institutional reform and new firm performance: more or ... · eberhart / eesley 8/2011 do not copy...

35
Page 1 of 38 DRAFT WORKING PAPER Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or Better Firms? Robert N. Eberhart SPRIE Researcher Stanford Program on Regions of Innovation and Entrepreneurship Charles Eesley Assistant Professor Department of Management Science and Engineering Stanford University August 2011

Upload: others

Post on 10-Aug-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Page 1 of 38

DRAFT WORKING PAPER

Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or Better Firms?

Robert N. Eberhart SPRIE Researcher

Stanford Program on Regions of Innovation and Entrepreneurship

Charles Eesley Assistant Professor

Department of Management Science and Engineering Stanford University

August 2011

Page 2: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 2 of 38

Introduction

What mechanisms drive superior new firm performance in the wake of institutional

reforms intended to increase the count of new firms? Entrepreneurship is now at the center of

many policy questions related to economic growth, employment opportunity then advancement

of science and the alleviation of poverty. There is a growing consensus that managing or at least

fostering an appropriate entrepreneurial habitat is important and that habitat affects the dynamic

of job growth through new company formation, (CTF). It is relevant to wonder if institutional

changes intended to create new and flourishing firms have the effect intended and what are the

mechanisms that drive changes in performance of new firms in the altered institutional

environment.

A new firm’s ability to flourish depends on the institutional environment within which it

was founded. Empirical research on institutional theory has demonstrated the impact of

institutions on the founding rates of new organizations (Thornton 1999; Russo 2001; Sine,

Haveman et al. 2005) and that certain individual characteristics are associated with a higher

likelihood of founding a firm (Sørensen 2007)a; 2007b, (Eesley 2010). Work in organizational

theory has also long been interested in how the prevailing institutional climate is related to

founding rates of new firms (Stinchcombe 1965); (Romanelli 1989).

The institutional environment can stimulate the formation of new firms, (Gompers,

Lerner et al. 2006). Institutional theories highlight the effects of institutions on organizations,

indicating that they shape the attractiveness of organizational forms, sectors, or practices and

result in shifts in aggregate founding rates over time (Sine and David 2003),(Baumol 1990;

Russo 2001). Institutions can affect the distribution of information about opportunities and this

Page 3: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 3 of 38

asymmetric information can give rise to heterogeneous new firms in terms of startup rates in

different industries, (Shane 2000). Moreover, different institutional arrangements can influence

the trajectory of new firms ((Barro 1996); (Peng and Zhou 2005). For example, formal

institutions such as the system of VC financing, (Davila, Foster et al. 2003), bankruptcy laws,

and informal institutions such as peer expectations, (Nanda and Sørensen 2008), can have a

significant influence on the decision to create a firm and the strategies employed to operate them,

(Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven 1990; Burton, Sorensen et al. 2002; Katila and Shane 2005)

Overall, the effects of institutional change on new firm formation rates and strategies have been

well studied. Scholars have paid less attention to the related questions linking performance to the

institutional settings, and so to bring a more complete understanding to the mechanisms of how

institutions affect the performance of nascent firms

In this paper we argue that the institutional environment alters the incentives of

individual decisions to start firms. In this, we are responding to calls in the literature to explain

the mechanisms of new firm growth to complement the already well-developed literature

documenting the amount of growth, (Davidsson, Achtenhagen et al. 2007), and to contribute to

studies of the intersection between entrepreneurship studies and institutional theory, (Tolbert,

David et al. 2010) Moreover, we are responding to calls for more empirical attention to data that

that can more directly explain and inform theories of the mechanisms by which institutions affect

new firm trajectories. (Sørensen and Chang 2006).

We examine these questions using data from Japan. This paper asks how a particular

institutional change in Japan, intended to encourage the formation of new firms, affected

mechanisms that alter the performance trajectory of new firms. We demonstrate that institutional

Page 4: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 4 of 38

changes that were designed to lower the costs and risks of entry did not alter the number and

variety of firms. To the contrary of predictions by a great deal of literature, we show that the

performance of new firms, after reforms, were materially improved suggesting that lowered entry

barrier may have either altered incumbent firm strategies, attracted individuals with greater

human capital, or that lowered entry barriers may have affected markets. Using data on 16,824

firms founded from 1950 to 2008 in Japan we test the idea that institutional reform can affect

entrepreneurial performance by altering the selection of individuals deciding to become

entrepreneurs in the context of incumbent form strategic resets while not changing the new firm

formation rate.

Cost of Entry in Japan

Entry costs affect the rate of new firm formation. Increased rate of return increases the

economic incentives for individuals to found new firm. Increasing costs of entry lower available

resource reserves and can thus discourage start-ups, (Evans and Jovanovich 1989; Klapper,

Laeven et al. 2006) while Numerous studies have demonstrated that financial constraints bind the

choices of potential entrepreneurs, (Buera 2009). Recent literature on entrepreneurial motivations

in Japan confirms that the level of personal assets are important in determining entrepreneurship

entry, (Masuda 2006). Further, changes in entry costs alter the opportunity cost thresholds that

have been shown to determine start-up rates, (Amit, Muller et al. 1995), because lowered entry

costs move up the opportunity costs of not starting firms for talented individuals making

entrepreneurship more likely. High entry costs can also alter the set of entrepreneurial

opportunities by exceeding expected and necessary capital costs in industries with low capital

intensity.

Page 5: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 5 of 38

Research demonstrates that even individuals with high financial assets such that capital

cost barriers are less important are deterred by potential costs of bankruptcy, (Lee, Yamakawa et

al. 2008). The risks of being an entrepreneur are of the loss - perhaps ruinous - of personal

capital and career reputation. Before 2003, company heads in Japan, for example, were subject to

complete personal liability and the inability to control their firm’s fate after declaring

bankruptcy. Consequently, entrepreneurs in Japan were deterred by bankruptcy risk,

alternatively directing their entrepreneurial efforts into “intrapreneurship”, that is, founding

business activities within an exiting company, (Harada 2005).

Institutional changes in Japan directly changed the environment and conditions under

which firms paid initial capitalization. In 2003, the formalities of starting new companies was

simplified and made much less costly with the introduction of the 1 yen minimum capital

requirement to become a corporation1. The preceding requirement was Y10,000,000 for a full

stock issuing corporation (kabushiki-kaisha), or Y3,000,000 for a limited firm called a yugen-

kaisha 2 and their minimum capital could not be immediately spent except in particular

circumstances. The law reducing the minimum capital to Y1 was aimed at increasing the rate of

new firms by lowering the capital that needed to be risked by the founders. Further, the change

enhanced the legitimacy of new firms. Forming a stock-issuing corporation (kabushiki-kaisha)

was viewed as a crucial distinction to create necessary legitimacy in Japanese commerce. As

1 In addition to other changes. 2 Of note, the company law of 2003 allowed the Y1 initial capitalization for new corporations (KK and YK) as long as the founder was founding a de novo firm and other requirements to ensure that “shell” corporations were not the outcome of this easing. It is notable that this law was extended and refined in 2006 with a comprehensive new Japan Company Law that, among many articles, abolished the yugen-kaisha, created new limited liability firms, and strengthened the codification if the 1Y capitalization requirement.

Page 6: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 6 of 38

such, most firms that sought substantial growth felt it necessary to form a kabushiki-kaisha

before reforms and were now enabled at a substantially lowered cost3, (Ohara 2009).

The benefits of a dramatically lowered capital requirement are simple to discern from the

point of view of the entrepreneur. It directly follows that less personal capital needs to be

invested at the riskiest stage of the firm and the return to entrepreneurship must increase as cash

invested is lowered. Moreover, in the absence of a minimum capital reserve, such money that is

invested can be immediately spent on organizational needs. Organization literature has

substantial support for this idea in the idea that liquidity constraints are important impediments to

entrepreneurial activity, (Holtz-Eakin, Joulfaian et al. 1994). Further, the less capital invested,

the lower the potential bankruptcy loss. Finally, lower capital costs, can enhance organizational

legitimacy, (Suchman 1995). By allowing constrained entrepreneurs to obtain business charters,

gain legitimacy from organizational form that may have been unobtainable before. This is

particularly apt with respect to Japan when the organizational form of a stock issuing company

(kabushiki kaisha), is an almost a certain prerequisite for a firm to establish commercial

relationships in most industries, (Ohara 2009).

HYPOTHESIS 1: Institutional reforms that lower entry costs increase the rate of new firm

formation

While this first claim is admittedly straightforward, if it cannot be confirmed it would

imply that the institutional reforms either have little effect or that other effects need to be

analyzed. Institutional effect might not only change the formation of firms but also change their

3 Only if the required capitalization of the firm for operational needs were less than the required initial capitalization before reform.

Page 7: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 7 of 38

dissolution. Next, we build upon this baseline hypothesis by examining whether extant firms are

more likely to dissolve after the bankruptcy reforms.

Bankruptcy Law Reform

The discouraging effects of bankruptcy risk imply that reduced burdens of bankruptcy are

should increase entrepreneurial activity by reducing the entrepreneurs’ exposure to risk,

especially personal risk. Entrepreneurs are more likely to found firms where the exposure to

personal asset loss is mitigated by legal exemptions, (Fan and White 2003). An additional

mechanism from the organizations literature argues that a threshold of performance and payoffs

is defined below which principals will act to dissolve the organization, (Gimeno, Folta et al.

1997). These mechanisms can compliment each other, The lowered expected cost of bankruptcy

encourages inefficient firms to exit, creating market opportunity in vacated niches for new firms

which are encouraged to enter by the lowered potential cost, (Lee, Yamakawa et al. 2008).

The risks of financial ruin through bankruptcy were altered in Japan with the passage of

laws reducing the exposure of entrepreneurs. Prior to that, several types of bankruptcies were

established in Japanese law. Liquidation (hasan-ho), and reorganization (kaisha kosei-ho),

similar to the U.S. Chapter 7 and 11 respectively were most commonly applied. Japanese law

also provided for a third type, the composition reorganization (wagi-ho) which was based in 19th

century German law and was a rehabilitation procedure that mandated the replacement of

managers, (Matsushita 2006). Not uncommon also, was an extra-legal procedure of private

reorganization that was especially prominent among very small firms. These procedures, even

rehabilitation and private agreements, usually meant the immediate replacement of the managers

and the loss of their interest in the firm. Unlike US procedures, the court or creditors would

Page 8: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 8 of 38

manage the firm during restructuring, (Xu 2007). Further, an informally governed but well

established system of contingent governance mandated the replacement of managers of firms in

financial distress by its financiers well before legal bankruptcy was attempted, (Aoki 1990).

Overall, there was a bleak prospect for the managers of a firm in bankruptcy. Liquidation or

reorganization in Japan sought to maximize recovery for the creditors, not rehabilitation of

management that substantially increased the risk of starting and managing a firm.

New bankruptcy procedures are more favorable to the creditor, (Helwege and Packer

2003). In 2003, as part of the overall effort to improve the business and start-up climate in Japan,

the rehabilitation form of bankruptcy (kosei kaisha-ho) was revised to allow retaining managers

during rehabilitations under court supervision. Also, private reorganizations were addressed to

create procedures of reorganization that allowed mangers to more actively participate in the

process. In 2004, the liquidation law (hasan-ho), was reformed to create a simpler and more

equitable distribution of residuals, (Matsushita 2006). Finally, the maximum liability that

directors and CEO’s were exposed to were reduced from unlimited personal exposure in many

cases, to limited assets at risk in most cases, (Schaede 2008). These reforms, taken together,

could potentially lower the risk of entrepreneurship by allowing a system of rehabilitation that

lets the entrepreneur survive in many cases and perhaps retain some of the residual.

The reduced capital requirement and bankruptcy costs should cause both the rate of new

formation and the rate of bankruptcy to increase. Notably, reforms in Japan may not generate the

growth of the number of firm but instead generate heterogeneity by increasing the number of

firms with high growth opportunities and increasing the number of failing firms, (Lee, Peng et al.

2007). So we hypothesize that:

Page 9: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 9 of 38

HYPOTHESIS 2: Institutional reforms that lower bankruptcy risks are likely to raise rate the

rate of bankruptcy as individuals controlling firms with marginal prospects of success face

lowered costs of exit.

Effect of Reforms on Entrant Teams And Human Capital

Organizations literature has found that more experienced entrepreneurs are associated

with better performance trajectories after founding (Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven 1990). These

entrepreneurs bring greater social networks allowing the new firm to access more resources. In

addition, depth of industry experience or of long social and professional ties with cofounders is

shown to be associated with better organizational performance as has depth of experience in

entrepreneurially prestigious firms, (Burton, Sorensen et al. 2002).

Recent social trends in Japan’s environment could interact with the legal reforms to bring

a comparatively talented pool of potential entrepreneurs to start new firms after reforms. First,

opportunities for the highly educated in Japan in traditional employment channels are being

altered and limited by social changes(Schaede 2008). The institution of lifetime employment, the

primary employment channel for the most highly educated for much of then post-war period, has

virtually disappeared with only a small percentage of Japan’s entering workforce taking that type

of employment, (Vogel 2006). Secondly, Japanese firms are eschewing the more traditional

system of seniority employment and skirting stringent Japanese employment laws by relying on

temporary employment agencies for a greater percentage of their skilled managerial workforce,

(ACCJ 2010). Overall, these employment patterns are altering career trajectories bringing many

Page 10: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 10 of 38

more well-educated actors into small company and short tenured employment situations and

increasing the likely pool of nascent entrepreneurs given the reformed costs.

Recent graduates in Japan face similar traditional challenges and a changing labor market

in Japan that no longer offers lifetime employment(Conrad 2009). It seems reasonable then the

lowered capital barriers would be of particular relevance to female entrepreneur that can find

optimal opportunity in low capital industries. Since these individuals are asset-poor, capital costs

can be especially constraining. By removing the constraint of forming a Y10 million capitalized

company, then, a broader group of less advantaged entrepreneurs can be expected to start firms

with greater frequency.

Thus we propose that:

HYPOTHESIS 3a: Institutional reforms that lower bankruptcy risks increase the likelihood that

older, male individuals from prestigious universities will start new firms

HYPOTHESIS 3b: Institutional reforms that lower entry costs encourage females and younger

individuals to start new firms

Institutional Reforms and Firm Performance

Strategy literature suggests three mechanisms that may operate to increase firm

performance as the highly educated careerist start firms. First, individuals from prestigious

universities with subsequent career tracks in notable firms develop social networks that enable

them to have advantageous access to resources that assist a firm’s growth. It has been

Page 11: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 11 of 38

demonstrated in resource-based literature that the resources that accrue through social networks

are decisive in determining firm performance, and that the more the academic quality of an

entrepreneur’s education, the better firm performance, (Barro 2001). Second, industry

experience among top management and founders in an industry is associated with improved firm

performance(Dencker, Gruber et al. 2009) and good technical educations are associated with

firm and consequent economic growth, (Murphy, Shleifer et al. 1991). A third mechanism

particularly relevant to Japan is the greater acquisition of generalist skills that have been shown

to be associated with improve new firm performance, (Lazear 2005). Corporate career executive

in Japanese firms are given broad training in many organizational fields rather than the more

specialized career trajectories in the U.S. Overall, social networks, industry experience and

generalist training should operate in complementary fashion to give performance advantages to

new firms.

Organizational learning theory may also play a role in allowing new firms to become

established. Incumbent organizations may be entrenched in strategic responses as new firms

deploy novel strategies in a changed environment,(Hannan and Freeman 1984) (Sorensen and

Stuart 2000). In the wake of regulatory change that lowers barriers to entry, incumbent firms

have been shown to refocus their efforts internally on core business and thus reduce their

competitive challenge outside of their core business, (Haveman, Russo et al. 2001) and these

organizational responses are associated with reduced performance, (Barnett and Carroll 1995).

Incumbent retrenchment in the wake of new firm challenges from lowered barrier can thus be

decisive in allowing new firms to establish competitive positions from whence incumbents have

retreated or reduced their aggression. Overall, performance can be enhanced as new firms exploit

these opportunities.

Page 12: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 12 of 38

HYPOTHESIS 4: The entry of prestigiously educated individuals subsequent to institutional reforms lowering the costs of entry and the risk of bankruptcy raises the growth rate of firms founded after reforms

Method

Although limited to Japan and the institutional reform environment there, our paper adds

to the knowledge of institutional reform and its effect on new organizations by using a unique

dataset and because comparatively little work on entrepreneurship has been done outside of the

U.S. and the E.U. Our data covers from over a broad span of time, from 1950 through 2008,

gathered in person by a firm that depends on the accuracy of its information, Teikoku Data Bank.

A credit rating company’s data of this type is suited to the study of business growth since the

determinants of credit decisions, sales growth, leverage, management demographics are similar

to those most commonly used in entrepreneurial studies. Further, because we sample across

industries, we are in a unique position to analyze the differential effect of institutions across an

economy and between industries.

If the lowering of the costs of entry and bankruptcy risks measurably affected the

performance of new firms in Japan, we would expect the effect to obtain most convincingly in a

difference between Japan’s pre-reform and post-reform environment. We argued earlier that

lowered capital requirements have been shown to affect firm startup rate, and performance and

that less onerous bankruptcy consequences and rationality have been shown to affect startup

rates and performance. Thus, we selected 2003 as our focal reform date or pre and post-reform as

it coincides with the implementation of lowered capital requirements and with the culmination of

a two-year process of bankruptcy reforms.

Page 13: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 13 of 38

Data

To test our hypotheses we collected a database of newly formed, independent Japanese

firms. We employ the COSMOS database of the Teikoku Data Bank (KK), a commercial credit

rating firm in Tokyo that has demographic, financial and descriptive data on Japanese firms.

TDB is long-established firm (founded 1890) and one of the two largest firms in Japan providing

credit ratings to corporate clients for the primary use of evaluating supplier and customer credit

worthiness. COSMOS is especially useful for our analysis as TDB verifies its data by personal

interviews and audits for all surveyed firms when collecting its financial and demographic data.

Moreover, as Japan’s largest credit rating service, it maintains a set of nearly all operating firms

by capturing firms as they incorporate, and adds other, non-incorporated, firms by either survey

or when there is a credit inquiry from a client about a firm not yet in the database. Teikoku

Databank data has been used in academic studies of bankruptcy, (Schaede 2008), contrasts

between Silicon Valley and Japan, (Suzuki, Kim et al. 2002), and policy evaluation, (ACCJ

2010).

We use the 2009 edition of TDB’s “COSMOS 2” database, which contains 155,022 firms

founded from 1950 to 2009. These include; stock issuing firms (kabushiki kaisha 株式会社),

special non-stock issuing corporations (tokurei yugen kaisha 特例有限会社 ), limited

partnerships (goshi kaisha 合資会社 and godo kaisha 合同会社), and general partnerships,

(gomei kaisha 合名会社), all with incorporation dates during 1998 through 1st quarter 2008.

All firms in the dataset were formally incorporated, subsequent to founding, from 1998 through

the first quarter of 2009. Data is available annually and is presented cross-section for 2009. Data

Page 14: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 14 of 38

for sales, and profitability are presented in three-year panel format, for the most recent three

fiscal years.

We imposed several restrictions on the data. We reduced our data set to 44,000 firms by

eliminating firms that were spin-offs of parent firms or non-operating firms. Further, since they

were not new or entrepreneurial firms, we eliminated some 126 bank and bank holding

companies from this study. We added 12,701 more firms from TDB’s BANKRUPTCY database

founded over the same period to avoid bias of examining only surviving firms increasing our

initial sample count to above 56,000. Since all bankrupt firms had complete foundation date data

and inclusion of the entire bankrupt data would bias the results, we randomly selected a

proportionate amount of the bankrupt firms. Finally, we eliminated 12,610 firms that had

incomplete financial and foundation date data. Our final sample count is 16,824. A summary of

the sample counts is presented in Table 1, below. Since there was a substantial reduction in

sample size, from the initial COSMOS database, we conducted univariate comparisons between

the full data set and the final sort that we used. We find no significant differences between the

databases with the exception of the initial capital of starting firms. We control for initial capital

in our models and find either an immaterial or no significant effect in our models. The results are

in Appendix 1. Descriptive statistics are in Table 1, below.

Insert Table 1 Here

Dependent Variables

Page 15: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 15 of 38

Performance variables are products of a complex interplay of strategy and environment

and their value depends on the interests of the firm’s various constituencies and stage of growth.

We focus on sales growth to measure a firm’s performance conditional upon it founding date. In

organizational literature, performance is frequently measured by sales growth, (Hall 1987;

Eisenhardt and Schoonhoven 1990; Gersick 1994; Hmieleski and Baron 2009; Baum and Bird

2010). It is particularly suitable to assess firm growth for several reasons. It generally applies

across industries and circumstances as all for-profit firms need sales to survive and sales growth

of new firms is imperative, and broad applicability is desirable to asses comparisons across

industries,(Barnett and Carroll 1995). Second, it is the one metric that entrepreneurs themselves

will report as the one that they watch and the one they try to affect most, (Barkham, Gudgin et al.

1996)). Third, it can be argued that sales growth is antecedent or a necessary condition to other

common metrics such as employment or profitability or cash flow, (Davidsson, Achtenhagen et

al. 2007). Sales growth has been a preferred performance metric in literature examining small

firms in Japan. Scholars studying new manufacturing firms in Japan (Honjo 2004; Honjo and

Harada 2006), in their analysis of data from new manufacturing companies, use sales growth

rates to assess entrepreneurial success, as do analyses of Japanese hi-tech startups, (Igarashi and

Taji 2006). Consistent with these streams of literature, we selected the cumulative average

growth rate of revenue since incorporation, cagr, as our dependent variable.

To test the exit rates of firms proximate to bankruptcy reforms, we use the exit hazard

event of bankruptcy, exit03-09, as our dependent variable. The hazard of bankruptcy is easy to

measure and is comparable across firms, industries and contexts(Barnett and Carroll 1995). The

COSMOS database provides the bankruptcy date of affected firms as well as the foundation date.

Since our research focuses on a new firm’s trajectory conditioned by the institutional

Page 16: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 16 of 38

environment on its founding date, we code our variable with a firm entering the dataset in its

foundation year and a firm exits upon bankruptcy. This binary variable takes the value of 1 if

particular firm entered bankruptcy during 2003-2009, or surviving but founded before 2003, to

incorporate surviving firms and mitigate right censoring of the data.

Independent Variables

To examine the effect of firm foundation before and after reform, we examine the

institutional environmental effects on new firm growth with an independent variable, reform. We

measured whether a firm was founded in the reformed institutional environment using an

indicator variable if a focal firm was founded after 2002. To test whether the founder’s

university background effects foundation rates or performance, we used a binary variable,

prestige_univ, to indicate that a focal firm’s CEO graduated from one of Japan’s top ten

universities ranked by QS World University Rankings. The age of CEO’s, ceo_age is directly

measured as a continuous variable of the birth year, and an indicator variable, female, is used to

identify the gender of the CEO.

We also want to isolate the growth and profitability due to reforms from the growth that

occurs in new firms over time. Economics literature has found that younger firms, ceteris

paribus, tend to grow faster than older forms even when controlling for early exits (Evans 1987).

But the effect diminishes as age increases. Accordingly we included a control for the age of the

firm, firm-age and included its square firm-age2, to capture expected diminishing quadratic

growth compounded over time, (Angelini and Generale 2008). To account for macro-economic

and other temporal effects, we controlled for a firm’s industry based on the SIC code category,

Page 17: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 17 of 38

by constructing nine industry classes to capture explanatory industry types; construction,

industrial, hi-cap tech, lo-cap tech, services, and sales, using primary industries as a base. We

distinguish between hi-capitalization technology firms (electronics, computer manufacturing,

semiconductors, etc.) and low capital-intensive technology firms, (software, ecommerce,

research, etc.) Our classification starts with the Kaufman database definition modified to include

important technology categories. The relevant codes are in Table 2. 4

Insert Table 2 here

Strategy literature indicates that differing levels of resources, and managerial talent,

might condition new firm evolution, (Haleblian and Finkelstein 1993; Burton and Beckman

2007). Following this literature, to control for differing founding resources, we selected initial

capital, (adjusted for inflation with constant 2008 yen), capital_ini, and controlled for managerial

heterogeneity by including a variable for the credit rating of the firm5, credit_rating. Since the

founder can be replaced and the data reports the data on the current CEO, we control this with a

binary variable, founder, that takes the value of 1 if the CEO had been replaced since founding.

We controlled for macroeconomic effects by including a variable for per capita GDP, (in yen

constant dollars), GDP_PC. To control for competition that may suggest differing initial

conditions for the newly founded firms (CTF), we include the number of firms in an industry,

comp, as a control.

4 We determine whether an SIC code is coded tech following the Kaufman Survey of Small Business, that uses the proportion of resources a focal firm dedicates to research and development to determine if a company is a technology firm, Hadlock, P., D. Hecker, et al. (1991). "High Technology Employment: Another View." Monthly Labor Rview 114.. However, software companies and other common technology firms such as spacecraft manufacturers escape the definition. In the case of our data, software-programming companies are the largest firm-level category of new incorporations over the study period, not designating them as technology firms could introduce bias. To correct for the omission we assigned four additional SIC classifications to designate tech firms. These codes are listed in Table 2. 5 This is TDB’s credit rating. This rating is central to the business purpose of TDB and is similar to a credit score.

Page 18: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 18 of 38

Model Specification and Econometric Issues

We estimated a hazard model to examine whether reforms that lower bankruptcy risks are

likely to raise rate the rate of bankruptcy. We employed a proportional hazards model (Cox

1972), (equation 1), to avoid specifying the relationship between the bankruptcy likelihood and

firm characteristics and there is a rich literature proposing many such relationships, (Gimeno,

Folta et al. 1997) Moreover, the model allow us to understand our variables’ effect on the timing

of the bankruptcy event by estimating the probability of declaring bankruptcy conditional on

both the prior founding of the firm, and adjusts for right censoring of the data. In our approach,

firms become “at risk” at the time of their founding and exit the data – experience the “hazard” –

when they declare bankruptcy. The coefficients we report are hazard rations with a value of 1.0

or greater indicating the associated variable increases the probability of the hazard occurring for

a focal firm. The specification of the model is:

(1) where the vector X includes our founder characteristics firm level variables . λ(t | X) is the rate at

which founders will declare bankruptcy at any particular date, given that they have not gone

bankrupt up until that point in time. The estimation takes into consideration the “right censoring”

that occurs because not all firms experience the hazard of bankruptcy

To test 3a and 3b we use the logistic regression, as the dependent variable is binary. The

logistic regression is appropriate for linear regression models with binary outcomes and we are

testing the outcome of starting a firm or not, (equation 2). We take care to report our outcome as

odds rations whose value, and thus the marginal value of the partial coefficients does not depend

on the variables’ starting value, (Hoetker 2007). Our model is:

( ) ( )βλλ 'exp)(| XtXt o=

Page 19: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 19 of 38

P yi =1 xi =e(X '! )

1+ e(X '! )

!"#

$%&

, (2)

where X is a vector of individual characteristics and controls that may influence the decision to

start a firm, and yi takes the value of 1 if a firm is started during or subsequent to 2003.

To test for firm performance in H4, we use ordinary least squares. We use four models,

(table 7). Models one through three use the cumulative average growth rate since foundation

(cagr) as the dependent variable and net profit as a percent of sales is the dependent variable in

model four. Model one is the basic model with industry controls. Model two adds the

independent variables, and model three adds interactive effects. There is reason to be concerned

that secular economic conditions, though, will affect the variance of growth and value of the firm

from location to location and over founding years violating the ordinary least squares assumption

of homoskedastic, normally distributed errors. Accordingly, a robust corrected ordinary least

squares regression approach is appropriate for our data, (MacKinnon and White 1985).

Results

In spite of the abundant academic literature that suggests that the reforms in Japan ought

to increase the rates of new firm formation, there is scant evidence of this in private and public

data. The most frequently reported data on Japan’s startup rate is the Enterprise and

Establishment Census of Japan issued by the Ministry of Internal Affairs and Communications.

This census is part of a system of statistical business databases that include the Survey on

Service Industries, METI’s Census of Commerce and Census of Manufactures.67 This data

6 The EEC employs field surveys to count the number of new establishments and count the number of establishments that have closed. The survey, after 2004, is conducted every 28-months. The number of new and closed establishments are divided by 28 to

Page 20: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 20 of 38

confirms that, for the overall Japanese economy during our period of study, there is no evidence

that the startup rate of all new firms has changed since 1993, (Chart1). Moreover, our database of

newly incorporated firms also indicates no increase in independent incorporation rates from 1998

through 2007, (Chart 2.) Overall there is no evidence to contradict the body of official statistics

that the startup rates of new firms in Japan have remained steady or slightly declining.

Insert Chart 1- 2 here

However, an examination of the industry components of the data indicates changes in the

heterogeneous mix of firms during the time of our study. Chart 3 describes the startup rates per

industry and there is a long-term decline in the construction industry. This decline is following

the asset bubble collapse and subsequent business decline follow by austerity measures of the

Japanese government restricting building programs, (Vogel 2006). While the changes in the

Japanese construction industry are beyond the scope of this paper, it is notable that this decline

masks an increase in other sectors, notably the service sector. We suggest that the entry of

individuals into the service sector after capital barriers were removed were overcome by a long-

term downward trend in contraction firms caused by exogenous political events. However, we do

not find strong support for our hypothesis 1 that reforms increase the amount of startups.

Insert Chart 3 here

establish an average monthly amount and then multiplied by 12 to establish an average annual amount. In addition, the Ministry of Agriculture, Fisheries and Forestry also produces statistical databases; the Census of Agriculture and Forestry, and the Fishery Census 7Alternative methods to track the number of new firms is to study the filings of payroll tax liabilities reported by the Ministry of Health Labor and Welfare issues in the Annual Report on Employment Insurance Programs. In addition, business starts are counted by compiling new incorporations. The Ministry of Justice issues the National Tax Agency Annual Statistics Report. In this case, new employer tax registrations serve to indicate starts and are compiled on an annual basis.

Page 21: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 21 of 38

Individuals Selecting Entrepreneurship

We next focus on our propositions that differing populations are more likely to start new

firms after reforms. The results of our logit regression are reported in table 6, below. Support for

H3a is indicated by the greater than unity and significant odd ratio for the exec variable, and

similarly for H3b by the significant and greater than 1 coefficient for female and the less than

one and significant coefficient on ceo_age. Together, they indicate the greater likelihood of

executives, females, and younger individuals starting firms after the reforms of 2003. This is

brought into better relief in Chart 6. The chart compares the rates of entry in our database of

executives stratified by industry and indicates greater entry rates for prestigiously educated

founders after reform in all studies industry categories. The effect is greatest in the industrial and

high capital technology industries. Similarly, for female founders illustrated in Chart 7, females

enter all industrial segments - except finance - at a greater rate after 2003 and the effect is

greatest in low capital technology firms and service industry segments. Overall, we find support

for both of the hypotheses related to individuals starting firms. It appears that after reforms, the

prestigiously educated, females, and younger individuals formed an increasing proportion of

founders.

It is notable, though, that they emphasize their entry in differing industry segments. The

executives increasingly selected high capital requirement industrial and technology firms while

female and younger entrants emphasized lower capital industries such as services, software and

e-commerce.

Insert Table 6; and Charts 6 and 7 here

Table 8 reports multivariate models. Model one reports controls only. Model 2 is our hazard

Page 22: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 22 of 38

model testing the likelihood of bankruptcy and model 2 are the result of our logit model of the

likelihood of individual types starting firms. Models 4 and 5 report the OLS results on the

growth performance of new firms before and after reforms. Model 5 includes various two-

variable interactions. Considering the control variables first, results support findings in prior

literature. As expected, growth is negatively related to firms’ age and positively related to the

square of firm age suggesting diminishing growth as the firm ages, indicating expected growth

patterns in the literature in that younger firms grow faster than older firms. Also giving expected

result, improved growth is associated with firms with larger initial capital endowments and

judicious use of credit. Consistent with both practice and observations of new firms in Silicon

Valley, companies that replace their founding CEO’s seem to perform better. Overall, controls in

our model give expected results adding to the robustness of our model.

In support of our Hypothesis 2, firms are more likely to enter bankruptcy after reforms.

We assess the results of our hazard ratio test in model 2 by examining the coefficient on the

yr03_09 variable that is significantly greater than unity. In addition, there is a significant and

negative coefficient on the age variable indicating that the older the firm, the less likely is

bankruptcy. Our argument is that entrepreneurs with career alternative post bankruptcy will be

likelier to exit is supported by the greater than one hazard ratio on the prestige_univ variable

implying that those for the top ten universities in Japan were liker than others to declare

bankruptcy after reforms. These results are consistent with prior literature that bankruptcy risk is

greatest when the firm is young and with the Gimeno (Gimeno, Folta et al. 1997) argument that

resistance thresholds were lowered in the decision problem of entrepreneurs after costs of

bankruptcy were lowered and are even lower for individuals with good alternatives. It is notable

that technology firms are less likely to exit with bankruptcy than others. It is possible that public

Page 23: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 23 of 38

efforts to particularly support technology firms in Japan can explain this, (Whittaker 2001).

Firms founded after reforms grow faster growth than firms founded before reforms

controlling for age. Reform is positive and significant in models 4 and 5, and the entry of

prestigiously educated individuals is associated with this as the coefficient on the prestige_univ

variable is positive and significant as well as the interaction of reform with the top tem alma

mater is significant and positive in model 5. Consistent with our argument that highly

enfranchised individuals select entrepreneurship after reforms, the interaction between the

founder’s age and reforms is positive and significant. The greater than one and significant odds

ratio on female and less than one odds ratios on ceo_age in model 3 indicates that younger

individual and females are also likelier to found firms, however, only the prestigiously educated

are directly associated with better growth. Moreover, the positive coefficient on the interaction

between ceo_age and reform in model 5 suggests that improved growth is associated with older

founders. Interpreting these results, it seems that after reforms, the prestigiously educated,

females and younger individuals are more likely to found firms, but performance is associated

with the older and prestigiously educated. This implies that it is the incentives that tempt the

more enfranchised individuals to enter is likely to cause the improved growth that we observe

after reforms. Overall, we find that even after controlling for traditional factors affecting firm

growth, reforms in the institutional environment changed the calculation of potential

entrepreneurs, and with their entry firm performance increased.

High Performance

If prestigiously educated individuals start better growing firms as our results suggest,

perhaps they are also associated with exceptionally performing firms in terms of growth. Extra-

Page 24: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 24 of 38

ordinary growths is found with interesting Silicon Valley firms such as Google and Facebook,

and are similarly associated with Japanese firms such as Softbank and Rakuten. Academic and

practitioner observers seek these signal firms as indications of the entrepreneurial habitat health

of an economic domain, (Miller 2000). We tested this idea by defining a variable, hicagr, a

binary variable that take the value of 1 if a firms cumulative growth rate since founding is 2.5

standard deviations above the mean cagr and using a logit regression against our control and

explanatory variables. The results are presented in Table 9. We examine the coefficients (odds

ratios) on the prestigious university and founder age variables and find them to be significant and

confirm that older alumni of top ten universities increase the likelihood of a firm founded after

reform to be an extraordinary growth performer.

Insert Table 9 and Chart 8 here

Discussion and Conclusion

Our result support our arguments that institutional reforms can alter the incentives of

individuals selecting entrepreneurship to effect performance as they form new firms even in the

absence of increased new formation rates. Institutional theorists have argued that institutions

impact the founding rates of new organizations, (Russo 2001; Sine, Haveman et al. 2005).

Institutional changes that increase the legitimacy of a sector appear to result in increased

entrepreneurial opportunity and founding activity (Sine and David 2003). Yet, there is increasing

interest in how institutions help to shape the behavior and performance of new firms. While

increased entrepreneurial activity might be beneficial for society in the aggregate, we have little

theory or evidence that would predict whether or when institutional change results in higher

performing firms. If institutional change merely increases the founding rate, but we leave

Page 25: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 25 of 38

unexplored the performance impact, then it leaves open the possibility that the net result is

simply a transfer of revenue or jobs from older, incumbent firms to new entrants. We seek to

contribute to this literature by arguing that institutions, through their effects on the type of

individuals founding firms and the character of the firms created, has effects on venture

performance. We provide support for our hypotheses by examining whether institutional reforms

in Japan that were targeted at increasing the rate of entrepreneurship had an impact on the growth

rate of entrepreneurial firms.

The reforms in Japan subsequent to the beginning of a decade of economic stagnation in

1990 provide us with the natural experiment to examine our ideas. Prior to the reforms,

institutions once viewed as crucial to Japan’s economic growth and stability came to be viewed

as barriers. Japanese labor market rigidity (Conrad 2009), idiosyncratic venture capital systems

(Kenney, Han et al. 2002), adverse risk attitudes (Suzuki, Kim et al. 2002; Bird 2003), infrequent

university technology licensing, (Kneller and Shudo 2008), and inadequate legal and accounting

infrastructure in Japan (Hawkins 1993), reduced the viability of start-up potential in comparison

to Silicon Valley.

Supporting the idea that Japan’s economic climate as inhospitable to a dynamic

entrepreneurial dynamic are data suggesting that the startup rate in Japan is low and declining

when compared to other advanced economies. The Global Entrepreneurship Monitor, for

example, reports that Japan has the lowest rate of entrepreneurial activity among surveyed

countries. Although this conclusion has recently come under critical scrutiny suggesting that

GEM methodology understate startup rate is understated, (Acs, Desai, Klapper 2008). Moreover,

the economic trajectory of China created economic uncertainty in Japan as manufacturing

Page 26: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 26 of 38

industries realigned their strategies, moved their factories to China, and focused on smaller and

more specialized business lines while engaging in new employment practices, (Vogel 2006;

Schaede 2008). This continuing re-assessment of Japan’s entrepreneurial and innovation climate

increasingly became the subject of a national policy reform based on the idea that the legal and

institutional architecture of Japan was no longer relevant to a new economic logic.

Before reforms, both the prestigiously educated and female entrepreneurs were

infrequently observed in Japan prior to in comparison to Silicon Valley. In a survey firms

founded between 1990 and 2000 in Japan and Silicon Valley, female entrepreneurs comprised

28% of the surveyed entrepreneurs in Silicon Valley yet were only 4.5% in Japan. In educational

background, there were substantive differences with 62% of Silicon Valley entrepreneurs

holding post-graduate degrees in contrast to 32% in Japan, (Suzuki, Kim et al. 2002). This is

consistent with the prior literature before the reforms of 2003 that entrepreneurs in Japan shared

idiosyncratic demographics compared to the well-studied homogeneity of typical careerists there.

It is likely that social institutions in Japan can account for much of the observed

difference in entrepreneurial populations before reforms. In the case of Japan potential

entrepreneurs farther along a career trajectory than new graduates have a greater risk of lifetime

earning impairment by entry into new firm employment (Harada 2005). High capital

requirements can comprise a substantial portion of a family’s retirement savings as many in the

past relied on company pensions. Thus the risk of loss of both pension and savings is potentially

more catastrophic for older entrants than younger. While jobs with pension benefits are

becoming increasingly scarce, the reliance on saving is even more essential and the onerous

bankruptcy burdens before reforms may have discouraged more experienced potential

Page 27: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 27 of 38

entrepreneurs. Overall, the lowering of entry capital requirements and reform of bankruptcy laws

can directly affect the financial calculations of these nascent entrepreneurs and perhaps cause

larger proportion to found new firms.

Our results suggest that after the 2003 Japanese reforms lowering the amount of capital

required to found a firm and reducing individual bankruptcy liability, that the performance of

firms increased. The post-reform performance of younger, entrepreneurial firms was even more

positively affected. These results support the idea that these reforms facilitated better performing

firms. The institutional change might have either encouraged the entry of individuals who have

sufficient ability but were otherwise financially-constrained from founding firms or encouraged

individuals towards a higher risk, higher reward style of entrepreneurship that resulted in an

increase of young, high growth firms. Notably, our results show that firms did not take on

significantly greater risk after the reforms. Rather, the debt to equity ratio (a common measure of

financial risk) actually fell in the post-reform time period. Further analysis will seek to

disentangle these two more detailed mechanisms.

This paper contributes to literature on institutional theory by highlighting the impact that

institutions have on entrepreneurial firm performance. While we might have expected, based on

previous work that institutional reforms targeting entrepreneurship might reduce firm

performance through increased levels of competition, resulting from more entry and thus prices

closer to marginal cost, instead we find evidence for increased firm performance. We examine

reforms that lowered capital requirements and reduced the risks associated with bankruptcy. The

findings suggest that while these reforms may have lead to a more competitive market, the

overall impact was that individuals became more likely to found higher growth firms. We

Page 28: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 28 of 38

contribute to the emerging view that institutions help to shape the level of productivity of new

firms in the economy through their effects on individuals and their choices to become

entrepreneurs. The paper also contributes to the entrepreneurship literature by showing the

importance of the broader institutional environment at founding in shaping the performance

outcomes of entrepreneurial firms.

Our results also have important practical implications for policymakers. Many local,

state, and national governments are currently seeking to encourage more high growth

entrepreneurship in the expectation that it leads to job creation and GDP growth. Previous work

had either shown institutional mechanisms for increasing the rate of entrepreneurship with little

to no evidence that these new firms were high growth firms (Sine, Haveman et al. 2005);

Romanelli 1989). In fact, prior work had suggested that by attempting to encourage

entrepreneurship, policymakers might actually be encouraging wealthy, but low ability

individuals to found firms that were more poorly performing. Our findings point to specific

reforms undertaken in Japan, which had a particularly strong impact on increasing the growth

rate of entrepreneurial firms. This finding suggests institutional changes that appear to increase

the rate of high growth entrepreneurship.

If entrepreneurship is the engine of economic growth and the perennial gale of “creative

destruction” referred to by Schumpeter (1934), it appears that the structure of institutions in

society plays an important role in determine how strong that gale is in the economy.

Page 29: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 29 of 38

Chart 1

Chart 3

Table 2 SIC Category Description Dataset

28 Chemicals Kauffman, STAJE 35 Industrial Machinery Kauffman, STAJE 36 Electronics (incl. Semiconductors) Kauffman, STAJE 38 Instruments, Test Equipment Kauffman, STAJE 372 Aircraft STAJE 376 Guided Missiles, Spacecraft STAJE 737 Software, Data Processing (incl. ISP’s) STAJE 871 Engineering Service STAJE 873 Research Centers STAJE

1993  

1994  

1995  

1996  

1997  

1998  

1999  

2000  

2001  

2002  

2003  

2004  

2005  

2006  

2007  

Entry   4.6   4.8   4.6   4.7   4.2   3.9   4.4   4.9   4.4   4.1   4   4.1   4.4   4.8   5  Exit   3.4   3.4   3.6   2.5   2.8   3.1   4   4   4.4   4.6   4.8   4.5   4.3   4.4   4.5  

0  1  2  3  4  5  6  

%  annual  change  -­‐  all  employment  

establishments  

Japan  Entry  and  Exit  Rates  Employment  Insurance  Data    

0  

0.1  

0.2  

0.3  

0.4  

0.5  

1999   2000   2001   2002   2003   2004   2005   2006   2007   2008  

Percentage    Share  of  Total  

Industry  Share  of  Startups  -­‐  Japan  Primary  

Construction  

Industrial  

Technology  

Whole/Retail  

Finance  

Page 30: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 30 of 38

Table 3

No Foundation Date Foundation Date t-test H0=0, unequal var Curr-Prof 2541 1201 1.53 Curr-Sales 336 311 0.9432 Capital 12586 7221 4.79 Gender 1.08 1.07 1.46 CEO_DOB 1961.9 1961.6 0.963 For_own 0.002 0.002 -0.329 Employees 10.6 10.4 0.169

Chart 7

Table 7 Covariance Matrix

reform top_coll gender dob founder brcagr Age credit gdp_cagr capital tech reform 1.0000 top_coll 0.0331 1.0000 gender 0.0293 -0.0090 1.0000 dob 0.1452 -0.0248 -0.0217 1.0000 founder -0.0353 -0.0215 -0.0543 -0.0012 1.0000 brcagr -0.0364 0.0207 -0.0024 0.0128 -0.0204 1.0000 Age -0.4215 -0.0274 -0.0296 -0.3435 -0.3381 0.0123 1.0000 credit -0.1173 -0.0561 0.0013 0.0558 -0.0981 0.1387 0.2187 1.0000 gdp_cagr -0.6180 -0.0391 -0.0277 -0.2801 -0.1059 0.0280 0.7558 0.1654 1.0000 capital -0.0003 0.0353 -0.0122 -0.0122 -0.0453 0.0447 -0.0104 -0.0906 -0.0014 1.0000 tech 0.0282 0.0221 -0.0250 0.0250 0.0063 0.0041 -0.0528 -0.0108 -0.0403 0.0284 1.0000

Page 31: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 31 of 38

Table 8  

MODEL Hazard 1 Logit 2 OLS 3 OLS 4 OLS 5

DV = MEANS bankrupt reform CAGR CAGR CAGR

firm_age 14.1 -.4794 *** -.1658 *** -.1658 *** -.099 *** firm_age2 .0042 *** .002 *** .0011 *** credit_rating 38.6 .0146 *** .0147 *** .0117 *** GDP_PC 3.9(MY) -.0007 -.005 *** -.003 *** capital_initial 12.9(MY) .0000008 *** .9999 ** .000002 ** .000002 ** .0000003 *** founder_CEO 8.8% -.3982 *** -.3344 *** -.1961 *** comp .9999 .0000001 .0000004 industrial .2601 1.239 .1565 .1139 .1398 * contruct .3271 .8076 -.1216 .0786 -.126 hi-capital tech .3898 1.335 -.0596 -.0696 .0287 lo-capital tech .0807 * .0554 -.1327 .0734 sales 1.574 * -.0156 -.0916 .0134 service 1.684 ** -.1142 ** .0568 -.0638 yr03-09 1.889 *** reform .6406 *** 5.057 *** prestige_univ 1.4% .3615 *** 2.186 *** .3338 *** -044 gender 6.4% .0624 1.24 ** -.0735 - -0265 ceo_age 48.7 .9643 *** .006 *** -.0005 ref X firm_age -8694 *** ref x col 1.261 *** ref x gen -.0589 ref x ceo_age .01254 *** . Constant NA NA 2.82 4.179 *** 2.546 F 62998 388.258 *** 273.34 *** 258.87 *** 397.22 *** R2 NA NA .2374 .283 .4010 N 16814 15399 11192 13190 12480 12480

 

8 Chi2

Page 32: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 32 of 38

Table 9 dv = hicagr odds ratio std. err. sig firm_age .7246 .3269 firm_age2 .8673 .0504 ** prestige_univ 2.386 1.254 * female .7419 .2506 ceo_age 1.012 .0081 * indus 2.206 1.871 constr 2.024 1.710 serv 1.846 1.543 tech .4278 .2206 * whole 3.243 2.699 retail 2.998 2.511 Log likelihood -463.961 No. of obs 14305 LR chi2 (12) 1493.83 *** Table 1

Sample Partition Count Ratio Initial COSMOS Data 155,022 Firms with company ownership or no operations for two years 112,745 0.73 Net Independent firms (extant) 42,277 Net Independent firms (bankrupt) 12,733

Firms with foundation date (extant) 12,822 0.30 Firms with foundation date (extant) 12,733 1.00 Random selection bankrupt firms 4002 0.31

Final Sample 16,824

dv = hiprof odds ratio std. err. sig firm_age .9899 .0258 firm_age2 1.0002 .0004 prestige_univ 3.147 1.179 *** female 1.474 .4222 ~ ceo_age .845 .0403 *** ceo_age2 1.001 .0004 *** indus .5454 .1967 * constr .1597 .0627 *** serv .6441 .2175 tech 1.643 .4665 * whole .1667 .0706 *** retail .3158 .1205 *** Log likelihood -826.648 No. of obs 14305 LR chi2 (12) 93.72 ***

Page 33: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 33 of 38

Bibliography

Amit, R., E. Muller, et al. (1995). "Opportunity Costs and Entrepreneurial Activity." Journal of Business

Venturing 10(2): 95-106. Angelini, P. and A. Generale (2008). "On the Evolution of Firm Size Distributions." American Economic

Review 98(1): 426-438. Aoki, M. (1990). "Toward an Economic Model of the Japanese Firm." Journal of Economic Literature

28(1): 1-27. Barkham, R., G. Gudgin, et al. (1996). The Determinants of Small Business Growth: An Inter-Regional

Study in the United Kingdom 1986–1990. J. Kingsley. London, Regional Studies Association. Barnett, W. and G. Carroll (1995). "Modeling Internal Organizational Change." Annual Review of

Sociology 21(1995): 217-236. Barro, R. (1996). DETERMINANTS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CROSS-COUNTRY EMPIRICAL

STUDY. NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES. Cambridge, MA, NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH.

Barro, R. (2001). "Human Capital and Growth." American Economic Review 91(2): 12-17. Baum, J. and B. Bird (2010). "The Successful Intelligence of High-Growth Entrepreneurs: Links to New

Venture Growth." Organization Science 21(2): 397-412. Baumol, W. J. (1990). "Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive." Journal of

Business Venturing 11: 3-22. Bird, A. (2003). "Entrepreneurs amd Entreprenuerial Processes: Historical Perspectives on

Entrepreneurship in the Japanese Contexts." Asian Perspectives 27(3): 125-175. Buera, F. (2009). "A dynamic model of entrepreneurship with borrowing constraints: theory and

evidence." Annals of Finance 5(3-4): 443-464. Burton, M. D. and C. Beckman (2007). "Leaving a Legacy: Position Imprints and Successor Turnover in

Young Firms." American Sociological Review 72: 239-266. Burton, M. D., J. Sorensen, et al. (2002). "COMING FROM GOOD STOCK: CAREER HISTORIES

AND NEW VENTURE FORMATION." Social Structure and Organizations Revisited (Research in the Sociology of Organizations) 19: 229-262.

Conrad, H. (2009). "From Seniority to Performace Principle: The Evolution of Pay Practices in Japanese Firms since the 1990's." Social Science Japan Journal 13(1): 1-21.

Davidsson, P., L. Achtenhagen, et al. (2007). What Do We Know About Small Firm Growth? . The Life Cycle of Entrepreneurial Ventures, Springer. 3: 361-398.

Davila, A., G. Foster, et al. (2003). "Venture capital financing and the growth of startup firms." Journal of Business Venturing 18: 689-708.

Dencker, J. C., M. Gruber, et al. (2009). "Pre-entry Knowledge, Learning, and the Survival of New Firms " Organization Science 20(3): 516-537.

Eesley, C. (2010). WHO HAS ‘THE RIGHT STUFF’? EDUCATIONAL ELITES, ENTREPRENEURSHIP AND INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE IN CHINA, Stanford University.

Eisenhardt, K. and C. Schoonhoven (1990). "Organizational Growth: Linking Founding Team, Strategy, Environment, and Growth Among U.S. Semiconductor Ventures, 1978-1988." Administrative Science Quarterly 35(3): 504-529.

Evans, D. S. (1987). "THE RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FIRM GROWTH, SIZE, AND AGE: ESTIMATES FOR 100 MANUFACTURING INDUSTRIES." Journal of Industrial Economics 35(4): 567-581.

Evans, D. S. and B. Jovanovich (1989). "An Estimated Model of Entrepreneurial Choice under Liquidity Constratints." Journal of Political Economy 97(4): 808-827.

Fan, W. and M. White (2003). "PERSONAL BANKRUPTCY AND THE LEVEL OF ENTREPRENEURIAL ACTIVITY." Journal of Law and Economics 46(October): 543 - 567.

Gersick, C. (1994). "Pacing Strategic Change: The Case of a New Venture." Academy of Management Journal 37(1): 9-45.

Page 34: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 34 of 38

Gimeno, J., T. Folta, et al. (1997). "Survival of the Fittest? Entrepreneurial Human Capital and the Persistence of Underperforming Firms." Administrative Science Quarterly 42.

Gompers, P., J. Lerner, et al. (2006). "Entrepreneurial Spawning: Public Corporations and the Genesis of New Ventures, 1986 to 1999." Journal of Finance 60(2): 577 - 614.

Hadlock, P., D. Hecker, et al. (1991). "High Technology Employment: Another View." Monthly Labor Rview 114.

Haleblian, J. and S. Finkelstein (1993). "Top Management Team Size, CEO Dominance, and Firm Performance: The Moderating Roles of Environmental Turbulence and Discretion." Academy of Management Journal 36(4): 844-863.

Hall, B. H. (1987). "The Relationship Between Firm Size and Firm Growth in the US Manufacturing Sector." The Journal of Industrial Economics 35(4): 583-606.

Hannan, M. and J. Freeman (1984). "Structural Inertia and Organizational Change." American Sociology Review 49: 149-164.

Harada, N. (2005). "Potential Entrepreneurship in Japan." Small Business Economics 25: 293-304. Haveman, H. A., M. V. Russo, et al. (2001). "Organizational Environments in Flux: The Impact of

Regulatory Punctuations on Organizational Domains, CEO Succession, and Performance." Organization Science 12(3): 253-273.

Hawkins, D. (1993). "NEW BUSINESS: ENTREPRENEURSHIP IN THE JAPANESE ECONOMY." Journal of Business Venturing 8: 137-150.

Helwege, J. and F. Packer (2003). "Determinants of the choice of bankruptcy procedure in Japan." Journal of Financial Intermediation 12: 96-120.

Hmieleski, K. and R. Baron (2009). "ENTREPRENEURS’ OPTIMISM AND NEW VENTURE PERFORMANCE: A SOCIAL COGNITIVE PERSPECTIVE." Academy of Management Journal 52(3): 473-488.

Hoetker, G. (2007). "The USe of Logit and Probit Models in Strategic Management Research: Critical Issues." Strategic Management Journal 28: 331-343.

Holtz-Eakin, D., D. Joulfaian, et al. (1994). "Entrepreneurial Decisions and Liquidity Constraints." The RAND Journal of Economics 25(2).

Honjo, Y. (2004). "Growth of New Start-up Firms: Evidence from the Japanese manufacturing industry " Applied Economics Letters 11(1): 21-32.

Honjo, Y. and N. Harada (2006). "SME Policy, Financial Structure, and Firm Growth: Evidence from Japan." Small Business Economics(27): 289-300.

Igarashi, S. and N. Taji (2006). "THE GROWTH MODEL OF JAPANESE HIGH-TECH START-UPS (INTERACTIVE PAPER)." Frontiers of Entrepreneurship Research 26(22).

Katila, R. and S. Shane (2005). "WHEN DOES LACK OF RESOURCES MAKE NEW FIRMS INNOVATIVE?" Academy of Management Journal 48(5): 814-829.

Kenney, M., K. Han, et al. (2002). Scattering Geese: The Venture Capital Industries of East Asia: A Report to the World Bank. UCAIS Berkeley Roundtable on the International Economy. Berkeley, University of California Berkeley.

Klapper, L., L. Laeven, et al. (2006). "Entry regulation as a barrier to entrepreneurship." Journal of Financial Economics 82: 591 - 629.

Kneller, R. and S. Shudo (2008). "Large Companies’ Preemption of University Inventions by Joint Research Is Strangling Japanese Entrepreneurship and Contributing to the Degradation of University Science." Journal of the Intellectual Property Association of Japan 5(2): 36 - 50.

Lazear, E. (2005). "Entrepreneurship." Journal of Labor Economics 23(4). Lee, S.-H., M. W. Peng, et al. (2007). "BANKRUPTCY LAW AND ENTREPRENEURSHIP

DEVELOPMENT: A REAL OPTIONS PERSPECTIVE." Academy of Management Review 32(1): 257-272.

Lee, S.-H., Y. Yamakawa, et al. (2008). Entrepreneurship and the Barrier to Exit: How Does an Entrepreneur-Friendly Bankruptcy Law Affect Entrepreneurship Development at a Societal Leve. Small Business Research Summary. Chapel Hill, NC, Babson College.

Page 35: Institutional Reform and New Firm Performance: More or ... · Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION Page 5 of 38 Research demonstrates that

Eberhart / Eesley 8/2011 DO NOT COPY OR CIRCULATE WITHOUT AUTHOR’S PERMISSION

Page 35 of 38

Masuda, T. (2006). "The Determinants of Latent Entrepreneurship i Japan." Small Business Economics 26: 227-240.

Matsushita, J. (2006). "Japan's Personal Insolvency Law." Texas International Law Journal 42: 765-772. Miller, W. F. (2000). The "Habitat" for Entrepreneurship. Asia Pacific Research Center Discussion

Series. Stanford, Stanford University. Murphy, K., A. Shleifer, et al. (1991). "The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth." The

Quarterly Journal of Economics 106(2): 503 - 530. Nanda, R. and J. B. Sørensen (2008). Peer Effects and Entrepreneurship. HBS Working Paper Series,

Harvard University. Ohara, K. (2009). R. Eberhart. Tokyo. Peng, M. and J. Zhou (2005). "How Network Strategies and Institutional Transitions Evolve in Asia."

Asia Pacific Journal of Management 22: 321 - 336. Romanelli, E. (1989). "Environments and strategies of organization start-up: Effects on Early Survival. ."

Administrative Science Quarterly 34(3). Russo, M. V. (2001). "Institutions, exchange relations, and the emergence of new fields: Regulatory

policies and independent power production in America, 1978-1992." Administrative Science Quarterly 46: 57-86.

Schaede, U. (2008). Choose and focus : Japanese business strategies for the 21st century. Ithaca, N.Y., Cornell University Press.

Shane, S. (2000). "Prior knowledge, and the discovery of entrepreneurial opportunities." Organization Science 11(4): 448-469.

Sine, W. D. and R. David (2003). "Environmental Jolts, Institutional Change, and the Creation of Entrepreneurial Opportunity in the U.S. Electric Power Industry." Research Policy 32: 185-207.

Sine, W. D., H. A. Haveman, et al. (2005). "Risky Business? Entrepreneurship in the New Independent-Power Sector." Administrative Science Quarterly 50(2): 200-232.

Sorensen, J. and T. Stuart (2000). "Aging, Obsolescence and Organizational Innovation." Administrative Science Quarterly 45(1): 81-112.

Sørensen, J. B. (2007). Closure and exposure: Mechanisms in the intergenerational transmission of self-employment. Research in the sociology of organizations, vol. 25: 83-124 Elsevier: JAI. M. R. M. Lounsbury, Elsevier. 25: 83-124.

Sørensen, J. B. and P. Chang (2006). Determinants of Successful Entrepreneurship: A Review of the Recent Literature, Ewing Marion Kauffman Foundation.

Stinchcombe, A. L. (1965). Social structure of organizations. Chicago, IL, Rand-McNally. Suchman, M. (1995). "Managing Legitimacy: Strategic and Institutional Approaches." Academy of

Management Review 20(3). Suzuki, K., S.-H. Kim, et al. (2002). "Entrepreneurship in Japan and Silicon Valley: A Comparative

Study." Technovation 22: 595-606. Thornton, P. (1999). "The Sociology of Entrepreneurship." Annual Review of Sociology 25: 19-46. Tolbert, P. S., R. David, et al. (2010). "Studying Choice and Change: The Intersection of Institutional

Theoryand Entrepreneurship Research." Organization Science Articles in Advance: 1-13. Vogel, S. K. (2006). Japan remodeled : how government and industry are reforming Japanese capitalism.

Ithaca, Cornell University Press. Whittaker, D. H. (2001). Crisis and Innovation in Japan: A New Future through Techno-

Entrepreneurship? MIT Japan Program. Cambridge, MA, MIT. Xu, P. (2007). Corporate Governance in Financila Distress: The New Role of Bankruptcy. Corporate

Governance in Japan. M. Aoki, G. Jackson and H. Miyajima. New York, Oxford University Press.