input market initiatives for web

Upload: aeioums4391

Post on 04-Apr-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    1/52

    Input market iniaves

    that support

    innovaon systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    2/52

    Contents

    Execuve Summary: Input Market Iniaves

    Introducon 2

    Relevant Literature Review 2

    Demand and Supply of Agricultural Inputs 3

    Current Policies and Programmes 4

    Constraints and Opportunies 5

    Strategic Opons for Input Market Iniaves 5

    Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems and Agricultural Value Chains in Africa

    1.0 Introducon 8

    Purpose and Objecves 8

    2.0 Literature Review 10

    3.0 Demand and Supply of Agricultural Inputs 14

    Global Macro-factors 15

    The Agricultural Context 16

    Income Growth and Dietary Change 16

    Bio-fuels 16

    Addional Agricultural Land 17

    Technology 17

    4.0 Current Policies and Programmes on Promong Ecient Input Market Iniaves 17

    5.0 Constraints and Opportunies for Promong Ecient Input Market Iniaves 19

    6.0 Strategic Opons for Promong Ecient Input Market Iniaves 24

    Farmer Knowledge and Skills 24

    The SCODP Approach 24

    Rural Agro-Dealer Networks 25Research-Commerce Linkage to Test Input Demand 26

    Financing Inputs and Aordability 26

    Reducing the Package Size 27

    Credit Through Building Farmer Associaons 27

    Group Lending 28

    Interlinked Markets in Transion 28

    The Out-grower Scheme 29

    Government Credit 30

    Reducing Risks 31

    Other Strategic Opons 32

    Inputs for Relief and Food Security 32Government-Run Programmes 33

    7.0 Enabling Environment for Strategic Opons 33

    Smallholder Challenges 33

    Organizaon of Input Markets 34

    Educaon and Training 34

    Role of Government and Private Sector 34

    8.0 Conclusion 35

    9.0 Maers Arising 35

    References 36

    Appendix: Terms of Reference 41Acronyms and Abbreviaons 45

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    3/52

    Forum for Agricultural Research in Africa

    12 Anmeda Street, Roman Ridge,

    PMB CT 173, Accra, Ghana

    2011

    Input Market Initiatives that Support

    Innovation Systems in Africa

    Wayo Seini

    Monty Jones

    Emmanuel Tambi

    Gbadebo Odularu

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    4/52

    Citaon: Wayo Seini, Monty Jones, Emmanuel Tambi, and Gbadebo Odularu 2011.

    Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa. Accra, Ghana.

    FARA encourages fair use of this material. Proper citaon is requested.

    Design: www.bluepencil.in / Print: www.praga.com

    Forum for Agricultural Research in Africa (FARA)

    12 Anmeda Street, Roman Ridge

    PMB CT 173, Accra, Ghana

    Tel: +233 302 772823 / 302 779421

    Fax: +233 302 773676

    Email: [email protected]

    Website: www.far a-a fri ca. org

    ISBN 978-9988-9373-4-3 (print)

    ISBN 978-9988-9373-0-5 (pdf)

    Wayo Seini Professor, Instute of Stascs, Social and Economic Research (ISSER), University of

    Legon, Ghana

    Monty Jones Execuve Director, Forum for Agricultural Research (FARA), Ghana

    Emmanuel Tambi Director, Advocacy and Policy, FARA

    Gbadebo Odularu Regional Policies and Markets Analyst, FARA

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    5/52

    Executive Summary:

    Input Market Initiatives

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    6/52

    Executive Summary: Input Market Initiatives

    Introduction

    As spelt out in the Terms of Reference (Appendix A), the purpose of the consultancy,

    therefore, is to document the lessons learnt from (ongoing) successful and failed inputmarket iniaves on innovaon systems and agricultural value chain in Africa. The specic

    objecves are to:

    1. Collect and review literature on the input market iniaves that support innovaon

    systems and agricultural value chains in Africa;

    2. Idenfy the parameters (constraints and opportunies) for promong ecient input

    market iniaves that support innovaon systems and agricultural value chains in Africa;

    3. Examine the current policies and programmes on promong successful input market

    iniaves that support innovaon systems and agricultural value chains in Africa; and,

    4. Propose strategic opons (technological, approaches, partnerships and socio-economic

    issues) for promong successful input market iniaves on innovaon systems and

    agricultural value chains in Africa.

    The methodology applied in this study is mainly desk review. Most of the review centred

    on relevant academic publicaons, project and stakeholder documents.

    Relevant Literature Review

    Input subsidies appear to be the central theme in the discussion of agricultural input

    markeng and a successful input markeng strategy for agricultural development hinges

    on how input subsidies are handled. As noted by Dorward et. al. (2008), agricultural input

    subsidies were a common element in agricultural development in poor rural economies

    in the 1960s and 70s, including successful green revoluons. Although subsidies have

    connued, to a greater or lesser extent in some countries, convenonal wisdom as well

    as dominant donor thinking in the 80s and 90s was that subsidies had an ineecve and

    inecient policy instrument in Africa, which contributed to government overspending and

    scal and macroeconomic problems.

    Dorward et.al. (2008) observe a resurgence of interest in agricultural input subsidies in

    Africa, in recent years, together with the emergence of innovave subsidy-delivery systems.

    The case for the resurgence in interest in subsidies in input markeng appears strong in

    the literature. Subsidies play a primary role of promong the adopon of new technologies

    and thus increase agricultural producvity in the process of agricultural development (Ellis

    1992). This is possible because subsidies allow farmers to access purchased inputs such

    as seeds and ferlizers at lower cost, and reduce the disincenves to adopon that result

    from farmers cash constraints.

    In spite of the strong case for subsidies, the literature also covers problems with subsidies.

    The most common problem is that costs of subsidies on inputs are very dicult to control,depending partly on the way they are delivered, for example, ferlizer producon or import

    2 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    7/52

    subsidies. Also, market distorons introduced by subsidies, and parcularly parastatal

    involvement in subsidized input delivery, tend to crowd out and inhibit private sector

    investment in input markets and provide opportunies for corrupon and rent seeking,

    and hence impede sustainable development (Dorward et. al. 2008).

    The role of subsidies in input markeng in the successful Asian Green Revoluons has

    also been widely discussed in the literature. For example, the implementaon of a

    subsidized credit-ferlizer-extension programme (Masagana programme) was a key part

    of the Green Revoluon in the Philippines (Djurfeldt et. al. 2005). Areas with beer than

    average producon potenal were selected for programme coverage in the early phase

    of implementaon, but subsidies were later re-routed to the small-scale farm sector as it

    aracted priority.

    Djurfeldt et. al. (2005) regard the Green Revoluon in Asia as a state-driven, market-

    mediated and small-farmer based strategy to increase the naonal self-suciency in

    food grains in a string of Asian countries. They argue that technology was an important

    precondion for the results aained. States or governments drove the development of the

    food grain commodity chains towards the goal of self-suciency, a goal that was movated

    not only by the threat of famine, but also by the volale world markets for grain, which

    made vulnerable those countries that depended on imports.

    Dorward et. al. (2004) argue that sustained (but not indenite) input subsidies were a

    major part of successful Green Revoluon packages, making a crical contribuon to

    thickening and thus kick-starng markets, rst within staple-food supply chains and then

    in the wider rural economy. Gregory (2006) argues that ferlizer subsidies for staple crops

    are a crical requirement for this process to occur in Africa.

    Input market policy reforms in Africa and other developing regions also receive aenon

    in the literature. Lack of growth in agro-input business, parcularly ferlizers, has been

    largely due to past governments over-involvement in its producon, importaon and

    distribuon. Ferlizer subsidies were parcularly expensive, thereby making heavy and

    growing demands on government budgets. These issues became the target of policy

    reforms in the agricultural sector, parcularly from the mid-1980s.

    Demand and Supply of Agricultural Inputs

    Africas consumpon of modern inputs, parcularly ferlizers, is comparavely very

    low. The FAO (2008) projects that the situaon will not change much in the short run as

    Africa will account for less than 3% of world ferlizer consumpon by the end of 2012. To

    understand the current low levels of modern input use in African agriculture one has to

    take into consideraon the developments and factors that drive the demand and supply

    of these inputs.

    The demand and supply of agricultural inputs are inuenced largely by changing and oen

    interrelated factors: populaon and economic growth; agricultural producon; prices; and

    government policy. These changes manifest themselves in the global macro-economicfactors, the agricultural context, income growth and dietary change, bio-fuels, addional

    3

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    8/52

    agricultural land culvated, and technology. They are the main drivers of both agricultural

    input demand and supply. In addion, changes in technology are crucial in the supply of

    agricultural inputs.

    Macro-factors aecng global demand and supply of agricultural inputs include: the

    economic context; oil; trade; freight rates; and exchange rates. In the economic context,

    developing countries and economies in transion connue their strong economic

    performance, and hence a connued increases in the demand for agricultural commodies

    and inputs (FAO 2008). High oil prices could depress the use of oil-based agricultural inputs

    (ferlizers and agro-chemicals) which have been behind much of the increases in farm

    producon during the past half century (FAO 2007). At the micro (farm level) the income of

    farmers is the most important factor aecng their demand for agricultural inputs.

    Growth of world exports is more than double that of global output markeng, a further

    deepening of economic integraon that can have posive eects on the demand and supply

    of agricultural inputs that are internaonally traded (FAO 2008). The impact of transport

    costs on imported agricultural input prices will grow as they are produced in fewer localies

    close to raw materials and ample energy availability (Ibid). The decline in the United States

    Dollar against most currencies in the world since 2005 has made imports from the United

    States cheaper (World Bank 2007). This is the major reason behind the brisk world import

    demand for agricultural inputs, parcularly ferlizer and agro-chemicals, that in spite of

    high prices, shows lile sign of retreat.

    Current Policies and Programmes

    Since input market iniaves in Africa and developing countries in general are dominated by

    subsidy issues, the new thinking in input market policy and programmes is also dominated by

    the same issues. The new thinking of subsidies in input market iniaves arise fundamentally

    from increased quesoning by African policians, NGOs and some policy analysts about

    the failure of liberalized policies in supporng broad based agricultural development,

    parcularly sustainable intensicaon of staple food crop producon (Dorward 2009).

    Thus, the concerns expressed by various stakeholders have led to the potenal for input

    subsidies to deliver a wider range of policy objecves than those formerly recognized in

    the convenonal wisdom. These policy objecves, as espoused by Dorward (2009) include:

    (i) short term private input market development; (ii) replenishment of soil ferlity; (iii)

    social protecon for poor subsidy recipients; (iv) naonal and household food security;

    and, (v) meeng broad based polical demands.

    Some of the current policy issues are reected in current programmes in Africa. These

    include: (1) Naonal Ferlizer Subsidy Programme in Ghana; (2) Zambia Ferlizer Support

    Programme (FSP); (3) Kenaya Naonal Accelerated Agricultural Input Programme (NAAIP);

    (4) Malawi Agricultural Input Subsidy Programme (AISP), Targeted Input Programme (TIP),

    and Starter Pack Programme (SP); (5) Sasakawa Global 2000; (6) Millennium Villages;

    (7) Malawi Sustaining Producve Livelihood through Iputs for Assets (SPLIFA); and,(8) Developing Agricultural Inputs Markets in Nigeria (DAIMINA).

    4 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    9/52

    Constraints and Opportunities

    The major challenges faced by the dierent products in the broadly suitable agro-ecological

    areas in SSA include:

    i. Technical challenges and opportunies to increase producvity and stability, though

    the nature and extent of these challenges and opportunies varies between productsand contexts;

    ii. Underinvestment in public goods provision (technical research and extension, market

    and instuons) parcularly for staples where prices and value chain prots are

    limited; and,

    iii. Uncertainty and variability in global commodity prices as they aect input and output

    prices. This aects all commodies.

    In addion to these broad challenges classied by product and agro-ecological zones,

    there are other constraints and challenges pertaining directly to limited expansion in input

    use by smallholder farmers in Africa. They are mainly supply side issues and include:

    i. Lack of sucient agro-input dealers to ensure that smallholder farmers, especially

    those in remote rural communies have adequate access to agro-inputs.

    ii. Limited business incenves (mainly tax) for agro-input dealers and business constraints

    including high transport costs (mainly due to poor infrastructure and long distances

    covered to source their goods), lack of adequate working capital, low demand, lack of

    market informaon, lack of storage facilies, and limited business skills and knowledge.

    iii. High farm level (or farm gate) prices for agro-inputs, compounded by lack of credit

    services for smallholder farmers.

    Nevertheless, there are opportunies for increased producvity in African agriculture.

    Dorward (2009) argues that the high potenal yields achievable with the high response

    cereals and roots and tubers suggests that these have the potenal to make major

    contribuons to driving and supporng pro-poor growth in African countries where these

    crops can be produced, depending on other potenal drivers of growth in these countries.

    Strategic Options for Input Market Initiatives

    A wide variety of eorts have been made to relieve the constraints of agricultural input

    market iniaves. These eorts have revealed a number of successful strategic oponsfor promong ecient input market iniaves in Africa, parcularly Sub-Saharan Africa

    (SSA). These opons are related to the three broad categories of demand and supply side

    constraints, i.e. knowledge and skills, nancial and risk issues.

    Farmer Knowledge and Skills: Strategic opons idened under this category include:

    (i) The SCODP Approach; (ii) Rural Agro-Dealer Networks; and (iii) Research-Commerce

    Linkage to Test Input Demand.

    Financing Inputs and Affordability: Opons in this constraint category include: (i) Reducing

    the Package Size; (ii) Credit Through Building Farmer Associaons; (iii) Group Lending;(iv) Interlinked Markets in Transion; and (v) The Out-grower Scheme.

    5

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    10/52

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    11/52

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    12/52

    1.0 IntroductionThe performance of African agriculture has been disappoinng over many decades. For

    example, sub-Saharan Africa is the only region in which per capita agricultural value

    added has not seen a substanal increase, with declining trend on average, since 1961,

    and considerable variaon over me and across countries (FAO 2008). As suchAfrica isthe only region of the world where per capita food producon has been declining over

    the past three decades. As a result, there is increasing rural poverty, rising food prices

    widespread famines and increasing food imports now esmated at US$ 25 billion per year

    (FAO 2007). Unfortunately, the Green Revoluon, which has saved many lives in Asia and

    South America, has bypassed Africa and hunger sll prevails on the connent despite the

    past research and development eorts.

    Some of the factors militang against agricultural development in Africa include inter alia,

    inadequate investment in agriculture; limited access to credit by smallholder farmers;

    high cost and unavailability of inputs such as ferlizers and improved seeds; inadequateuse of modern technologies; inecient agricultural input markets; and the absence of a

    conducive policy environment. In parcular, the use of improved agricultural inputs is very

    low in Africa and has remained largely stac over the last 25 years, with parcularly low

    usage in smallholder food crop and livestock producon systems.

    In response to this challenge, it is widely accepted that increased use of inputs (seeds,

    ferlizers and chemicals) play a crical role, along side organic soil ferlity enhancing

    pracces, in the technical change needed for sustainable smallholder agricultural growth in

    Africa. Indeed, farmers require ecient input markets in order to deliver the right product,

    at the right me, in the right amounts, at a convenient place, and for an aordable price.

    Against this background, there is a dire need to document the lessons learnt from (ongoing)

    successful and failed input market iniaves on innovaon systems and agricultural value

    chains in Africa. One of the juscaons for this study is that many African policymakers

    are not well informed about how input markets work and why the prices uctuate

    (Heinemann 2002). Further, they are inadequately informed about the successful input

    market iniaves that support innovaon systems and agricultural value chain. There is

    also a need to increase awareness about policy and instuonal implicaons of successful

    input market iniaves that support innovaon systems and agricultural value chain. Thisstudy will provide policymakers and key stakeholders with evidence-based informaon for

    strategic input markets policy formulaon in Africa.

    Purpose and Objectives

    The purpose of the consultancy, as spelt out in the Terms of Reference (Appendix A), is to

    document the lessons learnt from (ongoing) successful and failed input market iniaves

    on innovaon systems and agricultural value chain in Africa. The specic objecves are to:

    1. Collect and review literature on the input market iniaves that support innovaonsystems and agricultural value chains in Africa;

    8 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    13/52

    2. Idenfy the parameters (constraints and opportunies) for promong ecient input

    market iniaves that support innovaon systems and agricultural value chains in Africa;

    3. Examine the current policies and programmes on promong successful input market

    iniaves that support innovaon systems and agricultural value chains in Africa; and,

    4. Propose strategic opons (technological, approaches, partnerships and socio-economic

    issues) for promong successful input market iniaves on innovaon systems and

    agricultural value chains in Africa.

    A crucial component of the study will include drawing conclusions and lessons learnt from

    ongoing unsuccessful input supply because it is more economically impacul to document

    reasons why an iniave goes wrong than why it works perfectly.

    This study is in line with the Abuja declaraon of December 2006 which highlighted the

    categories of development iniaves that could be included in the eld of research for a

    successful African Green Revoluon. These are:

    i. Naonal food security programmes to accelerate staple food producon, e.g. cassava,

    NERICA, maize, legumes, livestock products, etc;

    ii. Eecve and nancially sustainable support systems to increase farm producon,

    markeng and trade;

    iii. Staple food processing of high quality products that could be marketed through space

    and me, e.g. conversion into high value products: feed for livestock and aquaculture

    producon, bio-fuel, and other industrial uses;

    iv. Eecve and sustainable research, extension and producer organizaon pracces for

    producon, processing and commercializaon; ecient management of naonal foodreserve systems;

    v. Linking smallholders to commercial opportunies, such as fast growing supermarket

    chain operaons;

    vi. Emerging successes to improve nutrional value of staple foods, e.g. forcaon,

    diversicaon of food commodies, Home Grown School Feeding Programmes,

    nutrion educaon, etc; and,

    vii. Strategies for targeng vulnerable groups and implemenng sustainable programmes

    linking food security objecves with wider developmental goals.

    The methodology applied in this study is mainly desk review. Most of the review centred

    on relevant academic publicaons, project and stakeholder documents.

    The report is presented in nine secons. Aer the literature review in secon two, the

    demand and supply of agricultural inputs is discussed in secon three. Secon four

    discusses the current policies and progremmes on promong ecient input market

    iniaves while the constraints and opportunies for promong ecient input market

    iniaves in African agriculture are discussed in secon ve. Secon six discusses strategic

    opons arising from the desk review followed by a discussion on creang an enabling

    environment for successful implementaon in secon seven. A brief conclusion is providedin secon eight followed by maers arising in secon nine.

    9

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    14/52

    2.0 Literature ReviewThe literature on input market iniaves in Africa in parcular (and in developing countries

    in general) is largely historical in nature and concentrate on ferlizer, seeds, pescides

    and, to a lesser extent, irrigaon. Subsidies, experiences of the Asian Green Revoluon,

    government intervenon, and policy reforms are the common features in the literature.Aer independence, most organized economic acvies in the African countries were

    largely owned and operated by the public sector through various public agencies. Such

    state intervenon was partly rooted in the past policy regimes and was partly a de facto

    outcome due to the absence of the previous entrepreneurs and instuons (Zohir 2001).

    However, input subsidies appear to be the central theme in the discussion of agricultural

    input markeng and a successful input markeng strategy for agricultural development

    hinges on how input subsidies are handled. As noted by Dorward et. al. (2008), agricultural

    input subsidies were a common element in agricultural development in poor rural

    economies in the 1960s and 70s, including successful green revoluons. Although subsidies

    have connued, to a greater or lesser extent in some countries, convenonal wisdom as

    well as dominant donor thinking in the 80s and 90s was that subsidies had been ineecve

    and inecient policy instrument in Africa, which contributed to government overspending

    and scal and macroeconomic problems.

    Dorward et.al. (2008) observe a resurgence of interest in agricultural input subsidies in

    Africa, in recent years, together with the emergence of innovave subsidy-delivery systems.

    The case for the resurgence in interest in subsidies in input markeng appears strong in

    the literature. Subsidies play a primary role of promong the adopon of new technologies

    and thus increase agricultural producvity in the process of agricultural development (Ellis

    1992). This is possible because subsidies allow farmers to access purchased inputs such

    as seeds and ferlizers at lower cost, and reduce the disincenves to adopon that result

    from farmers cash constraints.

    Subsidies, it is argued, also play a role in rural development and are somemes implemented

    to support agricultural development in more remote areas, mainly with pan-territorial

    pricing and subsidized delivery systems. Input subsidies have also been a means for raising

    farm incomes parcularly where farmers are being taxed in other ways through export

    taris and low xed domesc prices (Dorward et. 2008). The need for complementarycredit and extension services, have been stressed to encourage economically and

    technically ecient use of inputs (Ibid.).

    In spite of the strong case for subsidies, the literature also covers problems with subsidies.

    The most common problem is that costs of input subsidies are very dicult to control,

    depending partly on the way they are delivered, for example, ferlizer producon or

    import subsidies. It is argued that subsidies could be required for a short term for learning

    purposes (about both input use and benets), and then phased out. Yet, strong polical

    pressure for the expansion of subsidies oen make exits very dicult, with strong

    resistance to scaling down or terminaon of subsidies. Targeng input subsidies toparcular types of farmers is very dicult, with problems of diversion and leakage. Even

    10 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    15/52

    when it is used by the target group, arcially low prices may lead to overuse of inputs,

    or the adopon of input-intensive more than more economically ecient labour-intensive

    producon methods (Dorward 2009).

    Another problem with subsidy in the literature is that benets may be regressive in

    that they tend to benet large farmers who can aord subsidesed inputs. Also, market

    distorons introduced by subsidies, and parcularly parastatal involvement in subsidized

    input delivery, tend to crowd out and inhibit private sector investment in input markets

    and provide opportunies for corrupon and rent seeking, and hence impede sustainable

    development (Dorward et. al. 2008).

    Input subsidies are normally designed to promote the producon of an output. Thus, the

    need for complimentary policies that aect the output has been stressed in the literature.

    Policies aecng staple food prices, investment in roads, communicaon infrastructure

    and agricultural services, and facilitang private sector development and non-farm

    diversicaon are required to promote the eecveness of input subsidies in agricultural

    development (Dorward et. al. 2007).

    The role of subsidies in input markeng in the successful Asian Green Revoluons has also

    been widely discussed in the literature. The implementaon of a subsidized credit-ferlizer-

    extension programme (Masagana programme) was a key part of the Green Revoluon in

    the Philippines (Djurfeldt et. al. 2005). Areas with beer than average producon potenal

    were selected for programme coverage in the early phase of implementaon, but subsidies

    were later re-routed to the small-scale farm sector as it aracted priority.

    In Indonesia, shortages of ferlizer supplies and domesc credit, at the beginning of

    the Green Revoluon, prompted the government to start the BIMAS Gotong Royong(BGR or mutual self-help programme) in which foreign manufacturers of ferlizers and

    pescides were invited to parcipate directly in supplying credit and distribung inputs

    and management advice to rice farmers and extension sta in certain locaons (Djurfeldt

    et. al. 2005). The importance of government role in the Asian Green Revoluons was

    parcularly demonstrated in the Indonesian case with the establishment of BULOG (Badan

    Urusan Logisc), the new food logiscs agency directly responsible to the President,

    which developed into one of Asias most powerful food agencies. BULOG developed and

    implemented a comprehensive rice policy that beneted both consumers and producers

    and maintained appropriate price relaonships both within Indonesia and internaonalrice markets (Mears and Moeljono 1981).

    The success of the Indonesian Green Revoluon was also aributable to the strong

    commitment of the government to food self-suciency and rural development (Djurfeldt

    et. al. 2005). The governments vision on rural development resulted in two decades of

    sustained rural bias which included not only the protecon and support of agriculture but

    also substanal spending programmes to increase the provision of physical infrastructure

    and social services in rural areas. In addion, the creaon and expansion of a naonal

    ferlizer industry formed part of the strategy to become self-sucient in rice. Support

    to farmers during the Green Revoluon was mainly indirect through subsidized inputs ferlizers and credit (Ibid).

    11

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    16/52

    India represented a major variant of the Asian Green Revoluons in the sense that its

    agriculture is very diverse. Wheat and other cereals play a signicant role making it

    necessary to consider food grains as a group when trying to understand the countrys

    agricultural policy. Consequently, the early Green Revoluon in India was a queson of

    both wheat and rice producon, and it was the early success of the wheat sector that

    explained most of the growth (Djurfeldt et. al. 2005).

    Following the recommendaons of a group of American experts in the 1959 report on

    Indias Food Crisis and Steps to Meet It, the Indian government set up the Intensive

    Agricultural District Programme (IADP) to develop and implement policies for the Green

    Revoluon. The IADP was based on a package approach to increase Indias agricultural

    yields. The package included instuonal, economic and technical innovaons that were

    implemented at the district, block, village, farm, and eld level. On the basis of one pilot

    district in each of the seven states, India marshaled all the inputs that were needed for

    intensive high-yielding pracces, and made available to capable farmers (Perkins 1997).

    Apart from technical components improved seed, ferlizer, irrigaon and pescides thepackage approach also stressed the importance of adequate credit facilies, technical advise

    and a guaranteed price providing an incenve to accept the risk of trying a new technology.

    Following minimum inial success, due mainly to low yield response to ferlizer and

    other inputs in use of the then recommended variees which were locally developed,

    the objecve was narrowed down and instuonal support in the credit and cooperave

    elds was de-emphasized (Barker et. al. 1985). The new strategy was embodied in the High

    Yielding Variees Programme (HYVP) and involved a concentraon of seeds, ferlizer and

    extension in areas with high quality irrigaon condions. Shipment of semi-dwarf wheat

    seeds from Mexico and rice seeds from IRRI were rapidly supplied to the promoted areas.

    From the late 1970s to 2000, a period during which the Indian populaon doubled, food

    producon more than doubled as a result of the spread of the Green Revoluon within

    the country (Djurfeldt et. al. 2005). Compared with the Philippine and Indonesia cases,

    the Indian Green Revoluon recorded slow growth rates, at least inially, and had limited

    impact on poverty (Ibid).

    Djurfeldt et. al. (2005) regard the Green Revoluon in Asia as a state-driven, market-

    mediated and small-farmer based strategy to increase the naonal self-suciency in

    food grains in a string of Asian countries. They argue that technology was an important

    precondion for the results aained. States or governments were driving the development

    of the food grain commodity chains towards the goal of self-suciency, a goal that was

    movated not only by the threat of famine, but also by the volale world markets for grain,

    which made vulnerable those countries that depended on imports. They argue further

    that the Asian Green Revoluons were market-mediated in the sense that markets played

    a fundamental role in dierent parts of the chain, with regards to farm inputs and the

    trade and processing of grain. Also the Asian Green Revoluons were small-farmer based,

    i.e. they were not based on large-scale mechanized farming (Ibid).

    Djurfeldt et al. (2005) emphasize the crical role of market mediaon in the Asian GreenRevoluon. They argue that really exisng markets are not like the ideal type ones which

    12 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    17/52

    the economists build their theories around. Really exisng markets are not free ones,

    they show tendency to monopoly and monopsony and, most important of all, they are

    instuonalized and regulated by the surrounding society and in parcular the state. They

    contend that the Asian Green Revoluons were state-driven and market-mediated, in the

    sense that governments relied on private business to handle at least parts of the provision

    of inputs (seed, ferlizer irrigaon etc.) and to distribute the food grain produced from thefarm gate to the consumer. These markets were not free and in important respects they

    were controlled by the state. In many of the Asian countries, state agencies operated in

    farm markets, both on the input and the output sides (Ibid).

    Dorward et. al. (2004) argue that sustained (but not indenite) input subsidies were a

    major part of successful Green Revoluon packages, making a crical contribuon to

    thickening and thus kick-starng markets, rst within staple-food supply chains and then

    in the wider rural economy. Gregory (2006) argues that ferlizer subsidies for staple crops

    are a crical requirement for this process to occur in Africa.

    Input markets policy reforms in Africa and other developing regions also receive

    aenon in the literature. The convenonal wisdom in the 1960s to the early 1980s was

    for African countries to indulge in large scale (universal) agricultural input subsidies as

    a major feature of agricultural development policies. These were generally implemented

    as across the board price subsidies accessible to all producers, or to all producers of a

    parcular commodity (Dorward 2009). Convenonal arguments for subsidies in agricultural

    development have focused on the promoon of agricultural producvity through the

    adopon of new technologies (Ellis 1992). If subsidized inputs were sold through a state

    monopsony, then there were oen aempts of price discriminaon, with, for example, only

    smallholder farmers allowed to purchase subsidized inputs and forbidden from selling it on.

    Lack of growth in agro-input business, parcularly ferlizers, has been largely due to

    governments over-involvement in ferlizer producon, importaon and distribuon.

    Ferlizer subsidies were parcularly expensive and made heavy and growing demands on

    government budgets as they smulated increased ferlizer consumpon. In Nigeria, for

    example, subsidy on ferlizer was up to 85% of the cost of the ferlizers (FMARD 2003). In

    many cases price subsidy did not reach the intended beneciaries because of increasing

    corrupon and ineciency in the enre chain from procurement to logiscs management

    and delivery (Ibid).

    These issues became the target of policy reforms in the agricultural sector, parcularly from

    the mid-1980s, when most African countries adopted structural adjustment programmes

    (SAPs). The ulmate goal of the policy reforms was the liberalizaon of agricultural input

    markets. In most countries in Africa, and in most developing countries, reforms followed

    a similar paern: deregulaon of input prices (parcularly ferlizers); phasing out of input

    subsidies; transfer of procurement (import) and distribuon of inputs to private dealers;

    and divesture of state-owned agricultural enterprises ( Seini et a. 2005; Zohir 2001).

    Since the beginning of economic reforms in Sub-Saharan Africa, donors have generally

    discouraged the use of free or subsidized input distribuon. This discouragement waslargely due to some nancially unsustainable approaches that led many pre-reform

    13

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    18/52

    governments to the brink of bankruptcy. However, many SSA governments and some

    donors believe there are legimate food security and environmental issues that could be

    addressed by input subsidies (Kelly et al. 2003). In this regard, analysts agree that ferlizer

    subsidies should only be considered when ferlizer use is economically protable (Ibid).

    In other words, there should be a considerably strong crop response that ferlizer use

    remains protable when price distorons from subsidies and taxes are removed.

    Credit is another issue that received aenon under policy reforms in SSA, since nancing

    problems have long been evasive and aecng all sectors of the economy and all levels

    of the input markeng sector. Intervenonist policies dominated nancial sector markets

    in the 1960s and 1970s in most SSA countries and became the target of policy reforms

    (Aryeetey et al. 2000). In many countries poor repayment rates led to huge government

    decits that led, in turn, to donor condionalies on government spending (Commander

    et al. 1989).

    3.0 Demand and Supply of Agricultural InputsDierences in the state of agricultural development between countries and regions of the

    world can somemes be explained or illustrated by the intensity/quantum of consumpon/

    usage of agricultural inputs per unit of land. Table 1 shows the levels of ferlizer (Nitrogen)

    usage in regions in the world.

    Clearly, Africas consumpon is comparavely very low. The FAO (2008) projects that

    the situaon will not change much in the short run as Africa will account for less than3% of world ferlizer consumpon by the end of 2012. To understand the current low

    levels of modern input use in African agriculture one has to take into consideraon the

    developments and factors that drive the demand and supply of these inputs.

    Three major developments in recent mes disnguish current state of agricultural markets

    from past uctuaons: hike in world prices (aects nearly all food and feed commodies);

    record prices at the me of abundance rather than scarcity; and, the strengthening of

    linkages between agricultural commodity markets and other markets. These observaons

    Table 1: Regional Fertilizer (nitrogen) Consumption, 2008

    Region N fertilizer (%)

    Africa 3.4

    Europe 14.1

    America 19.8

    Asia 61.4

    Oceania 14.1

    Source: FAO Rome (2008): Current World Fertilizer Trends and Outlook to

    2010/11.

    14 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    19/52

    refer to a paradigm shi in agriculture away from decreasing real food prices over the

    past thirty years (FAO 2008). This paradigm shi has eect on the demand and supply of

    agricultural inputs, parcularly ferlizers.

    The demand and supply of agricultural inputs are inuenced largely by changing and oen

    interrelated factors: populaon and economic growth; agricultural producon; prices; and

    government policy. These changes manifest themselves in the global macro-economic

    factors, the agricultural context, income growth and dietary change, bio-fuels, addional

    agricultural land culvated, and technology. They are the main drivers of both agricultural

    input demand and supply. In addion, changes in technology are crucial in the supply of

    agricultural inputs.

    Global Macro-factors

    Macro-factors aecng global demand and supply of agricultural inputs include: the

    economic context; oil; trade; freight rates; and exchange rates.

    In the economic context, developing countries and economies in transion connue

    their strong economic performance, and hence a connued increases in the demand for

    agricultural commodies and inputs (FAO 2008).

    High oil prices contribute to price increases for most agricultural crops by raising input

    costs on the one hand, and by boosng the demand for agricultural crops used as feedstock

    in the producon of alternave energy sources (bio-fuels) on the other (Integer 2007).

    High oil prices could depress the use of oil-based agricultural inputs (ferlizers and agro-

    chemicals) which have been behind much of the increases in farm producon during thepast half century (FAO 2007).

    World trade expanded rapidly in the recent three years driven by increased trade of oil

    and non-oil commodies as well as capital goods (FAO 2008). Growth of world exports

    is more than double that of global agricultural commodity output markeng, a further

    deepening of economic integraon that can have posive eects on the demand and

    supply of agricultural inputs that are internaonally traded (Ibid).

    Freight rates have become a more important factor in agricultural markets than in the past.

    Increased fuel costs, stretched shipping capacity, port congeson, and longer trade routes

    due to altered trade paerns, have pushed up shipping costs. The impact of transport costs

    on imported agricultural input prices will grow as they are produced in fewer localies

    close to raw materials and ample energy availability (FAO 2008).

    Exchange rate swings play a crical role in all markets, including agricultural markets. Yet

    rarely have currency developments been as important in shaping agricultural prices as in

    recent mes. The decline in the United States Dollar against most currencies in the world

    since 2005 has made imports from the United States cheaper and lessons the true impact

    of the rise in world prices (World Bank 2007). This is the major reason behind the brisk

    world import demand for agricultural inputs, parcularly ferlizer and agro-chemicals,that in spite of high prices, shows lile sign of retreat.

    15

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    20/52

    Global economic growth is seen as remaining suciently robust to sustain demand for food

    (especially high value foods such as meat, fruits and vegetables) in emerging economies,

    thereby strengthening demand for ferlizers and other agricultural inputs (FAO 2008). At

    the micro (farm level) the income of farmers is the most important factor aecng their

    demand for agricultural inputs.

    The Agricultural Context

    Global populaon and economic growth are the major forces driving increased world

    food demand, crop producon and agricultural input use. With regards to populaon

    growth, absolute annual increments connue to be large in spite of slowing down of word

    populaon. More food and bre will be required to feed and clothe these addional people

    and to increase the daily uptake of millions of undernourished worldwide. There is thus

    signicant scope for further increases in demand for food and for that maer agricultural

    inputs, even as populaon growth slows down (FAO 2007).

    Income Growth and Dietary Change

    Global agricultural value added per capita has grown at an average rate of 0.4% per year in

    real terms since 1961. Sub-Saharan Africa is the only region in which per capita agricultural

    value added has not seen a substanal increase with declining trend on average for the

    period and considerable variaon over me and across countries (FAO 2008). At the same

    me, global dietary paerns have changed dramacally over the past four decades, both

    reecng and driving these changes (Ibid).

    Income growth, relave price changes, urbanizaon and shis in consumer preferences

    have altered dietary paerns parcularly in developing countries. Diets have shied away

    from staples such as cereals, roots and tubers and pulses towards more livestock and

    shery products, vegetable oils and fruits and vegetables. Increasing meat and aquaculture

    producon will require more feed (coarse grain and oilseed meals). Conversion of grain

    areas to vegetable and food producon will translate into higher ferlizer and agro-

    chemical agricultural input demand as average applicaon rates for these inputs are about

    double those of grain crops (FAO 2007).

    The above trends support connuing and increasing demand for agricultural inputs,

    parcularly mineral ferlizer to restore and enhance ferlity of the worlds agricultural

    land for higher yields and improved produce quality.

    Bio-fuels

    High oil prices are creang new markets for agricultural commodies that can be used as feed

    stocks for the producon of bio-fuels. Bio-fuels are being promoted as contribung to a wide

    range of policy objecves, most notably as providing greater energy security with regards

    to liquid fuels, increasing rural incomes, lowering greenhouse gas emission and providing

    economic opportunies for developing countries (Integer 2007). Increasing producon ofbio-fuel agricultural commodies could lead to increased demand of agricultural inputs.

    16 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    21/52

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    22/52

    growth. Instruments proposed for implemenng smart subsidies include (i) demonstraon

    packs; (ii) vouchers; (iii) matching grants; and, (iv) loan guarantees.

    Nevertheless, the interest in geng input subsidies to serve new funcons and policy

    objecves, and the extent to which input subsidies are the most cost-eecve way

    of achieving these policy objecves connues to be controversial. For example, while

    recognizing all the features of smart subsidies listed above, the 2008 World Development

    Report on Agriculture for Development takes a more restricted and convenonal posion,

    focusing on the roles of subsidy as being to provide sustainable soluons to market failures,

    through market smart approaches to jumpstart agricultural input markets, underwrite

    risks of early adopon of new technologies to help achieve economies of scale to reduce

    input prices, as part of a comprehensive strategy to improve producvity with credible exit

    opons (World Bank 2008). In other words subsidies, no maer how laudable the policy

    objecves may be, should have a life span.

    Some of the current policy issues are reected in current programmes in Africa. Theseinclude: (1) Naonal Ferlizer Subsidy Programme in Ghana; (2) Zambia Ferlizer Support

    Programme (FSP); (3) Kenya Naonal Accelerated Agricultural Input Programme (NAAIP);

    (4) Malawi Agricultural Input Subsidy Programme (AISP), Targeted Input Programme (TIP),

    and Starter Pack Programme (SP); (5) Sasakawa Global 2000; (6) Millennium Villages;

    (7) Malawi Sustaining Producve Livelihood through Iputs for Assets (SPLIFA); and,

    (8) Developing Agricultural Inputs Markets in Nigeria (DAIMINA).

    These current programmes are well spread in all sub-regions in SSA. They are ongoing and

    success or failure cannot be judged now. However, the current programmes in Africa have

    some common features in line with the new policy thinking, and also embody a range ofdierent approaches. With the excepon of the Global 2000 programme, all of the current

    programmes were iniated in response to the high food prices as well as rising ferlizer

    prices in early 2008. The common feature in all the current programmes is the role of

    government and the involvement of private sector operaves. Private companies import

    the ferlizers and other inputs under government tender. The distribuon is done through

    a government agency (as in the cases of Ghana and Nigeria), prastatal input suppliers (as

    in the case of Malawi), cooperave sociees (as in the case of Zambia) or through private

    agro-input dealers (as in the case of Kenya).

    A number of innovave approaches are also involved in these new programmes:

    i. Starter Pack: All farm households under the Malawi programme were given an input

    starter pack comprising 15kg of ferlizer, 2kg of maize seed and some legume seed in

    an aempt to boost producon of maize and legumes.

    ii. Targeted Input Programme: Targeted beneciaries were selected and inputs (mainly

    ferlizer) were provided to them (Malawi).

    iii. Demonstraon Plots: An approach used by Sasakawa Global 2000 under which farmers

    were given assistance in acquiring inputs on demonstraon plots

    iv. Millennium Villages: Integrated projects in selected villages to demonstrate thesubstanal changes that are possible with investments in health, agriculture and

    18 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    23/52

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    24/52

    Table2:TypologyofAgricultura

    lProductsbyRoles,CountriesandChallengesandOpportunities

    StapleProd

    ucers

    NonStaple

    Producers

    Highresponse

    cerealsMaize,

    rice?

    wheat?

    Lowresponsecereals

    Sorghum,

    millet

    Ro

    ots/tubers

    Ca

    ssava,

    (sweet

    po

    tatoes)

    Domestically

    consumed

    non-tradable

    Domestically

    consumedtradable

    Tr

    aditional/non-

    tra

    ditionalexports

    Bro

    adrole

    Pro-poorgrowth

    Leastcostwelfare,

    growthplatform

    Pr

    o-poorgrowth

    Supportgrowth,

    with

    staplespillovers

    Supportgrowth,

    with

    staplespillovers

    Drivegrowthwith

    staplespillovers?

    Countrieswith

    min

    erals

    Supportandsp

    read

    growth

    Subsistence,

    support

    andspreadgrowth

    Su

    pportandspread

    growth

    Supportandspread

    growth

    Supportandspread

    growth

    Minordriverand

    sp

    readsgrowth

    Coastal,nominerals

    Regionaldriver

    and

    supportsgrowth

    Subsistenceand

    supportgrowth

    Re

    gionaldriverand

    su

    pportsgrowth

    Supportgrowth

    Supportgrowth

    Regionaldriverand

    su

    pportsgrowth

    Landlocked,

    no

    min

    erals

    Majordriverandthen

    supporter

    Subsistence

    Majordriverandthen

    su

    pporter

    Supportgrowth

    Supportgrowth

    Driver

    Technology

    Irrigation

    Yieldpackage?

    Pr

    ocessing?

    Various

    Various

    Va

    rious

    Challenges

    Publicgoods

    (research,

    infrastructure,

    institutionalenvironment)

    Policycoordination

    Complementaryservicecoordination

    Globalcommodityandproductprices(protability,inputaffordability)

    Priceinstability

    (intraandinterseasonal)

    Price/productivitytightrope

    Sea

    sonalinputnance

    Source:

    Dorward

    A.

    2009

    .Re

    thinking

    Agricu

    ltura

    lInpu

    tSu

    bsi

    dy

    Programmes

    ina

    Chang

    ing

    Worl

    d.

    20 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    25/52

    need to be addressed in order to achieve increased producvity. Disncons are made

    between dierent types of crops and products (and implicitly between dierent agro-

    ecological zones associated with them). In the Table 2, maize, rice (notably NERICA) and

    possibly wheat (a much less important crop in Africa) are classied in Dorward (2009) as

    cereals with potenally high responses to signicant investments in inorganic and organic

    ferlizer applicaon.

    Millet and sorghum have generally lower yield potenal, but there are sll possibilies

    for signicant yield responses in the context of integrated soil ferlity management

    (ISFM) pracces, involving, for example, beer water control, use of organic maer and

    micro-dosing with crical nutrients (Ibid). Root crops, parcularly cassava sweet potatoes

    and yam, have the potenal for signicant yield increases with intensicaon but will

    require signicant increases in ferlizer inputs, there are inial opportunies for major

    yield increases from improved variees. Non-staple products are considered in terms of

    non-tradables and tradables, the laer broken down between domescally consumed and

    exported tradables.

    Dorward (2009) argues that the high potenal yields achievable with the high response

    cereals and roots and tubers suggests that these have the potenal to make major

    contribuons to driving and supporng pro-poor growth in African countries where these

    crops can be produced, depending on other potenal drivers of growth in these countries.

    On the other hand, in the more challenging agro-ecological condions the low response

    cereals achieve improved yields that are sll low. These improved yields will not be able

    to drive growth substanally but they should have important roles in supporng growth

    and in providing a lower cost and more developmentally benecial subsistence safety

    net (as compared with humanitarian relief). These developmental opportunies will vary

    between countries with opportunies for minerals, manufacturing industries and cash

    crops to drive growth (Ibid). Nevertheless, the more challenging agro-ecologies where

    these crops are grown are also likely to limit cash crop and livestock development opons.

    In these situaons, investment in increased staple producvity may be a least cost way of

    providing safety nets in a way that encourages economic acvity rather than dependency.

    The lower part of the Table 2 lists the major challenges faced by the dierent products in

    the broadly suitable agro-ecological areas. These challenges include:

    i. Technical challenges and opportunies to increase producvity and stability, thoughthe nature and extent of these challenges and opportunies varies between products

    and contexts;

    ii. Underinvestment in public goods provision (technical research and extension, market

    and instuons) parcularly for staples where prices and value chain prots are

    limited; and,

    iii. Uncertainty and variability in global commodity prices as they aect input and output

    prices. This aects all commodies.

    The locaon of the text and thickness of arrows in the Table 2 show that there areconsiderable dierences between dierent products in the challenges they face.

    21

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    26/52

    A.Farm-levelconstra

    ints

    B.Traderconstraints

    PurchaseInputs

    SupplyInputs

    Doesfarmerhave

    knowledgeof

    protableinputsthat

    heisnotusing?

    Doestraderbelieve

    thereiseecve

    demand?

    Doestraderhave

    enoughtechnical

    knowledgetoorde

    r

    andmarketinputs?

    Doestraderhave

    capitalneededtos

    tock

    inputs?

    Isthereasupplier

    available?

    Cantransportaon

    bearrangedfora

    reasonableprice?

    Islevelofrisk

    acceptable?

    Doesfarmerhave

    knowledgeandskills

    neededtoeciently

    usetheinput?

    Areinputsthebest

    useofavailable

    nancialresources?

    Areinputsaordable

    orcreditavailable?

    Areinputsavailable?

    Islevelofriskacceptable?

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    No

    No

    No N

    o

    No

    No N

    o

    No No N

    oNo

    No

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Yes

    Ye

    s

    Linkwithcreditservices

    Agro-dealerpr

    ograms

    Programt

    osu

    pportsuppliers

    buildingdistr

    ibuonnetworks

    Supportinputdealer

    associaons

    Ruralroadin

    vestments

    Lowervehicletaxes

    Supplierrisk

    sharing

    Insurance

    Tradertrain

    ing

    programs

    Informaon

    campaignb

    y

    researchan

    d

    extension

    Promoon

    ofinput

    traderasso

    ciaons

    Inputvouchers

    Mini-packs

    ISFM

    Outputpricesupport

    Insurance

    Mini-packs

    Credit

    Subsidy

    Improveprotabilityrelave

    toalternaveusesthrough

    researchorsubsidy

    Developsupply

    Extension

    Adversing

    On-farmd

    emos

    Parcipatory

    research

    Figu

    re1:IdentifyingandReducingInputMarketingConstrai

    nts

    Source:

    V.

    Ke

    llye

    tal./Food

    Pol

    icy

    28(2003)379404

    22 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    27/52

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    28/52

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    29/52

    The awareness-raising campaigns, carried out at markets and churches where farmers

    congregate, are a key component of the success. They were complemented with extension

    assistance to farmers willing to test the inputs.

    The strength of the programme appears to be its ability to inform both farmers and traders

    about inputs, and its ability to address mulple constraints: farmer knowledge through

    awareness campaigns, farmer skills through parcipatory input tesng, aordability

    through the use of min-packs and availability by establishing SCODP shops and smulang

    general merchandise traders to stock ferlizers.

    The lesson from the SCOPD experience is that eecve demand for inputs to be used on

    food crops can be developed among poor farmers if the knowledge, skill, availability, and

    aordability constraints are addressed. The most crucial step appears to have been raising

    awareness of inputs and their potenal among farmers seldom targeted by extension

    services (Kelly et al. 2003).

    In spite of the numerous successes of this strategic innovave opon, its sustainability willbe dependant on measures that are taken to migate the eects of subsidy withdrawals

    when donor support ends.

    Rural Agro-Dealer Networks

    Rural agro-dealer programmes increase retailer knowledge and decrease supplier risks.

    Therefore, an increasingly popular innovave strategic approach to agricultural input

    promoon focuses on rural agro-dealer networks (Kelly et al. 2003). These networks

    increase input availability by rst improving the technical knowledge of inputs and

    managerial skills among rural traders and then reducing capital constraints through a systemof guarantees that reduce the risk of input distributors supplying credit to retailers (Ibid).

    There are three disnguishing features of rural agro-dealer networks:

    i. Rural shop owners are trained by NGOs on general business management and technical

    knowledge of agricultural inputs;

    ii. Once cered, the agro-dealers are connected to major input supply companies using

    a credit guarantee scheme, which covers some of the risk-related costs normally borne

    by rms building rural input supply networks; and,

    iii. Linking agro-dealers to farmers eld schools, where they exist, to build eecvedemand for inputs by improving farmers knowledge.

    Kelly et al. (2003) idenfy three advantages to this strategic input markeng approach:

    i. It builds on exisng entrepreneurs who already have business skills and are able to take

    risks;

    ii. It moves inputs closer to farmers through a viable private sector system; by bearing

    a high proporon (up to 50%) of the input guarantee costs and retailer training, the

    suppliers share in the risk of developing these networks; and,

    iii. Scaling up is based on the ability of the agro-dealers to sell their products and repayinventory credit, rather than donor funds.

    25

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    30/52

    Agro-dealer networks have been used in input markeng programmes in Zimbabwe,

    Malawi and Mozambique. In general, performance in these cases suggests that agro-

    dealer programmes can eecvely link input suppliers to rural markets. As rural markets

    expand, farmers input search costs and prices should decline. An absence of policy

    reversals or government intervenons that cripple private sector incenves is crical in

    the development of agro-dealer networks.

    Research-Commerce Linkage to Test Input Demand

    Most smallholders in Africa culvate open-pollinated crops (e.g. millet, sorghum, peanuts,

    soybeans, cowpeas). Much research has gone into improved variees of open-pollinated

    seeds (OPV), yet the number of farmers using these improved variees on a regular basis

    remains very small (Kelly et al. 2003). Local traders are oen unwilling to stock such seeds

    because they perceive farmer demand as weak. Even when demand is strong, the fact that

    farmers need to purchase the OPV seeds only once in a year and can then subsequently

    produce their own seeds tend to hinder the development of commercial OPV seed markets.

    ICRISAT undertook a pilot programme with Seed Company of Zimbabwe (SeedCo) to improve

    the companys knowledge of potenal demand for OPV maize seeds, and recognized

    the importance of addressing the aordability constraint at the farm level. To improve

    aordability, the company was encouraged to sell OPV seeds in small packages. SeedCo,

    the major wholesaler of hybrid maize seed in Zimbabwe, then introduced the OPV small

    packs to farmers using an already well-established network of 14 credit-worthy retailers in

    Southern Zimbabwe who were familiar with seed markeng. SeedCo oered retailer credit

    and reduced retailer risk by taking back unsold stocks at the end of the season.

    However, the programme was disrupted by government price controls that forced wholesale

    margins to zero and a free distribuon programme that increased uncertainty not only in the

    emerging OPV seed market but also in the tradional hybrid maize market. Nevertheless,

    the experience shows that research instuons have an important role to play in raising

    awareness of new inputs among potenal suppliers. This type of research-private sector

    partnership, worked well in Zimbabwe (at least for some me) because a strong commercial

    seed sector had already been developed to supply hybrid maize. Consequently, SeedCo was

    able to draw on nancial reserves and distribuon networks to test the market for OPVs.

    Two important sub-components of the success story in this case were SeedCos buy-back

    policy, which reduced retailer risk, and their aenon to aordability through prescribed

    retailer margins and packaging in smaller units. On the other hand the case also shows

    that a supporve policy environment (i.e. absence of unreasonable price controls and

    compeon from seed give-away programmes) is necessary for both the inial success

    and long-run sustainability of commercial input markets.

    Financing Inputs and Affordability

    A number of recent eorts on the alleviaon of agricultural inputs aordability constraints

    employ two broad categories of strategic opons: (i) reducon in package size and (ii)a variety of acvies to improve access to input credit. Many publicaons have noted

    26 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    31/52

    that the current credit problem in Sub-Saharan Africa is typically characterized by one of

    market failure associated with imperfect informaon in the presence of risk (for examples,

    Dorward et al. 1998; Kydd et al. 2002). They inmate that market failures occur because it is

    costly to screen input credit applicants and instuons for contract enforcement are weak;

    moreover insurance is absent (for similar reasons) and farmers lack collateral for loans.

    Nevertheless, there have been innovave eorts, in recent mes, to solve the credit

    problems of smallholders. These have been led mainly by donor-funded NGOs to build

    farmer associaons capable of accessing private sources of input credit, group lending,

    interlinking market arrangements for export crops in various stages of transformaon from

    pre-reform parastatals to post-reform compeve markets, out-grower schemes, and

    government-run input credit programmes (Kelly et al. 2003).

    Reducing the Package Size

    Small packages of inputs appeal to farmers in general and to smallholder farmers in parcular

    for various reasons. It makes it possible for them to experiment with new seed variees

    without making a major nancial commitment; they can diversify their crops to reduce

    risk by purchasing small packages of several dierent seed types; and they can purchase

    ferlizers in small, incremental quanes as the rainy season progresses as this reduces the

    risk of purchasing large quanes that cannot be used eecvely due to poor rainfall.

    An enabling policy environment is crucial to encourage trader-led small-pack approach

    to input markeng. Policy reforms that remove price controls and subsidies as well as

    government withdrawal from direct market intervenon in the input sector are necessary

    to create an enabling input market environment.

    Both the SCODP and SeedCo programmes in Kenaya and Zimbabwe respecvely (discussed

    earlier) aribute a large share of their successes to the use of small and aordable

    packages. The trader-led small-pack approach in response to policy reform worked well

    where input dealers were already present and agriculture was highly protable. However,

    in the connued absence of commercial networks in marginal producon zones, there is

    the need for the expansion of NGO iniaves to act as catalyst to develop the demand

    necessary to enhance the commercial sector (Kelly et al. 2003).

    Credit Through Building Farmer Associations

    The logic behind the associaon building approach is that collecve acon has the capacity

    to reduce farm-level transacon costs for potenal input suppliers and output buyers. The

    approach is an aempt to foster the development of boom up associaons characterized

    by self-selecon and self-management.

    There are several examples of the associaon based approach in several countries in SSA.

    A collaborave CARE/CLUSA eort in Mozambique through the Viable Iniave for the

    development of Agriculture (VIDA) used this approach to organize 80,000 farm families

    into 1400 associaons to access credit from commercial companies for input purchase and

    output markeng. Maize yields doubled and incomes increased by 20-30% for parcipangfarmers (Kelly et al. 2003).

    27

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    32/52

    In Malis coon zone, USAID encouraged banks to provide input credit by oering loan

    guarantees to CLUSA-supported associaons during their rst four operang seasons. Both

    guarantees and farmer training were necessary to get the credit process started. Again

    in Mali, the promoon of village savings and loans associaons substanally improved

    access to input credit and repayment in Malis Oce du Niger irrigated rice producon

    zone where major credit defaults were common in the early 1990s (Kelly et. al 2003).

    An example of an integrated associaon system is a ve-year CLUSA programme in Zambia

    that has supported farmers in creang 371 rural group businesses (RGB), a network of

    97 depots (groups of RGBs which coordinate input distribuon and crop dispatch), and

    a farmer-operated extension service. According to Kelly et al. (2003), maize yields for

    parcipang farmers have tripled and the producon of newly introduced cash crops

    (paprika and chilies) has increased input use and net income.

    A common thread in the programmes for developing famer associaons is the need to

    develop farmer literacy and management skills for both individual and cooperave

    acvies. Another important element is the need to support banks through assistance

    with management informaon systems and/or loan guarantees. Also, promong

    agricultural input credit through farmer associaons works best when there are protable

    input technologies (oen a funcon of public goods such as roads, markets, irrigaon

    infrastructure as well as technology research) and strong contract-enforcement instuons

    (either social, polical, or legal).

    Group Lending

    An approach to micronance for rural farmers which has gained popularity among NGOs,

    in parcular, and donors in Ghana is the group lending scheme which is quite similar to

    farmer associaons. The raonale for group lending is to reduce transacon costs to the

    banks as well as the borrower, and to enhance repayment rates. Loans are accessed by

    groups of farmers (10-20) but disbursed to individuals within the group who are solely

    responsible for repayment. However, all group members are held jointly responsible for

    the total loan amounts (Al-Hassan 2000). Group lending has been useful in targeng poor

    and vulnerable rural farmers, parcularly female farmers.

    Interlinked Markets in Transition

    Interlinked markets permit exporters or processors to use farmers expected harvests as

    collateral for seasonal input credit. The system is expected to be mutually benecial: farmers

    get credit for yield-increasing inputs while buyers can lock-in potenal supply. Kelly et al.

    (2003) have observed that historically, credit repayment oered in the context of interlinked

    markets in SSA has experienced higher than average rates of repayment because the output

    markets were monopsonisc farmers had no alternave outlet so they sold to their creditor.

    However, as compeon for the targeted crop grows, opportunies diminish for linking

    input/output transacons capable of reducing credit risk and lowering input nancing costs.

    Examples of programmes involved in interlinked markets abound in SSA. Coon produconin Francophone West Africa has long been done under an arrangement where naonal

    28 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    33/52

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    34/52

    the required inputs. The Agricultural Development Bank (ADB) idenes input suppliers

    who are authorized to supply inputs to the nucleus farmers. It is the responsibility of the

    nucleus farmer to distribute inputs to out-grower farmers, monitor their use, and recover

    loans from the out-growers. Because the nucleus farmer is required to be a successful

    large scale farmer (and in some cases a processor of the raw commodity, in addion) he/

    she is expected to impart best pracces to the out-growers.

    The target crops under the scheme in Ghana are maize, pineapple, plantain, rice, soybeans,

    and vegetables. These are selected for reasons of improved food security (maize and

    plantain), increased non-tradional agricultural exports (pineapple and vegetables) and as

    import substutes to save foreign exchange (soybean). The out-grower scheme in Ghana

    has parcularly been successful in oil palm producon.

    Government Credit

    Government-run input credit programmes have been a common feature in most SSA

    countries, parcularly in the pre-reform era. Such credit programmes make credit more

    accessible in situaons where commercial banks nd costs prohibively high. Moreover,

    government-run credit programmes can increase aggregate demend for purchased inputs

    when there is a credit market failure, thereby boosng commercial interest in developing

    input supply networks. However, the poor performance of these programmes suggests a

    failure to address the underlying problems. Many beneciaries oen regard such credit

    as gis from government and in the emerging democracies, ruling polical party acvists

    regard government credit as rewards for their eorts. Thus, repayment rates are oen very

    low, ranging from 30% in Zambias programme to 60% in the case of Senegal (Kelly et al.

    2003).

    A sort of success story is the Ethiopia government-guaranteed credit scheme which

    was the driving force behind the Parcipatory Agricultural Development and Extension

    Training Service (PADETS), which followed the successful introducon of improved maize

    technologies by Sasakawa Global 2000. Approximately 42% of farm households rich and

    poor had access to modern inputs, and the programme is credited with making a major

    contribuon to increased cereal producon and a very high (over 98% in most years) loan

    repayment rates (Howard et al. 1999). The high repayment rate is aributed to Ethiopias

    very strong stand on repayment, with arrest or conscaon of assets where necessary

    (Kelly et al. 2003 with reference to Stepanek 1999). The success of the programme led to a

    drasc drop (80%) in maize prices, illustrang the need to combine technology promoon

    programmes with output market development acvies, including improvement in

    transportaon infrastructure to smulate more trade between surplus and decit zones.

    This second generaon problem arising out of a success story was encountered in Malawis

    agricultural input subsidy programme (MAISP) too (Chirwa et al. 2010).

    The issue of lack of cost-eecveness of these programmes in smulang commercial input

    market development has been raised. This arises out of the high cost of the programmes;

    heavy credit administraon obligaons placed on extension sta, making it dicult forthem to perform normal extension acvies; and high levels of rent seeking associated

    30 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    35/52

    with a tendency to favour polically well-placed suppliers, thereby constraining the

    development of lower cost, truly commercial input supply networks (Chirwa et al. 2010;

    Jayne et al. 2003; FSRP Zambia 2000).

    Reducing Risks

    Upton (1979) points out both price and producon risks that face African farmers (both

    subsistence and commercial farmers) and stresses the fact that household food security is

    the major objecve of smallholder farmers rather than output maximizaon. Thus, African

    smallholder farmers are oen reluctant to use new inputs because of both producon

    and price risks that can render input use unprotable in a given season or threaten food

    security. It is reported that risk averse behavior on the part of SSA farmers, has been

    found to account for ferlizer applicaon rates that are, at least, 20% below economically

    opmum rates (Binswinger and Sillers 1983).

    Most of the strategic opons discussed above addressed the risk issues in some way. These

    include:

    i. Small packs that reduce the monetary outlay necessary for input use thereby reducing

    the size of potenal losses;

    ii. Rescheduling of credit reduces farmers risk of having to pay for the negave

    consequences of producon risks in a single season;

    iii. Input quality control reduces the risk of farmers purchasing ineecve inputs;

    iv. Donor-funded credit guarantees provide a bridge between banks and farmer associaons

    and reduces the risk to banks and potenal input suppliers, thus encouraging themboth to enter the market and expand distribuon networks;

    v. Agro-dealer programmes provide a donor/distributor risk sharing mechanism that

    encourages distributors to oer credit to new input retailers;

    vi. The SeedCo buy-back scheme encouraged small retailers to parcipate in tesng the

    market for improved OPVs because they did not need to worry about the risk of carry-

    over stocks; and,

    vii. Contract enforcement in Ethiopia has reduced the risk of default and contributed to

    sustainable funding of an input credit programme.

    In addion to these, governments can reduce risks associated with input use and markeng

    in relavely low-cost ways as suggested by Kelly et al. 2003:

    i. Support for market informaon systems that report input and output prices on a

    regular basis will help farmers and traders make beer input use and supply decisions;

    ii. Extension services that train farmers parcipang in demonstraon programmes to

    evaluate the protability of input use over me, taking into account producon price

    variability, can improve farmer decision-making concerning input use;

    iii. Research and extension to provide soil ferlity management pracces can reduce therisks and costs of input use;

    31

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    36/52

    iv. Naonal programmes of input quality controls can increase farmers condence in input

    suppliers and protect honest suppliers against competors selling adulterated products;

    v. In negoang more equitable terms of trade for African farmers through WTO, African

    governments could reduce price volality in export markets and protect farm incomes;

    vi. Crop insurance programmes tend to be costly and inecient in developing countries,

    but recent research on rainfall insurance may ulmately provide a viable alternave for

    reducing producon risk associated with bad weather.

    Risk is widely regarded as pervasive at both the farm and commercial level. Governments

    have numerous opportunies to invest in public goods capable of reducing risk and should

    not be in a posion of increasing risks for economic actors through unnecessary intervenons.

    Other Strategic Options

    There are other strategic opons oen applied by Non-Governmental Organzaons and

    governments. They are controversial in nature and widely applicable to the three generalcategories of constraints. Such controversial strategic opons include inputs for relief and

    food security; and government-run programmes.

    Inputs for Relief and Food Security

    Following drought or civil unrest, governments (and donors) oen instute programmes of

    input distribuon to vicms as a relief measure. They are also somemes used to redress

    circular declines in agricultural producvity and rising food insecurity. Such programmes,

    however, increase risk and uncertainty for the emerging commercial sector.

    Seed is oen distributed aer a drought when it is thought that seed stocks have been

    depleted. However, the tendency of governments and donors to resort rapidly to input

    distribuon programmes, which are somemes connued beyond the inial emergency,

    erodes the incenves for local traders to develop markets that can respond to future

    emergencies. Among the recent innovaons for reducing the negave market impacts of

    relief programmes are:

    i. The use of empirical data to establish a real need for relief. For example, ICRISAT

    has developed a Seeds Needs Assessment Tool which has been used successfully in

    Mozambique;

    ii. Local purchase of seed by relief agencies;

    iii. Distribuon of cash rather than seed (used successfully in Mozambique);

    iv. Distribuon of vouchers redeemable for seed through established seed retailers or at

    seed fairs.

    Vouchers have been used in many African countries to the benet of both beneciaries and

    input markeng agents. Vouchers can target poor household while promong commercial

    input distribuon. For examples, cash-equivalent input vouchers, which farmers can

    redeem from a menu of approved inputs, have been used in Zimbabwe; the SG 2000

    programme uses vouchers to distribute their inputs in Uganda; Malawi used vouchers inconjuncon with its starter pack and targeted input programme. Also seed vouchers have

    32 Input Market Iniaves that Support Innovaon Systems in Africa

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    37/52

    been used in conjuncon with seed fairs sponsored by Catholic Relief Services (CRS) when

    the key constraint was access rather than availability. This oers the farmers exibility

    in terms of suppliers as vouchers can be redeemed for local seed purchased from other

    farmers or commercial seed purchased from established retailers (Remington 2002; Jones

    2002).

    Government-Run Programmes

    Concerns over the slow expansion of commercial input supply networks in the face of

    declining soil ferlity and rising food insecurity have rekindled interest in government-run

    distribuon programmes. A typical example is the Malawi starter pack (SP) programme

    which aimed to increase household and naonal food security by promong naonal food

    self-suciency. The instrument for achieving these objecves was free distribuon of seed

    and ferlizer packs perming all farmers to plant 0.1 ha of maize/legume intercrops.

    Resource constraints led to more targeted distribuon and this targeted input programme

    (TIP) encountered numerous dicules in liming the input packs to the most needy

    farmers (Chirwa et al. 2010). SP/TIP used vouchers rather than direct delivery in an

    eort to contribute to input market development. However, SP/TIP largely passed up

    the opportunity to build commercial capacies to esmate, nance, procure, store and

    distribute inputs. Retailers simply act as depots for turning starter packs over to voucher

    recipients. There is also general agreement that SP/TIP is responsible for some crowding

    out of demand for ferlizer purchases (Adesina 2002).

    Government input distribuon programmes face several problems: polical interference,

    ineecveness of means-targeng, sizable leakages, procurement and distribuon delays,

    and inadequate farmer training that reduces the eecveness of the package (Chirwa et

    al. 2010).

    7.0 Enabling Environment for Strategic OptionsDorwards (2009) classicaon of development opportunies and constraints facing

    African farmers by ecological zones implies that these strategic opons are country

    specic. Besides, the behavior of private operators in the input markets will vary from

    one country to another. Thus the successful implementaon of the strategic opons will

    depend on the creaon of a favourable enabling environment in each specic country.

    It is parcularly pernent to address issues pertaining to the challenges and factors that

    confront smallholder farmers in accessing input markets; the organizaon of input markets;

    the role of educaon; and the specic roles that governments and private sectors need to

    play in creang the enabling environment.

    Smallholder Challenges

    The major challenge that smallholder farmers face is poverty that also aect all aspects of

    their use of modern inputs. Smallholders oen rely on their own sources of input supply,parcularly seeds, that lead to low producvity. Even when they use modern inputs their

    33

  • 7/29/2019 Input Market Initiatives for Web

    38/52

    applicaon is oen below recommended dosage or me of applicaon. They oen face

    long distances to the supply base of inputs and this adds to the cost of modern inputs.

    Smallholders also face challenges from the input suppliers in the input market chain. Inputs

    are oen not properly stored or catered for in storage with the result that the inputs get to

    the farmers in very poor state with their viability quesonable. The general impression is that

    there are too many actors in the input market chain feeding on the poor smallholder farmers.

    This is exacerbated by cartels that exist among the oligopolisc input dealers in Africa who

    are oen protected by rent seeking ocials in privilege posions to inuence policy.

    Organization of Input Markets

    In most sub-Saharan African countries, the agricultural input markets are not well organized

    and are dicult to understand. An enabling environment for the successful implementaon

    of the strategic opons requires a well organized and transparent input market system.

    Transparency must transcend from input imports or manufacturing through wholesalers andagro-input dealers down to the smallholder farmer. Transparency will be enhanced by well

    dened enforceable laws, rules and regulaons that must be obeyed by all stakeholders in

    the input market chain, and there must be no protecon for deviants no maer their status.

    Education and Training

    Educaon will create awareness among stakeholders and farmers and improve input

    markets in Africa. It is a well known fact that human capital is the most strategic factor

    for agricultural development. The educaon and training of stakeholders will create input

    market chains that will open the doors to knew knowledge and allow them to enter into

    reliable arrangements for the ecient delivery of inputs. The training of smallholder

    farmers will enable them to use inputs eciently, increase their demand for inputs and

    improve on their producvity. In parcular, educaon and training of stakeholders and

    smallholder farmers will enhance the use of modern technologies such as informaon and

    communicaon technology (ICT) as a devise to transform input market space. For example,

    the use of electronic plaorm to deliver prices of inputs to smallholder farmers through the

    medium of cell phones requires an understanding of stakeholders and smallholder farmers.

    Role of Government and Private Sector

    The role of government and the private sector in creang an enabling environment for the

    successful implementaon of the strategic opons is crucial. Governments in Africa need

    to shi emphasis from commodity markets, where they oen like to intervene, to that of

    making factor and input markets work more eciently. Governments need to build strong

    instuons with legal mandate to provide input quality control, parcularly with regards

    to industrial inputs such as ferlizer, fungicides and pescides. There are ve funcons that

    these public instuons must serve for the input markets to work adequately: protecon

    of property rights, market regulaon, macroeconomic stabilizaon, social ins