journal of housing economics - southern methodist...

13
Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Housing Economics journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jhec Immigration and housing: A spatial econometric analysis Abeba Mussa a , Uwaoma G. Nwaogu b,, Susan Pozo c a Department of Economics, Farmingdale State College, 2350 Broad Hollow Rd, Farmingdale, NY 11735, USA b Economics, Accounting and Management Department, Central College, 812 University, Pella, IA 50219, USA c Department of Economics, Western Michigan University, 1903 West Michigan Ave, Kalamazoo, MI 49008, USA a r t i c l e i n f o Article history: Received 1 July 2014 Revised 6 August 2016 Accepted 2 January 2017 Available online 3 January 2017 JEL classification: F22 L85 R21 Keywords: Immigration Housing price Housing rent Spatial model Spillover effect a b s t r a c t In this paper we examine the effect of immigration into the U.S. on the U.S. housing market, both in terms of rents and single family house prices. We model the housing market in a spatial econometrics context using the spatial Durbin model. This approach helps us exploit and capture both the direct and indirect effects of immigration inflows on the U.S. housing market. We find that an increase in immi- gration inflows into a particular MSA is associated with increases in rents and with house prices in that MSA while also seeming to drive up rents and prices in neighboring MSAs. The patterns observed in the rental and house price markets, along with the larger spillover effects, are consistent with native-flight from immigrant receiving areas. © 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction For the last three decades, the United States has experienced a surge of immigration. Foreign-born households now account for about 14% of all U.S. households (Trevelyan et al., 2013) and two thirds of projected U.S. population growth from 1995 to 2050 is expected to be due to immigrants and their offspring (National Re- search Council, 1997). Much of the analysis on the effects of immi- gration on the U.S. economy has focused on its impacts on wages and has found mixed results (e.g. Ottaviano and Peri, 2012; Borjas, 2003, Borjas and Katz, 2007). While labor market effects are of in- terest, understanding how immigration affects other facets of the economy is also important. We focus on an area we know rela- tively little about and provide a coherent framework for measuring how immigration influences housing markets in a spatial context. In particular, we focus on the spillover effect of immigration on house prices and housing rents. We argue that immigration can be an important factor that drives house prices and rents, in particular, given immigrant’s re- We are grateful to the suggestions of 2 referees and the editor for numerous suggestions for improving this paper. Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: [email protected] (A. Mussa), [email protected] (U.G. Nwaogu), [email protected] (S. Pozo). cent and projected contributions to U.S. population growth. In principle, new immigrant demand for housing coupled with an upward-sloping housing supply in metropolitan areas (where im- migrants tend to settle) would be expected to yield rising rents and prices (Saiz, 2007). However, we need to also consider the pos- sibility that immigration is associated with decreasing prices and rents. There are a number of mechanisms by which this may take place. For example, if immigration is associated with driving down wages and income in a given area (Altonji and Card, 1991), it is conceivable that we observe an adverse shift in housing demand. This shift in the demand curve—a negative income effect—would likely depress housing values. An alternative mechanism that could result in downward pressure on housing values is if natives dislike residing in areas where immigrants tend to settle. This could lead to offsetting out-migration of natives in response to immigration. Depending on the relative magnitudes of the in-migration of im- migrants and out-migration of natives, we might observe a decline in aggregate housing demand and in housing prices in immigrant settlement areas. The possibility that immigration into an area may result in additional population flows (e.g. out-migration of natives) points to the importance of accounting for geography and for pos- sible spillover effects. In this paper we accomplish such by employ- ing spatial econometric methods. We observe how inflows of new immigrants into an MSA influences the housing market, not only in that MSA, but also in the surrounding MSAs http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jhe.2017.01.002 1051-1377/© 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Upload: others

Post on 01-Jun-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Journal of Housing Economics

journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jhec

Immigration and housing: A spatial econometric analysis

Abeba Mussa

a , Uwaoma G. Nwaogu

b , ∗, Susan Pozo

c

a Department of Economics, Farmingdale State College, 2350 Broad Hollow Rd, Farmingdale, NY 11735, USA b Economics, Accounting and Management Department, Central College, 812 University, Pella, IA 50219, USA c Department of Economics, Western Michigan University, 1903 West Michigan Ave, Kalamazoo, MI 49008, USA

a r t i c l e i n f o

Article history:

Received 1 July 2014

Revised 6 August 2016

Accepted 2 January 2017

Available online 3 January 2017

JEL classification:

F22

L85

R21

Keywords:

Immigration

Housing price

Housing rent

Spatial model

Spillover effect

a b s t r a c t

In this paper we examine the effect of immigration into the U.S. on the U.S. housing market, both in

terms of rents and single family house prices. We model the housing market in a spatial econometrics

context using the spatial Durbin model. This approach helps us exploit and capture both the direct and

indirect effects of immigration inflows on the U.S. housing market. We find that an increase in immi-

gration inflows into a particular MSA is associated with increases in rents and with house prices in that

MSA while also seeming to drive up rents and prices in neighboring MSAs. The patterns observed in the

rental and house price markets, along with the larger spillover effects, are consistent with native-flight

from immigrant receiving areas.

© 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

1

a

a

t

e

s

g

a

2

t

e

t

h

I

h

d

s

(

c

p

u

m

a

s

r

p

w

c

T

l

r

r

t

D

m

i

s

h

1

. Introduction

For the last three decades, the United States has experienced

surge of immigration. Foreign-born households now account for

bout 14% of all U.S. households ( Trevelyan et al., 2013 ) and two

hirds of projected U.S. population growth from 1995 to 2050 is

xpected to be due to immigrants and their offspring ( National Re-

earch Council, 1997 ). Much of the analysis on the effects of immi-

ration on the U.S. economy has focused on its impacts on wages

nd has found mixed results (e.g. Ottaviano and Peri, 2012; Borjas,

003, Borjas and Katz, 2007 ). While labor market effects are of in-

erest, understanding how immigration affects other facets of the

conomy is also important. We focus on an area we know rela-

ively little about and provide a coherent framework for measuring

ow immigration influences housing markets in a spatial context.

n particular, we focus on the spillover effect of immigration on

ouse prices and housing rents.

We argue that immigration can be an important factor that

rives house prices and rents, in particular, given immigrant’s re-

� We are grateful to the suggestions of 2 referees and the editor for numerous

uggestions for improving this paper. ∗ Corresponding author.

E-mail addresses: [email protected] (A. Mussa), [email protected]

U.G. Nwaogu), [email protected] (S. Pozo).

r

p

s

i

i

i

ttp://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jhe.2017.01.002

051-1377/© 2017 Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

ent and projected contributions to U.S. population growth. In

rinciple, new immigrant demand for housing coupled with an

pward-sloping housing supply in metropolitan areas (where im-

igrants tend to settle) would be expected to yield rising rents

nd prices ( Saiz, 2007 ). However, we need to also consider the pos-

ibility that immigration is associated with decreasing prices and

ents. There are a number of mechanisms by which this may take

lace. For example, if immigration is associated with driving down

ages and income in a given area ( Altonji and Card, 1991 ), it is

onceivable that we observe an adverse shift in housing demand.

his shift in the demand curve—a negative income effect—would

ikely depress housing values. An alternative mechanism that could

esult in downward pressure on housing values is if natives dislike

esiding in areas where immigrants tend to settle. This could lead

o offsetting out-migration of natives in response to immigration.

epending on the relative magnitudes of the in-migration of im-

igrants and out-migration of natives, we might observe a decline

n aggregate housing demand and in housing prices in immigrant

ettlement areas. The possibility that immigration into an area may

esult in additional population flows (e.g. out-migration of natives)

oints to the importance of accounting for geography and for pos-

ible spillover effects. In this paper we accomplish such by employ-

ng spatial econometric methods. We observe how inflows of new

mmigrants into an MSA influences the housing market, not only

n that MSA, but also in the surrounding MSAs

Page 2: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25

l

m

s

n

i

C

o

J

m

i

h

t

s

t

a

g

d

h

2

r

t

p

p

m

K

s

t

a

i

a

e

m

t

g

t

a

i

t

b

t

h

p

o

s

t

(

i

i

L

a

a

o

a

(

b

i

p

c

t

(

w

A positive relationship between immigration and housing val-

ues in immigrant receiving areas has been estimated by a number

of researchers. Using a general equilibrium model calibrated to U.S.

conditions, Ottaviano and Peri (2007) conclude that immigrant in-

flows into the U.S. raise rents for natives. Using data on MSAs and

an IV based approach that relies on historical levels of immigration

into metropolitan areas, Saiz (2007) estimates that an immigration

inflow equal to 1 percent of a city’s population is associated with

increases in average rents and housing values of about 1%. Qual-

itatively similar results have been reproduced in other countries

as well. Akbari and Aydede (2012) examine the effect of immi-

gration on house prices in Canada. Their result indicates that a 1

percentage point increase in the immigrant share of the popula-

tion raises house prices in Canada, though, by only a fraction of

a percent. They suggest that the relatively modest effect of immi-

gration might be due to out-migration of local natives from the

areas where new immigrants settle or to increased housing sup-

ply taking place in response to projected increases in immigra-

tion. More dramatic price findings are reported by Gonzalez and

Ortega (2013) who conclude that immigration to Spain in the pre-

vious decade was responsible for a 52% increase in housing values.

In addition they attribute 37% of new construction due to immi-

grants and argue that by contributing to the stock of construction

workers, immigration also propelled an increase in housing supply

experienced by Spain.

While it seems most reasonable to expect that immigration

raises housing values, there are several arguments for expecting

the converse, justifying the findings of a number of researchers

who have found that immigration results in declining housing val-

ues instead. Accetturo et al. (2014) suggest that natives might per-

ceive a deterioration in amenities (e.g. over-crowding) due to the

inflow of immigrants, causing native-flight from immigrant-dense

districts, thus slowing down price appreciation. Using district level

data for a sample of 20 large Italian cities, they show that a 10%

increase in immigrant stocks leads to a fall in housing prices of

2 percentage points in districts affected by the inflow in com-

parison with the rest of the city. Similarly, Sá (2015 ) finds nega-

tive effects of immigration on housing prices using UK data. She

finds evidence that immigration generates a negative income ef-

fect on housing demand by driving out natives who are relatively

high wage earners. Her results also show that the negative effect

is mainly driven in local areas where immigrants have lower levels

of education.

The timing of immigration (immigration vintage effects) may

also influence relative housing values. For example, Akbari and

Aydede (2012) note that immigrants tend to buy housing after a

period of residency in their adopted homelands, while recent im-

migrants tend to rent. We might, therefore observe excess demand

for rental housing units driving up rental prices when immigrants

first move in. But over time, as immigrants move onto becoming

homeowners, they may apply upward pressure on prices for single

family homes. Hence the vintage of immigrants may affect differ-

ent segments of the housing market in different ways. Using the

Mariel boatlift natural experiment, Saiz (2003) concludes that this

population influx raised rents and depressed home values in immi-

grant receiving areas. The Mariel immigrants tended to rent, pos-

sibly propelling natives to purchase housing in other areas. Using

finer distinctions (census tracts instead of MSAs) Saiz and Wachter

(2011) conclude that housing appreciation was slower in immi-

grant neighborhoods, with natives moving out in response to the

in-migration of the newcomers.

The idea that natives may move out when immigrants move

in and that home prices and rental rates may be differentiated by

the timing of immigration, points to the importance of accounting

for the geography of immigration. In addition, we note that im-

migrant settlement patterns tend to be clustered with clustering

ikely due to immigration networks. By reducing the costs of infor-

ation gathering, immigrant networks help channel immigrant to

pecific areas. However, the impact of immigration network might

ot be limited to the cities or MSAs in which immigrants are liv-

ng, but also the surrounding metropolitan areas. Immigrants in

hicago (New York City) are likely to be relatively well informed of

pportunities for new immigrants in Gary, Indiana (Newark, New

ersey). On account of information networks or because new im-

igrants drive older residents out, immigration inflow and hous-

ng prices, in one MSA may be highly spatially correlated with the

ome prices and rents in neighboring MSAs. We, therefore argue

hat it is important to take into account spatial dependence across

pace (MSAs) in order to better understand the effects of immigra-

ion on the housing market. As such we believe it is important to

pply spatial techniques when studying the interaction of immi-

rants with the housing market. In the following section we intro-

uce spatial methods and review how they have been applied to

ousing markets.

. Spatial methods and their application to housing markets

Spatial regression methods are useful for estimating economic

elationship characterized by a data generating process with spa-

ial dependence among observations. For example, we might ex-

ect that house prices in NYC are all relatively high, exhibiting

ositive spatial dependence. Similarly, the price of a house in Kala-

azoo, is likely to be relatively similar to other house prices in

alamazoo (and considerably less than NYC house prices). In this

etting, spatial dependence (rather than spatial independence) bet-

er describes the relationship of one observation to another. There

re a number of ways by which spatial dependence may manifest

tself and a variety of econometric models have been proposed to

ccount for differing data generating processes. Two popular mod-

ls are the spatial error model (SEM) and the spatial autoregressive

odel (SAR). Each model contains only one type of spatial interac-

ion effect ( Elhorst, 2010 ). The SEM incorporates a spatial autore-

ressive process in the error term while the SAR contains a spa-

ially lagged dependent variable as an additional explanatory vari-

ble.

A number of studies have explored the use of spatial methods

n the context of housing markets. DeSilva et al. (2012) examine

he impact of Blacks and Hispanics on house prices in a small ur-

an housing market in the U.S. Using simple OLS they find that

he presence of Blacks in a neighborhood is associated with lower

ouse prices while Hispanic neighborhoods seem to enjoy house

rice premiums. However, when employing, instead, spatial meth-

ds (SEM and SAR) the effect of Blacks in a neighborhood, while

till negative, is smaller and Hispanics do not appear to have a sta-

istically significant impact on housing prices. Basu and Thibodeau

1998) model housing using the SAR model. In their view, hous-

ng prices are autocorrelated spatially because values of properties

n a given neighborhood capitalize on shared location amenities.

ocation amenities such as the quality of the police department,

ssessment of the public schools, percent of the population with

college degree, distance to employment, availability of shopping

r transportation may affect house prices more generally in the

rea. Using data from a region in Norway, Osland and Thorsen

2013) use the SDM to examine how travel time from the central

usiness district and how labor market accessibility affect hous-

ng prices. Fernández-Avilés et al. (2012) examine the impact of air

ollution on housing prices in Madrid, Spain. Employing SDM they

orroborate other studies that fail to find a link between air pollu-

ion and housing prices.

Focusing on the negative externalities, Cohen and Coughlin

2008) note that houses located near noisy areas such as rail-

ay tracks and airports sell for lower prices. They use a spatial

Page 3: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25 15

f

i

I

g

n

e

i

l

a

a

D

(

t

I

p

o

v

r

e

t

w

k

i

i

S

m

i

(

s

h

i

i

f

a

o

o

p

e

2

y

w

t

a

d

y

W

f

a

a

e

f

s

a

p

P

a

w

s

t

r

E

o

t

i

[

s

a

h

p

h

t

i

i

d

d

o

E

S

r

r

r

t

s

t

c

s

a

3

d

d

h

d

(

a

r

ramework to examine the impact of airport-related noise on hous-

ng prices in the neighborhoods near Atlanta’s Harsfield-Jackson

nternational Airport. Based on a noise contour map, they cate-

orized houses into two zones; in one, noise does not disrupt

ormal activities while in the other it does. Employing a gen-

ral spatial econometrics model they show that houses located

n vicinities where noise disrupts normal activities sold for 20.8%

ess than houses located where noise does not disrupt normal

ctivities.

Presently, many spatial econometrics studies have shifted to

model with more than one spatial interaction called a spatial

urbin model (SDM). This model, introduced by LeSage and Pace

2009) , nests both the SAR and the SEM models by including spa-

ial lags of both the dependent variables and explanatory variables.

n addition to being more flexible in accommodating different as-

ects of spatial dependence, the SDM is attractive for its ability to

btain direct, indirect and total marginal effects for the explanatory

ariables, providing us with a more complete understanding of the

elationships we wish to explore. The SDM has only recently been

mployed in the context of housing markets. 1

Given the importance of immigration networks and the spa-

ial relationships we discussed earlier, we surmise that it might be

orthwhile to explore the impact of immigration on housing mar-

ets using the SDM methodology. Given its flexibility in account-

ng for the two models of spatial dependence, and given its abil-

ty to uncover both direct and indirect (or spillover) effects, the

DM is well positioned to model the complexities that follow im-

igration flows and housing prices. Spatial econometrics, however,

s not without its limitations. According to Gibbons and Overman

2012) while spatial econometrics provides a good description of

patial data, techniques for addressing causality in spatial models

ave not been well developed. For the question on hand—how does

mmigration impact house prices and rents—establishing causality

s key. 2 Therefore, in addition to employing spatial techniques, we

ollow Saiz (20 03, 20 07) and Saiz and Wachter (2011) and first

ttempt to achieve identification by modeling the first difference

f the log of rents and prices. We follow this specification with

ne that employs two stage instrumental variables with bootstrap-

ing to obtain unbiased coefficient values with correct standard

rrors.

.1. Marginal effects—spatial Durbin models

The spatial Durbin model can be specified as:

= αI n + X β + ρW y + W X ∅ + ε (1)

here I n denotes the identity matrix and Wy captures spatial in-

erdependence of the dependent variable in the model (see LeSage

nd Pace, 2009 ). The reduced form of the SDM model and implied

ata generating process can be written as:

= ( I n − ρW ) −1

( αl n + X β + W X ∅ ) + ( I n − ρW )

−1 ε with ε ∼ N

(0 , σ 2 I n

)(2)

The direct (feedback) effect estimate is captured by X β while

X captures the indirect (spillover) effect estimate. The total ef-

ects of the explanatory variables are the sum of direct (feedback)

nd indirect effect (spillover) estimates. According to LeSage and

1 See Fernández-Avilés et al. (2012 ) and Osland and Thorsen, 2013 . 2 According to Gibbons and Overman (2012) , natural experiments, IV techniques

nd differencing are alternative measures for dealing with identification although

ach has drawbacks. The IV technique can be used effectively if applied care-

ully with attention to the identification of specific causal parameters. Alternatively,

patial differencing removes relevant omitted variables, eliminating time-invariant,

rea-specific factors that simultaneously affect immigration and the level of house

rices and rents.

b

s

o

F

e

f

t

H

N

ace (2009) , the SDM model has several advantages over the SEM

nd SAR models. The model produces unbiased estimates even

hen the true data-generating process is simply a spatial lag or a

patial error process. Also, SDM does not impose any prior restric-

ions on the magnitude of spillover effects ( Elhorst, 2014 ). In de-

iving the marginal effects of the explanatory variables in the SDM,

lhorst (2010) provides the following matrix of partial derivatives

f the dependent variable in the different units with respect to

he k th explanatory variable in the different units (e.g., x ik for

= 1,…, N ) at time t :

∂y

∂ X 1 k

. . . ∂y

∂ X Nk

]t

=

⎢ ⎢ ⎣

∂ y 1 ∂ X 1 k

· · · ∂ y 1 ∂ X Nk

. . . . . .

. . . ∂ y N ∂ X 1 k

· · · ∂ y N ∂ X Nk

⎥ ⎥ ⎦

= ( I n W ) −1

⎢ ⎢ ⎣

βk w 12 ∅ k · · · w 1 N ∅ k w 21 ∅ βk w 2 N ∅ k

. . . . . .

. . . . . .

w N1 ∅ k w N2 ∅ k · · · βk

⎥ ⎥ ⎦

(3)

Three different marginal effects are obtained when estimating

patial models: direct (feedback) effects, indirect (spillover) effects,

nd total effects ( LeSage and Pace, 2009 ). In the context of the

ousing model, the direct effect records the impact of a housing

rice determinant, (e.g. immigration into that particular MSA) on

ousing prices in that MSA. The indirect (spillover) effect, in con-

rast, measures the effect of the housing price determinant (e.g.

mmigration into a particular MSA) on housing prices in surround-

ng MSAs. LeSage and Pace (2009) point out that the average of the

iagonal elements of the matrix on the right-hand of Eq. (3) is the

irect effect while the indirect effect is given by either the average

f the row or the average of the column (see Elhorst, 2010 ).

Given that the SDM nests both the SEM and the SAR models,

lhorst (2010) shows how one can obtain marginal effects for the

EM or SAR model by imposing restrictions on the matrix on the

ight-hand side of Eq. (3) . In the case of the SEM, the matrix above

educes to a diagonal matrix with βk on the main diagonals. As a

esult, the direct effect of the k th explanatory variable for the spa-

ial error model is βk , while the indirect effect will be zero. For the

patial lag model, ∅ k = 0. Elhorst (2010) notes that even though all

he off-diagonal terms of the right hand side matrix of Eq. (3) be-

ome zero, the marginal effects—direct and indirect effects—in the

patial lag model does not reduce to one single coefficient or zero

s in the spatial error model.

. Data and methodology

The availability of data at the MSA level determined both the

ependent variable and the time period for this study. Our panel

ata consist of 275 MSAs for the rent equation and 282 for the

ome price equation over the 2002–2012 period. Our housing rent

ata are from the Department of Housing and Urban Development

HUD) Fair Market Rent Series (FMR). The FMR corresponds to the

ctual (nominal) dollar price of a vacant 0 bedroom to 4 bedroom

ental unit at the 50% percentile (or median) of the MSA’s distri-

ution. It is calculated annually by HUD using data from the Cen-

us and American Housing Survey (AHS). Data on home prices are

btained from the Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA). Under

HFA, the Office of Federal Housing Enterprise Oversight (OFHEO)

stimates and publishes quarterly home price indexes for single-

amily detached properties. The OFHEO use the data on conven-

ional conforming mortgage transactions obtained from the Federal

ome Loan Mortgage Corporation (Freddie Mac) and the Federal

ational Mortgage Association (Fannie Mae). These are converted

Page 4: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

16 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25

Table 1

Descriptive statistics.

Rent equation Observations Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

Housing rent 3024 767.3 222.5 416.2 2049.6

Immigration inflows 3025 3313.5 13,536.9 11 224,4 4 4

Immigrant t /Pop t −1 2750 0.002061 0.001911 0.0 0 0 035 0.02267

Income per capita (chained 2005 $s) 3005 36905.9 10191.1 15619 90,528

Land per capita 3025 0.00795 0.01156 0.0 0 034 0.154655

Murder (per 10 0,0 0 0) 2687 4.72 3.36 0 28.2

Burglary (per 10 0,0 0 0) 2664 809.2 329.0 219.5 2179

Population 3025 808,391 1,763,195 67,371 19,837,753

Permit 2949 3612.2 7901.1 17 74,007

Unemployment rate (%) 3020 6.54 2.64 2.42 27.2

Population density 2731 2.28801 0.38930 0.8148 3.4296

Price equation

Housing price index 3102 174.2 35.9 102.9 363.1

Immigration inflows 3102 3398.9 13476.1 11 224,4 4 4

Immigrant t /Pop t −1 2821 0.002127 0.002398 0.0 0 0 0 0479 0.02266

Income per capita (chained 2005 $s) 3092 37,004.9 10,334.9 15,619 90,528

Land per capita 3102 0.00788 0.01145 0.0 0 034 0.154655

Murder (per 10 0,0 0 0) 2749 4.70 3.34 0 28.2

Burglary (per 10 0,0 0 0) 2725 806.51 327.96 219.5 2179

Population 3099 821,412 1,757,445 67,371 19,837,753

Permit 3026 3652.5 7860.2 17 74,007

Unemployment rate (%) 3101 6.55 2.63 2.5 27.2

Population density 2731 2.28801 0.38930 0.8148 3.4296

i

a

t

d

p

s

t

O

L

d

t

a

b

c

r

d

g

M

C

a

e

M

o

b

d

a

i

d

a

to an index that measures the movement of single-family home

prices.

The specific data source and some descriptive statistics for

home prices, rents and the other variables incorporated into our

price and rent equations are displayed in Table 1 and Appendix

Table A. Our main right hand side variable of interest, immigra-

tion inflows as a share of the MSA’s population, is derived with

information from the Department of Homeland Security (DHS) on

immigration and this is scaled by census estimates of population

by MSA. DHS reports on the number of “immigrants admitted to

the United States by MSA” specifically admission of foreign-born

individuals as permanent residents into the United States for the

year. 3 Average immigrant inflow for the housing sample is 3399,

slightly higher than the average inflow in the rent sample, 3314.

Nonetheless, the standard deviation is very high, pointing to the

wide dispersion in immigration inflows by geography with some

MSAs experience very large inflows while others receive very small

inflows. Once scaled by MSA population we find that there con-

tinue to be large variations in the immigrant inflows across the

United States with at least one MSA with immigration inflows as

a share of the population reaching 2 and a quarter percent. While

we might expect that immigration will have a positive impact on

rents and house prices, alternative scenarios are also possible. If

natives have a distaste for immigrant neighbors, we might instead

see offsetting outmigration that, to the contrary, depresses hous-

ing values. Or if immigrants impact labor markets by depressing

wages, housing values could instead fall due to a negative income

effect.

We assume that housing rents and housing prices are also in-

fluenced by wealth, land per capita, crime rates, availability of jobs

3 The timing of the admission of a foreign person as a permanent resident does

not necessarily coincide with the actual date of entry into the U.S. The data, also,

do not account for illegal immigrants or foreign-born individuals who stay in the

U.S. temporarily such as tourists and students. Undocumented and temporary im-

migrants usually rent rather than buy houses. The exclusion of these immigrants

would tend to cause us to overstate the effect of immigration on the rental mar-

ket. The housing price market, however, is less likely to be directly affected by the

nflow of illegal or temporary immigrants.

i

A

i

e

s

e

l

n

r

nd potential housing supply and therefore need to incorporate

hese controls in our estimation. Since wealth at the MSA level is

ifficult to obtain, we proxy for it using data on personal income

er capita. These are obtained from the Bureau of Economic Analy-

is (BEA) Regional Information System (REIS). According to the BEA,

his value is the income received by all persons from all sources.

n average, income per capita in our sample is around $37,0 0 0.

and per capita is defined as the MSA’s land area in square miles

ivided by total population of the MSA. Land per capita is indica-

ive of the availability of space and is postulated to have a neg-

tive impact on house prices and rents. We measure crime using

urglary and murder rates. These were obtained from FBI uniform

rime report and are expected to have negative impacts on both

ent and house prices as these characteristics make the MSA a less

esirable area in which to reside.

As we would anticipate, murder rates are much lower than bur-

lary rates. Finally, unemployment and housing permit rates at the

SA level are obtained from the Bureau of Labor Statistics and the

ensus Bureau respectively. Increases in the unemployment rate

re expected to reduce house prices and rents. On average the un-

mployment rate was about 6.5% over the time period in these

SAs. Housing permits are simply the number of new privately

wned housing units authorized by each MSA. As more houses are

uilt, all other things equal, rent and house prices are expected to

ecline.

Table 2 follows up on Table 1 and identifies the different MSAs

ssociated with the highest and lowest values for the variables

n the model. New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island Consoli-

ated Metropolitan Area (CMSA) has the highest immigration rate

nd population, but the lowest land per capita. Santa Fe, New Mex-

co and the New Orleans-Metairie-Kenner, Metropolitan Statistical

reas have the highest burglary and murder rates respectively. Res-

dents of San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, California pay the high-

st rents, while residents of Naples-Marco Island, Florida pay the

teepest housing prices. Las Vegas-Paradise, Nevada has the low-

st home prices and St. Joseph, MO-KS renters are charged the

east. In El Paso, Texas and San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, Califor-

ia unemployment rates are highest and income per capita lowest

espectively among the MSAs.

Page 5: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25 17

Table 2

MSA with minimum and maximum values for each explanatory and dependent variable.

Variable MSA with maximum value MSA with minimum value

Housing price index Naples-Marco Island, FL Las Vegas-Paradise, NV

Rent San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, CA St. Joseph, MO-KS

Immigration rate New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-PA Cheyenne, WY

Immigrant as a share of MSA

population

Charlottesville, VA Charleston-North Charleston, SC; Riverside-San

Bernardino-Ontario, CA

Murder (per 10 0,0 0 0) New Orleans-Metairie-Kenner, LA Wausau, WI; Bangor, ME; Billings, MT; Fargo, ND-MN

Burglary (per 10 0,0 0 0) Santa Fe, NM Bismarck, ND

Population New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-PA Casper, WY

Land per capita Flagstaff, AZ New York-Northern New Jersey-Long Island, NY-NJ-PA

Income per capita San Jose-Sunnyvale-Santa Clara, CA McAllen-Edinburg-Mission, TX

Permit Atlanta-Sandy Springs-Marietta, GA Wheeling, WV-OH

Unemployment El Paso, TX Fort Walton Beach-Crestview-Destin, FL

3

e

(

w

f

w

s

a

i

s

e

t

r

v

c

m

a

w

d

M

d

M

i

p

i

s

o

d

δ

i

s

n

o

M

W

e

y

W

w

p

t

t

4

fi

o

e

a

t

l

f

t

o

t

j

o

p

a

i

a

d

e

e

s

a

t

l

s

5 The spatial weight matrix W can also be column normalized. The interpretation

for column and row normalized matrix is different. For row normalized weight ma-

trix, the row gives the impact on a given unit by all other units. An element of a

column normalized matrix gives the impact of a given unit on all other units. 6 We use MATLAB code written by Paul Elhorst and James LaSage. See Elhorst’s

.1. Model

The study estimates the following SDM to obtain the marginal

ffects of rent and house price determinants.

ln ( H mt ) = ρW l n ( H mt ) +

Immigrant s m t

P opul ation m t−1

. δ1 + X mt β1

+ W

Immigrant s m t

P opulation m t−1

. δ2 + W X mt β2 + �μmt (4)

The dependent variable is the annual change in the log of rent

house prices) in MSA m at time t . Following the housing literature,

e model the first difference of the log of prices and rent. By dif-

erencing the price (rent) variable and employing panel methods,

e help control for time-invariant, area-specific factors that could

imultaneously affect immigration and the level of house prices

nd rents, helping remove a potential source of endogeneity. 4 This

s a conservative solution for achieving identification, given the

tate of spatial econometrics. GMM and 2SLS estimation are not

asily applied in the context of a spatial Durbin model according

o Pace et al. (2012 ) who note that the combination of correlated

egressors and the SDM specification provides a challenging en-

ironment for instrumental variable techniques. In spite of these

hallenges, in a final specification, we employ a two-step instru-

ental variables procedure to more fully account for endogeneity

nd we follow up with corrected standard errors via bootstrapping.

The coefficient ρ , in Eq. (4) and associated with the spatial

eight matrix, W , reflects inherent spatial interdependence in the

ata measuring the impact of rents (house prices) in a particular

SA on rents (house prices) in surrounding MSAs. The indepen-

ent variable of interest is the annual inflow of immigrants into

SA m divided by the MSA’s lagged population while the X matrix

ncludes all the other control variables. As noted in Saiz (2007) , the

arameter, δ1 , associated with the immigrant population ratio, is

nterpreted as the percentage change in rents (house prices) corre-

ponding to an annual inflow of immigrants equal to one percent

f the city’s population. In our case, δ1 and β1 correspond to the

irect effect estimates of immigration on house prices (rents) while

2 and β2 are the parameters for the indirect effect estimates of

mmigration on house prices (rents).

The spatial weight matrix, W , is a block diagonal matrix de-

cribing the arrangement of the spatial units (neighbors). The defi-

ition of neighbors used in the weights matrix is based on the idea

f borders or adjacent areas. The weights matrix assigns weights to

SAs m = i and m = j based on the following criteria:

i j =

⎧ ⎪ ⎨

⎪ ⎩

1 i f MSA i and j are in the same state or in states

that share a border

0 otherwise

4 See Saiz (2007) .

w

w

The diagonal elements of the matrix are set to zero and row el-

ments are standardized such that they sum to one. 5 For any year,

∈ [2002, 2012], W is defined as

=

⎢ ⎢ ⎢ ⎣

0 w i j · · · w ik

w

ji . . .

0 w

jk . . .

w ki w k j · · · 0

⎥ ⎥ ⎥ ⎦

(5)

here w ij defines the functional form of the weights between any

air of host MSAs i and j. We use maximum likelihood (MLE), the

echnique that has been adopted in spatial econometrics when es-

imating the SDM. 6

. Empirical results

Before discussing and comparing estimation results, we need to

rst determine the appropriate model specification that describes

ur data. In Section 2 of this paper, we noted that there are a vari-

ty of spatial models (SEM, SAR) but the incorporation of both into

single model (SDM) has not been commonly used to capture spa-

ial dependence in housing studies. Elhorst (2010 ) provides guide-

ines for determining the appropriate model specification and we

ollow them. We employ the Lagrange Multiplier (LM) test to de-

ermine whether a non-spatial model (OLS), the spatial lag model

r the spatial error model is appropriate. The LM test is based on

he residuals of the OLS model. 7 If the non-spatial model is re-

ected in favor of the spatial lag model, the spatial error model,

r in favor of both models, then the spatial model is the appro-

riate model to use. Table 3 presents the test results (LM classic

nd robust tests) for the different panel model specifications. Us-

ng the classic and robust LM tests, the hypothesis of no spatially

utocorrelated error term and the hypothesis of no spatially lagged

ependent variable were both rejected at the 1% significance lev-

ls (except for the rent equation with MSA and time period fixed

ffects, which was rejected at the 6% level). Overall these results

uggest that a spatial model rather than a non-spatial model is the

ppropriate model to use.

We also test whether unobserved heterogeneities (spatial and

ime period fixed effects) are jointly significant by performing like-

ihood ratio (LR) tests. The test results for the hypothesis that the

patial fixed effects are not jointly significant cannot be rejected

ebsite, http://www.regroningen.nl/elhorst/software.shtml and LaSage’s website

ww.spatial-econometrics.com/ . 7 See Matlab software for spatial panels by Elhorst (2010) .

Page 6: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

18 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25

Table 3

Test results for choosing between spatial and non-spatial models.

ln rent log house price

MSA fixed effect Time-period fixed

effect

MSA and

time-period fixed

effect

MSA fixed effect Time-period fixed

effect

MSA and

time-period fixed

effect

LM spatial lag(classic) 5304.443 156.404 138.530 5027.875 6 882.4 94 6203.984

[0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0]

LM spatial error (classic) 5330.378 146.788 130.442 8742.024 7616.052 7167.980

[0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.002] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0]

Robust LM SAR 29.238 19.212 11.551 316.018 39.091 143.922

[0.0 0 0] [0.013] [0.001] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0]

Robust LM SEM 55.174 9.596 3.464 4030.167 772.650 1107.918

[0.0 0 0] [0.002] [0.063] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0]

LR tests for the joint 246.713 258.831

Significance of spatial fixed effects [0.889] [0.8353]

LR tests for the joint 838.063 11545.834

Significance of time-period fixed effects [0.0 0 0] [0.0 0 0]

Notes : Probability values are in square brackets: ∗significant at 10%; ∗∗significant at 5%; ∗∗∗significant at 1%.

p

r

i

o

o

(

T

t

C

g

t

p

n

p

t

c

M

p

t

r

p

g

n

t

2

w

t

g

s

p

f

w

r

o

i

for both housing rent (246.7, p > 0.01) and house price (258.8,

p > 0.01) estimations. To the contrary, the test results for the hy-

pothesis that the time-period fixed effects are not jointly signif-

icant is rejected for both rent (838.1, p < 0.01) and house price

(11545.8, p < 0.01) estimations. These test results seem to justify

the extension of the model with only time period-fixed effects.

Since the OLS specification is rejected in favor of spatial mod-

els we proceed by estimating the SDM model. Recall that the SDM

nests both the SEM and the SAR models. We determine whether

or not the SDM can be simplified to one or the other (spatial lag

or spatial error model) using a Wald test ( Elhorst, 2010 ). Based on

the Wald test as well as the LR test result shown at the bottom

of column II of Tables 4 and 5 , the spatial lag and the spatial er-

ror model were rejected in favor of the SDM. We therefore use the

SDM model to describe rents and house prices.

The novelty of the SDM method is its ability to disaggregate the

marginal (total) effects into direct and indirect effects as displayed

in Tables 4 and 5 . The first column of each specification records

the direct effect – the impact of changes in determinants on rents

or house prices in a particular MSA. The indirect or spillover effect,

displayed in the second column of each specification, measures the

impact of rent (or price) determinants in a particular MSA on rents

(prices) in surrounding MSAs. The total effect is the sum of both

direct and indirect effects.

4.1. Rents

Table 4 presents the results for the rent equation with specifica-

tions I and II displaying the SDM results prior to and after control-

ling for unobserved fixed heterogeneities. One might further ques-

tion whether one should incorporate business cycle effects. The

problem is that there are no known model specification tests that

can attest to the appropriateness of their inclusion. We, nonethe-

less, report and discuss on a model incorporating business cycle

effects as displayed in Appendix Tables B and C for the rent and

house price models respectively. 8 Inspection of the business cycle

estimates reveal that the main results are very similar to specifi-

cations I and II. Given, therefore, the inability to assess the appro-

8 In the regional business cycle specification displayed in the Appendix, we in-

clude regional effects, and the interaction of such regional effects with a dummy

for the last 5 years in our sample. A quinquennial dummy separates the 20 02–20 07

boom period from the 2007–2012 bust period. In other words, we controlled for un-

observable trends that varied across regions and in two distinct periods of time. The

interaction term based on the four regions (Northeast, Midwest, West, and South),

and the housing boom (20 02–20 07) and housing bust (2008–2012) periods are in-

cluded and displayed in Appendix Tables B and C .

p

(

s

l

d

o

d

l

riateness of Business Cycle specification, we simply report these

esults and note that they are very similar to the results obtained

n specifications I and II—specifications we can formally evaluate.

The spatial coefficient, ρ , on ( W

∗rent), displayed in the first row

f Table 4 , is highly significant in all specifications suggesting that

ur estimation strategy is appropriate. When rents in one MSA rise

fall), the rents in surrounding MSAs tend to rise (fall) as well.

urning now to the explanatory variables, the methodology splits

he “total effect” into two—the “direct effect” and “indirect effect.”

onsidering first, the direct effect in specification I, the results sug-

est that immigration is positively associated with housing rents at

he MSA level. Specifically, the coefficient on immigration is inter-

reted as the percentage change in rents corresponding to an an-

ual inflow of immigrants equal to 1% of the MSA’s prior period’s

opulation. Before controlling for unobserved heterogeneities (Spa-

ial Durbin Model I), our results suggest that rent in an MSA in-

reased by 1.18% with an inflow of immigrants equal to 1% of the

SA’s population. A similar result holds after we control for time-

eriod fixed effects (specification II). Immigrant inflows equivalent

o 1% of the MSA’s population is associated with a 1.165% rise in

ents. A similar result is found in the Business cycle model dis-

layed in Appendix Table B . These results are intuitive as they sug-

ests that immigrant arrivals put pressure on rents as individuals

eed to secure places to live, positively affecting housing rents in

hose MSAs. Similar empirical results were obtained by Saiz (2003,

007) , and Susin (2001) , who find that rents are higher in cities

ith increased immigration.

The indirect effect results across the different model specifica-

ion (I and II and the Business Cycle model) indicate that immi-

rant arrivals into a particular MSA are associated with a positive

pillover (indirect) effect on surrounding MSAs and the effect ap-

ears to be larger relative to the direct effect. Prior to controlling

or unobserved heterogeneities, rent is found to increase by 12%

ith an immigration inflow of immigrants equal to 1% of the sur-

ounding MSAs population. A more modest impact, roughly 8%, is

bserved when we control for time-period fixed effects as we do

n model II while the business cycle model suggests a 7% rise.

Our result so far only tangentially account for endogeneity. The

anel structure along with the transformed dependent variable

percent change in price/rent)) helps correct for endogeneity by

weeping away fixed unobservable variables that could be corre-

ated with immigration and rents/home prices. However, an ad-

itional source of endogenity could nonetheless still be present

n account of reverse causality. It is logical that immigrants are

riven by housing costs, for example, moving to areas that offer

ower prices and rents. To further address endogeneity we use an

Page 7: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

A. M

ussa

et a

l. / Jo

urn

al o

f H

ou

sing E

con

om

ics 3

5 (2

017

) 13

–2

5

19

Table 4

Housing rent estimation.

Dependent variable �ln( Rent mt )

Spatial Durbin model I Spatial Durbin fixed effects model II SDM instrumental variables model III

Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect

ρ 0.801 ∗∗∗

(0.023)

0.412 ∗∗∗

(0.050)

0.467 ∗∗∗

(0.003)

Immigration t /Pop t −1 1.184 ∗∗

(0.546)

12.495 ∗

(7.216)

13.680 ∗

(7.308)

1.165 ∗∗

(0.536)

8.200 ∗∗∗

(2.907)

9.364 ∗∗

(2.897)

0.792 ∗∗∗

(0.072)

1.612 ∗∗

(0.777)

2.404 ∗∗∗

(0.728)

Murde t −1 0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

0.004

(0.005)

0.004

(0.005)

0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

0.004 ∗∗

(0.002)

0.004 ∗

(0.002)

0.0 0 0 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

0.002 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

ln Burglary t −1 0.002

(0.002)

0.015

(0.026)

0.017

(0.027)

0.002

(0.002)

−0.007

(0.013)

−0.005

(0.013)

−0.001 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.005 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

−0.006 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

Land per capita −0.031

(0.083)

−0.615

(0.978)

−0.646

(0.992)

−0.004

(0.081)

−0.358

(0.358)

−0.398

(0.356)

−0.046 ∗∗∗

(0.002)

−0.206 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

−0.252 ∗∗∗

(0.010)

ln Income per capita 0.003 ∗∗

(0.001)

0.002

(0.011)

0.004

(0.011)

0.003 ∗∗

(0.001)

−0.001

(0.008)

0.001

(0.009)

0.001 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.004 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

−0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

ln Permit −0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

−0.016

(0.012)

−0.019

(0.012)

−0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

−0.010 ∗

(0.006)

−0.013 ∗∗

(0.006)

−0.002 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

0.001

(0.001)

Unemployment t −1 0.0 0 0

(0.001)

−0.006 ∗

(0.003)

−0.006 ∗

(0.003)

0.0 0 0

(0.001)

−0.004 ∗∗

(0.002)

−0.004 ∗∗

(0.002)

−0.0 0 0 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

−0.001 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

Observation 2750 2750 2750

Log-likelihood 4715.537 4780.716 4831

Time fixed effect No Yes Yes

Wald test, spatial lag 14.681 [0.040] 5.658 [0.580]

Wald test, spatial 16.476 [0.021] 6.106 [0.5274]

LR test, spatial lag 14.792 [0.039] 5.654 [0.5806]

LR test, spatial 16.644 [0.020] 6.126 [0.5251]

Notes : Standard errors are in parentheses. The probability values for the various tests are in square brackets. Probabilities smaller than 0.05 point to significance of Wald or LR test. The dependent variable is the annual change

in the ln of rent in MSA m at time t . ∗ Significant at 10%. ∗∗ Significant at 5%. ∗∗∗ Significant at 1%.

Page 8: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

20

A. M

ussa

et a

l. / Jo

urn

al o

f H

ou

sing E

con

om

ics 3

5 (2

017

) 13

–2

5

Table 5

Housing price estimation.

Dependent Variable is �log ( Price mt )

Spatial Durbin model I Spatial Durbin FE model II SDM instrumental variables model III

Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect

ρ 0.906 ∗∗∗

(0.012)

0.881 ∗∗∗

(0.015)

0.877 ∗∗∗

(0.003)

Immigrant t /Pop t −1 −0.875 ∗∗∗

(0.183)

−24.470 ∗∗∗

(6.205)

−25.345 ∗∗∗

(6.300)

−0.700 ∗∗∗

(0.186)

−11.753 ∗

(6.086)

−12.452 ∗∗

(6.189)

0.810 ∗∗∗

(0.047)

9.594 ∗∗∗

(0.520)

10.404 ∗∗∗

(0.539)

Murder 0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

0.002

(0.006)

0.002

(0.006)

0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

0.003

(0.005)

0.002

(0.005)

0.0 0 0 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.001 ∗∗∗

(0.004)

−0.001 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

log Burglary −0.006 ∗∗∗

(0.002)

−0.173 ∗

(0.071)

−0.180 ∗

(0.072)

−0.006 ∗∗∗

(0.002)

−0.129 ∗∗

(0.060)

−0.135 ∗∗

(0.061)

−0.002 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.046 ∗∗∗

(0.003)

−0.049 ∗∗∗

(0.003)

Land per capita 0.136 ∗∗∗

(0.032)

0.480

(0.824)

0.617

(0.835)

0.128 ∗∗∗

(0.032)

0.201

(0.679)

0.329

(0.690)

0.148 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

−0.265 ∗∗∗

(0.023)

−0.117 ∗∗∗

(0.023)

log Income per Capita 0.001

(0.001)

0.010

(0.035)

0.011

(0.035)

0.0 0 0

(0.002)

−0.029

(0.083)

−0.030

(0.084)

−0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.151 ∗∗∗

(0.004)

−0.154 ∗∗∗

(0.004)

log Permit 0.004 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

0.153 ∗∗∗

(0.024)

0.157 ∗∗∗

(0.024)

0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

0.104 ∗∗∗

(0.031)

0.107 ∗∗∗

(0.032)

0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

0.031 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

0.031 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

Unemployment −0.001 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 02)

0.006 ∗∗

(0.003)

0.906

(0.012)

−0.002 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 02)

−0.003

(0.003)

−0.005

(0.004)

−0.002 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.012 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

−0.014 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

Observation 2820 2820 2820

Log-likelihood 7445.497 7433.129 7447

Time Fixed Effect No Yes Yes

Wald test, spatial lag 20.194 [0.005] 17.23 [0.016]

Wald test, spatial error 20.214 [0.005] 19.35 [0.007]

LR test, spatial lag 20.218 [0.005] 17.11 [0.017]

LR test, spatial error 20.348 [0.005] 18.93 [0.008]

Notes : Standard errors are in parentheses. The probability values for the various tests are in square brackets. Probabilities smaller than 0.05 point to significance of Wald or LR test. The dependent variable is the annual change

in the log of housing prices in MSA m at time t . ∗ Significant at 10%. ∗∗ Significant at 5%. ∗∗∗ Significant at 1%.

Page 9: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25 21

i

c

T

t

(

i

s

w

g

o

b

i

a

e

u

h

M

a

t

a

f

v

g

T

c

p

t

g

a

o

s

(

t

g

i

i

r

r

v

fi

t

fl

m

v

t

d

t

m

m

m

w

t

c

w

i

i

t

r

h

r

c

p

t

a

t

t

n

l

f

h

4

p

W

M

r

c

u

t

W

m

s

I

T

d

I

t

t

t

i

1

w

s

o

e

ability values reported under specification III are not corrected and cannot properly

interpret the fit of the model. 10 The “peso problem” refers to the idea that low probability events might not be

properly reflected in the price of an asset ( Sill, 20 0 0 ). 11 A procedure, comparable to that used in the rent estimation, was used to obtain

an instrument for immigration in the case of the house prices and subsequently

estimate the spatial model for house prices. However given the slightly different

availability of data for house price and rent series, (the house price series is avail-

able for 282 MSAs while the house rent series for 275 MSAs) the house price first

stage estimation required a new set of 150 replications for immigration inflows in

order to obtain appropriate standard errors. The far right two columns of Appendix

nstrumental variable approach that focuses on year to year

hanges in immigration inflows. As in Saiz (2007) , we construct a

shift-share” prediction of the inflow of immigrants into each MSA.

he prediction of immigration into MSA m at time t is based on

he total number of new immigrants in the United States in year t

immigrants US,t ) multiplied by the share of all US immigrants resid-

ng in that specific MSA in 1990:

hi f t share _ im m mt = ϕ m 1990 × immigrant s USt (6)

here shi f t share _ im m mt is the estimated number of new immi-

rants in metropolitan area m in year t and ϕm 1990 is the share

f all U.S. immigrants who resided in MSA m in 1990. The idea

ehind this variable is that immigration flows are propagated and

nfluenced by networks. Immigrants are likely to flow to areas that

lready house large numbers of immigrants.

After constructing the “shift share” variable for each period and

ach MSA, we estimate the model with the “shift share” variable

sing a 2SLS procedure. However, since an appropriate estimator

as not been worked out in the context of the Spatial Durbin

odel, we manually employ 2SLS to obtain coefficient estimates

nd follow up by obtaining bootstrapped standard errors. In order

o construct the immigration IV (first stage regression), we gener-

ted predictions for immigration to each MSA by estimating the

ollowing equation:

( ln immigration in f low ) mt = α0 + α1

( shi f t share _ im m mt

)+ α2 ( Murde r mt ) + α3 ( l nBurgl ar y mt )

+ α4 ( Land per Capit a mt ) + α5 ( lnIncome per Capit a mt )

+ α6 ( lnP ermi t mt ) + α7 ( unemploymen t mt )

+ t ime f ixed e f f ect s + e mt . (7)

Using the estimated coefficients from Eq. (7) along with actual

alues for all the explanatory variables, predicted ln(annual immi-

rant inflow) mt for all 275 MSAs in each time period is obtained.

hese values are transformed to immigrant t /population t −1 and in-

orporated into the spatial model for rent—part two of the 2-step

rocedure.

Appendix Table D displays the first stage coefficients along with

he corrected (bootstrapped) standard errors for the first stage re-

ression. The standard errors were obtained by generating 150 sep-

rate random samples without replacement of approximating 80%

f the 275 MSAs we work with. The standard deviation of the re-

ulting sampling distribution for each coefficient is the reported

bootstrapped) standard error in the first stage regression. Inspec-

ion of the first stage results suggest that the natural log of immi-

ration in an MSA is positively related to the share of immigrants

n that MSA in 1990, to per capita income, the issuance of build-

ng permits and to unemployment in the MSA. By contrast, murder

ates, burglary activity and land area per capita are all negatively

elated to the natural log of immigration. All of the explanatory

ariables are statistically significant at conventional levels for the

rst step in the rent estimation.

The second step of our estimation requires that we incorporate

he results of the first stage regression—predicted immigration in-

ows as a share of the population—into the SDM model and esti-

ate it. The standard errors in the SDM model are also obtained

ia bootstrapping. That is, the SDM model (4) is estimated 150

imes employing the predicted (immigrant t /population t −1 ) vector

erived from each of the 150 iterations of ( 7 ). In this way we ob-

ain sampling distributions for the coefficients in Eq. (4) , the SDM

odel with which to compute appropriate standard errors. 9

9 While we obtain corrected standard errors for the coefficients in the IV-SDM

odel, we cannot assess the probability value for the Wald and LR tests. The prob-

T

c

u

o

h

Inspection of the instrumented results, while a bit different in

agnitude, are similar in “spirit” to the earlier model specifications

ith respect to the main explanatory variable of interest, immigra-

ion inflows. A one percent rise in immigration to an MSA is asso-

iated with a 0.8% rise in rents. The indirect effect is about doubled

ith a 1% increase in immigration to an MSA raising rents by 1.6%

n surrounding areas. This result is somewhat more tempered than

n the case of the non-instrumented models. The other explana-

ory variables in the IV SDM model are somewhat intuitive. With

espect to the direct effects, burglary, land per capita, supply of

ousing (permits), and unemployment are associated with lower

ents, while income is associated with higher rents. The positive

oefficient on murder is not intuitive. Given that murder is a low

robability event perhaps this is reflective of a “peso problem” in

he case of housing markets with respect to some forms of crime. 10

Overall then, we have found that inflows of immigrants into

particular MSA are not only associated with increasing rents in

hat MSA, but also rents in surrounding MSAs. Also of note is that

he size of the immigration coefficients is quite different in mag-

itude with the spillover (indirect) effects appearing to be much

arger. These are interesting patterns that beg an explanation. Be-

ore further discussing these results in context, we examine the

ouse price market to see whether similar patterns are observed.

.2. House prices

The empirical results for the housing price equations are dis-

layed in Table 5 . Similar to rent, the spatial coefficient, ρ , on

∗rent, is highly significant suggesting that house prices in one

SA are positively affected by prices in surrounding MSAs and cor-

oborates the choice of a spatial model. Inspection of the main

o-variate of interest (immigration as a share of the MSA’s pop-

lation) across models reveals that, unlike in the case for rents,

he results of the non-IV and IV models do not coincide in spirit. 11

hile immigration is associated with increases in prices in the IV

odel, they are associated with decreases in prices in the non-IV

pecification. The difference in results in the case of IV and non-

V specifications, underscores the need to account for endogeneity.

he differential results may be the result of coefficient bias intro-

uced on account of the use of an endogenous regressor in models

, II, and in the Business Cycle model. For this reason we center

he remaining discussion on the instrumented results. According

o specification III, immigration inflows have a direct effect elas-

icity of 0.8. This implies that housing prices in a particular MSA

ncrease by about 0.8% following an inflow of immigrants equal to

% of the MSA’s population. This result is in keeping with rents

hich saw a similar increase. As in the rent model, the indirect or

pillover effect is larger than the direct effect. But the magnitude

f the difference is much larger. An increase in immigration inflows

quivalent to 1% of an MSA’s population increases house prices in

able D display the coefficient values along with the corrected standard errors. The

oefficient values for price are similar in sign though with somewhat different val-

es. As with the rent sample, all the coefficients are significant, with the exception

f burglary, which does not seem to be associated with immigration flows in the

ouse first stage regression.

Page 10: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

22 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25

Table 6

Native, immigrant estimation—spatial model.

Dependent variable �log( natives mt )

Time fixed effect Spatial and time fixed effect

Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect

ρ 0.127 ∗

(0.066)

0.124 ∗

(0.066)

log Immigration t −1 −0.053 ∗∗∗

(0.005)

0.075 ∗∗∗

(0.018)

0.020 ∗

(0.018)

−0.053 ∗∗∗

(0.005)

0.081 ∗∗∗

(0.017)

0.028 ∗

(0.018)

log Income per capita 0.023

(0.028)

0.035

(0.102)

0.058

(0.013)

0.028

(0.028)

0.168

(0.100)

0.196 ∗∗

(0.096)

Murder 0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

−0.003 ∗

(0.001)

−0.002

(0.002)

0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

−0.002 ∗

(0.002)

−0.001

(0.002)

log Burglary −0.002

(0.006)

0.020

(0.021)

0.018

(0.019)

−0.002

(0.006)

0.019

(0.028)

0.017

(0.029)

Unemployment t −2 −0.001 ∗

(0.001)

0.001

(0.002)

−0.0 0 0

(0.002)

−0.001 ∗

(0.001)

0.003 ∗

(0.002)

−0.002

(0.001)

Population Density −0.044 ∗∗∗

(0.007)

0.064

(0.047)

0.021

(0.780)

−0.043 ∗∗∗

(0.007)

0.090 ∗

(0.049)

0.047

(0.049)

Observation 2730 2730

Log-likelihood 6343.92 6360.196

Wald test, spatial lag 63.377 [0.0 0 0] 33.973 [0.0 0 0]

Wald test, spatial 44.653 [0.0 0 0] 27.127 [0.0 0 0]

LR test, spatial lag 68.879 [0.0 0 0] 37.969 [0.0 0 0]

LR test, spatial 55.551 [0.0 0 0] 34.392 [0.0 0 0]

Notes : Standard errors are in parentheses. The probability values for the various tests are in square brackets. Probabilities smaller than 0.05 point

to significance of Wald or LR test. ∗ Significant at 10%. ∗∗ Significant at 5%. ∗∗∗ Significant at 1%.

l

t

a

r

d

t

I

i

n

f

n

o

r

i

i

r

i

r

i

n

t

l

a

p

surrounding areas by close to 10%, quite a bit more in comparison

to the rental market.

4.3. Explanation for larger indirect effect

The estimates are suggesting that the indirect effect of immi-

gration on rents and house prices is much larger than the di-

rect effect. There are a number of plausible explanations for the

large spillover. A strong network effect may operate. When immi-

grants settle in a particular MSA, they may draw additional im-

migrant relatives and friends to settle in surrounding MSAs in or-

der to be close by and as such may explain the larger indirect ef-

fect. An alternative mechanism that could be at play is that im-

migrants moving to one MSA “push out” older residents. Perhaps

this is a manifestation of distrust of immigrant neighbors. Frey

(1995) , found that immigration plays an important role in the re-

distribution patterns of the U.S. population by influencing inter-

nal migration which is selective on race and socio-economic sta-

tus. Using 1990 Census data, Frey argues that natives, especially

whites, move-out from high-immigration areas. Similarly, Borjas

(2006) used census data from the 1960–2000 decennial censuses

to examine the impact of immigration on internal migration be-

havior of native-born workers. His result shows that “for every ten

immigrants who enter a particular MSA, between three and six na-

tives will choose not to live in that locality.”(p. 255).

Following Frey (1995) and Borjas (2006) , we explore the “native

out-migration” channel to see whether immigrants moving to one

MSA displace or “push out” older residents. If so, we can argue that

finding a larger indirect effect over the direct effect is consistent

with a displacement explanation. The native out-migration channel

is considered by estimating the following SDM equation: 12

12 Rather than estimating separate “native out-migration” equations for rent and

house price samples, we estimate one equation by using all the MSAs that are in

both rent and price equations. The MSA overlap is almost complete with only nine

MSAs in the rent sample not included in the house price sample and two MSAs in

house price sample that are not in housing rent sample. In total the equation we

estimate contains 273 MSAs.

5

e

p

log ( Nati v e mt ) = ρW l n ( Nati v e mt ) + l ogImmi g m t−1 . δ1 + X mt β1

+ W logImmi g m t−1 . δ2 + W X mt β2 + �μmt (8)

The dependent variable is the change in the log of native popu-

ation in MSA m at time t , while the main independent variable is

he log of immigrants. In addition to the immigration variable, we

lso controlled for GDP per capita, the unemployment rate, murder

ates, burglary rates and population density. Population density is

efined as the ratio of the number of people in MSA m divided by

he land area of the MSA.

Table 6 provides the result of the native, immigrant estimation.

n Specification I we controlled for MSA fixed effect while in spec-

fication II, we controlled for both MSA and time fixed effects. The

egative direct effect in conjunction with the positive indirect ef-

ect is consistent with the notion that inflows of immigrants cause

ative-flight. While the negative direct effect indicates that inflow

f immigrants in a particular MSA reduces the number of natives

esiding in that area the positive indirect effect shows an increase

n the number of natives in surrounding MSAs. A 1% increase in

mmigration inflows is associated with a 0.05% fall in the growth

ate of the native population. The indirect effect coefficient value

s positive and a tad higher at 0.08. This implies that the same 1%

ise in immigration inflows into an MSA is associated with a 0.08%

ncrease in native population growth in the surrounding MSAs. If

atives are moving from larger population areas to smaller popula-

ion areas, the larger indirect effect is plausible. Native-flight might

ie behind one of our main findings, a stronger indirect effect rel-

tive to direct effect estimate of immigration on rents and house

rices.

. Conclusions and discussion

Using data that span from 2002–2012, we find, as have oth-

rs, that immigration inflows are associated with rising rents and

rices. In our final specification, where we employ IV techniques

Page 11: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25 23

t

g

i

i

s

o

a

a

p

i

c

i

t

fi

r

i

n

t

t

t

l

a

b

t

r

t

l

h

s

fl

u

t

m

r

i

A

Table B

Spatial Durbin business cycle model for rent.

Dependent variable �ln( Rent mt )

Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect

P 0.412 ∗∗∗

(0.052)

Immigrant t /Pop t −1 1.108 ∗∗

(0.556)

7.261 ∗∗

(3.401)

8.369 ∗∗

(3.431)

Murder 0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

0.004

(0.003)

7.261 ∗∗

(3.401)

ln Burglary 0.001

(0.002)

−0.019

(0.018)

0.004

(0.003)

Land per capita −0.048

(0.080)

−0.336

(0.595)

−0.019

(0.018)

ln Income per capita 0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

0.007

(0.012)

−0.336

(0.595)

ln Permit −0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

−0.014 ∗

(0.007)

0.007

(0.012)

Unemployment 0.0 0 0

(0.001)

−0.003

(0.003)

−0.014 ∗

(0.007)

Northeast 0.003

(0.010)

−0.014

(0.019)

−0.010

(0.017)

Midwest 0.001

(0.007)

0.010

(0.014)

−0.009

(0.014)

West −0.001

(0.007)

−0.003

(0.016)

−0.004

(0.014)

Northeast ∗Bust −0.002

(0.005)

−0.002

(0.016)

−0.004

(0.012)

Midwest ∗Bust −0.012

(0.013)

0.004

(0.019)

−0.008

(0.012)

West ∗Bust 0.008

(0.012)

0.001

(0.016)

0.009

(0.010)

Observations 2750

Log-likelihood 4786.735

Time fixed effect Yes

Wald test, spatial lag 11.387 [0.578]

Wald test, spatial error 12.635 [0.476]

LR test, spatial lag 11.287 [0.587]

LR test, spatial error 12.721 [0.470]

Notes : Standard errors are in parentheses. The probability values for the various

tests are in square brackets. Probabilities smaller than 0.05 point to significance of

Wald or LR test. Bust is a dummy variable equaling 0 from 20 03–20 07 and 1 from

2008–2012. ∗ Significant at 10%. ∗∗ Significant at 5%. ∗∗∗ Significant at 1%.

o account for potential endogeneity, we find that a rise in immi-

ration inflows, equivalent to one percent of an MSA’s population,

s associated with an approximate eight-tenths of a percent rise

n rents. More importantly, the SDM methodology that we employ

hows, in addition, that the rent effects of immigrant inflows into

ne MSA spillover to neighboring MSAs. Immigrant inflows equiv-

lent to one percentage point of an MSA’s population are associ-

ted with a 1.6% increase in rents in surrounding MSAs. A similar

attern is found in house prices. The same increase in immigrant

nflows appears to drive house prices up by 0.8%. However, in the

ase of house prices the spillover is much larger, leading to a 9.6%

ncrease in home prices in the surrounding MSAs.

Furthermore, we find that immigrant inflow into an MSA seem

o be driving natives out and into surrounding MSAs. Hence our

ndings are suggestive of increase in rents and prices in sur-

ounding areas as being driven by native population movements

n response to immigrant inflows. Immigration appears to induce

ative-flight, possibly explaining the pattern in rents and prices

hat we observe across geography.

We find it curious that while the direct effects of immigra-

ion on rents and house prices in an MSA are similar in magni-

ude, the spillover effects in the house price market are so much

arger. A rise in immigration inflows, equivalent to one percent-

ge point of an MSA’s population raises rents in neighboring MSAs

y 1.8% while house prices rise by 9.6%. What might be driving

he larger spillover effect in the house price market relative to the

ental market? A number of reasons could explain the differen-

ial spillovers. One possibility is that the immigration inflows that

ead to native flight result not only in natives moving into rental

ousing in neighboring MSAs, but also a good percentage of those

witching into the house market from the rental market. Native

ight might provide an opportune time for those leaving a rental

nit in an immigrant receiving area to switch from being a renter

o a homeowner. Those higher demand pressures in the housing

arket might explain the larger indirect impacts for house prices

elative to rentals. Overall, these results point to complex dynamics

n housing markets following immigration.

ppendix

Table A

Variable definitions and data source.

Variable Description Source

Housing rent Fair market rent corresponds to the price of a vacant 0

bedroom to 4 bedroom rental units

Department of Housing and Urban Development (HUD)

http://www.huduser.org/portal/datasets/50per.html

House price index (HPI) The HPI is a broad measure of the movement of

single-family house prices

Federal Housing Finance Agency

http://www.fhfa.gov/DataTools/Downloads/Pages/

House- Price- Index- Datasets.aspx#qpo

Immigration Number of immigrants admitted to the United States by

MSA

Department of Homeland Security

http://www.dhs.gov/yearbook-immigration-statistics

Personal income per capita Personal income is the income received by all persons

from all sources

Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA)

http://www.bea.gov/regional/

Population Population estimate by MSA U.S. Census https://www.census.gov/popest/data/historical/

20 0 0s/vintage _ 20 08/metro.html

Burglary rate Rates are the number of reported burglary offenses per

10 0,0 0 0 population

FBI Uniform Crime Report http:

//www.fbi.gov/about- us/cjis/ucr/ucr- publications#Crime

Murder rate Rates are the number of reported murder offenses per

10 0,0 0 0 population

FBI Uniform Crime Report http:

//www.fbi.gov/about- us/cjis/ucr/ucr- publications#Crime

Unemployment Civilian unemployed as percent of total civilian labor force Bureau of Labor Statistics http://www.bls.gov/lau/

Housing permit Number of new privately owned housing units authorized

by each MSA

U.S. Census https://www.census.gov/construction/bps/

historical _ data/index.html

Land Land area in square miles U.S. Census http:

//www.census.gov/population/metro/data/pop _ data.html

Land density MSA’s land area in square miles divided by total

population of MSA

Constructed by the authors

Shift share to construct

immigrant IV

(Foreign-born population in 1990 census in the MSA)/Total

foreign born population in the U.S. in 1990

Obtained from the 1990 U.S. Census 5% IPUMS sample:

https://usa.ipums.org . Steven Ruggles et al. (2010 )

Page 12: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

24 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25

Table C

Spatial Durbin business cycle model for house price.

Dependent variable �log( Price mt )

Direct effect Indirect effect Total effect

ρ 0.874 ∗∗∗

(0.015)

Immigrant t /Pop t −1 −0.787 ∗∗∗

(0.192)

−15.267 ∗∗

(5.940)

−16.055 ∗∗∗

(6.054)

Murder 0.0 0 0

(0.0 0 0)

−0.001

(0.004)

−0.001

(0.005)

log Burglary −0.004

(0.003)

−0.056

(0.079)

−0.060

(0.081)

Land per capita 0.137 ∗∗∗

(0.042)

0.567

(1.281)

0.704

(1.309)

log Income per capita 0.001

(0.002)

0.002

(0.091)

0.003

(0.093)

log Permit 0.003 ∗∗∗

(0.001)

0.098 ∗∗∗

(0.032)

0.101 ∗∗∗

(0.032)

Unemployment −0.001 ∗∗∗

(0.0 0 0)

0.001

(0.005)

−0.001

(0.005)

Northeast 0.006

(0.004)

0.036 ∗

(0.018)

0.041 ∗∗

(0.017)

Midwest 0.0 0 0

(0.002)

0.037

(0.032)

0.037

(0.033)

West 0.0 0 0

(0.003)

0.015

(0.026)

0.017

(0.026)

Northeast ∗Bust 0.004

(0.005)

−0.061 ∗∗∗

(0.021)

−0.056 ∗∗∗

(0.021)

Midwest ∗Bust −0.002

(0.003)

−0.071 ∗∗∗

(0.021)

−0.073 ∗∗∗

(0.021)

West ∗Bust 0.003

(0.004)

−0.053 ∗∗∗

(0.016)

−0.050 ∗∗∗

(0.015)

Observations 2820

Log-likelihood 7459.956

Time fixed effect Yes

Wald test, spatial lag 36.0 04 [0.0 0 0]

Wald test, spatial error 36.663 [0.0 0 0]

LR test, spatial lag 35.815 [0.0 0 0]

LR test, spatial error 37.497 [0.0 0 0]

Notes : Standard errors are in parentheses. The probability values for the various tests are in square

brackets. Probabilities smaller than 0.05 point to significance of Wald or LR test. Bust is a dummy vari-

able equaling 0 from 20 03–20 07 and 1 from 2008–2012. ∗ Significant at 10%. ∗∗ Significant at 5%. ∗∗∗ Significant at 1%.

Table D

First stage regression for immigration inflows IV.

Immigration IV for rent estimate Immigration IV for price equation

Coefficient Bootstrapped SE Coefficient Bootstrapped SE

ln(share1990) 0.37 ∗∗∗ 0.027 log(share1990) 0.663 ∗∗∗ 0.016

Murder −0.015 ∗∗∗ 0.006 murder −0.005 ∗∗∗ 0.002

ln(burglary) −0.188 ∗∗∗ 0.070 log(burglary) −0.049 0.052

Land per capita −29.33 ∗∗∗ 4.163 Land per capita −7.97 ∗∗∗ 1.852

ln(percapita Y) 0.783 ∗∗∗ 0.050 log(percapita Y) 0.415 ∗∗∗ 0.030

ln(permit) 0.665 ∗∗∗ 0.025 log(permit) 0.372 ∗∗∗ 0.017

unemployment 0.111 ∗∗∗ 0.011 unemployment 0.010 ∗∗∗ 0.004

Observations 1812 2321

R -squared 0.827 0.899

Notes : Year effects incorporated but not shown. Coefficient values obtained from a first-stage regression with

corrected standard errors derived from 150 replications. See text for details.

B

C

D

References

Accetturo, A. , Manaresi, F. , Mocetti, S. , Olivieri, E. , 2014. Don’t stand so close to me:

the urban impact of immigration. Reg. Sci. Urban Econ. 45, 45–56 . Akbari, A.H. , Aydede, Y. , 2012. Effects of immigration on house prices in Canada.

Appl. Econ. 44 (13), 1645–1658 . Altonji, J.G. , Card, D. , 1991. The effects of immigration on the labor market outcomes

of less-skilled natives. In: Abowd, J.M., Freeman, R.B. (Eds.), Immigration, Tradeand Labor. University of Chicago Press, pp. 201–234 .

Basu, S. , Thibodeau, T.G. , 1998. Analysis of spatial autocorrelation in house prices. J.

Real Estate Finance Econ. 17 (1), 61–85 .

orjas, G.J. , 2003. The labor demand curve is downward sloping: reexamining the

impact of immigration on the labor market. Q. J. Econ. 118 (4), 1335–1374 . Borjas, G.J. , 2006. Native internal migration and the labor market impact of immi-

gration. J. Human Resour. 41 (2), 221–258 . Borjas, G.J. , Katz, L.F. , 2007. The evolution of the Mexican-born workforce in the

United States. In: Borjas, G. (Ed.), Mexican Immigration to the United States.

National Bureau of Economic Research Conference Report, Cambridge, MA . ohen, J.P. , Coughlin, C.C. , 2008. Spatial hedonic models of airport noise, proximity

and housing prices. J. Reg. Sci. 48 (5), 859–878 . eSilva, S. , Pham, A. , Smith, M. , 2012. Racial and ethnic price differentials in a small

urban housing market. Housing Policy Debate 22 (2), 241–269 .

Page 13: Journal of Housing Economics - Southern Methodist Universityfaculty.smu.edu/millimet/classes/eco7377/papers/mussa et... · 2017-12-06 · 14 A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics

A. Mussa et al. / Journal of Housing Economics 35 (2017) 13–25 25

E

E

F

F

G

G

L

N

O

O

O

P

S

R

S

S

S

S

S

T

lhorst, J.P , 2010. Matlab software for spatial panels. In: Paper presented at the IVthWorld Conference of the Spatial Econometrics Association (SEA). Chicago .

lhorst, J.P. , 2014. Spatial Econometrics: From Cross-Sectional Data to Spatial Panels.Springer, Berlin, New York, Dordrecht, London .

ernández-Avilés, G. , Minguez, R. , Montero, J.-M. , 2012. Geostatistical air pollutionindexes in spatial hedonic models: the case of Madrid, Spain. J. Real Estate Res.

34 (2), 243–274 . rey, W.H. , 1995. Immigration and internal migration ‘flight’ from US metropoli-

tan areas: toward a new demographic balkanisation. Urban Studies 32 (4–5),

733–757 . ibbons, S. , Overman, H.G. , 2012. Mostly pointless spatial econometrics. J. Reg. Sci.

52 (2), 172–191 . onzalez, L. , Ortega, F. , 2013. Immigration and housing booms: evidence from Spain.

J. Reg. Sci. 5 (1), 37–59 . eSage, J.P. , Pace, R.K. , 2009. Introduction to Spatial Econometrics. CRC Press Taylor

and Francis Group, Boca Raton, U.S .

ational Research Council, 1997. The New Americans: Economic, Demographic andFiscal Effects of Immigration. National Academy Press, Washington .

sland, L. , Thorsen, I. , 2013. Spatial impacts, local labour market characteristics andhousing prices. Urban Studies 50 (10), 2063–2083 .

ttaviano, G. I.P. and Peri, G. 2007. “The effects of immigration on U.S. wages andrents: a general equilibrium approach,” CReAM Discussion Paper 13/07, Center

for Research and Analysis of Migration.

ttaviano, G.I.P. , Peri, G. , 2012. Rethinking the effects of immigration on wages. J.Eur. Econ. Assoc. 10 (1), 152–197 .

ace, R.K. , LeSage, J.P. , Zhu, S. , 2012. Spatial dependence in regressors and its effecton performance of likelihood-based and instrumental variable estimators. In:

Terrell, D., Millimet, D. (Eds.). In: 30th Anniversary Edition (Advances in Econo-metrics), 30. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, pp. 257–295 .

ill, K. 20 0 0. “Understanding asset values: stock prices, exchange rates and the“peso problem.” Business Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Philadephia, Septem-

ber/October 20 0 0, pp. 3–13. uggles, S. , Alexander, T. , Genadek, K. , Goeken, R. , Schroeder, M.B. , Sobek, M. , 2010.

Integrated Public Use Microdata Series: Version 5.0. University of Minnesota,

Minneapolis [Machine-readable database] . á, F. , 2015. Immigration and house prices in the UK. Econ. J. 125 (587), 1393–1424 .

aiz, A. , 2003. Room in the kitchen for the melting pot: immigration and rentalprices. Rev. Econ. Stat. 85 (3), 502–521 .

aiz, A. , 2007. Immigration and housing rents in American cities. J. Urban Econ. 61(2), 345–371 .

aiz, A. , Wachter, S. , 2011. Immigration and the neighborhood. Am. Econ. J. Econ.

Policy 3 (2), 169–188 . usin, S. 2001. “The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the Miami Housing Market,”

Washington DC: U.S. Bureau of the Census. revelyan, E.N. , Acosta, Y.D. , De La Cruz, P. , 2013. Homeownership among the for-

eign-born population: 2011. Census Bureau. U.S. Department of Commerce .