introduction of health economics

66
Introduction to Health Economics Dr Hendramoorthy Maheswaran [email protected]

Upload: hussain-m-a-khuwaja

Post on 16-Apr-2015

41 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: introduction of health economics

Introduction to Health Economics

Dr Hendramoorthy [email protected]

Page 2: introduction of health economics

“Economics is usually a rather doom-laden subject, and in this respect is linked indirectly with medicine through the observation that the only two things in life that are certain are death and taxes.”

Alan Williams

Page 3: introduction of health economics

What is the purpose?

• Central problem addressed by the discipline of economics:

• resource scarcity

• The purpose behind economic analyses:• to help decision-makers faced with choices concerning

resource scarcity

Page 4: introduction of health economics

Overview

• Definitions

• Macro-economics

• Microeconomics

Page 5: introduction of health economics

DEFINITIONS

Page 6: introduction of health economics

Utility

• a measure of the relative satisfaction from, or desirability for, the consumption of goods or services

• “a utility function is a numerical representation of preferences” (Hargreaves-Heap, 1992)

Page 7: introduction of health economics

Health

• Perspective 1– health is one of many goods that can be produced in an economy, the

consumption of which produces utility– Welfarist

• Perspective 2 – health is a physical entity of which individuals have a stock, and of

which extra (gain) can be produced through the allocation of resources to health production.

– Here, health is valued for its own sake, and irrespective of whether or not it produces utility

– Extra-welfarist

Page 8: introduction of health economics

Opportunity costs

• The value of the consequences forgone by choosing to deploy resources in one way rather than in their best alternative use

Page 9: introduction of health economics

Efficiency - technical

• Producing output in the best way possible, without wasting scarce resources

• Meeting a given objective at least cost

Page 10: introduction of health economics

Efficiency - allocative

• Producing the pattern of output that best satisfies the pattern of consumers’ wants/needs

Page 11: introduction of health economics

Equity• Fairness

• Horizontal equity– Equal treatment of equals– the extent to which those who are equal with respect to health status have

equal access to healthcare

• Vertical equity– Unequal treatment of unequal's– the extent to which those who are unequal with respect to income differ with

respect to how much they have to contribute towards the cost of health care

• Economics can describe a system in terms of equity but statements about the fairness rely on value judgments

Page 12: introduction of health economics

MACROECONOMICS

Page 13: introduction of health economics

Financing Healthcare

• Nature of Public/Private mix:– Provision– Financing

• Methods of raising finances– Private Finance– Public Health Insurance– Direct Taxation

• Methods of paying providers:– Doctors– Hospitals

Page 14: introduction of health economics

Basic systems for raising finance

• Private Health Insurance

• The insurance company covers specified risks of ill health and incurs the consequential expense

• The insurance is paid by the consumer or shared by an employer

• Premiums are based on risk status• Coverage often lacking for the poor and chronically sick• e.g. US

Page 15: introduction of health economics

• Social Health Insurance (Welfare – oriented)

• Based on notion of ‘solidarity’• Usually administered by a monopolistic agent, e.g. a

designated agency (Social Insurance Fund)• Premiums tend to be related to income & not risk• Universal or part coverage• e.g. France; Germany; Luxemburg; the Netherlands

Page 16: introduction of health economics

• Direct taxation

• Finance provided by a public monopoly (e.g. UK NHS)• Finance is principally raised by general or hypothecated

taxation, supplemented by out-of pocket contributions• Universal coverage• e.g. UK; Denmark; Finland; Ireland; Italy; Portugal;

Spain; Sweden

Page 17: introduction of health economics
Page 18: introduction of health economics
Page 19: introduction of health economics
Page 20: introduction of health economics

Equity in finance

• Progressive financing system– The proportion of income that is used to pay for health care

rises as income rises

• Regressive financing system– The proportion of income that is used to pay for health care

falls as income rises

• Proportional financing system– The proportion of income paid does not vary with the level

of income

Page 21: introduction of health economics

Relationship between the progressivityand health care financing systems

• Evidence suggests that health care systems that are based:– Social health insurance

• Regressive

– Tax based• Tend towards progressivity

– Private health insurance• Highly regressive

Page 22: introduction of health economics

11 12

16 16

19

23

0

20

40

GER AUS NZ UK CAN US

Percent reporting test results/records not available at time of appointment in past two years

Does more mean better service?

GER=Germany; AUS=Australia; NZ=New Zealand; UK=United Kingdom; CAN=Canada; US=United States.Data: Analysis of 2005 Commonwealth Fund International Health Policy Survey of Sicker Adults; Schoen et al. 2005a.Source: Commonwealth Fund National Scorecard on U.S. Health System Performance, 2006.

6

9 10 11

1820

0

20

40

UK NZ CAN AUS US GER

Percent reporting that doctor ordered test that had already been done in past two years

Page 23: introduction of health economics

Difficulty Getting Care After Hours Without Going to the Emergency Room

34 33 2915 15 20 20

40

2823 27

21 1519 24

20

0

20

40

60

80

AUS CAN FR GER NETH NZ UK US

Somewhat difficult

Very difficult

Base: Adults with any chronic condition who needed after-hours care

Percent reported very/somewhat difficult getting care on nights, weekends, or holidays without going to ER

Data collection: Harris Interactive, Inc.Source: 2008 Commonwealth Fund International Health Policy Survey of Sicker Adults.

6256 56

3630

3944

60

Page 24: introduction of health economics

Diabetics Who Received Recommended Preventive Care Services

3639

31

40

5955

67

43

0

20

40

60

80

AUS CAN FR GER NETH NZ UK US

Base: Adults with diabetes

Percent received all four diabetes services*

Data collection: Harris Interactive, Inc.Source: 2008 Commonwealth Fund International Health Policy Survey of Sicker Adults.

* Hemoglobin A1c checked in past six months; feet examined for sores or irritations in past year; eye exam for diabetes in past year; and cholesterol checked in past year.

Page 25: introduction of health economics

Infant Mortality Rates

* 2001.Data: International estimates—OECD Health Data 2005;State estimates—National Vital Statistics System, Linked Birth and Infant Death Data (AHRQ 2005a).Source: Commonwealth Fund National Scorecard on U.S. Health System Performance, 2006.

Icel

and

Japa

nFi

nlan

dSw

eden

Nor

way

Spain

Fran

ceA

ustr

ia

Cze

ch R

epub

licG

erm

any

Bel

gium

Den

mar

k

Italy

Switz

erla

ndN

ethe

rland

sA

ustr

alia

Portu

gal

Irela

ndG

reec

e

Uni

ted

Kin

gdom

Can

ada

New

Zea

land

*U

nite

d Sta

tes

0

5

10

2.2

3.0 3.03.3 3.5

4.1 4.1 4.1 4.2 4.2 4.4 4.4 4.5 4.55.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.1 5.2 5.4 5.6

7.0

Infant deaths per 1,000 live births

International variation

Page 26: introduction of health economics
Page 27: introduction of health economics

Greater expenditure +Poorer outcomes

Page 28: introduction of health economics

Market failure

• Lack of perfect competition• Monopolies • Distribution of market power and prices

• Imperfect Knowledge• Health is uncertain• Moral hazard• Adverse selection• Agency relationship ->Supplier Induced Demand

• Externalities • Specifically in the USA:

– Administrative complexity and costs– Unwillingness to ration health care– Lack of Universal overage -> no risk pooling

Page 29: introduction of health economics

USA: Health Expenditure Growth 2000–2005 for Selected Categories of Expenditures

12.0

8.6 8.0 7.96.1

10.7

0

5

10

15

20

Total Hospital care Physician &clinical services

Nursing home &home health

Prescriptiondrugs

Prog. admin. &net cost of

private healthinsurance

Average annual percent growth in health expenditures, 2000–2005

Source: A. Catlin et al., “National Health Spending in 2005: The Slowdown Continues,”Health Affairs, Jan./Feb. 2007 26(1):142–53.

Page 30: introduction of health economics

Percentage of National Health ExpendituresSpent on Health Administration and Insurance, 2003

Net costs of health administration and health insurance as percent of national health expenditures

1.9 2.1 2.12.6

3.34.0 4.1 4.2

4.8

5.6

7.3

0

2

4

6

8

France

Finlan

d

Japan

Canada

United K

ingdom

Netherla

nds

Austria

Australi

a

Switzerla

nd

German

y

United S

tates

a b c *

a2002 b1999 c2001*Includes claims administration, underwriting, marketing, profits, and other administrative costs;based on premiums minus claims expenses for private insurance.Data: OECD Health Data 2005.Source: Commonwealth Fund National Scorecard on U.S. Health System Performance, 2006.

Page 31: introduction of health economics

Moral Hazard

• Presence of incentives which encourage individuals to act in ways that incur costs which they do not bear themselves

• Consumers pay nothing at the point of consumption, therefore use health care more often than if they did pay

• Effects:– Fewer incentives to adopt a healthier lifestyle.– Welfare loss - resources could have been used

elsewhere in the economy to provide more benefit.

Page 32: introduction of health economics

Adverse Selection

• Information asymmetry between insurer and insured.• low risk individuals choose not to purchase

insurance.• Insurance system collapses OR• Insurers learn people’s risks (i.e. solve problem of

information asymmetry), then set low price policies for low risk people and high price policies for high risk people.

• high risk individuals priced out of the market• gaps in insurance coverage.

Page 33: introduction of health economics

Uninsured Rates High Among Adults with Low and Moderate Incomes

15 17 18

33 37 37

1724 28

9

9 9 9

1615 16

1111

13

9

76 2 33

7 9

0

25

50

75 Insured now, time uninsured in past year

Uninsured now

Percent of adults ages 19–64

Note: Income refers to annual income. In 2001 and 2003, low income is <$20,000, moderate income is $20,000–$34,999, middle income is $35,000–$59,999, and high income is $60,000 or more. In 2005, low income is <$20,000, moderate income is $20,000–$39,999, middle income is $40,000–$59,999, and high income is $60,000 or more. Source: S.R. Collins et al., Gaps in Health Insurance Coverage: An All-American Problem, Findings from the Commonwealth Fund Biennial Health Insurance Survey, The Commonwealth Fund, April 2006.

26

52

35

16

4

24

49

28

13

4

Total Low income Moderate income

Middle income

High income

2001 2003 2005 2001 2003 20052001 2003 20052001 2003 20052001 2003 2005

28

53

41

18

7

Page 34: introduction of health economics

Supplier induced demand• Agency relationship – information asymmetry between patients (who

demand health care) and doctors (who supply health care)

• doctor acts as agents for the patient, s/he demands health care on the patient’s behalf

• Supplier (doctor) brings about a level of consumption that is different from that which would have occurred if the consumer (patient) had been fully informed and able to chose their own level of care.

• A problem if the best interests for the doctor are not the same as the best interests for the patient.

Page 35: introduction of health economics

Paying Doctors – no method is perfect, but some are better!

• Fee for Service• Rewards according to volume of service provided• Problems: Supplier Induced Demand (SID); cost inflation

• Capitation• Payment according to number of registered patients• Problems: Increase list size; refer patients to specialists

• Salaried• Monthly/hourly, based on level/rank, increases if promoted• Problems: Discontinuity of care as result of doctor’s quest for

promotion; label of ‘employee’ undesirable; lack of competition & motivation

Page 36: introduction of health economics

Who does Obama think he is?

Page 37: introduction of health economics

Or possibly...

Page 38: introduction of health economics

Theory of Second Best – Rationale for Government Intervention

• Market failure in health care is often unavoidable

• The ‘theory of second best’ states that if one of the criteria for Pareto optimum in unattainable then it becomes no longer desirable to ensure the other criteria are attained

• In this situation the optimum state, the second-best allocation of resources, is only achieved if we do not aim to ensure the other criteria are met

• Importantly, whilst there is only one state where we have Pareto optimality, there are a multitude of second best optimum states

Page 39: introduction of health economics

What

• Universal coverage• Regulate Insurance companies

• 80% of premiums to be spent on medical care• Pre-existing conditions • Rescission• <26 cover through parents

• Close Doughnut hole• Incentivise Primary Care on quality not volume• Health Insurance Exchanges

• Increase market power to 3rd party payer

Page 40: introduction of health economics
Page 41: introduction of health economics

MICROECONOMICS

Page 42: introduction of health economics

Economic Evaluations• Objective:

• to promote the efficient use of health care resources• to ensure the maximum total benefit is derived from the finite resources

available• to provide explicit means of linking evidence and scientific and social value

judgments with decisions• to provide information to decision makers of the implications of their decisions

• Definitions– ‘opportunity cost’

• the value of the consequences forgone by choosing to deploy a resource in one way rather than in its best alternative use

– ‘economic evaluation’• a comparative analysis of alternative courses of action in terms of both costs

and consequences

Page 43: introduction of health economics

So does economic evaluation impacton Technology Coverage Decisions?

Page 44: introduction of health economics

Why?

• Hard to implement savings: budget silos and other pressures

• Time horizons - lack of long term planning in policy cycles

• Rationing taboo• Interactive• Amount to little incentive to use EE

Page 45: introduction of health economics

• Can increase uncertainty:

There is nothing a government hates more than to be well-informed; for it makes the process of arriving at decisions much more complicated and difficult.

Keynes (quoted in Sharpe 1975)

• Utilitarianism:

Cost-benefit analysis can help you choose different routes to a goal you have agreed, but it cannot help you choose goals. For that we have politics.

Burke (2004)

Page 46: introduction of health economics

Types of economic evaluation

• Cost Minimisation Analysis (CMA)‐• Cost Benefit Analysis (CBA)‐• Cost Effectiveness Analysis (CEA)‐• Cost Utility Analysis (CUA)‐

Page 47: introduction of health economics

Cost minimisation analysis (CMA)‐

• All relevant consequences of alternatives are equivalent• Treatments equally effective• Cost is the only differentiating factor

• Special case of CEA

• Decision rule: least costly option is most efficient implies dominance

• Caution on use– Uncertainty around estimates of effect– Can only evaluate therapies that produce identical outcomes

Page 48: introduction of health economics

Cost Benefit analysis (CBA)‐

• Relates to welfare economics

• All benefits and all costs expressed in monetary terms

• Not used a great deal in health – mainly experimental studies

• Valuing benefits:– Human Capital Approach– Stated preference

• Contingent valuation - WTP

– Revealed preference• Wage-risk studies

Page 49: introduction of health economics

CBA: pros and cons• Pros:

– Broader in scope than CEA/CUA compare with other public sector ‐expenditure

– Broader scope in measuring benefits (eg to carers) – Can assess whether a programme is worthwhile, without reference to

any external standard -> society has already valued health benefit.– More suited for one-off decision making – Addresses both technical and allocative efficiency

• Cons:– Difficulties with valuation of health outcomes in monetary terms

» value of human life can be subject to bias according to income inequity» UK setting, ability to pay difficult to comprehend

Page 50: introduction of health economics

Cost effectiveness analysis (CEA)‐

• Consequences in most appropriate natural or physical units

• Results in terms of cost per unit effect• lives saved/complications avoided/symptom free

days/cancers detected

• Can address technical efficiency

• Decision rule: dominance or CE ratio

Page 51: introduction of health economics

CEA: pros and cons• Pros:

– Clear and easily understood– Common– Popular – Simpler methodology

• Cons:– Cannot address allocative efficiency – Can only compare therapies whose effects are measurable in the same units– Often no obvious main outcome– One-dimensional -> limited consideration of morbidity– There may be significant differences in secondary outcomes– Not preference based– Does not incorporate uncertainty

Page 52: introduction of health economics

Cost utility analysis (CUA)‐

• Outcomes measured in Quality Adjusted Life Years (QALYs) gained (or variant)

• Combines life years and quality of life

• Results in cost per additional QALY gained

• Can be used to compare across treatment areas

• Decision rule: dominance or CU ratio

• Required by decision makers (e.g. NICE)‐

Page 53: introduction of health economics

CUA: pros and cons

• Pros:– Summarises mortality and QoL into a single measure– Comparability with other diseases– Address both technical and allocative efficiency

• Cons:– Can only assess allocative efficiency if all programmes assessed

simultaneously – Cost & effort– Dependent on method/scale used– Decision making must invoke an external criterion of value (NICE

threshold).

Page 54: introduction of health economics

QALY• Combines:

• Length of life• Health-related quality of life

• QALY = Σ(length of life) x (QoL)• QOL – measuring utility:

– HRQOL questionnaire• EQ-5D

– 5 dimensions, 5 items– Mobility, self care, usual activities, pain / discomfort, anxiety / depression

• HUI2– 7 dimensions, 7 items– Sensation, mobility, emotion, self care, cognition, pain, fertility

– Direct valuation• Visual analogue• Standard Gamble• Time trade-off

• QALYs imperfectly reflect individual preferences

Page 55: introduction of health economics

Costing

• Costing Perspective:• Societal • 3rd Party payer

• Types of cost:– Direct costs

• Direct health care costs• Direct non-health care costs

– Indirect (productivity) costs• Indirect health care costs• Indirect non-health care

costs

Page 56: introduction of health economics

A cost-per-QALY league table:Where to draw the line?

Page 57: introduction of health economics

Discounting• A preference for benefits today rather than in the future

• The future is uncertain• Positive economic growth (since WWII) individuals might expect to be more wealthy in the

future

• The process that enables a comparison between the value of a commodity consumed in the future with the value of that same commodity consumed now

• Allowance needs to be made for the differential timing of costs and consequences

• Discounting future costs to present values

• NICE recommendations 2003/2004 :• 3.5% on costs and 3.5% on benefits

Page 58: introduction of health economics

The Incremental approach• An incremental economic evaluation answers the following

question:• ‘What is the difference in costs and the difference in consequences of option A

compared to option B?’

• The incremental cost effectiveness ratio is:‐

ICER = Difference in costs Difference in consequences

– Calculates the cost per extra unit of benefit

Page 59: introduction of health economics

The Cost-Effectiveness Plane

Page 60: introduction of health economics

Dominance

• NW quadrant• alternative is both more costly and less effective than

current (activity dominated)

• SE quadrant• alternative is both more effective and less costly than

current (activity dominates)

• “NW never invest, SE always invest”

Page 61: introduction of health economics

• NE Quadrant– New treatment is both more costly and more effective

than current– How much is society willing to pay (λ)?

• SW Quadrant– the alternative is less costly but less effective than current

treatment– If much less costly but slightly less effective, money saved

could in principle be used to better effect on other patient group

Page 62: introduction of health economics

• NE Quadrant: – Decision rule: if the activity is more effective but higher cost then for

it to be cost-effective the ICER must be less than the ceiling ratio λ– IF λ > ΔC/ΔE, the activity is cost-effective– IF λ < ΔC/ΔE, the activity is not cost-effective

• SW Quadrant:– Decision rule: if the activity is cheaper but less effective then the

decision rule is reversed – IF λ < ΔC/ΔE, the activity is cost-effective– IF λ > ΔC/ΔE, the activity is not cost-effective– Mirror image

Page 63: introduction of health economics

C-E Plane

Page 64: introduction of health economics

The importance of signs!

A negative ICER means dominance

A positive ICER could be in the SW quadrant

Page 65: introduction of health economics

Summary

“We are not defeatist prophets of gloom and doom, obsessed with death and taxes, but active workers for improvement, concerned to improve the quality of people’s lives to the maximum feasible extent. That is why I think that health economics is the cheerful face of the dismal science.”

Alan Williams

Page 66: introduction of health economics

Or are we!