institute for monetary and economic studies bank of … · greece (e.g., d™erasmo and mendoza...

42
IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF JAPAN 2-1-1 NIHONBASHI-HONGOKUCHO CHUO-KU, TOKYO 103-8660 JAPAN You can download this and other papers at the IMES Web site: https://www.imes.boj.or.jp Do not reprint or reproduce without permission. Sovereign Default Triggered by Inability to Repay Debt Michinao Okachi Discussion Paper No. 2019-E-10

Upload: others

Post on 15-Apr-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

IMES DISCUSSION PAPER SERIES

INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES

BANK OF JAPAN

2-1-1 NIHONBASHI-HONGOKUCHO

CHUO-KU, TOKYO 103-8660

JAPAN

You can download this and other papers at the IMES Web site:

https://www.imes.boj.or.jp

Do not reprint or reproduce without permission.

Sovereign Default Triggered by

Inability to Repay Debt

Michinao Okachi

Discussion Paper No. 2019-E-10

Page 2: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

NOTE: IMES Discussion Paper Series is circulated in

order to stimulate discussion and comments. The

views expressed in Discussion Paper Series are

those of authors and do not necessarily reflect

those of the Bank of Japan or the Institute for

Monetary and Economic Studies.

Page 3: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

IMES Discussion Paper Series 2019-E-10

July 2019

Sovereign Default Triggered by

Inability to Repay Debt

Michinao Okachi*

Abstract

The Greek sovereign default episode in 2012 was characterized by its high debt-to-

GDP ratio and the severe economic contraction following the default. Conventional

strategic default models designed to analyze a government's incentive to default

often fail to replicate these characteristics. To address this issue, we provide a

dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) model where a sovereign default is

triggered by the government's inability to repay its debt. We show that the inability-

to-repay model replicates the empirical features observed in Greece, while the

conventional strategic default model calibrated to the Greek economy does not.

Keywords: Sovereign Default; Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium; Inability

to Repay Debt; Strategic Decision to Default; Fiscal Limit; Laffer Curve

JEL classification: E32, E44, F34, H63

* Economist, Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan (currently,

Department of Economics, Graduate School of Economics and Management, Tohoku University,

E-mail: [email protected])

The author thanks Junko Koeda, Ichiro Muto, Ko Nakayama, Taisuke Nakata, Eiji Okano,

Tatsuyoshi Okimoto, Tatsushi Okuda, Shigenori Shiratsuka, Nao Sudo, Shingo Watanabe,

Tomohiro Tsuruga, Chung Tran, Francesco Zanetti, participants at CEF 2018, the JEA 2017

Spring Meeting and 2018 Spring Meeting, the 4th Hitotsubashi Summer Institute, and seminar

presentations at Aoyama Gakuin University, Australian National University, Chuo University,

Hosei University, Kobe University, and Osaka University. The views expressed in this paper are

those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official views of the Bank of Japan.

Page 4: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

1 Introduction

The Greek sovereign default episode in 2012 was extraordinary in two respects.1 First,

the size of the public debt was the highest in the history of default, reaching 199.2 billion

euros at the outset of its default. The debt-to-GDP ratio was over 150 percent when

it defaulted, approximately twice as high as the average of sovereign defaults in other

countries that took place from 1982 to 2013, as shown in Figure 1 (a). Second, the Greek

default had a huge impact on its domestic economy in terms of severity and length of the

economic contraction after the default. GDP dropped by more than 20 percent, as shown

in Figure 1 (b). In addition, the economic contraction in Greece continued for more than

3 years. This is in contrast with what most defaulting countries witnessed in previous

episodes. As shown in Figure 1, on average, GDP in defaulting countries declined by

about 3 percent when the government defaulted and recovered to the pre-default level at

a faster pace, typically within 3 years.

Figure 1: Development of Debt-to-GDP ratio and GDP around Default Period

(a) Debt-to-GDP Ratio (b) GDP

­3 ­2 ­1 0 1 2 3Year

0

50

100

150

200

Per

cent

AverageOne Std Deviation BandGreece (2012 episode)Argentina (2001 episode)

­3 ­2 ­1 0 1 2 3Year

­25

­20

­15

­10

­5

0

5

10

15

20

Per

cent

Notes 1: The horizontal axis represents the number of years after the onset of default.

2: The vertical axis in panel (b) represents the cumulative changes in GDP from 3 years

before default.

3: The numbers of default episodes used for computing debt-to-GDP ratio and GDP in the

�gure are 86 and 104, respectively. These episodes are taken from Schmitt-Grohe and

Uribe (2017).

Source: Historical Public Debt Database (IMF), and World Development Indicators (World Bank).

In the current paper, we argue that these empirical characteristics of the Greek de-

fault are not captured by conventional strategic default models in which the default is1In this paper, following the Standard and Poor�s de�nition, sovereign default is de�ned as the failure

of a government to meet a principal or interest payment on the due date. The duration of default isde�ned as the period that the country is not able to access bond markets after the default.

1

Page 5: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

triggered by the government�s strategic decision. While some studies in the literature

apply conventional strategic default models to explain the European debt crisis including

Greece (e.g., D�Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016),

they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP ratio and the severe contraction observed in

the data.2 As seminal strategic model studies such as Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), Arel-

lano (2008), Yue (2010) and Mendoza and Yue (2012) state clearly that their models are

developed to analyze emerging countries, strategic default models are originally designed

to describe defaults in emerging countries in which the debt-to-GDP ratio tends to be

low and the economic contraction is less severe. Regarding the debt-to-GDP ratio, as Bi

(2012) and Paluszynski (2017) point out, the strategic default models cannot replicate the

high debt outstanding observed in the data. For example, the average debt-to-GDP ratio

in Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), Yue (2010), and Mendoza and Yue (2012) ranges from

10 percent to 23 percent, substantially lower than the level observed in Argentina (50

percent) or Greece (150 percent). To address this issue, Hatchondo and Martinez (2009),

Chatterjee and Eyigungor (2012) and Hatchondo, Martinez and Sosa-Padilla (2016) in-

troduce long-term bonds into sovereign default analysis to explain debt-to-GDP ratio.3

However, these studies are focused on explaining defaults in emerging economies and not

applied to Greece where debt-to-GDP ratio is substantially higher.

As for the severe and lengthy economic contraction, strategic default models cannot

replicate the data observed in Greece. This is partly because the models assume the

period of exclusion from �nancial markets after default is shorter than the data. For

example, Arellano (2008) and Yue (2010) set the average exclusion period to be less than

1 year so that the economy in the model recovers to the normal state at a rapid pace. In

the data, as reported in Dias and Richmond (2009), the exclusion period for defaulting

emerging countries ranges from 5.7 to 8.4 years. To address this issue, some recent studies

such as Benjamin and Wright (2009), Bi (2008) and Asonuma and Joo (2019a) analyze

the lengthy default duration as a result of prolonged debt restructuring negotiations.

Alternatively, Gordon and Gerron-Quintana (2018), Park (2017) and Asonuma and Joo

(2019b) emphasize the role of capital with which economic recovery can be delayed by

the weak investment after the default. However, none of these studies analyzed both

high debt-to-GDP and the severe economic contraction in Greece in a uni�ed modelling

framework. We argue that when the debt-to-GDP ratio is high and the adverse e¤ects

2Paluszynski (2017) and Bocola, Bornstein and Dovis (2019) point out that those models do notproperly describe the crisis.

3D�Erasmo (2011) emphasizes the role of the government�s reputation in explaining high debt-to-GDPratios.

2

Page 6: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

of default are considerable as in the case of Greece, the government in strategic default

models is not willing to default because it is too costly.4 ;5

To address these issues, we propose a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE)

model where the sovereign default is triggered by the government�s inability to repay

its debt, rather than the government�s strategic decision (Bi 2012, Bi and Leeper 2013,

Juessen, Linnermann and Schabert 2016). As Bi (2012) points out, this class of models

can describe high debt-to-GDP ratios observed in advanced countries including Greece.

Following Bi (2012), our inability-to-repay default model assumes that the government

defaults when the debt outstanding exceeds the sum of discounted maximum future �scal

surpluses determined by the shape of the La¤er curve. The government imposes a tax

on �nal goods, and issues new bonds in order to �nance its expenditure and repayment.

When debt-to-GDP ratio is low, the tax rate follows a linear rule. When debt-to-GDP

ratio is higher, the government tries to satisfy the intertemporal government budget con-

straint as much as possible by raising the rate nonlinearly. However, the government

cannot raise tax revenue beyond the �scal limit level. Once defaults, the government

introduces the austerity measure, namely an increase in the tax rate, to maximize tax

revenue. The high tax rate during this period leads to a severe economic contraction.

Similarly to Mendoza and Yue�s (2012) model, the economy su¤ers from the e¤ects of

�nancial autarky after the default as well as the adverse e¤ects arising from the high tax

rate, because domestic �rms cannot raise working capital necessary to import intermedi-

ate goods from abroad.

We compare this model with Mendoza and Yue (2012)�s strategic default model, both

of which are calibrated to the Greek economy. We conduct a quantitative simulation

that demonstrates the inability-to-repay default model closely captures the empirical

characteristics of the Greek episode, i.e., the high debt-to-GDP ratio at the time of

default and the severe contraction in GDP and its components following the default. In

contrast, the strategic default model cannot generate the default itself.

4In addition to these two issues, the discount factor in many strategic default models is set to a fairlylow value in order to replicate the default probability in the data. For example, the discount factor usedin Aguiar and Gopinath (2006), Yue (2010) and Mendoza and Yue (2012) ranges from 0.74 to 0.88, whichis substantially lower than the value widely used in existing studies. For example, Smets and Wouters(2003) use 0.99 as the discount factor.

5In fact, there are several anecdotes that support the view that Greek government tried hard to avoidthe default. For example, the government increased both value added and income tax rates, implementedcuts in salary for public employees and reduced public pension payments. Consequently, the tax revenue-to-GDP ratio surged from 38.9 percent in 2009 to 44.0 percent in 2011. Besides, the government hadbeen under strong external pressure from EU nations and the IMF to avoid the disorderly default whenreceiving emergency funding. These anecdotes are consistent with the empirical results of Levy-Yeyatiand Panizza (2011) that policymakers tend to defer default until the government�s insolvency becomeapparent.

3

Page 7: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

This paper contributes to the literature in two aspects. First, to the best of our

knowledge, this is the �rst paper that develops an inability-to-repay type of sovereign de-

fault model that is calibrated in detail to the Greek economy.6 Second, we quantitatively

investigate which of the two default mechanisms can describe both the high debt-to-GDP

ratio and the severe economic contraction observed in Greek episode in a uni�ed frame-

work. We replicate both features with our calibrated inability-to-repay model. We also

show that the strategic default model such as Mendoza and Yue (2012) is not able to

explain Greek episode.7

This paper is organized as follows. In Section 2, we present both an inability-to-repay

default model and a strategic default model. In Section 3, we explain the calibration

strategy and solution methods. In Section 4, we conduct a quantitative analysis using

models calibrated to Greece and compare the implications of these two models. Finally,

we present concluding remarks in Section 5.

2 Model

In this paper, we construct two sovereign default models, each with its own distinct mech-

anism for triggering default. The common feature of the models is that both economies

are small open economies, consisting of four domestic agents: households, �nal goods

�rms, intermediate goods �rms and the government, and two foreign agents: foreign in-

vestors and foreign �rms. An overview of the model is given in Figure 2. The setting

of the private sector is borrowed from Mendoza and Yue (2012). Households consume

�nal goods and supply their labor to both �nal and intermediate goods �rms. Final

goods �rms produce �nal goods from labor and Armington-aggregated domestic and im-

ported intermediate goods with time varying TFP that follows the AR(1) process as:

At = �AAt�1 + "A;t, where "A � N(0; �2A). Imported intermediate goods consist of a

continuum of di¤erentiated intermediate goods that are aggregated using a Dixit-Stiglitz

aggregator. When importing the intermediate goods from abroad, �nal goods �rms need

to borrow working capital. This implies that when the government defaults, �nal goods

6In the literature, a range of research analyzes the interaction between sovereign default and nominaldevaluation (e.g., Na et al. 2018). In this paper, however, following the existing studies on the Greekdefault episode in 2012 (e.g., D�Erasmo and Mendoza 2016), we abstract such e¤ect on default. Thisis because Greece adopts euro as its currency, and its monetary policy is conducted by ECB which isliterally independent from the Greek government.

7Acharya and Rajan (2013) develops a model in which a sovereign default can be triggered by eitherthe inability to repay or by a strategic decision, and investigates the interaction between �scal stabilityand �nancial stability.

4

Page 8: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Figure 2: Model Overview

�rms lose access to the �nancial market and cannot import these intermediate goods.

The absence of imported intermediate goods leads to a loss in production e¢ ciency, and

results in a decline in �nal goods production. Intermediate goods �rms use only labor in

their production processes. See Appendix A for details of the settings regarding private

agents and the de�nition of the competitive equilibria under the two proposed models.

2.1 Government and Foreign Investors

At time t, the government repays its debt Bt issued in the previous period, spends govern-

ment expenditure Gt, collects tax revenue Tt, and issues new government bonds Bt+1 with

price qt. Government bonds are of one-period maturity, zero coupon and non-contingent,

taking both negative and positive values. A negative value for issuance of government

bonds indicates that the government�s net assets are positive and the government receives

interest income from foreign investors with the world risk-free interest rate rf . The gov-

ernment imposes a tax on production of �nal goods Yt. Thus, the total tax revenue Tt is

given by:

Tt = � tYt; (1)

5

Page 9: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

where � t 2 [0; 1] is the tax rate. In normal times, the government issues new governmentbonds Bt+1 to meet the budget constraint:

qtBt+1 � Bt +Gt � Tt: (2)

If the government defaults, it does not repay its debt to foreign investors. Instead, inter-

national organizations (e.g. the IMF) bail out all of the debts and provide funding �Ftto the government to make up its budget de�cit. Note that at this state, the government

cannot issue new bonds by itself due to exclusion from the �nancial market. Exclusion

from the �nancial market continues for at least � periods. After � periods, the govern-

ment returns to the �nancial markets with the exogenous probability #, and with the

exogenously given debt outstanding Br.

Foreign investors are risk-neutral and behave as perfectly competitive agents, invest-

ing in both government bonds and working capital, taking all prices as given. If the

government defaults, these investors receive only a reduced amount of government bond

(1 � �)Bt from the international organizations, where � is the haircut rate. From the

expected zero pro�t condition of investment in government bonds, the bond is priced by:

qt =1

1 + rff(1� P et ) + P et (1� �)g; (3)

where P et is the probability of default in the next period.

2.2 Default Scheme

In this section, we describe separately the two distinct default mechanisms, inability-to-

repay debt and strategic decision to default.

2.2.1 Inability-to-Repay Default

Tax Rate Rule Under the inability-to-repay default model, the tax rate rule consists

of three parts.

First, when the debt outstanding is su¢ ciently low, similar to Davig, Leeper and

Walker (2010) and Bi (2012), the government increases its tax rate in proportion to the

debt outstanding:

� lrt = � + �(Bt �B); (4)

6

Page 10: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

where � and B are the steady-state tax rate and debt outstanding that are exogenously

given, and �(� 0) is a tax rate adjustment parameter.Second, when the debt outstanding reaches a threshold value above which the govern-

ment cannot meet the intertemporal budget constraint, it adjusts the tax rate to satisfy

the constraint.8 The renewed intertemporal budget constraint is derived as:

Bt �nYj=0

qt+jBt+n+1 +

nXi=0

iYj=0

qt+j�1(T (� t+i; At+i)�G(gt+i)); (5)

where qt�1 = 1. Following Gali, López-Salido and Vallés (2007), gt is the government

expenditure expressed as deviations from the steady state, standardized by GDP, and

following the AR(1) process, i.e., gt = �ggt�1 + "g;t, where "g;t � N(0; �2g). The transver-

sality condition to ensure that the debt outstanding is not accumulated faster than the

discount rate is:

limn!1

nYj=0

qt+jBt+n+1 = 0: (6)

The intertemporal budget constraint with the transversality condition is derived as:

Bt �1Xi=0

iYj=0

qt+j�1(T (� t+i; At+i)�G(gt+i)): (7)

This constraint indicates that the current debt obligation has to be smaller than the sum

of the primary surplus over the entire future periods discounted by the price of government

bonds. The government tries to satisfy this constraint by changing the tax rate � t that

a¤ects the tax revenue Tt while the debt outstanding Bt is assumed to be predetermined

and government expenditure Gt is assumed to be exogenous. If the government maintains

the current tax rate � t in the future, the sum of the expected �scal surplus evaluated by

the price of government bonds St (hereafter, expected surplus) is:

St = S(� t; At; gt) = Et1Xi=0

iYj=0

qt+j�1(T (� t; At+i)�G(gt+i)): (8)

If the tax rate determined by the linear tax rate rule (4) does not satisfy the condition

Bt � S(� t; At; gt), i.e., the amount of debt outstanding Bt must be less than or equal to

8More precisely, the government sets the sequence of a speci�c tax rate that takes the same valuefrom the current period to the in�nite future, such that it satis�es the intertemporal government budgetconstraint.

7

Page 11: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

the expected surplus, the government needs to deviate from the linear rule and adjust

the tax rate to satisfy the condition, Bt = S(� t; At; gt). Thus, the tax rate in this case,

� est , is:

� est = S�1(Bt; At; gt): (9)

The threshold of the debt outstanding Bt at which the debt outstanding exceeds the

expected surplus under the linear rule is denoted by Zint(At; gt).

Third, we assume that the tax rate is bounded from above. The government is not

able to set a tax rate above some point at which the direct increase in tax revenue from

the tax rate increase is fully o¤set by the decrease in tax revenue that arises from the

drop in �nal goods due to the increase in the tax rate. In other words, in this case, the

economy is at the top of the La¤er curve. Moreover, following Bi, Shen and Yang (2014),

we assume that the government faces political disturbance % 2 [0; 1] that prevents thegovernment from setting the tax rate at the top of the curve. This political disturbance is

interpreted as policymakers�lacking the power or willingness to impose a severe austerity

policy because such policy is often accompanied by a heavy burden for taxpayers. Thus,

the maximum tax rate that the government can set, �mat , is:

�ma(At) = (1� %) ��argmax

� tT (� t; At)

�: (10)

The sum of expected maximum �scal surplus discounted by the price of government

bonds, denoted by Zmat , is:

Zma(At; gt) = Et1Xi=0

iYj=0

qt+j�1(T (�mat+i; At+i)�G(gt+i)): (11)

If the debt outstanding exceeds the expected maximum surplus Zma(At; gt), the govern-

ment does not increase the tax rate further, because of political disturbance, and declares

a default. The government�s tax rate rule is summarized as:

� t =

8>>>>>><>>>>>>:� lrt if Bt � Zint(At; gt);

� est if Zint(At; gt) < Bt � Zma(At; gt);

�mat if Bt > Zma(At; gt) .

(12)

8

Page 12: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Figure 3 illustrates this tax rate rule.9 ;10

Figure 3: Tax Rate Rule under Inability-to-Repay Default Model

Finally, in the default state, the government is forced by international organizations to

introduce the austerity measure and to set its tax rate so that it can collect the maximum

tax revenue without political disturbance, namely the rate that corresponds to the top

of the La¤er curve (� tot ).

Default Region In the inability-to-repay default model, the government defaults when

the debt outstanding exceeds the �scal limit. The �scal limit b�t is drawn from the

distribution of the sum of discounted maximum �scal surpluses denoted by B�:11

B�(At; gt) =

1Xi=0

iYj=0

qt+j�1(T (�mat+i; At+i)�G(gt+i)): (13)

Whether the economy is in the default state or not at the beginning of period t is

denoted by �t 2 f�n;t; �d;tg, where �n;t and �d;t represent non-default state and default9If Zint(At; gt) > Zma(At; gt), the tax rate rule only consists of two parts: � lrt and �

mat .

10As shown in Figure 3, the linear tax rule alone does not correspond to the default at expectedmaximum surplus, failing to explain the high debt to GDP upon default as observed in the data.

11As Ghosh et al. (2013) points out, a small shock to the current primary balance can lead to asubstantial di¤erence in the �scal limit. For example, if the interest rate is 1 percent, a 1 percentagepoint increase in the current �scal surplus relative to GDP pushes up the �scal limit relative to GDP by100 percentage points.

9

Page 13: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

state respectively.12 The default region �I(Bt; �n;t; b�t ) that shapes the set of TFP and

government expenditure in which the debt outstanding exceeds the �scal limit in the next

period is de�ned as:

�I(Bt; �n;t; b�t ) = fAt 2 A, gt 2 G : Bt > b�t , �t = �n;tg: (14)

The probability of inability-to-repay default in the next period P I;et is the probability

that TFP and government expenditure shocks fall into the default region:

P I;e(At; gt; Bt+1; �n;t+1; b�t+1) =

Z Z�I(Bt+1;�n;t+1;b

�t+1)

fA(At+1; At)fg(gt+1; gt)dAt+1dgt+1;

(15)

where fA and f g are the transition probability function of TFP and government expen-

diture respectively. Note also that, foreign investors are assumed to price the government

bonds depending on the probability of inability-to-repay default, i.e., the probability of

default is set at P et = P I;et .

2.2.2 Strategic Default

In this subsection, we explain the alternative default mechanism; strategic decision to

default that is widely studied in the existing literature. In this alternative model, the

government chooses to default if and only if defaulting is the better option for the gov-

ernment.13

Tax Rate Rule Similarly to existing studies, we assume that the government sets its

tax rate following the linear rule (4).

Default Region The government makes the decision regarding its default so as to

maximize households� lifetime utility. Thus, the government�s optimization problem is

12Obviously, the transition to the default state can take place only from the non-default state (i.e.�t = �n;t).

13The implicit assumption commonly made in strategic default models is that there is an upper boundregarding the debt-to-GDP ratio in the economy, and the government decides to default or not underthis upper bound. This assumption rules out Ponzi schemes. For example, Mendoza and Yue (2012)assume the largest debt amount the government can repay with full commitment as output over risk-free interest rate. One key di¤erence between this upper bound and the �scal limit considered in theinability-to-repay model is that the former considers the use of lump-sum tax whereas the latter doesnot. Following the convention of the strategic default model, we assume in the analysis below that thegovernment exploits the lump-sum tax to meet the intertemporal government budget constraint whenstudying the strategic default model. Note also that when studying the inability-to-default model, weassume that the government is unable to use a lump-sum tax.

10

Page 14: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

formulated as the maximization of its value function de�ned as:

V (At; gt; Bt; �n;t) = maxdt2f0;1g

f(1� dt)Vn(At; gt; Bt; �n;t) + dtVd(At; gt; �n;t)g; (16)

where dt represents the government�s default decision, taking 1 for default and 0 for non-

default, and Vn and Vd represent the government�s value functions corresponding to the

non-default state and default state respectively. They are de�ned as:

Vn(At; gt; Bt; �n;t) = u(Ct; Lt) + �Et[V (At+1; gt+1; Bt+1; �n;t+1)j(At; gt; Bt; �n;t)]; (17)

and

Vd(At; gt; �n;t) = u(Ct; Lt) + �f(1� #)Et[Vd(At+1; gt+1; �d;t+1)j(At; gt; �n;t)] (18)

+#Et[Vn(At+1; gt+1; Br; �n;t+1)j(At; gt; �n;t)]g;

where � 2 (0; 1) is the discount factor and # is an exogenously given recovery probabilitywith which the defaulted government reverts back to the non-default state.14 The default

region �S and the probability of default P S;e are de�ned as:

�S(Bt; �n;t) = fAt 2 A, gt 2 G : Vd(At; gt; �n;t) > Vn(At; gt; Bt; �n;t), �t = �n;tg; (19)

and

P S;e(At; gt; Bt+1; �n;t+1) =

Z Z�S(Bt+1;�n;t+1)

fA(At+1; At)fg(gt+1; gt)dAt+1dgt+1: (20)

The price of the government bond depends on the probability of strategic default as

P et = P S;et .

3 Calibration and Solution Method

For the purpose of the quantitative exercise focusing on the Greek default episode in

2012, we calibrate the two models to the Greek economy. In this section, we explain the

calibration strategy and solution method.

14In this model, following Mendoza and Yue (2012), we assume � = 0.

11

Page 15: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

3.1 Calibration Strategy

Most parameters are calibrated to the data from 1999Q1 to 2016Q4 except some deep

parameters that are set to be consistent with existing studies.

Government Regarding the parameters related to the government�s bond price, the

discount factor � is set at 0.99 following Smets and Wouters (2003), which implies the

risk-free interest rate rf is 0.01. We set the haircut rate � to 0.05 so as to be consistent

with the actual bond spread, i.e., the quarterly long-term interest rate di¤erential of

Greek government bonds relative to the German bonds in 2012.15 The government debt

outstanding at the steady state B is set so that the debt-to-GDP ratio at steady state is

104 percent, which matches with the historical average in Greece from 1999 to 2008.16 ;17

As for the parameters related to �scal surplus/de�cit, we set the steady state govern-

ment expenditure-to-GDP G to 0:385, to match the data from 1999 to 2008.18 To close

the �scal surplus/de�cit at the steady state, the steady-state tax rate � is set so that the

tax revenues are equalized to G.

Private Agents The households�utility function is of the Greenwood-Hercowitz-Hu¤man

(1988) preference19 as u(ct; Lt) =

�Ct�

L1+�t1+�

�1���1

1�� , where � is the degree of risk aversion,

which we set to unity so that the function is the log-utility, and � is the inverse Frisch

elasticity of labor supply, which we set at 0.455, the standard value used in existing RBC

models.

As for �rms, the intermediate input share in �nal goods production �M is set to

0:39 to match the total intermediate consumption over gross �nal goods in Greece in

the early 2000s, taken from the OECD�s STAN Input-Output data. The labor input

share in �nal goods production �L is set at 0:42 so that the proportion of labor input

to total input minus intermediate input share (i.e., �L=(1 � �M)) is equivalent to 0.7,

15More precisely, the haircut rate is set by matching the model produced bond spread with theobserved spread. The ex-post haircut rate of Greek debt restructuring was about 60 percent (Zettelmeyer,Trebesch and Gulati 2013). However, the amount of defaulted debt was limited to the equivalent of about100 percent of its GDP. GDP-linked warrants were also granted to investors. Thus, the e¤ective haircutrate could be much lower than the ex-post haircut rate observed in the data.

16The reason we drop the data in 2008 is that this is 1 year ahead of the year when underreportingof the government�s debt outstanding and de�cit is revealed.

17The government debt outstanding is not measured on a net basis but on a gross basis because ofdata limitations. However, as the gap between gross and net debt was less than 10 percent of GDP inGreece, it does not have any signi�cant quantitative e¤ect on the result.

18Government expenditure is measured as its total expenses, including social bene�ts, and excludinginterest payments.

19Under the Greenwood-Hercowitz-Hu¤man preference, labor supply depends only on the wage rate.

12

Page 16: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

which is often assumed in most literature. The Armington weight of domestic inputs

� is set at 0:63; to match the share of domestic intermediate goods-to-GDP, taken from

the OECD�s STAN Input-Output data. The substitution elasticity between domestic and

foreign intermediate goods is set at 0:9; following Evers (2015). Dixit-Stiglitz curvature

parameter � is set at 3; following Feenstra et al. (2018). The upper bound of imported

inputs with working capital � is set at 0.26 according to the World Bank data in 2005,

and time invariant TFP for intermediate goods production AI is set at 0.31, following

Mendoza and Yue (2012). The labor share in the production of intermediate goods is

set at 0.7.

Other Parameters Parameters associated with shocks are set using HP-�ltered cor-

responding time series. These parameters include the auto-regressive parameter and the

standard deviation of TFP shock, 0.600 and 0.015, and those of government expenditure

shock, 0.650 and 0.040 respectively. We set the period of exclusion from the �nancial mar-

ket after default � to 26 quarters,20 and the probability of recovery to the non-default

state # to 0.044 following Dias and Richmond (2009).

Tax Rate Rule under Inability-to-Repay Default Model To calibrate the para-

meters regarding the �scal rule we observe developments in the tax rate and the debt-

to-GDP ratio in Greece. Figure 4 (a) shows the historical relation between debt-to-GDP

ratios and tax rates.

The data can be roughly categorized into four sub-periods. First, before the debt-to-

GDP ratio hit around 100 percent, namely from 1984 to 1992, these two variables were

positively correlated. Second, from 1993 to 2008, the tax rate ranged between 30 percent

and 40 percent while the debt-to-GDP ratio remained at around 100 percent. Third, after

the onset of the global �nancial crisis in 2008, the debt-to-GDP ratio rose at quite a rapid

pace, while the pace of tax increase was moderate. Finally, the government defaulted in

2012, and both the debt-to-GDP ratio and the tax rate have been elevated since then.

In the model, the parameter of the linear tax rate rule is calibrated to the data from

1984 to 1992 using OLS estimation. The political disturbance % is set at 0.08, so that

the tax rate is consistent with the observed rate. In 2011, a year before the default,

the tax rate was about 8 percentage points lower than the post-default average during

2012-16, which implies that the government could have increased the tax rate by about

8 percentage points to increase tax revenue, if it had not been facing political concerns.

20This is because it took about 6.5 years for the Greek government to complete the �nal bailoutprogram funded by the European Stability Mechanism (ESM).

13

Page 17: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Table 1: Calibration to the Greek Economy

Parameter Value Target/Source�: Risk aversion 1 Log-utility�: Inverse Frisch elasticity of labor supply 0.455 Standard value�: Households�discount factor 0.99 Smets and Wouters (2003)�M : Intermediate input share in �nal goods production 0.39 OECD�L: Labor input share in �nal goods production 0.42 Standard value�: Armington weight of domestic inputs 0.63 OECD : Substitution elasticity across intermediate goods 0.9 Evers(2015)�: Substitution elasticity within intermediate goods 3 Feenstra et al. (2018)�: Imported goods with working capital 0.26 World BankAI : TFP for intermediate goods production 0.31 Mendoza and Yue (2012)rf : World risk-free interest rate 0.01 Smets and Wouters (2003) : Labor input share in intermediate goods production 0.7 Standard value�: Haircut rate 0.05 Bond premium in 2012�g: Persistence of gov�t expenditure shock 0.65 IMF�g: Standard deviation of gov�t expenditure shock 0.04 IMF�A: Persistence of TFP shock 0.6 OECD�A: Standard deviation of TFP shock 0.015 OECDG: Steady-state government expenditure 0.0163 IMF (G=GDP = 0:385)B: Steady-state government debt 0.0440 IMF (B=GDP = 1:04)� : Steady-state tax rate 0.385 Steady-state gov�t expenditure�: Elasticity of tax rate 0.02 OLS%: Political disturbance 0.08 IMF�: Period of exclusion 26 Duration of Bailout Program#: Probability of recovery 0.044 Dias and Richmond (2009)

Figure 4 (b) shows the calibrated tax rate rule under the inability-to-repay default

model. In the area where the debt-to-GDP ratio is below 100 percent and the tax rate

is below 39 percent, the government sets its tax rate according to the linear rule (line

marked with circles). In the area where the debt-to-GDP is higher than 100 percent

and the tax rate is above 39 percent, the line exceeds the expected surplus (solid curve)

derived from the equation (8). In this area, to sustain the high debt-to-GDP ratio, the

government deviates from the linear rule and sets the higher tax rate on the curve. Once

the tax rate reaches the maximum tax rate that is estimated to be 40.5 percent, the

government cannot contain any further increase in the debt-to-GDP ratio by raising the

tax rate, because of political pressures, and declares the default.

Table 1 summarizes all calibrated parameters for the Greek economy.21

21The explanation of calibrated parameter values for the Argentinean economy is provided in AppendixE.

14

Page 18: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Figure 4: Tax Rate Rule

(a) Greek Data (b) Calibrated Result

0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5 0.55Tax Rate

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

Deb

t / G

DP

1984­1992

2009­2011

2012­2016

1993­2008

Notes 1: The level of GDP in the right panel (b) is the steady-state value.

2: ES represents the expected surplus.

3: "High A" and "Low A" represent 5 percent higher and lower than the steady-state TFP respectively.

Source: OECD

3.2 Solution Method

There are two steps to solving the inability-to-repay model. In the �rst step, we compute

the mapping from a given productivity level At and expenditure level gt to the expected

surplus and �scal limit,22 since the �scal limit is a function of realizations of future shocks

to these variables that are drawn by Monte-Carlo sampling. In the second step, based

on the mapping, we solve the model on the discrete state space (DSS). To obtain the

DSS, following Coleman (1991) and Davig (2004), we �nd a �xed point of the decision

rule for government bonds by using the monotone map method for each of three tax rate

cases, � lrt , �est and �mat respectively. Then, we select the sequences of the tax rate and

corresponding endogenous variables, following the tax rate rule in (12).

As for the solution of the strategic default model, we apply a two-loop algorithm.

The outside and inside loops iterate the price of government bonds and government value

functions in both non-default and default states respectively. A detailed explanation of

the computational procedure is given in Appendix B.

22Following Bi (2012), to compute the �scal limit, we assume that the future government bond ispriced under the assumption of a zero default probability, i.e., the price of government bonds is onlydiscounted by the risk-free interest rate.

15

Page 19: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

4 Quantitative Analysis

In this section, we quantitatively investigate how each of the two proposed models �ts

with the Greek experience. As we explained in the previous section, the government

defaults when the current TFP and government expenditure fall into the default region.

In what follows, we study the default regions under the two proposed models and

investigate which of the two models can provide more plausible explanation of the Greek

default episode in 2012. Then we examine the simulated path of the economy under

the two models and see whether they can capture the severe and long-lasting economic

contraction around the default.

4.1 Trigger of Default

To investigate the trigger of the default, we compute the default regions constructed by

the two models.

First, we compute the La¤er curve of the economy in the inability-to-repay default

model. Panel (a) in Figure 5 shows the La¤er curve under di¤erent values of TFP,

taking the tax rate on the horizontal axis and the tax revenue over steady-state GDP

on the vertical axis.23 The tax rate at the top of the La¤er curve is about 44.5 percent,

and the maximum tax rate is about 40.5 percent. The maximum tax revenue over the

steady-state GDP is about 40 percent. This means that the maximum �scal surplus is

about 1.5 percent, i.e., the government can potentially accumulate about 1.5 percent of

�scal surplus over GDP, provided that the steady-state government expenditure-to-GDP

is maintained at 38.5 percent. When TFP is 5 percentage points higher (lower), the

tax revenue relative to GDP is about 5 percentage points higher (lower) than the steady

state. Panel (b) illustrates the probability of inability-to-repay default under di¤erent

values of current TFP, where we suppose that government expenditure is �xed at the

steady state. If the current TFP is at the steady state (bold line) and the debt-to-GDP

ratio is around 100 percent, then the probability of default is around 10 percent. The

probability increases with debt-to-GDP ratio and reaches 50 percent when the debt-to-

GDP ratio reaches about 160 percent.

Next, we show the value functions for the strategic default model. Panel (c) shows

the di¤erence between the two value functions, i.e., the value function if the government

chooses not to default and if it chooses to default, under di¤erent values of the current

23The steady-state GDP is computed, by feeding into the model the steady-state values of TFP andgovernment expenditure.

16

Page 20: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Figure 5: Comparison of Two Sovereign Default Models (Greece)

(b) Probability of(a) La¤er Curve (LC) Inability-to-Repay Default

0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5Tax Rate

0.32

0.34

0.36

0.38

0.4

0.42

0.44

0.46

Tax 

Rev

enue

 / G

DP

High ASteady ALow A

MaxFiscalSurplus

G / GDP

TauMax Top

of  LC

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3Debt / GDP

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Low ASteady AHigh A

(c) Value of Strategic Default (d) Default Region

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3Debt / GDP

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

Vn­

Vd

High ASteady ALow A

7.5

5.6

3.7

1.9

0

­1.9

­3.8

­5.6

­7.5

TFP

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3Debt / GDP

Non­def ault

Def aultedPoint

Incapability ­to­Repay

Notes 1: Debt-to-GDP is measured relative to the steady-state GDP.

2: TFP in panel (d) shows the deviation from the steady state.

3: Government expenditure is �xed at the steady state.

TFP. The di¤erence is positive over the plausible range of debt-to-GDP ratio below 300

percent. This suggests that the government has no incentive to choose to default.

For comparison, panel (d) illustrates the default regions with various values of TFP

given that government expenditure is �xed at the steady state. The default region of the

inability-to-repay default is located in the area where the debt-to-GDP ratio is higher than

150 percent, while the region of strategic default does not appear in this panel as implied

in panel (c). In other words, over the range considered in panel (d), the government does

not choose to default. The dotted point in the panel represents the pair of observations

of debt-to-GDP ratio and TFP that was observed at the onset of the default in Greece

in 2012. Overall, these pictures suggest that the Greek default was likely attributable

17

Page 21: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

to the government�s inability to repay its debts rather than the government�s strategic

decision.24

4.2 Simulation Analysis

In this section we examine the quantitative performance of the inability-to-repay default

model in explaining the severe economic contraction after the default in Greece. We

set the initial debt-to-GDP ratio to 80 percent, and the initial values of both TFP and

government expenditure at the steady-state values. Then we generate stochastic TFP

and government expenditure shocks 5,000 times over 500 quarters, and compute the

equilibrium time path of endogenous variables.

Table 2: Summary Statistics

Average Before Default Average After Default2009Q1-2011Q4 2012Q1-2015Q1

Unit Data Model Data ModelDebt-to-GDP Percent 141.1 148.1 167.6 170.9Probability of Default Percent 34.5 42.1 � �Bond Spread % Points 7.2 7.0 � �Tax Rate Percent 36.4 39.8 42.6 44.3

Table 3: Cumulative Changes around the Default

Economic Impact by DefaultUnit Data Model

GDP Percent -21.0 -13.8Consumption Percent -20.1 -21.6Imports Percent -13.2 -31.0

Note: Cumulative changes represent the percent change of the variables from 3 years before the default

to 3 years after the default.

Table 2 reports the summary statistics of the key variables in the data and simulation

before and after the default. This suggests that the inability-to-repay default model

successfully replicates these variables.25

Regarding other endogenous economic variables, Table 3 shows the cumulative changes

in GDP and its components from 3 years before the default until 3 years after the default.24In Appendix C, we conduct robustness analysis for di¤erent values of government expenditure and

con�rm that the results are not substantially altered.25The bond spread in the data is the 10-year Greek government bond yield against the 10-year German

government bond yield on a quarterly basis.

18

Page 22: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

This suggests that the model can replicate the signi�cant drop in GDP, consumption, and

imports around the default.

Figure 6: Key Endogenous Variables (Simulation vs Data)

(a) Debt-to-GDP ratio (b) Government Bond Spread

­3 ­2 ­1 0 1 2 3Year

110

120

130

140

150

160

170

180

190

Perc

ent

DataSimSim,AltSim,Band

­3 ­2 ­1 0Year

0

5

10

15

20

25

Perc

enta

ge P

oint

(c) Tax Rate (d) GDP

­3 ­2 ­1 0 1 2 3Year

32

34

36

38

40

42

44

46

48

50

Perc

ent

­3 ­2 ­1 0 1 2 3Year

­25

­20

­15

­10

­5

0

5

Perc

ent

(e) Consumption (f) Imports

­3 ­2 ­1 0 1 2 3Year

­30

­25

­20

­15

­10

­5

0

5

10

Perc

ent

­3 ­2 ­1 0 1 2 3Year

­40

­35

­30

­25

­20

­15

­10

­5

0

5

Perc

ent

Notes 1: Year 0 is set at 2012Q1 for the data.

2: 2Y-Alt simulation represents simulation results with 2 years of exclusion from the

�nancial market.

Figure 6 illustrates the developments in the key variables in both data and simulation

19

Page 23: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

before and after the default. Panel (a) shows the mean of the baseline simulation path of

debt-to-GDP ratio for defaulted samples. The simulated path (bold line) closely tracks

the realized path of the debt-to-GDP ratio within the one standard error band. Panel

(b) shows the mean of the simulation path of the spread. It illustrates that the nonlinear

increase in spread is somewhat captured by the simulation path, although some periods of

deviation from the error band are observed. Given the market turbulence in this period,

the deviation could be explained by other factors such as the e¤ect of overall uncertainty

regarding the euro area sovereign debt problem. Panels (d), (e), and (f) describe the

cumulative changes in GDP, consumption, and imports from 3 years before the default.

The model closely replicates the data as the deviations fall mostly in the one standard

error band. 26 ;27

Overall, the model generally accommodates features of the highly nonlinear dynamics

of key economic variables around the default.

4.3 Discussion: Argentinean Default in 2001

We have so far focused on the case of the Greek default throughout this paper. Because a

good number of recent studies of the sovereign default analyze the Argentinean default in

2001, however, it would be worthwhile to apply both the inability-to-repay default model

and the strategic default model to the Argentinean economy and highlight the di¤erences

between the two models.28

Essentially, the Argentinean default is attributable to the government�s strategic deci-

sion rather than its inability to repay its debt. The Argentinean default is not considered

as having been triggered by the government�s inability to repay its debt because, given

that economic contraction following the default was moderate, the government was con-

sidered to have been less reluctant to choose default. Panel (a) in Figure 7 shows the

La¤er curve in Argentina and the maximum �scal surplus. The tax revenue over GDP

that the government can achieve when the tax rate is set at the top of the La¤er curve

is about 32 percent, which is about 10 percentage points larger than the steady-state

government expenditure. Following Bi, Shen and Yang (2014) we set % to 0.33.29 As a

26In this analysis, we assumed that the period of exclusion from �nancial markets is at least 26quarters. This is relatively long when compared with existing studies.

27To verify the robustness of the results, we also present the mean of simulated path in which thedefault state continues for only 8 quarters, the standard assumption used in the literature. We �nd thatthe overall picture is little altered by this change in the setting.

28We explain the calibration strategy and results of the Argentinean economy in Appendix E.29Bi, Shen and Yang (2014) applies an inability-to-repay type model to Argentinean economy and

subtract 33 percent of the tax rate in all future periods by referring to the Argentinean political risk

20

Page 24: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Figure 7: Comparison of Two Sovereign Default Models (Argentina)

(a) La¤er Curve (LC) (b) Value of Strategic Default

0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6Tax Rate

0.1

0.15

0.2

0.25

0.3

0.35

0.4

Tax 

Rev

enue

 / G

DP

High ASteady ALow A

Top ofLC

Max FiscalSurplus

G / GDP

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1Debt / GDP

­0.3

­0.2

­0.1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

Vn­

Vd

High ASteady ALow A

(c) Default Region

7.5

5.6

3.7

1.9

0

­1.9

­3.8

­5.6

­7.5

TFP

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1Debt / GDP

Non­default

DefaultedPoint

StrategicDefaul t

Notes 1: Debt-to-GDP is measured relative to the steady-state GDP.

2: TFP in panel (c) shows the deviation from the steady state.

3: Government expenditure is �xed at the steady state.

result, the �scal surplus would be about 5 percent at the steady state and the potential

�scal limit is about 250 percent of GDP, which is substantially higher than the actual

debt-to-GDP ratio.

Regarding the strategic default model, we assume that the tax rate in the default

state is 5 percentage points lower than that in the non-default steady state, based on

the fact that the historical average of the tax rate in Argentina during 2002-03 was

5 percentage points lower than that of 1998-2002 in Argentina. Panel (b) shows the

di¤erence of value functions constructed by the strategic default model, i.e., non-default

value function minus the default value function. Given the steady-state value of TFP,

the value function at the default state exceeds the value function at the non-default state

factor taken from the International Country Risk Guide�s (ICRG�s) index in order to replicate the low�scal limit in emerging countries such as Argentina.

21

Page 25: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

for debt-to-GDP ratio by more than 70 percent. In other words, this value is considered

as the threshold at which strategic default is triggered.

Panel (c) illustrates the default region for various values of TFP and debt-to-GDP ra-

tio. Again, we assume that government expenditure is at the steady state. The inability-

to-repay default region does not appear in this picture where debt-to-GDP ratio ranging

from 0 to 100 percent is considered. The actual TFP and debt-to-GDP ratio at the time

the government defaulted in 2001 falls into the strategic default region in the panel.

The key di¤erence from the Greek case is that Argentina had more room to accumulate

future �scal surplus than Greece, which in turn made inability-to-repay default less likely.

Besides, choosing to default was considered less attractive to the Greek government than

the Argentinean government. This is because, given the low tax rate after default in

Argentinean data at the time of its default, economic contraction was relatively mild,

and the government could improve households�welfare by choosing to default and relieve

itself of having to continuously make interest payments.

5 Conclusion

We propose a DSGE model in which a sovereign default is triggered by a government�s

inability to repay its debt because the government has limited capacity to increase its �scal

surplus. We compare this model with the strategic default model in which the government

chooses to default to avoid the burden of debt. We conduct a quantitative analysis that

shows the Greek default in 2012 was attributable to the government�s inability rather

than to its strategic decision, this being consistent with the view that, fearing default

would lead to a large economic contraction, the Greek government had no incentive to

choose to default. In addition, our simulation study shows that the model can replicate

the high debt-to-GDP ratio and the substantial drop in GDP and its components.

Admittedly, the economic environments considered in the current paper are quite sim-

ple, and there is potential room to add various elements in the economy not covered here

that have an important bearing upon a government�s decision to default. For example,

as Borensztein and Panizza (2009) mentioned, to bring the model closer to the data, it

may be bene�cial to consider the banking sector and the government�s strategic decisions

that depend on which sector is holding bonds. Further research along these lines is left

as our future research agenda.

22

Page 26: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

References[1] Acharya, Viral V., and Raghuram G. Rajan, 2013. �Sovereign Debt, Government

Myopia, and the Financial Sector,�Review of Financial Studies, 26(6): 1526-1560.

[2] Aguiar, Mark, and Gita Gopinath, 2006. �Defaultable Debt, Interest Rates and theCurrent Account,�Journal of International Economics, 69(1): 64-83.

[3] Arellano, Cristina, 2008. �Default Risk and Income Fluctuations in EmergingEconomies,�American Economic Review, 98(3): 690-712.

[4] Asonuma, Tamon, and Hyungseok Joo, 2019a. �Sovereign Debt Restructurings: De-lays in Renegotiations and Risk Averse Creditors,�forthcoming in Journal of Euro-pean Economic Association.

[5] Asonuma, Tamon, and Hyungseok Joo, 2019b. �Sovereign Debt Overhang, Expen-diture Composition, and Debt Restructurings,�Unpublished.

[6] Benjamin, David, and Mark L.J. Wright, 2009. �Recovery Before Redemption:A Theory of Delays in Sovereign Debt Renegotiations,� CAMA Working Paper15/2009.

[7] Bi, Huixin, 2012. �Sovereign Default Risk Premia, Fiscal Limits, and Fiscal Policy,�European Economic Review, 56(3): 389-410.

[8] Bi, Huixin, and Eric M. Leeper, 2013. �Analyzing Fiscal Sustainability,�Bank ofCanada Working Paper 13-27.

[9] Bi, Huixin, Wenyi Shen, and Shu-Chun S. Yang, 2014. �Fiscal Limits, External Debt,and Fiscal Policy in Developing Countries,�International Monetary Fund WorkingPaper 14/49.

[10] Bi, Ran, 2008. ��Bene�cial�Delays in Debt Restructuring Negotiations,� Interna-tional Monetary Fund Working Paper 08/38.

[11] Bocola, Luigi, Gideon Bornstein, and Alessandro Dovis, 2019. �Quantitative Sov-ereign Default Models and the European Debt Crisis,�Journal of International Eco-nomics, 118: 20-30.

[12] Bocola, Luigi, and Alessandro Dovis, 2016. �Self-Ful�lling Debt Crises: A Quanti-tative Analysis,�National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 22694.

[13] Borensztein, Eduardo, and Ugo Panizza, 2009. �The Costs of Sovereign Default,�IMF Sta¤ Papers, 56(4): 683-741.

[14] Chatterjee, Satyajit, and Burcu Eyigungor, 2012. �Maturity, Indebtedness, and De-fault Risk,�American Economic Review, 102(6): 2674-2699.

[15] Coleman, Wilbur John II, 1991. �Equilibrium in a Production Economy with anIncome Tax,�Econometrica, 59(4): 1091-1104.

[16] Davig, Troy, 2004. �Regime-Switching Debt and Taxation,� Journal of MonetaryEconomics, 51(4): 837-859.

23

Page 27: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

[17] Davig, Troy, Eric M. Leeper, and Todd B. Walker, 2010. �Unfunded Liabilities andUncertain Fiscal Financing,�Journal of Monetary Economics, 57(5): 600-619.

[18] D�Erasmo, Pablo, 2011. �Government Reputation and Debt Repayment in EmergingEconomies,�Unpublished.

[19] D�Erasmo, Pablo, and Enrique G. Mendoza, 2016. �Distributional Incentives in anEquilibrium Model of Domestic Sovereign Default,� Journal of the European Eco-nomic Association, 14(1): 7-44.

[20] Dias, Daniel A., and Christine Richmond, 2009. �Duration of Capital Market Ex-clusion: An Empirical Investigation,�Unpublished.

[21] Evers, Michael P., 2015. �Fiscal Federalism and Monetary Unions: A QuantitativeAssessment,�Journal of International Economics, 97(1): 59-75.

[22] Feenstra, Robert C., Philip Luck, Maurice Obstfeld, and Natheryn N. Russ, 2018. �InSearch of the Armington Elasticity,�Review of Economics and Statistics, 100(1):135-150.

[23] Gali, Jordi, J. Divid López-Salido, and Javier Vallés, 2007. �Understanding the Ef-fects of Government Spending on Consumption,�Journal of the European EconomicAssociation, 5(1): 227-270.

[24] Ghosh, Atish R., Jun I. Kim, Enrique G. Mendoza, Jonathan D. Ostry, and MahvashS. Qureshi, 2013. �Fiscal Fatigue, Fiscal Space and Debt Sustainability in AdvancedEconomies,�Economic Journal, 123(566): 4-30.

[25] Gordon, Grey, and Pablo A. Guerron-Quintana, 2018. �Dynamics of Investment,Debt, and Default,�Review of Economic Dynamics, 28: 71-95.

[26] Greenwood, Jeremy, Zvi Hercowitz, and Gregory Hu¤man, 1988. �Investment, Ca-pacity Utilization and the Real Business Cycle,�American Economic Review, 78(3):402-417.

[27] Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, and Leonardo Martinez, 2009. �Long-Duration Bonds andSovereign Defaults,�Journal of International Economics, 79(1): 117-125.

[28] Hatchondo, Juan Carlos, Leonardo Martinez, and Cesar Sosa-Padila, 2016. �DebtDilution and Sovereign Default Risk,�Journal of Political Economy, 124(5): 1383-1422.

[29] Juessen, Falko, Ludger Linnemann, and Andreas Schabert, 2016. �Default Risk Pre-mia on Government Bonds in a Quantitative Macroeconomic Model,�Macroeco-nomic Dynamics, 20(1): 380-403.

[30] Levy-Yeyati, Eduardo, and Ugo Panizza, 2011. �The Elusive Costs of SovereignDefaults,�Journal of Development Economics, 94(1): 95-105.

[31] Mendoza, Enrique G., and Vivian Z. Yue, 2012. �A General Equilibrium Model ofSovereign Default and Business Cycles,�Quarterly Journal of Economics, 127(2):889-946.

24

Page 28: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

[32] Na, Seunghoon, Stephanie Schmitt-Grohe, Martin Uribe, and Vivian Yue, 2018.�The Twin Ds: Optimal Default and Devaluation,�American Economic Review,108(7): 1773-1819.

[33] Paluszynski, Radoslaw, 2017. �Learning about Debt Crises,�Unpublished.

[34] Park, JungJae, 2017. �Sovereign Default and Capital Accumulation,� Journal ofInternational Economics, 106: 119-133.

[35] Salomao, Juliana, 2017. �Sovereign Debt Renegotiation and Credit Default Swaps,�Journal of Monetary Economics, 90: 50-63.

[36] Schmitt-Grohe, Stephanie, and Martin Uribe, 2017.Open Economy Macroeconomics.Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

[37] Smets, Frank, and Raf Wouters, 2003. �An Estimated Dynamic Stochastic GeneralEquilibrium Model of the Euro Area,�Journal of the European Economic Associa-tion, 1(5): 1123-1175.

[38] Yue, Vivian Z., 2010. �Sovereign Default and Debt Renegotiation,�Journal of In-ternational Economics, 80(2): 176-187.

[39] Zettelmeyer, Jeromin, Christoph Trebesch, and Mitu Gulati, 2013. �The Greek DebtRestructuring: an Autopsy,�Economic Policy, 28(75): 513-563.

25

Page 29: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Appendix A. Private Agents and Competitive Equi-librium

A.1 Households

A representative household derives utility from consumption Ct and disutility from

labor Lt. The household provides its labor Lt to both �nal and intermediate goods �rms,

and receives labor income wtLt from these two types of �rms and pro�ts �ft and �mt

from each type of �rm respectively, where wt is the wage rate. The household solves the

following utility maximization problem:

maxCt;Lt

Et

" 1Xi=0

�iu(Ct+i; Lt+i)

#; (21)

subject to its budget constraint Ct � wtLt + �ft + �mt , where � 2 (0; 1) is the subjectivediscount factor, and the utility function u : R2+ ! R is continuous, twice di¤erential andsatis�es @u

@C> 0; @

2u@C2

< 0; @u@L< 0; @

2u@L2

< 0 and @2u@C2

@2u@L2

��

@2u@C@L

�2> 0.

A.2 Final Goods Firms

There is a continuum of �nal goods �rms, producing �nal goods from intermediate

goods Mt and labor inputs Lft .30 The production function follows Cobb-Douglas:

Yt = eAt�M�mdt ;m

�t

���M (Lft )�L ; (22)

where M�mdt ;m

�t

�is intermediate goods which are composed of domestic intermediate

inputs mdt and imported intermediate inputs m

�t . Parameters 0 < �M ; �L < 1 are the

share of intermediate goods and labor in �nal goods respectively, satisfying �M +�L < 1.

The technology of combining these two types of intermediate goods follows the CES

Armington aggregator:

M�mdt ;m

�t

�=

���mdt

� �1 + (1� �) (m�

t ) �1

� �1

; (23)

where � 2 [0; 1] is the weight of domestic intermediate goods in total intermediate goodscomposition and (> 0) is the elasticity of substitution across domestic and imported

30Following Mendoza and Yue (2012), we abstract capital input for simplicity.

26

Page 30: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

intermediate goods. The pro�t maximization problem of �nal goods �rms is:

maxm�t ;m

dt ;L

ft

�ft = Yt(1� � t)� p�tm�t � pmt m

dt � wtL

ft ; (24)

subject to the production function (22) and the combining technology of domestic and

imported intermediate goods (23). As explained above, the government imposes a tax on

their �nal goods production.

Then, the �rst-order conditions are:

eAt�M�M�mdt ;m

�t

���M� �1 (1� �)(m�

t )�1 �Lft

��L(1� � t) = p�t ; (25)

eAt�M�M�mdt ;m

�t

���M� �1 �

�mdt

��1

�Lft

��L(1� � t) = pmt ; (26)

eAt�L�M�mdt ;m

�t

���M �Lft ��L�1 (1� � t) = wt: (27)

The technology of combining the continuum of di¤erentiated imported intermediate goods

m�j;t is the Dixit-Stiglitz aggregator:

m�t �

�Z 1

0

�m�j;t

� ��1� dj

� ���1

; (28)

where �(> 0) is the substitution elasticity among imported intermediate goods. If the

government repays its debt, �nal goods �rms can access the �nancial market to borrow

working capital at the risk-free interest rate rf from foreign investors in order to import

a fraction � 2 [0; 1] of intermediate goods from foreign �rms. The foreign investors have

enough resources to lend the working capital, and �nal goods �rms repay it within the

period t. Thus, the cost minimization problem with respect to the imported intermediate

goods is:

minm�jt

Z 1

p�j;tm�j;tdj + (1 + rf )

Z �

0

p�j;tm�j;tdj: (29)

Then, the �rst-order conditions with respect to m�j;t are as follows:

m�j;t=

(1 + rf )p�j;t

p�t

!�vm�t ; for j 2 [0; �]; (30)

m�j;t=

�p�j;tp�t

��vm�t ; for j 2 [�; 1]: (31)

27

Page 31: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

The aggregate imported intermediate goods is provided by the CES index:

p�t =

�Z 1

�p�j;t�1�v

dj +

Z �

0

�(1 + rf )p�j;t

�1�vdj

� 11�v

: (32)

When the country is in a default state, �nal goods �rms cannot raise the working cap-

ital necessary to import intermediate goods. Thus, the price of aggregated imported

intermediate goods in this state is:

p�t =

�Z 1

�p�j;t�1�v

dj

� 11�v

: (33)

A.3 Domestic Intermediate Goods Firms

A representative domestic intermediate goods �rm produces intermediate goods from

labor Lmt and sells them to �nal goods �rms. The technology of domestic intermediate

goods production is:

mdt = AI (Lmt )

; (34)

where both parameters of AI and 2 [0; 1] are the time-invariant state of TFP and

the labor share respectively in intermediate goods production. The pro�t maximization

problem of intermediate goods �rms is:

maxLmt

�mt = pmt AI (Lmt )

� wtLmt : (35)

Then, the �rst-order condition with respect to Lmt is:

wt = pmt AI (Lmt )

�1 : (36)

A.4 Competitive Equilibrium

We de�ne the competitive equilibria of both the inability-to-repay default model and

the strategic default model. For convenience, we summarize state vectors as sI 2 fA, g,B, �, b�g for the former model and sS 2 fA, g, B, �g for the latter model. The prime

28

Page 32: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

symbol represents variables at the next period (i.e., B0 represents the debt outstanding

at the next period.).

De�nition 1

A recursive equilibrium of the inability-to-repay default model is de�ned as, given the

vector of state variables sI , the �scal limit in the next period b�0 and tax rate �(sI), a

set of government policies fB0(sI), G(g), T (sI)g, private allocation fC(sI), Y (sI), L(sI),M(sI), md(sI), m�(sI), Lf (sI), Lm(sI)g, factor prices fw(sI), p�(sI), pm(sI)g, and theprice of government bonds q(A, g, B0, �n, b

�0) such that:

(a) Government policies satisfy the rules of government expenditure and taxation (1),

and for � = �n, given q(A, g, B0, �n, b

�0), the amount of newly issued government bonds

follows the budget constraint (2); (b) For � = �n, given the default set �I(B; �n; b

�) and

the probability of default P e(A, g, B0, �n, b�0), the price of government bonds q(A, g,

B0, �n, b�0) satis�es the foreign investors�zero pro�t condition (3); (c) Households, �nal

goods �rms, and intermediate goods �rms solve their optimization problems respectively;

(d) The market for domestic intermediate goods clears; (e) The market for labor clears,

Lt = Lft + Lmt ; (f) The market for �nal goods clears, Yt � Tt � p�tm�t = Ct.

De�nition 2

A recursive equilibrium of the strategic default model is de�ned as, given the vector of

state variables sS, tax rate �(sS) and value functions V (sS), Vn(sS) and Vd(sS), a set

of government policies fd(sS), B0(sS), G(g), T (sS)g; private allocation fC(sS), Y (sS),L(sS), M(sS), md(sS), m�(sS), Lf (sS), Lm(sS)g, factor prices fw(sS), p�(sS), pm(sS)g,and the price of government bond q(A, g, B0, �n) such that:

(a) Government policies satisfy the rules of government expenditure and taxation (1),

for � = �n, given q(A, g, B0, �n), the amount of newly issued government bonds follows

the budget constraint (2) and the government solves its optimization problem (16); (b)

For � = �n, given the default set �S(B, �n) and the probability of default P

e(A, g,

B0, �n), the price of government bonds q(A, g, B0, �n) satis�es the foreign investors�

zero-pro�t condition (3); (c) Households, �nal goods �rms, and intermediate goods �rms

solve their optimization problems respectively; (d) The markets for domestic intermediate

goods, labor and �nal goods clear.

29

Page 33: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

In terms of the market clearing condition of �nal goods, the aggregate constraints

are di¤erent in the normal and default states as Yt�p�tm�t � (Bt� qtBt+1) = C t+G t and

Yt�p�tm�t +�

Ft = Ct+Gt respectively. However, by substituting the government�s budget

constraints in the normal state (2) and that in the default state, Tt + �Ft = Gt, for each

state of aggregate constraint, the same market clearing condition is derived regardless of

the government state.

30

Page 34: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Appendix B. Computational Algorithm

B.1 Expected Surplus and Fiscal Limit

1. Discretize the state space of tax rate (�), and TFP (A) and government expenditure

normalized by GDP (g) in terms of deviation from the respective steady-state value.

Take 101 grid points for the tax rate uniformly in the interval between 0.15 and

0.60.31 Tauchen�s method (1986) is applied to obtain the state space of TFP and

government expenditure, taking 25 grid points uniformly by setting the center points

to zero.

2. Calculate endogenous variables (Ct; Yt; Lt;mdt ;m

�t ; L

ft ; L

mt ; Tt; Gt; wt; p

mt ; p

�t ) for all

grid points.

3. Calculate the expected surplus and �scal limit separately.

(a) Expected Surplus: Aggregate the expected future �scal surplus discounted by

the risk-free interest rate EtP200

i=0

�1

1+rf

�t+i(Tt+i�Gt+i) given the correspond-

ing tax rate on each grid point.

(b) Fiscal Limit: Find the tax rate that maximizes the tax revenue in each state

variable (At; gt), and subtract the political disturbance. Then, draw the fu-

ture shocks for (At+i; gt+i) given the initial state (At; gt) and aggregate the

discounted future maximum �scal surplus over a 200-quarter horizon. Repeat

this procedure 5,000 times for all initial states of (At; gt). Finally, calculate

the cumulative distribution function of default probability.

B.2 Discrete State Space of Inability-to-Repay Default

1. Discretize the state space of TFP (At), government expenditure (gt) and govern-

ment debt (Bt), taking the same number of grid points for TFP and government

expenditure described in the previous section and 101 grid points for the govern-

ment debt Bt in the interval between -0.5 and 3.0 times the steady-state level of

GDP. Then, make an initial guess for the issuance of government bonds f b0 .

31We only study the tax rates within this range. This is because if the tax rate is too high, the�rst-order conditions of �nal goods �rms will not be obtained due to negative pro�ts as �rms produceat least the amount of government expenditure. Also, if the tax rate is too low, the �scal limit will benegative because of low tax revenues.

31

Page 35: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

2. Given the tax rate rules, � lrt , �est and �

mat , evaluate the probability of default P

I;e

with new government bond f b0 using a piecewise linear interpolation, and compute

other endogenous variables.

3. Update the guess for government bond issuance f b1 from the government intratem-

poral budget constraint (2) and the pricing equation of government bond (3).

4. Accept the decision rule f b1 if the di¤erence between the updated and old decision

rules f b0 is small enough (i.e. sup f b1 � f b0

< �).32 Otherwise, go back to step 2

with the updated decision rule f b0 = f b1 .

5. Finally, select the tax rule � t from the state spaces for (� lrt , �est and �

mat ) that satis�es

the rule (12) and the corresponding decision rule for government bond issuance f b

and endogenous variables.

B.3 Discrete State Space of Strategic Default

1. Discretize the state space of TFP (At), government expenditure (gt) and tax rate

(� t). Set the tax rate (� t) from its linear rule (4), corresponding to the debt out-

standing that ranges from -0.5 to 3 times the steady-state level of GDP. Take the

same number of grid points for TFP, government expenditure and tax rate as the

prior sections.

2. Make initial guesses for the non-default and default value functions Vn;0 and Vd;0

respectively, and initialize the government bond price q0 to be 1=(1 + rf ).

3. The government�s value function iteration.

(a) Given q0, calculate the private allocations and utilities for each state space in

non-default and default. Then, derive the tax rate in the next period and the

corresponding expected value functions using a piecewise linear interpolation.

(b) Calculate the updated value functions Vn;1 and Vd;1 from the expected value

functions and utilities, following equations (17) and (18) respectively.

(c) If the di¤erences between current and updated government value functions are

small enough (i.e. supfjVn;1 � Vn;0j, jVd;1 � Vd;0jg < "g), stop the iteration.Otherwise, go back to step (a) with the updated government value functions.

32We checked the local uniqueness of the solution by perturbing the policy function f b, and con�rmedits convergence.

32

Page 36: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

4. Calculate the default set �S and the probability of default P S;et , using a piecewise

linear interpolation on the tax rate grid points. Then, derive the price of government

bond q1.

5. If the di¤erence between the current and updated government bond price is small

enough (i.e. supjjq1 � q0jj < "g), stop the iteration. Otherwise, go back to step 3with the updated price of the government bond.

33

Page 37: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Appendix C. Quantitative Analysis under Di¤erent

Values of Government Expenditure

In section 4, we explained how the current level of TFP a¤ects the probability of default

under both the inability-to-repay default model and the strategic default model. In

this Appendix, we examine how the other state variable, i.e., government expenditure,

in�uences the results. Figure C shows these two cases under di¤erent values of government

expenditure, keeping the value of TFP at the steady-state value.

Figure C: Comparison of the Two Sovereign Default Models (Greece)

(a) Probability ofInability-to-Repay Default (b) Value Function of Strategic Default

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3Debt / GDP

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

High gSteady gLow g

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3Debt / GDP

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1V

n­V

d

Notes 1: Debt-to-GDP is measured relative to the steady-state GDP.

2: "High g" and "Low g" represent government expenditure at a level 5 percent higher and

lower than the steady state respectively.

3: TFP is �xed at the steady state.

Panel (a) shows that current high (low) government expenditure increases (decreases)

the probability of inability-to-repay default. However, similar to the TFP, variations in

the probability are small because government expenditure is assumed to return to the

steady-state level. Panel (b) shows that the non-default value (Vn) is larger than the

default value (Vd) in the plausible region of debt-to-GDP ratio, indicating that without

changes in TFP level, changes in government expenditure on their own would not have

triggered the Greek default.

34

Page 38: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Appendix D. Counterfactual Analysis

In the current paper we argue that the Greek default is likely attributable to the gov-

ernment�s inability to repay its debt as suggested by our simulation analysis. However,

why does the strategic default model fail to explain the Greek default? To see this more

clearly, in this appendix, we explore an extreme counterfactual scenario under which

strategic default can emerge as a plausible scenario. To be speci�c, we examine the case

where the tax rate under the default state is reduced by 8 percent from the baseline simu-

lation, equivalent to political disturbance, and government expenditure is 5 percent lower

than the baseline during the default state. Clearly, under these premises, the economic

contraction after the default would become more moderate, and therefore the government

has a higher incentive to choose to default.

Figure D: Trigger of Default

(a) Value Function of Strategic Default (b) Default Region

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3Debt / GDP

­1.5

­1

­0.5

0

0.5

1

Vn­

Vd

High AMiddle ALow A

7.5

5.6

3.7

1.9

0

­1.9

­3.8

­5.6

­7.5

TFP

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3Debt / GDP

Non­Default

Incapability­to­repay

Default inBoth Ways

StrategicDefault

DefaultedPoint

Notes 1: Debt-to-GDP is measured relative to the steady-state GDP.

2: TFP in panel (b) represents the deviation from the steady state.

3: The tax rate and government expenditure during default are assumed to be lower for 8% points

and 5% points than the baseline respectively.

Panel (a) in Figure D shows the di¤erence between the value function for non-default

and that for default. The default value exceeds the non-default value at the point where

the debt-to-GDP ratio is around 160 percent when TFP is at the steady-state level. The

threshold is lower when TFP is lower. Panel (b) shows the default regions with respect

to the TFP for di¤erent values of debt-to-GDP ratio. Again, we �xed the government

expenditure at 5 percent lower than the steady-state value. In this case, the strategic

35

Page 39: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

default region emerges when the debt-to-GDP ratio is relatively high. For example,

provided that TFP is at the steady-state value, the government chooses to default as a

result of the strategic decision when the debt-to-GDP ratio exceeds 160 percent. When

the ratio exceeds 180 percent, the government can default either by its inability to repay

its debt or by strategic decision. These two panels show that strategic default can occur

only under the assumptions of a moderate economic downturn during the default state,

which is, however, at odds with observations in the case of the Greek default.

36

Page 40: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Appendix E. Calibration

In this appendix, we explain calibrated parameter values for the Argentinean economy.

Most parameters are set following Mendoza and Yue (2012). The risk-free interest rate rf

is set at 2 percent, based on the average money market rate between 1993Q4 and 2001Q3.

The households� subjective discount factor � is set at 0.98. The ratio of government

expenditure to GDP is set at 21.9 percent, based on the historical average between

1993Q4 and 2001Q3. The steady-state tax rate � and the government expenditure-to-

GDP G are set as equal. The government debt-to-GDP B is set at 34 percent, based

on the historical average of the corresponding series between 1993Q4 and 2001Q3. The

political disturbance % is set at 0.33, in accordance with the International Country Risk

Guide�s (ICRG�s) index. We summarize the calibrated parameters for the Argentinean

economy in Table E. Other parameters not listed in this table are set at the same values

used in the Greek case.

Table E: Calibration to the Argentinean Economy

Parameter Value Target/Source�: Households�discount factor 0.98 1�rf�M : Intermediate input share in �nal goods production 0.43 Mendoza and Yue (2012)�L: Labor input share in �nal goods production 0.40 Mendoza and Yue (2012) : Substitution elasticity across intermediate goods 2.86 Mendoza and Yue (2012)�: Substitution elasticity within intermediate goods 2.44 Mendoza and Yue (2012)�: Armington weight of domestic inputs 0.62 Mendoza and Yue (2012)rf : Risk-free interest rate 0.02 Money Market RateG: Steady-state government expenditure 0.0106 IADB (G=GDP = 0:219)B: Steady-state government debt 0.0163 IMF (B=GDP = 0:335)� : Steady-state tax rate 0.219 Steady-state gov�t expenditure%: Political disturbance 0.33 Bi, Shen and Yang (2014)

37

Page 41: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

Appendix F. Data

Table F: Data

Variables Term Frequency Sources<Greece>Public debt-to-GDP 1999-2016 quarterly OECDGovernment expenditure-to-GDP 1999-2008 quarterly (SA) IMFGovernment tax revenue-to-GDP 1999-2016 quarterly (SA) IMFGDP 1999-2016 quarterly (SA) OECDConsumption 1999-2016 quarterly (SA) OECDImported intermediate goods early 2000s - OECD*Imports of goods and services 1999-2016 quarterly (SA) OECDDomestic intermediate goods 1999-2016 annual ECBLabor 1999-2016 quarterly (SA) OECDYields on Greek and German gov�t bonds 1999-2016 quarterly OECDTFP 1999-2016 quarterly (SA) OECD

<Argentina>Public debt-to-GDP 1993-2001 quarterly IMFGovernment expenditure-to-GDP 1993-2001 quarterly (SA) IADBMoney market rate 1993-2001 quarterly IMF

<World>Default Episodes 1982-2013 annual SUGDP 1979-2016 annual WB

Notes 1: SA indicates that data is seasonally adjusted.

2: * represents the OECD�s STAN Input-Output Data.

3: IADB represents the Inter-American Development Bank.

4: SU represents Schmitt-Grohe and Uribe (2017).

Most of the Greek data we use is that of from 1999Q1 to 2016Q4, except for gov-

ernment expenditure-to-GDP and imported intermediate goods, where the data for gov-

ernment expenditure-to-GDP is that from 1999Q1 to 2008Q4, since the steady state and

exogenous shock associated with government expenditure-to-GDP needs to be calibrated

with pre-crisis data, and the data for imported intermediate goods is that from the early

2000s due to data limitation. Most Argentinean data we use is from 1993Q4 to 2001Q3

which is 1 quarter prior to the crisis.

Note also that government expenditure is the government�s total expenditure, includ-

ing social bene�ts minus interest payments; tax revenue includes social contributions;

and labor is total employment for those aged 15 and over. Yields on both Greek and

38

Page 42: INSTITUTE FOR MONETARY AND ECONOMIC STUDIES BANK OF … · Greece (e.g., D™Erasmo and Mendoza 2016, Salomao 2017, and Bocola and Dovis 2016), they do not replicate the high debt-to-GDP

German government bonds are measured from 10-year bond yields. TFP is de�ned as

GDP per person employed. The world default episodes are obtained from Schmitt-Grohe

and Uribe (2017). The GDP data for defaulting countries is from World Development

Indicators, published by the World Bank (WB).

39