jaffee, “kinks in the intermodal supply chain…” 1 · jaffee, “kinks in the intermodal...

42
Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain: Longshore Workers and Drayage Drivers David Jaffee Professor of Sociology Department of Sociology and Anthropology University of North Florida [email protected] Paper prepared for presentation at the annual meetings of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economics, Philadelphia, PA, June, 2010. WORKING DRAFT: Do not quote or cite without permission of author.

Upload: others

Post on 16-Aug-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1

Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain:

Longshore Workers and Drayage Drivers

David Jaffee Professor of Sociology

Department of Sociology and Anthropology University of North Florida

[email protected]

Paper prepared for presentation at the annual meetings of the Society for the Advancement of Socio-Economics, Philadelphia, PA, June, 2010.

WORKING DRAFT: Do not quote or cite without permission of author.

Page 2: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 2

The logistics intermodal supply chain has been shaped by globalization,

containerization, deregulation, and interorganizational relations and strategies. As a chain

of linked and integrated organizations characterized by sequential interdependence,

spatial dispersion, and multiple technologies directed toward not the production, but

movement, of commodities, one finds a range of industrial practices, organizational

arrangements, labor market conditions and workplace practices. In spite of the increasing

importance of this economic sector, transportation and logistics organizations and

workers in goods-moving versus goods-producing industries have not received sufficient

attention in the socio-economic literature. This paper compares and contrasts the

organizational structures and strategies of the port container terminal operators and the

port drayage trucking segments of the intermodal supply chain, their interorganizational

relationship, and the labor conditions for longshore workers and drayage drivers.

The paper combines insights from organization theory and labor studies as well as

outlines the ways in which environmental forces have differentially impacted the port

terminal and port drayage industries resulting in divergent organizational structures and

practices. We also include a brief case study relevant to the question based on research

conducted on drayage drivers at the Port of Jacksonville Florida (Jaxport). This

demonstrates how the differences in industry/organizational characteristics translate into

working conditions and intermodal forms of antagonism between drivers and longshore

workers. This has implications for the integrative efficiency of the intermodal supply

chain as well as the prospects for labor solidarity among logistics and transportation

workers. The core argument of the paper is that the relationship between the port

terminal and drayage operations is characterized by intermodal disarticulation and

intermodal labor segmentation.

TERMINOLOGY

Because this paper seeks to integrate literatures and areas of inquiry that do not

routinely intersect, it is important to define some terminology that is more familiar to

students of transportation and logistics than to social scientists studying work and

Page 3: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3

organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or more entities…directly

involved in the upstream and downstream flows of products, service, finances, and/or

information from a source to a customer.” (Mentzer, DeWitt, Keebler, Min, Nix, Smith,

& Zacharia, 2001, p. 4). The same authors define supply chain management as “the

systemic, strategic coordination of the traditional business functions and tactics across

these business functions within a particular company and across businesses within the

supply chain, for the purposes of improving the long-term performance of the individual

companies and the supply chain as a whole” (p. 18). Logistics is considered one aspect of

supply chain management and is concerned with the planning and management of the

movement and distribution of materials through the supply chain. Intermodalism refers to

the movement of goods or materials using integrated but different modes of

transportation. The shipping container is a technology that has enhanced and facilitated

the intermodal transport of goods due to its standard size and the existence of common

handling equipment. Thus, in a supply chain, a container holding finished or semi-

finished cargo can be transported by and transferred between container ship, truck

chassis, and/or rail car. The focus of this paper is on the industries and organizations

responsible for handling containers at the port terminal and moving the containers off the

terminal by truck.

THE LANDSCAPE OF THE PORT ECONOMY

The process of globalization and associated global commodity chains, global

production networks, and global value chains (Gereffi & Korzeniewicz 1994; Henderson,

et al., 2004; Coe, et al., 2004) have generated a spatial dispersion of economic activities.

Under a globalized production system, raw materials are extracted in one place, parts and

components may be produced in another, manufacturing may take place in yet another,

and final consumption still another. As the geographic space between interdependent

activities in a commodity chain increases, transportation and logistics take on an

increasingly vital role in the circulation and distribution of commodities and in the

coordination and integration of interdependent units and activities (Panayides, 2002).

In this paper the focus is on the elements of the intermodal supply chain that are

associated with the port economy. On the one hand, the port, as a node in global

Page 4: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 4

production networks, has increased in relevance and significance as a result of the spatial

dispersion of production, the growing distance between production and consumption, and

the subsequent need for transportation and logistics networks and gateways (Hesse &

Rodrigue, 2004, 2006). On the other hand, the port economy itself engenders a spatially

concentrated set of interdependent landside distribution activities, usually in urban

settings (see Jacobs, Ducruet, & de Langen, 2010), the integration of which is the primary

focus of this inquiry. In the context of the firms serving the port economy, Aoyama, et al.

(2006: 335) note this dual spatial relationship “…although the logistics industry serves an

integral function in the globalization of production, it also remains one of the most

localized and embedded industries of all” (for countertrends see Notteboom & Rodrigue,

2005).

The present analysis views the port economy as a by-necessity geographically

concentrated set of organizational actors – given the need for the two sectors of interest to

physically interface in the movement of containers -- that are integrated on the basis of

intermodal functionality and interdependence (Van Der Horst & De Langen, 2008).

Logistics related services are central to this concentrated activity, described by Bonacich

(2008:64) as “a special kind of industrial district, one geared to the process of

international trade.” Rodrigue, Comtois, and Slack (2009) describe these areas as

“freight distribution clusters where an array of distribution activities agglomerate” with

the advantages of spatial proximity based on the factors of land, accessibility,

infrastructure, planning and regulation, economies of agglomeration, and internal

multiplying effects. And, in relation to the focus of this paper, Robinson (2006) argues

that “port-oriented freight movement, may be conceptualized as chain structures

involving transactional relationships between corporate players in logistics pathways

between sellers and buyers” (p. 46). Spatial concentration applies especially to the

corporate players of the supply chain under analysis in this paper – terminal operations

and drayage trucking.

A focus on the port economy generally, and intermodal logistics activities

specifically, introduce a set of new and interesting questions about divisions of labor and

interorganizational integration:

Page 5: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 5

1. Most of the work on inter-organizational relations in the organization theory and

management literature focuses on the relationship between suppliers and producers in the

production process, or the sphere of production. In contrast, the port economy pertains to

the sphere of circulation or distribution of semi-finished and finished goods. It, therefore,

is less about the geography of production than the geography of distribution (Hesse and

Rodrigue, 2004). In Marxist terms, this is conceptualizing as the means of ensuring rapid

turnover time in the circuit of capital and the “annihilation of space-by-time” (Harvey,

1989; Janelle & Beuthe, 1997; Stratton, 2000).

2. Following directly from #1, the interorganizational relations in question are not

involved in a sequential process of transforming/assembling of raw materials and

components into a finished product but rather the sequential transportation of

containerized finished (or semi-finished) products from one transport/distribution mode

to another on the way to the final point of consumption. Thus, we examine the

relationship between modes of transportation and distribution, or what is referred to as

“intermodalism”. While the analysis of intermodal supply-chains include some

theoretical terrain familiar to many economic sociologists and organization theorists –

such as the globalization of production, commodity chains, transaction costs, and

interorganizational networks – it has largely been neglected by social scientists (for

notable exceptions see the work of Bonacich and Wilson, 2008 and Bensman, 2008a).

This paper advocates much more theoretical and empirical attention to the sphere of

circulation and distribution (as opposed to the spheres of production and consumption)

and the logistics industry. An examination of the port economy, the intermodal

transportation of goods, and the logistics industry highlight a different but related set of

organizational challenges revolving around the pressure to construct an integrated

seamless interorganizational interface.

3. A singular technological innovation has driven and facilitated the intermodal system

and network. This is the shipping container (see Levinson, 2006). The challenge is

moving the container, and its contents, door-to-door from the point of production to the

point of consumption.

6. Unlike production workers who may engage in economic activity for interdependent

organizations, workers in different sectors of the intermodal supply chains may come in

Page 6: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 6

contact with one another and interact in the course of moving the goods or containers

from one point to the next.

ORGANIZATION THEORY AND INTERORGANIZATIONAL DYNAMICS

The questions examined in this paper connect to a well-established literature in

organization theory. I have placed the question on interorganizational relationships and

arrangements in the context of a larger meta-tension inherent to all organizations –

arranging a rational division of economic activities and, at the same time, ensuring that

these activities are coordinated and integrated (Jaffee, 2001). Differentiation, divisions of

labor, and specialization are fundamental economic and organizational principles. No

single individual or organization is able to assume responsibility for all production and

distribution activities. This necessitates interdependence and inter-party transactions.

Once divided and differentiated, how do different workers, jobs, departments, units, and

organizations coordinate and integrate their interdependent activities? This question has

posed a major challenge for both organization theory and management practice in terms

of conceptualizing and implementing organizational changes and strategies.

There are two divisions of labor that all organizations must configure and address.

The first operates at the intraorganizational level involving the division of activities

within the firm, enterprise, or organization. This is the technical division of labor. This

includes not only the horizontal dimension, where humans carry out different kinds of

tasks at the same level of the organization, but also the vertical dimension involving

differences in power, authority, rewards and decision-making.

A second division of economic activities takes place at the interorganizational

level among separate production units. This is the social division of labor. It involves the

exchange of inputs and outputs, the buying and selling, and the supplying and distributing

relationships among firms. The general challenge for both divisions of labor stems from

the interdependent nature of economic activity within and among firms and the need to

coordinate and integrate these activities. The focus in this paper will be on the social

division of labor.

Page 7: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 7

A consideration of the social division of labor involves transactions among

interdependent but distinct phases or sequences in a production or distribution process

and the functional integration of these interdependent production units. Organizational

differentiation that is mediated through a market exchange and contractual arrangements

between organizations can pose uncertainties that threaten the ability to carry out a well-

coordinated production process. This creates pressures for a more tightly integrated chain

of inter-organizational relations.

One approach to this problem is provided by the transaction cost model of Coase

(1937) who identified the problems involved in market exchange under conditions of

self-interest and insufficient information. This necessitates contractual verification and

protection; but negotiating, writing, and enforcing contracts is costly. A “firm”, or

organization, may decide to reduce these costs by assuming the activity itself rather than

relying upon another organization. This would be an alternative to market exchange.

Once the activities are controlled by a single organization, market transactions are

replaced by directives and commands. Transaction costs associated with obtaining

information about prices, or establishing contractual obligations, are eliminated. Coase’s

conceptual framework has been extended and modified in the work of Williamson (1975;

1985) who describes the non-market solution as “hierarchy” which is more commonly

known as vertical integration. This is the process of joining sequentially related and

interdependent production units and processes under the control of a single organizational

authority system. Vertical integration will make sense when the cost of hierarchical

administration is less than the cost of market transaction (Teese, 1976). The tension arises

as to whether the organization should specialize in what it does best and rely on the social

division of labor to access needed resources, or integrate the entire process under a single

organizational umbrella, or develop an alliance of independent but affiliated firms.

Langlois and Robertson (1995) make the important distinction between ownership

integration and coordination integration. Generally, ownership integration is the

assumed outcome of hierarchy. One firm buys up another firm, owns its assets, and

presumably integrates its economic activity into its own. Coordination integration

implies coordinating the activities of legally independent entities. Langlois and

Robertson correctly emphasize that ownership does not automatically create tight

Page 8: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 8

coordination, cooperation, or structural and social integration. It is conceivable that

higher levels of collaboration and cooperation can exist between two legally independent

firms. This suggests that control and certainty can be established without resorting to a

vertically integrated arrangement.

Resource dependence theory (Pfeffer & Salancik, 1976) offers another

way to look at inter-organizational relations. This perspective goes far beyond the

immediate exchange partners to consider the larger resource environment that impacts an

organization. The greatest focus has been on the “task environment” (Dill 1958; Scott

1981). This refers to those elements of an organization's environment which have a

direct impact on the ability of the organization to carry out its specific production-related

tasks. The four major sectors of the task environment include: customers, suppliers,

competitors, and regulatory groups. Since the focus here is on the relationship between

two directly interacting segments of the intermodal supply chain, it is customers and

suppliers that would constitute the most relevant elements. One strategy suggested by

resource dependence theory is “bridging” (Pfeffer and Salancik 1976). This involves

developing relationships and formal connections with other organizations in the task

environment. Bridging can include long-term contracts that establish supply and price

over an extended period, or a joint venture that brings together the managerial personnel

from different firms and contributes to a perception of common interests between the

interdependent entities. A further bridging strategy is the vertical merger in which, for

example, a producer buys out a supplier and gains control of the critical resource.

The various bridging strategies identified by resource dependence theorists have

informed the more sweeping organizational trend among theorists who have opted for a

middle ground solutions between markets and hierarchies that some have described as

embedded networks (Gereffi and Hamilton, 1996). This term connotes aspects of

interorganizational relations that defy the market-hierarchy duality. Network relations

imply some structural interdependence; embeddedness implies that the relations are

situated in a social normative context. An embedded network is just one of the many

ways to articulate the myriad interorganizational arrangements that defy the market-

hierarchy duality and which have become increasingly common. Embedded networks

can include temporary alliances, arrangements, or agreements designed to combine the

Page 9: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 9

core competencies and capacities of different firms. The network is characterized by

cooperation, collaboration, and the sharing of information.

Information technologies play a key role in facilitating the rapid transmission of

information among firms -- through computer networks and telecommunication systems -

- and permit the integration of differentiated units. One of the key attributes of the

successful network is its “connectedness” (“its structural ability to facilitate noise-free

communication between its components”) and “consistency” (“sharing of interests

between the network’s goals and the goals of its components”) (Castells 1996:171).

Connectedness implies communication and coordination; consistency implies shared

goals and objectives.

Here we examine the differentiation-integration tension in the context of the port

economy and the inter-organizational relations that are configured to move containerized

commodities from a container vessel to the warehouse/distribution center or railhead.

More specifically, within this intermodal supply chain, we will examine the relationship

between the port container terminal and drayage operations and the workers in each of

these organizational settings.

In the analysis here, we argue that there may be forces impeding the

implementation of ideal-type integrative strategies suggested by various

interorganizational theories. First, as with the commodity production process and related

commodity chains, in the intermodal logistics supply-chain there are also strong pressures

to squeeze costs out of the goods moving transportation logistics processes. This means

that while theoretically there may be optimal means for ensuring interorganizational

integration, as suggested above, there are also cost considerations and

institutional/structural constraints that may work to support and preserve organizational

arrangements that are less economically efficient but that shift costs from one party to

another, and are therefore tolerated (see e.g. Nickerson & Silverman, 2003). Second,

interorganizational chains of transportation and distribution may possess distinct

properties that make models based on interorganizational chains of production less

applicable (Pirrong, 1993; Lafontaine & Masten, 2002). For the structural relationship

between the drayage sector and the port terminal operations, this will imply the existence

of persistent intermodal disarticulation.

Page 10: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 10

THE INTEGRATION AND DIFFERENTIATION OF LABOR

The transaction cost and resource dependence literature cited above -- central for

organization theory -- is written largely at the level, and from the perspective of, the firm,

and pertains to how business and capital seek to develop seamless and economically

rational relationships among interdependent organizations. For the workers involved in

these interdependent industries and organizations, there are different interests and

concerns, theoretically and practically. The question here is: how do workers in

sequentially interdependent industries and organizations differ, interact, cooperate, relate

to, and build solidarity with one another. There is very little theoretical or research

literature that addresses this question.

One theoretical point of entry into this issue is through the study of labor markets

and the now well-recognized fact that labor markets are segmented, bifurcated, and non-

equivalent (Piore, 1972; Reich, Gordon, & Edwards, 1973; Harrison & Sum, 1979;

Dickens & Lang, 1988). There are two interrelated theoretical approaches that can inform

this analysis – segmented or dual labor market theory (Edwards, Reich, & Gordon, 1975;

Beck, Horan, & Tolbert, 1978) and split labor market theory (Bonacich, 1972). Both

theories point to the structural factors that account for different labor market experiences

and working conditions for workers in the same and/or different occupations, industries

and economic sectors.

Segmented labor market theory provides a descriptive and explanatory framework

for studying how work in different industries, economic sectors, and organizations shape

the labor market outcomes of different workers (Reich, Gordon, & Edwards, 1973;

Edwards, Reich, & Gordon, 1975; Beck, Horan, & Tolbert, 1978). The theory revolves

around the distinction between the primary and secondary sectors, or core and periphery,

of the economy. In the primary sector one finds large capital intensive firms exercising

quasi-monopoly pricing power; as a consequence, labor market conditions are more

favorable to workers. These might include unionization, collective bargaining,

productivity-based wage increases, and health and retirement benefits. In contrast, the

secondary sector is characterized by smaller labor intensive firms operating in highly

competitive environments with downward pressure on profit margins. As a consequence,

Page 11: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 11

workers in this sector experience greater economic insecurity, low wages, weak

bargaining power, and few if any fringe benefits. The two sectors also differ in terms of

the skills and job requirements of workers. This theory can inform the variable labor

market experiences that characterize different segments of the intermodal logistics supply

chain. That is, to what extent are the differences in working conditions across the

logistics supply chain attributable to the variation in industry and organizational

structure?

Split labor market theory (Bonacich, 1972) explains divisions among workers

where there is competition between well-paid dominant group workers and low paid

minority group workers in the same occupation or skill class. Ethnic and racial

antagonism, hostility, and conflict can emerge from the tensions produced by economic

competition between different groups of workers vying for labor market advantages and

resources. This theory can inform an understanding of the relationship between workers

in different segments of the logistics supply chain and the source of potential tension (see

Cummings, 1980; Turner, 1986). That is, to what extent is the conflict and hostility

between workers in different segments of the logistics supply chain the result of

perceptions of competition from cheaper labor and/or resentment toward workers who are

perceived to be occupying a privileged status?

Closely related to the work on segmented labor markets are the various employer

strategies designed to create greater flexibility and cost control over the deployment of

labor such as numerical or external flexibility (see Kalleberg, 2003). Numerical

flexibility involves the creation of nonstandard employment relations which “limit the

duration of employment through the use of parttime and (especially) short-term

temporary workers who (a) are often viewed as being disposable and can be recruited and

selected quickly, (b) may be used when the organization does not have the authorization

to hire, and (c) often cost less than regular, full-time employees. These workers are on the

company payroll but have relatively weak ties to the organization, are generally hired for

finite periods on an as-needed basis, and, at least in the United States, typically receive no

or few benefits. In addition, organizations can obtain numerical flexibility and often

reduce costs by externalizing administrative control…” (Kalleberg, 2003, p. 155). The

fact that such employment relations have become increasingly common (Beck, 2000;

Page 12: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 12

Osterman, 2000) would suggest that a growing proportion of the United States labor

market is taking on the characteristics of the secondary sector. Further, it is not

uncommon to find standard and nonstandard, or secure and precarious, employment

relationships existing among workers in the same organization, industry, and economic

sector though significant research has been devoted to correlating the use of temporary,

nonstandard, and external employment relations with organizational and industry

characteristics (Kalleberg, Reynolds, & Marsden 2003; Masters & Miles, 2002; Davis-

Blake & Uzzi, 1993; Kalleberg & Schmidt, 1996).

For the purposes here, we are interested in the labor market conditions that prevail

in two adjacent and interacting supply chain industries, port terminal and drayage

trucking operations, the relationship between workers in these industries, and how that

can impact both supply chain integration and labor solidarity. Where there are sharp dual

economy differences in industry and organizational characteristics, and correlating

differences in racial/ethnic composition between the two sectors, we would expect higher

levels of antagonism.

PORT TERMINAL AND DRAYAGE SEGMENTS OF THE SUPPLY CHAIN

In order to better understand the inter-organizational relations we must identify

and describe the focal industries, organizations, and workers. For our purpose, we will

focus on two segments of the chain – the container port terminal and drayage trucking in

the United States. We will discuss the organizational characteristics and labor relations in

each and then turn to the challenge of structurally and socially integrating these segments

of the chain.

Port terminal organizations. Rather than focus on the port as the unit of

analysis, there is a growing consensus for conceptualizing the “terminalization of

seaports” as a way to correctly identify the relevant unit of analysis (Slack, 2007; Olivier

& Slack, 2006; Rodrigue & Notteboom, 2009)). A more accurate description of the

maritime landscape, according to these theorists, is a corporate network of terminal-

operating transnational corporations. A single port may have multiple terminals that

“throughput” very different types of cargo and are managed by very different types of

administrative arrangements, public and private. In an effort to remain competitive, port

Page 13: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 13

authorities are increasingly ceding control of the terminals to the shipping lines and/or

privately-owned global terminal operators (Olivier & Slack, 2006; Slack & Fremont,

2005) employing the now dominant “landlord” port model that represents the furthest

privatization of port operations (Baird, 2002; Turnbull & Wass, 2007). It is increasingly

common for a particular terminal to be leased, managed, and operated by a private firm

specializing in terminal operations (e.g. Dubai Ports World, Port of Singapore Authority,

SSA Marine, Hutchison Port Holdings, APM Terminals) or by a single shipping line that

has vertically integrated their operations to include terminal operations (e.g. Mitsui

shipping lines and Tra-Pac terminal operations).

Economies of scale are reflected in the increasing concentration in the container

vessel industry, the increasing size of the container vessels, and the increasing investment

in and space devoted to containers terminals (Notteboom, 2004; Heaver, Meersman,

Moglia, & Van De Voorde, 2000; Nooteboom & Winkelmans, 2001; Notteboom &

Rodrigue, 2009). Concentration has resulted from horizontal integration through liner

conferences, operating agreements, and mergers and acquisition (Notteboom, 2004;

Fremont, 2009). Fewer shipping lines control a greater proportion of terminal slot

capacity and the global TEU (twenty-foot equivalent) container throughput (Notteboom

& Rodrigue, 2010). In addition, a greater proportion of containers are being transported

by the largest container vessels that can transport over 5000 TEU containers (Notteboom,

2004). Container terminals are becoming larger, are controlled by a smaller number of

global terminal operators who lease dedicated container terminal facilities and have been

the recipient of massive financial capital investment. In 2006 American International

Group (AIG) bought six U.S. terminals from Dubai-owned company DP World. In that

same year, Goldman Sachs acquired Associated British Port Holdings, and in 2007 the

investment bank bought a 49% share in Carrix, a subsidiary of SSA Marine, the largest

US-based terminal operator. As reported in the business press at that time, “Ports and port

operators have become the hottest investment targets for fund managers across the

world…” (Arabian Business 2006).

The primary forms of labor conducted at the port terminal involve stevedoring (by

longshoreworkers) – the loading and unloading of cargo from ocean carriers – and the

transferring (by clerks and checkers) of cargo to other modes of transportation. We focus

Page 14: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 14

here on containerized cargo which is loaded, unloaded, and maneuvered by the use of

cranes. Once unloaded from the ship, containers can be placed directly on a truck chassis,

can be placed on a rail car, or can be stacked at the terminal for movement at a later time.

Of the different labor forces involved in the intermodal supply chain, a significant

segment of port terminal workers can be regarded as the “labor aristocracy” by virtue of

their representation by longshore unions. In spite of some major setbacks stemming from

the reorganization of the shipping industry (Turnbull & Wass, 2007), most notably

containerization, the waterfront remains a relatively unique organized labor stronghold.

Finally, as noted above, the global terminal operators, and the shipping lines to which

many are linked, represent industries that are in the core or primary sector of the

economy. These organizations are capital intensive, hold pricing power, can establish

strong bargaining power, are multinational, and have profit margins large enough to make

them attractive to major investment banks.

What are some of the other factors contribute to the ability of waterfront unions to

exercise bargaining power? Erik Olin Wright (2000) has outlined the various ways in

which “class compromise” involves the interaction between the strength of the

associational power of labor and the realization of the material interests of capital. The

extent to which compromise or accommodation is possible hinges on the degree to which

the level of associational power is either a direct threat or a potential contribution to an

employer’s objectives. Compromise is most likely in the latter case. Hypothesized as a

reverse J-curve, low levels of working-class associational power are associated with a

greater realization of capitalists’ interests. As associational power increases, there is a

continuing decline in capitalists’ interests, but as working class power increases beyond

some intermediate threshold, the curve bends upward with high levels of working-class

organization potentially benefiting the material interests of capital. The logic of the non-

inverse relationship between working class power and capitalists’ interests is based on the

potential for “high levels of bargained cooperation between workers and capitalists,

rationalized systems of skill upgrading and job training, enhanced capacity for solving

macroeconomic problems, and a greater willingness of workers to accept technological

change given the relative job security they achieve because of union protections”

Page 15: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 15

(Wright, 2000, pp. 959-960). This model of associational power applies fairly well to the

case of longshore workers.

As it relates to the waterfront and the situation of dockworkers, one can bring

some greater specification to the class compromise dynamic. There are several factors to

consider. First, the port is a geographic node that cannot be relocated and thus the threat

of offshore capital flight is nullified. Second, the gigantic size of container vessels and

container terminals create economies of scale and massification levels (Rodrique, et al.,

2009) that enhance and strengthen the conditions for collective labor organization. Third,

as already noted, vertical integration, involving ocean carriers extending their control

over the terminal operations, and concentration within the industry more generally, can

work to strengthen the bargaining power of workers and unions (Finlay, 1987). Fourth,

once cargo arrives at the port it is vital, given the sequentially interdependent “just in

time” supply-chain system, to move it as quickly and efficiently as possible without any

threat of delays, slowdowns, or stoppages. Equally important, the shipping lines have an

interest in unloading the cargo and redeploying the vessel capacity for additional

container business. Lastly, Silver’s (2003) observation about transport workers applies

most specifically to this labor force: “Transport workers have possessed and continue to

possess relatively strong workplace bargaining power. This is especially clear after we

conceptualize their workplace as the entire network in which they are enmeshed. Thus,

the source of the workplace bargaining power is to be found less in the direct impact of

their actions on immediate (often public) employers and more on the

upstream/downstream impact of the failure to deliver goods, services, and people to their

destinations.”(p. 100). The desire by capital to ensure stability and certainty in the

movement of cargo works to the advantage of labor, who are able to exercise

“interdependent power” (Piven, 2006). We will see that there are some limits to this

assertion as we move to the next transport mode in the supply chain.

However, longshore labor is not invulnerable. Forces that have and can

erode the relative strength of port unions (Fisher & Kondra, 1993; Turnbull & Wass,

2007) include containerization and related “technological fixes”(Levinson, 2006; Ircha &

Garey, 1992;Turnbull & Wass, 2007); port competition (Heaver, 1995;

Heaver, Meersman, & Van De Voorde, 2001); the existence of two different labor unions

Page 16: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 16

representing East (ILA - International Longshoremen’s Association) and West coast

(ILWU - International Longshore and Warehouse Union) longshore workers (Monaco &

Olsson, 2005); threatened and actual shifting of cargo from the West to East coasts of the

U.S. (Jaffee, 2009); the introduction of “flexible working practices” Turnbull & Wass,

2007); and the continuous effort to automate as much of the waterfront cargo handling

process as possible (Schwarz-Miller & Talley, 2002; Betcherman & Rebne, 1987;

Killingsworth, 1962). Like all workplaces, the waterfront remains a contested terrain.

It is because of these various threats, and the fact that the numbers of

longshore workers handling cargo on the waterfront is diminishing, that one of the

longshore unions (ILWU) is setting its sights inland on the other cargo moving/handling

sectors that have experienced employment expansion. Thus, a major study conducted by

the University of California’s Institute for Labor and Employment (Dube, Evans, Hall,

Olney, Swearington, Willis, & Wolff, 2004) recommended that the union “must confront

the challenge of thinking industrially beyond the docks and organizing the full cargo-

handling supply chain whether on or off the docks…Increasing solidarity among

longshore and warehouse workers (and potentially truck drivers)…is the only one that

provides any hope of shifting the balance of power in the logistics industry…” (p.35).

This suggests a different kind of integration strategy designed to socially integrate labor

across the supply chain as a way to retain power and leverage vis-à-vis private

employers. However, as longshore unions begin their “march inland” the first labor force

they will confront are the port truckers, to whom we can now turn.

Port drayage organizations. The unloading of shipping containers at the port

terminal, carried out by the increasingly privatized and specialized terminal operators, is

followed by the transferring to another transport mode for movement off the terminal, out

of the port enterprise, and to a distribution facility or other transport mode. The most

common mode of transport for the movement of containers from the terminal is by truck

and known as “drayage”. Drayage is the hauling of intermodal containers on a

detachable trailer chassis and an essential link in the intermodal movement of goods,

serving as the link to/from the port terminal and to/from railhead and distribution centers

across inland portions of North America.

Page 17: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 17

The drayage sector is characterized by a large number of logistics and trucking

firms, many quite small, that contract with shippers for the movement of containers.

Drivers in this sector may be employees of the firms but are much more commonly,

“independent owner-operators”. If dockworkers are the labor aristocracy, owner

operators are the serfs of the intermodal supply chain.

The most comprehensive study and general treatment of truck driving working

conditions is Michael Belzer’s Sweatshop On Wheels (2000). It is a story about the steady

decline in labor market conditions revolving around the transition of trucking from the

status of a protected and regulated, to unprotected and deregulated, industry with the

passage of The Motor Carrier Act of 1980 (Belzer, 2000; Belman & Monaco, 2001;

Bensman, 2009a; Peoples & Talley, 2004). Prior to the 1980 Act, licensing requirements

enforced by the Interstate Commerce Commission restricted the number of trucking firms

and trucks. This had the effect of stabilizing prices and, with Teamster representation of

drivers, providing truckers with attractive compensation and benefits. Rising wages and

operating expenses were simply passed on in the form of higher shipping costs. The

Motor Carrier Act radically altered the trucking landscape allowing the entry of low-cost,

non-union trucking firms. The low barriers to entry, increasing number of players, and

the heightened competition exerted a downward pressure on trucker compensation and a

steady decline in union representation. Particular sectors, including drayage, became

highly competitive and fragmented as a result, and the net effect has been a decline in

compensation levels and mass de-unionization (Belzer, 1995).

Another major consequence of deregulation was the rise of the “owner-operator”

or “independent contractor” arrangement. Under this now-dominant drayage industry

standard, trucking firms -- rather than owning trucks and hiring workers as employees --

contract with “self-employed” drivers who own or lease their own truck. These drivers

work for, but are not officially employed by, the trucking companies, and they are paid

by the trip or load, instead of by the hour. They are typically prohibited from working for

more than one company. The implication of being an independent owner-operator, as

fictional as the designation might be in practice (see Bensman, 2009b), effectively frees

trucking companies from any financial and legal obligations they would incur under an

official employment relationship (e.g. social security, health benefits, retirement).

Page 18: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 18

Finally, and quite significantly, as an “independent business”, rather than a company

employee, the owner operator is prohibited from joining with other owner-operators in

organizing a labor union, as this would violate federal anti-trust laws.

While the deregulation of trucking has negatively impacted working conditions

for many drivers, it is port truckers who face the most severe circumstances. According to

Prince (2005), the trucking labor force is internally stratified. At the top of the pyramid

are the fulltime employees of the major national trucking firms who may also be

unionized. Below this relatively privileged segment of the trucking labor force are the

various owner-operators. Among owner operators there is also a hierarchy. “At the

bottom of the pyramid are owner-operators hauling international containers – the fastest

growing segment of intermodal traffic. After expenses, many of them make about $6 an

hour, less than what many fast-food jobs pay” (Prince, 2005, p. 13). Or, as Bonacich

notes, “Of all the global trade related logistics workers, port truckers are the most

oppressed” (2003, p. 46).

Several studies provide insight into the condition and character of work for this

segment of the logistics labor force serving U.S. ports (Monaco & Grobar, 2004;

Bensman, 2009a, 2009b; Bensman & Bromberg, 2009; Harrison, Hutson, West, & Wilke,

2008; Port Jobs, 2007; East Bay Alliance for a Sustainable Economy, 2007; Jaffee &

Rowley, 2009). A number of patterns have been identified. A majority of drivers in all

cases occupy minority group status (for example Hispanic/Latino drivers made up 92% in

Los Angeles/Long Beach and 66% in New Jersey; in Jacksonville African American and

Hispanic/Latino combine to make up over 50% of drivers). This signals the

“racialization” of this particular segment of the trucking labor market in which ethnic and

racial minority groups occupy and are concentrated in the least advantaged employment

categories, and/or move into those occupational sectors that have experienced downward

mobility in terms of compensation and working conditions (see Bonacich, Alimahomed

& Wilson, 2008). Trucking generally, and port drayage in particular, is representative of

this type of occupation.

Further supporting evidence for the marginalized character of port drayage is

provided by the fact that the majority of drayage drivers are owner-operators – from 86%

in Los Angeles/Long Beach to 68% in Jacksonville Florida according to the studies cited

Page 19: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 19

above. As noted, the owner-operators are essentially “dependent” contractors who are

not allowed to work for more than one trucking firm, receive no employee benefits, are

compensated by the trip rather than the hour, and absorb all costs associated with the

operation of their vehicles as well as the inefficiency of the system. In terms of the latter,

what are most significant are the routine but costly delays and bottlenecks (terminal

security clearance, dependence on terminal operations to locate containers or provide

roadworthy chassis). For owner-operators who are paid by the trip rather than the hour,

wait time at the container terminal and warehouse/distribution center is one of the most

significant factors impacting extended hours and low rates of compensation. The average

net income (after subtracting truck expenses) of drivers in LA/LB was $29,903 (2004

dollars) and in NJ it was $30,000 (2008 dollars). These figures include both employees

and owner-operators. Consistent with the literature on the relative position of the owner-

operator drayage trucker, Bensman and Bromberg report an average net income of

$35,000 for employee drivers and $28,000 for owner-operators. To place this level of

compensation into a larger context, it is important to consider the number of hours per

week driver’s work to achieve these levels of income. At LA/LB the average number of

hours drivers worked per week was 56, in NJ 58, and in Houston 55. This figure is

consistent with the “self-exploitation” that would characterize owner-operator conditions

that involve no salary or hourly wage and constant pressure to maximize the number of

“trips” or “turns” in order to increase income.

The two sectors of the logistics industry – container terminals and port drayage –

and their contrasting structural characteristics and labor market conditions, conform in

many ways with the theoretical expectations of dual economy theory and labor market

segmentation. How do these differences impact the integration of these two intermodal

supply chain segments?

INTERMODAL DISARTICULATION

We have described two segments of the intermodal logistics supply chain that are

very different in terms of industry structure and labor market conditions. Yet the two

segments must interface and ideally integrate their operations in a seamless fashion so

that the goods can move rapidly through the supply chain. In this section we describe

Page 20: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 20

and attempt to explain the disarticulation problems between the two sectors and some

strategies that have been suggested or used to improve efficiency.

As the goods move between the various modes and organizations, there is

enormous pressure for seamless integration and rapid transit (Van Der Horst & De

Langen, 2008; Panayides, 2002; Capineri & Leinbach, 2006; Robinson, 2006). As

Panayides (2006) has observed, “The convergence of maritime transport and logistics

may be largely attributed to the physical integration of modes of transport facilitated by

containerization…At the centre of maritime logistics is the concept of integration, be it

physical (intermodal), economic strategic (vertical integration, governance structure), or

organizational (relational, people and process integration across organizations)” (p. 5).

The integration imperative for intermodal flows -- or what one author describes as the

“speed imperative” (Kasarda, 2000) that implies “time-based competition” (Meersman &

van de Voorde, 2001) -- suggests a need for tighter control and coordination across the

supply chain.

In the context of the integration imperative, there is a clear argument for viewing

the port as an integral, rather than peripheral or incidental, part of the supply chain and,

further, that the port’s integration with other organizations is critical to its competitive

viability (Heaver, 1995; Bichou & Gray, 2004; Jacobs & Hall, 2007; Marlow & Paixao,

2003; Song and Panayides, 2008; Robinson, 2002; Notteboom & Winkelmans, 2001;

Heaver et al., 2000; Fremont, 2009). The combination of containerization, intermodalism,

and discretionary cargo give shippers and carriers greater latitude in selecting ports of

call which intensifies the competition between ports. This weakens the bargaining power

of ports in terms of providing unique access to a particular geographic location or market,

creates greater dependence of ports on the decisions of ocean carriers, and relegates ports

to ‘pawns in a game’ controlled by larger global corporations (Slack, 1993). This has

also required ports to be more entrepreneurial and more active in developing, marketing,

and demonstrating their logistics and supply chain capacities. As Jacobs and Hall (2007:

328, emphasis added) argue: “…the port authority or operator’s competitive strategic

advantage is not only based upon operational efficiency or location, but increasingly on

the degree to which it is embedded in supply chains, is able to enhance the efficiencies

within these supply chains, and is able to extract value from them.” They believe that

Page 21: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 21

ports vary in their level of embeddedness and, accordingly, there ability to provide highly

integrative services to their customers.

Private terminal operators have recognized the value of extending their services

into the supply chain in an effort to enhance integration. If not involving actual vertical

integration into inland transport, third party logistics providers, and warehousing, there

can be systematic coordination with these supply chain entities. SSA Marine, for

example, boasts of its provision of rail yard, trucking, warehousing, and off-dock yard

services. In the case of Hutchison Port Holdings, they have created a separate logistics

division – Port Services and Logistics – which can offer customers “seamless logistics

support around he world”. Similarly, an ocean carrier may “in-source” terminal

operations to a subsidiary (e.g. Mitsui’s Tra-Pac Inc. or Maersk’s APM Terminals) that

also forges an integrative relationship at least as far as the terminal. This is where one is

most likely to find vertical integration in the intermodal chain. While a great deal has

been written about the activities of shipping lines in more fully integrating their

operations, it has been much more at the level of horizontal than vertical integration, and

in maritime versus inland transport (Evangelista & Morvillo, 1999). This has resulted in

significant economies of scale at the ocean carrier level. However, Fremont’s (2009)

analysis challenges the claim that ocean carriers are extending the integration in a fully

vertical direction controlling inland logistics operations. He argues that the greatest

concern is with – not surprisingly – “vessel logistics” and the full utilization and capacity

of vessels, the minimization of costs, and the optimization of cash flow. Secondly,

“container logistics” entails the procurement, organization, monitoring, and balancing of

the container fleet among the different trade routes. There is far less involvement or

concern with controlling the actual drayage process or operations.

The extent to which a container terminal is integrated into the larger supply chain

is the focus of a study by Panayides and Song (2008). They develop a theoretical and

empirical construct – “terminal supply chain integration” (TESCI) -- that is based on the

four critical indicators of a container terminal’s integration with the supply chain:

information and communication systems for the sharing of information with supply chain

partners; the provision of value-added services; the use of multi-modal transport systems

Page 22: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 22

and operations; and the planning and organization of supply-chain integration practices

that extend beyond the borders of the terminal.

One common strategy, given the range of parties and transportation modes

involved in the movement of goods, has been for shippers to outsource the integration

and coordination function of intermodal transport to what are called third-party logistics

firms, or 3PLs. From this perspective, the 3PL conforms to the definition of Lieb et al.

(1993) which “involves the use of external companies to perform logistics functions that

have traditionally been performed within an organization. The functions performed by the

third party can encompass the entire logistics process or selected activities within that

process.” More generally, it is safe to say that the 3PLs owe their existence and rising

prominence to the trend toward increasingly complex global production networks and the

pressure to keep the freight and cargo in constant motion from production to

consumption. Or, as Bonacich (2008: 15) has remarked, “logistics experts operate on the

principle that capital not in motion ceases to be capital”.

In spite of the recognition that the terminal is most competitive and effective

when it forges integrative connections, and the use of 3PLs to assume responsibility for

coordinating movement across the chain, there seems to be a unanimous opinion that the

terminal-drayage connection is the weakest and least efficient link in the intermodal

logistics supply chain (Morlok & Spasovic, 1994; Srour, 2010; Bensman, 2009a, 2009b ;

Taylor & Jackson, 2000; Payne, 2007; Coalition for Healthy Ports, 2009; Monico &

Grobar, 2004). Observers site a wide range of deficiencies. The various problems

identified include the following interrelated factors: traffic congestion, environmental

impacts, pickup scheduling, truck terminal delays, uncertainty, inadequate

communication and application of IT solutions, poor working conditions and

compensation for drivers, the inefficient allocation of empty containers, diseconomies of

atomization in the trucking industry, extended turn times, inefficient procedures for

locating and positioning containers, and unavailability and poorly maintained

maintenance of container chassis. What might account for these persistent and widely-

recognized intermodal deficiencies?

Within the context of the theoretical literature on interorganizational integration

(e.g. transaction cost and resource dependence), the logic and incentives for particular

Page 23: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 23

integrative strategies are based on a customer-supplier model and set of functional

linkages that do not entirely apply to the intermodal transportation logistics chain

generally, or the container terminal-drayage nexus, in particular. Most significant is the

fact that the drayage sector is neither a customer nor a required resource for the terminal

operator. The terminal is primarily concerned with meeting the needs of the backward

linkage (on the import side) to the shipping lines. Once the terminal operators unload the

cargo from the vessel they have an obligation to make it available and accessible to the

next mode of transport but strong financial incentive structures are much weaker than

they would otherwise be if terminal operators were paying trucking firms for a service

provided. Williamson’s (2008) recent application of transaction cost economics (TCE) to

supply chain management reiterates that the “paradigm transaction” of TCE is the make-

or-buy decision. He asks: what is the paradigm problem for supply chain management? I

would answer that for the intermodal case studied here it is not “make or buy” but “the

handoff”. What seems most critical is not the cost and quality of the physical objects

being moved through the chain, but rather the speed at which the objects are moving.

At closer examination it seems clear that there are other parties that have a greater

interest than the terminal operators in the expeditious and seamless handoff of containers.

One is the port authority that bases its competitive position on marketing and

demonstrating the efficient integration of terminals with inland transportation modes. The

other is the third-party logistics firms, brokers, and shippers who are trying to ensure the

rapid transit of freight through the supply-chain and, importantly, who are the customers

of the trucking firm.

The structural economic dualism represented by the two interacting sectors may

also be a major factor contributing to integrative inefficiencies. Rodrigue, Comtois, &

Slack, 2009 have identified this situation as a problem of “massification” and

“atomization” in the “last mile” of freight distribution. “The containerization process is

thus confronted with a growing tension between a massification at sea and an atomization

on land. Growing vessel size has led to the massification of unit cargo at sea. On

terminals and at the landside, massification makes place for an atomization process

whereby each individual container has to find its way to its final destination.” While this

is an inevitable aspect of the geography of distribution, it is severely exacerbated and

Page 24: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 24

introduced prematurely by the fragmented drayage industry yielding an array of different

trucking firms, brokers, and logistics companies moving containers off the terminal.

Whatever economies of scale are achieved at the vessel and terminal level, they are

quickly eroded at the drayage level.

The persistence of this widely acknowledged dysfunctional system would suggest

that there are benefits deriving from the arrangement for particular parties. The cost

effectiveness of such a system may be associated with the party that bears the greatest

direct economic cost – the drivers. Poorly organized, as atomized as the industry in which

they work, and largely powerless, costs and risks are shifted to, borne by, and

concentrated among the owner-operators or, more accurately, “dependent contractors”.

One of the consistent observations made by those who study the port drayage system

pertains to the issue of who bears the costs and risks, and who would have the greatest

economic incentive to institute alternative arrangements (Bensman, 2009a, 2009b;

Monaco & Grobar, 2004). If the terminal operators paid a direct economic price for the

delays and bottlenecks reported by drivers, there would be an incentive to streamline the

system or negotiate different terms with the unionized port workers responsible for

operating the gates and directing the truckers through the terminal. If the drivers were

organized and/or paid by the hour, the trucking firms would have an incentive to organize

for a more rational system that would minimize time delays. Firms have little incentive to

pay drivers as employees, by the hour, when up to half the working day is spent waiting

rather than actually moving a container. As it currently stands, the negative external

effects of congestion, delays, or inefficient terminal operations are borne and absorbed by

the drivers. In short, it is profitable, or at least cost effective, to take the “low road”

strategy when it comes to the drayage side of the equation (Milkman, 2002). As is often

the case in these situations, what is individually rational for the trucking firms is

collectively irrational for the larger supply chain. These delays and inefficiencies impact

all parties in the sequentially interdependent inter-organizational supply chain. Therefore,

there should be a common interest working to ensure a more timely movement of

containers from the terminal to the subsequent mode of transport or distribution. More

generally, this issue points to the need to internalize costs that are currently externalized

and to modify the employment relationship that reinforces an arrangement that minimizes

Page 25: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 25

the costs to “employers” and maximizes the costs incurred by workers (see Hacker, 2006

on this larger trend in the U.S. labor market).

There are several developments in the area of drayage that are intended to address

the weak links and gaps in the system. First, designed to reduce wait times and

congestion, is an appointment system for procuring containers. Second, and most

consistent with strategies discussed thus far, there is the vertical coordination between the

ocean and landside carrier. Several recent examples include a joint venture between APL

shipping lines with Con-way Freight to integrate and customize intermodal container

transit. The fact that APL has access to dedicated terminals enhances the ability to make

such collaboration possible. Similarly, J.B. Hunt Transport Services has partnered with

ocean carrier Matson Navigation to integrate services and guarantee transit and delivery

times. Finally, the fragmentation of the trucking industry is being addressed with the

emergence of large scale nationwide trucking firms. Most notable is Roadlink USA

which was created out of the merger of seven regional intermodal transportation

companies. Roadlink claims to be the “largest private, independent North American

Intermodal Logistics service provider” combining local market expertise with the scale

and scope of nationwide coverage and service. These strategies are designed to match the

scale economy of terminal operations with scale economy of drayage operations (see

Watson, 1999).

A number of other proposals have been suggested for improving drayage related

efficiencies. The “virtual container yard” is aimed at eliminating the wasted transport

time and resources devoted to returning and picking up empty containers (Theofanis,

Boile, Janakiraman, & Naniopoulos, 2007 ; Rodrigue, Comtois, & Slack, 2009). The

system would coordinate the regional demand for containers with drivers delivering

containers directly to the point of use rather than temporary port stockpiles. Two other

proposed enhancements are related to the congestion and delays associated with having to

match a particular driver with a particular container or a particular chassis. Solutions

involve the creation of a “trucking pool” from which drivers working for different firms

could be used to transport containers for any other firms (Payne, 2007). Similarly, a

chassis pool would be established from which drivers could use any available chassis

regardless of which shipping line had ownership. All three of these proposals to address

Page 26: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 26

bottlenecks in this particular segment of the chain require cooperative and collaborative

relations among separate and potentially competing firms. They also point to the way

cooperation rather than competition can produce a more optimal arrangement for the

efficiency of the supply chain.

None of the proposals above address directly the problematic owner-operator

status of drayage drivers. The conversion of owner operators to employees could

conceivably be either a cause or consequence of improving the efficiency of the system.

On the one hand, if firms were paying drivers as employees they would have an incentive

to fix the system. On the other hand, if the system were more time efficient the firm

might be more willing to pay drivers as hourly employees.

INTERMODAL LABOR SEGMENTATION

We do not have good information on the nature of the relationship between

workers who interact and can potentially contribute to the greater efficiency of the

intermodal system. What is rarely examined are the occasions when the different labor

forces from the different segments come in contact with one another and interact in the

process of moving the goods. In this section, based on research on port truckers

conducted at the Talleyrand terminal in Jacksonville Florida (Jaffee & Rowley, 2009), we

consider some interesting organizational and labor dynamics illuminated by the interface

between the drayage and terminal operations. While the analysis here is preliminary, we

hope that it can point the way to future research on how the intersection of different labor

forces and conditions can impact the quality of work, interorganizational integration, and

prospects for labor unity.

We have already described the work environment and organizational challenges

facing drayage drivers. In a survey distributed to drivers at Jaxport, respondents were

invited to add additional comments and information about their working conditions. The

qualitative data derived from this section of the survey pointed to several key issues not

addressed by the closed-ended survey items in our study. One of the most frequent

comments, or complaints, registered by the drivers concerned the poor treatment they

receive from the terminal employees. This ranged from a lack of respect to an indifferent

Page 27: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 27

attitude toward the drivers’ need to obtain and transport the container in a timely fashion.

Some representative expressions are as follows:

The ILA clerks are in no hurry to do anything as they are paid on an hourly basis and are SLOW, SLOW, and SLOW! Redundant holdups, dealing with people who could care less that a driver has a time schedule to keep. Arrogant disregard with any problem a driver has. They label us as stupid truck drivers! At the port, they are very nasty to drivers. They discriminate at the port. They treat drivers like dirt when we are the ones responsible for their salary. They treat the minorities very badly. The way that they treat drivers at the port is humiliating

Bonacich and Wilson’s research on the West coast ports reports similar tensions

and animosities between drivers and terminal workers. “Port truckers complain that the

ILWU [International Longshore and Warehouse Union] clerks treat them discourteously

or take breaks, leaving drivers to wait in long lines. Drivers feel that they face some

racism from ILWU members. And the truth is that some ILWU members blame the

immigrants for the downfall of the union in the ports” (2008, pp. 223-224). The study of

port truckers in Seattle (Port Jobs, 2007, p. 39) also highlights this issue:

Conflict between longshore workers and truck drivers at the marine terminals is a

problem that is acknowledged by all stakeholders in the system.

Miscommunication and disagreements in this high-stress environment can lead to

physical altercations. This affects working conditions for everyone at the

terminals, and can reduce the efficiency of terminal operations. Drivers report that

they are often treated disrespectfully; while longshore workers report that they are

often frustrated by inexperienced drivers.

In Jacksonville, the clerks and checkers working at the port terminal are

represented by the International Longshoremen’s Association (ILA). It is worth noting

that the ILA has a long-standing and largely accepted (on both sides) history of “biracial

unionism” (Nelson, 2001; Arnesen, 1998). This is manifested in a racial division of labor

Page 28: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 28

with African-Americans dominating the cargo handling and stevedoring functions while

white workers are heavily overrepresented among the clerks and checkers. In fact, in

Jacksonville, as in some other East and Gulf coast ports, there are two separate ILA

locals – one for the stevedores and one for the clerks and checkers. In this context, the

racial dimension becomes somewhat more significant given that African-Americans are

disproportionately overrepresented among the drivers while the clerks and checkers are

largely white.

The divergent working conditions conform with the dual economy and segmented

labor market perspectives where the longshore workers exist in the primary sector (or

core) and the drayage drivers exist in the secondary sector (or periphery). These models

associate different industrial/organizational structural characteristics with divergent labor

market conditions. These sectoral differences have also been alternatively described

above as massification in the primary sector and atomization in the secondary sector. This

situation creates not only potential bottlenecks and supply-chain inefficiencies, but the

juxtaposition in organizational structure is replicated at the level of working conditions in

the two industries. The term “economic apartheid” has been used to describe the

contrasting situation for the two groups of workers. While these labor forces are

sequentially interdependent, the divergent organization conditions have contributed to an

inability to communicate effectively, build solidarity, or act collectively. Kalleberg

(2003) has noted how such segmentation can also have a direct impact on organizational

performance. “Nonstandard employment relations are attractive to employers because

they may often reduce employment costs in addition to enhancing flexibility. On the

other hand, in some cases the use of nonstandard workers may create conflicts with

regular employees and thereby diminish cooperation and teamwork.” (Kalleberg, 2003, p.

171). The same disarticulation that hampers supply-chain efficiency also undermines

cooperation, teamwork, social integration that can translate into high performance

workplace – due to low road strategies and the existence of core/periphery distinctions

throughout the supply chain that translate into flexible labor arrangements and

nonstandard work.

While the data collected at the Jacksonville port only represent the perspective of

the drivers, conversations with longshore workers and terminal operators suggest several

Page 29: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 29

additional speculative explanations to account for the less than harmonious relations. At

the most rudimentary level, longshore workers may simply disrespect drivers on the basis

of status/racial/ethnic differences. The “racialization” of drayage has already been noted.

In addition, the immigrant status of drivers as well as communication problems stemming

from language differences may also fuel tensions. Further, the longshore workers may

regard the drivers as a disorganized collection of menial laborers who lack any class

consciousness and who undermine and threaten the skill-based and relatively high-wage

environment established by longshore workers. On the surface, these seem to be

operative dynamics.

However, we should consider more carefully the workplace context and the

particular identities of the interacting workers in order to develop a more nuanced

analysis. There is something relatively unique about one group of workers physically

encroaching upon the terrain of another. In this case drivers are entering the terminal, or

“the waterfront”, which is regarded as the sacred jurisdiction of longshore workers. These

workers have a long history of labor solidarity among their members and an established

set of work rules and procedures for moving, organizing, consigning, and physically

arranging shipping containers. The drivers, on the other hand, have one objective – to

obtain the container as quickly as possible in order to complete a trip. They have typically

spent time waiting to get into the terminal, and experienced delays at the gate while their

credentials and truck are checked for security purposes. When they finally reach the

container yard they are ready to grab the load. They are not interested in union-based

protocols or work rules. Further, the sense of urgency and impatience expressed by the

drivers may be regarded as an imposition on the longshore workers. Under such a

scenario, it is not difficult to imagine how tensions and antagonisms can quickly develop

between the two groups of workers. Thus, added to the structural and impersonal

intermodal disarticulation based on poorly integrated transport processes and manifested

in bottlenecks and delays in container transit, are the personal relations between drivers

and longshore workers based on segmented labor markets and manifested in intergroup

antagonisms.

Beyond these personal animosities and tensions are the questions this raises for

organizing different workers that are potentially united by their common involvement in

Page 30: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 30

moving cargo, possessing interdependent power by virtue of their strategic position in the

supply chain, but practically divided by organization, industry, race/ethnicity and labor

market status. As mentioned, one of the objectives of the ILWU is to “march inland” to

organize cargo moving workers and expand union jurisdiction. How will the divisions

between the adjacent labor forces that we have described impact such a strategy?

DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

This paper has examined two segments of the intermodal container supply chain –

the port container terminal and drayage operations. The purpose was to develop a better

understanding of the different organizational and industrial features of the two

interdependent sectors, the divergent labor market and working conditions, and the extent

to which such differences impact the level of integration and seamlessness between the

two interacting segments of the supply chain. The analysis has been informed by the

interorganization theories of transaction cost and resource dependence as well as labor

market theories of segmentation and dualism. The sharp differences in industrial structure

between the two segments – in terms of scale economy, capital intensiveness,

concentration, multinational reach – and consequent labor market conditions generate

both intermodal disarticulation and intermodal labor segmentation that undermine the

supply chain objectives of integrative seamlessness as well as prospects for labor unity.

There are some larger implications, both theoretical and practical, that are also

worth noting. First, the study of interorganizational integration and governance structures

has been heavily influenced by transaction cost theory. However, the analysis here would

suggest that the intermodal transport chain is characterized by unique interorganizational

relations and characteristics that cannot be completely incorporated into the logic of

transaction cost theory. The terminal-drayage nexus does not conform to a “make-or-

buy” calculus or the common supplier-customer relationship inherent to production

processes. More generally, this points to the need for greater specification of the

differences between production and distribution processes in the application of

transaction cost theory and what would constitute optimal governance arrangements in

intermodal supply chains (see e.g. Pirrong, 1993; Lafontaine & Masten, 2002). Even if

we were able to easily apply transaction cost theory to this case, a second related issue

Page 31: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 31

would immediately emerge – the extent to which costs come into play and, more

specifically, how they are externalized. From the perspective of the terminal operator, the

container has been received, is stacked in the container yard, and is made available for

pickup. The primary costs are associated with container movement, storage and space

utilization rather than expeditious departure. From the perspective of the trucking firm,

there is an interest in moving the container expeditiously to its next destination but while

delays and bottlenecks associated with port terminal entry are widely recognized and

acknowledged, there is no alternative terminal where a container can be obtained, and the

costs are absorbed by the drivers rather than the trucking firms. Externalization of costs,

rather than the absence of costs, in this case, makes the transaction cost model

problematic as a basis for predicting interorganizational arrangements and solutions (see

Bensman, 2009a for a full inventory of externalized costs). This is just one example of

the larger phenomenon in which negative externalities are not cost-accounted for by firms

and, in turn, not reflected in the market price of commodities or services (Patel, 2010).

A second major implication of this study pertains to relations among workers at

different points in the intermodal supply chain. While all are contributing to the

movement of commodities, there are sharp disparities in compensation and working

conditions between workers in the different organizations and industries involved in

intermodal transport and cargo handling. Dual economy and segmented labor market

theories can inform and contribute explanations for these differences but greater theory

and research should be directed toward those occasions of direct interaction between

workers and the translation of structural differences into hostility and antagonism that

impacts both efficiency and labor solidarity. The existence of nonstandard and temporary

labor arrangements, becoming increasingly common, exacerbates social divisions across

the intermodal supply chain.

Among the policy implications, Bensman (2009a) has outlined some of the key

elements in his analysis from the drayage side of the equation. Generally, this would

involve a reregulation of the drayage sector with the objective of more accurately

classifying owner-operators as employees, implementing stricter diesel emission

standards that would remove older trucks from the road, and develop uniform chassis

standards to address highway safety. As already noted, and as Bensman emphasizes,

Page 32: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 32

internalizing costs to trucking firms would provide a strong incentive to invest in the

technologies and electronic information and communication systems that would tighten

the drayage-terminal and drayage-warehouse interface.

In addition, on the port terminal side, there is a need to organize meetings with

and facilitate greater communications between longshore workers and drayage drivers to

discuss the issues of concern and to establish mutual respect and understanding of the

challenges facing both groups of workers in carrying out their jobs. This raises the larger

question of responsibility and accountability in a port economy, which often becomes

muddled under particular port governance arrangements (Brooks, 2003). For example,

under the increasingly dominant “landlord” model, the port leases its property to various

“tenants” (Slack & Fremont, 2005). The landlord port is often reluctant to impose

prescriptive and/or restrictive guidelines and will typically view actions by tenants,

assuming they don’t violate federal or state laws and regulations, as managerial

prerogatives. This can make it more difficult to align the port economy with the interests

of the larger community or the range of stakeholders (Notteboom & Winkelmans, 2003)

or for the port authority to mitigate negative externalities.

Finally, on the drayage issue the recent implementation of clean ports programs,

most notably at the Port of Los Angeles, has brought the status of port responsibility and

drayage driver classification status to the forefront while also potentially addressing,

maybe unintended, the broader efficiency of the drayage-terminal linkage. Because many

owner operators drive older trucks that expel greater levels of toxic diesel emissions, and

because the cost to either upgrade to new models or retrofit is beyond the financial

capacity of most drivers, the Port of Los Angeles mandated that only employee drivers,

rather than independent owner operators, could enter the terminal. This was designed to

improve air quality by ensuring that newer emission compliant vehicles, bought, owned,

and maintained by trucking companies rather than owner operators, would be doing the

local drayage. As employees paid by the hour, and with newer truck models, incentives

would be in place to reduce time delays and implement electronic information and

communication technologies. The Port of LA policy was challenged by the American

Trucking Association, and the employee only provision was deemed unconstitutional. .

However, recent congressional hearings on the Clean Truck programs at the ports of Los

Page 33: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 33

Angeles and Long Beach ended up focusing primarily on the plight of the owner

operators, their contractual arrangements with trucking companies, and their

misclassification as “independent” contractors. There is likely to be further investigation

of this issue and some federal policy proposals that could ultimately impact the drayage-

terminal nexus.

Page 34: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 34

REFERENCES

Aoyama, Y., Ratick, S., & Schwarz, G. (2006). Organizational dynamics of the US logistics industry: An economic geography perspective. The Professional Geographer, 58(3), 327-340.

Arabian Business. (2006). 2006 port acquisitions just the beginning. Arabian Business.Com. December 1. http://www.arabianbusiness.com/4076?tmpl=component&page

Arnesen, E. (1998). Up from exclusion: Black and white workers, race, and the state of labor history. Reviews in American History, 26(1), 146-174.

Baird, A. (2002). Privatization trends at the worlds top-100 container ports. Maritime Policy &# 38; Management, 29(3), 271-284.

Beck, U. (2000). The brave new world of work. Cambridge: Polity Press.

Beck, E., Horan, P. M., & Tolbert, C. M. (1978). Stratification in a dual economy: A sectoral model of earnings determination. American Sociological Review, 43(5), 704-720.

Belman, D. L., & Monaco, K. A. (2001). The effects of deregulation, de-unionization, technology, and human capital on the work and work lives of truck drivers. Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 54(2A), 502-524.

Belzer, M. H. (1995). Collective bargaining after deregulation: Do the teamsters still count? Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 48(4), 636-655.

Belzer, M. H. (2000). Sweatshops on wheels: Winners and losers in trucking deregulation Oxford University Press, USA.

Bensman, D. (2008a). Globalization and the labor markets of the logistics industry. Industry Studies Conference Paper.

Bensman, D. (2009a). PORT TRUCKING DOWN THE LOW ROAD. New York, NY: Demos.

Bensman, D. (2009b). Port trucking: The weak link in the US global logistics train. Industry Studies Association,

Bensman, D., & Bromberg, Y. (2008b). Port truckers survey at New Jersey ports. . New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University.,

Page 35: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 35

Betcherman, G., & Rebne, D. (1987). Technology and control of the labor process: Fifty years of longshoring on the US west coast. Workers, Managers, and Technological Change: Emerging Patterns of Labor Relations, , 73-89.

Bichou, K., & Gray, R. (2004). A logistics and supply chain management approach to port performance measurement. Maritime Policy & Management, 31(1), 47-67.

Bonacich, E. (1972). A theory of ethnic antagonism: The split labor market. American Sociological Review, 37(5), 547-559.

Bonacich, E. (2003). PULLING THE PLUG: Labor and the global supply. New Labor Forum, , 12(2) 41-48.

Bonacich, E., Alimahomed, S., & Wilson, J. B. (2008). The racialization of global labor. American Behavioral Scientist, 52(3), 342.

Bonacich, E., & Wilson, J. B. (2008). Getting the goods: Ports, labor, and the logistics revolution Cornell University Press.

Brooks, M. (2004). The governance structure of ports. Review of Network Economics, 3 (2), 168-183.

Capineri, C., Leinbach, T. R., & Gips, D. (2006). Freight transport, seamlessness, and competitive advantage in the global economy. EJTIR, 6(1), 23-38.

Castells, M. (1996). Rise of the network society: The information age: Economy, society and culture.

Coalition for Healthy Ports. (2009). Driving on fumes: port truck congestion exposes the high cost of doing business in Newark. July. http://www.healthyports.org/fileadmin/files_nynj/Driving_on_Fumes_low_FINAL.pdf

Coase, R. (1937). The nature of the firm. Economica, 4(16), 386-405.

Coe, N. M., Hess, M., Yeung, H. W., Dicken, P., & Henderson, J. (2004). 'Globalizing'regional development: A global production networks perspective. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 29(4), 468-484.

Cummings, S. (1980). White ethnics, racial prejudice, and labor market segmentation. American Journal of Sociology, 85(4), 938-950.

Davis-Blake, A., & Uzzi, B. (1993). Determinants of employment externalization: A study of temporary workers and independent contractors. Administrative Science Quarterly, 38(2), 195-223.

Page 36: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 36

Dickens, W. T., & Lang, K. (1988). The reemergence of segmented labor market theory. The American Economic Review, 78(2), 129-134.

Dill, W. R. (1958). Environment as an influence on managerial autonomy. Administrative Science Quarterly, 2(4), 409-443.

Dube, A., Evans, R., Hall, P., Olney, P., Swearington, V., Willis, A., & Wolff, G. (2004). On the waterfront and beyond: Technology and the changing nature of cargo-related employment in the West coast. Institute for Labor and Employment. University of California. August.

East Bay Alliance for a Sustainable Economy. (2007). Taking the low road. Oakland, CA.: East Bay Alliance for a Sustainable Economy.

Edwards, R., Reich, M., & Gordon, D. M. (1975). Labor market segmentation DC Heath.

Evangelista, P., & Morvillo, A. (1999). Alliances in liner shipping: An instrument to gain operational efficiency or supply chain integration? International Journal of Logistics Research and Applications, 2(1), 21-38.

Finlay, W. (1987). Industrial relations and firm behavior: Informal labor practices in the west coast longshore industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 32(1), 49-67.

Fisher, E. G., & Kondra, A. (1993). Responding to environmental change in longshoring: Four north american experiences. Journal of Labor Research, 14(1), 1-27.

Frémont, A. (2009). Empirical evidence for integration and disintegration of maritime shipping, port and logistics activities. OECD/ITF Joint Transport Research Centre Discussion Papers,

Gereffi, G., & Korzeniewicz, M. (1994). Commodity chains and global capitalism Greenwood Pub Group.

Gereffi, Gary and Gary G. Hamilton. 1996. “Commodity Chains and Embedded Networks: The Economic Organization of Global Capitalism.” Paper presented at the annual meetings of the American Sociological Association, New York City.

Hacker, J. S. (2006). The great risk shift: The assault on american jobs, families, health care, and retirement and how you can fight back Oxford University Press, USA.

Harrison, B., & Sum, A. (1979). The theory of" dual" or segmented labor markets. Journal of Economic Issues, 13(3), 687-706.

Harrison, R., Hutson, N., West, J., & Wilke, J. (2007). Characteristics of drayage operations at the port of houston, texas. Transportation Research Record, 2033(-1), 31-37.

Page 37: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 37

Harvey, D. (1989). The condition of postmodernity: An enquiry into the origins of cultural change Blackwell Pub.

Heaver, T., Meersman, H., Moglia, F., & Van De Voorde, E. (2000). Do mergers and alliances influence european shipping and port competition? Maritime Policy & Management, 27(4), 363-373.

Heaver, T., Meersman, H., & Van De Voorde, E. (2001). Co-operation and competition in international container transport: Strategies for ports. Maritime Policy & Management, 28(3), 293-305.

Heaver, T. D. (1995). The implications of increased competition among ports for port policy and management. Maritime Policy & Management, 22(2), 125-133.

Henderson, J., Dicken, P., Hess, M., Coe, N., & Yeung, H. W. C. (2002). Global production networks and the analysis of economic development. Review of International Political Economy, 9(3), 436-464.

Hesse, M., & Rodrigue, J. P. (2004). The transport geography of logistics and freight distribution. Journal of Transport Geography, 12(3), 171-184.

Hesse, M., & Rodrigue, J. P. (2006). Global production networks and the role of logistics and transportation. Growth and Change, 37(4), 499-509.

International Asset Systems. n.d. “The Virtual Container Yard: Reducing the Operational and Environmental Costs of Container Management”

Ircha, M., & Garey, D. (1992). Labour/management relations in north american ports. Maritime Policy & Management, 19(2), 139-156.

Jacobs, W., Ducruet, C., & De Langen, P. (2010). Integrating world cities into production networks: The case of port cities. Global Networks, 10(1), 92-113.

Jacobs, W., & Hall, P. V. (2007). What conditions supply chain strategies of ports? the case of dubai. GeoJournal, 68(4), 327-342.

Jaffee, D. (2001). Organization theory: Tension and change McGraw-Hill Humanities/Social Sciences/Languages.

Jaffee, D. (2009). Cargo votes with its rudder: The geographic mobility of shipping and the role of labor. Unpublished Manuscript.,

Jaffee, D., & Rowley, A. (2009). Hauling containers: Port drayage drivers in the logistics supply chain. Paper Prepared for Presentation at the Annual Southern Sociological Society Meetings, April, 2009, Atlanta.,

Page 38: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 38

Janelle, D. G., & Beuthe, M. (1997). Globalization and research issues in transportation. Journal of Transport Geography, 5(3), 199-206.

Kalleberg, A. L. (2003). Flexible firms and labor market segmentation: Effects of workplace restructuring on jobs and workers. Work and Occupations, 30(2), 154.

Kalleberg, A. L. (2009). Precarious work, insecure workers: Employment relations in transition. American Sociological Review, 74(1), 1-22.

Kalleberg, A.L. and Schmidt, K. (1996). Contingent employment in organizations: Parttime, temporary, and subcontracting relations. Organizations in America: Analyzing their Structures and Human Resource Practices, , 253-275.

Kalleberg, A. L., & Marsden, P. V. (2005). Externalizing organizational activities: Where and how US establishments use employment intermediaries. Socio-Economic Review, 3(3), 389.

Kalleberg, A. L., Reynolds, J., & Marsden, P. V. (2003). Externalizing employment: Flexible staffing arrangements in US organizations. Social Science Research, 32(4), 525-552.

Kasarda, J. D. (2000). New logistics technologies and infrastructure for the digitized economy. 4th International Conference on Technology Policy and Innovation, 28-31.

Killingsworth, C. C. (1962). Industrial relations and automation. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 340(1), 69.

Lafontaine, F., & Masten, S. E. (2002). Contracting in the absence of specific investments and moral hazard: Understanding carrier-driver relations in US trucking. NBER Working Paper,

Langlois, R. N., & Robertson, P. L. (1995). Firms, markets, and economic change: A dynamic theory of business institutions Routledge.

Levinson, M. (2006). The box: How the shipping container made the world smaller and the world economy bigger Princeton Univ Pr.

Lieb, R., Millen, R., & Van Wassenhove, L. (1993). International Journal of Physical Distribution and Logistics Management, 6(23), 35-44.

Marlow, P. B., & Paixão Casaca, A. C. (2003). Measuring lean ports performance. International Journal of Transport Management, 1(4), 189-202.

Page 39: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 39

Masters, J. K., & Miles, G. (2002). Predicting the use of external labor arrangements: A test of the transaction costs perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 45(2), 431-442.

Meersman, H., & Van de Voorde, E. (2001). International logistics: A continuous search for competitiveness. Handbook of Logistics and Supply-Chain Management, , 61.

Mentzer, J. T., DeWitt, W., Keebler, J. S., Min, S., Nix, N. W., Smith, C. D., et al. (2001). Defining supply chain management. Journal of Business Logistics, 22(2), 1-26.

Milkman, R. (2002). High road or low road? Industrial Relations: Critical Perspectives on Business and Management, , 87.

Monaco, K., Grobar, L., (2005). A study of drayage at the ports of los angeles and long beach METRANS Transportation Center; Available through the National Technical Information Service.

Monaco, K., & Olsson, L. (2005). Labor at the ports: A comparison of the ILA and ILWU. Unpublished Paper, Department of Economics, California State University, Long Beach,

Morlok, E., & Spasovic, L. N. (1994). Redesigning rail-truck intermodal drayage operations for enhanced service and cost performance. Transportation Research Forum, , 34 16–31.

Nelson, B. (2001). Divided we stand: American workers and the struggle for black equality Princeton University Press.

Nickerson, J. A., & Silverman, B. S. (2003). Why firms want to organize efficiently and what keeps them from doing so: Inappropriate governance, performance, and adaptation in a deregulated industry. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48(3), 433-465.

Notteboom, T. E. (2004). Container shipping and ports: An overview. Review of Network Economics, 3(2), 86-106.

Notteboom, T. & Rodrigue, J-P. 2010. The corporate geography of the global container terminal operators. in K. Dobrowolski and J. Zurek (eds), Enterprises on the Global Market, The Foundation of the Development of Gdansk University: Gdansk. Nooteboom, T. & Rodrigue, J-P. (2009). Economic cycles and the organizational and geographical attributes of global value chains: Is the pendulum changing direction. Paper presented at Integrating Maritime Transport in Value Chains workshop, Montreal, June.

Page 40: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 40

Notteboom, T. E., & Rodrigue, J. P. (2005). Port regionalization: Towards a new phase in port development. Maritime Policy & Management, 32(3), 297-313.

Notteboom, T. E., & Winkelmans, W. (2001). Structural changes in logistics: How will port authorities face the challenge? Maritime Policy & Management, 28(1), 71-89.

Olivier, D., & Slack, B. (2006). Rethinking the port. Environment and Planning A, 38(8), 1409-1427.

Osterman, P. (2000). Securing prosperity: The American labor market: How it has changed and what to do about it Princeton University Press.

Panayides, P. M. (2002). Economic organization of intermodal transport. Transport Reviews, 22(4), 401-414.

Panayides, P. M. (2006). Maritime logistics and global supply chains: Towards a research agenda. Maritime Economics &# 38; Logistics, 8(1), 3-18.

Panayides, P. M., & Dong-Wook Song. (2008). Evaluating the integration of seaport container terminals in supply chains

Patel, Raj. 2010. The Value of Nothing: How to Reshape Market Society and Redefine Democracy. Picador. Payne, G. (2007). "Everyone in the pool!," Containerisation International, July.

Peoples, J., & Talley, W. K. (2004). Owner-operator truck driver earnings and employment: Port cities and deregulation. Transportation Labor Issues and Regulatory Reform, Research in Transportation Economics, 10, 191-213.

Pfeffer, J., & Salancik, G. R. (1976). The external control of organizations: A resource dependence perspective Stanford Business Books.

Piore, M. (1972). Notes for a theory of labor market stratification. Working Papers,

Pirrong, S. C. (1993). Contracting practices in bulk shipping markets: A transactions cost explanation. Journal of Law and Economics, 36(2), 937-976.

Piven, F. F. (2006). Challenging authority: How ordinary people change america Rowman & Littlefield Pub Inc.

Port Jobs. (2007). Big rig, short haul: A study of port truckers in seattle. Port Jobs, Seattle, WA,

Prince, T. (2005). Endangered species: Economic instability threatens drayage operators and their customers. Journal of Commerce, , 12–16.

Page 41: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 41

Reich, M., Gordon, D. M., & Edwards, R. C. (1973). A theory of labor market segmentation. The American Economic Review, 63(2), 359-365.

Robinson, R. (2006). Port-oriented landside logistics in australian ports: A strategic framework. Maritime Economics & Logistics, 8(1), 40.

Rodrigue, J. P., & Notteboom, T. (2009). The terminalization of supply chains: Reassessing the role of terminals in port/hinterland logistical relationships. Maritime Policy &# 38; Management, 36(2), 165-183.

Rodrigue, J-P, Comtois, C., Slack, B. (2009). The Geography of Transport Systems. New York: Routledge. Available online at: http://www.people.hofstra.edu/geotrans/index.html

Schwarz-Miller, A., & Talley, W. K. (2002). Technology and labor relations: Railroads and ports. Journal of Labor Research, 23(4), 513-533.

Scott, W. R. (1981). Organizations: Rational, natural, and open systems Prentice hall Upper Saddle River, NJ.

Silver, B. J. (2003). Forces of labor: Workers' movements and globalization since 1870 Cambridge Univ Pr.

Slack, B., 2007, The Terminalization of Seaports, in J. Wang et al. (eds) Ports, Cities, and Global Supply Chains, Aldershot, Ashgate, pp. 41-50.

Slack, B. (1993). Pawns in the game: Ports in a global transportation system. Growth and Change, 24(4), 579-588.

Slack, B., & Frémont, A. (2005). Transformation of port terminal operations: From the local to the global. Transport Reviews, 25(1), 117-130.

Song, D. W., & Panayides, P. (2008). Global supply chain and port/terminal: Integration and competitiveness. Maritime Policy and Management, 35(1), 73-88.

Srour, F. (2010). Dissecting drayage: An examination of structure, information, and control in drayage operations.

Stratton, S. (2000). Marxist theory, the globalization of port development and the role of labour. Journal of Social Change and Critical Inquiry, 2, 11-12.

Taylor, J., & Jackson, G. (2000). Conflict, power, and evolution in the intermodal transportation industry's channel of distribution. Transportation Journal, 39(3), 5-17.

Page 42: Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 1 · Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 3 organizations. A supply chain is defined as “a set of three or

Jaffee, “Kinks in the Intermodal Supply Chain…” 42

Teese, D. J. (1976). Vertical Integration and Vertical Divestiture in the U.S. Oil Industry: Analysis and Policy Implications. Stanford: Stanford University Institute for Energy Studies.

Theofanis, S., Boile, M., Janakiraman, S., & Naniopoulos, A. (2007). Reducing unproductive empty container movements around marine container terminals: The role of a virtual container yard. Proceedings of the 2007 IAME Conference, Athens, Greece,

Turnbull, P. J., & Wass, V. J. (2007). Defending dock workers-globalization and labor relations in the world's ports. Ind.Relat., 46(3), 582-612.

Turner, J. H. (1986). Toward a unified theory of ethnic antagonism: A preliminary synthesis of three macro models. Sociological Forum, , 1(3) 403-427.

Van Der Horst, M. R., & De Langen, P. W. (2008). Coordination in hinterland transport chains: A major challenge for the seaport community. Maritime Economics &# 38; Logistics, 10, 1(2), 108-129.

Watson, R. 1999. "National Drayage Company: Idea Whose Time Has Come?", The Journal of Commerce Home Page, October 19, pp. 1-2.

Williamson, O. E. (1975). Markets and hierarchies, analysis and antitrust implications Simon & Schuster.

Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism. New York: Free Press.

Williamson, O. E. (2008). Outsourcing: Transaction cost economics and supply chain management.. Journal of Supply Chain Management, 44(2), 5-16.

Wright, E. O. (2000). Working-class power, capitalist-class interests, and class compromise 1. American Journal of Sociology, 105(4), 957-1002.