass n (1925)Container Corporation (1969)United States Gypsum (1978)United States Gypsum (1978)

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 9

Page 10: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Some Key Authority on Jointness 2

Some other key Supreme Court cases National Society of Professional Engineers (1978)National Society of Professional Engineers (1978)

Broadcast Music (1979)Maricopa County Medical Society (1982)Maricopa County Medical Society (1982)NCAA v. University of Oklahoma (1984)

Three lower court cases worth mention Three lower court cases worth mention Addyston Pipe (6th Cir. 1898), aff’d (1899)United States v Morgan (S D N Y 1953)United States v. Morgan (S.D.N.Y. 1953)United States v. Brown University (3d Cir. 1993)

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 10

Page 11: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Some Key Authority on Jointness 3

Major government policy statementsHealth Care Statements (1996)Health Care Statements (1996)

Guidelines on Competitor Collaboration (2000) Various business review letters Various business review letters

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 11

Page 12: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Main Legal Principles

Information exchange as discussed here is subject to rule of reason treatmentsubject to rule of reason treatment

Certain content is riskier than other contentP i i f ti i i ki th t d th Price information is riskier than cost and other non-price information

Detailed information is riskier than aggregatedDetailed information is riskier than aggregated information

– Multiplicity of sources– Granularity of content

Future information is riskier than stale information

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 12

Page 13: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

But Uncertainties Remain

When are buffers required?Internal firewalls Internal firewalls

Third-party intermediaries

What is required as to efficiencies? What is required as to efficiencies?When must they be shown?

By whom? By whom?How proven?

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 13

Page 14: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

But Uncertainties Remain

When are buffers required?Internal firewalls Internal firewalls

Third-party intermediaries

What is required as to efficiencies? What is required as to efficiencies?When must they be shown?

By whom? By whom?How proven?When presumed?When presumed?

– Even antagonists recognize potential procompetitive benefits and efficiency gains

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 14

Page 15: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

But Uncertainties Remain 2

How is competitive effect to be assessed?Who has the burden of proving effect?Who has the burden of proving effect?

How are benefits and adverse effects to be measured?measured?

Material differences emerging between US and Europeand EuropeUS standards seem to be more permissive Alan Ryan will be discussing in several minutesy g

We will be working through examples of the various uncertainties later in this program

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 15

a ous u ce a es a e s p og a

Page 16: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Special Case: The Premerger Context

Joe Krauss will be addressing in greater detail momentarilydetail momentarily

To anticipate his remarks:C d b FTC d DOJ b i iConcern expressed by FTC and DOJ beginning around 1990

Has led to protocols governing the sharing ofHas led to protocols governing the sharing of competitively sensitive information between competitors

Concern largely limited to competitors– But parallel strand of “premature control” applies to non-

competing merger parties as well

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 16

p g g p

Page 17: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Special Case: The Premerger Context 2

Mostly developed through agency consent settlementssettlements Insilco (1998)Computer Associates (2002)Computer Associates (2002)Gemstar-TV Guide (2003)

All involve egregious conduct All involve egregious conduct One published case in federal courts

Omnicare (N D Ill 2009) on appeal to 7th CirOmnicare (N.D. Ill. 2009), on appeal to 7th Cir.

Information Sharing Between Competitors · December 14, 2010 17

Page 18: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

I f iInformation Sharing Between William Blumenthal gCompetitors

William [email protected]

www.cliffordchance.com

Clifford Chance, 2001 K Street NW, Washington DC 20006-1001 USA© Clifford Chance US LLP 2010

Page 19: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Information Sharing by Competitors:g y pIn the Premerger Context

Joseph G. KrausspDecember 14, 2010

Page 20: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Applicable Antitrust LawsApplicable Antitrust Laws• Sherman Act Sec. 1 – prohibits contracts,

combinations, or conspiracies in restraint of trade • Also applies to company’s conduct in premerger

time period

• Clayton Act Sec. 7a (HSR Act) – prohibits certain mergers, acquisitions, and joint ventures from being g , q , j gconsummated before end of the HSR waiting period

• Merging parties are prohibited from “acting as ” i t i ti f HSR i done” prior to expiration of HSR period

www.hoganlovells.com 20

Page 21: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Guidance from Merger CasesGuidance from Merger Cases

• Insilco (1998)• Computer Associates (2002)• Gemstar-TV Guide (2003)( )• Omnicare (2009)

www.hoganlovells.com 21

Page 22: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

U.S. v. Gemstar/TV GuideU.S. v. Gemstar/TV Guide

• Parties were competitors in providing interactive program guides p g g

• Merger stemmed from settlement discussions of a pending patent infringement litigation

• DOJ alleged:“Slo roll” agreement agreed to dela competing for– “Slow roll” agreement — agreed to delay competing for customers until able to act jointly

– Allocation of customers — TV Guide agreed to handle cable operators while Gemstar to focus on consumer electronicselectronics

– Agreement on prices and terms to be offered during pre-consummation period

• Remedies:$– Civil penalties — $5.6 million

– Optional rescission of contracts– Injunction against these acts in future transactions

www.hoganlovells.com 22

Page 23: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Omnicare, Inc. v. UnitedHealth Group, Inc., et al. (2009)p, , ( )

• Plaintiff (a customer) alleged that parties shared “strategic” information related to its businesses before the merger was closed

• Plaintiff alleged this information impacted subsequent negotiations and led to it paying higher reimbursement rates

• Trial Court decision:– acknowledged the need for a buyer to obtain information from a

seller during due diligence – noted need to strike a balance between legitimate business

conversations during merger talks and opening the door for “sham” merger negotiations with free exchange of competitively sensitive information between rivalsinformation between rivals

– Court set forth factors to consider, including: (a) who was involved in the information exchange and what precautions were taken to limit distribution of competitively sensitive information, (b) whether the specific information exchanged was necessary(b) whether the specific information exchanged was necessary to evaluate the transaction, (c) whether the information exchanged was competitively sensitive, (d) when the information exchange occurred, and (e) whether pre merger integration planning was clearly

www.hoganlovells.com 23

(e) whether pre-merger integration planning was clearly prospective in nature.

Page 24: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

FTC Guidance in the Premerger ContextFTC Guidance in the Premerger Context“On the one hand, firms proposing to merge are not yet a single

entity, and their activities are subject to Section 1 of the Sherman Act 2 which governs collective action in restraint of trade [and]Act,2 which governs collective action in restraint of trade . . . [and] Section 7A of the Clayton Act,3 more commonly known as the Hart-Scott-Rodino Antitrust Improvements Act . . .

On the other hand, the merging firms have a legitimate interest in engaging in certain forms of coordination that would not be g g gexpected except in the merger context. The most common forms are due diligence and transition planning, both of which necessarily will involve exchanges of information at levels of detail that would not normally occur among independent firms. In addition merging firms sometimes enter into covenants oraddition, merging firms sometimes enter into covenants or engage in practices that would not normally be seen among independent firms. These forms of premerger coordination will often be reasonable and even necessary to implement the legitimate objectives of the merger agreement. ”legitimate objectives of the merger agreement.

William Blumenthal, General Counsel, Federal Trade Commission,

The Rhetoric of Gun Jumping Remarks before the Association of Corporate Counsel

www.hoganlovells.com 24

The Rhetoric of Gun-Jumping, Remarks before the Association of Corporate Counsel(Nov. 10, 2005)

Page 25: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Why Is This Still Important?Why Is This Still Important?

• Investigations of information sharing can be extremely costly and burdensomeburdensome– Threat of treble damages– Substantial civil damages– Substantial criminal penalties for some types of antitrust law violationsSubstantial criminal penalties for some types of antitrust law violations

• M&A transactions threatened – An investigation can significantly slow antitrust review of a transaction

• Substantial document requests• Substantial document requests• Detailed interrogatories• Depositions and interviews• Major distraction• Major distraction

– Can delay consummation of merger and put transaction at risk– Investigations can result in penalties and loss of business

Can happen e en if nderl ing transaction does not raise serio s

www.hoganlovells.com 25

– Can happen even if underlying transaction does not raise serious issues

Page 26: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

General Guidelines

www.hoganlovells.com 26

Page 27: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

A Balancing of Interests in Sharing Information PremergerPremerger

Legitimate Interests of the Parties• Value assets• Preserve value of deal prior to closing• Integration planning

Government’s Enforcement Goals

M i t i th ti i d d t i d• Maintain the parties as independent companies and preserve competition prior to closing

• Preserve the government’s ability to investigate the titi f t ti i tcompetitive consequences of a transaction prior to

closing• Ensure that the antitrust agencies can obtain an

ff ti d

www.hoganlovells.com 27

effective remedy

Page 28: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

General GuidelinesGeneral Guidelines

• Avoid exchange of information that is titi l iti i ticompetitively sensitive or impose precautions

to limit distribution of competitively sensitive information

• Limit information exchanged to that which is necessary to evaluate the transaction or for legitimate transition planninglegitimate transition planning

• Manage the timing of the information exchange – the closer to closing (and after premerger clearance), the betterg ( p g ),

• Limit premerger integration planning to that which is clearly prospective in nature – plan but not implement prior to closing

www.hoganlovells.com 28

closing

Page 29: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

What is competitively sensitive information?What is competitively sensitive information?• Non-public current or future prices • Non-public current or future marketing plansp g p• Competitively sensitive customer-specific or

contract-specific data• Non public current or prospective• Non-public current or prospective

profitability or cost data• Information regarding specific business

t iti f hi h th ti i htopportunities for which the parties might compete on prior to closing

• Research and development expendituresp p• Trade secrets • Non-public information on output expansion

or reduction plans

www.hoganlovells.com 29

or reduction plans.

Page 30: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Guidelines for Exchanges of Competitively Sensitive InformationSensitive Information

• Avoid disclosure of information which is competitively sensitive for the client, their

li t thsuppliers or customers, or others– Historical information on these topics is generally

somewhat less sensitive • When sensitive competitive information must be

disclosed, limit the details of the disclosure and the people receiving the information – Do not disclose to pricing or marketing personnel– To the greatest extent possible, limit exposure to

people who are not involved in any competitive or other business activities between the parties (e.g., accountants, consultants, lawyers and operations personnel from other areas of the parties’

ti )

www.hoganlovells.com 30

operations)

Page 31: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Concluding Thoughtsg g

www.hoganlovells.com 31

Page 32: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Summary GuidelinesSummary Guidelines• Company and Target must remain independent companies

until closing and should not take any action that reduces that independence or reduces any competition between them.

• But, due diligence/integration teams can and should be allowed to review non-public information to properly value theallowed to review non public information to properly value the business and make plans that will enable the parties to integrate their operations after the acquisition has closed.

• There should be no discussions agreements understandings• There should be no discussions, agreements, understandings, or exchanges of information that would eliminate or reduce any competition between the companies before the acquisition is completedcompleted.

• Company and Target cannot become involved in each other’s day-to-day operations.

www.hoganlovells.com 32

Page 33: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

BiographyBiographyJoe Krauss is a partner in the Antitrust, Competition and Economic Regulation Practice Group of Hogan Lovells US LLP, resident in the firm’s Washington, D.C. office.His practice is devoted entirely to the area of antitrust and economic regulation, with a particular emphasis on merger and acquisition counseling and litigation in all industries, and before federal, state, and foreign antitrust authorities. He has counseled clients in numerous matters relating to mergers and acquisitions, j i t t di t ib ti i Sh A t d H t S tt R di A t li J hjoint ventures, distribution issues, Sherman Act, and Hart-Scott-Rodino Act compliance. Joe has represented clients from a number of industries, including automotive, electric utility, manufacturing, health, natural resources, e-commerce, computer hardware and software, and telecommunications, before both the U.S. Federal Trade Commission (FTC) and the Antitrust Division of the U.S. Department of Justice in merger investigations, civil nonmerger investigations, and in compliance matters before the agencies.

Joe joined Hogan & Hartson in 1999 after serving 11 years at the FTC. During his tenure at the commission, he served in a variety of capacities, most recently as the Assistant Director of the Premerger Notification Office and Acting Assistant Director and Deputy Assistant Director of the Mergers II DivisionNotification Office and Acting Assistant Director and Deputy Assistant Director of the Mergers II Division where he was responsible for the management and oversight of investigations of proposed mergers in a number of industries, including computer, chemicals, natural resources, and automotive parts. Joe’s career at the commission included serving two commissioners as an attorney advisor counseling on matters of antitrust policy and enforcement.

He has spoken numerous times on antitrust enforcement and policy. In addition, he has traveled to Eastern Europe to assist competition agencies there in their development and enforcement of antitrust law and policy and has met with numerous representatives of competition bureaus throughout the world to advise

joseph.krauss@hoganlovells com

Joseph G. Krauss Partner

Washington, D.C.

policy, and has met with numerous representatives of competition bureaus throughout the world to advise and discuss issues of antitrust enforcement and policy. He has spoken at international competition conferences in Bonn, Germany; Capetown, South Africa; Bogotá, Columbia; and Moscow.Joe is a nongovernmental advisor to the Mergers Working Group of the International Competition Network (ICN).

Joe recently was appointed Trustee at the request of the U.S. Department of Justice to oversee the divestiture of a steel mill to resolve competitive concerns raised by a merger of international steel

d J th l d ti t d d fi iti h t l d t $810

lovells.comPhone

+1.202.637.5832Fax +1.202.637.5910

producers. Joe oversaw the sales process and negotiated a definitive purchase agreement valued at $810 million.

He has also been profiled in a number of prestigious publications, including the most recent Chambers USA, which noted, "Formerly at the FTC, Joseph Krauss... gained client commendation for his 'strategically sound' advice and 'strong negotiation skills with the agencies.'"

C O

www.hoganlovells.com 33

EDUCATION J.D., Delaware Law School of Widener University, 1983 B.S., University of Delaware, 1978

Page 34: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

www.hoganlovells.com

Hogan Lovells has offices in:

Abu DhabiAlicanteAmsterdamBaltimoreBeijingBerlinBoulderBrussels

CaracasColorado SpringsDenverDubaiDusseldorfFrankfurtHamburgHanoi

Hong KongHoustonJeddah*LondonLos AngelesMadridMiamiMilan

MunichNew YorkNorthern VirginiaParisPhiladelphiaPragueRiyadh*Rome

ShanghaiSilicon ValleySingaporeTokyoUlaanbaatar*WarsawWashington DCZagreb*Brussels

Budapest*HanoiHo Chi Minh City

MilanMoscow

RomeSan Francisco

Zagreb

"Hogan Lovells" or the "firm" refers to the international legal practice comprising Hogan Lovells International LLP, Hogan Lovells US LLP, Hogan Lovells Worldwide Group (a Swiss Verein), and their affiliated businesses, each of which is a separate legal entity. Hogan Lovells International LLP is a limited liability partnership registered in England and Wales with registered number OC323639. Registered office and principal place of business: Atlantic House, Holborn Viaduct, London EC1A 2FG. Hogan Lovells US LLP is a limited liability partnership registered in the District of Columbia.

The word "partner" is used to refer to a member of Hogan Lovells International LLP or a partner of Hogan Lovells US LLP, or an employee or consultant with equivalent standing and qualifications, and to a partner, member, employee or consultant in any of their affiliated businesses who has equivalent standing. Rankings and quotes from legal directories and other sources may refer to the former firms of Hogan & Hartson LLP and Lovells LLP. Where case studies are included, results achieved do not guarantee similar outcomes for other clients. New York State Notice: Attorney Advertising.

© Copyright Hogan Lovells 2010. All rights reserved.

* Associated offices

Page 35: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Information Sharing by Competitionsg y pThe EU perspective

Alan RyanAlan Ryan14 December 2010

Page 36: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

No “one size fits all” approach to information sharing across all scenariosscenarios

Different approaches toDifferent approaches to

Pre-merger discussionsPre merger discussions

JVs: within the JV, JV to parent, parent to parent

Efficiency – enhancing information exchange vs hard core cartels y g g

Slide 36

Page 37: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Pre – merger discussions

Art 7(I) EC Merger Regulation prohibits “implementation” prior to clearance

No case law on information exchange as implementation (some decisions on deal closing) but several investigations

Pre-merger information exchange also falls under Art 101 TFEU, again no specific case law

Standard practice is to apply US practice to pre-merger exchanges, p pp y p p g g ,including due diligence but to apply greater caution as no “legitimate interest” exception

Slide 37

Page 38: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Joint Ventures

No JV exception

Only exception to “standard” competition law is for subsidiary with no Only exception to standard competition law is for subsidiary with no independent autonomy from parent (see Viho), i.e. wholly owned subsidiary or majority owned subsidiary with small, inactive other shareholdersshareholders

Numerous cases of a JV or affiliate being fined for cartel behaviour separately from its parents

Several cases of parties being fined for conspiracy with a subsidiary (e.g. Kodak)

Even a “concentrative JV” cleared under the EC Merger Regulation is Even a concentrative JV cleared under the EC Merger Regulation is an independent party from its parents so can be fined for parent-JV conspiracy

Slide 38

Page 39: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Joint Ventures

Need for strong firewalls between parent and JV and parent to parent

e.g. COMP/M.4760 Amadeus/Sabre/JV (Moneydirect), para 25: “The Commission has analysed closely the arrangements that will be put in place by A d d S b t t ti titi i f ti “ ill ” t dAmadeus and Sabre to prevent anti-competitive information “spill-over” to and from the JV. The Joint Venture Agreement specifies which types of information will be shared between Moneydirect, Amadeus and Sabre. No information that is not normally available to shareholders of a JV will be disclosed by s ot o a y a a ab e to s a e o de s o a J be d sc osed byMoneydirect to its parent companies. As a general rule, information obtained and produced by the JV will be treated as confidential and will not be made available to the parent companies. Amadeus’ and Sabre’s access to information will be limited to their own respective transactions The parties state in the Jointwill be limited to their own respective transactions. The parties state in the Joint Venture Agreement that they consider it paramount to keep confidential pricing and transaction information of the JV’s customers. The only persons from the parent companies that will be granted access to detailed information about p p gcustomer’ payment transactions will be employees formally seconded to the JV that do not have any sales or managing function within Amadeus or Sabre.”

Slide 39

Page 40: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Legitimate efficiency – enhancing information exchanges

“Above the Table” information exchanges often, but not always,analysed under Art 101 (3) TFEU (Similar purpose to rule of reason y ( ) ( p panalysis): focus on type of information exchanged and market structure might it lead to reducing competitive uncertainty

“But not always”: depends on perceived purpose of exchange: if profitBut not always : depends on perceived purpose of exchange: if profit maximisation, then even if done at customers’ request, real risk of being sanctioned as a hard core cartel

“ nder the table” information e changes al a s in estigated as hard “under the table” information exchanges always investigated as hard core cartel e.g. Plasterboard

Slide 40

Page 41: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

UK Tractor Registration Exchange

Commission decision of 1992, upheld by European Court of Justice (Case C-7/95P)( )

UK Government Scheme for exchange of information on tractors registered by type and location

UK tractor sales market considered oligopolistic

Very detailed information: retail sales and market shares pre locality (based on post code), tractor type and time period( p ), yp p

Information only available to producers, not consumers

Exchange found to infringe the Art 85, now 101

Slide 41

Page 42: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Woodpulp

Commission Decision: system of price announcements considered to support an illegal cartelpp g

European Court of Justice annulled: price announcements might be rational response to need for sellers and buyers to minimise commercial riskcommercial risk

Slide 42

Page 43: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

COMP/M.2830 GF-X

EC Merger Regulation clearance for Global Freight Exchange: B2B platform “facilitating the sale of air freight capacity between air freight forwarders (the buyers( and air freight carriers (the sellers)”( y ( g ( )

“GF-X is setup in such a way (i.e., confidentiality rules, firewalls safeguards etc) as to prevent the exchange of commercially sensitive information between the members The Commission’s investigationinformation between the members. The Commission s investigation confirmed that such an exchange is technically impossible. In particular, member carriers will not have access to the air freight fares or capacity figures of other member carriers. Moreover, sales negotiations will be g , gconducted on a bilateral basis and as such they will not reveal more information than is currently made available to buyers under the existing sales channels (i.e., telephone or fax). the creation of the joint venture will therefore not lead to any co-ordination for the competitive conduct of the parent companies on the market for air freight transport”

Slide 43

Page 44: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

© Freshfields Bruckhaus Deringer LLP 2010

This material is for general information only and is not intended to provide legal advice.

Alan RyanAlan [email protected]

+32 2 504 7076

Slide 44

Page 45: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Hypothetical #1

Giant Defense Manufacturer (GDM) produces nosecones, rockets, and engines, which together make a "rocket system " It is the only fully-integrated supplier of

yp

which together make a rocket system. It is the only fully integrated supplier of rocket systems (at least of the type relevant here). Specialized Engine Supplier (SES) purchases nosecones and rockets from GDM, which SES then marries up with its proprietary engines to offer a competing rocket system. A lot of technology goes i t h f th t d th t d t k t th th tinto each of the components, and the components need to work together, so that SES needs to provide detailed technical specifications to GDM. In addition, to develop its bids for the rocket systems that it sells, SES needs detailed transfer pricing for at least the nosecones and rockets that it purchases from GDM. Are there p g pany limits on GDM's using its knowledge of SES's technical specs and costs (that is, the price received by GDM, the cost to SES, for the nosecones and rockets) when it frames the pricing for its own rocket system?

45

Page 46: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Hypothetical #2yp

Major Sports League has 20 teams in various geographic areas. All of the teams sell paraphernalia such as caps and jerseys Each reserves the right to license its ownparaphernalia, such as caps and jerseys. Each reserves the right to license its own marks to vendors and to sell the paraphernalia. In addition, each licenses Major Sports League Marketing (MSLM), a joint venture of the 20 teams, to use and sublicense its marks to paraphernalia vendors, with MSLM then selling the products t ti l t hi h h i th hi d bto national accounts, which have a presence in the geographic area served by every team. Are there any limits on the respective teams' sharing information with MSLM about the prices at which they sell their individual paraphernalia? And are there any limits on the information that the individual teams, as co-owners of MSLM, receive , ,about the prices at which MSLM sells to the national accounts?

46

Page 47: Information Sharing by Competitors: Minimizing Antitrust

Hypothetical #3ypWidget Standard Setting Organization (WSSO) has a central role in developing voluntary standards on key technologies that are central to the production of modern-day widgets, and 200 widget producers, their suppliers, and their customers are allday widgets, and 200 widget producers, their suppliers, and their customers are all members. WSSO passes a bylaw requiring that members disclose all patents, patent applications, and in-lab technologies that may reasonably anticipated to give rise to patent applications within two years. Legal or illegal?

Midsize Widget Company (MWC), with roughly a 5% share of widget sales, is developing a break-through technology in its labs, and it believes the technology will enable it to leapfrog the rest of the industry. The technology can be invented around, p g y gythough, so MWC believes it will yield a material competitive advantage for only three years from the date that rivals learn of its existence. In light of WSSO's bylaw, it files a notice objecting to the WSSO bylaw and asserting that they bylaw is unlawful. In return WSSO cancels MWC's membership and bars MWC from technical meetingsreturn, WSSO cancels MWC s membership and bars MWC from technical meetings, depriving MWC of access to information about forthcoming standards with which the new technology would have to operate. Legal or illegal?

47