introduction to modern economic growthintroduction to modern economic growth 6.9. taking stock 305...

739
Introduction to Modern Economic Growth Daron Acemoglu Department of Economics, Massachusetts Institute of Technology

Upload: others

Post on 14-Jul-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Introduction to ModernEconomic Growth

    Daron Acemoglu

    Department of Economics,

    Massachusetts Institute of Technology

  • Contents

    Preface xi

    Part 1. Introduction 1

    Chapter 1. Economic Growth and Economic Development:The Questions 3

    1.1. Cross-Country Income Differences 31.2. Income and Welfare 81.3. Economic Growth and Income Differences 111.4. Origins of Today’s Income Differences and World Economic Growth 141.5. Conditional Convergence 191.6. Correlates of Economic Growth 231.7. From Correlates to Fundamental Causes 261.8. The Agenda 291.9. References and Literature 32

    Chapter 2. The Solow Growth Model 372.1. The Economic Environment of the Basic Solow Model 382.2. The Solow Model in Discrete Time 482.3. Transitional Dynamics in the Discrete Time Solow Model 612.4. The Solow Model in Continuous Time 662.5. Transitional Dynamics in the Continuous Time Solow Model 712.6. Solow Model with Technological Progress 792.7. Comparative Dynamics 922.8. Taking Stock 942.9. References and Literature 952.10. Exercises 97

    Chapter 3. The Solow Model and the Data 1033.1. Growth Accounting 1033.2. Solow Model and Regression Analyses 1073.3. The Solow Model with Human Capital 1173.4. Solow Model and Cross-Country Income Differences: Regression

    Analyses 1253.5. Calibrating Productivity Differences 135

    iii

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    3.6. Estimating Productivity Differences 1413.7. Taking Stock 1483.8. References and Literature 1503.9. Exercises 151

    Chapter 4. Fundamental Determinants of Differences in EconomicPerformance 155

    4.1. Proximate Versus Fundamental Causes 1554.2. Economies of Scale, Population, Technology and World Growth 1604.3. The Four Fundamental Causes 1634.4. The Effect of Institutions on Economic Growth 1784.5. What Types of Institutions? 1994.6. Disease and Development 2024.7. Political Economy of Institutions: First Thoughts 2064.8. Taking Stock 2074.9. References and Literature 2084.10. Exercises 211

    Part 2. Towards Neoclassical Growth 213

    Chapter 5. Foundations of Neoclassical Growth 2155.1. Preliminaries 2155.2. The Representative Household 2185.3. Infinite Planning Horizon 2265.4. The Representative Firm 2295.5. Problem Formulation 2325.6. Welfare Theorems 2335.7. Sequential Trading 2415.8. Optimal Growth in Discrete Time 2455.9. Optimal Growth in Continuous Time 2465.10. Taking Stock 2475.11. References and Literature 2485.12. Exercises 250

    Chapter 6. Dynamic Programming and Optimal Growth 2556.1. Brief Review of Dynamic Programming 2566.2. Dynamic Programming Theorems 2606.3. The Contraction Mapping Theorem and Applications* 2666.4. Proofs of the Main Dynamic Programming Theorems* 2726.5. Fundamentals of Dynamic Programming 2806.6. Optimal Growth in Discrete Time 2916.7. Competitive Equilibrium Growth 2976.8. Another Application of Dynamic Programming: Search for Ideas 299

    iv

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    6.9. Taking Stock 3056.10. References and Literature 3066.11. Exercises 307

    Chapter 7. Review of the Theory of Optimal Control 3137.1. Variational Arguments 3147.2. The Maximum Principle: A First Look 3247.3. Infinite-Horizon Optimal Control 3307.4. More on Transversality Conditions 3427.5. Discounted Infinite-Horizon Optimal Control 3457.6. A First Look at Optimal Growth in Continuous Time 3517.7. The q-Theory of Investment 3527.8. Taking Stock 3597.9. References and Literature 3617.10. Exercises 363

    Part 3. Neoclassical Growth 371

    Chapter 8. The Neoclassical Growth Model 3738.1. Preferences, Technology and Demographics 3738.2. Characterization of Equilibrium 3788.3. Optimal Growth 3838.4. Steady-State Equilibrium 3848.5. Transitional Dynamics 3878.6. Technological Change and the Canonical Neoclassical Model 3908.7. Comparative Dynamics 3988.8. The Role of Policy 4008.9. A Quantitative Evaluation 4028.10. Extensions 4058.11. Taking Stock 4068.12. References and Literature 4078.13. Exercises 408

    Chapter 9. Growth with Overlapping Generations 4179.1. Problems of Infinity 4189.2. The Baseline Overlapping Generations Model 4219.3. The Canonical Overlapping Generations Model 4279.4. Overaccumulation and Pareto Optimality of Competitive Equilibrium

    in the Overlapping Generations Model 4299.5. Role of Social Security in Capital Accumulation 4339.6. Overlapping Generations with Impure Altruism 4369.7. Overlapping Generations with Perpetual Youth 4419.8. Overlapping Generations in Continuous Time 445

    v

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    9.9. Taking Stock 4539.10. References and Literature 4559.11. Exercises 456

    Chapter 10. Human Capital and Economic Growth 46310.1. A Simple Separation Theorem 46310.2. Schooling Investments and Returns to Education 46610.3. The Ben Porath Model 46910.4. Neoclassical Growth with Physical and Human Capital 47410.5. Capital-Skill Complementarity in an Overlapping Generations Model 48010.6. Physical and Human Capital with Imperfect Labor Markets 48510.7. Human Capital Externalities 49210.8. Nelson-Phelps Model of Human Capital 49510.9. Taking Stock 49810.10. References and Literature 50010.11. Exercises 502

    Chapter 11. First-Generation Models of Endogenous Growth 50511.1. The AK Model Revisited 50611.2. The AK Model with Physical and Human Capital 51311.3. The Two-Sector AK Model 51611.4. Growth with Externalities 52111.5. Taking Stock 52611.6. References and Literature 52811.7. Exercises 529

    Part 4. Endogenous Technological Change 535

    Chapter 12. Modeling Technological Change 53712.1. Different Conceptions of Technology 53712.2. Science, Profits and the Market Size 54212.3. The Value of Innovation in Partial Equilibrium 54512.4. The Dixit-Stiglitz Model and “Aggregate Demand Externalities” 55512.5. Individual R&D Uncertainty and the Stock Market 56212.6. Taking Stock 56412.7. References and Literature 56512.8. Exercises 567

    Chapter 13. Expanding Variety Models 57113.1. The Lab Equipment Model of Growth with Product Varieties 57213.2. Growth with Knowledge Spillovers 58613.3. Growth without Scale Effects 58913.4. Growth with Expanding Product Varieties 593

    vi

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    13.5. Taking Stock 59813.6. References and Literature 60013.7. Exercises 601

    Chapter 14. Models of Competitive Innovations 60914.1. The Baseline Model of Competitive Innovations 61014.2. A One-Sector Schumpeterian Growth Model 62314.3. Step-by-Step Innovations* 62914.4. Taking Stock 64514.5. References and Literature 64614.6. Exercises 647

    Chapter 15. Directed Technological Change 65515.1. Importance of Biased Technological Change 65615.2. Basics and Definitions 66015.3. Baseline Model of Directed Technological Change 66315.4. Directed Technological Change with Knowledge Spillovers 68115.5. Directed Technological Change without Scale Effects 68615.6. Endogenous Labor-Augmenting Technological Change 68815.7. Other Applications 69215.8. Taking Stock 69315.9. References and Literature 69415.10. Exercises 698

    Part 5. Stochastic Growth 705

    Chapter 16. Stochastic Dynamic Programming 70716.1. Dynamic Programming with Expectations 70716.2. Policy Functions and Transitions 70716.3. Few Technical Details* 70716.4. Applications of Stochastic Dynamic Programming 70716.5. Taking Stock 70716.6. References and Literature 70716.7. Exercises 707

    Chapter 17. Neoclassical Growth Under Uncertainty 70917.1. The Brock-Mirman Model 70917.2. Equilibrium Growth under Uncertainty 71017.3. Application: Real Business Cycle Models 71017.4. Taking Stock 71017.5. References and Literature 71017.6. Exercises 710

    Chapter 18. Growth with Incomplete Markets 711

    vii

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    18.1. The Bewley-Aiyagari Model 71118.2. Risk, Diversification and Growth 71118.3. Taking Stock 71118.4. References and Literature 71118.5. Exercises 711

    Part 6. Technology Diffusion, Trade and Interdependences 713

    Chapter 19. Diffusion of Technology 71519.1. Importance of Technology Adoption and Diffusion 71519.2. A Benchmark Model of Technology Diffusion 71519.3. Human Capital and Technology 71519.4. Technology Diffusion and Endogenous Growth 71619.5. Appropriate Technology and Productivity Differences 71619.6. Inappropriate Technologies 71719.7. Endogenous Technological Change and Appropriate Technology 71819.8. Taking Stock 72319.9. References and Literature 72319.10. Exercises 723

    Chapter 20. Trade, Technology and Interdependences 72520.1. Trade, Specialization and the World Income Distribution 72520.2. Trade, Factor Price Equalization and Economic Growth 73120.3. Trade, Technology Diffusion and the Product Cycle 73220.4. Learning-by-Doing, Trade and Growth 73620.5. Trade and Endogenous Technological Change 73620.6. Taking Stock 73620.7. References and Literature 73620.8. Exercises 736

    Part 7. Economic Development and Economic Growth 737

    Chapter 21. Structural Change and Economic Growth 73921.1. Non-Balanced Growth: The Demand Side 73921.2. Non-Balanced Growth: The Supply Side 74321.3. Structural Change: Migration 74321.4. Structural Change: Transformation of Productive Relationships 74321.5. Towards a Unified Theory of Development and Growth 74321.6. Taking Stock 74321.7. References and Literature 74321.8. Exercises 743

    Chapter 22. Poverty Traps, Inequality and Financial Markets 74522.1. Multiple Equilibria From Aggregate Demand Externalities 745

    viii

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    22.2. Human Capital Accumulation with Imperfect Capital Markets 75422.3. Income Inequality and Economic Development 76122.4. Financial Development and Economic Growth 76122.5. Taking Stock 76122.6. References and Literature 76122.7. Exercises 761

    Chapter 23. Population Growth and the Demographic Transition 76323.1. Patterns of Demographic Changes 76323.2. Population and Growth: Different Perspectives 76323.3. A Simple Model of Demographic Transition 76323.4. Exercises 763

    Part 8. Political Economy of Growth 765

    Chapter 24. Institutions and Growth 76724.1. The Impact of Institutions on Long-Run Development 767

    Chapter 25. Modeling Non-Growth Enhancing Institutions 77725.1. Baseline Model 78125.2. Technology Adoption and Holdup 79525.3. Inefficient Economic Institutions 79825.4. Exercises 802

    Chapter 26. Modeling Political Institutions 80326.1. Understanding Endogenous Political Change 80326.2. Exercises 815

    Part 9. Conclusions 817

    Chapter 27. Putting It All Together: Mechanics and Causes of EconomicGrowth 819

    Chapter 28. Areas of Future Research 821

    Part 10. Mathematical Appendix 823

    Chapter 29. Review of Basic Set Theory 82529.1. Open, Closed, Convex and Compact Sets 82529.2. Sequences, Subsequences and Limits 82529.3. Distance, Norms and Metrics 825

    Chapter 30. Functions of Several Variables 82730.1. Continuous Functions 82730.2. Convexity, Concavity, Quasi-Concavity 827

    ix

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    30.3. Taylor Series 82730.4. Optima and Constrained Optima 82730.5. Intermediate and Mean Value Theorems 82730.6. Inverse and Implicit Function Theorems 827

    Chapter 31. Review of Ordinary Differential Equations 82931.1. Review of Complex Numbers 82931.2. Eigenvalues and Eigenvectors 82931.3. Linear Differential Equations 82931.4. Separable Differential Equations 82931.5. Existence and Uniqueness Theorems 829

    References (highly incomplete) 831

    x

  • Preface

    This book is intended to serve two purposes:

    (1) First and foremost, this is a book about economic growth and long-runeconomic development. The process of economic growth and the sourcesof differences in economic performance across nations are some of the mostinteresting, important and challenging areas in modern social science. Theprimary purpose of this book is to introduce graduate students to thesemajor questions and to the theoretical tools necessary for studying them.The book therefore strives to provide students with a strong backgroundin dynamic economic analysis, since only such a background will enable aserious study of economic growth and economic development. It also triesto provide a clear discussion of the broad empirical patterns and historicalprocesses underlying the current state of the world economy. This is moti-vated by my belief that to understand why some countries grow and somefail to do so, economists have to move beyond the mechanics of models andpose questions about the fundamental causes of economic growth.

    (2) In a somewhat different capacity, this book is also a graduate-level intro-duction to modern macroeconomics and dynamic economic analysis. It issometimes commented that, unlike basic microeconomic theory, there is nocore of current macroeconomic theory that is shared by all economists. Thisis not entirely true. While there is disagreement among macroeconomistsabout how to approach short-run macroeconomic phenomena and what theboundaries of macroeconomics should be, there is broad agreement aboutthe workhorse models of dynamic macroeconomic analysis. These includethe Solow growth model, the neoclassical growth model, the overlapping-generations model and models of technological change and technology adop-tion. Since these are all models of economic growth, a thorough treatmentof modern economic growth can also provide (and perhaps should provide)an introduction to this core material of modern macroeconomics. Althoughthere are several good graduate-level macroeconomic textbooks, they typ-ically spend relatively little time on the basic core material and do notdevelop the links between modern macroeconomic analysis and economicdynamics on the one hand and general equilibrium theory on the other.

    xi

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    In contrast, the current book does not cover any of the short-run top-ics in macroeconomics, but provides a thorough and rigorous introductionto what I view to be the core of macroeconomics. Therefore, the secondpurpose of the book is to provide a first graduate-level course in modernmacroeconomics.

    The topic selection is designed to strike a balance between the two purposesof the book. Chapters 1, 3 and 4 introduce many of the salient features of theprocess of economic growth and the sources of cross-country differences in economicperformance. Even though these chapters cannot do justice to the large literatureon economic growth empirics, they provide a sufficient background for students toappreciate the set of issues that are central to the study of economic growth andalso a platform for a further study of this large literature.Chapters 5-7 provide the conceptual and mathematical foundations of modern

    macroeconomic analysis. Chapter 5 provides the microfoundations for much of therest of the book (and for much of modern macroeconomics), while Chapters 6 and7 provide a quick but relatively rigorous introduction to dynamic optimization.Most books on macroeconomics or economic growth use either continuous time ordiscrete time exclusively. I believe that a serious study of both economic growth andmodern macroeconomics requires the student (and the researcher) to be able to gobetween discrete and continuous time and choose whichever one is more convenientor appropriate for the set of questions at hand. Therefore, I have deviated from thisstandard practice and included both continuous time and discrete time materialthroughout the book.Chapters 2, 8, 9 and 10 introduce the basic workhorse models of modern macroe-

    conomics and traditional economic growth, while Chapter 11 presents the first gen-eration models of sustained (endogenous) economic growth. Chapters 12-15 covermodels of technological progress, which are an essential part of any modern economicgrowth course.Chapter 16 generalizes the tools introduced in Chapter 6 to stochastic envi-

    ronments. Using these tools, Chapter 17 presents the canonical stochastic growthmodel, which is the foundation of much of modern macroeconomics (though it isoften left out of economic growth courses). This chapter also includes a discus-sion of the canonical Real Business Cycle model. Chapter 18 covers another majorworkhorse model of modern macroeconomics, the neoclassical growth model withincomplete markets. As well as the famous Bewley-Aiyagari model, this chapter dis-cusses a number of other approaches to modeling the interaction between incompletemarkets and economic growth.Chapters 19-23 cover a range of topics that are sometimes left out of economic

    growth textbooks. These include models of technology adoption, technology diffu-sion, appropriate technology, interaction between international trade and technol-ogy, structural change, poverty traps, inequality, and population growth. These

    xii

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    topics are important for creating a bridge between the empirical patterns we ob-serve in practice and the theory. Most traditional growth models consider a singleeconomy in isolation and often after it has already embarked upon a process ofsteady economic growth. A study of models that incorporate cross-country inter-dependences, structural change and the possibility of takeoffs will enable us to linkcore topics of development economics, such as structural change, poverty traps orthe demographic transition, to the theory of economic growth.Finally, Chapters 24-26 consider another topic often omitted from macroeco-

    nomics and economic growth textbooks; political economy. This is motivated bythe belief that the study of economic growth would be seriously hampered if wefailed to ask questions about the fundamental causes of why countries differ intheir economic performances. These questions invariably bring us to differences ineconomic policies and institutions across nations. Political economy enables us todevelop models to understand why economic policies and institutions differ acrosscountries and must therefore be an integral part of the study of economic growth.

    A few words on the philosophy and organization of the book might also beuseful for students and teachers. The underlying philosophy of the book is that allthe results that are stated should be proved or at least explained in detail. Thisimplies a somewhat different organization than existing books. Most textbooks ineconomics do not provide proofs for many of the results that are stated or invoked,and mathematical tools that are essential for the analysis are often taken for grantedor developed in appendices. In contrast, I have strived to provide simple proofs ofalmost all results stated in this book. It turns out that once unnecessary generalityis removed, most results can be stated and proved in a way that is easily accessibleto graduate students. In fact, I believe that even somewhat long proofs are mucheasier to understand than general statements made without proof, which leave thereader wondering about why these statements are true.I hope that the style I have chosen not only makes the book self-contained, but

    also gives the students an opportunity to develop a thorough understanding of thematerial. In addition, I present the basic mathematical tools necessary for analy-sis within the main body of the text. My own experience suggests that a “linear”progression, where the necessary mathematical tools are introduced when needed,makes it easier for the students to follow and appreciate the material. Consequently,analysis of stability of dynamical systems, dynamic programming in discrete timeand optimal control in continuous time are all introduced within the main body ofthe text. This should both help the students appreciate the foundations of thetheory of economic growth and also provide them with an introduction to the maintools of dynamic economic analysis, which are increasingly used in every subdisci-pline of economics. Throughout, when some material is technically more difficultand can be skipped without loss of continuity, it is clearly marked with a “*”. The

    xiii

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    only material that is left for the Mathematical Appendix are those that should be fa-miliar to most graduate students. Therefore the Mathematical Appendix is includedmostly for reference and completeness.I have also included a large number of exercises. Students can only gain a

    thorough understanding of the material by working through the exercises. Theexercises that are somewhat more difficult are also marked with a “*”.

    This book can be used in a number of different ways. First, it can be used in aone-quarter or one-semester course on economic growth. Such a course might startwith Chapters 1-4, then use Chapters 5-7 either for a thorough study or only forreference. Chapters 8-11 cover the traditional growth theory. Then Chapters 12-15can be used for endogenous growth theory. Depending on time and interest, anyselection of Chapters 18 and 19-26 can be used for the last part of such a course.Second, the book can be used for a one-quarter first-year graduate-level course

    in macroeconomics. In this case, Chapter 1 is optional. Chapters 8, 3, 5-7, 8-11 and16-18 would be the core of such a course. The same material could also be coveredin a one-semester course, but in this case, it could be supplemented either withsome of the later chapters or with material from one of the leading graduate-levelmacroeconomic textbooks on short-run macroeconomics, fiscal policy, asset pricing,or other topics in dynamic macroeconomics.Third, the book can be used for an advanced (second-year) course in economic

    growth or economic development. An advanced course on growth or developmentcould use Chapters 1-11 as background and then focus on selected chapters fromChapters 19-26.Finally, since the book is self-contained, I also hope that it can be used for

    self-study.

    Acknowledgments. This book grew out of the first graduate-level introduc-tion to macroeconomics course I have taught at MIT. Parts of the book have alsobeen taught as part of a second-year graduate macroeconomics course. I would liketo thank the students who have sat through these lectures and made commentsthat have improved the manuscript. I owe a special thanks to Monica Martinez-Bravo, Samuel Pienknagura, Lucia Tian Tian and especially Alp Simsek for out-standing research assistance, to Lauren Fahey for editorial suggestions, and to PolAntras, George-Marios Angeletos, Olivier Blanchard, Simon Johnson, Chad Jones,and James Robinson for suggestions on individual chapters.

    Please note that this is a very preliminary draft of the bookmanuscript. Comments are welcome.Version 1.1: April 2007

    xiv

  • Part 1

    Introduction

  • We start with a quick look at the stylized facts of economic growth and the most

    basic model of growth, the Solow growth model. The purpose is both to prepare us

    for the analysis of more modern models of economic growth with forward-looking

    behavior, explicit capital accumulation and endogenous technological progress, and

    also to give us a way of mapping the simplest model to data. We will also dis-

    cuss differences between proximate and fundamental causes of economic growth and

    economic development.

  • CHAPTER 1

    Economic Growth and Economic Development:The Questions

    1.1. Cross-Country Income Differences

    There are very large differences in income per capita and output per worker

    across countries today. Countries at the top of the world income distribution are

    more than thirty times as rich as those at the bottom. For example, in 2000, GDP

    (or income) per capita in the United States was over $33000. In contrast, income per

    capita is much lower in many other countries: less than $9000 in Mexico, less than

    $4000 in China, less than $2500 in India, and only about $700 in Nigeria, and much

    much lower in some other sub-Saharan African countries such as Chad, Ethiopia,

    and Mali. These numbers are all at 1996 US dollars and are adjusted for purchasing

    power party (PPP) to allow for differences in relative prices of different goods across

    countries. The gap is larger when there is no PPP-adjustment (see below).

    We can catch a glimpse of these differences in Figure 1.1, which plots estimates of

    the distribution of PPP-adjusted GDP per capita across the available set of countries

    in 1960, 1980 and 2000. The numbers refer to 1996 US dollars and are obtained

    from the Penn World tables compiled by Summers and Heston, the standard source

    of data for post-war cross-country comparisons of income or worker per capita. A

    number of features are worth noting. First, the 1960 density shows that 15 years

    after the end of World War II, most countries had income per capita less than $1500

    (in 1996 US dollars); the mode of the distribution is around $1250. The rightwards

    shift of the distributions for 1980 and for 2000 shows the growth of average income

    per capita for the next 40 years. In 2000, the mode is still slightly above $3000, but

    now there is another concentration of countries between $20,000 and $30,000. The

    density estimate for the year 2000 shows the considerable inequality in income per

    capita today.

    3

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    1960

    19802000

    0.0

    0005

    .000

    1.0

    0015

    .000

    2.0

    0025

    Den

    sity

    of c

    outri

    es

    0 10000 20000 30000 40000 50000gdp per capita

    Figure 1.1. Estimates of the distribution of countries according toPPP-adjusted GDP per capita in 1960, 1980 and 2000.

    Part of the spreading out of the distribution in Figure 1.1 is because of the

    increase in average incomes. It may therefore be more informative to look at the

    logarithm of income per capita. It is more natural to look at the logarithm (log) of

    variables, such as income per capita, that grow over time, especially when growth is

    approximately proportional (e.g., at about 2% per year for US GDP per capita; see

    Figure 1.8). Figure 1.2 shows a similar pattern, but now the spreading-out is more

    limited. This reflects the fact that while the absolute gap between rich and poor

    countries has increased considerably between 1960 and 2000, the proportional gap

    has increased much less. Nevertheless, it can be seen that the 2000 density for log

    GDP per capita is still more spread out than the 1960 density. In particular, both

    figures show that there has been a considerable increase in the density of relatively

    rich countries, while many countries still remain quite poor. This last pattern is

    sometimes referred to as the “stratification phenomenon”, corresponding to the fact

    4

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    1960

    1980

    2000

    0.1

    .2.3

    .4D

    ensi

    ty o

    f cou

    tries

    6 7 8 9 10 11log gdp per capita

    Figure 1.2. Estimates of the distribution of countries according tolog GDP per capita (PPP-adjusted) in 1960, 1980 and 2000.

    that some of the middle-income countries of the 1960s have joined the ranks of

    relatively high-income countries, while others have maintained their middle-income

    status or even experienced relative impoverishment.

    While Figures 1.1 and 1.2 show that there is somewhat greater inequality among

    nations, an equally relevant concept might be inequality among individuals in the

    world economy. Figures 1.1 and 1.2 are not directly informative on this, since they

    treat each country identically irrespective of the size of their population. The alter-

    native is presented in Figure 1.3, which shows the population-weighted distribution.

    In this case, countries such as China, India, the United States and Russia receive

    greater weight because they have larger populations. The picture that emerges in

    this case is quite different. In fact, the 2000 distribution looks less spread-out, with

    thinner left tail than the 1960 distribution. This reflects the fact that in 1960 China

    and India were among the poorest nations, whereas their relatively rapid growth in

    5

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    1960

    19802000

    01.

    000e

    +09

    2.00

    0e+0

    93.

    000e

    +09

    D

    ensi

    ty o

    f cou

    tries

    wei

    ghte

    d by

    pop

    ulat

    ion

    6 7 8 9 10 11log gdp per capita

    Figure 1.3. Estimates of the population-weighted distribution ofcountries according to log GDP per capita (PPP-adjusted) in 1960,1980 and 2000.

    the 1990s puts them into the middle-poor category by 2000. Chinese and Indian

    growth has therefore created a powerful force towards relative equalization of income

    per capita among the inhabitants of the globe.

    Figures 1.1, 1.2 and 1.3 look at the distribution of GDP per capita. While this

    measure is relevant for the welfare of the population, much of growth theory will

    focus on the productive capacity of countries. Theory is therefore easier to map to

    data when we look at output per worker (GDP per worker). Moreover, as we will

    discuss in greater detail later, key sources of difference in economic performance

    across countries include national policies and institutions. This suggests that when

    our interest is understanding the sources of differences in income and growth across

    countries (as opposed to assessing welfare questions), the unweighted distribution

    may be more relevant than the population-weighted distribution. Consequently,

    6

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    1960

    1980

    2000

    0.1

    .2.3

    .4D

    ensi

    ty o

    f cou

    tries

    6 8 10 12log gdp per worker

    Figure 1.4. Estimates of the distribution of countries according tolog GDP per worker (PPP-adjusted) in 1960, 1980 and 2000.

    Figure 1.4 looks at the unweighted distribution of countries according to (PPP-

    adjusted) GDP per worker. Since internationally comparable data on employment

    are not available for a large number of countries, “workers” here refer to the to-

    tal economically active population (according to the definition of the International

    Labour Organization). Figure 1.4 is very similar to Figure 1.2, and if anything,

    shows a bigger concentration of countries in the relatively rich tail by 2000, with

    the poor tail remaining more or less the same as in Figure 1.2.

    Overall, Figures 1.1-1.4 document two important facts: first, there is a large

    inequality in income per capita and income per worker across countries as shown by

    the highly dispersed distributions. Second, there is a slight but noticeable increase

    in inequality across nations (though not necessarily across individuals in the world

    economy).

    7

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    ESP

    TJK

    MDG

    TZA

    ECU

    ARG

    TUN

    MAC

    BFA

    LUX

    HKG

    BOL

    LCA

    IRN

    URY

    MYSPER

    FRA

    MWI

    ETH

    RWATCD

    ZAF

    GHA

    BLZ

    PAN

    NOR

    GTMMAR

    COL

    CAN

    MDA

    KNA

    NZL

    DZA

    KAZATG

    LVA

    ZMB

    GEO

    SEN

    AUTGBR

    CIV

    SLVVCT

    MKD

    GNQ

    CHN

    EGY

    HND

    BEN

    SYCKOR

    BGR

    FIN

    TGO

    LBN

    NER

    GAB

    CRI

    TTOMUS

    USA

    BRB CHE

    GMB

    ZWE

    GRD

    HRVRUS

    GER

    SVK

    BDI

    COM

    PRY

    MEXCHL

    IRL

    IDNARM

    BLR

    PRT

    KGZ

    BEL

    ROM

    NLD

    GRC

    BGD

    CZE

    POL

    CPVDMA

    ALBUKR

    NIC

    NGA

    VEN

    LKAGIN

    COG

    THA

    ISLAUS

    LSO

    CMR

    DOM

    PAK

    SWZ

    PHL

    BRA

    NPLKEN

    YEM

    JPN

    STP

    HUN

    IND

    EST

    DNK

    MLI

    GNB

    SYR

    ITA

    JAM

    MOZ

    TUR

    SWEISR

    LTU

    SVN

    JOR

    AZE

    UGA

    56

    78

    910

    log

    cons

    umpt

    ion

    per c

    apita

    200

    0

    6 7 8 9 10 11log gdp per capita 2000

    Figure 1.5. The association between income per capita and con-sumption per capita in 2000.

    1.2. Income and Welfare

    Should we care about cross-country income differences? The answer is undoubt-

    edly yes. High income levels reflect high standards of living. Economic growth

    might, at least over some range, increase pollution or raise individual aspirations, so

    that the same bundle of consumption may no longer make an individual as happy.

    But at the end of the day, when one compares an advanced, rich country with a

    less-developed one, there are striking differences in the quality of life, standards of

    living and health.

    Figures 1.5 and 1.6 give a glimpse of these differences and depict the relationship

    between income per capita in 2000 and consumption per capita and life expectancy

    at birth in the same year. Consumption data also come from the Penn World

    8

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    ALB ARG

    ARM

    AUSAUT

    AZE

    BDI

    BEL

    BEN

    BFA

    BGD

    BGR

    BLR

    BLZ

    BOL

    BRA

    BRB

    CANCHE

    CHL

    CHN

    CIVCMR

    COG

    COL

    COM

    CPV

    CRI

    CZEDNK

    DOM

    DZA

    ECU

    EGY

    ESP

    EST

    FINFRA

    GAB

    GBR

    GEO

    GHA

    GINGMB

    GNBGNQ

    GRC

    GTM

    HKG

    HND

    HRV

    HUN

    IDN

    IND

    IRL

    IRN

    ISLISR ITA

    JAMJOR

    JPN

    KAZ

    KEN

    KGZ

    KOR

    LBNLCA

    LKA

    LSO

    LTU

    LUX

    LVA

    MAC

    MARMDA

    MDG

    MEXMKD

    MLI

    MOZ

    MUS

    MWI

    MYS

    NERNGA

    NIC

    NLDNOR

    NPL

    NZL

    PAK

    PAN

    PERPHL

    POL

    PRT

    PRYROM

    RUS

    RWA

    SEN

    SLV

    SVKSVN

    SWE

    SWZ

    SYR

    TCD

    TGO

    THA

    TJK

    TTOTUN

    TUR

    TZA

    UGA

    UKR

    URY

    USA

    VCTVEN

    YEM ZAF

    ZMB

    ZWE

    ETH

    4050

    6070

    8090

    life

    expe

    ctan

    cy 2

    000

    6 7 8 9 10 11log gdp per capita 2000

    Figure 1.6. The association between income per capita and life ex-pectancy at birth in 2000.

    tables, while data on life expectancy at birth are available from the World Bank

    Development Indicators.

    These figures document that income per capita differences are strongly associ-

    ated with differences in consumption (thus likely associated with differences in living

    standards) and health as measured by life expectancy. Recall also that these num-

    bers refer to PPP-adjusted quantities, thus differences in consumption do not (at

    least in principle) reflect the fact that the same bundle of consumption goods costs

    different amounts in different countries. The PPP adjustment corrects for these

    differences and attempts to measure the variation in real consumption. Therefore,

    the richest countries are not only producing more than thirty-fold as much as the

    poorest countries, but they are also consuming thirty-fold as much. Similarly, cross-

    country differences in health are nothing short of striking; while life expectancy at

    9

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    birth is as high as 80 in the richest countries, it is only between 40 and 50 in many

    sub-Saharan African nations. These gaps represent huge welfare differences.

    Understanding how some countries can be so rich while some others are so poor

    is one of the most important, perhaps the most important, challenges facing social

    science. It is important both because these income differences have major welfare

    consequences and because a study of such striking differences will shed light on how

    economies of different nations are organized, how they function and sometimes how

    they fail to function.

    The emphasis on income differences across countries does not imply, however,

    that income per capita can be used as a “sufficient statistic” for the welfare of the

    average citizen or that it is the only feature that we should care about. As we will

    discuss in detail later, the efficiency properties of the market economy (such as the

    celebrated First Welfare Theorem or Adam Smith’s invisible hand) do not imply

    that there is no conflict among individuals or groups in society. Economic growth is

    generally good for welfare, but it often creates “winners” and “losers.” And major

    idea in economics, Joseph Schumpeter’s creative destruction, emphasizes precisely

    this aspect of economic growth; productive relationships, firms and sometimes indi-

    vidual livelihoods will often be destroyed by the process of economic growth. This

    creates a natural tension in society even when it is growing. One of the important

    lessons of political economy analyses of economic growth, which will be discussed in

    the last part of the book, concerns how institutions and policies can be arranged so

    that those who lose out from the process of economic growth can be compensated

    or perhaps prevented from blocking economic progress.

    A stark illustration of the fact that growth does not mean increase in the liv-

    ing standards of all or most citizens in a society comes from South Africa under

    apartheid. Available data illustrate that from the beginning of the 20th century un-

    til the fall of the apartheid regime, GDP per capita grew considerably, but the real

    wages of black South Africans, who make up the majority of the population, fell dur-

    ing this period. This of course does not imply that economic growth in South Africa

    was not beneficial. South Africa still has one of the best economic performances in

    sub-Saharan Africa. Nevertheless, it alerts us to other aspects of the economy and

    also underlines the potential conflicts inherent in the growth process. These aspects

    10

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    1960

    1980

    2000

    05

    1015

    20D

    ensi

    ty o

    f cou

    tries

    -.1 -.05 0 .05 .1average growth rates

    Figure 1.7. Estimates of the distribution of countries according tothe growth rate of GDP per worker (PPP-adjusted) in 1960, 1980 and2000.

    are not only interesting in and of themselves, but they also inform us about why

    certain segments of the society may be in favor of policies and institutions that do

    not encourage growth.

    1.3. Economic Growth and Income Differences

    How could one country be more than thirty times richer than another? The

    answer lies in differences in growth rates. Take two countries, A and B, with the

    same initial level of income at some date. Imagine that country A has 0% growth

    per capita, so its income per capita remains constant, while country B grows at 2%

    per capita. In 200 years’ time country B will be more than 52 times richer than

    country A. Therefore, the United States is considerably richer than Nigeria because

    it has grown steadily over an extended period of time, while Nigeria has not (and

    11

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    SpainSouth Korea

    India

    Brazil

    USA

    Singapore

    Nigeria

    Guatemala

    UK

    Botswana

    67

    89

    10lo

    g gd

    p pe

    r cap

    ita

    1960 1970 1980 1990 2000year

    Figure 1.8. The evolution of income per capita in the United States,United Kingdom, Spain, Singapore, Brazil, Guatemala, South Korea,Botswana, Nigeria and India, 1960-2000.

    we will see that there is a lot of truth to this simple calculation; see Figures 1.8,

    1.11 and 1.13).

    In fact, even in the historically-brief postwar era, we see tremendous differences

    in growth rates across countries. This is shown in Figure 1.7 for the postwar era,

    which plots the density of growth rates across countries in 1960, 1980 and 2000. The

    growth rate in 1960 refers to the (geometric) average of the growth rate between

    1950 and 1969, the growth rate in 1980 refers to the average growth rate between

    1970 and 1989 and 2000 refers to the average between 1990 and 2000 (in all cases

    subject to data availability; all data from Penn World tables). Figure 1.7 shows

    that in each time interval, there is considerable variability in growth rates; the

    cross-country distribution stretches from negative growth rates to average growth

    rates as high as 10% a year.

    12

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    Figure 1.8 provides another look at these patterns by plotting log GDP per capita

    for a number of countries between 1960 and 2000 (in this case, we look at GDP per

    capita instead of GDP per worker both for data coverage and also to make the

    figures more comparable to the historical figures we will look at below). At the top

    of the figure, we see the US and the UK GDP per capita increasing at a steady pace,

    with a slightly faster growth for the United States, so that the log (“proportional”)

    gap between the two countries is larger in 2000 than it is in 1960. Spain starts

    much poorer than the United States and the UK in 1960, but grows very rapidly

    between 1960 and the mid-1970s, thus closing the gap between itself and the United

    States and the UK. The three countries that show very rapid growth in this figure

    are Singapore, South Korea and Botswana. Singapore starts much poorer than the

    UK and Spain in 1960, but grows very rapidly and by the mid-1990s it has become

    richer than both (as well as all other countries in this picture except the United

    States). South Korea has a similar trajectory, but starts out poorer than Singapore

    and grows slightly less rapidly overall, so that by the end of the sample it is still

    a little poorer than Spain. The other country that has grown very rapidly is the

    “African success story” Botswana, which was extremely poor at the beginning of

    the sample. Its rapid growth, especially after 1970, has taken Botswana to the ranks

    of the middle-income countries by 2000.

    The two Latin American countries in this picture, Brazil and Guatemala, il-

    lustrate the often-discussed Latin American economic malaise of the postwar era.

    Brazil starts out richer than Singapore, South Korea and Botswana, and has a rela-

    tively rapid growth rate between 1960 and 1980. But it experiences stagnation from

    1980 onwards, so that by the end of the sample all three of these countries have

    become richer than Brazil. Guatemala’s experience is similar, but even more bleak.

    Contrary to Brazil, there is little growth in Guatemala between 1960 and 1980, and

    no growth between 1980 and 2000.

    Finally, Nigeria and India start out at similar levels of income per capita as

    Botswana, but experience little growth until the 1980s. Starting in 1980, the Indian

    economy experiences relatively rapid growth, but this has not been sufficient for

    its income per capita to catch up with the other nations in the figure. Nigeria, on

    the other hand, in a pattern all-too-familiar in sub-Saharan Africa, experiences a

    13

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    contraction of its GDP per capita, so that in 2000 it is in fact poorer than it was in

    1960.

    The patterns shown in Figure 1.8 are what we would like to understand and

    explain. Why is the United States richer in 1960 than other nations and able to grow

    at a steady pace thereafter? How did Singapore, South Korea and Botswana manage

    to grow at a relatively rapid pace for 40 years? Why did Spain grow relatively rapidly

    for about 20 years, but then slow down? Why did Brazil and Guatemala stagnate

    during the 1980s? What is responsible for the disastrous growth performance of

    Nigeria?

    1.4. Origins of Today’s Income Differences and World Economic Growth

    These growth-rates differences shown in Figures 1.7 and 1.8 are interesting in

    their own right and could also be, in principle, responsible for the large differences

    in income per capita we observe today. But are they? The answer is No. Figure 1.8

    shows that in 1960 there was already a very large gap between the United States on

    the one hand and India and Nigeria on the other. In fact some of the fastest-growing

    countries such as South Korea and Botswana started out relatively poor in 1960.

    This can be seen more easily in Figure 1.9, which plots log GDP per worker in

    2000 versus GDP per capita in 1960, together with the 45◦ line. Most observations

    are around the 45◦ line, indicating that the relative ranking of countries has changed

    little between 1960 and 2000. Thus the origins of the very large income differences

    across nations are not to be found in the postwar era. There are striking growth

    differences during the postwar era, but the evidence presented so far suggests that

    the “world income distribution” has been more or less stable, with a slight tendency

    towards becoming more unequal.

    If not in the postwar era, when did this growth gap emerge? The answer is that

    much of the divergence took place during the 19th century and early 20th century.

    Figures 1.10, 1.11 and 1.13 give a glimpse of these 19th-century developments by

    using the data compiled by Angus Maddison for GDP per capita differences across

    nations going back to 1820 (or sometimes earlier). These data are less reliable than

    Summers-Heston’s Penn World tables, since they do not come from standardized

    national accounts. Moreover, the sample is more limited and does not include

    14

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    ARG

    AUSAUT

    BDI

    BEL

    BENBFA

    BGD BOL

    BRA

    BRB

    CANCHE

    CHL

    CHN

    CIVCMR

    COG

    COL

    COM

    CPV

    CRI

    DNK

    DOM

    ECU

    EGY

    ESP

    ETH

    FINFRA

    GAB

    GBR

    GHA

    GIN

    GMB

    GNB

    GRC

    GTM

    HKG

    HND

    IDN

    IND

    IRL

    IRN

    ISLISRITA

    JAM

    JOR

    JPN

    KEN

    KOR

    LKA

    LSO

    LUX

    MAR

    MDG

    MEX

    MLIMOZ

    MUS

    MWI

    MYS

    NERNGA

    NIC

    NLDNOR

    NPL

    NZL

    PAK

    PAN

    PERPHL

    PRT

    PRYROM

    RWA

    SEN

    SLV

    SWE

    SYC

    SYR

    TCDTGO

    THA

    TTO

    TUR

    TZA

    UGA

    URY

    USA

    VENZAF

    ZMB

    ZWE

    78

    910

    1112

    log

    gdp

    per w

    orke

    r 200

    0

    6 7 8 9 10log gdp per worker 1960

    Figure 1.9. Log GDP per worker in 2000 versus log GDP per workerin 1960, together with the 45◦ line.

    observations for all countries going back to 1820. Finally, while these data do

    include a correction for PPP, this is less reliable than the price comparisons used

    to construct the price indices in the Penn World tables. Nevertheless, these are the

    best available estimates for differences in prosperity across a large number of nations

    going back to the 19th century.

    Figures 1.10 shows the estimates of the distribution of countries by GDP per

    capita in 1820, 1913 (right before World War I) and 2000. To facilitate comparison,

    the same set of countries are used to construct the distribution of income in each

    date. The distribution of income per capita in 1820 is relatively equal, with a very

    small left tail and a somewhat larger but still small right tail. In contrast, by 1913,

    there is considerably more weight in the tails of the distribution. By 2000, there are

    much larger differences.

    15

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    1820

    19132000

    0.5

    11.

    5D

    ensi

    ty o

    f cou

    tries

    4 6 8 10 12log gdp per capita

    Figure 1.10. Estimates of the distribution of countries according tolog GDP per capita in 1820, 1913 and 2000.

    Figure 1.11 also illustrates the divergence; it depicts the evolution of average

    income in five groups of countries, Western Offshoots of Europe (the United States,

    Canada, Australia and New Zealand), Western Europe, Latin America, Asia and

    Africa. It shows the relatively rapid growth of the Western Offshoots and West Eu-

    ropean countries during the 19th century, while Asia and Africa remained stagnant

    and Latin America showed little growth. The relatively small income gaps in 1820

    become much larger by 2000.

    Another major macroeconomic fact is visible in Figure 1.11: Western Offshoots

    and West European nations experience a noticeable dip in GDP per capita around

    1929, because of the Great Depression. Western offshoots, in particular the United

    States, only recover fully from this large recession just before WWII. How an econ-

    omy can experience such a sharp decline in output and how it recovers from such a

    16

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    Western Offshoots

    Western Europe

    AfricaLatin America

    Asia

    67

    89

    10lo

    g gd

    p pe

    r cap

    ita

    1800 1850 1900 1950 2000year

    Figure 1.11. The evolution of average GDP per capita in WesternOffshoots, Western Europe, Latin America, Asia and Africa, 1820-2000.

    shock are among the major questions of macroeconomics. While the Great Depres-

    sion falls outside the scope of the current book, we will later discuss the relationship

    between economic crises and economic growth as well as potential sources of eco-

    nomic volatility.

    A variety of other evidence suggest that differences in income per capita were

    even smaller once we go back further than 1820. Maddison also has estimates for

    average income per capita for the same groups of countries going back to 1000 AD or

    even earlier. We extend Figure 1.11 using these data; the results are shown in Figure

    1.12. While these numbers are based on scattered evidence and guesses, the general

    pattern is consistent with qualitative historical evidence and the fact that income

    per capita in any country cannot have been much less than $500 in terms of 2000

    US dollars, since individuals could not survive with real incomes much less than this

    17

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    level. Figure 1.12 shows that as we go further back, the gap among countries becomes

    much smaller. This further emphasizes that the big divergence among countries has

    taken place over the past 200 years or so. Another noteworthy feature that becomes

    apparent from this figure is the remarkable nature of world economic growth. Much

    evidence suggests that there was little economic growth before the 18th century and

    certainly almost none before the 15th century. Maddison’s estimates show a slow

    but steady increase in West European GDP per capita between 1000 and 1800. This

    view is not shared by all historians and economic historians, many of whom estimate

    that there was little increase in income per capita before 1500 or even before 1800.

    For our purposes however, this is not central. What is important is that starting in

    the 19th, or perhaps in the late 18th century, the process of rapid economic growth

    takes off in Western Europe and among the Western Offshoots, while many other

    parts of the world do not experience the same sustained economic growth. We owe

    our high levels of income today to this process of sustained economic growth, and

    Figure 1.12 shows that it is also this process of economic growth that has caused

    the divergence among nations.

    Figure 1.13 shows the evolution of income per capita for United States, Britain,

    Spain, Brazil, China, India and Ghana. This figure confirms the patterns shown in

    Figure 1.11 for averages, with the United States Britain and Spain growing much

    faster than India and Ghana throughout, and also much faster than Brazil and

    China except during the growth spurts experienced by these two countries.

    Overall, on the basis of the available information we can conclude that the ori-

    gins of the current cross-country differences in economic performance in income

    per capita formed during the 19th century and early 20th century (perhaps during

    the late 18th century). This divergence took place at the same time as a number

    of countries in the world started the process of modern and sustained economic

    growth. Therefore understanding modern economic growth is not only interesting

    and important in its own right, but it also holds the key to understanding the causes

    of cross-country differences in income per capita today.

    18

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    Western Offshoots

    Western Europe

    Africa

    LatinAmerica

    Asia

    67

    89

    10lo

    g gd

    p pe

    r cap

    ita

    1000 1200 1400 1600 1800 2000year

    Figure 1.12. The evolution of average GDP per capita in WesternOffshoots, Western Europe, Latin America, Asia and Africa, 1000-2000.

    1.5. Conditional Convergence

    We have so far documented the large differences in income per capita across

    nations, the slight divergence in economic fortunes over the postwar era and the

    much larger divergence since the early 1800s. The analysis focused on the “uncondi-

    tional” distribution of income per capita (or per worker). In particular, we looked at

    whether the income gap between two countries increases or decreases irrespective of

    these countries’ “characteristics” (e.g., institutions, policies, technology or even in-

    vestments). Alternatively, we can look at the “conditional” distribution (e.g., Barro

    and Sala-i-Martin, 1992). Here the question is whether the economic gap between

    two countries that are similar in observable characteristics is becoming narrower or

    wider over time. When we look at the conditional distribution of income per capita

    across countries the picture that emerges is one of conditional convergence: in the

    19

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    USA

    Britain

    Spain

    Ghana

    Brazil

    China

    India

    67

    89

    10lo

    g gd

    p pe

    r cap

    ita

    1800 1850 1900 1950 2000year

    Figure 1.13. The evolution of income per capita in the UnitedStates, Britain, Spain, Brazil, China, India and Ghana, 1820-2000.

    postwar period, the income gap between countries that share the same character-

    istics typically closes over time (though it does so quite slowly). This is important

    both for understanding the statistical properties of the world income distribution

    and also as an input into the types of theories that we would like to develop.

    How do we capture conditional convergence? Consider a typical “Barro growth

    regression”:

    (1.1) gt,t−1 = β ln yt−1 +X0t−1α+ εt

    where gt,t−1 is the annual growth rate between dates t− 1 and t, yt−1 is output perworker (or income per capita) at date t−1, and Xt−1 is a vector of variables that theregression is conditioning on with coefficient vector α These variables are included

    because they are potential determinants of steady state income and/or growth. First

    note that without covariates equation (1.1) is quite similar to the relationship shown

    20

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    in Figure 1.9 above. In particular, since gt,t−1 ' ln yt − ln yt−1, equation (1.1) canbe written as

    ln yt ' (1 + β) ln yt−1 + εt.

    Figure 1.9 showed that the relationship between log GDP per worker in 2000 and

    log GDP per worker in 1960 can be approximated by the 45◦ line, so that in terms

    of this equation, β should be approximately equal to 0. This is confirmed by Figure

    1.14, which depicts the relationship between the (geometric) average growth rate

    between 1960 and 2000 and log GDP per worker in 1960. This figure reiterates

    that there is no “unconditional” convergence for the entire world over the postwar

    period.

    ARG

    AUS

    AUT

    BDI

    BEL

    BEN

    BFA

    BGD

    BOL

    BRA

    BRB

    CAN

    CHE

    CHL

    CHN

    CIV

    CMR

    COG

    COL

    COM

    CPV

    CRI

    DNK

    DOM

    ECU

    EGY

    ESP

    ETH

    FINFRA

    GAB

    GBR

    GHAGIN

    GMB

    GNB

    GRC

    GTM

    HKG

    HND

    IDN

    IND

    IRL

    IRN ISL

    ISR

    ITA

    JAM

    JOR

    JPN

    KEN

    KOR

    LKALSO

    LUX

    MAR

    MDG

    MEX

    MLIMOZ

    MUS

    MWI

    MYS

    NERNGA NIC

    NLD

    NOR

    NPL

    NZL

    PAK

    PAN

    PER

    PHL

    PRT

    PRY

    ROM

    RWA

    SEN

    SLV

    SWE

    SYC

    SYR

    TCD

    TGO

    THA

    TTO

    TUR

    TZA

    UGA

    URY

    USA

    VEN

    ZAF

    ZMB

    ZWE

    -.02

    0.0

    2.0

    4.0

    6an

    nual

    gro

    wth

    rate

    196

    0-20

    00

    6 7 8 9 10log gdp per worker 1960

    Figure 1.14. Annual growth rate of GDP per worker between 1960and 2000 versus log GDP per worker in 1960 for the entire world.

    21

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    While there is no convergence for the entire world, when we look among the

    “OECD” nations,1 we see a different pattern. Figure 1.15 shows that there is a

    strong negative relationship between log GDP per worker in 1960 and the annual

    growth rate between 1960 and 2000 among the OECD countries. What distinguishes

    this sample from the entire world sample is the relative homogeneity of the OECD

    countries, which have much more similar institutions, policies and initial conditions

    than the entire world. This suggests that there might be a type of conditional

    convergence when we control for certain country characteristics potentially affecting

    economic growth.

    AUS

    AUT

    BEL

    CAN

    CHE

    DNK

    ESP

    FIN

    FRA

    GBR

    GRC

    IRL

    ISL

    ITA

    JPN

    LUX

    NLD

    NOR

    NZL

    PRT

    SWE

    USA

    .01

    .02

    .03

    .04

    annu

    al g

    row

    th ra

    te 1

    960-

    2000

    9 9.5 10 10.5log gdp per worker 1960

    Figure 1.15. Annual growth rate of GDP per worker between 1960and 2000 versus log GDP per worker in 1960 for core OECD countries.

    This is what the vector Xt−1 captures in equation (1.1). In particular, when this

    vector includes variables such as years of schooling or life expectancy, Barro and

    1That is, the initial members of the OECD club plotted in this picture, which excludes morerecent OECD members such as Turkey, Mexico and Korea.

    22

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    Sala-i-Martin estimate β to be approximately -0.02, indicating that the income gap

    between countries that have the same human capital endowment has been narrowing

    over the postwar period on average at about 2 percent a year.

    Therefore, while there is no evidence of (unconditional) convergence in the world

    income distribution over the postwar era (and in fact, if anything there is diver-

    gence in incomes across nations), there is some evidence for conditional convergence,

    meaning that the income gap between countries that are similar in observable char-

    acteristics appears to narrow over time. This last observation is relevant both for

    understanding among which countries the divergence has occurred and for determin-

    ing what types of models we might want to consider for understanding the process

    of economic growth and differences in economic performance across nations. For

    example, we will see that many of the models we will study shortly, including the

    basic Solow and the neoclassical growth models, suggest that there should be “tran-

    sitional dynamics” as economies below their steady-state (target) level of income

    per capita grow towards that level. Conditional convergence is consistent with this

    type of transitional dynamics.

    1.6. Correlates of Economic Growth

    The discussion of conditional convergence in the previous section emphasized the

    importance of certain country characteristics that might be related to the process

    of economic growth. What types of countries grow more rapidly? Ideally, we would

    like to answer this question at a “causal” level. In other words, we would like to

    know which specific characteristics of countries (including their policies and institu-

    tions) have a causal effect on growth. A causal effect here refers to the answer to the

    following counterfactual thought experiment: if, all else equal, a particular charac-

    teristic of the country were changed “exogenously” (i.e., not as part of equilibrium

    dynamics or in response to a change in other observable or unobservable variables),

    what would be the effect on equilibrium growth? Answering such causal questions

    is quite challenging, however, precisely because it is difficult to isolate changes in

    endogenous variables that are not driven by equilibrium dynamics or by some other

    variables.

    23

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    ARG

    AUS

    AUT

    BDI

    BEL

    BENBFA

    BGD

    BOL

    BRA

    BRB

    CAN

    CHE

    CHL

    CHN

    CIV CMR

    COG

    COL

    COM

    CPV

    CRI

    DNK

    DOM

    DZAECU

    EGY

    ESP

    ETH

    FINFRAGAB

    GBR

    GHA

    GIN

    GMB

    GNB

    GNQ

    GRC

    GTM

    HKG

    HND

    IDN

    IND

    IRL

    IRN

    ISLISRITA

    JAM

    JOR

    JPN

    KEN

    KOR

    LKALSO

    LUX

    MAR

    MDG

    MEX

    MLI

    MOZ

    MUS

    MWI

    MYS

    NER

    NGANIC

    NLD

    NOR

    NPLNZL

    PAK

    PAN

    PER

    PHL

    PRT

    PRY

    ROM

    RWASEN

    SLV

    SWE

    SYCSYR

    TCD

    TGO

    THA

    TTO TUR

    TZA

    UGAURY

    USA

    VEN

    ZAF

    ZMB

    ZWE

    -.02

    0.0

    2.0

    4.0

    6av

    erag

    e gr

    owth

    gdp

    per

    cap

    ita 1

    960-

    2000

    -.05 0 .05 .1 .15average growth investment 1960-2000

    Figure 1.16. The relationship between average growth of GDP percapita and average growth of investments to GDP ratio, 1960-2000.

    For this reason, we start with the more modest question of what factors correlate

    with post-war economic growth. With an eye to the theories that will come in the

    next two chapters, the two obvious candidates to look at are investments in physical

    capital and in human capital.

    Figure 1.16 shows a strong positive association between the average growth of

    investment to GDP ratio and economic growth. Figure 1.17 shows a positive cor-

    relation between average years of schooling and economic growth. These figures

    therefore suggest that the countries that have grown faster are typically those that

    have invested more in physical capital and those that started out the postwar era

    with greater human capital. It has to be stressed that these figures do not imply

    that physical or human capital investment are the causes of economic growth (even

    though we expect from basic economic theory that they should contribute to in-

    creasing output). So far these are simply correlations, and they are likely driven, at

    24

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    ARG

    AUS

    AUT

    BDI

    BEL

    BEN

    BGD

    BOL

    BRA

    BRB

    CAN

    CHE

    CHL

    CHN

    CMR

    COG

    COL

    CRI

    DNK

    DOM

    DZA ECU

    EGY

    ESP

    FINFRA

    GBR

    GHA

    GMB

    GRC

    GTM

    HKG

    HND

    IDN

    IND

    IRL

    IRN

    ISL ISRITA

    JAM

    JOR

    JPN

    KEN

    KOR

    LKALSO MEX

    MLI

    MOZ

    MUS

    MWI

    MYS

    NERNIC

    NLD

    NOR

    NPLNZL

    PAK

    PAN

    PER

    PHL

    PRT

    PRY

    RWASEN

    SLV

    SWE

    SYR

    TGO

    THA

    TTOTUR

    UGA URY

    USA

    VEN

    ZAF

    ZMB

    ZWE

    -.02

    0.0

    2.0

    4.0

    6av

    erag

    e gr

    owth

    gdp

    per

    cap

    ita 1

    960-

    2000

    0 2 4 6 8 10average schooling 1960-2000

    Figure 1.17

    least in part, by omitted factors affecting both investment and schooling on the one

    hand and economic growth on the other.

    We will investigate the role of physical and human capital in economic growth

    further in Chapter 3. One of the major points that will emerge from our analysis

    there is that focusing only on physical and human capital is not sufficient. Both

    to understand the process of sustained economic growth and to account for large

    cross-country differences in income, we also need to understand why societies differ

    in the efficiency with which they use their physical and human capital. We normally

    use the shorthand expression “technology” to capture factors other than physical

    and human capital affecting economic growth and performance (and we will do so

    throughout the book). It is therefore important to remember that technology dif-

    ferences across countries include both genuine differences in the techniques and in

    25

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    the quality of machines used in production, but also differences in productive effi-

    ciency resulting from differences in the organization of production, from differences

    in the way that markets are organized and from potential market failures (see in

    particular Chapter 22 on differences in productive efficiency resulting from the orga-

    nization of markets and market failures). A detailed study of “technology” (broadly

    construed) is necessary for understanding both the world-wide process of economic

    growth and cross-country differences. The role of technology in economic growth

    will be investigated in Chapter 3 and in later chapters.

    1.7. From Correlates to Fundamental Causes

    The correlates of economic growth, such as physical capital, human capital and

    technology, will be our first topic of study. But these are only proximate causes of

    economic growth and economic success (even if we convince ourselves that there is

    a causal element the correlations shown above). It would not be entirely satisfac-

    tory to explain the process of economic growth and cross-country differences with

    technology, physical capital and human capital, since presumably there are reasons

    for why technology, physical capital and human capital differ across countries. In

    particular, if these factors are so important in generating large cross country income

    differences and causing the takeoff into modern economic growth, why do certain

    societies fail to improve their technologies, invest more in physical capital, and ac-

    cumulate more human capital?

    Let us return to Figure 1.8 to illustrate this point further. This figure shows

    that South Korea and Singapore have managed to grow at very rapid rates over the

    past 50 years, while Nigeria has failed to do so. We can try to explain the successful

    performance of South Korea and Singapore by looking at the correlates of economic

    growth–or at the proximate causes of economic growth. We can conclude, as many

    have done, that rapid capital accumulation has been was very important in gener-

    ating these growth miracles, and debate the role of human capital and technology.

    We can blame the failure of Nigeria to grow on its inability to accumulate capital

    and to improve its technology. These answers are undoubtedly informative for un-

    derstanding the mechanics of economic successes and failures of the postwar era.

    But at some level they will also not have answered the central questions: how did

    26

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    South Korea and Singapore manage to grow, while Nigeria failed to take advantage

    of the growth opportunities? If physical capital accumulation is so important, why

    did Nigeria not invest more in physical capital? If education is so important, why

    did the Nigerians not invest more in their human capital? The answer to these

    questions is related to the fundamental causes of economic growth.

    We will refer to potential factors affecting why societies end up with differ-

    ent technology and accumulation choices as the fundamental causes of economic

    growth. At some level, fundamental causes are the factors that enable us to link the

    questions of economic growth to the concerns of the rest of social sciences, and ask

    questions about the role of policies, institutions, culture and exogenous environmen-

    tal factors. At the risk of oversimplifying complex phenomena, we can think of the

    following list of potential fundamental causes: (i) luck (or multiple equilibria) that

    lead to divergent paths among societies with identical opportunities, preferences and

    market structures; (ii) geographic differences that affect the environment in which

    individuals live and that influence the productivity of agriculture, the availability

    of natural resources, certain constraints on individual behavior, or even individual

    attitudes; (iii) institutional differences that affect the laws and regulations under

    which individuals and firms function and thus shape the incentives they have for

    accumulation, investment and trade; and (iv) cultural differences that determine

    individuals’ values, preferences and beliefs. Chapter 4 will present a detailed discus-

    sion of the distinction between proximate and fundamental causes and what types

    of fundamental causes are more promising in explaining the process of economic

    growth and cross-country income differences.

    For now, it is useful to briefly return to South Korea and Singapore versus Nige-

    ria, and ask the questions (even if we are not in a position to fully answer them

    yet): can we say that South Korea and Singapore owe their rapid growth to luck,

    while Nigeria was unlucky? Can we relate the rapid growth of South Korea and

    Singapore to geographic factors? Can we relate them to institutions and policies?

    Can we find a major role for culture? Most detailed accounts of post-war economics

    and politics in these countries emphasize the growth-promoting policies in South

    Korea and Singapore– including the relative security of property rights and invest-

    ment incentives provided to firms. In contrast, Nigeria’s postwar history is one of

    27

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    civil war, military coups, extreme corruption and an overall environment failing to

    provide incentives to businesses to invest and upgrade their technologies. It there-

    fore seems necessary to look for fundamental causes of economic growth that make

    contact with these facts and then provide coherent explanations for the divergent

    paths of these countries. Jumping ahead a little, it will already appear implausible

    that luck can be the major explanation. There were already significant differences

    between South Korea, Singapore in Nigeria at the beginning of the postwar era. It

    is also equally implausible to link the divergent fortunes of these countries to geo-

    graphic factors. After all, their geographies did not change, but the growth spurts

    of South Korea and Singapore started in the postwar era. Moreover, even if we

    can say that Singapore benefited from being an island, without hindsight one might

    have concluded that Nigeria had the best environment for growth, because of its

    rich oil reserves.2 Cultural differences across countries are likely to be important

    in many respects, and the rapid growth of many Asian countries is often linked to

    certain “Asian values”. Nevertheless, cultural explanations are also unlikely to pro-

    vide the whole story when it comes to fundamental causes, since South Korean or

    Singaporean culture did not change much after the end of WWII, while their rapid

    growth performances are distinctly post-war phenomena. Moreover, while South

    Korea grew rapidly, North Korea, whose inhabitants share the same culture and

    Asian values, had one of the most disastrous economic performances of the past 50

    years.

    This admittedly quick (and perhaps partial) account suggests that we have to

    look at the fundamental causes of economic growth in institutions and policies that

    affect incentives to accumulate physical and human capital and improve technol-

    ogy. Institutions and policies were favorable to economic growth in South Korea

    and Singapore, but not in Nigeria. Understanding the fundamental causes of eco-

    nomic growth is, in large part, about understanding the impact of these institutions

    2One can then turn this around and argue that Nigeria is poor because of a “natural resourcecurse,” i.e., precisely because it has abundant and valuable natural resources. But this is not anentirely compelling empirical argument, since there are other countries, such as Botswana, withabundant natural resources that have grown rapidly over the past 50 years. More important, theonly plausible channel through which abundance of natural resources may lead to worse economicoutcomes is related to institutional and political economy factors. This then takes us to the realmof institutional fundamental causes.

    28

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    and policies on economic incentives and why, for example, they have been growth-

    enhancing in the former two countries, but not in Nigeria. The intimate link between

    fundamental causes and institutions highlighted by this discussion motivates the last

    part of the book, which is devoted to the political economy of growth, that is, to

    the study of how institutions affect growth and why they differ across countries.

    An important caveat should be noted at this point. Discussions of geography,

    institutions and culture can sometimes be carried out without explicit reference

    to growth models or even to growth empirics. After all, this is what many non-

    economist social scientists do. However, fundamental causes can only have a big

    impact on economic growth if they affect parameters and policies that have a first-

    order influence on physical and human capital and technology. Therefore, an un-

    derstanding of the mechanics of economic growth is essential for evaluating whether

    candidate fundamental causes of economic growth could indeed play the role that

    they are sometimes ascribed. Growth empirics plays an equally important role in

    distinguishing among competing fundamental causes of cross-country income dif-

    ferences. It is only by formulating parsimonious models of economic growth and

    confronting them with data that we can gain a better understanding of both the

    proximate and the fundamental causes of economic growth.

    1.8. The Agenda

    This discussion points to the following set of facts and questions that are central

    to an investigation of the determinants of long-run differences in income levels and

    growth. The three major questions that have emerged from our brief discussion are:

    (1) Why are there such large differences in income per capita and worker pro-

    ductivity across countries?

    (2) Why do some countries grow rapidly while other countries stagnate?

    (3) What sustains economic growth over long periods of time and why did

    sustained growth start 200 years or so ago?

    • In each case, a satisfactory answer requires a set of well-formulated modelsthat illustrate the mechanics of economic growth and cross-country income

    differences, together with an investigation of the fundamental causes of the

    29

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    different trajectories which these nations have embarked upon. In other

    words, in each case we need a combination of theoretical models and em-

    pirical work.

    • The traditional growth models–in particular, the basic Solow and the neo-classical models–provide a good starting point, and the emphasis they

    place on investment and human capital seems consistent with the patterns

    shown in Figures 1.16 and 1.17. However, we will also see that technolog-

    ical differences across countries (either because of their differential access

    to technological opportunities or because of differences in the efficiency of

    production) are equally important. Traditional models treat technology

    (market structure) as given or at best as evolving exogenously like a black-

    box. But if technology is so important, we ought to understand why and

    how it progresses and why it differs across countries. This motivates our

    detailed study of models of endogenous technological progress and tech-

    nology adoption. Specifically, we will try to understand how differences in

    technology may arise, persist and contribute to differences in income per

    capita. Models of technological change will also be useful in thinking about

    the sources of sustained growth of the world economy over the past 200

    years and why the growth process took off 200 years or so ago and has

    proceeded relatively steadily since then.

    • Some of the other patterns we encountered in this chapter will inform usabout the types of models that have the most promise in explaining eco-

    nomic growth and cross-country differences in income. For example, we

    have seen that cross-country income differences can only be accounted for

    by understanding why some countries have grown rapidly over the past

    200 years, while others have not. Therefore, we need models that can ex-

    plain how some countries can go through periods of sustained growth, while

    others stagnate.

    On the other hand, we have also seen that the postwar world income

    distribution is relatively stable (at most spreading out slightly from 1960

    to 2000). This pattern has suggested to many economists that we should

    focus on models that generate large “permanent” cross-country differences

    30

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    in income per capita, but not necessarily large “permanent” differences in

    growth rates (at least not in the recent decades). This is based on the

    following reasoning: with substantially different long-run growth rates (as

    in models of endogenous growth, where countries that invest at different

    rates grow at different rates), we should expect significant divergence. We

    saw above that despite some widening between the top and the bottom, the

    cross-country distribution of income across the world is relatively stable.

    Combining the post-war patterns with the origins of income differences

    related to the economic growth over the past two centuries suggests that we

    should look for models that can account both for long periods of significant

    growth differences and also for a “stationary” world income distribution,

    with large differences across countries. The latter is particularly challenging

    in view of the nature of the global economy today, which allows for free-flow

    of technologies and large flows of money and commodities across borders.

    We therefore need to understand how the poor countries fell behind and

    what prevents them today from adopting and imitating the technologies

    and organizations (and importing the capital) of the richer nations.

    • And as our discussion in the previous section suggests, all of these questionscan be (and perhaps should be) answered at two levels. First, we can use

    the models we develop in order to provide explanations based on the me-

    chanics of economic growth. Such answers will typically explain differences

    in income per capita in terms of differences in physical capital, human capi-

    tal and technology, and these in turn will be related to some other variables

    such as preferences, technology, market structure, openness to international

    trade and perhaps some distortions or policy variables. These will be our

    answers regarding the proximate causes of economic growth.

    We will next look at the fundamental causes underlying these proximate

    factors, and try to understand why some societies are organized differently

    than others. Why do they have different market structures? Why do some

    societies adopt policies that encourage economic growth while others put

    up barriers against technological change? These questions are central to

    31

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    a study of economic growth, and can only be answered by developing sys-

    tematic models of the political economy of development and looking at the

    historical process of economic growth to generate data that can shed light

    on these fundamental causes.

    Our next task is to systematically develop a series of models to understand the

    mechanics of economic growth. In this process, we will encounter models that un-

    derpin the way economists think about the process of capital accumulation, techno-

    logical progress, and productivity growth. Only by understanding these mechanics

    can we have a framework for thinking about the causes of why some countries are

    growing and some others are not, and why some countries are rich and others are

    not.

    Therefore, the approach of the book will be two-pronged: on the one hand,

    it will present a detailed exposition of the mathematical structure of a number of

    dynamic general equilibrium models useful for thinking about economic growth and

    macroeconomic phenomena; on the other, we will try to uncover what these models

    imply about which key parameters or key economic processes are different across

    countries and why. Using this information, we will then attempt to understand the

    potential fundamental causes of differences in economic growth.

    1.9. References and Literature

    The empirical material presented in this chapter is largely standard and parts of

    it can be found in many books, though interpretations and exact emphases differ.

    Excellent introductions, with slightly different emphases, are provided in Jones’s

    (1998, Chapter 1) and Weil’s (2005, Chapter 1) undergraduate economic growth

    textbooks. Barro and Sala-i-Martin (2004) also present a brief discussion of the

    stylized facts of economic growth, though their focus is on postwar growth and

    conditional convergence rather than the very large cross-country income differences

    and the long-run perspective emphasized here. An excellent and very readable

    account of the key questions of economic growth, with a similar perspective to the

    one here, is provided in Helpman (2005).

    32

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    Much of the data used in this chapter comes from Summers-Heston’s Penn World

    tables (latest version, Summers, Heston and Aten, 2005). These tables are the re-

    sult of a very careful study by Robert Summers and Alan Heston to construct

    internationally comparable price indices and internationally comparable estimates

    of income per capita and consumption. PPP adjustment is made possible by these

    data. Summers and Heston (1991) give a very lucid discussion of the methodology

    for PPP adjustment and its use in the Penn World tables. PPP adjustment enables

    us to construct measures of income per capita that are comparable across coun-

    tries. Without PPP adjustment, differences in income per capita across countries

    can be computed using the current exchange rate or some fundamental exchange-

    rate. There are many problems with such exchange-rate-based measures. The most

    important one is that they do not make an allowance for the fact that relative prices

    and even the overall price level differ markedly across countries. PPP-adjustment

    brings us much closer to differences in “real income” and “real consumption”. In-

    formation on “workers” (active population), consumption and investment are also

    from this dataset. GDP, consumption and investment data from the Penn World

    tables are expressed in 1996 constant US dollars. Life expectancy data are from the

    World Bank’s World Development Indicators CD-ROM, and refer to the average

    life expectancy of males and females at birth. This dataset also contains a range of

    other useful information. Schooling data are from Barro and Lee’s (2002) dataset,

    which contains internationally comparable information on years of schooling.

    In all figures and regressions, growth rates are computed as geometric averages.

    In particular, the geometric average growth rate of variable y between date t and

    t+ T is defined as

    gt,t+T ≡µyt+Tyt

    ¶1/T− 1.

    Geometric average growth rate is more appropriate to use in the context of income

    per capita than the arithmetic average, since the growth rate refers to “proportional

    growth”. It can be easily verified from this formula that if yt+1 = (1 + g) yt for all

    t, then gt+T = g.

    Historical data are from various works by Angus Maddison (2001, 2005). While

    these data are not as reliable as the estimates from the Penn World tables, the

    33

  • Introduction to Modern Economic Growth

    general patterns they show are typically consistent with evidence from a variety

    of different sources. Nevertheless, there are points of contention. For example, as

    Figure 1.12 shows, Maddison’s estimates show a slow but relatively steady growth

    of income per capita in Western Europe starting in 1000. This is disputed by many

    historians and economic historians. A relatively readable account, which strongly

    disagrees with this conclusion, is provided in Pomeranz (2001), who argues that

    income per capita in Western Europe and China were broadly comparable as late as

    1800. This view also receives support from recent research by Allen (2004), which

    documents that the lev