lectures on international money - handelshøyskolen bihome.bi.no/fgl00001/int_money.pdf · lectures...

381
Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002 February 28, 2003

Upload: others

Post on 13-May-2020

6 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Lectures onInternational Money

Haakon O. Aa Solheim

Norwegian School of Management, 2002

February 28, 2003

Page 2: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

“There is no sphere of human thought in which it is

easier to show superficial cleverness and the appearance

of superior wisdom than in discussing questions of

currency and exchange.”

Winston Churchill,

House of Commons, September 29, 1949

Page 3: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Preface

These lectures where prepared for for a course the course “International

money”, held at the Norwegian School of Management during the spring

of 2002.

The notes are incomplete, as far as they include no citations.

Sandvika, March 2003

Haakon O. Aa. Solheim

Page 4: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Contents

1 Money 6

1.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

1.2 Money and currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6

1.2.1 Examples of money . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8

1.2.2 The creation of a national currency . . . . . . . . . . . 13

1.3 Money versus currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 15

1.4 Money and prices—the Cagan model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 17

1.4.1 Solving the Cagan model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 19

1.4.2 Seignorage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 28

1.5 The balance sheet of the central bank . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 32

1.5.1 Models without money . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 34

1.6 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 35

2 International money 37

2.1 Some final remarks on the importance of money . . . . . . . . 37

2.2 Introduction to a discussion on international money . . . . . . 39

2.3 The relationship between the national currency and the inter-

national currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 40

2.3.1 A model of the exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 41

2.3.2 Choice of exchange rate regime . . . . . . . . . . . . . 48

1

Page 5: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

2.4 The central bank and the supply of money . . . . . . . . . . . 49

2.4.1 The balance sheet of the central bank . . . . . . . . . . 49

2.4.2 Central bank interventions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 52

2.5 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 56

3 Exchange rate regimes 59

3.1 Relating the national currency to the international currency

market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 59

3.1.1 A short history of exchange rate regimes . . . . . . . . 61

3.1.2 Types of exchange rate regimes . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65

3.1.3 Optimal currency areas . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 68

3.1.4 The death of fixed exchange rates? . . . . . . . . . . . 70

3.2 Why a fixed exchange rate system might be unstable . . . . . 82

3.2.1 The n-1 problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 82

3.2.2 The adjustment problem . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 87

3.2.3 The problem of a credible policy—the Barro Gordon

model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 90

3.2.4 Appendix: The real exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . 93

4 Currency crises 96

4.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 96

4.2 Speculative attacks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 98

4.3 The Krugman model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103

4.4 Crises with no trend? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 106

4.4.1 The strategy of speculators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 109

4.4.2 The role of large speculators . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 113

4.4.3 A short note on the Tobin tax . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 120

4.5 Contagion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121

2

Page 6: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

4.5.1 Transmission of currency crisis via trade channels . . . 124

4.5.2 Transmission via a credit crunch . . . . . . . . . . . . . 127

5 The FX-market 130

5.1 Some definitions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130

5.1.1 Instruments . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 130

5.1.2 Bid-ask . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 131

5.2 What we know for certain about the FX-market . . . . . . . . 132

5.2.1 Triangular arbitrage . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 132

5.2.2 Covered interest rate parity—CIP . . . . . . . . . . . . 133

5.3 How the FX-market is organised . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 134

5.4 Data from the FX-market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 140

5.4.1 International currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 141

5.4.2 The roles of international money . . . . . . . . . . . . 143

6 The floating exchange rate 152

6.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 152

6.2 High expectations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153

6.3 “Excess volatility” and some ‘puzzles’ of exchange rate eco-

nomics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 155

6.3.1 The FX market vs. the stock market . . . . . . . . . . 157

6.4 Random walk?—the Meese and Rogoff results . . . . . . . . . 164

6.5 Equilibrium models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 167

6.6 Disequilibrium models . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 169

6.6.1 The Dornbusch model . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 171

6.7 Chartists and noise traders . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 179

6.8 Microstructure theories . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 182

6.9 The uncovered interest rate parity (UIP) . . . . . . . . . . . . 185

3

Page 7: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

6.9.1 Testing the UIP . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 188

7 Portfolio choice, risk premia and capital mobility 193

7.1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 193

7.1.1 Some notes on methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 194

7.2 Demand for foreign currency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 195

7.2.1 The minimum-variance portfolio . . . . . . . . . . . . . 198

7.2.2 The speculative portfolio . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 199

7.2.3 Empirical calculations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 200

7.2.4 Heterogenous agents . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 202

7.2.5 Aggregate behaviour . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 203

7.3 The collapse of a currency board . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 214

7.3.1 Risk premium and the need for capital . . . . . . . . . 214

7.3.2 Risk premium and expected depreciation . . . . . . . . 214

7.3.3 Effects of a fall in risk premiums . . . . . . . . . . . . 216

7.4 Empirical applications of the portfolio choice model . . . . . . 219

7.5 Appendix . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 220

7.5.1 Mean-variance vs. state-preference . . . . . . . . . . . 220

7.5.2 The exchange rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 221

8 The real exchange rate and capital flows 223

8.1 Some notes on research strategy . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223

8.2 Some empirical observations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 223

8.2.1 Differences in the price level . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 225

8.3 Accounting for what we do not know about the real exchange

rate . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 227

8.3.1 External balance . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 230

8.4 Explaining long term shifts in the real exchange rate . . . . . 232

4

Page 8: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

8.4.1 The Balassa-Samuelson effect . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 233

8.5 Fluctuations in the real exchange rate and capital flows . . . . 242

8.5.1 Model of two countries and terms of trade shocks . . . 243

8.6 The importance of capital flows for consumption smoothing . . 255

8.6.1 Explaining the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle . . . . . . . . 256

9 International capital flows, the IMF and monetary reform 259

9.1 Topics . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259

9.2 Capital flows . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 259

9.3 The international debt market . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 265

9.4 Can a country default? . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 273

9.5 The role of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) . . . . . . 274

9.6 Capital controls in Chile . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 280

10 Exercises 284

11 Solutions 319

5

Page 9: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 1

Money

1.1 Introduction

This lecture will discuss the topic of money. Why do we use money? I then

present the “Cagan model”—a framework that provides a useful view on the

relationship between money and prices. In the next lecture we will use this

model as a basis for a first discussion of foreign exchange rates.

1.2 Money and currency

If you ask a non-economist what he thinks of when he hears the word eco-

nomics he will probably say money. But as you are approaching the last

months of a four year study in economics, how much have you actually learned

about money?

Economics is not about money. Economics is about maximising utility

under constraints. To achieve this prices must adjust to clear markets. Prices

are only ratios—the price of good 1 is the number of good 2 you need to obtain

one unit of good 1. You don’t need “money”—that is currency—for that.

6

Page 10: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

You only need more than one good.

However, without money the economy turns into a barter economy. I will

trade with you only if you have a good that I need, and you will trade with me

only if I have a good you need. For a barter economy to work, there must be

a high coincidence of wants. That might work in an economy where everyone

supplies most of their own needs. In a more advanced economy individuals

become specialised, and coincidence of wants become scarce. The economy

needs an asset used for transactions. That asset is money.

Money is introduced to play three main roles. It is supposed to be

• a unit of account,

• a means of payment, and

• a store of value.

The unit of account is just an accounting measure. We need something

so standardised that everyone has a common understanding of its value. We

can then measure the value of other things in quantities of this unit.

The means of payment is the physical thing we use for transactions. In-

stead of exchanging one good for another we can exchange the good in the

means of payment, and use this in new transactions. It is important that it

is easy to evaluate the true value of this ‘product’. It must be reasonably

safe from forgery or fraud. And it should be easy to carry around.

The store of value is a more difficult concept. A store of value must be

safe—one must be reassured that it does not lose its value over time. Iron,

that rusts, is dominated by gold. Paper that receives no interest, like a USD

100 bill, is dominated by a bond that receives interest.

The good that is supposed to fill these three criteria in the modern econ-

omy is currency. Today a currency is generally understood as a liability on

7

Page 11: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

the national central bank. The national currency works as a unit of account,

as a means of payment and as a store of value. As a store of value currency,

that receives no interest, it is dominated by a number of other goods. Note

that money is something more than currency. In this course money and

currency will however be the same thing, unless otherwise stated.

1.2.1 Examples of money

Different periods have solved the need for money by different means. Here

is a number of examples of money.

• In World War 2 prison camps the Red Cross supplied prisoners various

goods, like food, clothing and cigarettes. However, the goods were

distributed without attention to the prisoners actual needs; one might

get cigarettes even if one was not a smoker. In these camps there

evolved a system for trading the Red Cross rations. The “money” in

this system was cigarettes.

– A unit of account: all prices were stated in cigarettes. Mankiw

(1992) reports that one shirt costed about 80 cigarettes.

As a unit of account cigarettes is adequate. However, note that it

would not work if the quality of different types of cigarettes differ

to much. If e.g. American cigarettes were much better than e.g.

German cigarettes, the price would have to specify the type of

cigarette as well.

– A means of payment: cigarettes are easily transportable. One

problem is that they lose value if they get wet.

– Store of value: cigarettes can be stored for some time without

losing flavour. And there was a stable underlying real demand, as

8

Page 12: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

smokers would demand cigarettes even if they were not used as

money. However, cigarettes could be expected to lose value when

the war ended.

• Gold coins.

Metal became the leading fabric used for currency in the European

economies. Three metals were used: copper for smaller purchases, silver

for medium sized purchases and gold for larger purchases. These were

all commodity money. That means that they had a value independent

from their value as money. One is willing to hold precious metals even

if one can not use them in day-to-day transactions.

– As a unit of account: gold works well if one can agree on a stan-

dardised weight. However, often one can not. This is one reason

why currency, even in the time of the gold standard, was national.

Weight measures were national specific to the end of the last cen-

tury. They still to some degree are—i.e. the difference between

US and European standards.

– As a means of payment: gold as such is not a good means of

payment. First, it is very expensive. For most purchases the

amount need is so small that other metals, like copper, is more

useful. Second, it needs to be meticulously measured each time to

assure that one pay the right amount.

To alleviate the last problem public authorities or banks—like the

banks in Florence, therefore the “Florin”—issued gold coins. Each

coin had a standardised value.

However, even such coins can be problematic. A coin can be

“shaved”—i.e. people take of some gold and hope to sell the coin

9

Page 13: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

for its original value. Or the issuing institution can attempt to

make money by issuing coins with less gold content, but sell the

coin for its original value. This is called debasing the currency.

In fact, debasing might lead to currency crises—people will try to

store the coins with high gold content, and sell the coins with low

gold content. Such currency crises were frequent in the later years

of the Roman empire.

– Store of value: over time the value of gold depends on who much

gold is available. If much gold is found, the value of gold will fall.

However, gold is scarce. And as gold has an intrinsic value in its

beauty, it can be considered fairly safe.

• Gold backed currency.

Gold is bulky, heavy and difficult to carry around. So instead of using

gold directly, people started to use claims on gold. A bank issues a “bill

of credit” that states that a given amount of gold can be redeemed from

the bank with this bill. E.g.: I deposit 1 ounce of gold in Bank A. Bank

A gives me a bill stating that I get one ounce of gold if I make a claim

with this bill in bank A. I use this bill to purchase a radio. The radio

salesman uses the bill to pay his rent. The landlord uses the bill to pay

... → the bill works as currency.

Why does a bank issue such a bill? As long as it is not required to

keep 100 per cent reserves, it can make an income on the interest rate

differential. 100 per cent reserves would imply that the bank keeps one

unit of gold for each unit of gold backed currency issued. However, it

is not likely that everyone will claim their bills at once. So the bank

can keep less than 100 per cent of the gold as actual reserves. It can

10

Page 14: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

therefore invest some of the gold deposited in activities with a positive

return, and thereby get an interest rate. The return on issuing currency

is the difference between this interest rate and the interest rate paid on

the bill (usually zero). So why do I give my gold to the bank? A bill

of credit is easier and safer to carry than gold.

– As a unit of account: if everyone understand the denomination, i.e.

how much gold one unit refers to, it should work well. However, it

is clearly most useful if every bank uses the same denomination.

– As a means of payment: bills of credit are easy to carry. However,

here the value depends on the bank that has issued the bill. If

you don’t trust the bank, you don’t trust the money.

– Store of value: In the case of gold we had uncertainty about the

future value of gold. Here we must add the uncertainty about the

bank. And we still (normally) get no interest rate. So this bill is

probably dominated as a store of value.

The currencies above are all based on commodities. That means that

the currency have a potential value even if it is not used as a currency.

However, there are problems with such currencies. The supply of money is

exogenous—it is mostly decided by factors outside the economy. This is not

perfectly true: the mining activity for gold would to some degree depend on

its monetary value. However, over time the gold supply is independent of

how much money the economy actually needs.

• Fiat currency

Fiat money is an asset that only has value as a medium of exchange. An

example of fiat money is a bill issued by a national monopoly stating

11

Page 15: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

that it is the standard means of payment in a given country. The bill is

however not redeemable in any commodity from the side of the issuer.

Norges Bank is not obliged to give anything else in return for paper

money than new paper money—a 50 NOK bill will only return you a

new 50 NOK bill. It only has value because it is accepted as a means

of payment.

– As a unit of account? Actually fiat money is not very good.

The problem is that the issuer, in theory, can issue as much such

currency as he likes. But of course, it an infinite amount of cur-

rency is issued, then the currency loses all value. So in practice

the issuer will limit the amount issued. However, inflation is or

has been a problem in almost every country with a fiat currency.

If inflation is high or unpredictable, the currency is no longer a

good unit of account. In countries with extreme inflation one of-

ten changes the unit of account to a foreign currency, although

the national currency is still the means of payment. E.g. in many

high inflation countries the USD is used as a unit of account.

– As a means of payment: fiat currency works good, as long as

people trust the issuer. But it depends on how many uses the

currency. If everyone accepts it, it is very handy. If no-one accepts

it, it has no value—the value of a currency depends on its use.

– As store of value: very uncertain, and clearly dominated by a

number of other goods, including gold and bonds.

12

Page 16: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

1.2.2 The creation of a national currency

In modern times we have seen a movement from gold backed currency to fiat

currency, and a movement from the use of currency issued by private banks

to currency issued by a state monopoly.

Those two movements probably depended on each other. The issuer of

a currency need to be trustworthy, stable and have good credit. The mod-

ern state came to fulfill these criteria during the 19th-century, as national

governments were firmly established, and tax systems were implemented.

The private banking system seems to have worked in a satisfying manner.

As an example the USA had no national currency from 1838 to 1863. All

currency was issued by private banks. The Federal Reserve System was first

established in 1913. However, there are potential problems:

• “Wild-cat banking”—banks issues bills with no backing, or they keep

insufficient reserves.

• Potential instability. A currency becomes more valuable the more peo-

ple who uses it. However, to extend the use of its currency, the bank

needs to extend the number of customers. More customers generally

means more bad customers as well. So a big bank might become more

unstable, and the currency more unsafe. We get the potential of cur-

rency crashes.

• Private banking creates uncertainty among general users, as it is diffi-

cult to evaluate if a bank is safe or not.

• The state loses possible income from seignorage—the profit from issuing

money.

13

Page 17: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 1.1: Norwegian CPI from 1835 to 2000. Log of index value. 1920=100

3

4

5

6

7

8

1835

1840

1845

1850

1855

1860

1865

1870

1875

1880

1885

1890

1895

1900

1905

1910

1915

1920

1925

1930

1935

1940

1945

1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1980

1985

1990

1995

2000

Gold standard Bretton Woods

Pure fiat currency

These factors brought forward the nationalisation of the “currency indus-

try” and centralisation of currency issuance by “central banks”. Note that a

central bank is not always public. The only requirement is that it gets the

monopoly to issue valid currency for a country. Norges Bank was a private

institution in the first years of its existence. However, after some time most

central banks were nationalised.

A state backed monopoly issuer has less need for gold to back the value

of its currency. Why? A government back the currency on the trust of the

people and the income generated from future taxes. However, it is much

easier to impose inflation if the currency is issued by a monopolist than if

one has private issuance of currency.

14

Page 18: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

1.3 Money versus currency

Is money and currency the same thing? Currency is money, but money is

not only currency. Currency is very liquid money, money used as means of

payment and unit of account. However, other forms of money exists:

• A short term bank deposit is money. But it is not as liquid as currency

(there are stores that do not accept a debit card).

• A savings account is money. However, these money are more illiquid

than the primary account. One can not make purchases directly on a

traditional savings account.

• If one holds long term bonds, these can be bought and sold, but is not

redeemed before after a certain number of years.

Different types of assets have different degrees of liquidity. One moves

one’s holding between different types of money all the time. Traditionally,

and everything else equal, the return of an asset is decreasing in the degree

of liquidity. Currency, i.e. very liquid money, usually returns no interest.

Money has been divided into groups, like M1, M2 and M3. M1 is the most

liquid money (currency and short term deposits), M2 is less liquid money

and so on.

Note: in modern banking the distinctions between different types of

money is falling. My credit card offers an account with free debit card access

and an interest rate formerly only expected on long term deposits. More and

more money is stored electronically as we extend the use of bank cards. Most

people no longer holds large holdings of non-interest bearing currency.

15

Page 19: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 1.2: Notes and coins in the Norwegian economy. Millions of NOKNotes and coin in the Norwegian economy

(Millions NOK)

25 000

27 000

29 000

31 000

33 000

35 000

37 000

39 000

41 000

43 000

45 000

des.9

2

mar

.93

jun.9

3

sep.

93

des.9

3

mar

.94

jun.9

4

sep.

94

des.9

4

mar

.95

jun.9

5

sep.

95

des.9

5

mar

.96

jun.9

6

sep.

96

des.9

6

mar

.97

jun.9

7

sep.

97

des.9

7

mar

.98

jun.9

8

sep.

98

des.9

8

mar

.99

jun.9

9

sep.

99

des.9

9

mar

.00

jun.0

0

sep.

00

des.0

0

mar

.01

jun.0

1

sep.

01

des.0

1

Figure 1.3: M1 versus notes and coins

0

50 000

100 000

150 000

200 000

250 000

300 000

350 000

400 000

450 000

des.9

2

mar

.93

jun.9

3

sep.

93

des.9

3

mar

.94

jun.9

4

sep.

94

des.9

4

mar

.95

jun.9

5

sep.

95

des.9

5

mar

.96

jun.9

6

sep.

96

des.9

6

mar

.97

jun.9

7

sep.

97

des.9

7

mar

.98

jun.9

8

sep.

98

des.9

8

mar

.99

jun.9

9

sep.

99

des.9

9

mar

.00

jun.0

0

sep.

00

des.0

0

mar

.01

jun.0

1

sep.

01

des.0

1

M1

Notes and coins

All numbers in million NOK

16

Page 20: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 1.4: Inflation and money growth in Argentina, 1974-91

International Monetary System2. Banking system

The QTM in Argentina, 1974-1991 (log scale)

10

100

1000

10000

100000

10 100 1000 10000

Annual Money Growth Rate

An

nu

al C

PI In

flati

on

Rate

8

1.4 Money and prices—the Cagan model

In the IS-LM model the relationship between money and prices is given by

the LM-curve,Md

Pt

= L (Yt, it+1) , (1.1)

where Md is money demand, Pt is the price level at time t, Y is output and i is

the nominal interest rate. The LM curve assumes that real money demand is

rising in Y (because when output grows on needs higher real money holdings)

and falling in i, as a higher interest rate rises the alternative cost of holding

money (remember that money here is the same as currency).

Phillip Cagan argued that during a period of hyperinflation expected

17

Page 21: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

inflation would swamp all other influences on money demand. Figure 1.4

illustrates the relationship between money growth and price inflation in Ar-

gentina over the period from 1974 to 1991. This was a period with very high

inflation. As we can see, as inflation gets higher, the relationship between

money growth and inflation becomes stronger. Under high inflation one can

therefore ignore the effect of output and interest rates, and instead write

Mdt

Pt

= Et

(Pt+1

Pt

)−η

. (1.2)

Equation (11.48) tells us that if expected inflation rise, we reduce our demand

for real money balances. If we know that prices will rise tomorrow, we want

to hold less money today, as these money will lose value tomorrow.

Et shows us that we look at expectations at time t. η is the semielasticity

of demand for real balances with respect to expected inflation. It is parameter

that tells us how much demand for real balances—the money stock divided

by the price level—reacts to a change in expected inflation. If η is large this

indicates that we would make a large adjustment in money balances if we

know that prices will change tomorrow. If η is close to zero we do not care

about inflation when deciding the level of real money balances.

If we take logarithms on both sides we obtain

mdt − pt = −ηEt (pt+1 − pt)) , (1.3)

where small letters are the logarithms of large letters. We will use the equa-

tion on logarithmic form, as this simplifies the analysis.

18

Page 22: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

1.4.1 Solving the Cagan model

We want to study the relationship between money and prices. So we need to

find the equilibrium of the model.

We have an equation for money demand. However, we know that in

equilibrium supply must equal demand. So we must have

md = mt. (1.4)

We can then restate equation (11.48) as

mt − pt = −ηEt(pt+1 − pt). (1.5)

Further, let us assume that all agents are rational and have perfect foresight.

If so we can eliminate the expectation term. We get

mt − pt = −η(pt+1 − pt). (1.6)

Equation (11.53) is a first order difference equation. We want to find the

relationship between p and m, in other words we want an expression of the

type

pt = γm. (1.7)

The easiest way to solve a first order difference equation is by iteration.

First, write equation (11.53) with pt on the left hand side. We get

pt =1

1 + ηmt +

η

1 + ηpt+1. (1.8)

We see that today’s price level depends on the unforseen price level of to-

morrow. What does the price level of tomorrow depend on? Lead equation

19

Page 23: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(1.8) with one period, and we get

pt+1 =1

1 + ηmt+1 +

η

1 + ηpt+2. (1.9)

We can now substitute the expression from equation (1.9) into equation (1.8).

Doing so we obtain

pt =1

1 + η

(mt +

η

1 + ηmt+1

)+

1 + η

)2

pt+2. (1.10)

If we repeat this procedure, eliminating pt+2 and then pt+3 and so on, we

will in the end get

pt =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

ms + limT→∞

1 + η

)T

pt+T . (1.11)

How shall we interpret equation (1.11)? We often choose to assume that

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

pt+T = 0. (1.12)

This is the same as assuming that there is no “speculative bubbles” in the

price level. Indeed, equation (2.10) will be zero unless the level of prices

changes at an ever increasing proportional rate.

Bubbles

What is a speculative bubble? One can say that a bubble is an explosive

path which brings the level progressively farther away from economic funda-

mentals. However, “economic fundamentals” is something we define—it is

a “model specific term”.1 A better definition is probably that a bubble is

1What do I mean with “model specific term”? When we build a model we define arelationship between variables. The only thing we know about the relationship between

20

Page 24: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

a movement that leads to increasing divergence from the equilibrium value

defined by an economic model.

Notice that in this model we assume perfect foresight and rational agents.

Despite this quite strong assumptions we can not rule out the existence of

rational bubbles. We can only assume that they do not exist. However, it is

reasonable to believe that rational bubbles exist?

Bubble can not exist if we know that it will “burst” at a given point of

time. Why? If we know the price level will revert to its “true value” at a

given time, we will try to make a fortune going short in the asset. However,

if everyone does this, prices must fall today. A bubble can never exist if there

is certainty about when the bubble will collapse.

It is easier to see this if think about e.g. stocks instead of the general

price level. Assume that there is stock price bubble. If we expect the prices

to fall at time t, we will go “short” today—i.e. we will sell assets for delivery

at time t + 1. Why? Because we expect that we can buy stock to a much

lower price than in the forward contract when time t+1 arrives. At t+1 we

buy stock in the spot market at a low price to fulfill our forward contract.

However, if the timing of the crash of the bubble is uncertain, a bubble

can exist even if everyone knows it is a bubble. If we expect prices to rise

in this period, and the next period, and the period after that, we can make

money by buying the asset today. But doing so, we just fuel the bubble—the

more people who buy the asset, the more do prices rise. In fact everyone

find it profitable to let the bubble exist—although everyone knows that a

some time in the future the prices need to revert to a lower level. “Rational

bubbles” are models where the there is much uncertainty about when the

the price level and money is what we have defined in economic models. If the price leveldoes not behave as in the model we say that it does not behave according to “economicfundamentals”. However, notice that we do not know if the behaviour of the price leveldefies logic, or if it is our model that is flawed.

21

Page 25: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

bubble will collapse.

Note that it is very difficult to test if a bubble really exists. If we test for

the existence of a bubble, we will simultaneously test whether

1. there is a divergence from the values predicted by the economic model,

and

2. whether the economic model in fact is the true model, or if the diver-

gence only is the product of bad modelling.

It is more or less impossible to distinguish these two issues from each other.

Prices and money—a solution?

We assume no bubbles. We can then rewrite equation (1.11) as

pt =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

ms. (1.13)

We can draw several interesting conclusions from equation (1.13):

• First, note that2

1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

=1

1 + η(

1

1− η1+η

) = 1. (1.14)

2Here I use the rules of summations. Remember the following two results from yourclasses in mathematics:

∞∑s=t

ks =1

1− k

T∑s=t

ks =1− kT−t

1− k

22

Page 26: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

If the money supply is constant, i.e. m = m we have that

pt = m. (1.15)

Not only is inflation zero for all periods, the price level is also fixed at

the level m. However, if the money supply makes an unexpected jump

at time t to a new level, i.e.

mt =

m t < t

m′ t ≥ t, (m′ > m),

(1.16)

this implies that

pt =

m, t < t

m′, t ≥ t.

(1.17)

As we see, if there is an unexpected shock to m the price level will

change immediately. The change in the price level will be equipropor-

tionate with the change money stock.

These results implies that in this model, money is fully neutral. Changes

in the level of money supply or changes in the denomination used, i.e.

a change in the unit of account, leads to an immediate equal propor-

tional change in the price level. For example, exchanging 8 “old NOK”

with 1 “new NOK” will only lead to all prices being divided by 8. This

result will be found in all models that have no nominal rigidities, such

as sticky prices, and no “money illusion”.3

• Real variables are not affected by a change in money supply—we have

3Money illusion is the idea that people do not understand the consequences of a changein the money supply immediately).

23

Page 27: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

real-monetary dichotomy—money affect only prices. Money is a “veil”—

and rational agents are able to look through it without letting it affect

their decisions.

• Notice that prices depend on expectations of the future. This implies

that

– it will matter whether a shock is expected to be temporary or

permanent, and

– it will matter whether the shock is expected or unexpected.

Above we illustrated the case of an unexpected shock. Assume instead

that at time t the government announces a change in the money supply

at some future time T . Suppose

mt =

m t < T

m′ t ≥ T, (m′ > m).

(1.18)

One will then find that the path of the price level becomes4

pt =

m + ( η1+η

)T−t(m′ −m), t < T

m′, t ≥ T.

(1.19)

The price level will make a small jump when the news is announced.

It will so accelerate over time until it reaches its new level at time T .

News will immediately be incorporated in the price setting.

Last, consider the case when the money supply grows at a fixed rate.

Assume that mt = m+µt. It is reasonable to believe that if money grows at

4A proof is provided at the end of the lecture notes.

24

Page 28: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 1.5: A perfectly anticipated rise in the money supply

mm

m’

time

Price level

t T

the rate µ, prices must grow at the same rate, so that inflation also equals

µ. If we insert this in the real money demand function, equation (11.48), we

have

mt − pt = −ηµ, (1.20)

or

pt = mt + ηµ. (1.21)

This result will be used later in the course.

Does the Cagan-model fit Norwegian data?

According to the above model an unexpected increase in the money stock

should lead to

• an immediate, equiproportionate increase in the price level, and

25

Page 29: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

• causality should go from money to prices, not the other way around.

One empirical methodology to identify unexpected shocks is to do a so-

called Vector Auto Regression (VAR) and find impulse response functions. A

VAR is a system of equations estimated simultaneously. An impulse response

function estimates how the variables in the system will react to a shock in the

error term of one variable. The error term is something that is not explained

in the model. A shock to the error term is therefore by definition unexpected.

Figure 1.6 illustrates the impulse response functions from a shock in the

12-month growth rate of M1. The results can be summarised as follows:

• Prices react to a change in the money stock. However, the reaction

occurs with a lag of between 4 and 10 months.

• We see that a shock to money affects prices, but a shock to prices do

not affect money. This should imply that causality runs from money

to prices.

There is a correlation between money and prices. However, the prediction

of an immediate jump in the price level is not reflected in the data. This

might have two causes:

• the shocks in the model are not “unexpected”, or

• prices only react to a shock in money with a lag.

The first explanation is not implausible, as we only estimate a model contain-

ing lagged values of changes in the CPI and M1. However, it is reasonable

to believe that prices do indeed only react with a certain lag. Three expla-

nations are offered for why prices do not react immediately to a shock to

money:

26

Page 30: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 1.6: Money growth versus inflation—Norway 1987-2001

-0.1

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

5 10 15 20 25 30 35

Response of DCPI to DCPI

-0.1

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

5 10 15 20 25 30 35

Response of DCPI to DM1

-1

0

1

2

3

5 10 15 20 25 30 35

Response of DM1 to DCPI

-1

0

1

2

3

5 10 15 20 25 30 35

Response of DM1 to DM1

Response to One S.D. Innovations ± 2 S.E.

DCPI is the 12-month change in CPI, and DM1 is the 12-month change inM1.

27

Page 31: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

1. Sticky prices. This is the traditional assumption in Keynesian models.

It is built on the argument that contracts take time to adjust.

2. Money illusion. When people get more money between their hands,

they are not able to conclude if this is the result of increased produc-

tivity on their part, or of more money in circulation.

3. Portfolio balancing. People will not adjust their money holdings im-

mediately. As a result the effect of increased money supply will take

time to dissipate through the economy.

These theories have different implications. However, on one account they all

agree: if prices do not adjust immediately, a change in money growth might

have real effects on the economy. Money will no longer be neutral.

1.4.2 Seignorage

Seignorage is the revenue the government acquires by using newly issued

money to buy goods or repay debts. It is assumed that most hyperinflations

are results of the government’s need for seignorage revenues.5 Seignorage in

period t is defined as

Seignoraget =Mt −Mt−1

Pt

. (1.22)

This is the real increase in the money supply from period (t− 1) to period t.

However, above we saw that the price level depends on the present money

supply and future expected money growth. This implies that there must be

a limit to how much the government can collect as seignorage. To see this,

5A hyperinflation is a period when prices rise at a rate averaging 50 per cent per month.The highest monthly inflation recorded is in Hungary in July 1945 when prices rose 19800per cent in one month.

28

Page 32: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rewrite equation (1.22) as

Seignoraget =Mt −Mt−1

Mt

Mt

Pt

. (1.23)

If higher money growth leads to higher expected inflation, demand for real

balances (M/P ) will fall. So higher money growth might not always increase

seignorage revenues.

We can use the Cagan model to find the of money growth will maximize

seignorage revenues. We had that

Mt

Pt

= Et

(Pt+1

Pt

)−η

. (1.24)

If we substitute (1.24) into (1.23) and rearrange a little, we get

Seignoraget = (1− Mt−1

Mt

)

(Pt+1

Pt

)−η

. (1.25)

We now assume that the government can commit itself to a certain rule

for money growth. More specifically, we assume that money growth is given

byMt

Mt−1

= 1 + µ ⇔ mt+1 −mt = µ. (1.26)

If money supply grow at a constant rate µ, we have seen that prices grow at

the same rate µ, so we have that

Mt

Mt−1

= 1 + µ =Pt

Pt−1

. (1.27)

Substituting (1.27) into (1.25) we obtain

Seignoraget = (1− 1

1 + µ)(1 + µ)−η = µ(1 + µ)−η−1. (1.28)

29

Page 33: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

We find the µ that optimises seignorage by taking the first-order condition

of (11.73) and setting equal to zero, so that

(1 + µ)−η−1 − µ(η + 1)(1 + µ)−η−2 = 0. (1.29)

The revenue maximising net rate of money growth must equal

µMAX =1

η. (1.30)

This is the inverse of the semielasticity of real balances with respect to money.

In fact, we have just found out that an optimising central bank will behave

in exact the same way as monopolist with zero marginal cost of production

(we simplify by ignoring the cost of printing currency). That should not

be a surprise; after all a central bank is just a monopolist in the “currency

issuance market”.

An other way to see the result from equation (1.30) is illustrated in figure

1.7. We can draw a “Laffer-curve” for seignorage revenue. There will be

a level of money growth that maximises seignorage revenue—to issue more

money than this will only be counter productive.

In a hyperinflation it is reasonable to believe that the government exceeds

this optimal level of money growth. But why? If expectations are not forward

looking, but backward looking, the government might earn money by printing

money at an increasing speed. If expectations are backward looking, everyone

believes that last periods money growth will be next periods money growth.

Increasing money growth in the next period over the money growth in this

period will by definition exceed expectations. It is however doubtful if one

can fool the public for a long time in this way.

A problem with the above analysis is that we assume that the government

30

Page 34: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 1.7: “Laffer-curve” for seignorage revenue

Rate of money growth

Seignorage revenue

1/n

Note that n in the figure equals η in the model.

can commit itself to a given rate of money growth for an infinite future.

However, if this is credible, the government has an incentive to fool the public

by increasing the rate of money growth for one period, thereby getting an

extra revenue. If the public does not trust the government, the optimal rate

of money growth might be less than what implied from the above analysis.

In the end, how large is actual seignorage revenue? For most industri-

alised countries the yearly revenue is about 0.5 per cent of GDP. In the case

of Norway that would be about 500 million USD. In developing countries it

can be much more of total government expenditure, however it reportedly

rarely exceeds 5 per cent of GDP on a sustained basis.

31

Page 35: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

1.5 The balance sheet of the central bank

The government is often seen as one entity in economic models. It should

not matter that one public institution has a surplus on its books, if another

public institution has a deficit. What matters are the net position over all

government institutions.

However, in monetary matters it is useful to distinguish between the

“fiscal authority” and the “central bank”. In fact this distinction is artificial.

As long as the central bank is publicly owned, it is part of the governments

balance sheet. Money, a liability on the central bank, is at the same time

a liability on the government. However, because money is so important for

the workings of the modern economy, there tends to be a separation between

government expenditure and the central bank.

If there was no separation between the central bank and the government,

the government would have two choices if it needed to finance a deficit:

• it could issue more money, or

• it could issue bonds.

An independent central bank is supposed to be a guarantee against monetary

financing of public expenditure. However note that the distinction between

issuing bonds and money is only a “veil”. If the central bank issues money

to purchases government bonds, the two cases are exactly the same.

In most advanced economies there is a tight wall separating the fiscal

and monetary authorities. If the government uses money to finance public

deficits, the money will loose value, and no longer fulfill its purposes as unit

of account, means of payment and store of value. In the long term the cost of

undermining the value of money exceeds the potential gains from financing

public deficits by printing money. However, leading experts on monetary

32

Page 36: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

economics (like Michael Woodford) have argued that a target for inflation

will only be credible if there is some target for public spending as well.

Over time the one needs to see the government accounts from a consolidated

standpoint—and one can not expect that the central bank balances its book

if other parts of the government do not balance their books.

A central bank typically holds four types of assets. These are

• claims on foreign entities, i.e.

– foreign currency, and

– foreign-currency-denominated bonds.

• gold (although the stock of gold has been reduced in the later years) and

SDR’s (claims on the International Monetary Fund, so-called “paper

gold”), and

• home-currency-denominated bonds.

On the liability side the central bank has two types of assets,

1. currency and

2. required reserves.

Required reserves are accounts domestic banks must hold in the the central

bank to be able to borrow money from the central bank. Currency plus

required reserves make up what is called the “monetary base”. The liability

side will also contain an accounting term, “net worth” to assure that the

accounts balance. The balance sheet is presented in figure 2.3.

If the central bank want to reduce the monetary base, it sells one of its

assets to the public. When it wants to increase the money supply, it buys

assets from the public.

33

Page 37: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 1.8: The balance sheet of the central bank

Assets

Net foreign-currency bonds

Net domestic-currency bonds

Foreign money

Gold

Net worth

Monetary base

Liabilities

1.5.1 Models without money

Although we have spent much time in this lecture on the topic of money, one

will usually find that discussions of monetary policy is conducted in models

that do not contain the term money at all. The reason is that is very difficult

to establish stable econometric relationships between the money and other

variables in the economy. The lack of stable money aggregates make money of

little use in practical policy. Indeed, attempts to focus on the money supply,

as was conducted by e.g. the Bank of England in the early 1980’s, failed.

Instead of targeting money, most central banks today target the inflation

rate, and use the interest rate as instrument, not the money supply.6

However, the central bank’s control of short term nominal interest rates

ultimately stems from its ability to control the quantity of base money in

existence. If some power different from the central bank could control M ,

6The ECB makes one important exception. They have continued the tradition fromthe Bundesbank, and keep an official target for money growth.

34

Page 38: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

then this power could directly affect monetary policy. One should also note

that although modern monetary theory looks like a theory with no money,

it still rests on the assumption that in the long run inflation is a monetary

phenomena.

1.6 Appendix

Proof of equation (1.19).

pt =1

1 + η

T∑s=t

1 + η

)m +

1

1 + η

∞∑s=T

1 + η

)m′

pt =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)m +

1

1 + η

∞∑s=T

1 + η

) (m′ −m

)

pt = m +1

1 + η

∞∑s=T

1 + η

) (m′ −m

)

pt = m +1

1 + η

[∞∑s=t

1 + η

)−

T∑s=t

1 + η

)] (m′ −m

)

pt = m +1

1 + η

(1 + η)−1−

1+η

)T−t

1−(

η1+η

)(

m′ −m)

pt = m +1

1 + η

[(1 + η)− (1 + η) + (1 + η)

1 + η

)T−t] (

m′ −m)

pt = m +1

1 + η

[(1 + η)

1 + η

)T−t] (

m′ −m)

35

Page 39: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

pt = m +

1 + η

)T−t (m′ −m

)

36

Page 40: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 2

International money

2.1 Some final remarks on the importance of

money

In Lecture 1 we discussed the nature of money. The value of the currency

we hold at a given point of time depends on how much we can purchase for

this amount. If the price level increases, our currency loses value. The value

of money depends on the price level. Currency is an asset were the level of

return is given by inflation. The higher inflation, the lower the return on

holding currency, as high inflation implies a falling value of your currency

holdings.

Several points were made in the first lecture:

• For all types of money, even for a commodity currency, there is a need

for trust between the issuer of a currency and the holder of currency

for the currency to be accepted.

• The Cagan model showed us that the trust in a currency depends on

the future expected supply of the currency. This implies that money is

an asset—its value depends on expectations of the future.

37

Page 41: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

• Our example of seignorage revealed that a fiat currency is indeed only

a product supplied by a monopolist. However, for this monopolist to

maximise profit, given perfect foresight, there is an absolute limit to

how fast money supply can grow. This limit depends on the semielas-

ticity of money demand in expected inflation.

The value of money depend on the credibility of the issuer of money. In

that respect money does not differ from other assets we are holding, like

bank deposits, bonds or equity. However, why are money special? Two

things make the credibility issue of special importance when we talk about

money:

1. Money is one of the few assets that encompass the whole economy.

2. For many people money the only financial asset they hold. For them

money is an asset with no alternatives.

For a large group of people, especially among the poor, financial markets

are incomplete. Most important are perhaps that the poor have difficulties

getting loans. This implies that they do not posses the credit necessary to

buy e.g. their own home.

For these people money or short term deposits are the only store of value.

Further, almost all expenses are based on nominal prices. If prices rise very

fast, wages tend to lag prices. At the same time their holdings of money are

diminished by inflation.

Loans are and real assets are both a hedge against inflation. Even though

interest rise, the cost of a loan tends to fall if inflation is high, because a loan

is fixed in nominal terms. The price of real assets should be expected to rise

with inflation. The value of the holdings of money is however diminished by

inflation.

38

Page 42: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The problem of incomplete financial markets grow the less sophisticated

the financial market is. One implication is that instability in the value of

money might is especially costly in developing countries.

2.2 Introduction to a discussion on interna-

tional money

In the first lecture we argued that the economy needed money; something

that could work as a unit of account, means of payment, and also be a store

of value. It was also pointed out that the value of money depended on the

use of money. However, why are money national?

There has always (i.e. as long as there has existed money) existed in-

ternational money—means of payment accepted across borders. However,

generally small change and money used in daily transactions have been na-

tional currency. That is probably a question of both trust, standards and,

with the emergence of a national state, the ability of a government to impose

a monopoly.

• If e.g. gold is used as a currency, everyone must agree on a weight unit

if gold is going to work as a unit of account. However, weight measures

have traditionally differed between countries.

• The value of money is a question of trust in the institution that has

issued the money. Proximity traditionally increases the ability to trust.

• The revenue from seignorage has been an important factor when gov-

ernments have imposed a state monopoly in currency issuance.

Would it be optimal to have only one currency? One has compared a

currency to a language: the more people who use a language, the more useful

39

Page 43: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

does it get. But would it be optimal for everyone to speak the same language?

In a world where communication is difficult, languages get specialised. Even

if one starts up with one language, the different needs of different areas

turn a common language into different dialects, and over time into distinct

languages.

In the current world, with easy communication over long distances a

common language could probably be an option. However, is it optimal?

Perhaps one would have created only one language if we could redraw the

world from scratch. Given that multiple languages already exist it would

probably not be optimal to impose one language on everyone. However,

for international communication only a few languages are in fact actively

used. These function as “international languages”. This is also the case with

money: side by side there exists national currencies and international monies.

In this lecture we will discuss what determines the use and value of cur-

rencies in international markets. How is the value of national currencies

determined? How does monetary policy affect the value of an exchange rate?

And what is the role of international money?

2.3 The relationship between the national cur-

rency and the international currency

In the last lecture we used the Cagan model to say something about the

relationship between money and prices. However, one can also use the Cagan

model to get an understanding of how a currency is priced in international

markets. This is a starting point for our discussion of monetary policy and

exchange rates.

40

Page 44: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

2.3.1 A model of the exchange rate

General assumptions

We can use the Cagan model to derive a monetary model of the exchange

rate. However, we want the model to be more general than the one we

discussed in the first lecture, so we reintroduce nominal interest rates and

real income in the equation. If we assume that expected inflation is low or

non-existing, we can write the demand for real money balances on log-form

as

mt − pt = −ηit+1 + φyt. (2.1)

Here i is the nominal interest rate 1 and y is real output.

We want to find a link between the model of money and the exchange

rate. Let us first define the exchange rate ε, as the price of one unit of

foreign currency denominated in domestic currency. This is the standard

denomination in most countries2. It implies that

ε · (domestic currency) = (one unit foreign currency). (2.2)

Note that seen from the point of view of the home country, a higher exchange

rate implies that the home currency has depreciated, or has lost value. A

higher exchange rate means that it takes more units of the home currency to

buy one unit of the foreign currency. Similarly, a lower exchange rate implies

an appreciation of the home currency. Also note that the log of ε will have

the label e.

To be able to say anything about an exchange rate we need to make two

assumptions, linking the value of local money to the value of foreign money.

1Formally measured as log of 1+i, where i is the nominal interest rate.2One exception is Great Britain, where a currency is usually quoted as units of foreign

currency that is needed for the purchase of GBP 1.

41

Page 45: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

If we shall be able to say something about relative prices we must assume

• free trade, and

• free capital mobility.

Unless these two requirements are fulfilled, the monetary model will not

give a good empirical fit. However, what does these two assumptions imply

for our model?

1. The assumption of free trade makes it possible to assume purchasing

power parity, or PPP. PPP implies that the exchange rate between two

countries shall equal the relative ratio of the price levels between two

countries,

Pt = εtP∗t , (2.3)

where ε is the exchange rate and P ∗ is the foreign price level. On logs

(2.3) can be expressed as

pt = et + p∗t . (2.4)

The PPP states that the price level should be the same in all countries

if prices are re-calculated to one currency. One way to look at this is

through the “law of one price”. LOP states that if a good is priced

differently in two countries, arbitrage would assure that the good is

bought in the country where it is cheap, and transported to the country

where it is expensive. Over time this should trade away the price

difference.

There is a number of problems concerning the PPP. Although there

is free trade of many physical products, there are e.g. restrictions on

the trade of labour, so one should assume it to be considerable price

42

Page 46: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

differences in labour intensive products. This is taken account of in

the “Balassa-Samuelson” model, presented in your prior macro course.

However, for the time being we assume the PPP to hold.

2. If markets are efficient, free capital mobility should assure that the

return on capital assets are equalised between currencies. This rela-

tionship is formalised in the uncovered interest rate parity (UIP), that

can be written as1 + it+1

1 + i∗t+1

= Et

(εt+1

εt

). (2.5)

What does the UIP say? It states that the expected return on invest-

ment should be independent on the currency the bond is denominated

in. If I hold NOK I should get the same return if I invested my money

in a Norwegian bond, or if I exchanged NOK for EUR today, invested

in a perfectly similar bond in the Euro zone, and exchanged back to

NOK after the bond came up for payment. Why should this hold? If

there is perfect foresight it should hold by pure arbitrage. If one ex-

pected a higher return in EUR-bonds than in NOK bonds, everyone

would buy EUR-bonds, depressing the interest rate on such bonds. On

logs the UIP can be written as

it+1 − i∗t+1 = Etet+1 − et. (2.6)

Deriving the exchange rate

If we substitute equations (2.4) and (2.6) into equation (11.31) we obtain

mt − (p∗t + et) = −η(Etet+1 − et + i∗t+1) + φyt. (2.7)

43

Page 47: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Again we assume perfect foresight, so that we can dispose of the expectation

term. Then equation (2.7 can be rewritten as

et =1

1 + η(mt − φyt + ηi∗t+1 − p∗t ) + ηet+1. (2.8)

If you remember back to lecture 1, you will see that this is the same difference

equation as we derived in the stochastic Cagan hyperinflation model. The

only change is that we have exchanged p with e and m with (m−φy+ηi∗−p∗).

In the same way as we solved for p in lecture 1 we can now solve for e. The

solution will be

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s) + limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T .

(2.9)

As in the case of the solution for the price level we obtain two terms. The

last term is a potential bubble term. A rational model with perfect foresight,

and where the PPP and the UIP hold at every point of time is not enough to

be certain that bubbles does not exist. However, it is usual to assume that

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T = 0. (2.10)

If so we can express the exchange rate as

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s). (2.11)

We see that an increase in the money stock will lead to a higher exchange

rate. In other words, an increase in the money stock leads to a depreciation

as a higher rate implies that you must pay more for foreign currency because

the local currency loses value. A lower money stock will imply a stronger

exchange rate. Higher output will imply a stronger currency. However, if

foreign interest rates rise, the currency will depreciate.

44

Page 48: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Implications

As we will later discuss, this model does not have a very good empirical fit

in the short term. Whether this is due to

• the fact that the assumptions of free trade and free capital mobility do

not hold,

• whether it is due to a bad model specification,

• whether it is due to bubbles actually being a factor,

• whether it is due to public interference not captured in the model,

• whether we do not understand how expectations are formed, or

• whether markets are just not as rational as this model assumes,

is not easy to tell. These are important questions in current economic re-

search.

However, a monetary model of this type is not an unreasonable approxi-

mation to the exchange rate in the long term. And there are several impor-

tant implications that can be derived from the monetary approach.

1. The exchange rate must be seen as an asset price—the exchange rate

depends on the expectation of future variables. That is a very impor-

tant finding. One should analyse the exchange rate in the same way

as one analysis e.g. a stock or bond. In fact, we still know very little

about how asset markets are actually priced. As we will find later in

this course, this is also the case for exchange rates.

2. The exchange rate is determined by stocks, not flows. Up till the 1970’s

45

Page 49: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

most models of supply and demand in the FX-market3 was based on a

flow approach. Foreign exchange was seen as medium of exchange for

executing international trade transactions. In this model the currency

is treated as an asset—something that is infinitely durable, which can

be transferred but not destroyed. One important implication of this

shift:

• in the flow approach exchange rate movements are expected to be

sluggish, as flow specifications would be slow to change.

• in the stock approach exchange rate movements are expected to

be quick to reflect new information.

The last is clearly a better description of a floating exchange rate than

the first.

3. It is important to distinguish between different types of shocks. The

consequence of a temporary shift in a variable will differ from the con-

sequence of a permanent shift. Likewise, the consequence of an antic-

ipated shock will be differ from the consequence of an unanticipated

shock.

In the last lecture we distinguished between an unexpected and expected

shock. Let us see how a permanent shock will differ from a temporary shock.

• Let y, i∗ and p∗ all equal zero4, and assume that there is no bubble. As-

sume that at time T the government announces a permanent change in

the money supply. Then the exchange rate must rise equiproportionate

3This is the short term for “the foreign exchange market”—the markets where curren-cies are traded.

4As these are on logarithmic form, setting a value equal to zero implies setting theactual value equal to one. As you know, ln(1) = 0.

46

Page 50: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

with the money stock, i.e.

mt =

m, t < T

m′, t ≥ T , (m′ > m).

(2.12)

implies that

et =

m, t < T

m′, t ≥ T .

(2.13)

• Assume that at time T the government announces a temporary increase

in the money supply. However, at T the money supply reverts to its

level before T :

mt =

m, t < T

m′, t ∈{T , T

}(m′ > m)

m, t > T .

(2.14)

We find that the path of the exchange rate becomes5

et =

m, t < T

m′ −(

η1+η

)T−t

(m′ −m) < m′, t ∈{T , T

}m, t > T .

(2.15)

The price level will make a jump in period T . However, the jump will

be less than if the shock was permanent. The exchange rate will then

fall, just to reach its previous level at time T . Both cases are illustrated

in figure 2.1.

5Proof provided in the appendix.

47

Page 51: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 2.1: Temporary vs. permanent shock to the money supply

T_ time

e

m

m'

T�

2.3.2 Choice of exchange rate regime

Let us assume two extreme cases.

1. The government fixes the exchange rate, i.e.

et+1 = et. (2.16)

For simplification we set ε = 1, which implies e = 0 ⇒ pt = p∗t and

it+1 = i∗t+1. It follows that

mt = p∗t − ηi∗t+1 + φyt. (2.17)

→ the money stock that is necessary to support a fixed exchange rate is

determined by changes in real output, foreign prices and foreign interest

rates. The central bank must adjust the money supply accordingly. For

the fixed exchange rate regime to be credible the central bank must let

48

Page 52: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

the money supply be endogenous.

2. The government fixes the money supply. The money supply is the only

variable the central banks can control directly in this system. Fixing

the money supply is the most extreme example of an exogenous rule

for money supply.

For simplicity we assume the central banks sets m = 0.6

Using the equations above, we obtain that the exchange rate is given

by

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(−φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s). (2.18)

The central bank can not influence any of the variables in equation

(11.43). This implies that the exchange rate become an endogenous

variable—it is determined within the system. The exchange rate is

outside the control of the central bank. The central bank can not

control the money supply and the exchange rate at the same time.

2.4 The central bank and the supply of money

A choice of exchange rate regime is the same as a choice of a rule for money

growth. But how do the central bank affect the money supply in the first

place?

2.4.1 The balance sheet of the central bank

The government is often seen as one entity in economic models. It should

not matter that one public institution has a surplus on its books, if another

6This is not the same as setting money supply to zero. Remember that m = log(M),and that log1 = 0.

49

Page 53: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 2.2: Fixed exchange rate vs. fixed money supply. Consequences of ashock to output

e

m

y2

y1

y0

m

e2

e1

e0

Fixed money supplye

m

y2y1y0

m0 m1 m2

Fixed exchange rate

A shock to output will have different consequences depending on the choiceof target in the monetary policy.

public institution has a deficit. What matters are the net position over all

government institutions.

However, in monetary matters it is useful to distinguish between the

“fiscal authority” and the “central bank”. In fact this distinction is artificial.

As long as the central bank is publicly owned, it is part of the governments

balance sheet. Money, a liability on the central bank, is at the same time

a liability on the government. However, because money is so important for

the workings of the modern economy, there tends to be a separation between

government expenditure and the central bank.

If there was no separation between the central bank and the government,

the government would have two choices if it needed to finance a deficit:

• it could issue more money, or

• it could issue bonds.

50

Page 54: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

An independent central bank is supposed to be a guarantee against monetary

financing of public expenditure. However note that the distinction between

issuing bonds and money is only a “veil”. If the central bank issues money

to purchases government bonds, the two cases are exactly the same.

In most advanced economies there is a tight wall separating the fiscal

and monetary authorities. If the government uses money to finance public

deficits, the money will loose value, and no longer fulfill its purposes as unit

of account, means of payment and store of value. In the long term the cost of

undermining the value of money exceeds the potential gains from financing

public deficits by printing money. However, leading experts on monetary

economics (like Michael Woodford) have argued that a target for inflation

will only be credible if there is some target for public spending as well.

Over time the one needs to see the government accounts from a consolidated

standpoint—and one can not expect that the central bank balances its book

if other parts of the government do not balance their books.

A central bank typically holds four types of assets. These are

• claims on foreign entities, i.e.

– foreign currency, and

– foreign-currency-denominated bonds.

• gold (although the stock of gold has been reduced in the later years) and

SDR’s (claims on the International Monetary Fund, so-called “paper

gold”), and

• home-currency-denominated bonds.

On the liability side the central bank has two types of assets,

1. currency and

51

Page 55: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 2.3: The balance sheet of the central bank

Assets

Net foreign-currency bonds

Net domestic-currency bonds

Foreign money

Gold

Net worth

Monetary base

Liabilities

2. required reserves.

Required reserves are accounts domestic banks must hold in the the central

bank to be able to borrow money from the central bank. Currency plus

required reserves make up what is called the “monetary base”. The liability

side will also contain an accounting term, “net worth” to assure that the

accounts balance. The balance sheet is presented in figure 2.3.

2.4.2 Central bank interventions

If the central bank want to reduce the monetary base, it sells one of its assets

to the public. When it wants to increase the money supply, it buys assets

from the public. The central bank can adjust money supply in two ways:

1. it can intervene in the FX-market by buying or selling currency, or

2. it can change the short-term interest rates.

52

Page 56: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The first alternative implies a change in the holdings of the foreign currency

denominated assets held by the central bank. The second alternative implies

a change in some of the domestic currency denominated assets of the central

bank. However, in theory these types of interventions are equivalent.

To see this, remember that for every change made on the asset side of

the central bank’s balance sheet, an equivalent change needs to made on

the liability side. If the central bank intervenes in the FX-market by selling

foreign currency, it must at the same time reduce its liabilities. So the stock

of currency falls. This implies an increase in the interest rate

Likewise, a change in the interest rate will be an indirect change in the

money supply. When the central bank increases an interest rate it offers

government bonds in the market at the new rate. When the central bank

sells a bond, it gets domestic currency in return. The supply of domestic

currency in the market will fall, and the supply of bonds will increase. The

money supply will contract.

In fact the central bank will not set an exact target for neither exchange

rate nor money supply. In a fixed exchange rate regime the exchange rate

will be allowed to fluctuate inside a defined target zone. If demand for the

currency increases, the currency will appreciate. If demand shift so much

that the going rate will be at the boundary of the target zone, the central

bank will adjust money supply to keep the exchange rate within the target

zone.

In a inflation targeting regime the central bank will (indirectly) target the

money supply. The money supply shall be kept inside a certain band. the

central bank will no longer intervene in the markets because of fluctuations

in the exchange rate. Rather it will intervene because of fluctuations in the

money supply. The choice between an inflation target and an exchange rate

53

Page 57: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 2.4: A fixed exchange rate target

e

m

D

elow

S

ehigh

54

Page 58: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 2.5: A price level target

e

m

D

mlow

S

mhigh

target will therefore imply a choice between price volatility and exchange

rate volatility.

Sterilised vs. unsterilised interventions

In the discussion above I assume that the central bank uses interventions to

change the domestic money supply. Such an intervention will affect prices

and interest rates. However, in many instances the central bank would like

to influence the exchange rate without affecting prices and interest rates.

A sterilised intervention means that while the central bank e.g. buy NOK

55

Page 59: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

in the foreign exchange market it will simultaneously buy bonds (or in the

Norwegian case, something called F-loans). In other words, when the central

bank reduces its holdings of foreign currency assets, it will at the same time

increase its holdings of domestic currency assets. That way it leaves the total

supply of NOK unaffected. However, in our model only an actual change in

m can affect the exchange rate. In the monetary model presented above,

sterilised interventions make no sense.

Two reasons have been presented for why sterilised interventions might

work.

1. Portfolio balance effects: if investors believe that foreign and domes-

tic assets are imperfect substitutes, a change in the relative supply of

foreign and domestic assets might have real effects.

2. Signaling: an intervention, even if it is sterilised, can signal to the

market that the central bank believe the exchange rate to be out of

bounds. Unless the market corrects this itself, the central bank might

go in with real interventions in the future.

Economist often argue that the effect of sterilised interventions are low.

However, central banks continue to use them. Making things even more

curious, most interventions are done in secret, which should in fact reduce

the signaling effect.

2.5 Appendix

Proof of equation (2.15).

pt =1

1 + η

T∑s=t

1 + η

)m′ +

1

1 + η

∞∑s=T

1 + η

)m

56

Page 60: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 2.6: From the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis:

International Monetary System2. Banking system

A discussion of sterilized intervention (from the St. Louis Fed):FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ST. LOUIS

SEPTEMBER /OCTOBER 2000 21

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK of ST. LOUIS

central banks keep interventions secret? Taylor(1982a and 1982b) suggests that the practice datesback to the Bretton-Woods era of fixed exchangerates, when reports of intervention could trigger arun on the currency. Given that the practice haspersisted for more than 25 years after the end offixed exchange rates, one also must consider the

possibility that central banks are reluctant to releasesuch information because they are trying to avoidaccountability. Finally, it is possible that secret inter-ventions—or at least concealing the size of inter-vention—may make the transaction more effectivein influencing the exchange rate in certain circum-stances (Bhattacharya and Weller, 1997).

Because exchange rates are important prices thatinfluence the time path of inflation and output, centralbanks often intervene in the foreign exchange market,buying and selling currency to influence exchangerates. Such intervention typically is sterilized, meaningthat the central bank reverses the effects of the foreignexchange transactions on the monetary base.1 Forexample, if the Federal Reserve Bank of New York—following the instructions of the Treasury and theFederal Open Market Committee—purchased $100million worth of euros, the U.S. monetary base—com-posed of U.S. currency in circulation plus depositsof depository institutions at the Federal ReserveBanks—would increase by $100 million in the absenceof sterilization. This transaction is illustrated in thestylized balance sheet items marked as (1). To preventchanges in domestic interest rates and prices, theFederal Reserve Bank of New York also would sell$100 million worth of government securities—ster-ilizing the intervention by reducing deposits withthe Federal Reserve—to absorb the liquidity. Thistransaction is marked as (2) in the balance sheet.

To prevent euro-denominated short-term interestrates from rising, the European Central Bank wouldhave to conduct similar open market purchases ofeuro-denominated securities to increase its moneystock to completely sterilize the original transaction.The final net effect of such a sterilized interventionwould be to increase the relative supply of U.S.government securities versus euro-denominatedsecurities on the market.

Because sterilized intervention does not affectthe U.S. monetary base or interest rates, it cannot

influence the exchange rate through price or interestrate channels. It might, however, affect the exchangerate through the portfolio balance channel and/or thesignaling channel. The reasoning behind the port-folio balance channel is that if foreign and domesticbonds are imperfect substitutes, investors must becompensated with a higher expected return to holdthe relatively more numerous bonds. In the examplein which the Federal Reserve purchases euros/sellsdollars (USD), the intervention must result in an imme-diate depreciation of the dollar that creates expec-tations of future appreciation, increasing the expectedfuture return to dollar-denominated assets and con-vincing investors to hold the greater quantity of them.The signaling channel, on the other hand, suggeststhat official intervention communicates to the marketinformation about future monetary policy or thelong-run equilibrium value of the exchange rate.A purchase of euros/sale of dollars may signal tothe markets that the central bank considers thedollar’s current value to be too high given currentand expected future policy. The consensus of theresearch on sterilized intervention is that anyinfluence intervention has on the exchange rate isweak and temporary.2

1 Unsterilized intervention is equivalent to domestic monetary policy

and therefore is often implicitly excluded from discussions of the

efficacy of intervention.2 Humpage (1999) provides some evidence that U.S. intervention may

influence dollar exchange rates.

Stylized Balance Sheet of the U.S. Monetary Authorities

Assets Liabilities

Foreign exchange reserves 1$100 million (1) Currency plus deposits held 1$100 million (1)with the Federal Reserve 2$100 million (2)

U.S. government securities 2$100 million (2)

STERILIZED INTERVENTION

15

57

Page 61: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

pt =1

1 + η

1−(

η1+η

)T−t

1−(

η1+η

) m′ +

1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)−

T∑s=t

1 + η

)m

pt =1

1 + η

[(1 + η)− (1 + η)

1 + η

)T−t]

m′+1

1 + η

[(1 + η)

1 + η

)T−t]

m

pt = m′ −(

η

1 + η

)T−t

m′ +

1 + η

)T−t

m

pt = m′ −(

η

1 + η

)T−t (m′ −m

)

58

Page 62: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 3

Exchange rate regimes

3.1 Relating the national currency to the in-

ternational currency market

If a country wants to trade with an other country without adopting the other

country’s currency, there needs to be some mechanism that assures that a

currency can be used for international transactions. Most important, it must

be some system for converting the local currency into other currencies.

The government has three measures to assure international convertibility.

1. It can use coercion or control—all trade with abroad must be approved,

and conducted at a given rate. This was the system in Europe after

the Second World War, in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe until

1989, and is still the case in some developing countries.

2. It can commit to a certain fixed exchange rate, and guarantee that it

will use all measures to defend that rate.

3. It can depend on the trust of the markets, and let the market set the

rate.

If trade is severely restricted, coercion is the only way to assure some

59

Page 63: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

balance in currency flows. However, most developed economies allow a rela-

tively high degree of free trade. This leaves the choice between commitment

and a free float.

Classical economic doctrine argues that markets will give the optimal

solution. However, for this to be true markets need to have a certain degree

of liquidity and a sufficient number of participants to work effectively. If these

requirements do not hold, markets can be manipulated. Whether this is a

real problem in the FX-market is uncertain. But remember that the financial

market of small and/or developing countries are often very small compared

to the financial markets of large and/or developed countries. There are a

number of American funds managers that control resources that exceeds the

total Norwegian GDP—and measured in GDP Norway is a large country.

Second, and perhaps more important for political decision makers, open

markets might imply serious limitations on the degrees of freedom in national

policies, as the exchange rate is vulnerable to swings in the moods of market

participants. This have lead governments to limit the mobility of capital.

If capital flows are limited, it is possible to achieve some degree of freedom

in monetary policy at the same time as the exchange rate is fixed This is

because the UIP will not hold if capital can not move freely. However, most

economist believe that it is impossible to have both an independent monetary

policy, a fixed exchange rate and free mobility of capital at the same time.

For the markets to work properly, the national economy must be devel-

oped and financial markets sufficiently sophisticated. In fact, the combina-

tion of a fiat currency and free convertibility was first introduced in the early

1970’s. Before that all forms of currency exchange across boarders had im-

posed either coercion or commitment to guarantee the value of the currency.

60

Page 64: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

3.1.1 A short history of exchange rate regimes

“The gold standard” describes a system where national currencies were con-

vertible to gold at fixed rates. This implied that the exchange rates were

fixed as well. The gold standard was in existence from about 1870 to 1914,

although it worked properly only in the first part of that period. This was a

period with very strong commitment. Even if a “crisis” of some kind made

a country unable to fulfill the requirements of the gold convertibility for a

certain period, it was usual for governments to make a strong effort to return

to the previous parity after the crisis had ended. At the same time it was

little or no coercion, as there existed no limitations on capital flows.1

During the First World War most countries abolished the convertibility

to gold, and instead imposed strong coercion, as trade flows was restricted.

After the war many countries attempted to return to their old parity values.

However, as prices had risen quite extensively during the war, a return to

parity implied that prices had to be deflated. This became a very costly affair

for a number of countries, Norway included. Britain, the leading country in

international relations up till the First World War, managed to restore the

old parity in the late 1920’s, only to be forced of gold in 1931. Commit-

ment was soon again replaced by control and coercion. During the 1930’s

many countries restricted the flow of goods, and limited trade to bilateral

agreements.

In 1944 a number of economists met at the Bretton Woods Hotel in up-

state New York. There it was worked out an agrement on how the exchange

1As we will see later in this course, according to some measures capital flows was largerper unit of output in the year 1900 than in the year 2000. It can also be noted that GreatBritain, which as the leading economy of the world at that time had a vested interest ina stable foreign exchange market, intervened heavily in support of other currencies underpressure. Great Britain worked as a stabiliser in the world markets, to some degree fillingthe role the IMF has today.

61

Page 65: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.1: Commitment versus coercion in the exchange rate system

coercion

commitment

Norway, 1945,Early Bretton Woods

Norway, 1990,USA 1945-1973

USA,Japan,Germanyafter 1973

Most small open economies today

62

Page 66: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rate system should work after the war. To make a long history very short,

the gold standard (where every currency was convertible into gold) was ex-

changed with a “dollar-gold” standard: all currencies was to be convertible

into USD, and USD was to be convertible into gold at a given rate (USD 35

per ounce of gold).2 The International Monetary Fund (IMF) was founded

to oversee the international currency system.

After the Second World War there was a large demand for investments

in most European countries. At the same time many people had money they

wanted to spend on luxury imports from abroad (i.e. the US). European

governments were afraid that if they let people exchange home currency into

USD without restrictions, to much of private spending would be used on the

imports of luxury goods, and not enough on more important investment. It

was therefore enforced quite strong restrictions on capital movements and

the private exchange of currency.

As currencies was not freely convertible balance in international trade

could not be left to the markets. To balance trade between two countries can

be compared with a barter economy on the country level—each country must

accept what the other has to offer, or there will be no trade. To make the

system more flexible one therefore institutionalised a multilateral payment

system—e.g. if Norway had a trade deficit versus Denmark and trade surplus

versus Great Britain, while Denmark had a deficit versus Great Britain, this

could be netted out in the system. Payments and receipts were handled by

the Bank of International Settlements (BIS) in Basel. By the end of the

1950’s the financial system was stable enough to allow for free convertibility.

By the end of the 1960’s great strain was put on the system. Bretton

Woods collapsed in early September 1971. In 1973 the big currencies (USD,

2This was a natural solution, as 70 per cent of all gold reserves in 1945 was held by theFederal Reserve System.

63

Page 67: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

JPY, DEM and GBP) was allowed to float. It was predicted that this would

result in reduced international trade and more financial uncertainty. That

does not seem to have happened. By 1973 the major economies had estab-

lished trust in their economic policies. Increased volatility could probably

be handled as long as there was certainty about the long-term value of the

currencies.

However, in parallel with the experience of floating exchange rates be-

tween the large currencies, one saw an co-operation to stabilise exchange

rates at the regional level. European economies worked out an “exchange rate

snake”, a system that was supposed to reduce volatility between European

currencies. The “snake” evolved into the European Monetary System—a sys-

tem of stabilising the currencies of the member countries towards a common

currency basket, defined as the ECU. On paper all countries in the EMS was

supposed to support each other if any one country faced pressure against

the fixed rate. However, in practice EMS was a fairly flexible system, that

allowed for frequent changes in the exchange rates between countries. And

while Germany was the country in the EMS with the lowest inflation, and also

the most credible monetary policy, Germany became “first among equals”.

In practice the EMS looked like a system for fixing European currencies to

the value of the DEM.

In the end of the 1980’s EMS changed character. EMS was now described

as the forerunner to the future European currency union that was expected

to be established sometime during the 1990’s. As a first step in this pro-

cess the flexibility in the EMS was reduced. From 1987 until 1992 the EMS

worked as a pure fixed exchange rate system. However, in 1992 severe specu-

lative attacks forced many countries to leave the EMS. Despite this seeming

setback the process towards the EMU continued, and a common European

64

Page 68: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

currency with 11 (currently 12) members was established January 1, 1999.

The national bills and coins where exchanged with bills and coins denom-

inated in EUR from January 1, 2002. The transformation was completed

within the end of February 2002.

3.1.2 Types of exchange rate regimes

A country can choose between a number of different regimes for the exchange

rate. Note that when we e.g. say that the USD is a floating currency, we mean

that the federal Reserve will not attempt to reduce short-term volatility in the

USD. However, the USD might still be fixed against a number of currencies,

simply because many countries choose to stabilise their currencies against

the USD. This will be unilateral pegs. Also note that an exchange rate

regime must be defined not for a currency, but for an exchange rate cross.

If Argentina has fixed its currency to the USD this does not imply that the

the ARP (Argentinean peso) has a fixed value in the market. It only means

that the currency cross ARP/USD will be fixed. The ARP will be floating

with regard to all currencies that are floating with regard to the USD. E.g

the ARP/EUR will be a floating rate, as the USD/EUR rate is floating.

One can describe seven different types of exchange rate regimes:

1. A floating rate. The central banks make no attempt to stabilise the

exchange rate in the short run. (Examples: USD/EUR, JPY/USD)

2. A managed float. There exist some statement that the central bank

will not allow to much fluctuation in the exchange rate. If the exchange

deviates much from a target value, the central bank might make limited

interventions, either in the form of interest changes or in the form of

direct currency interventions. (Example: NOK/ECU (1993-1998(?)))

65

Page 69: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

3. Multilateral exchange rate pegs. Several countries agree to sta-

bilise their currencies against each other. The currencies shall fluctu-

ate within predetermined bounds. All countries retain an independent

monetary policy. However for the country to remain in the system,

monetary policy must be adjusted according to the monetary policy

of the system as a whole. Mostly a multilateral peg is dominated by

a single country. The countries are obligated to support each other if

there is a speculative attack against any one country. If one country

wants to make an adjustment in its exchange rate, the other countries

in the system must be informed in advance. (Example: the European

Monetary System (EMS)—European currencies were stabilised against

ECU)

4. Unilateral peg. One country fixes its currency to some other cur-

rency. There is no obligation from the other country with regard to

interventions. (Example: NOK/ECU from 1990 to 1992).

However, more often a country fixes the value of its currency to a

“currency basket”—an index value of several currencies. The basket

weights are often based on the composition of trading partners. (Ex-

ample: NOK, SEK and FIM in the 1980’s)

5. Currency board. The currency is fixed completely to the value of

another currency. There is no allowance for a target zone as in a mul-

tilateral or unilateral peg. The central bank promises to exchange the

local currency into the foreign currency at the fixed rate, and must have

sufficient reserves to make this promise credible. There is no longer an

independent monetary policy. The only role of the central bank is to

adjust the level of reserves to assure that the fix remains credible at

66

Page 70: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

every point of time. The central bank can no longer adjust the money

stock in periods of e.g. banking crises, and can therefore no longer

work as credible lender of last resort. A speculative attack against a

currency board can therefore often take the face of a speculative attack

against banks (as in e.g. Argentina).

6. Dollarisation. The local economy adopts a foreign currency as its

own. All local currency must be exchanged at a given rate, and de-

structed. All contracts must be re-denominated in the foreign currency.

There is no central bank in the sense of a monetary authority. All mon-

etary policy is made in the country of the adopted currency, without

consideration for local needs. (Examples: Ecuador and Panama have

adopted the USD. The Jugoslav province of Montenegro has adopted

the EUR.)

7. Currency unions. Several countries come together and create a com-

mon currency. A new central bank is created. Monetary policy is to

be adjusted for the best of the currency union as a whole. (Example:

EMU)

Note that the distinctions between these groups are not strict. Even in a

floating currency like the USD monetary authorities will from time to time

make interventions to adjust what is perceived as “extreme misalignments”.

One example is the so called Louvre Accord in 1985 when the G-7 agreed

that the USD was overvalued. In the following months the USD depreciated

extensively. A currency board will often be followed by dollarisation of much

of the economy. There will almost always remain uncertainty about the

long-term prospects of the board. Many will therefore chose to use foreign

currency instead of the home currency as a store of value.

67

Page 71: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

If any exchange rate peg shall be successful, one must keep the inflation

close to the inflation in country to which the currency is targeted. In shorter

periods, an exchange rate peg can survive even if monetary policy is not

fixed. In the long run a fixed exchange rate does demand a common monetary

policy. As most exchange rate pegs are in reality unilateral, that will normally

imply that the smaller country must adopt the monetary policy of the larger

country if a fixed currency shall be credible. Over longer periods of time this

only observed in very few cases. The Austrian peg to DEM is one of a few

such instances. Obstfeld and Rogoff (1995) find that only a few so-called

fixed exchange rates indeed had been fixed for more than 10 years.

Unilateral exchange rate system will generally be unstable, as a fixed

exchange rate by definition demands some sort of common monetary policy.

This is first solved if the unilateral system evolves into a currency union.

3.1.3 Optimal currency areas

Lack of credibility has made governments turn to fixed exchange rates to

assure convertibility. However, a fixed exchange rate might leave the open

for sudden adjustments, so-called currency crises (to which we return in the

next lecture). Although day-to-day volatility is less than in a flexible regime,

the volatility over time might be high if one has to leave the exchange rate

system at some time. This leaves us with the question of why a country

needs an independent currency at all.

In general one would at least keep a currency area as large as the area of

political independence—i.e. an optimal currency area will at least contain the

national borders of one country. That is not to say that the borders of this

“political area” necessarily comprise the borders of the “optimal currency

area”. From the OCA theory it might well be that e.g. the US should have

68

Page 72: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

had more than one currency. In practice political realities always overrule

the OCA-theory. If multinational organisations get a strong hand in national

decision making, one can extend the optimal currency area to the extension

of the whole (or parts) of the organisation, as has been done in the EU

through the European Monetary Union, EMU.

The main benefits of entering a common currency have been listed to be

that a currency union

• reduce transaction costs from currency conversion,

• reduce accounting costs and give greater predictability of relative prices

for firms doing business with firms in the other countries of the currency

area,

• if prices are sticky, insulate from monetary disturbances that could

affect real exchange rates, and

• reduce political pressure for trade protection based on swings in the

exchange rate.

For a small open economy the first two points are probably the most impor-

tant.

The potential costs of joining an optimal currency area include to

• forgo the possibility to use monetary policy to respond to regional-

specific real shocks. Remember that if the exchange rate is fixed, the

money supply is endogenous. It can no longer be adjusted by the

government.

• Further, one can no longer inflate away public debt or increase revenues

by extracting more seignorage.

69

Page 73: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

In the end the choice of the size of currency unions remains a political

one. The more integrated an area is, the less will the costs of a common

currency be, and the higher will the potential gains be. However, areas

that are tightly integrated economically, are often tightly integrated in other

dimensions as well. How integrated an area needs to be for a currency union

to work is uncertain. However, with increasing ease of communication, many

of the traditional arguments for national currencies disappear. There is for

example difficult to see why the citizens of EMU should trust the ECB less

than they trusted their former central banks.

3.1.4 The death of fixed exchange rates?

To assure an efficient flow of trade it is necessary that there is some sort of

convertibility between the national currency and the international currency.

If the national currency is not accepted abroad the country reverts to defacto

barter trade. This is the case for e.g. North Korea. Almost all trade with

North Korea is in the form of bilateral trade agreements—North Korea gets a

certain amount of one good against the delivery of a certain amount of North

Korean goods. Until the early 1970’s it was accepted that to assure growth

in trade there had to some sort of fixed relationship between currencies to

avoid to much uncertainty.

The actual experience after 1970, with more liberalised capital flows, has

shown us that

• floating exchange rates, although volatile, does not seem to be desta-

bilising for world trade nor financial flows as long as there is sufficient

trust in the governments issuing the currencies. For most developed

countries a floating exchange rate does not seem to reduce national

welfare.

70

Page 74: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

• With free capital flows speculative attacks cause abrupt adjustments in

fixed exchange rates. These adjustments might be very destabilising.

Many economist argue that the danger of such adjustments make fixed

exchange rates very unfortunate.

A popular argument today is that one no longer can make a unilateral

decision to peg a currency. According to this argument, there is only two

options:

• to float, or

• to “super-fix” the exchange rate, either through a currency board, dol-

larisation or by joining a currency union.

This view is captured by the following quote made by then U.S. Secretary of

the Treasury, Larry Summers in 2000:

“[F]or economies with access to international capital markets,

[the choice of the appropriate exchange rate regime] increasingly

means a move away from the middle ground of pegged but ad-

justable rates toward the two corner regimes of either flexible

exchange rates, or a fixed exchange rate supported, if necessary,

by a commitment to give up altogether an independent monetary

policy. ... [This policy prescription] probably has less to do with

Robert Mundell’s traditional optimal currency areas considera-

tions than with a country’s capacity to operate a discretionary

monetary policy in a way that will reduce rather than increase

the variance in economic output.”

From a historical perspective this view seems to be based more on a dis-

illusionment with the intermediate alternatives—like pegged-but-adjustable

71

Page 75: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rates or managed floats, than the historical merits of either of the two corners.

In fact, there are only a small number of countries that have attempted to

“super fix” their exchange rate. Likewise, with the recent exception of Mex-

ico, one has no good example of a developing market with a long experience

of a floating exchange rate.

The super-fixed exchange rate

A super fixed exchange rate includes a currency board and dollarisation. Sup-

porters of super-fixed exchange rates have argued that these arrangements

provide

• credibility,

• transparency

• very low inflation, and

• financial stability.

In addition, as in principle a super-fixed rate should reduce the risk of spec-

ulation and devaluation, domestic interest rates should be lower than under

alternative regimes.

The argument in favour of a super-fixed exchange rate is made even

stronger if one can argue that there is a correlation between country risk

and currency risk. Country risk is the risk of investing in a given country.

This can be measured as the premium on long-term domestic government

bonds relative to foreign government bonds. Country risk should, among

other things depend on the long term prospects of a country.

Currency risk is the risk of devaluation. This can, assuming the UIP to

hold, be measured as the premium on short-term domestic interest rates over

72

Page 76: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

foreign short-term interest rates. The argument is that a stable exchange rate

results in an environment that is more conductive to long term growth. So

low currency risk should lead to lower country risk. As can be seen from

figure 3.2, it does seem to be a relationship between these two measures in

the case of Argentina.

However, several things must be in place for a super-fixed rate to be

credible.

• Fiscal solvency. In a super-fixed rate regime the government can no

longer reduce the burden of public debt through inflation. This in-

creases the need for fiscal responsibility. Also, as monetary policy can

not be used for stabilisation purposes, there must be in place an ability

to run counter-cyclical fiscal policy.

• The lender of last resort function, which under flexible and pegged-but-

adjustable regimes is provided by the central bank, has to be delegated

to some other institution. This can either be a consortium of foreign

banks or some international organisation.

• Related to the point above, there is a need for a very solid domestic

banking sector, as the lender of last resort function will not function

properly.

• A currency board requires that the central bank holds enough reserves,

an amount that in fact will exceed the monetary base.

For a super-fixed exchange rate to succeed, all the above points need to

be satisfied. However, even then super-fixed regime will not be without

problems. There will always remain the possibility of a regime switch. If the

cost of the regime increases, e.g. due to an external shock, this can create

73

Page 77: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.2: Currency risk vs. country risk, Argentina 1994-1999

61

Figure 4:

Currency vs Country Risk Premia:

Argentina, 1994-1999

-5

0

5

10

15

0 500 1000 1500 2000 2500

Currency Risk Premium

Cou

ntry

Ris

k P

rem

ium

Source: Edwards, 2000

74

Page 78: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

uncertainty about the future of the regime. If investors start to move money

out, domestic interest rates will increase, thereby further increasing the cost

of maintaining a fixed regime.

Argentina adopted a currency board early in 1991. At that point the

Argentinean peso had lost confidence. In the late 1980’s the USD had become

the de facto unit of account. For many types of purchases the USD worked

as means of payment as well.

The currency board fixed the exchange rate between ARP and USD at 1:1.

The currency risk from 1993 to 1999 is illustrated in figure 3.3. In the early

years of the board, Argentine inflation exceeded US inflation, leading to a

real appreciation of the the ARP. Argentina was hit hard by the ripple effects

of the Mexican devaluation (the “Tequila-crisis”) in late 1994. However, as

the board survived this event, the confidence grew. Inflation stabilised, and

Argentina faced deflation in 1999 and 2000.

Argentina addressed the lender of last resort issue in three ways:

• Banks were required to hold a very high level of reserves.

• The central bank negotiated a substantial credit line with a consortium

of international banks to be used in times of financial pressure.

• Many of the domestic banks were taken over by foreign banks. Seven

out of eight of Argentina’s largest banks were in 2000 owned by major

international banks.

An important problem in the case of Argentina was probably fiscal sol-

vency. The Argentine government was not able to reform government in an

efficient manner. Attempts of privatisation did not result in increased pro-

ductivity, mainly because public monopolies were often exchanged for private

monopolies.

75

Page 79: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.3: Interest differential between peso and dollar denominated de-posits

62

Figure 5: Argentina, Interest Rate Differential between Peso and Dollar Denominated Deposits

(Weekly Data 1993-1999)

0

5

10

15

20

2/09/93 1/10/95 12/10/96 11/10/98

ARG_DIFSource: Edwards, 2000

76

Page 80: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.4: Fiscal balance in Argentina, 1991-2001

Source: The Economist, 2002

77

Page 81: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

At no time did expectations of devaluation disappear completely. The

result was a certain interest differential between the ARP and the USD.

One implication was that Argentineans choose to deposit money as ARP—

as ARP’s got the highest interest rate. However, if they borrowed money,

they borrowed USD, as the interest rate in USD was lower. This made the

banking sector very vulnerable to the effects of a change in the currency

board.

So what happened in Argentina? We will return to that question in the

next lecture. Argentina’s government did fulfill most requirements of a stable

currency board. However, it evidently failed on two important accounts: it

was not able to get full control of fiscal policy, and it was never able to remove

all doubts about the long term viability of the regime, not even among their

own people. In the end these two things terminated the regime.

The floating exchange rate?

If a super-fixed regime is so difficult to achieve, a floating exchange rate

remains the alternative. Table 3.5 shows that over the last twenty years more

and more countries have chosen managed or flexible exchange rate regime

instead of a regime with an exchange rate peg or limited flexibility. However,

recent empirical studies show that this apparent “floating” of exchange rates

might not be as clear cut as the IMF data suggests. In fact, ? find that most

developing countries that claim to have a float or a managed float do not

let their exchange rate fluctuate much outside a band of +/-2.5 per cent—

equivalent to pegged regime. This is even true for a number of industrialised

countries including, until recently, Norway. Floating regimes resemble non-

credible pegs—an observation Calvo and Reinhart attributes to a “fear of

floating”.

78

Page 82: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.5: Choice of exchange rate regime�������"�0%���� ��3����4����������������������A����

A���

8����������� ���������������������$�����$����������������������1����

����� ��

8� @������

��%�������

1��� �� ���%����

�>C� >C"� �"� �"� �"E

�>C� I."> ��"� �."> ��"�

�>E� .E"> �"I ,C"� E".

�>E� ..". �"I .I"� ��"�

�>>� �>", �."> .�"I .I"�

�>>� �."> E". .E"> .E">

�>>> ��"� ��"� ..". ,,"�

Source: Calvo and Reinhart, 2000

Why should there be a fear of floating in emerging markets? This can

probably be attributed to a lack of credibility.

• A fixed exchange rate provides a more clear-cut nominal anchor, as the

exchange rate is observable today. An inflation target will depend on

expectations about future inflation rates—and if credibility is low this

might result in higher interest rate volatility.

• In emerging markets debts are often denominated in foreign currency.

Large swings in exchange rates might impair the access to financial

markets. Sharp depreciations can be very expensive as the cost of

servicing debt rise.

• The pass through from exchange rates to inflation is traditionally higher

in emerging markets than in developed markets.

There is an ongoing debate on the issue of fixed versus flexible exchange

rates. Mainstream academic economists in the US and Europe, and the IMF,

79

Page 83: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.6: Exchange rate volatility in recent of current “floating” exchangerate regimes������������ �������������������� ����� ���������� ��������������� ����������������

��� ��� ������ ����������������������� ���������� ����� ����

��� ������� �������������������

!"#�$������ ���� �� !"#���%������ ���� �

����� ������

����

�������� ���������� ����

� !" #"!�

$���� �������� ���������� ���� ��!" �!�

&�������� '� �����$()*#&�����$((( �) +,�-

.���/�� 0���������$()%#1��������$((+ +��) (-�(

�� ��� '� ��$(+,#&�����$((( 2)�� (-�2

3 ��� 4�����$((-#&�����$((( )��� (-�*

5� �� 6�������$((-#1��������$((+ %, +���

4���� 1��������$((*#&�����$((( -*�2 2-�%

7���8���� � 4�����$()%#&�����$((( -(�$ +���

7������ 6�������$()2#4�����$((- -2�* +*�%

7����� 1��������$((�#1��������$((* +(�� (%�)

���� &������$((,#&�����$((( *%�� +$�*

�������� �� '� �����$())#&�����$((( 2,�+ +*�(

0�����&����� '� �����$()-#&�����$((( -��) 22��

0��� '� �����$()*#4���$()( %+�) (-�)

0���� 7�/������$((�#&�����$((( -%�$ +%�%

9�� �� '� �����$((�#&�����$((( %��( ++�(

&/�����:������� ��9�0��� ��'��� %$�2+ +(��+

0�� �������/����� :������� ��9�0��� ��'��� $+�)- $$�*$

4����� ��� ���������#&��� #�������;���������

3 �� ���� '����$((+#&�����$((( (�% $*�-

5���� 7�/������$((+#&�����$((( %�( $+�+

������ � '����$((+#&�����$((( $*�- -)�$

Source: Calvo and Reinhart, 2000

80

Page 84: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.7: Exchange rate volatility in recent of current “managed floating”exchange rate regimes������-����� �������������������� ����� ���������� ��������� ������������ ���������������

��� ��� ������ ����������������������� ���������� ����� ����

��� ������� �������������������

!"#�$������ ���� �� !"#���%������ ���� �

����� ������

����

�������� ���������� ����

� !" #"!�

$���� �������� ���������� ���� ��!" �!�

.���/�� '� �����$(()#&�����$((( $,, $,,

.��<�� '����$((*#1��������$(() )-�$ (*�-

����� 6�������$()�#&�����$((( *%�% )-�)

�������� '� �����$(+(#&�����$((( $%�2 )2�)

���� =��������$(($#1��������$(() (%�+ ()�(

>����� '� �����$(++#1��������$((+ %)�2 )%�-

3 ��� =��������$(+(#=��������$((- %-�2 )*�%

3 �� ���� 7�/������$(+)#'� ��$((+ (2�* ((�$

3����� 1��������$(($#&�����$((( *%�% (,�(

5� �� '� �����$(()#&�����$((( %$ +,�2

5���� 4�����$(),#6�������$((+ ),�$ (+�2

4������� 1��������$((�#0���������$(() %(�* )$��

4���� '� �����$()(#7�/������$((* 2*�- (%�+

7����� '� �����$((%#&�����$((( %2�( (,��

��?���� '� �����$()�#&�����$((( ++�) (��)

0� ������ '� �����$())#&�����$((( 2$�% ))�(

���?�� '� �����$(),#&�����$((( $��2 -2�)

9������ '� �����$((-#&�����$((( ���+ (�

�� �<���� &�����$((2#&�����$((( 2,�2 (-�(

&/�����:������� ��9�0��� ��'��� 2,�,% )+�%*

0�� �������/����� :������� ��9�0��� ��'��� �%�*- $*��)

Source: Calvo and Reinhart, 2000

81

Page 85: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

argue in support of flexible rate regimes. Many economists from developing

countries, and some western economists as well, are in support of more fixed

rates. As an example, several Asian countries have recently signed agree-

ments to secure common interventions in the case of speculative attacks—

certainly not what one would do in a floating exchange rate regime. For many

countries some sort of fixed exchange rate regime is still the only option for

gaining credibility in their monetary policies.

3.2 Why a fixed exchange rate system might

be unstable

As we seen in the above discussion, there are benefits and costs of having

a fixed exchange rate. However, even if a fixed exchange rate seems like an

optimal solution, it is difficult to retain a stable exchange rate. As we have

noted, few exchange rates remain fixed for a long period of time.

The n-1 problem illustrates a problem that occurs if two countries fix

their common exchange rate. A fixed exchange rate implies that if one coun-

try changes its money supply, the other country must do so as well if the

fixed exchange rate shall survive. The second problem occurs when differ-

ent shocks implies different policy strategies in the two countries. The third

problem occurs because the two governments might have different goals for

their monetary policy.

3.2.1 The n-1 problem

In the last lecture we found that if the exchange rate was fixed, money supply

would be determined by real output, the foreign interest rate and the foreign

price level:

mt = p∗t − ηi∗t+1 + φyt. (3.1)

82

Page 86: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The central bank must adjust the money supply to assure that equation (3.1)

hold.

In a unilateral exchange rate regime the country that fixes its exchange

rate will take the interest rate and the price level in the other country as

given. However, in a bilateral fixed exchange rate regime this becomes more

tricky. The fixed exchange rate determines the ratio of the money stocks

in the two countries, but not the level of the money stock. Either the two

countries must agree on how the money stock shall be determined, or one

country must accept the money stock set by the other country.

To see this we can use the following example. From the UIP we know that

if exchange rates are fixed between two countries, the nominal interest rate

must be the same in both countries. From the real money demand functions

discussed in the Cagan model we know that there is a relationship between

the interest rate and the money stock. For every level of the money stock

there will be a certain interest rate. We illustrate this relationship in figure

3.8.

If we have a fixed exchange rate, and the UIP hold, then the following

relationship must hold: if the interest rate in the foreign country fall because

the foreign country increases the money stock, then the domestic interest

rate must fall as well. This can only be achieved by increasing the money

stock in the home country. So a change in the money stock of one country

must imply a similar change in the money stock in the second country.

This is the n-1 problem. One has two countries, but only one exchange

rate. The basis of a multilateral exchange rate agreement is that the two

countries agree on how interest rates and money stocks shall be set. However,

often a multilateral fixed exchange rate regime is containing countries that

are not willing to compromise their opinion of what is the optimal money

83

Page 87: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.8: Interest rates and money stock

Country ACountry Bi

aib

ma

mb

supply. If the two countries can not agree, the fixed exchange rate will break

down.

Most fixed exchange rate systems has a de facto “base country” that is

supposed to work as a “nominal anchor”—i.e. set the money stock. In the

Bretton Woods the US was the base country. In the European Monetary

System (EMS) Germany was the base country. In both cases this worked

fine as long as the interests of the base country were the same as the interest

of the countries who took part in the exchange rate system. However, in

both instances situations occurred when that were no longer the case.

The breakdown of Bretton Woods

In the end of the 1960’s the USA were running considerable trade deficits.

When a country run a trade deficit, we must expect the currency to be over-

valued. As the exchange rate was fixed, an overvaluation can be alleviated

either through deflation in the home country or by inflation abroad. Accord-

84

Page 88: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

ing to the rules of the Bretton Woods system such deficits should not cause

a problem to the exchange rate.

The process was supposed to proceed as follows: if a country was running

a trade deficit, there is increased demand for foreign currency in the home

country. To meet this demand for foreign currency, the local central bank

must sell foreign exchange reserves. When the foreign exchange reserves are

reduced, this should cause a proportionate change in the money base. When

the money base falls, the local price level shall fall. A falling price level will

reduce the overvaluation. Over time the trade deficit will disappear.

A trade deficit in one country should be reflected in a trade surplus in

another country. The country with a trade surplus will experience excess

demand for the domestic currency. This will imply that the central bank

increases its holdings of foreign reserves. An increase in the holdings of

foreign reserves should imply an increase in the money base, and a rise in

the domestic price level. The real exchange rate should appreciate.

The US experienced a an increase in home demand mainly due to the

welfare reforms conducted under the Johnson administration, and due to the

increasing costs of the Vietnam war. The US government financed its public

deficit by printing more money. This money was used to purchase goods

abroad. To reduce the money base would reduce the US ability to run a

public deficit. The US administration was not interested in paying such a

cost.

The countries running trade surpluses were countries like Germany, Japan

and Switzerland. The US money stock had increased. To alleviate the mis-

alignments in the system, these countries had to allow their money stocks to

increase as well.

However, a country like Germany was not interested in importing US

85

Page 89: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

inflation. When the demand for DEM increased, the Bundesbank chose to

sterilise the increase in its currency reserves. At the same time as currency

reserves rose, it sold domestic bonds. This way the German money base

remained stable. However, at the same time the automatic stabilisation in

the Bretton Woods system broke down.

The real problem here was perhaps not that Germany did not want to

import inflation. In fact, the Bretton Woods system was supposed to include

an additional check to assure that the US should use its all important position

to impose inflation on other countries. Remember that the USD was fixed

to gold at the rate of USD 35 per ounce of gold.

If the holdings of USD increased to much, central banks in other countries

was supposed to bring these dollars to the Federal Reserve and claim gold in

return. Doing so, they would reduce the asset holdings of the Federal Reserve.

The Federal Reserve was supposed to react to such claims by reducing the

money base.

However, the most important holders of excess USD reserves, Japan and

Germany, chose not to do this. The reason was that both countries depended

on the US for both political and military reasons. They did not want to

endanger these relationships by forcing the US to reduce its money supply.

The only country that to some degree did claim gold for USD was France.

Over time it became “evident” to speculators that countries like Germany,

Japan and Switzerland rather would revaluate their exchange rates at a new

level than stay at a fixed level with an increased money stock. At this time

speculators started to move from USD to DEM, CHF and JPY. As no country

was willing to compromise about the optimal money supply in the Bretton

Woods system, the system was posed to break down. In early September 1971

US president Richard Nixon declared that the US was no longer committed

86

Page 90: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.9: Money supply shock in the US...

USD/DEM

MDEM

DUSD

S1USD

S0USD

US money supply increased as a result of more public spending, due to welfarereforms and the Vietnam war.

to fixed parity between USD and gold. With this declaration the Bretton

Woods system was de facto dead.

3.2.2 The adjustment problem

The point is this: If a country has a fixed exchange rate, it can not use

monetary policy for stabilising the economy. However, assume that there is

a shock to only one of the countries in the exchange rate mechanism. Then

the government must make a choice. Either it can use fiscal policy to stabilise

the economy, or it can leave the fixed exchange rate and use monetary policy.

Why might it choose the last strategy?

87

Page 91: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 3.10: And the consequences for Germany

DEM/USD

MDEM

DoDEM

D1DEM

SDEM

A money supply shock in the US increases demand for DEM. To hold the ex-change rate within the target zone Germany has two alternatives: exchangeUSD-reserves for gold, and thereby contract the US money supply (howeverthis was not politically feasible), or increase their own money supply (whichthey did not want to do, as this would imply importing US inflation to Ger-many).

88

Page 92: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

There will be a cost of leaving a fixed exchange rate. E.g. the government

might loose credibility if it wants to go back to a fixed exchange rate at a later

stage. However, there might also be a cost of not using monetary policy for

stabilisation. This will especially the case if prices and wages are sticky—i.e.

that they adjust only slowly.

Example: Assume that the cost of producing in the home country in-

creases. This might e.g. be due to a restriction of working hours that have

a negative effect on labour productivity. Implicitly this is a wage shock that

will affect the domestic price level. If the domestic price level increases, Q

will fall. The country experiences a real appreciation.

A real appreciation implies that domestic goods are less competitive on

international markets. This will have a real economic cost. However, to

alleviate the real appreciation the government has two choices:

1. it can force the price level down, or

2. it can devalue the nominal exchange rate.

The last option will however imply a break with the fixed exchange rate

policy. Why would a government choose this option over the option of de-

flating the economy? In fact it is very difficult to impose a downward change

in wages. It is also a process that might take a very long time, as most wages

are set by long term contracts. By devaluing the exchange rate home goods

will become cheaper abroad over night, without lowering wages at home. One

should however note that the purchasing power of home wages of course will

fall—as imports become more expensive.

Note that if the shock is symmetric, i.e. both countries in the system get

the same shock, monetary policy can be used for adjustment. Both countries

now have incentive to move the money supply in the same direction. This

89

Page 93: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

can be done without affecting the fixed exchange rate. Remember that the

fixed exchange rate can be sustained for an infinite number of different money

supplies, but only for one ratio of home money over foreign money. However,

in this case the real exchange rate will of course not be affected.

3.2.3 The problem of a credible policy—the Barro Gor-

don model

From your former lessons in macro, you know the concept of a Phillips curve.

The Phillips curve implies a relationship between unemployment and infla-

tion. In “modern macroeconomics” one thinks about the Phillips curve as

a fluctuations around a “non-accelerating-inflation-rate-of-unemployment”

(the NAIRU). The NAIRU is seen as the long-run rate of unemployment.

In the short term unemployment can be higher or lower than the NAIRU,

depending on whether inflation is higher or lower than expected inflation. If

we call unemployment for u, the NAIRU for un and inflation for π, and we

let πe be expected inflation, we can express the Phillips curve as

u = un + a(πe − π). (3.2)

If inflation exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for a short

period be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect inflation to

exceed expected inflation over time.

We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep inflation

stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the government has as a

goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un. This can be rationalised if

ne think there are some sort of inefficiencies in the labour market that lead

to an increase in the NAIRU rate. As a second best policy the government

90

Page 94: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

target an unemployment rate below the NAIRU. We specifically assume that

u∗ = σun, (3.3)

where 0 < σ < 1.

The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these two

elements:

L = π2 + b[u− u∗]2, (3.4)

where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemployment at u∗.

If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and (11.86), we obtain

L = π2 + b[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)]2. (3.5)

The government want to set inflation such that it minimises the value of

L. To do so we must take the derivative of L with regard to π, and set equal

to zero. This gives us

δL

δπ= 2π − 2ab[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)] = 0 (3.6)

If we solve with regard to π we get

πopt =ab(1− σ)un

1 + ba2+

ba2πe

1 + ba2. (3.7)

Assume that the government set π = 0, and that this is fully credible (the

public believes the government, so that πe = 0 as well). The the loss would

be

L = b[(1− σ)un]2. (3.8)

However, if πe = 0 we know that the optimal inflation rate from the point of

91

Page 95: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

view of the government would be

π =ab(1− σ)un

1 + ba2, (3.9)

which would give a loss of

L =1

1 + ba2b[(1− σ)un]2. (3.10)

One can show that

b[(1− σ)un]2 >1

1 + ba2b[(1− σ)un]2 (3.11)

for all values of b > 0. So, in a one period game—if the government only

cares about today, and not about the future, it will always be rational for

the government to try to fool the public by setting inflation higher than they

expect.3

However, if the public have rational expectations they will look through

this strategy. In fact the public will understand which inflation rate will

minimise the loss of the government, and expect this inflation rate. Indeed,

equilibrium if we assume rational expectations must be that πopt = πe. We

therefore know that

πe =ab(1− σ)un

1 + ba2+

ba2πe

1 + ba2, (3.12)

which implies that the equilibrium rate of inflation will be

π = πe = ab(1− σ)un. (3.13)

3Why should the government play one period games? Very simplified: because anelected government is supposed to only think about the next election.

92

Page 96: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

This will give the government a loss of

L = [ab(1− σ)un]2 + b[(1− σ)un]2 > b[(1− σ)un]2. (3.14)

The government will in other words be worse of than if it could follow a

credible policy of no inflation. However, it can not, because if a zero inflation

policy is indeed credible, the government has incentive to cheat be setting

inflation above zero for one period. The government is not able to tie itself

to the mast.

How should this affect a fixed exchange rate regime? Assume that country

A (e.g. Norway) has fixed its exchange rate to country B (e.g. Germany),

and that Germany follows a “zero inflation” policy. That is, Germany has

a bG = 0. If we assume the PPP to hold, the results from the Cagan model

implies that Norway must follow a zero inflation policy too. However, if the

Norwegian government has a bN > 0, such a policy will not be credible for

Norway.

3.2.4 Appendix: The real exchange rate

One reason why exchange rates are important for international trade is that

they are closely related to the real relative price of foreign goods. For ex-

ample, let P ∗ be the price, in foreign currency, of a bushel of foreign wheat,

and let P be the dollar price of a bushel of domestic wheat. We assume that

the quality of foreign and domestic wheat is the same. Which good is more

expensive? The relative price of foreign to domestic wheat is the ratio

Q = εP ∗

P. (3.15)

This makes sense. P ∗ is the price of foreign wheat, and ε is the domestic price

of foreign currency, so εP ∗ must be the price of foreign wheat in domestic

93

Page 97: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

currency. We then find the relative price by taking the ratio.

Q is often referred to as the real exchange rate. This is another way

of saying ‘relative price of imports’. Also, in practice we often use prices of

larger baskets of goods, such as the country specific CPI’s, to form the relative

price. Loosely speaking, the real exchange rate indicates how competitively

priced foreign goods are in terms of domestic goods: higher real exchange

rates tend to make a country’s exports more attractive on world markets.

If you think domestic and foreign goods are very similar, and that there

are relatively few barriers to trade it is reasonable to expect little variation

in the real exchange rate. The extreme case is to assume Q = 1. To see why

this is reasonable, assume that Q < 1, This implies that imported goods are

less costly than domestic goods. Consumers will therefore tend to purchase

foreign goods, creating a downward pressure on either (or both) the price

of domestic goods or the value of the domestic currency, until Q = 1. In

other words, prices of common goods should, expressed in units of a common

currency, be the same. When we talk about one good, price equalisation is

called the law of one price. When we talk about basket of goods, we call this

assumption purchasing power parity, PPP. Remember that when we defined

PPP in lecture 2 as

ε =P

P ∗ , (3.16)

we implicitly assumed that Q = 1.

Although in theory a fixed exchange rate can only be viable if the PPP

holds, in practice on will find that the PPP does not hold exactly all the time.

More specifically, if shocks differ between countries, Q might at any point of

time be bigger or smaller than one. If Q exceeds one, domestic goods improve

their competitiveness abroad, and we should expect that there evolves a trade

surplus. If Q < 1, domestic goods have lost competitiveness abroad, and the

94

Page 98: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

country should turn to trade deficit.

95

Page 99: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 4

Currency crises

4.1 Introduction

Some definitions:

• A “devaluation” is the move taken by the government to change the

target value of the fixed exchange rate regime to a weaker (higher)

exchange rate. A “revaluation” is the move taken by the government to

change the target value of the fixed exchange rate regime to a stronger

(lower) exchange rate.

• A speculative attack is a situation where a large number of market

participants go “one way” in the market—all participants either sell

or buy the asset. In a speculative attack on a fixed exchange rate the

central bank is obliged to stand as counter party to all transactions

within the target zone, unless someone else takes the deal. The central

bank will either do so by intervening in the markets directly, or by

changing interest rates. Changing interest rate might induce private

investors return to the currency to profit on the interest differential.

At the same time higher interest rates increase the cost of speculation.

When (if) the central banks pulls out the price of the asset will fall (or

96

Page 100: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rise). Often a period of turbulence occurs before a new equilibrium is

established.

• A “currency crisis” is a situation where a speculative attack forces the

central bank to make a change in the fixed exchange rate not actually

intended by the central bank.

What is the difference between a “controlled” change in the exchange

rate and a currency crisis? If the markets believe that the central bank will

change the target rate, rational investors would only trade on one side of

the markets—i.e. behave like in a speculative attack. The central bank has

incentive to present this as if it was forced to abandon the fixed exchange

rate, although its own behavior actually caused the markets to behave as

they did.

Note that a currency crisis might occur even if the exchange rate is not

fixed. If the markets bring forth a large change in a floating exchange rate

over a short period of time, the central bank will be expected to intervene, as

large changes in an exchange rate might destabilise financial markets. The

inability of the central bank to keep the exchange rate at the wanted target

can be considered a “currency crisis”, even if it does not induce a formal

devaluation.

There are three sides to all currency crisis: the government, investors with

liquid assets and investors with illiquid assets. For the government a currency

crisis is a question of credibility, of flexility in political decision making and

about a possible fallout because of negative implications of a sudden change

in the exchange rate. For a liquid, well informed investor a currency crisis is

a question of potential financial gains.

The illiquid investors are the most vulnerable to currency volatility. They

might not have the financial strength to diversify investments, or they might

97

Page 101: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

be contained to long term contracts. Further, these investors also tend to be

smaller and perhaps less informed than the liquid investors. The presence

of illiquid investors is especially a problem in countries with underdeveloped

financial markets.

In this lecture we will discuss the interaction between government incen-

tives and the behavior of the markets, by which we mean the liquid investors.

We will return to issue of the illiquid investors in the last part of the course.

4.2 Speculative attacks

In the last lecture we discussed three reasons for why a fixed exchange rate

might break down. They were all based on the fact that in a fixed exchange

rate system monetary policy is outside the full control of the central bank.

Changes in the money supply must be symmetric between the countries in-

volved in the system. If optimal policy makes for asymmetric monetary

policy, a fixed exchange rate is not sustainable.

1. The n-1 problem: the countries involved can not agree on a proper rate

of growth in the money supply.

2. The adjustment problem: if we have asymmetric shocks and sticky

prices, it might be optimal with leave the fixed rate regime.

3. The credibility problem: a fix is not sustainable if the governments

involved have different loss functions, i.e. they care about different

things.

If these were all the reasons why fixed exchange rate systems broke down,

one should expect that governments chose to leave such systems by purpose.

However, countries often first leave a fixed exchange rate system after a

98

Page 102: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

“speculative attack”, an event where the whole market has sold the currency

to the central bank because everyone believes that the central bank soon will

break its promise of a fixed rate.

An example of this is the EMS-crisis in 1992-93. After 1990 the countries

in the European Monetary System had attempted to limit fluctuations in

their exchange rates more actively—they had agreed on a less lenient use

of the escape clause. Some countries outside the EMS, as Norway, Sweden

and Finland also attempted to fix their currencies closer to the ECU. In the

August of 1992 the currencies came under great stress. First, investors sold

ITL and FIM. Both countries choose to devalue (or more exact—they let the

value of the currency float). In early September Great Britain left the EMS.

This attack is famous for the role of George Soros. His Quantum Funds is said

to have increased its value with 25 per cent due to exchange rate movements

in the fall of 1992. The speculators then turned to Scandinavia. Sweden came

under pressure. However, the Swedish government, eager to build credibility

in a new monetary policy, attempted to defend the exchange rate by rising

over night interest rates to 500 per cent. This policy was not sustainable,

and when the rates came down the attack continued. In November Sweden

devalued. Norway devalued in December after heavy interventions.

In a fixed exchange rate regime the central bank has promised to buy and

sell the currency at specified levels. The distance between the sell and buy

price will be the “target zone”, the room for fluctuations in the exchange

rate. The target zone is usually about +/- 2.5 per cent around the stated

“fixed rate”. However, a central bank can only buy the local currency in

exchange for foreign currency as long as it has foreign reserves available. In

theory it can borrow reserves for interventions. However, one rarely sees this

in practice. If the level of reserves become too low, the cost of standing by

99

Page 103: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.1: Swedens exit from the EMS—1992

0

20

40

60

80

100

6/01/92 10/19/92 3/08/93 7/26/93 12/13/93

SEINT1W

3.2

3.6

4.0

4.4

4.8

5.2

6/01/92 10/19/92 3/08/93 7/26/93 12/13/93

DEMSEK

100

Page 104: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

the promise of a fixed exchange rate might become to expensive—and the

currency is devalued.

There has been much effort to understand the nature of speculative at-

tacks. Some of what we know about speculative attacks can be summarised

in these points:

• From the “first-generation model” (the Krugman model), we have that

– A currency crisis will occur if the “shadow exchange rate”—the

exchange rate that would have been if the rate was floating—is

sufficiently different from the fixed rate ⇒ there must be some

relationship between the fixed rate and a “fundamentally sound”

rate.

– If there are any kind of “trend” that will affect the shadow ex-

change rate the timing of an attack can be calculated. The time

will be independent of “news”—it will only be a function of the

rate of growth in the trend and how this affects the shadow ex-

change rate.

• If there is no trend affecting the shadow rate, the shadow rate might

still fluctuate due to shocks.

– If fundamentals are very strong (the shock is weak) the govern-

ment will probably defend the currency no matter what.

– If fundamentals are very weak (the shock is strong) the govern-

ment will probably choose to devalue anyway.

– Between these levels there will be a “window of uncertainty”. For

a speculative attack to occur in this window, a sufficient number

of speculators must believe in a crisis at the same time. If only

101

Page 105: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

a few investors speculate against the currency, they might lose

money. For a speculative attack to succeed many investors must

act simultaneously.

This is the so-called “second generation model, or the “Obstfeld model”.

In this case speculation can cause a devaluation even if the government

did not intend to devalue if there had been no speculation.

In the last couple of years (after the Asian crisis) new questions have been

raised.

• Originally a trend that affected the shadow rate, as described in the

Krugman model, was understood as growth in the money supply or

depletion of foreign reserves. However, new models have emphasized

the role of implicit obligations of the government: if the government

has growing obligations to e.g. the banking sector, this might have the

same implications for the shadow exchange rate as a fall in the actual

level of foreign reserves.

• There has been much discussion on the question of contagion: why do

currency crises tend to occur in “batches”—why do several countries

experience currency crises at the same time?

• One has investigated whether e.g. hedge funds play a special role un-

der speculative attacks. One can show that this might be the case if

different investors have different information. If hedge fund have more

information than others, and this is known to everyone, the presence

of hedge funds might increase the volatility of capital flows.

• Last, much has been done on the role of regulating the exchange rate

market. This is an issue we return to at the end of the course.

102

Page 106: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

4.3 The Krugman model

We consider a small open economy where both the PPP and the UIP holds,

and all investors have perfect foresight. Further, we assume for simplification

that y = 0, i∗ = 0 and p∗ = 0. If we use a continuous time setting, and we

let·e be the rate of change in e, we can write the Cagan equation from the

lecture 2 on the form

mt − et = −η·e. (4.1)

It follows from equation (11.96) that if the exchange rate is fixed at e, the

money stock is fixed at

m = e. (4.2)

We now assume that the money stock is composed by two parts, domestic

credit, D, and foreign reserves, R, such that

Mt = Dt + εRt, (4.3)

when R is denominated in foreign currency terms. Let us further assume

that the government follows a policy that expand domestic credit at a fixed

rate µ, such that·D

D=

·d = µ. (4.4)

This can be thought of as a fiscal deficit monetisation by the central bank,

i.e. that the central bank issues money to pay for government expenditure.

However, if the central bank at the same time follows a fixed exchange rate

policy, if can not let the expansion of domestic credit affect the exchange

rate. So by definition we must have that

·D = −

·R, (4.5)

103

Page 107: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

⇒ expansion of domestic credit must be followed by a fall in the level of

reserves.

Such a policy can not last. Domestic credit can increase forever. Foreign

reserves have only a limited supply. At some point of time the foreign reserves

must be zero. At this time the central bank will no longer be able to stand by

its obligations in the fixed exchange rate regime—with no foreign reserves the

central bank can not fulfill the promise to exchange the domestic currency

into foreign currency at a given rate. So a policy of domestic credit expansion

must necessarily lead to the fall of the fixed exchange rate system.

When will such a collapse happen? Will it be when the inconsistent

policy is introduced? Or will the the exchange rate first collapse when the

the reserves are zero? In fact we observe that “currency crises” often seem

to occur independent of new information. How can we explain that in this

framework?

Let us define a “shadow exchange rate”, e, as the exchange rate that would

have been if the speculative attack had already occurred. After a speculative

attack, foreign reserves must be zero. In this case the money stock will only

contain domestic credit, so we must have that mt = dt. However, we assume

that domestic credit continues to grow at the rate µ. If the money supply

grows at a fixed rate, the exchange rate must depreciate at the rate ηµ, as

we found Lecture 1. This implies that the shadow rate of the exchange rate

will be

et = mt + ηµ = dt + ηµ = d0 + µt + ηµ. (4.6)

The Krugman model argues that by arbitrage the fixed exchange rate

must collapse at the moment when the shadow rate equals the fixed rate,

e = e. Why? Assume that the fixed exchange rate equals the shadow rate

at time T . Let the fixed exchange rate collapses at a T + 2. In this case

104

Page 108: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

the shadow rate will exceed the fixed rate. The fixed rate is terminated at

this point, the exchange rate must make a jump from e to e. A discrete

jump in the exchange rate will imply infinite profit opportunities for rational

speculators. As everyone have perfect foresight, everyone will try to sell the

domestic currency at time T + 1. Hence, the speculative attack will take

place at T +1. However, at T +1 the jump will still be discrete. So everyone

will sell at T .

Why not sell at T − 1? Simply because one would lose money by doing

so. If everyone sell at T − 1 the exchange rate actually will appreciate, as

the shadow rate at this time is lower than the fixed rate.

If we know when a speculative attack will occur, we can calculate the

exact timing of an attack. We know that the attack will occur when

e = d0 + µT + ηµ. (4.7)

Further, we know that

e = mo = ln(D0 + R0) (4.8)

so that

ln(D0 + R0) = d0 + µT + ηµ. (4.9)

T will then be given by

T =ln(D0 + R0)− d0 − ηµ

µ. (4.10)

We see that the larger the initial holdings of reserves, the higher must T be.

Further, T will decrease in the rate of growth in domestic credit.

T must occur at a time when R > 0. The speculative attack will occur

when the central bank still has some foreign reserves left. The result will

105

Page 109: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

be a fall in the money supply at time T as the central bank must sell its

foreign reserves during the attack. The reason why the money stock must

fall is because the investors expect the growth in domestic credit to continue

after the attack. Before the attack we had e = m. After the attack we have

e = m + µη. The money stock must fall so that

m = mT + µη ⇒ m−mT = µη. (4.11)

There are a number of weaknesses in the Krugman model. These include

that we assume perfect foresight, that we assume the UIP to hold at every

point of time and that we assume that the government follow a totaly incon-

sistent policy over time. One relevant question is why, when everybody has

perfect foresight, should the government care to follow an inconsistent policy

of this kind? However, the model tells us that if we want to understand why

a seemingly “irrational” event occurs—remember, here a speculative attack

occurs even if the central bank still controls foreign reserves—it is impor-

tant to understand long term underlying trends, and how these affect the

expectations of market participants.

4.4 Crises with no trend?

In the August 1993 the French franc, the Belgian franc and the Danish krone

all experienced severe speculative attacks. As a result of this the countries

agreed to widen their target zones within the EMS system from +/-2.5 per

cent to +/-15 per cent. However, within two years of the attack all three cur-

rencies were not far from the edge of the original band. Figure 4.3 illustrate

the movements of the BEF over the period from 1990 to 1999.

Over this time period little changed in the Belgian economic policy. Bel-

gium had with success followed a low inflation policy in the late 1980’s.

106

Page 110: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.2: Anatomy of a speculative attack

time

time

time

Tlog exchange rate

log foreign reserves

log money supply

Shadow floating rate

Fixed rate

Level of foreign reserves attime of attack

107

Page 111: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.3: The BEF against DEM—1990 to 1999BGF TO DEM

19.5

20

20.5

21

21.5

22

22.5

24.0

4.90

24.0

7.90

24.1

0.90

24.0

1.91

24.0

4.91

24.0

7.91

24.1

0.91

24.0

1.92

24.0

4.92

24.0

7.92

24.1

0.92

24.0

1.93

24.0

4.93

24.0

7.93

24.1

0.93

24.0

1.94

24.0

4.94

24.0

7.94

24.1

0.94

24.0

1.95

24.0

4.95

24.0

7.95

24.1

0.95

24.0

1.96

24.0

4.96

24.0

7.96

24.1

0.96

24.0

1.97

24.0

4.97

24.0

7.97

24.1

0.97

24.0

1.98

24.0

4.98

24.0

7.98

24.1

0.98

24.0

1.99

24.0

4.99

24.0

7.99

24.1

0.99

Inflation remained low. The Belgian state debt was high—it was (and is)

well above 100 of GDP—however it remained stable over the whole period.1

There was strong support in Belgium for the long term goal of joining a

common European currency. There was no obvious “trend” in Belgian pol-

icy that could be considered as incompatible with the commitment to a fixed

exchange rate.

The Krugman model is clearly not able to explain events such as those

we observed in Denmark, France and Belgium in 1993. In fact, a number of

more recent currency crises have aspects that are similar to what we observe

in these three countries. The Norwegian devaluation in 1992 happened in a

country that at the time of attack had lower inflation than Germany and a

very sound fiscal position.

A new line of currency crises models therefore emerged to suggest that

1One should note that the Belgian debt is mainly debt issued in domestic currency todomestic residents. This makes the high debt levels less of a problem with regard to theexchange rate.

108

Page 112: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

even sustainable currency pegs could be attacked and even broken. These

models focus on the choice of governments: they assume that the government

will make a continuous comparison of the net benefits from changing the

exchange rate versus the net benefits of defending it. When costs become to

high the fixed rate is abandoned. An important aspect is that speculation

itself will affect to the cost of holding an exchange rate fixed.

4.4.1 The strategy of speculators

The following game theoretic approach2 illustrates the case of how specula-

tive attacks might occur even in situations when the exchange rate peg is

sustainable. The basis of the argument is that there is a correlation between

the “discomfort” a government will feel about a devaluation and the level of

reserves the government chooses to hold.

Assume that if fundamentals are very strong, the government is not under

any circumstances willing to give up the fixed rate. In this case the level of

reserves the government is willing to commit to defending the exchange rate

is high. If fundamentals are very weak—think e.g. about a period when

the real exchange rate is overvalued—the government might be willing to,

or even interested in devaluing the exchange rate. So the level of reserves

committed to defending the rate will be low.

The problematic case is the “grey zone”. Where do “good” fundamentals

end and “bad” fundamentals start? Assume that the currency is slightly

overvalued in real terms. However, there are reasons to believe that one can

adjust this through lower inflation and tight fiscal policy. So the exchange

rate peg is sustainable. However, given the economic difficulties, the gov-

ernment is not willing to put its full force behind the exchange rate peg.

2From Obstfeld, 1995.

109

Page 113: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

In the model we assume that at such “intermediate” levels of fundamentals

the government is only willing to commit an intermediate level of reserves to

defend the exchange rate.

More specific, we assume three possible states of the economy. In the

good state the governments commits reserves equal to 20 “domestic money

units”, e.g. 20 billion NOK. For simplicity we assume that this equals the

total monetary base. In fact, such a commitment will make it impossible for

speculators to topple the exchange rate.

In the intermediate stage the government commits reserves equal to 10.

In this situation it is possible for speculators to topple the regime, but only if

the whole markets reacts at the same time. In the bad state the government

commits reserves equal to 6. In this case one large trader can topple the

regime alone.

We assume the existence of two traders. Each trader control resources

of 6 domestic money units. The traders incur a cost of −1 by attacking

the exchange rate. Figure 4.4 presents the result of alternative strategies

in the “good state”. In this case the traders will not be able to topple the

regime under any circumstances. They will gain 0 by doing nothing, and

lose −1 by speculating against the currency. The case of “hold, hold” can be

characterised as a “Nash equilibrium”.3

Assume that we are in the low state, and that one trader attack the

exchange rate. Then the central bank will offer this trader its whole portfolio

of reserves, equal to 6. Assume the currency depreciates with 50 per cent.

The trader makes a profit of 2—the income from the speculation is 34 and

3A Nash equilibrium is a state where nobody, when the behaviour of everyone else istaken as given, can improve on their outcome by changing their own strategy.

4Assume that the peg was on the level 1:1. The trader exchanges 6 domestic currencyunits in 6 foreign currency units at the rate 1:1. After the devaluation she can exchangeback at the rate 1.5:1—for her 6 units of foreign currency she will get 9 units of domestic

110

Page 114: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.4: Attack when fundamentals are strong. Committed reserves=20.

0,0

-1,-1-1,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

111

Page 115: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.5: Attack when fundamentals are weak. Committed reserves=6.

0,0

1/2,1/22,0

0,2

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

the cost of speculation is −1. However, if both traders sell at the same time,

the traders will share the central bank reserves between each other. Both

will make an income of 3/2, and a profit of 1/2. This case is illustrated in

figure 4.5. In this case the “sell, sell” strategy will be a Nash equilibrium.

The most interesting case is made up by the intermediate fundamentals.

In this case no trader can topple the regime alone. So if a trader acts alone,

she will gain nothing, and lose the cost of speculation. However, if both

traders attack at the same time, both will gain 5/2 − 1 = 3/2, as they will

share the committed reserves of the central bank between them. This case

is illustrated in figure 4.5. Her we have two Nash equilibria—it will be an

equilibrium to “hold, hold”, but it will also be an equilibrium to “sell, sell”.

currency. She will make a profit of 9− 6 = 3 units of domestic currency.

112

Page 116: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.6: Attack when fundamentals are “intermediate”. Committed re-serves=10.

0,0

3/2,3/2-1,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

In this situation we have possible instability—the peg might survive or it

might not, depending on whether the traders are able to co-ordinate their

attack or not.

4.4.2 The role of large speculators

Of course, the investor will never know exactly what commitment the central

bank is ready to offer. So the investor must first observe some signal that

gives her an opinion about the economy. Then she makes up her mind about

a speculation strategy. If she finds that she have positive expected returns,

she will attack. If expected returns are negative, she will not attack.

One question that has been asked is what role large speculators play in

113

Page 117: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

determining the fait of fixed exchange rate regimes. Above, I referred to the

story of George Soros and the devaluation of the GBP in 1992. Soros is said

to have made billions of USD during this attack.

What is a large speculator? There exist funds that control enormous

amounts of money. Several American pension funds have resources in excess

of the Norwegian GDP. However, when we talk about a “large player” in

the FX-market, it is not necessarily market capitalisation that is interesting.

Rather it is the ability to take high risk positions. Most banks and pensions

funds have strong restrictions on the level of risk they can take.

However, there exists a type of institutions that have no juridical restric-

tions on their risk positions. These are the so-called hedge funds. Hedge

funds are financial institutions that specialise on making money on poten-

tial mis-pricing in financial markets. The hedge fund will form an opinion

of what it perceives to be the “shadow exchange rate”. If the fixed rate

and the “shadow rate” diverges, there are potential profits to be gained by

speculating in this market.

The main difference between a hedge fund and a e.g. mutual fund is that

while public regulators will take some responsibility for checking up on the

practices of a mutual fund, the investors in a hedge fund is perceived to be

able to take care of themselves. There is no restrictions on how a hedge fund

can invest.

The fast way to make money in financial markets is by gearing risk. That

is to gamble with loaned money. Assume that you expect the stock of firm

A to increase with 50 per cent over a year. You have NOK 100. If you invest

all you have in the firm, you expect to make NOK 50. However, assume

that you gear your investment 10 times. That is, you offer a bank 100 as a

security, and borrow 1000 for investment in the stock. The cost of the loan

114

Page 118: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

is 10 per cent, i.e. 100 for a year. If your expectations go in you gain 500 on

your investment, and earn 400 after loan cost are paid. So you increase your

profits by 800 per cent. However, the risk is of course considerable. Say that

the firm actually goes bust. Then you lose 500 plus the cost of the loan, a

total of 600. That is 500 more than you have...

An institution that basis its investment strategy on gearing is called a

highly leveraged insinuation. Most hedge funds fall in this category. This

implies that even a relatively small fund can take very large positions during

e.g. a speculative attack.

How can an American hedge fund with no NOK assets attack a currency

peg involving the NOK? It can do so by going short—i.e. sell currency in

the forward market. When the hedge funds sells a forward contract on the

delivery of NOK, the opposing party will be a bank. The contract implies that

the bank must take a delivery of NOK sometime into the future. However,

the bank does not want to expose itself to currency risk. So it will cover the

contract by selling NOK today. If there is no market for this NOK today,

the central bank must intervene, and foreign reserves will be depleted. The

hedge fund can force a spot sale of NOK today by intervening in the forward

market. However, one should note that this strategy is not risk free. The

cost of the forward contract is the same as the interest differential between

the two currencies of the contract. To short sell NOK is equivalent to taking

a loan in NOK. If Norges Bank increases its interest rates to stop the attack,

the cost of such a contract can be high.

Hedge funds have been accused of trying to destabilise financial markets.

The accusors are both politicians and economists, and they include, in a ran-

dom order of importance, the former French president Francois Mitterand,

the Malaysian prime minister Dr. Mathahir and the head of Norges Bank

115

Page 119: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Svein Gjedrem. The central banks of Hong Kong and Australia have both

issued reports where they accuse hedge funds of manipulating the local ex-

change rates. In the case of Norway, it has been reported that the fund

Tiger Management has been actively involved in speculation against NOK.

The same is the case of Chase Manhattan, although Chase is not a hedge

fund.

The idea is that a “large player” could generate profits by secretly selling

the currency forward and then deliberately trigger a crisis by making a large

spot sale combined with some public statements of how weak the currency is.

One example of manipulation might have taken place in Hong Kong in 1998.

It is said that funds short sold both the HKD and the Hang Seng index at

the same time. The idea was that by selling HKD they would force the Hong

Kong Monetary authority to leave the currency peg. Then they would make

money in on the currency contracts. Short selling the stock market would

increase the pressure for a devaluation. However, if the authorities raised

interest rates to defend the pegged rate one should expect the stock market

would fall. Then the investors would make money on the stock contracts

instead.

Was this a case of manipulation? “Fundamental analysis” probably could

justify both going short in the currency, and short in the stock market. Of

course by taking such positions, investors might contribute to making such

events inevitable. But whether this is “manipulation” or not is hard to say.

In fact the Hong Kong authorities pulled of a “double defence”. They

increased interest rates to defend the peg. However, at the same time they

intervened in the stock market to boost prices. This way investors lost money

on both their contracts. Hong Kong authorities might have fooled potential

speculators. The question is how this willingness to intervene in the markets

116

Page 120: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

affected the perception of other potential investors in Hong Kong.

How should we analyse the role of large investors? Take the example of

speculation given above. Assume that the two traders have unequal size. E.g.

let one investor control resources equal to 9 domestic currency units, and the

small investor controls resources equal to 3 units. What would change? The

“good state” remains as before. No devaluation would occur. In the bad

state the small investor could no longer attack the currency alone. In fact,

the “large player” gets a proportional share of the central bank reserves—

i.e. 75 per cent of the reserves, as she has 75 per cent of the market, then

the small investor would not care about the currency markets at all. The

small investor would lose money by selling anyway, given the high costs of

speculation. This is illustrated in figure 4.7.

In the intermediate case however, there would be no real change. The

large trader needs the support of the small trader to succeed. Only the

payoffs would be different from the case where the traders were of equal size.

If size is the only difference between two traders, this might affect who

takes part in an attack when the central bank has only a low commitment

to a fixed exchange rate. However in these cases an attack is probably due

to happen anyway. In the cases when fundamentals are stronger, the whole

market still needs to take part for an attack to succeed.

If the large trader is different from the small trader on other counts than

just size, this argument will of course change. If the large player is perceived

to have superior information, that might increase her ability to influence the

behavior of the market. If the large player has less cost of speculating than

the small investor, this might also affect the results. An extreme version of

this case is reflected in figure 4.9. Here we assume the large trader has no

cost of speculating. In this case it would be optimal for the large trader to

117

Page 121: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.7: Attack when fundamentals are weak. Committed reserves=6.Trader 1 controls 9 units, trader 2 3 units.

0,0

5/4,-1/42,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

118

Page 122: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.8: Attack when fundamentals are intermediate. Committed re-serves=10. Trader 1 controls 9 units, trader 2 3 units.

0,0

11/4,1/4-1,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

119

Page 123: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.9: Attack when fundamentals are intermediate and the large traderhas no cost of speculation. Committed reserves=10. Trader 1 controls 9units, trader 2 3 units.

0,0

15/4,1/40,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

always speculate—and therefore for the the small trader to speculate as well.

If the costs of speculation is very small, the volatility of the exchange rate

might increase.

4.4.3 A short note on the Tobin tax

A Tobin tax is a proposed tax on on all transactions in the foreign exchange

market.

Intention: to reduce excess volatility caused by low costs of transaction.

Will it work? Yes—and no.

• Hinder currency crises? If the cost is high relative to expected gains

120

Page 124: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

a tax will reduce the probability of crises. However, the tax necessary

must probably be high. And there are possible problems, see example

below.

• A tax would make the markets less liquid. It is not perfectly clear how

that will effect the price process. However, short term volatility might

fall.

• It has been argued that for a Tobin tax to be effective it must be

implemented in all territories—if only a tiny bit of land is excluded one

could move all FX transactions there to avoid the tax. However, a tax

that covers the OECD countries will probably still have a substantial

effect.

• The real problem is financial derivatives. It is possible to speculate

in the FX-market without being in the FX-market—one can create

financial derivatives that reflect the risk in the FX market.

4.5 Contagion

Figure 4.11 depicts the development of Asian currencies over the period from

1996 to 1998. As we see, during 1997 there occurred a period of severe

volatility that lead to a shift from fixed exchange rate regimes to floating

exchange rate regimes.

In figure 4.12 we take a closer look at the period from May 15 to De-

cember 31 1997. We observe that the crises did not occur simultaneously.

Rather they occurred one after another. There is signs of some sort of re-

gional “spread”. This phenomena is often referred to in the literature as

“contagion”.

121

Page 125: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.10: Example of how a Tobin tax can be destabilising (note thatthis is an extreme case). Trader 1 controls 6 units, trader 2 6 units. Costincreases from 1 to 2.

0,0

1/2,1/22,0

0,2

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

0,0

-1/2,-1/21,0

0,1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

Attack when fundamentals are weak. Committed reserves=6. In first casecost of speculation is set to -1. In second case cost of speculation is set to-2. In the first case we have one Nash equilibrium, in the lower, right corner.In the second case we have two Nash equilibria, in the upper right and lowerleft corner. This creates the possibility of a more unstable situation.

122

Page 126: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 4.11: Asian currencies against USD, 1996-98

-0.5

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

01.0

1.96

01.0

2.96

01.0

3.96

01.0

4.96

01.0

5.96

01.0

6.96

01.0

7.96

01.0

8.96

01.0

9.96

01.1

0.96

01.1

1.96

01.1

2.96

01.0

1.97

01.0

2.97

01.0

3.97

01.0

4.97

01.0

5.97

01.0

6.97

01.0

7.97

01.0

8.97

01.0

9.97

01.1

0.97

01.1

1.97

01.1

2.97

01.0

1.98

01.0

2.98

01.0

3.98

01.0

4.98

01.0

5.98

01.0

6.98

01.0

7.98

01.0

8.98

01.0

9.98

01.1

0.98

01.1

1.98

01.1

2.98

Indonesian rupiah

South Korean won

Malaysian ringgit

Thai bath

Taiwan dollar

Figure 4.12: Asian currencies against USD, May 15, 1997-December 31, 1997

-0.2

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

15.0

5.97

22.0

5.97

29.0

5.97

05.0

6.97

12.0

6.97

19.0

6.97

26.0

6.97

03.0

7.97

10.0

7.97

17.0

7.97

24.0

7.97

31.0

7.97

07.0

8.97

14.0

8.97

21.0

8.97

28.0

8.97

04.0

9.97

11.0

9.97

18.0

9.97

25.0

9.97

02.1

0.97

09.1

0.97

16.1

0.97

23.1

0.97

30.1

0.97

06.1

1.97

13.1

1.97

20.1

1.97

27.1

1.97

04.1

2.97

11.1

2.97

18.1

2.97

25.1

2.97

Thailand

Malaysia

Indonesia

South Korea

123

Page 127: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Why do contagion occur? Four reasons have been presented:

1. Several countries can be similarly affected by a common shock.

2. Trade linkages can imply that a crisis in one country weakens funda-

mentals in other countries.

3. Financial interdependence.

4. A currency crisis in one country can change market participants’ per-

ceptions of other countries, resulting in the withdrawal of capital.

Argument one is providing a “fundamental” explanation of the spread of

crises. Argument number four favour the perception of crisis as “self-fulfilling”.

This argument does however depend on assumptions of limited rationality

among market participants. It is no reason why a crisis in one country should

affect rational expectations of other countries unless there are real links be-

tween the two economies. Arguments two and three are therefore perhaps

the more interesting, as they provide explanations of why a crisis can be

transmitted between countries even if there are no common shock.

4.5.1 Transmission of currency crisis via trade chan-

nels

It is important to point out that transmission via trade channels do not

depend on the existence of trade channels between the countries affected. In

fact, in the case of Asia one common feature is the relatively small trade

flows between the countries affected by the speculative attacks.

The important feature is to which degree the exports of two countries

are competing in foreign markets. In table 4.3 we illustrate the case with

countries A and B exporting to countries C and D. Country A sends most

124

Page 128: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

of her exports to country C, while country B sends most of her exports to

country D.

Assume that country A devalues with 10 per cent. What is the effect on

the exports of country B? To say something about this we must make some

assumptions about how close substitutes the goods of A and B are in C and

D. We assume that there is a one-to-one relationship between a devaluation

and an change in demand in the importing country. If the price of goods

from country A falls with 10 per cent, the demand for goods from country B

falls with 10 per cent. The relative price elasticity ρ, is set equal to 1.

The total effect of a devaluation in country A on the exports of country

B will be given by

∆exshareB =∑

k=C,D

[ρ(k) · exshareB(k) ·marketshareA(k)] · dev, (4.12)

where exshareB(k) is the export share of country B in market k, k ∈ {C, D},

and dev is the devaluation in per cent. If we substitute in from table 4.3 we

obtain

∆exshareB = [1 · 0.1 · 0.9] · 0.1 + [1 · 0.9 · 0.1] · 0.1 = 1.8%. (4.13)

The exports of country B will fall by 1.8 per cent.

However, assume that country A and B are competing in the same mar-

kets. An example is given in table 4.2.

In this case the effect of a 10 per cent devaluation in country A will be

∆exshareB = [1 · 0.1 · 0.5] · 0.1 + [1 · 0.9 · 0.5] · 0.1 = 5%, (4.14)

a 5 per cent fall in the exports of country B.

In the case of South East Asia, these countries were all competing in

125

Page 129: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Tab

le4.

1:N

on-c

ompet

ing

trad

eflow

sIn

itia

ltr

ade

flow

sExport

share

Mark

et

share

valu

eC

Dper

cent

CD

per

cent

CD

Fro

mA

9010

A90

10A

9010

B10

90B

1090

B10

90

Tab

le4.

2:C

ompet

ing

trad

eflow

sIn

itia

ltr

ade

flow

sExport

share

Mark

et

share

valu

eC

Dper

cent

CD

per

cent

CD

Fro

mA

1090

A10

90A

5050

B10

90B

1090

B50

50

126

Page 130: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

foreign markets. They all specialised on electronics and computer compo-

nents, sending their goods to Japan, the USA and Europe. The actual trade

between these countries was of lesser importance. However, in this case the

actual devaluations were not 10 per cent. Thailand, Malaysia and South

Korea experienced devaluations of close to 50 per cent. If we assume a 50

per cent devaluation in country A, we get a 9 per cent fall in exports in

country B in the “little competition case”, and as much as 25 per cent fall

in the exports of country B in the “strong competition case”. Effects of that

magnitude would certainly create a “fundamental” basis for a devaluation in

country B as well.

4.5.2 Transmission via a credit crunch

We consider a case where two banks, bank 1 and 2, lend to three different

countries, A, B and C. However, the dependence on the two banks differ

between the three countries. This is not an unrealistic assumption. Often

banks will specialise on lending to specific geographical regions.

No assume that there is a speculative attack in country A, and that

country A defaults on its foreign debt. Both bank 1 and 2 will lose all they

have lent to country A. As a result both banks need to recall loans to satisfy

the demands of their creditors. Bank 1 have total loans of 40 (20+20) after

the default of A. It must recall a total of 20, which makes up 20/(20+20)=50

per cent of its loan portfolio. Bank 2 had an exposure of 10. It must no

recall 10, which makes up 10/(10+80)=11.1 per cent of its portfolio.

For country B this means that total loans are reduced from 30 to

20 ∗ 0.5 + 10 ∗ 0.899 = 18.9.

That implies a reduction in total loans of (30-18.9)/30=37 per cent. For

127

Page 131: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Tab

le4.

3:B

ank

dep

enden

ceIn

itia

lport

folio

Exposu

reD

ependence

Fro

m:

Ban

k1

Ban

k2

Ban

k1

Ban

k2

Ban

k1

Ban

k2

Tota

l:To:

A20

1033

10B

2010

3310

6633

100

C20

8033

8020

8010

0Tota

l:10

010

0

128

Page 132: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

country C we find that total loans are reduced from 100 to

20 ∗ 0.5 + 80 ∗ 0.899 = 81.1.

That implies a reduction in total loans of (100-81.1)/100=18.9 per cent.

The point here is that a default in one country might have large effects

on the financing of other countries if there are some kinds of concentration

in lending. If credit channels and trade channels are both regional specific

the transmission effects can be substantial. In other words, a shock to one

country might have substantial implications for other countries, even though

these countries before the crisis had “strong fundamentals”, and even if we

assume investors to be fully rational. Through trade and credit channels

economies can be interdependent despite no direct links between them.

129

Page 133: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 5

The FX-market

5.1 Some definitions

5.1.1 Instruments

• Spot market: Spot transactions in the FX-market are transactions

made today that shall be completed within two days, i.e. formal deliv-

ery of the currency will take place in two days.

• Outright forward: transaction that contract delivery of the currency at

some point beyond two days.

• Option: The right to buy (or sell) an asset at a predetermined value.

• Swap: Bundles two FX transactions that go in opposing directions.

Usual to combine a spot transaction and an outright forward.

Example: buy 100 million EUR today for USD at spot exchange rate.

At the same time agree to sell EUR 100 million in one month. Purpose:

Lock in interest rate differential. If I need EUR 100 million from now

and one month into the future, I can reduce the cost of holding this

sum to the interest differential between EUR and USD by doing a swap

today. I will remove all exchange rate risk.

130

Page 134: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Swaps come in two types.

– “Short swaps” are contracts that give delivery today or tomorrow—

i.e. before the delivery in a standard spot contract. Short swaps

are used for liquidity purposes.

– “Long swaps” are swaps with spot contracts and future contracts

with delivery beyond two days.

5.1.2 Bid-ask

All exchange rates are quoted as two prices—a bid and an ask. On the

Reuters screes you will see quotes of the type:

USD/EUR 0.8810-0.8812

0.8810 will be the price where the bank is willing to buy EUR. This is the

bid price for EUR.

0.8812 will be the price where the bank is willing to sell EUR. This is the

ask price for EUR. The seller asks 0.8812 USD to give you one EUR.

Note that the bid price for EUR will be the aks for USD—the price of

one USD is after all only the inverse of the price of one EUR. This might be

confusing...

Table 5.1: Example of bid-ask. Assume that CAD/USD=1.5858/1.5865Bid Ask

Price of USD 1.5858 1.5865Price of CAD 0.6303 0.6306

Trading in the market, dealers will only quote the last two numbers of

the exchange rate. In the above transactions, dealers will say they have a

bid of 10 and an ask of 12.

131

Page 135: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The spread is measured in basis points. One basis point is one 1/10000 of

the unit, that is one point in the fourth decimal of the quote. In the above

example the spread is two basis points.

The spread is the only ‘transaction cost’ in non-brokered interbank foreign

exchange transactions. The spread is a ‘fee’ on the trading. Note that the

spreads in the sport FX-market is much lower than what you will expect

in most financial markets. E.g. a standard fee in equity trading can be 1

per cent of amount transacted—if the fee is symmetric (same for sell and

purchase) that amounts to the the equivalent of 200 basis points. In the FX

market spreads are seldom above 10 points in liquid markets.

5.2 What we know for certain about the FX-

market

The FX-market is riddled with “puzzles”—things we do not understand.

However, there are a few things we do know will hold for certain. In both

examples bellow we will ignore the bid-ask spread. This simplifies things

considerably. However, the logic still holds it we assume the existence of

spreads.

5.2.1 Triangular arbitrage

Let us ignore the bi/ask spread. Assume that we have

• HKD/USD 7.70 (HKD-Hong Kong Dollar)

• ZAR/USD 11.9 (ZAR-South African Rand)

What is the HKD/ZAR rate?

HKD/USD

ZAR/USD=

7.70

11.9= 0.6471 HKD/ZAR. (5.1)

132

Page 136: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Suppose not. Suppose e.g. that HKD/ZAR=0.75. This means that we

can make a profit by arbitrage. How? Sell one ZAR and get 0.75 HKD. Sell

0.75 HKD and get 0.0974 USD. Sell 0.0974 USD and get 1.159 ZAR ⇒ you

have made a profit of 16 per cent!

Such profits can not exist for long in a free market. They will be traded

away. In the end triangular arbitrage must hold.

5.2.2 Covered interest rate parity—CIP

Let F be the forward exchange rate. Consider two portfolios:

1. Invest 1 USD at the US 1 year interest rate of i. In one year you will

have USD · (1 + i).

2. Convert 1 USD to GBP at the spot rate ε today. This gives you a total

of GBP=USD/ε. Invest this at the UK 1 year interest rate of i∗. In

one year you will have the equivalent of (USD/ε) · (1 + i∗). However,

you measure your money in USD, so you want to convert back to USD

in the end of the year. To lock in the profit you buy a forward contract

at the price F for delivery of USD in one year. The contract should

cover an amount of GBP=(USD/ε) · (1 + i∗). The amount earned will

then be (USD/ε) · (1 + i∗) · F .

These two transactions are equivalent. If the UK and the US assets are

similar, there is no risk difference involved by doing one transaction versus

the other. So we should expect that:

(1 USD) · (1 + i) =(1 USD)

ε· (1 + i∗) · F. (5.2)

133

Page 137: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

It follows that we must have

F

ε=

(1 + i)

(1 + i∗). (5.3)

CIP should hold at every point of time unless there are restrictions on

the trade in capital assets.

To sum up: it should not be possible to lend riskless dollars at different

rates in two different markets. A covered international investment is the

same as a domestic investment: they both involve no currency risk. Ergo,

the return should be the same. The forward rate should reflect this.

In logarithmic terms the return of the covered international investment

will be

i∗ + f − e. (5.4)

The return on the domestic investment must be i. So we must have that

f − e = i− i∗. (5.5)

5.3 How the FX-market is organised

Assets are traded in three different types of markets:

1. Auction market. Customers submit orders. These can either be

• market orders—buy or sell at the current market price, or

• limit orders—buy or sell at a the in the contract predetermined

price. When the market reaches the limit price, the order is ex-

ecuted. If the market never reaches the limit price, the order is

never executed, or at least not at that price.

There will be no dealers in this market, only a system for organising

the stream of orders.

134

Page 138: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

An example of an auction market is to be found at the Paris Stock

Exchange.

2. Single-dealer market. In this market we have one dealer who offers a

best bid and a best ask. The customer must accept the offer of the

dealer. FX markets in some developing countries will work as single

dealer markets, with the central bank acting as the single dealer.

3. Multiple dealer market.

• Centralised. Quotes from many dealers will be available at one

screen at the same time. Example: NASDAQ.

• Decentralised. Many dealers will offer quotes. However, there is

no system to keep track of all offers in the market at the same

time.

The FX-market can best be described as a decentralised multiple dealer

market. There exists no exchange and no common screen for all quotes.

This means that trading will be partly fragmented—it is not possible

to observe the price in all simultaneous transactions.

Note that there are two types of traders that are active in the FX-market:

1. brokers, and

2. dealers.

These groups offer slightly different services.

Dealers will offer two-way prices (both bid and ask). Direct trade between

dealers will be conducted over a computer system, or over the telephone.

Mostly they will use something called Reuters D2000-1. An example of

communication over Reuters D2000-1 is provided in figure 5.1. One dealer

135

Page 139: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.1: Interdealer communication on D2000-1

Figure 3 provides an example of a D2000-1 conversation when a trade takes place. Aconversation starts by a dealer contacting another dealer. The contacting dealer usuallyasks for bid and ask quotes for a certain amount, for instance USD one million.4 Whenseeing the quotes, the contacting dealer states whether he wants to buy or sell. Some-times he asks for better quotes, or end the conversation without trading. However, mostconversations result in a trade (70%). All D2000-1 transactions in the data set take placeat quoted bids or asks.

Figure 3: D2000-1 conversationFrom ‘‘CODE’’ ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’ *0728GMT ????98 */7576

Our Terminal: ‘‘CODE’’ Our user: ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’

DEM 1

# 45.47

BA> I BUY

# TO CONFIRM AT 1,8147 I SELL 1 MIO USD

# VAL ??(+2)??98

# MY DEM TO ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’

# THANKS AND BYE

TO CONFIRM AT 1,8147 I BUY 1 MIO USD

VAL ??(+2)??98

MY USD TO ‘‘FULL NAME HERE’’

THANKS FOR DEAL FRDS. CHEERS

#

# END REMOTE #

^ ## TKT EDIT OF CNV 7576 BY ‘‘CODE’’ 0728GMT ????98

^ STATUS CONFIRMED

^ ##ENDED AT 07:27 GMT#

( 293 CHARS)An example of a D2000-1 conversation when a trade takes place. The first word means that the call came “From”another dealer. There are information regarding the institution code and the name of the counterpart, and the time(Greenwich Mean), the date, and the number assigned to the communication. DEM 1 means that this is a requestfor a spot DEM/USD quote for up to USD 1 million, since it is implicitly understood that it is DEM against USD.At line 4, we find the quoted bid and ask price. Only the last two digits of the four decimals are quoted. In thiscase, the bid quote is 1.8145 and the ask quote is 1.8147. When confirming the transaction, the communicationrecord provides the first three digits. In this case, the calling dealer buys USD 1 million at the price 1.8147. Therecord confirms the exact price and quantity. The transaction price always equals the bid or the ask. There is alsoinformation regarding the settlement bank. “My DEM to “Settlement bank” identifies the settlement bank of “ourbank”, while “My USD to “Settlement bank” identifies the settlement bank of the other bank. It is usual to end aconversation with standard phrases, such as “thanks and bye,” “thanks for deals friends.”

3.2.2 Electronic broker systems

Electronic broker systems fill the same functions as voice-brokers, but are more efficient.A bank dealer with access to one of the electronic broker systems can enter his buy and/orsell price into the system as a market maker. D2000-2 and EBS show only the highestbid and the lowest ask, thereby minimizing the spread. These will normally be entered bydifferent banks, but the identity of the inputting bank is not shown. The total quantityentered for trade on these quotes is also shown. This means that when more than onebank input the same best bid (ask) price, the quantity shown is the sum of that offered bythese banks. This quantity is shown as integers of USD one million, and in some bilateralcases DEM one million. When the quantity is at least ten million, “R” is entered on theD2000-2 screen. EBS shows two set of bid and ask quotes, for amounts up to ten millionUSD or DEM, and for amounts of at least ten millions. This information is optional on

4In some rare cases, the contacting dealer also tells whether he wants to buy or sell.

9

Source: Bjønnes and Rime, 2001

will contact another, and ask for a price quote. These quotes are considered

to be binding. A market maker is a dealer that is supposed to always be

able to give a quote. In direct interdealer contact the opposing party will be

known.

A single dealer will mostly specialise in only one currency cross. The

dealer might take considerable positions in this currency intra-day. However,

most dealers close their positions over night. Figure 5.2 illustrate observed

dealer inventories for four different dealers in two different markets over one

week, collected from a Norwegian bank. As we see, dealer strategies can

136

Page 140: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.2: Dealer inventoryFigure 2: Dealer Inventory

-20

-10

0

10

20

Mon Tue Wed Thu Fri

USD

-4

-2

0

2

4

6

Mon Tue Wed Thu Fri

USD

-60

-40

-20

0

20

40

60

Mon Tue Wed Thu Fri

DE

M

-15

-10

-5

0

5

10

Mon Tue Wed Thu Fri

USD

a) Dealer 1: DEM/USD Market Maker b) Dealer 2: DEM/USD "Nintendo-dealer"

c) Dealer 3: NOK/DEM Market Maker d) Dealer 4: DEM/USD

The evolution of dealers inventory over the week. Dealer 1 (panel a), 2 (panel b) and 4s (panel d) inventory arein USD million, while Dealer 3s inventory is in DEM million. The horizontal axis is in“transaction”-time. Verticallines indicate end of day. The numbers are in USD million.

8

Source: Bjønnes and Rime, 2001

be described as “individual”.1 In this sample we see that dealer might take

intra-day positions of up to 20 million USD. It is not unusual for dealers to

trade for USD 1 billion a day. As a comparison US equity traders trade for

an average of USD 10 million a day.

A broker is a pure matchmaker. Dealers will submit limit orders to the

broker. The broker will post these orders on a screen. One such system is

the Reuters D2000-2. In the broker system traders can observe the quotes

available in the market on one screen. However, it is not revealed who has

1The dealer consistently making most money of these four is supposed to have beenthe “Nintendo-dealer”—a guy who never held a position for more than two minutes.

137

Page 141: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

posted the quote. This is first revealed after the trade has been completed.

A difference between the direct trade and the broker system is that the as

the broker system is based on limit orders, one will post a maximum size of

the order at a given price. Further, one needs not post limit orders on both

sides of the market. A dealer can choose to post orders a bid or an ask.

The cost of trades will depend on the counterparty. Direct interdealer

contact has the lowest spreads. Brokers take somewhat higher spreads, not

least because brokers only make money through transaction costs. Customer

get the highest spreads. The market is illustrated in figure 5.3

Three characteristics of the FX market:

1. A very high volume,

2. high intra-dealer volume, and

3. low transparency.

In all these regards the FX-market is different from other multiple dealer

asset markets. The daily volume in the FX spot market in April 1998 was

600 billion USD, of which about 2/3 is supposed to have been intradealer

trade. As a comparison, the daily volume in the New York Stock Exchange

in this period was 30 billion USD, and average daily world trade in goods

and services was about 15 billion USD.

One way to explain the high amount of trade in the FX-markets is the

“hot-potato-hypothesis.” Assume that a dealer gets an order from a cus-

tomer. However, the dealer wants to keep his inventory as close to zero as

possible. So the dealer makes a trade with another dealer. This dealer will

keep a little, and trade the rest. And so on. That way every customer trade

gets multiplied when we look at the FX-market as a whole. One question

might be why dealers conduct such trading. Seemingly they could try to seek

138

Page 142: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.3: The FX-market

Customer à dealerSpread: 3-7 basis points

Brokered interdealerSpread: 2-3 basis points

Direct interdealerSpread: 2 points

Why use a broker?1. Do not have access to direct

market2. Do not have to reveal identity

before trade is completed3. Access to a larger market

Source: Lyons, 2001

139

Page 143: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

a better match for their orders, thereby reducing the number of rounds before

the currency risk is spread thin enough to satisfy the market. The willingness

to trade might be explained through the low transparency in these markets.

The only way dealers can obtain information about the flows in the market

is by trading themselves.

The FX-market has evolved almost with no government intervention.

This might point to low transparency being in the interest of the dealers.

Low transparency gives active dealers an advantage in the markets—and it

might be an advantage for their customers as well, as they always get the best

quotes. The smaller and less informed loose out however. In fact we have

seen an increasing concentration in the FX-market over the last 10 years.

The largest 10 firms did in 1998 control about 50 per cent of the market.

5.4 Data from the FX-market

In April every three years Bank of International Settlements, BIS, collect

data on transactions in the FX-market from 48 national central banks. The

total volume reported in the survey for 2001 is found in figure 5.4. As we can

see, after years of increase in FX-volume, the volume has fallen considerably

over the last three years. This is probably fairly simple to explain—with

the introduction of the EUR the number of heavily traded currencies fell

dramatically.

Figure 5.5 summarises the types of instruments used in the market. We

see that most deals are made with ‘reporting’ dealers—dealers that are ‘reg-

istered’ by the central bank as reporters. We also see that most swaps are

conducted as transactions with a life of less than 7 days—short-swaps are

the leading type of swap transactions in this market.

140

Page 144: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.4:

4/13

Table 1

Global foreign exchange market turnover1

Daily averages in April, in billions of US dollars

Instrument 1989 1992 1995 19982 2001

Spot transactions 317 394 494 568 387

Outright forwards 27 58 97 128 131

Foreign exchange swaps 190 324 546 734 656

Estimated gaps in reporting 56 44 53 60 36

Total “traditional” turnover 590 820 1,190 1,490 1,210

Memorandum item:

Turnover at April 2001exchange rates3 570 750 990 1,400 1,210

1 Adjusted for local and cross-border double-counting. 2 Revised. 3 Non-US dollar legs of foreign currency transactions wereconverted into original currency amounts at average exchange rates for April of each survey year and then reconverted into US dollaramounts at average April 2001 exchange rates.

Source: BIS, 2001

5.4.1 International currency

Just as domestic currency is the reference in the domestic economy, there

needs to be a point of reference in the international currency markets as

well. In a flexible currency system this point is not clear. However, at dif-

ferent times Greek coins, Roman coins, Florins, bills of credit on German

banks or British pounds have worked as accepted means of payment in inter-

national transactions. Since the Second World War USD has filled this role,

although some observers now predict a larger role for the EUR. How do we

define an international currency? What will determine which currencies are

dominating the world markets?

Factors that the determine the international use of a currency is

• size of the economy,

• importance in international trade,

• size, depth, liquidity, and openness of domestic financial markets,

141

Page 145: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.5:

5/13

Table 2

Reported foreign exchange market turnover by instrument, counterpartyand maturity1

Daily averages in April, in billions of US dollars

Instrument/counterparty 1992 1995 19982 2001

Spot ....................................................... 394 494 568 387

With reporting dealers ............................... 282 325 348 218With other financial institutions .................. 47 94 121 111With non-financial customers..................... 62 75 99 58

Outright forwards .................................... 58 97 128 131

With reporting dealers ............................... 21 33 49 52With other financial institutions .................. 10 28 34 41With non-financial customers..................... 28 36 44 37Up to 7 days .............................................. … 50 66 51Over 7 days and up to 1 year .................... … 44 59 76Over 1 year................................................ … 2 5 4

Foreign exchange swaps........................ 324 546 734 656

With reporting dealers ............................... 238 370 512 419With other financial institutions .................. 39 108 124 177With non-financial customers..................... 47 68 98 60Up to 7 days .............................................. … 382 529 450Over 7 days and up to 1 year .................... … 155 192 197Over 1 year................................................ … 7 10 8

Total.......................................................... 776 1,137 1,430 1,173

With reporting dealers ............................... 541 728 909 689With other financial institutions .................. 96 230 279 329With non-financial customers..................... 137 179 241 156

Local.......................................................... 316 526 658 499Cross-border.............................................. 391 613 772 674

1 Adjusted for local and cross-border double-counting. 2 Revised.

Source: BIS, 2001

Figure 5.6: The roles of international money

reserves in this currency and (ii) as a medium ofexchange if it is used for intervening in currencymarkets.

The three functions of an international currencyreinforce each other. For example, the use of acurrency for invoicing trade and holding financialassets increases the likelihood that the currencywill be used as a vehicle currency. In the officialsector, if a country pegs its exchange rate to anothercurrency, it is likely to hold reserves in that currencyand conduct its interventions in exchange marketsin that currency. In addition, the use of an inter-national currency by one sector reinforces its useby the other sector. For example, using a currencyas an exchange rate peg facilitates the use of thatcurrency in debt contracts and foreign trade.

DETERMINANTS OF AN INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY

What determines the likelihood that a cur-rency will be used in the international exchangeof goods, services, and assets? Five key factors areas follows:

• Size of the economy• Importance in international trade• Size, depth, liquidity, and openness of

domestic financial markets • Convertibility of the currency• Macroeconomic policies

The size of a country’s economy is importantbecause it determines the potential use of thecurrency in international markets. Economic sizeis linked with the importance of a country in inter-national trade and the size of its financial markets.For example, exports account for a much greatershare of the output of the Korean economy thanfor the U.S. economy. Nevertheless, because theU.S. economy is nearly 14 times larger than the

Korean economy, U.S. exports comprise a muchlarger share of world exports.

Clearly the dominance of the U.S. economyand the decline of the U.K. economy in the twentiethcentury were related to the rise of the dollar andthe decline of the pound as international currencies.Likewise, the growth of the German and Japaneseeconomies in the last several decades of the twen-tieth century prompted the use of their currenciesin international markets. As a result, the overwhelm-ing dominance the dollar held in internationalmarkets in the 1950s and 1960s diminished.

Table 2 compares the relative size of the U.S.,euro-area, and Japanese economies. The U.S. econ-omy is the largest in the world, accounting for about22 percent of world output. The establishment ofeconomic and monetary union in Europe, linkedthrough the euro, has created the world’s secondlargest economy. The Japanese economy is lessthan half the size of the euro area.5

The share of a country in international tradeas well as the size and openness of its financialmarkets are determinants of the demand for thatcountry’s currency in world markets. The UnitedStates accounts for a lower share of world exportsthan does the current euro area, as shown in Table2. The size of U.S. financial markets as measuredby the sum of bank assets, outstanding domesticdebt securities, and stock market capitalization,however, is much larger than in the euro area. Japanis a distant third in terms of its share of worldexports, but its financial markets are close in sizeto those in the euro area.

The convertibility of a country’s currency isanother important determinant of its use in inter-national markets. Restrictions on the ability to

18 SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

R E V I E W

5 In 1994 the Chinese economy surpassed the size of the Japaneseeconomy. Based on purchasing power parity valuations of GDP, Chinaaccounted for 11.2 percent of the world’s output in 1999. Nevertheless,Japan remains the world’s third major economic power.

Table 1

Functions of an International Currency

Sector

Function Private Official

Unit of account Invoice Exchange rate peg

Store of value Financial assets Reserves

Medium of exchange Vehicle/substitution Intervention

Source: Pollard, 2001

142

Page 146: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.7: Factors that determine the international use of a currency

exchange a currency for other currencies limits itsglobal use. At the end of World War II almost everycountry, with the exception of the United States,restricted the convertibility of its currency. Thisinconvertibility persisted for the first decade after thewar. The convertibility of the U.S. dollar promptedits use as the currency in which international tradewas conducted.

Macroeconomic policies also play an impor-tant role in determining whether a country’s cur-rency will be used internationally. These policiesaffect a country’s economic growth and its open-ness to the world economy. Policies fostering a lowinflation environment are especially important.Countries experiencing hyperinflation and/orpolitical crises often see the use of their curren-cies collapse not only internationally but alsowithin the domestic economy, as residents turnto a substitute currency.

Clearly the size and openness of the U.S. econ-omy have been major factors in encouraging theinternational use of the dollar in the post-WorldWar II period. Its use as an international currencyin the private sector and the effect of the emergenceof the euro in this sector is examined in the nextsection.

THE PRIVATE USES OF AN INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY

As stated above, a currency operates as aninternational currency in the private sector (i) ifinternational trade and debt contracts are priced in

this currency; (ii) if this currency is used to facilitatethe exchange of other currencies; and (iii) if thiscurrency is used as a substitute currency.

Invoice Currency

The dollar is the main currency that functionsas a unit of account for private international trans-actions. Although data on the currency of invoicein international trade are limited, the available dataconfirm the dominance of the dollar. In 1995 theU.S. dollar was used as the invoice currency for morethan half of world exports, down only slightly from1980, as shown in Table 3. The Deutsche mark wasthe next most popular invoice currency, used forapproximately 13 percent of world exports, followedby the French franc and the British pound. Whilethe yen’s use in world trade lagged behind theseEuropean currencies, its share had more thandoubled since 1980. The combined share of thefour major euro currencies was less than half thatof the U.S. dollar.

More importantly, there is a clear distinctionbetween the use of the dollar and other invoicecurrencies. The U.S. dollar is the only currencywhose use in world trade far surpasses its countryshare in world trade, as shown by its international-ization ratio in Table 3. An internationalization ratioless than 1.0, as with the yen, lira, and guilder,indicates that not all of that country’s exports aredenominated in the local currency. An internation-alization ratio greater than 1.0, as with the dollar,the mark, and the pound, indicates that other coun-

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 19

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Table 2

Comparison of United States, Euro-Area, and Japanese Economies in 1999

United States Euro area Japan

Share of world GDP (%) 21.9 15.8 7.6

Share of world exports (%) 15.3 19.4 9.3

Financial markets ($ billions) 40,543.8 24,133.4 20,888.5

Bank assets ($ billions) 7,555.3 12,731.3 6,662.5

Domestic debt securities outstanding ($ billions) 15,426.3 5,521.9 6,444.9

Stock market capitalization ($ billions) 17,562.2 5,880.2 7,781.4

NOTE: GDP is based on purchasing power parity equivalents. World exports excludes intra-euro-area trade.

SOURCE: GDP: IMF, World Economic Outlook, October 2000. Exports: IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics Quarterly, September 2000.Bank assets: European Central Bank, Monthly Bulletin; Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Flow of Funds Accounts;IMF, International Financial Statistics. Debt securities: Bank for International Settlements, Quarterly Review of International Bankingand Financial Market Developments. Stock market: Eurostat.

Source: Pollard, 2001

• convertibility of currency, and

• macroeconomic policies. Policies fostering low inflation (i.e. a stable

value of money) are especially important.

So what currencies are actually used in international currency markets?

As can be seen from tables 5.8 and 5.9 the most traded currency is the USD,

and the most traded currency pair is the USD/EUR.

5.4.2 The roles of international money

Invoice currency

Rules for choice of invoice currency:

• Between industrialised countries: price the good in the currency of the

exporter.

• Between industrialised countries and developing countries: price the

good in the currency of the industrialised country, or in a third country

currency (most likely the USD).

143

Page 147: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.8: Currency distribution of reported global foreign exchange marketturnover

6/13

Table 3Currency distribution of reported global foreign exchange market turnover1

Percentage shares of average daily turnover in April

Currency 1989 1992 1995 19982 2001

US dollar................................................. 90 82.0 83.3 87.3 90.4Euro ....................................................... . . . . 37.6Deutsche mark3 ...................................... 27 39.6 36.1 30.1 .French franc ........................................... 2 3.8 7.9 5.1 .ECU and other EMS currencies ............. 4 11.8 15.7 17.3 .Japanese yen ......................................... 27 23.4 24.1 20.2 22.7Pound sterling ........................................ 15 13.6 9.4 11.0 13.2Swiss franc ............................................. 10 8.4 7.3 7.1 6.1Canadian dollar ...................................... 1 3.3 3.4 3.6 4.5Australian dollar...................................... 2 2.5 2.7 3.1 4.2Swedish krona4 ...................................... … 1.3 0.6 0.4 2.6Hong Kong dollar4 .................................. … 1.1 0.9 1.3 2.3Norwegian krone4................................... … 0.3 0.2 0.4 1.5Danish krone4......................................... … 0.5 0.6 0.4 1.2Singapore dollar4 .................................... … 0.3 0.3 1.2 1.1South African rand4 ................................ … 0.3 0.2 0.5 1.0Mexican peso4........................................ … … … 0.6 0.9Korean won4........................................... … … … 0.2 0.8New Zealand dollar4 ............................... … 0.2 0.2 0.3 0.6Polish zloty4............................................ … … … 0.1 0.5Brazilian real4 ......................................... … … … 0.4 0.4Russian rouble4 ...................................... … … … 0.3 0.4Taiwan dollar4......................................... … … … 0.1 0.3Chilean peso4 ......................................... … … … 0.1 0.2Czech koruna4........................................ … … … 0.3 0.2Indian rupee4 .......................................... … … … 0.1 0.2Thai baht4 ............................................... … … … 0.2 0.2Malaysian ringgit4 ................................... … … … 0.0 0.1Saudi riyal4 ............................................. … … … 0.1 0.1Other currencies..................................... 22 7.7 7.1 8.2 6.7

All currencies........................................ 200 200.0 200.0 200.0 200.0

1 Because two currencies are involved in each transaction, the sum of the percentage shares of individual currencies totals200% instead of 100%. The figures relate to reported “net-net” turnover, ie they are adjusted for both local and cross-borderdouble-counting, except for 1989 data, which are available only on a “gross-gross” basis. 2 Revised. 3 Data for April 1989exclude domestic trading involving the Deutsche mark in Germany. 4 For 1992-98, the data cover local home currencytrading only.

Source: BIS, 2001

144

Page 148: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.9: Reported foreign exchange turnover by currency pairs

7/13

Table 4

Reported foreign exchange turnover by currency pairs1

Daily averages in April, in billions of US dollars and percentages

1992 1995 19982 2001

Currency pair Amount %share

Amount %share

Amount %share

Amount %share

USD/EUR .............. . . . . . . 352 30USD/DEM.............. 192 25 254 22 291 20 . .USD/FRF............... 19 2 51 4 58 4 . .USD/XEU............... 13 2 18 2 17 1 . .USD/OthEMS ........ 43 6 104 9 176 12 . .USD/JPY ............... 155 20 242 21 257 18 230 20USD/GBP .............. 77 10 78 7 118 8 125 11USD/CHF............... 49 6 61 5 79 5 57 5USD/CAD .............. 25 3 38 3 50 3 50 4USD/AUD .............. 18 2 29 3 42 3 47 4USD/Oth ................ 48 6 72 6 172 12 197 17EUR/JPY ............... . . . . . . 30 3EUR/GBP .............. . . . . . . 24 2EUR/CHF............... . . . . . . 12 1EUR/Oth ................ . . . . . . 22 2DEM/JPY............... 18 2 24 2 24 2 . .DEM/GBP.............. 23 3 21 2 31 2 . .DEM/CHF .............. 13 2 18 2 18 1 . .DEM/FRF............... 10 1 34 3 10 1 . .DEM/XEU .............. 6 1 6 1 3 0 . .DEM/OthEMS ........ 21 3 38 3 35 2 . .DEM/Oth................ 20 3 16 1 18 1 .OthEMS/OthEMS3 . 3 0 3 0 5 0 . .Other currencypairs....................... 25 3 30 3 31 2 24 2

All currency pairs 778 100 1,137 100 1,430 100 1,173 100

1 Adjusted for local and cross-border double-counting. 2 Revised. 3 The data cover local home currency tradingonly.

Source: BIS, 2001

145

Page 149: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.10: Invoice currency

tries use that currency to invoice some (or all) oftheir exports.6

What determines the currency of invoice inworld trade? A number of studies including thoseby Grassman (1973), Page (1981), and Black (1990)revealed the following patterns. Trade in manufac-tured goods among the industrial economies ismost often priced in the currency of the exporter.If the exporter’s currency is not used, then theimporter’s currency is the most frequent choice.Only rarely is a third country’s currency used. Tradebetween industrial and developing countries isgenerally priced in the currency of the industrialcountry or that of a third country. Trade betweendeveloping countries is often priced in the currencyof a third country. When a third country’s currencyis used for invoicing trade, the U.S. dollar is themost likely choice. Trade in primary commoditiesis almost always invoiced in U.S. dollars becausethese products are predominantly priced in dollarson international exchanges.

According to Hartmann (1996), two factorsthat explain these patterns are transaction costsand acceptability. The lower the cost of buying andselling a currency in the foreign exchange market,the more likely is its use for invoicing trade. Inaddition, the more accepted a currency is for othertransactions, the more likely it is to be used as aninvoice currency. Clearly these two factors are mutu-ally supportive. The more accepted a currency is,

the lower its transaction costs; the lower its trans-action costs, the more likely it is to be accepted.

Related factors that explain these patterns areconvertibility and the expected stability of thecurrency. As noted above, the use of the dollar asan invoice currency was prompted by the lack ofconvertibility of most other currencies in the 1950s.The limited use of developing countries’ currenciesin world trade arose in part because many of thesecountries restricted (and some continue to restrict)the convertibility of their currencies. Black (1990)showed that the share of a country’s exports denom-inated in its domestic currency declines the greateris the expected depreciation of its currency. Thus,the currencies of countries with high inflation areseldom used in international trade.

The mere creation of the euro as a currencyshould provide ample incentive for its use as aninvoice currency. Replacing the currencies of 12countries with a single currency reduces thetransaction costs involved in currency exchanges.Although only a small number of firms within theeuro area have already switched to invoicing ineuros, the advent of euro notes and coins, along

20 SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

R E V I E W

6 An internationalization ratio greater than or equal to 1.0 does notimply that all of the home country’s exports are priced in its currency.According to data provided in Bekx (1998) in 1995, 92 percent of U.S.exports, 75 percent of German exports, 62 percent of British exports,and 52 percent of French exports were invoiced in their domesticcurrencies.

Table 3

Trade Invoiced in Major Currencies

Percent of world exports Internationalization ratio

Currency 1980 1995 1980 1995

U.S. dollar 56.4 52.0 4.5 3.9

Japanese yen 2.1 4.7 0.3 0.6

Deutsche mark 13.6 13.2 1.4 1.4

French franc 6.2 5.5 0.9 1.0

British pound 6.5 5.4 1.1 1.1

Italian lira 2.2 3.3 0.5 0.8

Netherlands guilder 2.6 2.8 0.7 0.9

Euro-4 24.6 24.8 NA NA

NOTE: Euro-4 is the share of the four euro-area currencies listed in the table. No data were available for the other euro-area currencies.World exports includes intra-euro-area trade. The internationalization ratio is the ratio of the share of world exports denominated ina currency to the share of the issuing country in world exports.

SOURCE: Bekx (1998, Table 3, p. 8).

Source: Pollard, 2001

• Between developing countries: most likely price the good in USD.

Commodities (like oil, metals et.c.) are mainly priced in USD.

• Is it important which currency is used as an invoice currency? Yes,

it might reduce currency risk for businesses situated in the country

where this currency belongs. However, currency risk might generally

be removed quite cheaply by using options or forward contracts.

• Would it reduce risk if a commodity is priced in the national currency?

In Norway oil price risk has two factors: changes in the oil price mea-

sured in USD, and changes in the exchange rate between USD and

NOK. In the US one only has the oil price risk. However, notice that

taking two risks instead of one does only imply increased risk if the

fluctuations of the two assets are positively correlated. In fact there is

no reason to believe that the oil price and the USD is positively corre-

lated. In the case of Norway, the volatility of changes in the oil price

measured in NOK is not very different from the volatility changes in

146

Page 150: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.11: The oil price in NOK and USD from 1998 to 2001. Indexedvalues, index=100 in January 1, 1998

50

100

150

200

250

300

1/01/98 10/08/98 7/15/99 4/20/00 1/25/01

OILNOKI OILUSDI

Source: Datastream

the oil price measured in USD (a standard deviation on daily data from

1990 to the end of 2001 gives 3.58 against 3.60. Notice however that

this result will be very sample dependent).

Vehicle currency

When making a transaction between e.g. NOK and NZD one will have several

choices available. One can

• buy NZD against the delivery of NOK. This does however assume a

147

Page 151: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

coincidence of wants. The bank selling NZD should also want NOK.

• buy USD against the delivery of NOK, and then buy NZD against the

delivery of USD.

• or even more intricate, buy EUR against the delivery of NOK, USD

against the delivery of EUR and NZD against the delivery of USD.

Why should one choose a strategy involving more than one transaction?

Because the transactions costs will depend on the liquidity in each bilateral

currency market. E.g. 80 per cent of all spot trade (that is trades to be

delivered within two working days) in the Norwegian market is conducted

between NOK and EUR. According to table 5.9 in April 2001 91 per cent

of all currency trades included the USD. Most trades in NZD is probably

conducted against USD. So it might well generate the lowest transaction

costs if one makes two or three transactions instead on only one.2

A vehicle currency will emerge each time the indirect exchange costs

through the vehicle currency are less than the direct exchange costs between

non-vehicle currencies. In Norway (and other small European nations) EUR

probably works as a vehicle currency. For most other transactions, the USD

is probably the vehicle currency of choice.

Store of value—the choice of denomination of financial assets

Diversification is an important concept in finance. One wants to diversify

one’s portfolio across interest bearing paper and equity, between different

2This has very real application in the small scale. If you carry foreign currency to e.g.Eastern Europe one would normally find a much lower spread (distance between bid andask prices—or the sell and buy offers) if one trades with EUR than with NOK. One canoften save money if one exchanged NOK to EUR in a Norwegian bank, and only usedEUR when travelling. In more developed markets, the cost of using NOK instead of othercurrencies is however small.

148

Page 152: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.12: Vehicle currency

kets.” Whereas, the infrequent interventions byindividual European central banks in securitiesmarkets “tended to discourage the development ofprivate securities markets and foster the predomi-nance of bank-intermediated finance.” The ECB hascontinued this practice of infrequent interventions.In general, it is active in securities markets onlyonce per week.

For now U.S. financial markets continue to leadthe world in both size and liquidity. As a result, theU.S. dollar remains the major currency in inter-national bond markets. The euro, however, hasalready become a major player in these markets,and its use will likely expand as euro-area financialmarket integration proceeds. The development ofa euro-area capital market similar to the U.S. marketshould provide benefits to both economies byincreasing the options available to borrowers andlenders on both sides of the Atlantic.

Vehicle Currency

There are no direct data available on vehiclecurrencies, but this information can be gleaned fromthe shares of currencies in foreign exchange trans-actions, as shown in Table 8.18 In 1998 the dollar wasinvolved in 87 percent of all currency exchanges.19

The euro legacy currencies were involved in 52percent of all exchanges, with the Deutsche markthe most often traded of these currencies. The yenwas used in 21 percent of all currency trades. Thedollar’s dominance was especially clear in forwardand swap transactions. The dollar was involved in81 percent of all forward trades compared with themark’s and yen’s shares of 28 and 27 percent, respec-tively. In swaps the contrast was even greater. Thedollar was involved in 95 percent of all swaps, with

the mark and yen taking part in 20 and 17 percent,respectively, of all trades.

The use of the dollar in foreign exchange trans-actions was well above its use in international tradeand debt contracts, indicating its role as a vehiclecurrency. The BIS (1999) notes that evidence of thedollar’s role as a vehicle currency is provided by itsuse in seven of the ten most heavily traded currencypairs. The report also notes that it is standard prac-tice for the dollar to be used as a vehicle currencyin swaps, which explains the high percentage ofswaps involving the U.S. dollar and the low use ofthe yen and mark in these trades.

The use of a currency as a vehicle currency isdetermined primarily by transactions costs. Trans-actions costs are inversely related to volume in eachbilateral currency market.20 This volume is in turndetermined by a currency’s share in internationaltrade and capital flows. Thus, the use of a currencyin invoicing international trade, in internationalcapital markets, and as a reserve currency lowersthe transactions costs associated with the use ofthat currency.

A vehicle currency emerges whenever theindirect exchange costs through the vehicle are lessthan direct exchange costs between two non-vehiclecurrencies. For example, given the depth of theexchange market for dollars, it may be less costly

26 SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

R E V I E W

18 These data are gathered from a triennial survey of foreign exchangemarkets conducted by the BIS.

19 Since there are two currencies involved in an exchange, the totalshare of all currencies traded on international exchanges will equal200 percent. However, a single currency can, at most, be involved in100 percent of all exchanges.

20 The use of transactions cost theory to explain the rise of a vehiclecurrency was developed by Krugman (1980) and Chrystal (1984).

Table 8

Foreign Exchange Market Transactions Involving Select Currencies (Percent of Total) April 1998

Category U.S. dollar Japanese yen Deutsche mark French franc Euro area* Pound sterling

Spot 78.8 24.7 42.7 3.3 56.8 11.6

Forwards 81.4 26.7 28.0 5.1 50.7 12.3

Swaps 95.2 16.7 20.0 6.5 48.8 10.2

Total 87.4 20.8 29.8 5.1 52.2 11.0

*Euro area includes the currencies of the current member countries plus the Danish krone and the ecu.

SOURCE: Bank for International Settlements, Central Bank Survey of Foreign Exchange and Derivatives Market Activity 1998. Basle:BIS, May 1999.

Source: Pollard, 2001

issuers of bonds and equity and also between different currencies. However,

the willingness to invest in a certain currency will depend on size, openness,

and liquidity of financial markets and the stability of the currency.

The EUR will only be able to compete with USD as the currency of choice

in international debt markets if the European financial markets get the same

size and liquidity as the American markets. This will probably depend on

the level of integration in the European financial markets.

The use of a substitute currency

If there is loss of trust in the national currency, people will try to exchange

their holdings of this currency into presumably safer assets. Loss of trust can

e.g. occur under periods of hyperinflation, or if the country has an exchange

rate regime that might break down.

In countries with a weak legal system or a weak central bank, large hold-

ings of currency is often kept in foreign currency. In most countries the

currency of choice will be the USD. In some Eastern European countries the

EUR is more popular than USD, mainly because of the proximity and trade

with the EU countries. Montenegro is probably the most extreme case—they

have adopted the EUR as the means of payment.

149

Page 153: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.13: Denomination of international debt

the 1950s. By the 1970s, however, the currencydenomination of bond issues had become morediversified, as shown in Table 5. Nevertheless, theU.S. dollar has remained the most popular currencychoice for issuing bonds in international markets,as shown in Table 6.9 By the 1960s the euro legacycurrencies, taken together as a group, had becomethe second most widely used currency in inter-national bond markets, a status that continues today.The Japanese yen was not used at all until the 1970s,and its share of new issues lags far below that of thedollar or euro. The use of the Swiss franc in inter-national bond markets, which rivaled the Deutschemark in the 1970s, declined precipitously in the1990s.10

In international money markets as well, thedollar is the currency of choice, but again itsdominance has declined, as noted in Table 6. Theincreased use of the euro legacy currencies in thesemarkets during the 1990s is particularly noteworthy.In 1993 these currencies accounted for 8.5 percentof the outstanding debt in international moneymarkets. By 1998 this share had increased to 19.2percent.

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001 23

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

9 The data in Tables 5 and 6 rely on different sources and hence maynot be directly comparable.

10 Some policymakers in Switzerland were concerned that the creationof the euro might result in a sharp rise in demand for assets denomi-nated in Swiss francs. See Laxton and Prasad (1997) for an analysisof this argument.

Table 6

International Debt Securities by Currency of Issue (Percent)

Amounts outstanding Share of new issues

Currency 1993 1998 2000 1998 1999 2000

Total securities

U.S. dollar 41.1 45.9 48.7 54.1 45.2 44.0

Japanese yen 13.2 11.3 8.2 5.6 5.3 8.3

Swiss franc 7.3 3.8 2.2 3.3 2.0 1.7

Euro area* 24.8 27.2 30.1 24.6 36.8 33.9

Other E.U.† 7.9 8.5 8.2 8.9 8.0 9.2

Pound sterling 7.6 7.9 7.8 8.3 7.7 9.1

Bonds and notes

U.S. dollar 38.9 45.3 48.7 51.1 43.8 42.3

Japanese yen 14.0 11.7 8.6 6.3 6.7 11.4

Swiss franc 7.7 3.8 2.2 2.7 1.6 1.4

Euro area* 25.7 27.6 30.0 28.0 38.3 34.2

Other E.U.† 8.1 8.5 8.1 9.0 7.3 8.4

Pound sterling 7.8 7.9 7.7 8.2 7.0 8.2

Money Market

U.S. dollar 79.4 59.9 49.1 61.0 48.8 47.5

Japanese yen 0.2 2.5 2.3 4.0 1.4 1.9

Swiss franc 1.8 4.5 2.3 4.7 2.9 2.3

Euro area* 8.5 19.2 32.4 17.2 32.9 33.2

Other E.U.† 4.1 8.4 9.5 8.8 9.8 11.0

Pound sterling 4.0 8.3 9.3 8.7 9.7 11.0

*Euro area includes the currencies of the 11 original members of the euro area and currency composites, such as the ecu.†Other E.U. includes the currencies of Denmark, Sweden, and the United Kingdom.

SOURCE: Bank for International Settlements, Quarterly Review of International Banking and Financial Market Developments, March 2001.

Source: Pollard, 2001

150

Page 154: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 5.14: US seignorage revenue

billion on a yearly basis over this period. One methodof estimating the importance of these seignioragerevenues is to calculate the share of governmentexpenditures accounted for by these revenues. Thisis shown in the bottom panel of Figure 2. On averageless than 1 percent of the expenditures of the U.S.federal government have been financed by seignior-age revenues on currency held abroad.25

The euro is not likely to rapidly replace thedollar as the substitute currency of choice. In fact,the use of the euro as a substitute currency is likely

to lag behind its use as an international currency.Foreign holders of a substitute currency want a sta-ble, secure currency. Uncertainty surrounding thevalue of the euro, particularly given its declineagainst the dollar during the first two years of itsexistence, will limit the near-term attractiveness ofthe euro as a substitute currency.

If the euro does become increasingly used as asubstitute currency, the seigniorage earnings of theECB will rise. It is difficult to predict how large theserevenues might be, as they depend on the worlddemand for substitute currencies, the shares of theeuro and the dollar, and interest rate conditions.Emerson et al. (1992) estimated that these seignior-age revenues would, at most, amount to $2.5 billiona year for the ECB.

THE OFFICIAL USES OF AN INTERNATIONAL CURRENCY

Exchange Rate Peg

Under the Bretton Woods system that existedfrom 1946 to 1973, most currencies in the worldwere tied to the U.S. dollar. With the demise of theBretton Woods system, many countries chose to lettheir currencies float while others set the value oftheir currency against that of another country. Ofthose countries choosing the latter option, mostcontinued to peg their currency to the U.S. dollar.In 1975, 52 members countries (about 41 percent)of the International Monetary Fund (IMF) peggedtheir currency to the dollar, as shown in Table 9.The euro legacy currencies were the second mostpopular choice. The French franc was the peg forthe African Financial Community (CFA) franc, thecurrency used by the then 13 members of the CFA;and the Spanish peseta was the exchange rate pegfor the currency of Equatorial Guinea. The poundwas the only other European Union currency to beused as an exchange rate peg.

Over time the popularity of currency pegs hasdeclined. However, both the number and percent-age of member countries pegging their currenciesto the euro have risen. In 2000, 24 IMF membercountries tied their currencies to the euro.26 The 14

28 SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER 2001

R E V I E W

25 The seigniorage benefits must be weighed against the problems theforeign holdings of currency create for monetary policy. As Porterand Judson (1996) note, if foreign demand for a country’s currency isunrelated to domestic demand, then the interpretation of movementsin monetary aggregates becomes more difficult.

26 These 24 include San Marino, which uses the Italian lira as its currency,and Greece, which is now a member of the euro area.

Figure 2

Seignorage Revenues from Foreign Holdingsof U.S. Dollars

1973 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 19990

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

1973 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 19990.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

Billions of 1996 $

Percent of federal government expenditures

SOURCE: Department of Commerce, Bureau of EconomicAnalysis, and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

Source: Pollard, 2001

It is estimated that about 55 per cent (!) of the total U.S. currency

held by the non-bank public was held outside the US in 1995. The same

number for the DEM was 35 per cent. The seignorage revenue from foreign

holdings is estimated to an average of about 9 billion USD a year over the

last decade. That is less than one per cent of US government expenditure.

However it would amount to between 5 and 7 per cent of Norwegian GDP—

still a reasonably large sum of money.

151

Page 155: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 6

The floating exchange rate

6.1 Introduction

Michael Mussa has summarised our understanding of flexible exchange rates

in the following way:

[T]he largely random character of exchange rate fluctuations

under floating exchange rate regimes is explained by the preva-

lence of “news” in inducing most exchange rate changes; the ten-

dency for nominal and real exchange rates to move in together

under a floating rate regime is explained by the contrast between

the behavior of nominal exchange rates as randomly fluctuating

asset prices and the behavior of national price levels as relatively

sluggishly adjusting variables; and with respect to the influence of

economic policies on exchange rates, what matters is not simply

what policies governments pursue today, but also to an important

extent, the policies they are expected to pursue in the future.

Despite this progress made over the last 30 years, we still do not have

a good understanding of the observed behavior of exchange rates. Jeffrey

Frankel and Andrew Rose (1995) state that

152

Page 156: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

[t]o repeat a central fact of life, there is remarkably little evi-

dence that macroeconomic variables have consistent strong effects

on floating exchange rates, except during extraordinary circum-

stances such as hyperinflations. Such negative findings have led

the profession to a certain degree of pessimism vis-a-vis exchange

rate research.

6.2 High expectations

During the Bretton Woods era many economist argued in favour of floating

exchange rates. Six main claims were made.

1. Real exchange rates would be more stable with floating than fixed ex-

change rates. The argument was that since the exchange rate could

adjust faster than the price level, one should expect a floating exchange

rate to allow faster adjustment than a fixed exchange rate, as in the

last case all adjustment was left to the domestic price level.

Outcome: in fact variability in the real exchange rate has increased

considerably with floating exchange rates. Real and nominal exchange

rates tend to move together, and nominal exchange rate changes tend

to increase the variability in the real exchange rate, not alleviate vari-

ability.

2. Adjustments in fixed exchange rates tend to be infrequent, but abrupt

and large. They often take a form that can be described as “crises”.

Floating exchange rates was supposed to change slowly, smoothly and

predictably.

Outcome: Flexible exchange rates have been very volatile. Changes

are abrupt and fast. Neither are they predictable, as we will see in the

153

Page 157: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

discussion of the UIP below.

3. Floating exchange rates were supposed to adjust to insulate the econ-

omy against shocks from abroad. Remember the n-1 problem: in a

fixed exchange rate regime monetary policy had to be adjusted in all

countries if adjusted in one country.

Outcome: In fact, correlation between business cycles have tended to

increase, not fall, over the last three decades. Even in a floating regime

the n-1 problem can not be ignored. If interest rate differentials between

economies are allowed to be to high, we experience changes in real

exchange rates that are not easily accepted. The result is that real

interest rates are highly correlated.

4. In a floating exchange rate the central bank gets complete control over

the money supply.

Outcome: Even in a floating regime the exchange rate can not be ig-

nored. The exchange rate is probably the most important “price” in

every moderately open economy. The stylised example of an indepen-

dent monetary policy is an illusion.

5. With floating exchange rates, exchange rates would adjust faster to

balance the current account, thereby decreasing the political pressure

for e.g. tariffs an other measures to reduce trade imbalances.

Outcome: if anything, current account imbalances have increased with

floating exchange rates.

6. With a floating exchange rate one did no longer need a foreign exchange

reserve. These money could be freed for other purposes.

154

Page 158: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Outcome: Foreign exchange reserves are in real terms larger today than

in the Bretton Woods era.

How come that we have missed the point so completely? Two possibilities:

either our models have been just plain wrong, or we did not interpret them

correctly. The main problem is probably that floating exchange rates are

much more volatile than was expected. However, this is a feature exchange

rates share with all asset markets—asset prices tend to fluctuate much more

than underlying “fundamentals” should presume.

6.3 “Excess volatility” and some ‘puzzles’ of

exchange rate economics

In the beginning of this course we made two basic assumptions when we

moved from the domestic relationship for money demand to a function for

the exchange rate. We assumed that PPP and UIP would hold. PPP implies

that given the functionQt

εt

=P ∗

t

Pt

, (6.1)

we assume Q to be one, or at least stable over time. The UIP states that

Etεt+1

εt

=1 + it1 + i∗t

. (6.2)

According to the UIP Etεt+1 should be our best guess of εt at time t.

Table 6.1 give the standard deviations of return for a number of variables.

What we can see from this table is that from week to week one should expect

very limited volatility in prices. The volatility in interest rates are 10 times

the volatility in prices.1 The volatility in the exchange rate is a 100 times

1Note that as we are looking at the volatility in bond interest rates and not bond priceswe underestimate the risk of investing in long term bonds. A one per cent swing in a bondwith maturity in 10 years implies a substantial swing in the current price of the bond.

155

Page 159: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

that of the interest rate. However, we can notice that exchange rate volatility

can only be characterised as “excess” if compared with the volatility of prices

and interest rates. Compared with return in the stock market or in a highly

traded storable good like oil, volatility is in fact rather low.

Table 6.1: Standard deviation of weekly return (weekly change) for differentmarkets. Sample cover 11.1992-03.2002

St.dev. in per centCPINorway 0.0003Germany 0.000210 year gov. bond*Norway 0.003Germany 0.0033 month interbank*Norway 0.006Germany 0.004spread (NOK-DEM) 0.005Exchange ratesNOK/DEM 0.79DEM/USD 1.37Stockmarket indexNorway 2.79Germany 3.44Traded goodsoil in USD 5.21*volatility in i

What conclusion can we draw if we combine our results from table 6.1

with the two parity conditions stated above? If price volatility is low, and the

nominal exchange rate volatility is high, the volatility of the real exchange

rate must be highly correlated with the volatility in the nominal exchange

rate. Further, it the volatility in the differential between domestic and foreign

interest rates is low, while the volatility of the current spot rate is high,

then we should expect a very high correlation between the expected future

156

Page 160: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

exchange rate and the current exchange rate as well.

These are de facto puzzles. However, they are probably not puzzles only

related to the market for foreign exchange. Rather they are related to all

asset markets. In general changes in asset prices are not well explained by

changes in fundamentals, at least not over a “short time horizon” of say, up

to two years. The reason is that asset prices fluctuate so much more than

other variables in the economy. This volatility can not be well explained with

current economic models. One therefore often hear that asset markets show

“excess volatility”.

We should add a third problem not reflected in the table above. The

real exchange rate tends to fluctuate in long cycles, with a mean reversion

time of between 2 and 6 years, depending on the country and the exchange

rate regime. This implies that over time fundamentals do seem to explain

exchange rates after all. Why is this a puzzle? Because we can not under-

stand why fundamentals should only be reflected in asset prices over a time

span of over two years. Most of the explanations given below for the high

volatility in exchange rates might give a good explanation for a divergence

between fundamentals and the exchange rate for a few months, or maybe a

year. However none of the models can explain why exchange rates are mean

reverting over 4-6 years...

6.3.1 The FX market vs. the stock market

Given the focus on excess volatility in the FX market it is reasonable to

compare this market with the volatility of the stock market. Figure 6.1

depict the log of NOK/DEM exchange rate, indexed to 100 in week 47 1992.

In the figure we have drawn a trend line over the period.2 Figure 6.2 depict

2The trend line is calculated as with Hodrick-Prescott filter with a smoothing parameterof 100,000.

157

Page 161: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.1: The NOK/DEM exchange rate. Log of index=100 in week 47,1992. Trend calculated with H-P filter.

4.55

4.60

4.65

4.70

4.75

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

EURNOKINDEX HPNOKEURINDE100a similar figure for the Oslo Stock Exchange.

In figure 6.3 we depict only the trend lines. We see that the the two graphs

have many similar features. Both tend to move in long swings. However, as

becomes very clear in figure 6.4, over time the underlying movements in the

stock exchange are of much larger magnitude than the long term changes in

the exchange rate.

Figure 6.5 depict the difference between the actual value and the trend.

As we see both series fluctuate considerably around the trend. Also here the

two series have substantial similarities. When we take the two series into

the same diagram, as is done in figure 6.6, we see that even here the stock

exchange has a much higher volatility than the exchange rate.

158

Page 162: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.2: Index of Oslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47,1992. Trend calculated with H-P filter.

4.4

4.6

4.8

5.0

5.2

5.4

5.6

5.8

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

OSLOINDEX HPTREND09

159

Page 163: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.3: The H-P trend in NOK/DEM exchange rate and the Oslo StockExchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992.

4.58

4.60

4.62

4.64

4.66

4.68

4.70

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

HPNOKEURINDE100

4.6

4.8

5.0

5.2

5.4

5.6

5.8

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

HPOSLOINDEX100

160

Page 164: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.4: The H-P trend in NOK/DEM exchange rate and the Oslo StockExchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992.

4.4

4.6

4.8

5.0

5.2

5.4

5.6

5.8

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

HPNOKEURINDE100 HPOSLOINDEX100

161

Page 165: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.5: The difference from H-P trend for NOK/DEM exchange rate theOslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992.

-0.10

-0.05

0.00

0.05

0.10

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

EURNOKINDEXVOL

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0.0

0.1

0.2

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

OSLOINDEXVOL

162

Page 166: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.6: The difference from H-P trend for NOK/DEM exchange rate theOslo Stock Exchange. Log of index=100 in week 47, 1992.

-0.4

-0.3

-0.2

-0.1

0.0

0.1

0.2

11/20/92 10/21/94 9/20/96 8/21/98 7/21/00

EURNOKINDEXVOL OSLOINDEXVOL

163

Page 167: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Some tentative conclusions:

• The stock market and the FX market reveal many of the same features.

They both tend to move in long swings, with substantial volatility

around these swings.

• However, both the movements in the trend and the volatility around

the trend tends to be less for the FX market than for the stock market.

• This might indicate that the FX market is slightly more “efficient” than

the stock market. If so, this is not a surprising conclusion. After all,

as we discussed in Lecture 5, transaction costs are lower and volume is

higher in the FX market than in the stock market. Both factors should

contribute to a more efficient market.

6.4 Random walk?—the Meese and Rogoff

results

During the 1970’s much work was done on econometric models for forecasting

exchange rates. Some of these models showed promising results. However,

in 1983 there was published a study by Meese and Rogoff that summarised

the ability of such econometric models to forecast exchange rate changes

out-of-sample. The results were devastating.

To forecast something in-the-sample tells us about the ability of the model

to explain the observations we use in the regression. In out-of-sample fore-

casts we use the model to forecast time periods that was not included in the

actual regression analysis.

Meese and Rogoff estimated four different models using monthly data.

They had data from March 1973 to June 1981. First they estimated the

164

Page 168: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Table 6.2: Out-of-sample forecasting performance of different exchange ratemodels—root of mean squared error of forecasts 1, 6 and 12 months ahead.

Random walk Monetary Dornbusch Portfolio balanceUSD/DEM1 month 3.7 3.2 3.7 3.56 month 8.7 9.6 12.0 10.012 month 13.0 16.1 18.9 15.7USD/JPY1 month 3.7 4.1 4.4 4.26 month 11.6 13.4 13.9 11.912 month 18.3 18.6 20.4 19.0USD/GBP1 month 2.6 2.8 2.9 2.76 month 6.5 8.9 8.9 7.212 month 9.9 14.6 13.7 14.6

Source: Meese and Rogoff, 1983

models over the period from March 1973 to November 1976. Then they used

the parameters estimated to forecast the changes in the exchange rate 1, 6 and

12 months into the future from November 1976. In this forecast they used

actual realised values of the “fundamental variables”—taking a very strict

assumption of perfect foresight. They then extended the regression with

one month, to December 1976, and reported forecasts. They repeated this

procedure for the whole period till June 1981. Having made these forecasts,

they compared the forecasts with actual outcomes, and reported the squared

errors of the forecasts. A summary of their findings is given in table 6.2.

Meese and Rogoff had estimated three models with “economic contents”—

a monetary equilibrium model, the Dornbusch model and a portfolio balance

model. In addition they had estimated a “naive” model with no economic

content—i.e. a random walk. A random walk is taking the very simple as-

sumption that the current exchange rate is the best predictor of the future

165

Page 169: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

exchange rate, i.e.

et+1 = a + et + ut, (6.3)

where a is a constant and u is the error term, with the expected normal

distribution u ∼ N(0, σ2). As we can see from table 6.2 the random walk

was the best predictor in eight out of nine cases. This is really equivalent to

stating two things:

• Changes in the exchange rate are unpredictable, and

• the exchange rate is not mean reverting.

This has lead to the idea that exchange rates are in fact following a ran-

dom walk process. However, one needs to take this with some modifications.

• The result is only valid if we talk about purely floating exchange rate

between industrialised countries in the short term.

• And even here the random walk is not completely satisfying. It shows

up that exchange rate returns—an other word for the change in the

exchange rate—have fat tails. In other words, returns are not normally

distributed after all. What does fat tails mean? While most changes in

the exchange rate are small, some changes are very large. We see more

large changes than we should expect if the errors were drawn from a

normal distribution.

• More specific, the exchange rate tends to follow an ARCH/GARCH

process. This implies that a period of high volatility is usually followed

by more periods of high volatility, and a period of low volatility is

followed by periods of low volatility. Volatility in the exchange rate is

to some degree predictable.

166

Page 170: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

6.5 Equilibrium models

Ideally we want to build models that assume rational behavior and complete

information. The rational behavior/perfect information case is in the end the

only real benchmark we have. We need to gain full understanding of what

this framework can tell us before we modify these basic assumptions.

The rational behavior/perfect information was our starting point when

we derived an exchange rate model in Lecture 2. We concluded that the

exchange rate, e, could be expressed as a function of money supply, real

output, foreign interest rates and foreign prices, i.e. as

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s). (6.4)

The above framework is known as a “monetary equilibrium model”. In

this model all volatility should be a result of new information, “news”, as

all history will be reflected in the price at every given point of time. How-

ever, given our observations of the very high volatility in the exchange rate

compared to the fundamental variables in this equation, it is tempting to

conclude that this model is no good. There have been attempts to model

exchange rate movements using a reasonable assumption of what is “news”.

Such research tend to find that the exchange rate moves as much in periods

with no “news” as it does in periods with “news”. So “news” do not seem to

explain the exchange rate very well. One should on the other hand not forget

that the monetary equilibrium model does seem to to have some explanatory

power in the long run. The exchange rate is reverting to fundamentals. It

only takes much longer than we are able to explain.

We should ask why our model is no good in the short and medium term.

Some arguments:

167

Page 171: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

• The model specification might be no good. E.g. most tests of the

above model are done assuming a linear framework. It is however an

established fact that asset prices have a non-linear relationship to fun-

damentals. One result from research on “chaos models”, as discussed

in ch. 9 in De Grauwe, is that in a non-linear framework there might

be a relationship between fundamentals and prices even in the short

run. A problem has been that such non-linear models are very difficult

to make intellectually tractable.

• Some of our basic assumptions, like the assumptions of free trade and

free capital mobility might not hold. There might also be public inter-

ference not captured in the model.

• In equation (6.4) we have made the very convenient assumption of no

bubbles. However, in the many cases bubbles might be a real problem,

i.e. remember our discussion of rational bubbles.

• More problematic is the fact that we really do not understand how ex-

pectations are formed. This is probably the best explanation of why the

equilibrium models do not fit, because it is an explanation that helps

us understand why we do not understand asset market in general—the

FX market is nothing special. What do we not understand? Perhaps

markets are not as rational as this model assumes, or perhaps we do

not fully understand what ‘rational behaviour’ really implies. The eco-

nomic definition of rationality—to be a forward looking and maximise

some simple utility function—might not be a good description of reality.

Other possibilities exist as well:

• In the above model we assume that all variables, i.e. the price level,

as everything else is given exogenously, will adjust instantaneously to

168

Page 172: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

clear all markets. However, we know that prices might be sticky, at

least for periods of up to a year. If we assume that prices take time

to adjust, we must take into regard that it takes time to move from

one equilibrium to another. The economy will spend time “outside

equilibrium”—i.e. the introduction of “disequilibrium models”—the

main tool in the “New Keynesian economics”; dominating much of

current research in macroeconomics.

• When we looked at the FX-market, we saw that different dealers seemed

to follow different strategies. This will be the case for many agents in

asset markets. E.g. we know for certain that many traders will buy

assets based on so-called technical analysis. Technical analysis bases

buy and sell recommendations on graphs of historic prices. Such traders

will by definition be backward looking—they will not fit our forward

looking framework.

• An other feature of the FX market was low transparency. This might

indicate that we as researchers do not have full control over which

information dealers actually use when they set their exchange rates.

We might have a “missing variable” problem.

In the following sections we will investigate whether these three options can

help us understand the “exchange rate puzzle”.

6.6 Disequilibrium models

Disequilibrium models come in many forms. We will focus on the assumptions

that prices are sticky. How will this affect our discussion of the exchange rate?

When we derived the model in equation (6.4) we assumed both the PPP and

the UIP to hold at the same time. However, if prices are sticky this can no

169

Page 173: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

longer be the case. In the short term either the UIP or the PPP will not hold.

We will have a state that differs from the long term stable condition—we will

be out of equilibrium.

In the model we will present, due to Rudi Dornbusch, we assume that

while the UIP will hold at every point of times, although the PPP will not.

Assume that there is an unexpected shock to the money supply. Money sup-

ply increases. According to the equilibrium model prices should immediately

increase and the exchange rate should depreciate, leaving the real exchange

rate unaffected. The interest rate would not change.

What happens if prices take time to adjust? The long term expectations

will be the same as in the equilibrium model. When the price adjustment

has taken place, the two models have the same implications. The price

level will be higher, and the exchange rate will be higher. However, in the

short term only the exchange rate will adjust. Prices do not change. Hence,

domestic interest rates must fall. This is necessary to induce people to hold

the higher money supply—remember that lower interest rates make people

increase their holdings of currency. If prices had risen immediately people

would have been be willing to hold more money just because prices were

higher, and the interest rate would have been unaffected.

If the exchange rate immediately settles at its long term value, while

interest rates for a period fall bellow the foreign interest rate, the UIP can

not hold. But we have assumed the UIP to hold at every point of time.

So what must happen? If the UIP shall hold when domestic interest rates

are bellow foreign interest rates, we need to expect the exchange rate to

appreciate—as Etet+1 must be smaller than et.

This leads to overshooting—when the money shock occurs the exchange

rate must change by more than its long term expectations. This is the only

170

Page 174: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

way the UIP can hold—because only if the exchange rate depreciates “too

much” now, it can be expected to appreciate back to its long term value.

6.6.1 The Dornbusch model

Let us assume a real money demand function of the type we used in Lecture

2. We assume the real money demand, m − p is a function of the expected

interest rate, i, and real output, y. If interest rates increase, you want to

reduce your holdings of currency, so the sign of i is negative. If real output

increases you want to increase your holdings of currency, so the sign of y is

positive. Further, we assume perfect foresight. We an then write real money

demand as

m− p = −ηi + φy. (6.5)

Assume that UIP holds, and that et+1 − et =·e so that

·e = i− i∗. (6.6)

Further, we assume that there are both traded and non-traded goods in the

economy. The price of non-traded goods is pd. The price of traded goods is

equal to the foreign price level, p∗. We can define the price level as a weighted

average of traded and non-traded goods,

p = σpd + (1− σ)(e + p∗). (6.7)

You see that when σ = 0 the price level evolves according to the PPP.

However, if σ > 0 prices will not adjust automatically to the PPP level.

If we substitute for (6.6-6.7) into (6.5) we obtain

m− (σpd + (1− σ)(e + p∗)) = −η(i∗ − ·e) + φy. (6.8)

171

Page 175: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.7: The equilibrium model vs. the disequilibrium model

e

timet

p

timet

i

timet

i=i*

The whole lines give the solution to an unexpected positive monetary shock inthe monetary equilibrium model. This is as discussed in lecture 1 and 2. Thedashed lines give the movements of e, p and i as is expected in the Dornbuschmodel. 172

Page 176: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

When we reorder we obtain

·e =

σ

ηpd +

1− σ

ηe +

1− σ

ηp∗ − i∗ +

φ

ηy − 1

ηm. (6.9)

We concentrate about p and e. All other variables are exogenous in this

model. For simplicity we define a variable z that includes all exogenous

variables:

z = (1− σ)p∗ − ηi∗ + φy −m. (6.10)

We can then write·e as

·e =

σ

ηpd +

1− σ

ηe +

1

ηz. (6.11)

This gives us a first order difference equation for the change in the exchange

rate measured in e and p.

To complete the model we need a description of the movement in the

price level. We can define the real exchange rate, q, as3

q = p− p∗ − e. (6.12)

We define the exchange rate that will assure that q = 0 as e, i.e.

e = p− p∗. (6.13)

If e > e the exchange rate is undervalued, if e < e the exchange rate is

overvalued.

We postulate that the the price level will move up when the exchange rate

is undervalued and that the price level will move down when the exchange

3De Grauwe includes real shocks into the PPP equation. Such shocks do however notaffect the results we intend to discuss, so we just ignore them. They make no differencehere.

173

Page 177: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rate is overvalued. The change in prices,·p, can be written as

·p = δ(e− e), (6.14)

where δ > 0. If we substitute (6.13) into (6.14) we obtain

·p = δ(e− p + p∗). (6.15)

Equation (6.5) describe the domestic price level as a weighted average of

traded and non-traded goods. If we substitute (6.5) into (6.15) and rearrange

we obtain·p = σδ(e− pd + p∗). (6.16)

If σ is zero, there will be no over- or undervalued exchange rate, as the PPP

will hold at all times.

We have two first order difference equations, one for·e and one for

·p. We

now set·e =

·p = 0. From equation (6.11) we obtain

pd = −1− σ

σe +

1

σz. (6.17)

From equation (6.16) we obtain

pd = e + p∗. (6.18)

An equilibrium is a situation where variables are stable. Equation (6.17)

defines under what conditions the financial markets are in equilibrium. Equa-

tion (6.18) defines under what conditions the goods markets are in equilib-

rium.

The financial equilibrium is illustrated in figure 6.8. In the financial

market equilibrium we adjust the exchange rate. Assume the price level of

non-traded goods is “too high”—i.e. we are at a point above the line defined

174

Page 178: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.8: Financial market equilibrium

p

de=0

e

in equation (6.17). For the real exchange rate to adjust towards PPP the

nominal exchange rate must depreciate—i.e. the direction of the arrow in the

diagram. If prices are “too low”, the nominal exchange rate must appreciate.

The goods market equilibrium is illustrated in figure 6.9. In this equilib-

rium we adjust the price level. If the exchange rate is “too high”—at a point

to the right in the figure—the price level must rise for the real exchange rate

to adjust. If the exchange rate is “too low”—i.e. we are in the left of the

figure—the price level must fall for the real exchange rate to adjust.

Together the financial market and the goods market define the economy.

If we bring the two equilibrium conditions into one diagram we can identify

175

Page 179: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.9: Goods market equilibrium

p

dp=0

e

176

Page 180: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.10: Market equilibrium

p

dp=0

e

de=0

ethe equilibrium of the economy. However, outside this equilibrium we have

possible unstable situations. How the market is expected to move in the

different areas is described by the arrows in figure 6.10. The model has a

“saddle point” where the two lines cross. There is only one stable line that

leads from disequilibrium to the saddle point, and this path is defined by

the “saddle path” in the figure. Every other path than the “saddle path”

will lead to increasing deviations from fundamentals. However, as foresight

is assumed to be perfect, it is reasonable to believe that the economy will be

at the saddle path.

Now we can analyse shocks. A money shock is a shock to the financial

177

Page 181: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.11: A positive money shock

p

dp=0

e

de=0

de’=0

market. An increase in the money supply will shift the line for·e out. At the

same time interest rates must fall to bring prices down.

In a phase diagram we will not expect an immediate shift to the new

saddle point. Prices will be sticky in our model. So the price level will take

time to adjust. In the short term only the exchange rate can move. It will

do so by shifting to the right, to the new saddle path. However, this rate

will be higher than the rate in the saddle point. Over time the exchange rate

must appreciate as it moves towards the saddle point. In parallel interest

rates will rise and prices will rise. A new equilibrium will be established with

a higher price level and an interest rate equal to the foreign interest rate.

178

Page 182: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The weakness of the Dornbusch approach

What is the the problem of the Dornbusch model? The model gained at-

tention because the overshooting result gave a possible explanation for the

high volatility in the exchange rate. If the exchange rate tended to over-

shoot, we should expect exchange rate volatility to be substantially higher

than the volatility in underlying fundamentals. Further, the model gives an

explanation of why we should expect to see a high correlation between the

nominal and the real exchange rate. After all, prices do not move here, while

the nominal exchange rate overshoots. This should imply that even the real

exchange rate will overshoot for a period of time. However, the model only

gives this result in the case of monetary shocks. If there is a shock to de-

mand, through e.g. public spending, this will shift the·p = 0 equation. Such

a shift does not lead to overshooting in this model.

Is it reasonable to assume that frequent monetary shocks are the main

cause of the high volatility in the exchange rate? Empirically, monetary

shock are very hard to distinguish, so this is not an easy question to answer.

However, as we pointed out above, the high volatility in the FX market is a

feature it shares with almost every other asset market. It is fairly certain that

monetary shocks does not explain why other asset markets are so volatile.

Probably the Dornbusch model is to specific to give any good understanding

of the high volatility in exchange rates. It is however still important as a

benchmark for much of the current literature in exchange rate economics.

6.7 Chartists and noise traders

The monetary equilibrium model assumes that all traders are using the same

strategy. They have estimated a model for the exchange rate that they are

179

Page 183: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

continuously updating, based on expected fundamental underlinings for the

exchange rate. If the exchange rate is “overvalued” compared with their

expectations they sell, it the exchange rate is “undervalued” they buy.

However, different traders might be using different strategies. E.g. most

surveys of traders active in the FX market reveal that at least 30 per cent

tend to use chartist methods to forecast the exchange rate. A chartist will

use historic values of the asset price to predict future movements in the asset

price. They are assumed to use rules that are extrapolative, like “buy when

the 1-week moving average crosses above the 12-week moving average.”

Milton Friedman argued in 1953 that non-fundamental speculators would

over time lose money. However, it has been shown by a number of studies

that one can make money using a chartist strategy. Therefore it might be

perfectly rational to be a chartist, although this implies a trading strategy

that does not care about “fundamentals”. If the exchange rate only reverts

to fundamentals in the long term, much money can be made following the

short term trends. Feedback trading can also be rationalised if one assumes

that the availability of information is limited. If we assume some traders to

have more information than others, the less informed will have to observe

the trading process, as the actual trading is a source of how other agents are

behaving.

If many traders are operating as chartists, this might increase the proba-

bility for the exchange rate to move in long swings. If the value of a currency

is appreciating, chartist strategies would probably indicate to buy the cur-

rency, thereby fuelling the trend. One the other hand, if this trend is moving

away from fundamentals, should not “fundamental traders” force the rate

back?

At some point they will. However, their total force might not be big

180

Page 184: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

enough to do so before the exchange rate has deviated quite substantially

from the underlying rate. Some potential problems:

• There is actual uncertainty about the future. Unless the discrepancy

between the rate and fundamentals become “too large”, there can al-

ways occur some unexpected “news” that would justify the current

rate. The fear of such events might hinder a rational investor from

short-selling to bring the exchange rate back.

• Even if the rate is currently overvalued, there is no guarantee for when

the trend will turn. Hence, if you sell today, while the rate continues

to move away from fundamentals, you will miss out on an even bigger

profit opportunity tomorrow.

• Even if you base your predictions on fundamentals, you are never cer-

tain that your model is a 100 per cent correct.

The noise trader paradigm is a continuation of the chartist-fundamentalist

approach. A noise trader is defined as someone who responds to random

price movements. Experiments tend to show that investors are overconfident

about their own predictive abilities. Other studies have shown that many

traders believe a large change in the exchange rate to be the most important

“news” over the course of a day—rather odd, given that “news” should be

something generated outside the market. Such findings might indicate that

actual behaviour does not fit the monetary equilibrium model’s definition of

“rational”. Describing noise traders is however difficult. Recent theoretical

studies tend to model noise trading by assuming that noise traders behave

like chartists.

181

Page 185: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

6.8 Microstructure theories

In Lecture 5 we discussed the institutional framework of the FX market. We

saw, among other things, that the FX market tended be distinguished by

high volume and low transparency compared with other markets. The mi-

crostructure theory is a sidetrack of exchange rate economics that investigate

how institutional factors influence the pricing process in the market.

There have been two lines in the literature. The traditional approach has

been to see whether the trading process, e.g. the use of different trading

system, will have a price impact. These studies are generally restricted to

looking at very short term price fluctuations, mainly basing their findings on

tick-by-thick data, or the continuous flow of orders in the market.4

A more recent strain of the literature focuses on the the lack of trans-

parency. The argument is that different investors will have different informa-

tion. This information will be reflected to the market through their trading.

One measure of trading is “order flow”. Order flow is defined as net initi-

ated purchases of foreign currency. If a customer calls a dealer and asks for

10 EUR in the SEK/EUR market, this implies an order flow of 10. If the

customer asks for 10 SEK, this implies an order flow of -10.

Order flow reflects “excess demand” in the market. What is “excess

demand”? Should not always demand equal supply? Well, the demand curve

might shift. Excess demand reflects the direction of shifts in the demand

curve.

How does this differ from the equilibrium models? In the monetary equi-

librium model demand is determined by the current value of a number of

fundamental variables. The models assume that everyone has the same infor-

mation, and that everyone uses the same model to interpret this information.

4A ‘thick’ is a single trade.

182

Page 186: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

However, “fundamental variables” are mostly reported only with a lag.

E.g. the inflation rate is reported only once a month, and with at least one

month lag. Real output is reported at a quarterly basis, with several months

lag. The numbers are often revised several times after that. At every given

point of time there exists no consensus of what real output is in exactly this

point. Further, it is no reason to believe that every investor uses the same

model to evaluate the information available.

It is however reasonable to assume that investors’ beliefs about current

fundamentals will be reflected in their trading. So if investors demands more

of a currency, this might imply that there are reasons for the exchange rate

to appreciate.

The main proponent of this approach, Richard Lyons, argues that actual

dealers hardly care about “news” when they are setting prices. He claims

that dealers mainly observe the amount of incoming trade, and adjust prices

as a result of this. If so, order flow will be the determinant of much of the

price fluctuations we can observe in the data.

Figure 6.12 depicts accumulated customer order flow in the Swedish mar-

ket and the SEK/DEM exchange rate. As the order flow has a negative

number, we see that customers are net buying SEK. On the opposing side

must be either Sveriges Riksbank, or the reporting banks—the Riksbank or

the dealers must be accumulating DEM if customers shall be able to ac-

cumulate SEK. As we see there is a fairly strong correlation between the

customer order flow and the exchange rate. Table 6.3 reports regression re-

sults when we include order flow in regressions on the exchange rate. As we

see, including order flows in the regressions improve the R2 quite consider-

ably compared with regression only including “fundamental variables”, like

interest rates and the stock exchange.

183

Page 187: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Tab

le6.

3:E

stim

atin

gdai

lyre

turn

s—01

.01.

1998

to06

.30.

1998

retu

rns

(1)

t-st

at(2

)t-st

at(3

)t-st

at(4

)t-st

atC

onst

ant

0.00

00.

576

0.00

00.

984

0.00

12.

776

**0.

001

2.79

8**

Tot

alcu

stom

erO

F7.

72E

-07

3.98

7**

Sw

edis

hcu

stom

erO

F6.

61E

-07

2.97

9**

6.24

E-0

72.

880

**For

eign

cust

omer

OF

6.11

E-0

72.

951

**7.

06E

-07

3.44

2**

Dea

ler-

dea

ler

flow

-1.9

4E-0

7-0

.637

-1.7

6E-0

7-0

.594

Chan

gein

for.

rese

rves

-3.6

3E-0

6-3

.026

**-3

.78E

-06

-3.1

94**

Inte

rest

dif.,

d(r

dif

)0.

002

0.17

3-0

.002

-0.1

51-0

.006

-0.5

070.

000

-0.0

35Sto

ckin

dex

retu

rn,d(l

OM

XC

)-0

.054

-2.4

72*

-0.0

51-2

.437

*-0

.055

-2.6

95**

-0.0

53-2

.689

**Lag

ged

retu

rn(4

)0.

195

2.44

5*

Adj

ust

edR

20.

030.

140.

180.

30D

W2.

092.

022.

052.

15S.E

.ofre

gres

sion

0.00

30.

003

0.00

30.

001

Note

1:

Est

imate

dw

ith

OLS

Note

2:

*-5

per

cent,

**

-1

per

cent

Note

3:

We

incl

ude

5la

gged

valu

esof

retu

rnin

this

regre

ssio

n.

Only

the

fourt

hla

gis

signifi

cant.

184

Page 188: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.12: Accumulated customer order flow in the SEK/DEM market andthe SEK/DEM exchange rate, January 1, 1998, to June 30, 1998

Chart1

Page 1

-30000

-25000

-20000

-15000

-10000

-5000

01

2.1

2.11

2.12

2.13

2.14

2.15

2.16

2.17

2.18

2.19

Customer order flow

log(SEK/DEM)

6.9 The uncovered interest rate parity (UIP)

In Lecture 5 we discussed the covered return to investing one krone in the

foreign money market. We argued that this return should equal the return

of investing one krone in the Norway. From this we derived the CIP, or

Ft

εt

=1 + it1 + i∗t

. (6.19)

In log form this can be written

ft − et = it − i∗t . (6.20)

The uncovered return to investing one krone in the foreign money market

will be(1 + i∗t )Etεt+1

εt

, (6.21)

185

Page 189: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

or in logs

i∗t + Etet+1 − et. (6.22)

As described in Lecture 2 the UIP is the idea that if expectations are rational,

then the the expected uncovered return of this investment should equal the

return of investing one krone in Norway. Arbitrage should assure that the

uncovered excess return should be zero on average. We should expect

Et(i∗t + Etet+1 − et − it) = 0. (6.23)

There are three interpretations of this equation.

1. The expected depreciation rate equals the interest rate differential. Let

us define expected depreciation as Etdt+1 = Etet+1 − et. If we insert

this into (6.23) we obtain

Etdt+1 = it − i∗t . (6.24)

2. Forward interest rates are unbiased predictors of future spot rates. If

we insert (6.20) into (6.23) we obtain

ft − et = Etet+1 − et, (6.25)

or

ft = Etet+1. (6.26)

3. The international Fisher relationship. From previous courses you should

be familiar with the term “real interest rate”, ir. The real interest rate

is defined by the Fisher equation that states that the real interest rate

is the differential between the nominal interest rate and expected in-

186

Page 190: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

flation,

irt = it − Etπt+1 ⇒ it = Etπt+1 + irt (6.27)

Similar, we must have

i∗t = Etπ∗t+1 + ir∗t (6.28)

If we substitute equations (6.27) and (6.28) into (6.24) we obtain

Etdt+1 = (Etπt+1 + irt )− (Etπ∗t+1 + ir∗t ). (6.29)

The PPP states that

et = pt − p∗t . (6.30)

We should also have that

Etet+1 = Etpt+1 − Etp∗t+1. (6.31)

So the PPP implies that

Etet+1 − et = Etpt+1 − Etp∗t+1 − (pt − p∗t ). (6.32)

This can be rewritten as

Etdt+1 = Etπt+1 − Etπ∗t+1. (6.33)

So if the PPP holds we must have that

Etπt+1−Etπ∗t+1 = (Etπt+1 + irt )− (Etπ

∗t+1 + ir∗t ) ⇒ irt = ir∗t . (6.34)

The real interest must be equal between countries.

187

Page 191: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

6.9.1 Testing the UIP

The ‘expectations hypothesis’ or the ‘efficient market hypothesis’ is built

on the idea that if there are free capital flows and rational expectations we

should expect

ft = Etet+1 (6.35)

to hold if markets are efficient. It is reasonable to try to test whether this

hypothesis holds in empirical data. To do so we define a forecast error, u, as

et+1 = Etet+1 + ut+1 ⇒ Etet+1 = et+1 − ut+1. (6.36)

The forecast error is the difference between the realised exchange rate in

period t + 1 and the expected exchange rate.

If we substitute (6.36) and the CIP into the the UIP equation we obtain

et+1 − ut+1 − et = ft − et. (6.37)

From (6.37) we can obtain the following testable equation

dt+1 = a + b(ft − et) + vt+1, (6.38)

where a is a constant and v is an error term. This is equivalent to testing

the equation

dt+1 = a + b(it − i∗t ) + vt+1. (6.39)

According to the UIP hypothesis we should expect a to be zero and b to be

1.

Figure 6.13 reports the finding of this regression for five different markets.

As we see b is not close to one in any of the five reported regressions. In fact

b is significant and negative. This implies that the interest rate differential

is negatively correlated with depreciation of the currency. An investor who

188

Page 192: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

holds funds in a high yield currency not only benefits form higher yields, but

also tends to benefit from an appreciation in the long run. You simply get a

double dividend. But how can such excess returns exist?

We should notice that although the UIP does not seem like a good idea,

it is not certain that one can make money on doing the opposite of the UIP.

Even if the t-ratios of the b-parameters are significant, the R2 of the equations

are very low, indicating a poor fit of our model. It is reason to doubt whether

one can make money on trading against the UIP in the long run. However,

one certainly can make money trading against the UIP in the short run.

Figure 6.14 depicts the interest differential between Norwegian and German

three month interbank rates and the NOK/EUR exchange rate. In this case

Norway has over 3 per cent higher interest rates than Germany. According

to the UIP we should expect NOK to depreciate substantially vis-a-vis the

EUR. However, during the last months NOK has appreciated. Lending in

EUR, investing in NOK has given a double dividend—both a substantial

interest differential and an appreciation of NOK. Such cases are difficult to

explain using the UIP.

We are certainly missing out one something here. Notice that when we

set the expected future exchange rate equal to the forward rate we leave out

any discussion of risk. However, most investors are risk averse. We should

probably take this into regard in our calculations. Fama decomposed the

forward premium, ft − et into two parts:

ft − et = (ft − Etet+1︸ ︷︷ ︸rt

) + (Etet+1 − et︸ ︷︷ ︸dt

). (6.40)

where r = the risk premium and d as before is expected depreciation. One

implication of the above regression results is that r certainly must be different

from zero. However, here, as in many other parts of the asset pricing litera-

189

Page 193: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.13: Regressions on the UIP

Forward and Eurocurrency Markets4. UIP

Regression results

StandardCurrency a b Error R2

British Pound -0.0067 -2.306 0.0322 0.0344(0.0028) (0.862)

Canadian Dollar -0.0027 -1.464 0.0120 0.0247(0.0009) (0.581)

French Franc -0.0026 -0.806 0.0326 0.0015(0.0032) (0.928)

German Mark 0.0032 -3.542 0.0333 0.0287(0.0043) (1.348)

Japanese Yen 0.0084 -1.813 0.0334 0.0201(0.0032) (0.719)

Source: Backus, Foresi and Telmer (2001)“Affine Models of Currency Pricing”

http://bertha.gsia.cmu.edu

18

190

Page 194: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 6.14: The interest differential between Norwegian and German threemonth interbank rates and the NOK/EUR exchange rate

0

1

2

3

4

10/26 11/30 1/04 2/08 3/15

NOK3-DEM3

2.03

2.04

2.05

2.06

2.07

2.08

2.09

10/26 11/30 1/04 2/08 3/15

LNOKEUR

191

Page 195: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

ture, it is difficult to interpret the risk premium implicated by our findings. If

the risk premium was constant this should have been reflected in the finding

that a 6= 0, however that is not clear from the regressions in figure 6.13. If

the UIP shall match the data, the risk premium must fluctuate extensively.

This does not seem credible.5

Several explanations of the rejection of the UIP build on the presumption

that expectations are not perfectly rational. The peso problem is the idea

that investors expect a large correction of the exchange rate at some time,

they are however not certain when the correction will take place. If this

correction did not take place in the sample used to test the UIP, the UIP

will not hold.

In the regression (i−i∗) is known today while the actual value of e will first

be known in the future. The idea that expectations are an unbiased predictor

of future exchange rates will just hold if the environment is stable. If the

environment is unstable, one must expect investors to continuously update

their expectations. This ongoing learning process will create problems if we

try to test for the UIP.

Researchers have substituted actual data with expected depreciation rates,

as is reported in surveys from the financial markets. It shows up that if one

uses survey data instead of actual data, b tends to be close to one, and a is

significantly different from zero. This implies that on survey data the UIP

holds if one takes into regard a constant risk premium. People might in-

deed act according to the UIP, however their expectations are not the best

unbiased prediction of the future.

5In the stock market one has attempted to use risk premiums as an explanation for thehigh returns in equity compared with risk free assets. However, to make the model matchthe data one must assume an incredible degree of risk aversion. The data simply does notsquare at reasonable parameter assumptions.

192

Page 196: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 7

Portfolio choice, risk premia

and capital mobility

7.1 Introduction

The first six lectures have focused on how we should understand the exchange

rate from a macroeconomic point of view. If investors are rational and for-

ward looking, we should expect the exchange rate to be determined by the

expectations of future values of certain economic variables, so-called funda-

mentals. We have discussed how the government would want to influence

the trade-off between an independent monetary policy and a stable exchange

rate, and investigated the limitations the government faces when it tries to

stabilise the exchange rate. Further we have looked at some institutional

factors of the exchange rate market. In the last lecture we discussed how

the equilibrium approach could be adjusted to better understand the actual

experience with floating exchange rates.

In this lecture we will turn to the investor. In the equilibrium model all

investors will be similar—everyone uses the same model, and has the same

expectations of the future. In Lecture 6 we made some attempts to modify

these assumptions. We looked at the possibility that agents might form their

193

Page 197: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

expectations independently. In this lecture we will focus on the fact that

investors have different national affiliation. National affiliation must not be

understood as “citizenship”. Affiliation is decided by the the denomination

of costs and income. If your operating costs are paid in NOK, and your

sales are paid in NOK, how should you then adjust your currency holdings

to maximise your financial income?

7.1.1 Some notes on methodology

In economics one has tended to focus on utility maximisation when analysing

decisions under uncertainty. An economist is expected to work with as gen-

eral specifications of the utility function as possible. The set up is as follows:

You control a number of variables, so-called choice variables. In addition

there is a number of factors you can not control, so-called state variables.

Let the choice variable be how much you will sow on a field. The state

variable will be the amount of rain that falls in the following months.

The payoff in the next period will depend on both factors. The more

you sow, the higher expected output. But output will be different for each

different state—it will depend on how much rain that falls. When you decide

how much to sow you must first make up your mind about the likelihood of

different states, e.g. the possibility of much rain, little rain or no rain. Then

you must calculate expected profits under each state. Having done this, you

can make a decision about how much to sow.1

This set up is of course also applicable to financial decisions. The state-

preference framework concludes that the fundamental object of choice in

financial decisions are payoffs offered at different states of nature. However,

1Just to point out how complicated this can get: assume that how much you cansow next year depends on how much you do sow this year. In this case you must notonly calculate the possible outcomes for all states this year, you must also calculate theoutcomes for all possible states next year, and the year after that, and ... .

194

Page 198: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

it is extremely difficult to list all payoffs offered at different states of nature.

As a result, the state-preference theory is almost without empirical content—

it is impossible to test it, as we can not characterise the objects of choice.

In finance this problem is solved by assuming that investors indifference

curves are defined in terms of the means and variance of asset return. It

is clear that this is only a very special case of the utility maximisation ap-

proach.2 However, in financial economics the possibility of empirical testing

is seen as more important than the generalisation of the theory.

In this lecture we will use the mean-variance analysis to derive demand

functions for foreign currency. The main idea behind the portfolio approach

to exchange rates is that assets in the home country and in the foreign coun-

try are not perfect substitutes. This is an important difference from the

monetary approach analysed in the previous lectures. In the monetary ap-

proach all assets are perfect substitutes, and the uncovered interest parity is

supposed to hold by assuming arbitrage. However, if similar assets at home

and abroad are not perfect substitutes the UIP will not hold—this leads to

the introduction of the concept of risk premium.

7.2 Demand for foreign currency

In the mean-variance analysis, the investor is assumed to maximise a utility

function, U , of the form

U = E(π)− 1

2Rvar(π), (7.1)

where π is real rate of return on the portfolio, E is an expectation operator,

and R is the coefficient of relative risk aversion. We assume R > 0. The

higher R, the higher the risk aversion. High risk aversion implies that the

2See appendix.

195

Page 199: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

investor is willing to sacrifice more in the form of lower return if she can reduce

her risk. Risk is measured as the variance of return. In the currency market

risk is a factor because of uncertainty about depreciation and inflation.

The investor is assumed to hold two types of assets: domestic currency,

B, and foreign currency, F . Total real wealth, W , denominated in local

currency will be

W =B

P+

εF

P, (7.2)

where ε is the exchange rate. The share of total wealth the investor chooses

to hold in foreign currency is

f =εF

PW. (7.3)

The model treats f as the the choice variable. Given f , one can compute

F = f PWε

and B = (1− f)PW .

Expected real return on the portfolio will be given by

π = (1− f)(i− ·p) + f(i∗ +

·e− ·

p) = (1− f)i + f(i∗ +·e)− ·

p, (7.4)

where i is the interest rate,·p=rate of inflation,

·e=rate of depreciation and ∗

denotes foreign values.

We assume that·p is a stochastic variable with the distribution

·p ∼ N(µp, σpp). (7.5)

µp is the expected mean of a change in inflation, and σpp is the expected

standard deviation around the mean. Similar, we assume that

·e ∼ N(µe, σee). (7.6)

The correlation between·p and

·ee is σep. There is no uncertainty about the

196

Page 200: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

interest rate, as it is observable today.

Given this, and using the rules for expectations and variances of linear

combinations of stochastic variables, we obtain

E(π) = (1− f)i + f(i∗ + µe)− µp, (7.7)

and3

var(π) = f 2σee + σpp − 2fσep. (7.8)

If we substitute into equation (7.1) we obtain

U = (1− f)i + f(i∗ + µe)− µp −1

2R

[f 2σee + σpp − 2fσep

]. (7.9)

If we maximise with regard to f we obtain

δU

δf= −i + (i∗ + µe)−

1

2R [2fσee − 2σep] = 0. (7.10)

Solving (11.84) for f leaves us with

f =σep

σee

+1

Rσee

(i∗ + µe − i). (7.11)

We see that local investors demand for foreign currency increase as the

foreign interest rate increases, and decrease as the domestic interest rates

increases. Note that in the monetary model we assume the UIP to hold, which

implies that i∗+µe− i = 0, as µe is just expected depreciation, Et(et−1− et).

In this model we assume that there is a risk premium on domestic currency,

r, that is given by

r = i− i∗ − µe. (7.12)

r is the extra return needed to hold domestic currency. Note that r can be

3Remember that if z = αx + βz, and x and y is normally distributed, var(z) =α2σxx + β2σyy + 2 · αβσxy.

197

Page 201: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

negative—it might be that the risk is on the foreign currency.

Using the definition of r we can restate (11.48) as

f =σep

σee

− r

Rσee

. (7.13)

We see that the holdings of foreign currency can be divided in two terms.

The first term, σep

σee, is called the minimum-variance portfolio, fM . This is

the share of foreign currency that minimises the variance of the return. The

second term, − rRσee

, is the speculative portfolio, fS.

7.2.1 The minimum-variance portfolio

In this model we have no risk free asset, as the real rates of return in both

assets, i.e. domestic and foreign currency, are uncertain. It will only be

optimal to hold no foreign assets in the case when the correlation between

inflation and depreciation is zero. If the correlation is negative, one should

short-sell foreign currency. However, it is most reasonable to assume that

σep is positive. It would therefore be optimal to hold some foreign currency

in the minimum-variance portfolio.

One example can be to assume that PPP holds. Then we have that·e =

·p −

·p∗. If domestic and foreign inflation is uncorrelated (σpp∗ = 0), the

PPP implies that σee = σpp + σp∗p∗ , and σep = σpp. We can then write the

share of foreign currency in the minimum-variance portfolio as

fM =σpp

σpp + σp∗p∗, (7.14)

and the share of domestic currency in the minimum-variance portfolio as

1− fM =σp∗p∗

σpp + σp∗p∗. (7.15)

Note that if the variance of inflation in the home country goes to infinity,

198

Page 202: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

e.g. because of hyperinflation, it would be optimal to hold only foreign

currency. If there is no inflation risk in one of the two countries, an investment

in that country would be equal to a risk-free investment. The investor would

minimise risk by only holding that currency. In general the investor should

divide her portfolio in inverse proportion to the variance in inflation in the

two countries.

An implication is that we should expect currency substitution in high

inflation countries. If inflation is spiraling out of control, domestic residents

should shift their holdings to foreign currency. This is actually what we

observe. In most high inflation currencies people tend to prefer to hold USD.

Domestic currency is only held in small amounts for transaction purposes.

In some hyperinflation countries people have actually substituted the local

currency with foreign currency as a means of payment.

If we instead assume that there is no correlation between prices and the

exchange rate we have σep = 0. In this case holding foreign currency would

only add risk, and the minimum-variance portfolio will only contain domestic

currency. In general deviations from PPP will create a preference for the

domestic currency in the minimum-variance portfolio.

7.2.2 The speculative portfolio

The speculative portfolio, − rRσee

, depends on three parameters: the risk

premium, the risk aversion and the variance of the exchange rate.

First, observe that the sign is negative. This is due to the fact that

we define the risk premium as the risk premium of investing in domestic

currency. Remember that the risk premium is defined as i − i∗ − µe. If

this risk premium is positive one would optimise the speculative portfolio by

increasing the exposure in domestic currency. This can be done by borrowing

199

Page 203: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

in foreign currency and investing at home. We see that the exposure to

foreign currency will decrease as the risk premium rises.

Second, the effect on the speculative portfolio of a change in R or σee

will depend on the sign of r. If risk aversion increases, the speculative port-

folio will be reduced in size. If risk premium is negative, one will reduce

the exposure to foreign currency. However, if risk premium is positive one

will increase the exposure to foreign currency, as one reduces the specula-

tive exposure to domestic currency. The same argument holds for increased

volatility in the exchange rate.

Capital mobility is the ability of capital to move freely across borders.

A high degree of capital mobility means that differences in expected return

have a strong effect on the supply of foreign currency. That should imply

that the share of foreign holdings in the investor’s portfolio should increase

if the risk premium decreases. The smaller the value of R and σee, the

more does a change in r affect the optimal currency portfolio. There will be

perfect capital mobility, fS → ∞, if risk aversion is zero, or it there is no

exchange rate risk (σee = 0). In this case all capital will flow to the country

with highest return. This should lead to the elimination of all risk premia,

implying a speculative portfolio of zero.

7.2.3 Empirical calculations

Let us take a look at Norwegian data for the period from January 1993

September 2001. Over this period we find

• σep = −1.85 ∗ 10−5, and

• σee = 0.003850.

200

Page 204: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Note that these are results on monthly data. For the exchange rate we use

NOK/EUR (DEM before 1.1.99). This tells us that fM should be very small

in the Norwegian market—there is no reason to hold foreign currency to

hedge against inflation risk.

It is a general finding that the minimum-variance holdings of foreign

currency should be small for industrialised countries with stable inflation

rates. However, for countries with high inflation, this changes radically. Over

a high inflation period in Argentina it was found that the optimal holdings

of USD in the minimum-variance portfolio of an Argentinean investor was

86 per cent. As a comparison, the optimal holdings of USD for a German

investor was found to be 9 per cent.

Calculating the speculative portfolio is more difficult, not least because

we do not know the actual coefficient of the risk aversion. However, it is

usual to assume this to be around 2. Note that if the risk aversion is very

high, capital mobility becomes very low.

A simple estimate of the risk premium is to take realised interest rates

and return in the exchange market over the period we investigate. This is

obviously not the correct measure of the risk premium, as this depend on

expected values. However it should be reasonably close if we assume rational

expectations. I the case of Norway vs. Germany we find that over the period

from 1993 to 2001 we have

• i− i∗ = 0.0156

• ·e = −0.00034

The interest differential is the annualised value of the three month rates. We

use the mean of·e as a measure of the expected depreciation.4 This leaves

4One should however be aware that the distribution of·e is severely skewed (it is not

normally distributed), so the mean might not be appropriate here. The median is as a

201

Page 205: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

us with a risk premium, measured as an annual return, of r = 0.0156 ∗

−(−0.00034) ∗ 12 = .0198. Investing in NOK has over the last 9 years been

a purely win-win situation—you have got a higher interest rate than abroad,

and in addition the positive return from an appreciating currency.

The optimal speculative holdings of foreign currency by a Norwegian in-

vestor is found to be

fS =−0.0198

2 ∗ 0.00385 ∗ 12= −0.214. (7.16)

Norwegian investors should have negative holdings of EUR. Norwegians should

borrow in foreign currency, and invest in Norway. In other words, they should

go short in foreign currency. In fact this is what we see—Norwegian banks

borrow extensively abroad to finance loans in NOK. And to a growing extent,

Norwegian households do the same. Note that foreigners should choose to

hold Norwegian currency.

7.2.4 Heterogenous agents

Capital mobility depends not just on the risk aversion, but also on how

much wealth, W , is actually invested. Assume e.g. that wealth is held

by two groups, households and professional investors. One would usually

expect that a household has a much higher coefficient of risk aversion than

a professional investor.

Assume only professional investors are active in the market, and that

these have a low R. Then even a small change in r or σee can lead to large

movements in the portfolio holdings of a currency. This can explain the

movements of currencies under speculative attacks. If a country has held a

high interest rate to attract foreign investors, we can expect these investors

comparison 0.00046—however both values are close to zero.

202

Page 206: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

to hold mainly short term, liquid funds. If expected σee change, e.g. due to

a change in international circumstances, large funds might be extracted over

night.

One should also note that a the proportion of investors that take active

positions in the currency market might vary over time. If there is a cost of

obtaining information about the risk of investing in foreign currency, small

investors might prefer domestic currency. However, this will only be true up

to a certain point. If expected return in foreign currency increases beyond

the cost of investing, a large share of investors will shift from being “passive”

to being “active”. Such shift can be induced by dramatic movements in

interest rates, exchange rates or reserves. This might be one explanation for

contagion of currency crises, as we discussed in Lecture 4.

One should be aware that high R or high costs of information might not

be the only reason for not taking speculative positions in foreign currencies.

Many banks and insurance companies must fulfill regulations that often stip-

ulate a limit for currency risk. That will regulate their ability to speculate

in the currency markets. An other factor might be credit constraints. If f

is outside the interval [0, 1] the investor must borrow money to obtain the

optimal portfolio.

7.2.5 Aggregate behaviour

Before we proceed we must understand the balance sheet of the economy.

Assume that we can divide the economy in three sectors,

• domestic government (superscript g),

• domestic private, and

• foreign (superscript *). Note that ‘foreign’ here will include both for-

203

Page 207: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

eign private investors and the foreign government.

We retain the assumption of only two assets; domestic currency, B, and

foreign currency, F .

We are only looking at financial assets. Net financial holdings of an asset

summed over all sectors in the economy must be zero—investments made by

one group must be reflected as loans taken up by another group. In other

words: one agent’s assets are the liabilities of another agent.

A currency is the liability of the government. Net outstanding liabili-

ties on the government must equal total holdings of domestic currency by

domestic private and foreign investors. We must have that

Bg + B + B∗ = 0. (7.17)

This must also hold for foreign currency. We must have that

F g + F + F ∗ = 0. (7.18)

Real financial wealth in for the private domestic sector, measured in do-

mestic currency, will be

W =B + εF

P. (7.19)

Likewise, the real financial wealth of the foreign sector, measured in foreign

currency, will be

W ∗ =B∗

ε+ F ∗

P ∗ , (7.20)

where P ∗ is the foreign price level.

If we use equation (11.53) and substitute that into (10.29) we obtain the

demand for foreign currency by domestic private investors,

F = fPW

ε=

[σep

σee

− r

Rσee

]PW

ε. (7.21)

204

Page 208: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Likewise we know that foreigner’s holdings of domestic currency, b∗, which

from the point of view of the foreigner will be holdings of foreign currency,

will be

b∗ = −σep∗

σee

+r

Rσee

. (7.22)

Note that we change signs, as the currency is defined as the price of foreign

currency in domestic currency. From the point of view of the foreigner a de-

preciation of the domestic currency becomes an appreciation of the currency

of his home currency, and vice versa.

The demand for foreign currency by foreign residents will then be

F ∗ = (1− b∗)P ∗W ∗ =

[1 +

σep∗

σee

− r

Rσee

]P ∗W ∗. (7.23)

Supply of currency to the central bank

If we insert equations (7.19-11.52) into (7.18), we obtain

F g = −[σep

σee

− r

Rσee

](B

ε+ F

)−

[1 +

σep∗

σee

− r

Rσee

](B∗

ε+ F ∗

). (7.24)

This can be restated as

F g = −[σep

σee

](B

ε+ F

)−

[1 +

σep∗

σee

](B∗

ε+ F ∗

)+

r

Rσee

(B + B∗

ε+ F + F ∗

).

(7.25)

This gives us the supply of foreign currency to the domestic central bank. If

we e.g. think about the NOK/EUR market, this will be the supply of EUR

to Norges Bank.

How Norges Bank reacts to a change in supply of foreign currency de-

pends on the exchange rate regime. In a floating rate regime F g is given

exogenously, and the right hand side of (7.25)) will determine the exchange

rate, as the exchange rate adjusts to clear the market. If the exchange rate

205

Page 209: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

is fixed, F g must be adjusted to clear the market. This will be done through

interventions from the central bank.

If we draw a diagram with ε on the y-axis, and foreign reserves on the

x-axis, we tend to assume that supply of foreign currency to the central bank

will increase if the domestic currency fall in value,as we have done in figure

7.1.5 In other words, we expect δF g

δε> 0. This will hold if

δF g

δε=

[σep

σee

](B

ε2

)+

[1 +

σep∗

σee

](B∗

ε2

)− r

Rσee

(B + B∗

ε2

)> 0. (7.26)

This can be rewritten as

δF g

δε= f

(B

ε2

)+ (1− b∗)

(B∗

ε2

)> 0. (7.27)

The condition will always be satisfied if both domestic and foreign investors

hold a positive amount of both currencies.

We can bring our understanding a little further. Let us make the conve-

nient assumption that σep = σep∗ = 0. That is similar to a statement that the

PPP does not hold. We know that this implies that the minimum-variance

portfolio should contain no foreign currency. This is not unreasonable as a

short term description of a floating exchange rate.

Given this, we have that b∗ = −f . We also know that B = −B∗ −Bg. If

we substitute this into (11.59) we can solve for the condition of δF g

δε> 0 by

solving

f (−B∗ −Bg) + (1 + f)B∗ > 0. (7.28)

We obtainB∗

Bg> f. (7.29)

5This is equivalent to assuming that demand for domestic currency rise as domesticcurrency get cheaper, an assumption we used when drawing supply and demand for foreignexchange in previous lectures.

206

Page 210: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

We also know that B∗ = −fP ∗W ∗ε, from which we obtain

P ∗W ∗ε

Bg< −1. (7.30)

Bg is domestic currency issued by the central bank. As money is a liability

on the government, it must be assumed to be a negative number. (7.30) will

be equivalent toP ∗W ∗ε

−Bg> 1. (7.31)

P ∗W ∗ε is foreign wealth denominated in domestic currency. Bg is domestic

currency issued by the domestic central bank. This will be a proxy for the

size of the domestic economy.

The implication is as follows: as long as foreign wealth is larger than the

domestic economy, δF g

δε> 0. In other words, if the foreign economy exceeds

the local economy, a reasonable assumption for most countries, the foreign

reserves will increase with a higher (weaker) exchange rate. However, note

that the slope of the line will depend on the ratio of foreign wealth to the

domestic economy. The smaller the domestic economy, the steeper the slope.

The intuition might be as follows: if the foreign currency reserves of the

domestic central bank increases, the holdings of domestic currency among

private domestic and foreign residents must increase. That follows from the

asset sheet of the central bank. Foreigners will hold more domestic currency if

this asset becomes cheaper—if it depreciates. Locals will retain more of their

earnings in domestic currency if it becomes more valuable—if it appreciates.

If both groups are equally large, the price of the currency need not adjust for

the market to absorb the increased supply of domestic currency. However, if

foreigners are the largest group, the price must depreciate. If locals are the

largest group, the price must appreciate, and the line will have downward

slope.

207

Page 211: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 7.1: Supply of foreign currency to the central bank and the exchangeratee

Fg

Monetary policy,fixed rate

Monetary policy,floating rate

Supply of foreigncurrency to thecentral bank

208

Page 212: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

What can we bring of this? A reasonable question is how the holdings of

F ∗ is affected by a shift in f . If we retain the assumption of σep = σep∗ = 0,

we can rewrite equation (11.57) as

F g = −fPW

ε− (1 + f)P ∗W ∗. (7.32)

Maximising with regard to f we then obtain that

δF g

δf= −PW

ε− P ∗W ∗ < 0. (7.33)

An increase in f will shift F g inwards in the diagram in figure 7.1. A fall in

f will shift F g out in the diagram in figure 7.1. If the central bank holds the

foreign currency reserves fixed, the central bank supply function is a vertical

line. Note that this gives an interesting application if we compare a small

country with a large country. In a small country the line is expected to be

steep. In a large country is almost horisontal. An implication will be that a

similar shift in f will cause quite different effects depending on whether we

are in a large country or a small country. In a small country the exchange

must adjust much more to balance the market than what is the case in a

large country. In previous lectures we have discussed the fact that small

countries and developing countries have tended to be sceptical to a freely

floating exchange rate. This might give an additional explanation of this

fact. In a country with a small economy small shifts in investor sentiment

might cause much larger impact on the exchange rate than what is the case

in rich and large countries.

A current account surplus

A current account surplus is the same as a shift in wealth from foreigners

to domestic private residents. A transfer of wealth shall not affect the spec-

209

Page 213: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 7.2: Implications for how much the exchange rate much change toclear the market if f change—small vs. large country

e

Fg

Fall in ”f”

Large/rich country

Small/poor country

Effect, large/richcountry

Effect, small/poorcountry

ulative portfolio, only the minimum-variance portfolio. A positive current

account will increase the central banks holding of foreign currency if the

share of foreign currency is higher in the minimum variance portfolio of for-

eigners than of domestic residents, i.e. that there is home bias in currency

preferences. Mathematically speaking this can be expressed as

1 +σep∗

σee

>σep

σee

. (7.34)

This seems like a fairly reasonable assumption, not least given the empirical

numbers reported above. A country with a positive current account, like Nor-

way, will accumulate foreign reserves. However, countries with substantial

negative current accounts shall, according to this rule, lose foreign reserves.

In our figure a current account surplus should lead to and outward shift

in F g. In a floating exchange rate regime a current account surplus should

lead to an appreciation of the domestic currency. However, as in the above

210

Page 214: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

examples, the effect will depend on the relative size of the economy. A current

account surplus or deficit will presumably have less effect on the exchange

rate in a large countries like the US or Japan, than in small countries, like

Norway or Sweden.

One should note the following special case. If the PPP holds, we have

that σep∗ = −σp∗p∗ , σep = σpp and σee = σp∗p∗ + σpp. This would imply that

1 +σep∗

σee

=σep

σee

, (7.35)

asσp∗p∗ + σpp

σp∗p∗ + σpp

− σp∗p∗

σp∗p∗ + σpp

=σpp

σp∗p∗ + σpp

. (7.36)

When the PPP holds, the minimum-variance portfolio share should depend

only on the difference in inflation volatility between the two countries. Devi-

ations from the PPP create a preference for the domestic currency. Current

account movements make no difference.

To understand the full effect on the government’s position one needs to

include government debt. If a country has a current account deficit there

will a drain of foreign reserves from the central bank. If it in addition has

a fiscal deficit it needs to finance this by issuing new debt. However, there

is no demand for domestic currency. So debt cannot be financed through

domestic currency bonds. The government has two choices:

• either it reduces foreign reserves, or

• it must borrow in foreign currency.

The first possibility is a short term solution. The second option might be

extremely expensive. A developing country with both substantial debts and

a current account deficit is not seen a especially creditworthy. If foreigners

211

Page 215: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

doubt the long term prospects of the country, the demand for debt might

dry up.

Many developing countries are not able to finance their debt in long term

contracts. Much of the debt is short term. This implies that developing

countries are in the market for new loans not just to pay for a current deficit,

but also to refinance previous debts. If the borrowing possibilities in world

markets dry up, the country has to choose between depletion of the foreign

reserves or asking for a moratorium, i.e. a default on the foreign debt. This is

the story we see in countries like Russia in 1998, Brazil in 1999 and Argentina

in 2002.

Equilibrium risk premium

Let us restate equation (7.25) as

F g = −fM

(PW

ε

)− (1− b∗M) (P ∗W ∗) +

r

Rσee

(PW

ε+ P ∗W ∗

). (7.37)

If we solve for the risk premium, r, we obtain

r = Rσee

[fMPW + (1− b∗M)εP ∗W ∗

PW + εP ∗W ∗ − −εF g

PW + εP ∗W ∗

](7.38)

Note that as F g = −F − F ∗, the last term can be written as

−εF g

PW + εP ∗W ∗ =ε(F + F ∗

PW + εP ∗W ∗ . (7.39)

This is the share of foreign currency of total wealth held by private domestic

and foreign residents. Let us define this as f . As one can just hold two

assets, the share of total wealth held in domestic currency, b, must be

f = 1− b. (7.40)

212

Page 216: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The termfMPW + (1− b∗M)εP ∗W ∗

PW + εP ∗W ∗ (7.41)

gives the share of the minimum-variance portfolio of foreign currency of total

wealth. This tells us how much foreign currency investors will hold just to

minimise risk. Let us define this share as fM . Using the same argument as

above, we must have that

fM = 1− bM . (7.42)

This implies that we can simplify equation (7.38) to

r = Rσee

(b− bM

). (7.43)

We see that the risk premium is a product of three factors: R, σee and(fM − f

). Risk premium will be high if risk aversion or exchange rate volatil-

ity are high. This is a result of low capital mobility.(b− bM

)tells us to which

extent investors are taking more exchange rate risk in the domestic currency

than the minimum that would optimise their portfolio. If “excessive risk”

goes up, the risk premium increases. b > bM implies that the market is “over-

supplied” with domestic currency, so the risk premium must be positive to

make supply meet demand.

This is an equilibrium condition. We have previously defined r as

r = i− i∗ − ·e. (7.44)

Interest rates and the expected depreciation must adjust to assure that equa-

tion (7.43) holds.

213

Page 217: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

7.3 The collapse of a currency board

In previous lectures we have discussed the role of currency boards. A currency

board is an institution that guarantees to exchange the domestic currency in a

foreign currency at a given parity. The board is supposed to control an mount

of foreign currency that at least equals the amount of domestic currency in

circulation. On paper a currency board should be a fully credible institution

if the rules are followed. The risk of depreciation should be zero. If the UIP

holds there should be no risk premium on the country with the currency

board. However, when we discussed the case of Argentina in Lecture 3 we

found that (i − i∗) > 0 for the whole period since the currency board was

imposed in 1991.

7.3.1 Risk premium and the need for capital

In Argentina the trust of the government has been low for a long time. Even

with a currency board, it was reasonable to keep much of private holdings

in foreign currency. Foreigners would probably only place their money in

Argentina if it was for speculative purposes. So bM was probably low.

However, Argentina is a developing country with need for capital invest-

ments. There was need for b > bM to fulfill these needs. If this conditions

was to be satisfied, the equilibrium risk premium had to be positive. Both

Argentineans and foreigners would take advantage of this risk premium. As a

result Argentines held a negative speculative portfolio of foreign currency—

they borrowed money abroad and invested them in ARP assets.

7.3.2 Risk premium and expected depreciation

We need to give a short comment on the risk premium at this point. Expected

depreciation is not an easy term to handle. Even if domestic interest rates

214

Page 218: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

are higher than foreign interest rates, the risk premium might be zero or

negative if expected depreciation exceeds the interest rate spread.

This makes it important to distinguish between risk premium at differ-

ent time horizons. In most fixed exchange rate regimes it is only a small

probability that a devaluation will take place tomorrow. The probability of

a devaluation over the time frame of one week, or even one month is still rel-

atively small. However, the longer the time span, the higher the probability

of an adjustment within that time span.6

In the case of Argentina, it was clear that the commitment to the currency

board was strong. The chance of a devaluation over night was considered

small. So if iARP > iUSD we should expect the short term risk premium in

Argentinean pesos to be positive. However, few believed the currency board

would exist for ever. So for long term investments the risk premium was

probably much smaller.

Note one implication for short term vs. long term capital flows: if we

believe the above argument, the risk premium tend to be higher in the short

run than in the long run in a fixed exchange rate regime. This encourages

the stream of short term capital over long term capital. A floating exchange

rate might increase the risk of adjustments in the exchange rate in the short

term. This will discourage short term flows.

One often assume that a country wants to attract long term capital. Long

term capital tends to be invested in firms with a long term horizon. This

might have give more utility for the home country than short term capital

flows. It is not clear whether expected depreciation over the long term will

be higher in a fixed or a floating exchange rate regime. If fundamentals are

important in the long run, it probably should make no difference. However,

6This is the same argument as is applied in the “Peso problem” discussed in Lecture 6.

215

Page 219: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

fixed exchange rate regimes often break down during periods of speculative

attacks. Speculative attacks tend to increase macroeconomic uncertainty for

some period of time. It might actually be that a fixed exchange rate regime

will discourage long term flows.

7.3.3 Effects of a fall in risk premiums

So what made the situation in Argentina unstable? Notice that if doubts are

created about the currency board, two things happen simultaneously:

1. Expected r will fall as expected depreciation,·e rises.

2. σee rises as uncertainty rises.

It was clear that the competitiveness of Argentina had been eroded over a

long time. This was due to two factors:

• the USD was appreciating compared to other currencies. As a result

the ARP was appreciating compared to other currencies. In addition, a

Brazilian devaluation in 1999 had further worsened the competitiveness

of Argentine exporters.

• The fiscal deficit of Argentina created uncertainty about the long term

viability of the regime.

One option was to change the parity of the board. But the Argentine govern-

ment repeatedly stated that the currency board would not be fiddled with.

However, in the middle of 2001 the Minister of Fiance, Domingo Cavallo,

openly suggested that leaving the currency board was an option.

Over night, the argument for taking speculative positions in the ARP

vanished. One held ARP because the risk premium was high. The risk

premium was high because one believed the currency board to be credible.

216

Page 220: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

In the new situation everyone wanted to re-balance their portfolios with less

risk in ARP and more risk in USD.

Everyone went to the bank to exchange currency holdings of ARP into

USD. At the same time they wanted to close their ARP deposits. Remember

that people had loans denominated in USD and deposits denominated in

ARP.

According to the rules of a currency board, the board should be able to

redeem every currency note in circulation at parity. However, in this case

the currency in circulation was increasing fast, as everyone were withdrawing

deposits in exchange for currency. So possible demands on the currency board

far exceeded the amount of USD actually held by the board.

Further, the banking system was on the verge of collapse. The banks had

most of their assets in the form of long term USD loans. They did not have

sufficient reserves in ARP to cover all ARP deposits. The banks were not

able to redeem their holdings of ARP since they did not have the money in

their vaults. In this case the speculative attack on the currency was at the

same time a speculative attack on the banking system.

The government had two choices:

1. They could devalue over night. However, as most Argentineans had

loans in USD, and the cost of these loans would increase dramatically

if the currency collapsed, this option would certainly lead to immediate

social unrest. Indeed the government probably hoped they could retain

the currency board.

2. They could restrict the currency in circulation. The way of doing so was

to restrict the amount one could withdraw from the banks. The hope

was that this could give the government time to restore credibility. If

the amount of currency in circulation was restricted, it was possible to

217

Page 221: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

redeem the currency that was in circulation into USD, thereby showing

that the system worked. At the same time one avoided a collapse of

the banking system. The problem was that this system was both unfair

and very problematic.

(a) It was unfair because they who had redeemed their money before

the restrictions now seemed to get a better deal—they could ex-

change their money at parity. Those who had trusted the system

got screwed.

(b) As we all know, most of us depend on the possibility to take

money out of our accounts every week if we shall be able to pay

our bills. Over night this possibility was restricted. Many middle-

class Argentineans found themselves in grave liquidity problems.

On top of this the Argentinean government needed to borrow money.

Argentina had both a fiscal and a current account deficit. Foreigners were

of course doubtful about the long term prospects of Argentinean debt, not

least because the country was asking for a moratorium on existing debt. The

Argentinean government had to borrow at home. But nobody wanted to hold

domestic currency. The only way to solve the problem was to force people to

hold government debt. State wages were paid in government bonds. State

debts were paid in government bonds.

This further undermined the credibility of the system. On the one side the

government tried to reduce the amount of ARP in circulation to strengthen

the credibility of the currency board. On the other side they issued something

looking very much like new money in everything but the name. Argentina

became a country with many currencies. State bonds were used as means

of payment, although they were accepted to much under their face value.

218

Page 222: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Argentina was de facto experiencing inflation out of control.

The system could not work over time. People went on the streets de-

manding their money. The currency board was abolished, and the ARP

depreciated with about 50 per cent against the USD. To sweeten the pill

people were allowed to exchange their USD loans in Argentinean banks into

ARP loans at the old parity, at an unidentified cost to the government. Ar-

gentina declared that they were unable to repay foreign debts. The country

went into a state of total disarray from which it has yet, as of May 2002, to

emerge.

7.4 Empirical applications of the portfolio choice

model

There are two main problems if we want to test the above theory.

1. We have made very simplistic assumptions of monetary policy. The

most reasonable would be to assume a central bank reaction function

that was neither horisontal nor vertical, but downward sloping. The

actual slope is probably difficult to identify.

2. In practice we can observe the flow of private, government and domestic

holdings of foreign currency. However, we can not observe the stocks

involved. In the science of accounting it is by no means certain that

flows and stocks are compatible. However, one can perhaps argue that

observing flows might be sufficient if the focus of the analysis is on the

change in the exchange rate—not the level of the exchange rate.

One of the results above was that one should expect portfolio shifts to

have more impact in small than in large countries. One implication might

219

Page 223: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

be that small floating currencies are more volatile than large floating cur-

rencies. That is not an obvious result from empirical data. Testing equality

of variance in daily returns on EUR/USD, SEK/USD and NOK/USD from

01/01-1999 to 04/01-2002 we find that there is no difference in the vari-

ance when we compare EUR/USD and SEK/USD. However, the variance in

NOK/USD is significantly lower than for the two other exchange rates.

It is very difficult to evaluate whether this is a result of our theory being

wrong, or if the Norwegian and Swedish governments make a stronger effort

to sterilise the effects of changes in currency flows on the currency than the

Federal Reserve does. This might be the case even though both Norway

and Sweden claim to have a freely floating exchange rate. Norway provides

an interesting example. Although there has been no “intervention” since

the beginning of 1999, Norges Bank is continuously active in the market,

accumulating foreign exchange that is invested in the government controlled

“Petroleum Fund”. It is hard to identify the actual effects on the exchange

rate from these activities. Likewise, we observe that Svenska Riksbanken is

de facto accumulating reserves in periods of current account surplus. Is this

just a random event, or the results of a conscious strategy?

7.5 Appendix

7.5.1 Mean-variance vs. state-preference

The mean-variance approach will match the state-preference utility maximi-

sation if:

1. Preferences are time separable—the utility of consumption in the next

period does not depend on the current level of consumption.

2. The relative risk aversion is constant over time.

220

Page 224: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 7.3: ARP/USD exchange rate 1998-2002

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

01.0

1.98

01.0

3.98

01.0

5.98

01.0

7.98

01.0

9.98

01.1

1.98

01.0

1.99

01.0

3.99

01.0

5.99

01.0

7.99

01.0

9.99

01.1

1.99

01.0

1.00

01.0

3.00

01.0

5.00

01.0

7.00

01.0

9.00

01.1

1.00

01.0

1.01

01.0

3.01

01.0

5.01

01.0

7.01

01.0

9.01

01.1

1.01

01.0

1.02

01.0

3.02

01.0

5.02

3. Both the price level, P , and the exchange rate, ε, follow Wiener pro-

cesses, or Brownian motions. This implies that that level of return in

the two variables,·p and

·e, are normally distributed and independent

over time.

4. Expectations, variances and covariances are constant over time.

7.5.2 The exchange rate

The most simplistic way to write equation (7.25) will be

F g = −f

(PW

ε

)− (1− b∗) (P ∗W ∗) . (7.45)

If we solve this for the exchange rate we obtain

ε =−fPW

F g + (1− b∗)P ∗W ∗ . (7.46)

221

Page 225: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

In previous lectures we have stated that in a floating exchange rate regime

the central bank will hold no foreign reserves. We simplify by setting F g = 0.

We then obtain

ε =−f

(1− b∗)

W

W ∗P

P ∗ . (7.47)

Remember that the PPP states that the exchange rate is given as

ε =P

P ∗ . (7.48)

In this framework one ratio will differentiate the exchange rate from the PPP

rate: the ratio of nominal wealth held in the foreign currency unit. If this

fraction is shifting over time, we should expect to see the nominal exchange

rate changing, and we should also expect a correlation between the real and

the nominal exchange rate.

222

Page 226: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 8

The real exchange rate and

capital flows

8.1 Some notes on research strategy

Modern macroeconomics is built on analysing the maximising behavior of

agents in a general equilibrium multi period setting. Although this research

has been going on for some time—the book of Obstfeld and Rogoff from 1996

is probably the best summary of this kind of analysis in an open economy

framework—many questions remain unsolved. However, interesting ques-

tions can now be analysed in such a framework. Not least, this framework

allows to discuss questions in a more dynamic setting than what is possible

in the traditional models, like the Swan diagram or the Mundell-Fleming

model.

8.2 Some empirical observations

We remember that the real exchange rate, Q is defined as

Q = εP ∗

P. (8.1)

223

Page 227: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 8.1: The real exchange rate. DEM/USD

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2

jul.7

3

jul.7

4

jul.7

5

jul.7

6

jul.7

7

jul.7

8

jul.7

9

jul.8

0

jul.8

1

jul.8

2

jul.8

3

jul.8

4

jul.8

5

jul.8

6

jul.8

7

jul.8

8

jul.8

9

jul.9

0

jul.9

1

jul.9

2

jul.9

3

jul.9

4

jul.9

5

jul.9

6

jul.9

7

jul.9

8

Real exchange rate calculated using CPI.

A central assumption in the monetary equilibrium model was the purchasing

power parity—the belief that arbitrage would assure that the real exchange

rate is constant over time. However, if we use the consumer price index as a

proxy for the price level, and calculate the real exchange rate, we find that

for most countries this is certainly not constant. Two examples are given in

figures 8.1 and 8.2.

Using the CPI for such measurement is not unproblematic. The weights

of goods in the CPI will differ between countries, and they will change over

time. Relative prices will change with changes in tariffs or taxes. However,

the findings illustrated in figures 8.1 and 8.2 are fairly representative for

the results reported in numerous empirical studies of the PPP. For countries

at about the same level of productivity, the PPP seems to hold over time,

although the real exchange rate tends to move in long swings, with a mean

reversion of about 3-6 years. The length of this cycle has been described

224

Page 228: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 8.2: The real exchange rate. JPY/USD

0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1

1.2

jul.7

3

jul.7

4

jul.7

5

jul.7

6

jul.7

7

jul.7

8

jul.7

9

jul.8

0

jul.8

1

jul.8

2

jul.8

3

jul.8

4

jul.8

5

jul.8

6

jul.8

7

jul.8

8

jul.8

9

jul.9

0

jul.9

1

jul.9

2

jul.9

3

jul.9

4

jul.9

5

jul.9

6

jul.9

7

jul.9

8

jul.9

9

jul.0

0

jul.0

1

Real exchange rate calculated using CPI.

as a “puzzle”, given that the most reasonable explanation for swings in the

real exchange rate, sticky prices, should imply a mean reversion of about 1

year—in other words much faster than what is observed.

For countries with more marked differences in technical development the

PPP does not seem to hold. A general result is that countries with high

economic growth tend to experience real appreciation over time. This is

clearly illustrated in the case of Japan in figure 8.2.

8.2.1 Differences in the price level

Implicit in the assumption of purchasing power parity is the assumption that

over time the ratio of price levels will be one if measured in the same exchange

rate, i.e. ε = PP ∗ . The implication is that the price level should be the same

across countries.

Price levels are very difficult to measure. The standard measure of prices

225

Page 229: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

published by statistical bureaus is the consumer price index, the CPI. How-

ever, the CPI does not measure the price level, only relative change in the

cost of a basket of consumption goods. The best measure of actual price lev-

els is provided in the Penn World Tables, where prominent economists have

done empirical estimates of the relative price of comparable goods baskets

for a number of countries. These tables are only available with a lag of many

years—the most recent numbers are from the mid-1990’s.

However, what is clear from these data is that the price level is not the

same across countries. In general one finds that the price level is much higher

in countries with high income per capita. An interesting test of this result

can be found if we compare the numbers in the renown “Big Mac index”

published by The Economist in the end of April every year. The Economist

collects the price of a Big Mac sold by MacDonalds in a number of countries.

It calculates the price in USD at the current exchange rate. If absolute PPP

holds, the price of one Big Mac should be the same as in the US.

Of course, there are a number of problems using a Big Mac as an indicator

of the price level. This is one very specific good, not very representative of

“normal” consumption. One the other hand it is a very standardised good.

We are in fact pretty certain that we compare identical items across boarders.

The item contains both tradable parts, like beef and bread, and non-tradable

parts, like labour input.

Table 8.1 gives the price of a Big Mac measured in USD for seven different

countries. We can summarise some stylised facts from the table:

• The price is clearly much higher in the five industrialised countries than

in China and Russia.

• The prices are fluctuating over time.

226

Page 230: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

• With the exception of Russia the price has moved towards the US price

from 1995 to 2002. This might be an indication that price levels over

time tend to converge.

Table 8.1 also illustrates how difficult it is to compare welfare when we

compare gross domestic product per capita using the nominal exchange rate.

If a Norwegian earn 30,000 USD a year, he can purchase 7,300 Big Macs...

However, in China, a wage of only USD 9300 will suffice to get the same

amount of food. To get a true picture of the purchasing power in Norway

and China income per capita must be adjusted for differences in price levels.

These are so-called PPP-adjusted per capita output numbers. Table 8.1 gives

a very simplified shoot at such estimates. Of course, one should be cautious

when interpreting such numbers.1 However, the table clearly illustrates that

output per capita measured in actual exchange rates is not a good measure

of the welfare of nations. Norway might be one of the richest countries in

the world. That does not necessarily imply that Norwegians are the people

best of—in fact purchasing power of Norwegians is (at best) in line with the

purchasing power of other Western European countries.

8.3 Accounting for what we do not know about

the real exchange rate

The data does not match with the assumptions used in previous lectures.

To understand what we do not understand, it can be useful to make a short

1E.g. the GNI numbers and the Big Mac prices are not transferred into USD at thesame exchange rate. The GNI numbers use the World Bank method of the average rateover three years (in this case 1999, 2000 and 2001), and adjust for inflation differences tothe the average of the inflation level in the G5 countries (USA, Japan, Germany, Franceand Great Britain). The Big Mac price is calculated in USD at the spot exchange rate asof April 2002. This probably leads to an overestimation of the “welfare” in Japan, and anunderestimation of the “welfare” in Europe compared to the US.

227

Page 231: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Tab

le8.

1:P

rice

leve

lsan

dw

elfa

re.

Rel

ativ

eprice

leve

lm

easu

red

aspri

ceof

aB

igM

acin

1995

and

2002

1995

2002

Rat

ioG

NI

per

capi

taRat

ioto

US

PPP

adj.

GN

Ipe

rca

pita

Rat

ioto

US

Nor

way

n.a

.4.

090.

6133

650

0.98

2048

60.

60Switze

rlan

d5.

203.

810.

6538

120

1.11

2491

30.

73U

SA

2.32

2.49

1.00

3426

01.

0034

260

1.00

Ger

man

y3.

482.

371.

0525

050

0.73

2631

80.

77Jap

an4.

652.

011.

2434

210

1.00

4238

01.

24Chi

na

1.05

1.27

1.96

840

0.02

1647

0.05

Russ

ia1.

621.

251.

9916

600.

0533

070.

10T

he

firs

ttw

oco

lum

ns

giv

eth

eth

epri

ceof

aB

igM

ac

inse

ven

diff

eren

tco

untr

ies.

Mea

sure

din

USD

at

curr

ent

mark

etex

change

rate

.Ratio

isth

eco

untr

ypri

cepri

cere

lative

toth

eU

S.

GN

Iper

capita

isnum

ber

sfo

r2000,

mea

sure

dat

the

“A

tlas

met

hod”,

ath

ree

yea

raver

age

exch

ange

rate

.T

he

PP

Padju

sted

GN

Iper

capit

ais

the

GN

Iadju

sted

wit

hth

ere

lative

cost

ofB

igM

ac

in2002.

Sourc

es:

The

Eco

nom

ist

and

The

Worl

dB

ank.

228

Page 232: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

summary.

First, let us restate the covered interest rate parity, a parity we know will

hold with certainty. The CIP can be written as

et = i∗t,T − it,T + ft,T . (8.2)

when we it,T is the interest rate over the period from t to T . Further, we

can define the premium for bearing exchange rate risk—taking the chance on

buying the exchange rate spot at time T instead of securing the price today

by buying the exchange rate forward to ft,T —as the risk premium, r, which

can be defined as

rt,T = ft,T − Et(eT ). (8.3)

If we substitute (8.2) into (8.3) we obtain

et = i∗t,T − it,T + rt,T + Et(eT ). (8.4)

Let us define the real interest rate, ir, as

irt,T = it,T − (Et(pT )− pt). (8.5)

If we substitute (8.5) into (8.4) we obtain

et = (ir∗t,T + Et(p∗T )− p∗t )− (irt,T + Et(pT )− pt) + rt,T + Et(eT ). (8.6)

The real exchange rate, q, is defined as

qt = et + (p∗t − pt). (8.7)

Reordering, and using (8.7) we obtain

qt =(ir∗t,T − irt,T

)+ rt,T + Et(qT ). (8.8)

229

Page 233: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The real exchange rate is given as the real interest differential, the expected

risk premium and the expected future real interest rate. In theory this should

be valid for any choice of T , but generally q is assumed to move towards some

equilibrium value over time, so the equation is probably most interesting

when analyzed over some time horizon.

But what does this actually tell us? Variability in the real exchange rate

can be transmitted through three channels:

• variability in the real interest differential,

• variability in the risk premium, and

• variability in the expected real exchange rate.

Empirical evidence suggests that the real interest rate does not explain much

of the variability in the real exchange rate. This leaves us with the risk

premium and the expected real exchange rate.

The effects of variability in the risk premium was discussed in lecture 8.

In general risk premiums will be of most interest if we assume that there are

some kind of imperfect substitution between holding domestic versus holding

foreign assets. As we saw, such differences might explain substantial swings

in capital flows.

In this lecture we will focus on the variability in the expected real ex-

change rate. Analysis of the expected real exchange rate must be seen to-

gether with the concept of “external balance” in the economy.

8.3.1 External balance

Defining external balance is not obvious. In more classic models, like the

Swan-diagram that analysis the relationship between “internal” and exter-

nal balance, external balance is a balanced current account, and and internal

230

Page 234: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

balance is an unemployment rate equal to the long term non-inflation accel-

erating rate of inflation (NAIRU). However, external balance need not mean

a balanced current account in a dynamic framework; at least not in the short

or medium term.

External balance will generally be achieved if the current account is con-

sistent with “desired capital flows”. But what is “desired capital flows”?

First note that if the economy is in “equilibrium”—population is sta-

ble and capital intensity is according to the “golden rule” and there is no

unexpected changes, just to mention three requirements—then the current

account probably should be zero. These are not realistic assumptions. Dif-

ferent measures will affect long term prospects:

• If there is any sort of “consumption smoothing” in the economy, it will

be optimal to try to spread the effects of shocks between periods. If

there is a negative shock today, and we expect this to be temporary,

we would borrow today to smooth the consumption pattern. However,

on the national level borrowing is reflected as a current account deficit.

• “Structural shocks”: if a country finds e.g. natural resources, the struc-

ture of the economy must be expected to change to take advantage of

these opportunities. Very simplified such an economy can be expected

to venture through three periods:

1. An investment period, where income from production is low, and

costs are high.

2. A period of collecting rent from the resource.

3. A period of restructuring, as the fields are emptied.

From beginning to end the current account should accumulate to zero.

However, over the time from the source is found until it has been fully

231

Page 235: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

extracted, we should expect the current account to be negative in the

initial period, positive in the producing period, and negative again as

saved income is used to build new industries.

• Imbalances in demographic developments should probably be reflected

in long periods with a current account different from zero, without this

reflecting an imbalance in the economy. E.g. the USA has a demo-

graphic profile very different from other developed nations, a fact that

can probably explain much of the US current account deficit. Most

developed countries must save to finance the increase of pensioners

relative to the working part of the population. The US will not expe-

rience this for many years, and can therefore for the time being focus

on investments instead of saving.

In fact, modern economics is still searching for models that can describe the

external balance over time. It is clear that our current knowledge does not

give a full description of how we should expect the current account to behave

in a dynamic framework. This also affects our ability to understand the real

exchange rate.

8.4 Explaining long term shifts in the real ex-

change rate

Note: section 4 is not required reading in GTA1333/6607. You should how-

ever be familiar with the main conclusions, as summarised in De Grauwe, ch.

5.3.

When we looked at figures 8.1 and 8.2 we saw that the behaviour of the

real exchange rate seemed to differ quite markedly in the case of DEM/USD

232

Page 236: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

and JPY/USD. In the first case the real exchange rate was fluctuating around

1. In the second case, we clearly see a consistent downward trend.

The assumption of PPP builds on the law of one price, that states that

the price of a good that is traded between countries should be equal between

countries, give or take transportation costs between the two destinations. If

the law of one price, arbitrage should increase demand where the good is

expensive, and reduce supply where the good is cheap. However, empirical

analysis only find support for the law of one price in the case of storable,

highly traded goods, like corn, metals and oil. For most goods the law of one

price does not hold. Possible causes might be

• transportation costs,

• trade barriers, and

• non-competitive market structure.

For some goods transportation costs are so high that they are hardly

traded at all. These are non-tradable goods. One should not forget that

all goods sold will have contents that are not tradable across boarders, like

the cost of handling in the import country. The role of non-traded goods

is important if we want to understand structural shifts in the real exchange

rate.

8.4.1 The Balassa-Samuelson effect

The Balassa-Samuelson effect is an attempt to explain why poor countries

tend to experience real appreciation. The building block is that countries

with higher productivity in tradables compared with non-tradables tend to

have a higher price level. High growth is accomplished through high growth

in tradables. As productivity in the traded sector rise, the wage level in

233

Page 237: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

this sector rises. However, if there are inter-sector labour mobility, this will

cause a rise in the wage level in the sector producing non-traded goods. To

compensate increased wage levels at a constant productivity, the price of

non-traded goods must rise. It follows that countries with high growth will

experience a rise in the price level, and thereby a real appreciation.

The price level in a two sector economy

The driving force in the following results will be our assumptions about the

movement of capital and labour. We assume that capital can move freely

between countries. We look at a small country. This assures that the real

interest rate, here denoted as i, will be the at home and abroad. The interest

rate is given exogenously. Labour is not mobile between countries. However,

it is assumed to be freely mobile between sectors in the economy. As a result

the average wage level, w, will be the same in all sectors.2 This is only

a realistic assumption if we look at the economy over time—this must be

perceived as a description of long term price adjustments.

The exogenous interest rate and the equalisation of the wage level between

sectors give the domestic economy a certain flexibility to meet shocks to

demand and supply. An increase in domestic demand should increase the

price level of non-traded goods. However, at the same time, an increase in

demand should lead to more capital and labour employed in the non-traded

sector. It can be shown that our assumptions of capital and labour mobility

is enough to assure shocks to domestic demand will not affect the relative

price of non-traded goods in this economy.

Note that we focus on the real effects to the real exchange rate. This

implies that we disregard money. All prices will be measured relative to the

2The way to think about this is that two persons with the same education and back-ground will receive the same wage in both sectors.

234

Page 238: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

price of a traded industrial good, Pi, a price we set equal to 1. This implies

that in the following analysis we assume

• no nominal rigidities,

• no feedback from money, and

• no risk premium.

These assumptions are not credible in the short term. This implies that the

models are best fitted to explain medium or long term movements in the real

exchange rate.

The economy has two sectors. The traded sector is producing two goods,

industrial goods and a natural resource, e.g. oil. The price of industrial

goods is set to 1. We assume that extraction of oil returns a rent of τ in

excess to the price of industrial goods. The amount of oil produced make

up a share γ of total production of industrial goods. We then have that the

average income from one good sold in the traded sector must be

(1− γ) · 1 + γ(1 + τ) = 1 + γτ . (8.9)

The price of non traded goods is measured in quantities of industrial goods.

The price is set to Pd.

The production function of the traded sector is given as AtF (Kt, Lt),

where At is the level of productivity in the traded sector, Kt is the level of

capital stock, and Lt is the labour employed in this sector. The production

function in the non-traded sector is AdG(Kd, Ld), where d denotes the non-

traded sector. Both production functions have constant returns to scale.

Total supply of labour, L, must be the labour employed in the traded and

non-traded sector combined, L = Lt +Ld. There is no unemployment in this

economy, and prices are fully flexible.

235

Page 239: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Over time excess profit must be zero in both sectors. This gives us two

equilibrium conditions. For the traded sector we must have that

∞∑s=t

(1

1 + is

)[(1 + γsτ s)At,sF (Kt,s, Lt,s)− wsLt,s − isKt,s] = 0. (8.10)

For the non-traded sector we must have that

∞∑s=t

(1

1 + is

)[(Pd,sAd,sG(Kd,s, Ld,s)− wsLd,s − isKd,s] = 0. (8.11)

If there are no unexpected shocks, these conditions are expected to hold

in every period. Under this assumption we can remove the time notation,

and state that

(1 + γτ)AtF (Kt, Lt)− wLt − iKt = 0, (8.12)

and

PdAdG(Kd, Ld)− wLd − iKd = 0. (8.13)

In macroeconomics we often state output as a fraction of employment.

Let us define capital per employee in the traded sector as

kt =Kt

Lt

. (8.14)

As the production function has constant returns to scale, we have that

F (Kt, Lt) = LtF

(Kt

Lt

,Lt

Lt

)= Ltf(kt). (8.15)

Likewise, we have that

kd =Kd

Ld

, (8.16)

and

G(Kd, Ld) = LdG

(Kd

Ld

,Ld

Ld

)= Ldg(kd). (8.17)

236

Page 240: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

We can no restate equations (8.12) and (8.13) as

(1 + γτ)Atf(kt)− w − ikt = 0, (8.18)

and

PdAdg(kd)− w − ikd = 0. (8.19)

These are equilibrium conditions. But what happens if there is a marginal

change in one of the variables? If we take the total differential of equation

(8.18) we obtain

τAtf(kt)dγ +(1+γτ)f(kt)dAt +(1+γτ)Atf′(kt)dkt−dw− idkt = 0, (8.20)

As i and τ are given exogenously, so we hold them constant. Note that if you

take the differential of equation (8.10) with regard to Kt you obtain that

(1 + γτ)AtFK(Kt, Lt) = i, (8.21)

where

FK(Kt, Lt) =δF (Kt, Lt)

δKt

. (8.22)

From this we know that

(1 + γτ)Atf′(kt) = i, (8.23)

as

FK(Kt, Lt) = Lt1

Lt

f ′(kt) = f ′(kt). (8.24)

We can then restate equations (8.20) as

τAtf(kt)dγ + (1 + γτ)f(kt)dAt + idkt − dw − idkt = 0. (8.25)

It is easier to interpret this equation if we look at percentage changes. If dx

237

Page 241: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

is the change in x, then dxx

is the percentage change in x. Further we want

to look at percent of total output in the traded sector, (1 + γτ)Atf(kt). If

we divide (8.25) by (1 + γτ)Atf(kt) and rearrange we obtain

γτ

(1 + γτ)

γ+

dAt

At

− w

(1 + γτ)Atf(kt)

dw

w= 0. (8.26)

Let us define labour’s share of total output in the traded sector as

µLt =wLt

(1 + γτ)AtF (Kt, Lt). (8.27)

As (1 + γτ)AtLtf(kt) = (1 + γτ)AtF (Kt, Lt) we can restate equation (8.26)

asγτ

(1 + γτ)

γ+

dAt

At

− wLt

(1 + γτ)AtF (Kt, Lt)

dw

w= 0. (8.28)

Rearranging, we obtain

µLt

dw

w=

γτ

(1 + γτ)

γ+

dAt

At

. (8.29)

If we turn to the non-traded sector, we find that the total differential of

equation (8.19) as

Adg(kd)dPd + Pdg(kd)dAd + PdAdg′(kd)dkd − dw − idkd = 0. (8.30)

We know that

PdAdg′(kd) = i, (8.31)

so (8.30) can be simplified as

Adg(kd)dPd + Pdg(kd)dAd − dw = 0. (8.32)

As above, we can define labour’s share of output in the non-traded sector as

µLd =wLd

PdAdF (Kd, Ld). (8.33)

238

Page 242: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Dividing by total output in the non-traded sector, and rearranging, we obtain

dPd

Pd

= µLd

dw

w− dAd

Ad

. (8.34)

We have obtained an expression for the price level of non-traded goods.

However, the wage level must be the same in both the traded and the non-

traded sectors. This implies that there must be a relationship between the

two sectors. From equation (8.29) we can obtain an equation for dww

. If we

subsitute this into (8.35) we obtain

dPd

Pd

=µLd

µLt

[γτ

(1 + γτ)

γ+

dAt

At

]− dAd

Ad

. (8.35)

The fraction of labour’s share of output in the non-traded over the traded

sector, µLd

µLt, can be assumed to be bigger than one. In general the non-traded

sector is more labour intensive than the traded sector.

If productivity in traded goods rise while productivity in non-traded

goods remains constant, the price of non-traded goods will rise. We also

see that a higher share of “high rent” products in the traded sector will rise

the price of non-traded goods. The intuition is simple: more high rent prod-

ucts lead to a rise in the wage level in the traded sector. This puts pressure

on the wage level in the non-traded sector, and forces up the price of non-

traded goods. Norway, a country that has experienced a substantial change

in the composition of traded goods over the last 30 years, is a good example.

The increase in the share of high rent products in Norwegian exports have

put pressure on wages in other sectors in the Norwegian economy, raising

Norwegian prices. This is one explanation for the high Norwegian price level

documented in table 8.1. 3

3As noted above, the price level in non-traded goods does not depend on domesticdemand for non-traded goods in this model.

239

Page 243: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

In general one assumes that productivity growth is higher in the traded

than in the non-traded sector. This is the so-called Baumol-Bowen Paradox.

The reasoning is that the non-traded sector is dominated by services. These

are labour intensive, with low capital input per worker. Many examples of

services, like hair cutting, health care or cultural activities, depend on high

input of manual labour. Quality of such services can be made better by

machines, but only to a limited degree.

It is a general assumption that rich countries are rich because of their high

productivity in traded goods. An implication is that rich countries should

be expected to have a higher price level than poor countries. Again, this is

in line with the empirical facts stated above.

The price index and the real exchange rate

The real exchange rate is the ratio of national price levels. In this case the

price level will be the cost of some representative basket of consumption

good. The terms of trade is the ratio of relative prices of exports to the

relative prices of imports. The terms of trade tells us something about the

competitiveness of the national economy.

Let us assume that the price index is made up of traded and non-traded

goods. For simplicity, let us assume that the price of non traded goods is Pd,

and the price of traded goods in local prices is Pt. The weight of non traded

goods is σ, and the weight of traded goods is (1− σ). If we assume that the

price index, P , is made up as geometric average, P is given as

P = P σd P 1−σ

t . (8.36)

For simplicity we assume the relative consumption of traded and non-traded

good to be the same between countries. The foreign price index, P ∗, is then

240

Page 244: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

given as

P ∗ = P ∗σd P

∗(1−σ)t . (8.37)

We assume the exchange rate between the two countries to be fixed at 1:1.

The ratio of home-to-foreign prices become

P

P ∗ =P σ

d

P ∗σd

P 1−σt

P∗(1−σ)t

. (8.38)

However, it is reasonable to assume that the price of traded goods will be the

same—eventual price differences will just be traded away. So we can simplify

equation (8.38) toP

P ∗ =

(Pd

P ∗d

. (8.39)

This has an important implication for the real exchange rate. If we ignore

shocks to the nominal exchange rate, changes in the real exchange rate will

depend on the relative prices of non-traded goods.

If we take the total derivative of equation (8.39) we obtain

σ

[1

P ∗d

dPd +−Pd

P ∗2d

dP ∗d

]σ−1

= 0. (8.40)

If we rearrange, we obtain

σ

[Pd

P ∗d

dPd

Pd

− Pd

P ∗d

dP ∗d

P ∗d

]σ−1

= 0. (8.41)

This can be rewritten as [dPd

Pd

− dP ∗d

P ∗d

]σ−1

= 0. (8.42)

We have already obtained an expression for dPd

Pd. If we substitute in from

241

Page 245: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

equation (8.35) we obtain[(µLd

µLt

[γτ

(1 + γτ)

γ+

dAt

At

]− dAd

Ad

)−

(µ∗Ld

µ∗Lt

[γ∗τ

(1 + γ∗τ)

dγ∗

γ∗+

dA∗t

A∗t

]− dA∗

d

A∗d

)]σ∗−1

= 0.

(8.43)

We make two simplifying assumptions. We focus on differences in produc-

tivity, and assume that γ = 0 for both countries. Further, we assume that

µLt and µLn is the same in both countries. We can then rewrite (8.44) as[µLd

µLt

[dAt

At

− dA∗t

A∗t

]−

(dAd

Ad

− dA∗d

A∗d

)]σ∗−1

= 0. (8.44)

Changes in the real exchange rate will depend on the relative changes in

the traded and non-traded sectors. Countries with relatively higher growth

in the traded sector will experience a real appreciation as the price level of

non-traded goods in these countries increase relative to the price level of

non-traded goods in the other countries.

8.5 Fluctuations in the real exchange rate and

capital flows

The following model is an example of an intertemporal approach to modelling

the real exchange rate. This is a two country-two goods model, assuming that

each country are producing separate goods, and that all goods are traded.

Even in this “simple” framework we can achieve some interesting implica-

tions about how shocks to the economy should be expected to affect the real

exchange rate, and how capital flows and trade patterns might influence the

the movement in the real exchange rate.

242

Page 246: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

8.5.1 Model of two countries and terms of trade shocks

We are in a two-country world, where each country produce a single good.

The home country produces good H, and the foreign country good F . Each

good has the price of unity measured in the local currency. The relative

price of the two goods, which is the same as the real exchange rate, Q, will

be measured as the price of one unit of foreign good denominated in home

currency,

Q =PF

PH

. (8.45)

This is in line with the definition of the exchange rate used in this course.

A higher Q implies a real depreciation, a lower Q a real appreciation, when

seen from the home country.

Total consumption in the home country of good H is CH , and total con-

sumption of good F is CF . Foreign consumption is C∗H and C∗

F . Consumption

of good H, CH and C∗H , is denominated in home currency, and consumption

of good F , CF and C∗F , is denominated in foreign currency. Total production

of the home country is Y = H, and total production of the foreign country

is Y ∗ = F .

The net capital inflow of the home country is B. B will equal the negative

of the current account,

B = −CA, (8.46)

as we have that the capital account=the current account, and a current

account surplus must give a capital outflow. B reflects capital mobility. If

B is zero, there is no capital mobility. Note that there might still be trade.

However, the trade balance must always be zero.

The rate of absorption, A, is the total consumption and investment in

243

Page 247: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

the home country. In standard terms we have that

Y = C + I + G + CA, (8.47)

where C is total consumption, I is investment, and G is government con-

sumption. Absorption is then given by

A = C + I + G. (8.48)

For convenience we set I and G equal to zero. We then see that

A = Y − CA = Y + B. (8.49)

Similarly, we have that

A∗ = Y ∗ + B∗. (8.50)

Notice that

B∗ =−B

Q, (8.51)

as B∗ is measured in foreign currency, and capital inflow in one country

by definition must equal capital outflow in the other, as we have only two

countries.

We make the convenient assumption of Cobb-Douglas utility functions.

That implies that the utility function are given by

U = C1−mH (QCF )m, U∗ =

(C∗

H

Q

)m∗

(C∗F )1−m∗

. (8.52)

where m reflects the share of foreign goods in home consumption, and m∗

is the share of home goods in foreign consumption. Further, it is natural to

assume that

1−m > m∗, (8.53)

244

Page 248: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

which implies that foreigners have a weaker preference for good H than the

residents of the home country themselves.

We now have the two maximisation problems. For the home country we

have

Max U = C1−mH (QCF )m s.t. A = Y + B = CH + QCF , (8.54)

and for the foreign country

Max U∗ =

(C∗

H

Q

)1−m∗

(C∗F )m∗

s.t. A∗ = Y ∗ − B

Q=

C∗H

Q+ C∗

F . (8.55)

To solve these equations, we use a standard Lagrange function:

L = C1−mH (QCF )m + λ (Y + B − CH −QCF ) . (8.56)

The choice variables are CH and CF . We obtain

δL

δCH

= (1−m)C−mH (QCF )m + λ = 0, (8.57)

δL

δCF

= mQm(CF )m−1C1−mH + Qλ = 0, (8.58)

andδL

δλ= Y + B − CH −QCF = 0. (8.59)

Equation (11.81) can be reformulated as

m(QCF )m−1C1−mH + λ = 0. (8.60)

Setting (8.57) equal to (8.60) we obtain

(1−m)C−mH (QCF )m = −λ = m(QCF )m−1C1−m

H , (8.61)

245

Page 249: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

which implies that(1−m)

mQCF = CH . (8.62)

If we insert (8.62) into (8.59) we obtain that

(1−m)

mQCF = Y + B −QCF ⇒ CF = m

Y + B

Q. (8.63)

This gives us a function for home country consumption of the foreign good,

CF . Inserting (11.62) in (8.62) we obtain the function for consumption of

the home produced good,

CH = (1−m)(Y + B). (8.64)

The similar procedure can be applied to the the consumption problem of the

foreign country. We will then find that

C∗H = Qm∗(Y ∗ − B

Q), CF = (1−m∗)(Y ∗ − B

Q). (8.65)

We have now identified the optimal consumption structure for both countries.

Market clearing demands that

CH + C∗H = Y, CF + C∗

F = Y ∗, (8.66)

as total consumption by definition must equal total production. If we insert

(8.64) and (11.66) into (11.70) we get

(1−m)(Y + B) + Qm∗(Y ∗ − B

Q) = Y. (8.67)

Here Y , Y ∗, m and m∗ are assumed to be given exogenously. However, Q

and B must adjust to clear markets. Our main focus is on the real exchange

rate. Taking B as given, we can use (8.67) to calculate the market-clearing

246

Page 250: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

level of the exchange rate as

Q =mY

m∗Y ∗ −(1−m−m∗)B

m∗Y ∗ . (8.68)

The real exchange rate has two parts: one is the result of the relative pref-

erence for the demand of good H as a share of output in the two countries,

and the other is a result of capital flows between the two countries. If cap-

ital flows are zero, the real exchange rate will only be a product of relative

demand for home and foreign goods in the two countries.

It is interesting to look at how Q is affected by changes in Y , Y ∗ and B.

We find thatδQ

δY=

m

m∗Y ∗ > 0. (8.69)

This implies that if there is a positive supply shock to the domestic economy,

the exchange rate will depreciate. A positive supply shock implies that there

is an increase of domestic goods offered in the market—a supply shock here is

by definition an increase in production. The real exchange rate must weaken

to induce increased demand for domestic goods in the foreign country.

We also find that

δQ

δY ∗ = −mY − (1−m−m∗)B

m∗Y ∗1

Y ∗ = − Q

Y ∗ < 0. (8.70)

A positive supply shock in the foreign country will lead to a real appreciation.

This time the exchange rate must adjust to increase demand for foreign goods

in the home country. A real appreciation will increase the purchasing power

of domestic residents.

Last, we have that

δQ

δB= −(1−m−m∗)

m∗Y ∗ < 0. (8.71)

247

Page 251: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The result follows from equation (11.68), as we know that (1−m−m∗) > 0.

The real exchange rate appreciates if there is increased capital inflow to the

home country. An example of such inflows might be increased lending due

to a positive demand shock. Increased lending increases the total amount

available for purchases in the home country. As more of this is used to

purchase domestic goods than foreign goods, the price of domestic goods rise

more than the price of foreign goods, leading to a real appreciation.

However, there will normally be a relationship between a shock to Y or Y ∗

and B. Let us assume that there is a shock θ that affects all three variables.

To analyse the effect of θ we can take the total differential of Q.4 Assume

that Y = Y (θ), Y ∗ = Y ∗(θ) and B = B(θ). The total differential of Q with

regard to θ will then be given by

dQ

dθ=

δQ

δY

dY

dθ+

δQ

δY

dY ∗

dθ+

δQ

δY

dB

dθ. (8.73)

Inserting the results from equations (8.69-8.71) we obtain

dQ

dθ=

m

m∗Y ∗dY

dθ− Q

Y ∗dY ∗

dθ− (1−m−m∗)

m∗Y ∗dB

dθ. (8.74)

We can simplify the notation be setting dQdθ

= ∆Q, dYdθ

= ∆Y , dY ∗

dθ= ∆Y ∗

and dBdθ

= ∆B. Further, we assume that the initial trade balance is zero. This

implies that

m∗Y ∗ =mY

Q, (8.75)

as m∗Y ∗ is the fraction of foreign output denominated in foreign currency

4What is the total differential? Assume that we have a function F = (X(θ), Y (θ)).The differential of X with regard to θ, X ′(θ) = dX

dθ . From the product rule we know that

dF

dθ=

δF

δX

dX

dθ+

δF

δY

dY

dθ. (8.72)

This gives the total differential of F with regard to θ.

248

Page 252: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

that foreigners use to purchase good H. If there is a trade balance this must

equal the fraction of home output used to purchase good F , denominated in

foreign currency, namely mYQ

. Also note that if we assume a trade balance,

we implicitly assume that B = 0 in the initial period.

If we insert (11.69) into (8.74) we obtain

∆Q =Qm

mY∆Y − Q

Y ∗∆Y ∗ − Q(1−m−m∗)

mY∆B. (8.76)

It is easier to interpret changes in ∆QQ

than in ∆Q, as ∆QQ

represent the

percentage change in Q. If we divide (8.76) by Q, we get

∆Q

Q=

∆Y

Y− ∆Y ∗

Y ∗ − (1−m−m∗)

m

∆B

Y. (8.77)

We here have expressed the percentage change in the real exchange rate as a

function of the effect of a relative change in home output, the relative change

in foreign output and the relative change in capital inflow as a percentage of

home output.

Analysing the effect of shocks

Let us discuss some specific cases.

• Assume a symmetric shock to the two countries, and that B is zero.

We see that in this case the real exchange rate will be unaffected.

• Assume that there is a negative shock to home output only, and that

there is no capital mobility. Then the real exchange rate will appreciate

equiproportionate to the change in home output:

∆Q

Q=

∆Y

Y. (8.78)

• Assume that there is full capital mobility, but that the shock to home

249

Page 253: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

output, Y , is perceived to be permanent. It would not be rational to

borrow in the international markets to compensate for a permanent

shock. Optimal behavior would suggest that the most effective way to

behave if the shock is permanent is to adjust absorption immediately

to the new long term sustainable level. This implies a change in the

real exchange rate of∆Q

Q=

∆Y

Y. (8.79)

If there is capital mobility and shocks are perceived to be temporary,

there will be a relationship between ∆B and ∆Y that depends on the rate of

capital mobility and the cost of borrowing abroad. Let us assume that that

people care about future generations just like they care about themselves.

If there is a temporary negative shock to Y the effect on current absorption

can be limited if one borrows in the international markets. The possibility

to borrow will be given by x and the cost of borrowing will be set to the

international real interest rate, r.

Assume that we can repay the loan over an infinite number of periods, so

we can disregard repayments. The cost of the loan in each period will be the

interest paid on the loan, rB. We postulate that the economy in this case

will choose to borrow according to the rule

∆B = −∆Y · x− r∆B, x ≥ 0. (8.80)

This implies that if borrowing is possible (x > 0) how much one will borrow

will depend on both the opportunity to borrow, x and the cost of borrowing,

r. Inflow will be positive is the shock to output is negative, therefore we have

a negative sign on ∆Y . The loan will be repayed by all future generations at

250

Page 254: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

the cost of rB. From this we can derive the optimal ∆B, which is given by

∆B =−∆Y x

1 + r. (8.81)

If the shock is temporary and we assume consumption smoothing, it would

not be optimal to let the present generation bear the whole cost of the shock.

To alleviate the negative shock the country will borrow in the international

markets and let ∆B = −∆Y x1+r

. If so we have

∆Q

Q=

∆Y

Y+

(1−m−m∗)

m

x

1 + r

∆Y

Y. (8.82)

where we know that (1−m−m∗)m

∈ [0, 1〉 .

The effect under a temporary shock will depend on four variables: x, r,

m and m∗. We can show that

δ(∆QQ

)

δx=

1

1 + r

(1−m−m∗)

m

∆Y

Y> 0, (8.83)

δ(∆QQ

)

δr= − x

(1 + r)2

(1−m−m∗)

m

∆Y

Y< 0, (8.84)

andδ(∆Q

Q)

δm=

x

1 + r

[(1−m∗)

m2

]∆Y

Y> 0. (8.85)

The effect of a supply shock on the real exchange rate will be higher the

higher the capital mobility and the more international trade. However, the

effect will decrease with the cost of borrowing.

Note one important implication: freer capital flows will enhance the ef-

fects of a real supply shock on the real exchange rate. What is the intuition

behind such a result? If there is no capital flows, the real exchange rate

must adjust to clear the markets. A negative supply shock will lead to a fall

in supply of good H, and a relative in the price of H, thereby leading to a

251

Page 255: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

real appreciation. If the shock is alleviated by capital inflow, such inflow will

increase the relative demand for good H over good F , as we assume the con-

sumers of the home country to have a higher share of H in their consumption

than the share of F . This will put further pressure on the price of H, leading

to an even stronger real appreciation.

Assume output is back to its long term value in the next period. Even

if the shock only lasts for one period, the country is now left with a net

debt. This debt must be repaid. There is a capital inflow of ∆B = ∆Y x1+r

in

the period of the shock, and a capital outflow of ∆B = −rB for all future

periods. Absorption must fall to a new level in the period of the shock, and

remain at this level for all future—or at least to the next shock.

The capital outflow, giving a negative value of ∆B, must affect the real

exchange rate as well. The real exchange rate will no depreciate to a level

above its value before the shock, as absorption now will be below absorption

before the shock. Capital flow will not only enhance the effect on the real

exchange rate in the period of the shock, it will enhance the change in the

following periods as well.

The case of a negative supply shock is illustrated in figures 8.4 and 8.3.

Figure 8.4 show the effect on Y and Q. Figure 8.4 is a more complex diagram.

If there are no capital flows A = Y and the economy must be at the 45 degree

line all the time. However, in every point we can adjust absorption through

capital flows. This will lead to an adjustment of Q according to the rule

∆Q

Q= −(1−m−m∗)

m

∆B

Y. (8.86)

This is the downward sloping line in the diagram. Note that with our “rule”

absorption will settle at a new long term value in the period of the shock.

252

Page 256: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 8.3: The effect on the real exchange rate of a temporary negativesupply shock (a)

time

Y

time

Q

Free capital flow

No capital flow

253

Page 257: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 8.4: The effect on the real exchange rate of a temporary negativesupply shock (b)

Q

Y

45 degree line. Defines B=0In Y=45 degree line, Y=A

dQ/Q =(dY/Y)+-[1/(1+r)]*[(1-m-m*)/m]*(dY/Y)Full capital mobility (x=1).Period of shockdQ/Q=dY/Y

No capital mobility.

Y0, Y2Y1

A0: Absorption before shockA1,1 :Absorption inperiod of shock ifno capital mobility.

Absorption=output, beforeshock

A1,2 : Absorption in allfuture periods if fullcapital mobility and”optimal policy”

r*B, current account surplus for all future

Current account deficit inperiod of shock, optimalpolicy.

dQ/Q =(dY/Y)+-[1/(1+r)]*[(1-m-m*)/m]*(dY/Y)Full capital mobility (x=1). All future periods.

Lines given by:dQ/Q -[(1-m-m*)/m]*(dB/Y)

254

Page 258: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

This policy is only one of many policy options available. The actual lend-

ing in response to a negative supply shock might not follow the rule described

above. If actual lending is less than described in this rule, absorption will

fall more in the period of the shock. However, it will bounce back to a level

higher than under the described policy for all future periods, as repayment

costs are less. The real exchange rate will appreciate less in the period of the

shock. It will however also depreciate less in the following periods.

A demand shock will not affect the levels of Y or Y ∗. If there is no

capital mobility, the demand shock must be compensated through an adjust-

ment of the national price level, and a similar adjustment of the nominal

exchange rate, leaving the real exchange rate unaffected. However, if there

is capital mobility, a positive demand shock will lead to capital inflow, and

an appreciation of the real exchange rate, given by

∆Q

Q= −(1−m−m∗)

m

∆B

Y. (8.87)

8.6 The importance of capital flows for con-

sumption smoothing

There are short term and long term capital flows. Short term flows will

be in the form of interbank flows, i.e. flows between banks, and purchases

of money market instruments, such as Treasury bills, i.e. government bonds

with less than one year from issuance to maturity, or other commercial paper.

Long term flows will be in the form of purchases of bonds or equity, either

as portfolio investment or for the purpose of direct control.

For consumption smoothing long term flows are of most importance.

Given our discussion above, it is of some interest to measure the degree

of mobility of long term capital.

255

Page 259: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Feldstein and Horioka, in a paper published in 1980, argued that if capital

mobility is high one should expect zero or low correlation between national

saving and investment, as countries would use the current account to smooth

consumption. They tested this proposition by estimating the equation(I

Y

)i,t

= α + β

(S

Y

)i,t

+ ui,t, (8.88)

where I/Y is the investment rate and S/Y is the savings rate. If capital

mobility is high, β is expected to be close to zero. However, on data from

1961 to 1980, what they found was(I

Y

)= 0.035

(0.018)+ 0.89

(0.074)

(S

Y

)R2 = 0.91, (8.89)

where numbers in parenthesis are standard errors. Instead of β close to zero,

they were not able to reject β = 1 at a 95 per cent level. This results is now

known as the “Feldstein-Horioka puzzle”.

8.6.1 Explaining the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle

There are two ways to react to this result. Either you try to explain why

capital mobility is so low, or you argue that the estimation does not really

estimate capital mobility. After all, our intuition on this question is not

really clear. One the one hand we do see substantial flows of capital between

countries. One the other hand, one finds that many types of investment,

and especially high risk investments like venture capital, tend to be national

more than international.

There is a good argument for why we should not expect β = 0 even if

capital is mobile. In the model in section 8.5 we argued that if shocks were

permanent, it would be optimal to adjust absorption immediately. In the

life-cycle theory of consumption, sustained shocks to e.g. productivity or

256

Page 260: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

demographics that will affect investments should also be expected to affect

savings. So if shocks are mainly perceived as permanent we would expect

a high correlation between savings and investments even with full capital

mobility.

However, there are also good reasons to assume that capital mobility is,

or has been limited:

1. Currency risk. Financial firms usually state their liabilities, i.e. de-

posits, in the national currency. Investing abroad means taking a cur-

rency risk. For long term investments such risk is difficult and/or ex-

pensive to hedge.

An indication of how importance currency risk is can be found be com-

paring capital flows between countries and capital flows between regions

within countries. Generally, one finds little or no correlation between

savings and investment in studies of inter-country data. The imple-

mentation of the euro will in a few years provide a very strong test of

the importance of currency risk.

2. Until recently, government regulations on capital flows were widespread,

even in developed countries. Only in the last ten to twenty years have

restrictions on capital flows been fully removed. The Feldstein-Horioka

result might therefore just reflect that capital restrictions were in fact

effective. More recent studies tend to find that the estimate of β is

getting smaller as new observations are added. β is however still sig-

nificantly larger than zero.

In line with the Feldstein-Horioka puzzle, it is generally found that coun-

tries do not tend to smooth consumption as much as the theory would expect.

Why this is so, and whether this impression will change as (or if) we see more

257

Page 261: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 8.5: Stylized view of capital mobility in modern historyFigure 1: Conjecture? A Stylized View of Capital Mobility in Modern History

1914

2000

1880

19711918 1925

1929

1945

1960

19801860

1900

1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

Gold Standard1880–1914

Bretton Woods1945–71

Float1971–2000

Interwar1914–45

High

Low

Source: Introspection.

for exchange-rate flexibility coupled with inflation targeting.In the 1990s, the term “globalization” has became a catch-all to describe the

phenomenon of an increasingly integrated and interdependent world economy, onethat exhibits supposedly free flows of goods, services, and capital, albeit not oflabor. Yet for all the hype, economic history suggests that we be a little cautious inassessing how amazing this development really is. We will show that a period ofimpressive global integration has been witnessed before,at least for capital markets,at the turn of the twentieth century, just about a hundred years ago. Of course, thatearlier epoch of globalization did not endure. As the above discussion suggests,if we were roughly to sketch out the implied movements in capital mobility, wewould chart an upswing from 1880 to 1914; this would be followed by a collapseto 1945, though perhaps with a minor recovery during the brief reconstructionof the gold standard in the 1920s, between the autarky of World War One and theDepression; we would then think of a gradual rise in mobility after 1945, becomingfaster after the demise of Bretton Woods in the early 1970s.

For illustrative purposes, let us make the tenuous assumption that internationalcapital mobility or global capital market integration could be measured in a singleparameter. Suppose we could plot that parameter over time for the last century or so.

6

Source: Obstfeld and Taylor, 2002

global integration in the coming years, is uncertain. One should however note

that international mobility of factors is a rather recent feature of the post-

war world. Obstfeld and Taylor (2002) argue that as late as in 1980 capital

mobility was still lower than in the early years of the Gold Standard. Only

over the last 20 years have we seen a radical shift in capital mobility between

countries. According to Obstfeld and Taylor we did not reach pre-World War

1 levels of capital mobility before in year 2000. Their “introspective” view is

given in figure 8.5. Two conclusions from this illustration might be that

1. capital mobility is nothing new, and

2. making assumptions of high capital mobility in data from the period

1945-1990 is probably not reasonable.

258

Page 262: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 9

International capital flows, the

IMF and monetary reform

9.1 Topics

• History of capital mobility

• The Eurodollar market

• International debt

• Interbank lending and bank regulation

• International bonds and national defaults

• The IMF

• Taxation of capital flows

9.2 Capital flows

• International bank lending

– lending to customer

259

Page 263: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 9.1: Stylized view of capital mobility in modern historyFigure 1: Conjecture? A Stylized View of Capital Mobility in Modern History

1914

2000

1880

19711918 1925

1929

1945

1960

19801860

1900

1860 1880 1900 1920 1940 1960 1980 2000

Gold Standard1880–1914

Bretton Woods1945–71

Float1971–2000

Interwar1914–45

High

Low

Source: Introspection.

for exchange-rate flexibility coupled with inflation targeting.In the 1990s, the term “globalization” has became a catch-all to describe the

phenomenon of an increasingly integrated and interdependent world economy, onethat exhibits supposedly free flows of goods, services, and capital, albeit not oflabor. Yet for all the hype, economic history suggests that we be a little cautious inassessing how amazing this development really is. We will show that a period ofimpressive global integration has been witnessed before,at least for capital markets,at the turn of the twentieth century, just about a hundred years ago. Of course, thatearlier epoch of globalization did not endure. As the above discussion suggests,if we were roughly to sketch out the implied movements in capital mobility, wewould chart an upswing from 1880 to 1914; this would be followed by a collapseto 1945, though perhaps with a minor recovery during the brief reconstructionof the gold standard in the 1920s, between the autarky of World War One and theDepression; we would then think of a gradual rise in mobility after 1945, becomingfaster after the demise of Bretton Woods in the early 1970s.

For illustrative purposes, let us make the tenuous assumption that internationalcapital mobility or global capital market integration could be measured in a singleparameter. Suppose we could plot that parameter over time for the last century or so.

6

Source: Obstfeld and Taylor, 2002

260

Page 264: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Table 9.1: International capital flowsIn billion USD Total stocks, 1997 % of totalLend. to final user:from bank 5285 0.60bonds and notes 3358 0.38money market 184 0.02Total: 8827 1.00Interbank dep. 5098FX-reserves 1732Direct for. invest. 3000FX-trading per day 1600

– interbank

• Securities

– money market instruments

– bonds and notes

• Portfolio investments

• Direct investments

“Eurobanking”—banking services provided in a currency that is not the

currency of country where the bank is located

“Eurodollars”—USD deposited in banks outside US. There exists “Euro

markets” for most currencies.

Note:

• Commercial banks: hold their reserves as cash or deposits with a central

bank.

• Eurobanks hold all reserves as deposits with commercial banks. In

the end every dollar in the Eurobank system will be a liability on a

commercial bank in the US.

261

Page 265: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 9.2: Capital flows—poor vs. rich countriesFigure 10: Did Capital Flow to Poor Countries? 1913 Versus 1997

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

<20 20–40 40–60 60–80 >80

Per capita income range of receiving region (U.S.=100)

Shar

e of

wor

ld s

tock

of

fore

ign

capi

tal

1913, gross stocks1997, gross stocks

Sources: The 1913 stock data are from Woodruff (1967) and Royal Institute for International Affairs (1937), incomes

from Maddison (1995). The 1997 data are from Lane and Milesi-Ferreti (2001), based on the stocks of inward direct

investment and portfolio equity liabilities.

they are today, so it is all the more remarkable that so much capital was directedto countries at or below the 20 percent and 40 percent income levels (relative tothe U.S.). Today, a much larger fraction of the world’s output and population islocated in such low productivity regions, but a much smaller share of global foreigninvestment reaches them.69

As we have noted, capital is discouraged from entering poorer countries by ahost of factors, and some of these were less relevant a century ago. Capital controlspersist in many regions. The risks of investment may be perceived differentlyafter a century of exchange risks, expropriations, and defaults. Domestic policiesthat distort prices, especially of investment goods, may result in returns too low toattract any capital. These conditions make a difficult situation much worse. Poorercountries must draw on foreign capital to a greater extent than they do at present ifthey are to achieve an acceptable growth in living standards. That is a fundamentalreason why reform and liberalization in the developing world, despite the setbacksof the late 1990s, are likely to continue, albeit hopefully with due regard to thepainful lessons learned in the recent past.

69See Clemens and Williamson (2001) for a detailed analysis of the determinants of Britishcapital export before 1914.

60

Source: Obstfeld and Taylor, 2002

Evolved in London. Half the market in Europe, rest in Asia and tax

havens.

History:

1. avoid restrictions on capital flows,

2. invest in USD without investing in the US.

1957: capital restrictions imposed in UK. UK residents wanted to avoid

restrictions by investing in USD. 1958: several European currencies made

convertible, making USD investments possible.

Russia in need of USD, did however not want deposits in US in fear of

retaliation.

New growth in the 1970’s: OPEC got income in USD, did however not

want to invest in US.

262

Page 266: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Easy access for third world countries. Main market for international debt.

Eurodollar market generally offers lower spreads than domestic commer-

cial banks—Eurobanks have higher deposit rates and lower loan rates.

How?

• Little or no regulation in the Euro market. Until recently the US

banking market was heavily regulated.

– Regulation Q—maximum deposit rates

– Interest Equalisation Tax and Voluntary Foreign Credit Restraint

Guidelines: imposed to reduce US lending to foreigners.

However, today little regulations in the US market.

– No minimum reserve requirements.

– Economics of scale—used to deal in large loans.

Credit multiplier: do the existence of Eurobanks affect the liquidity in

the USD market?

Supply of USD, M :

M = Mp + ME, (9.1)

Mp = dollars held by private sector excluding Eurobanks, ME = USD

held by Eurobanks with domestic US banks as reserves.

Liquid assets held by the private sector, L:

L = Mp + E, (9.2)

E = the public’s holding of Eurodollar (deposits in Eurobanks).

263

Page 267: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

How does the existence of Eurobanks affect L? We see that

L

M=

Mp + E

Mp + ME

. (9.3)

L can be expressed as

L

M=

Mp

E+ 1

Mp

E+ ME

E

. (9.4)

ME

E: Reserve to deposit ratio in the Eurobank system. Expect to be

low.

Mp

E: Ratio of holdings of dollars outside the Eurobanks to the holdings

in the Eurobanks. Expect to be high.

⇒ should probably expect that LM≈ 1.

Eurobanks have only a marginal effect on liquidity in the USD-market.

9.3 The international debt market

Makes it possible to finance current account deficits over long periods

of time without any automatic stabilisation effects

⇒ same countries remain deficit countries over long periods of time.

⇒ “ballooning” of debt for some countries.

Assume three regions: US, Latin America and Europe. Only trade

between Latin America and US, between US and Europe, not trade

between Europe and Latin America.

US trade surplus of 100 with Latin America, deficit of 100 with Europe.

US: trade balance.

Europe: surplus of 100.

Latin America: Deficit of 100.

264

Page 268: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Latin America finance deficit by borrowing 100 in Eurodollar market.

Europe accumulates assets of 100 as deposits in Eurobanks. If pattern

continues, Latin America will accumulate debt, Europe accumulate as-

sets.

Eurodollar market continue to grow as long as balance of payments

deficit persists.

Why no automatic stabilisation?

– Growth of euro-dollar market is non-inflationary as for each amount

borrowed there is an equal amount saved. Money base does not

change here.

– Balance-of-payments surpluses “recycled”, world aggregate de-

mand remains unchanged.

– Note that the ballooning of USD debt is created although the US

have a balanced current account.

What is driving this?

Europe willing to hold USD. Latin America needs USD, not EUR.

If Europe not willing to hold USD, US would have to use foreign reserves

to finance deficit with Europe. The US money base would be reduced.

US competitiveness would grow, US imports fall.

At the same time, Latin America would not get USD to finance US

imports—would have to improve own competitiveness.

Result: more US exports to Europe, more Latin American exports to

US.

With Eurobanks: Latin America can postpone reform of exporting

sector. Imbalances not corrected.

265

Page 269: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Latin America is the debtor of the Eurobanks. Eurobanks are the

debtors of Europe.

So Latin America owes its debt to Europe? No—and yes. Europe

has deposits in banks—seemingly a safe investment. However, if Latin

America defaults the bank will default, and Europe will not get any

money.

Why is this a problem:

– In many cases the creditors of banks believe banks to be “safe”,

because they believe banks will not be allowed to default. So bank

deposits are sometimes made with a “wrong” perception of risk.

– Assume “Europe” is a number of smaller investors. If Latin Amer-

ica defaults on its debt this will lead to losses for a potentially large

group of people.

– As pointed out above, debt allows Latin America to postpone

reform. However, if they can just default and get rid of debt, do

they ever have incentive to reform?

Inter-bank market: loans and transactions between banks

– To satisfy (short-term) needs to fulfill regulation criteria in resi-

dent country.

– Banks obtain deals at different times—continually need to balance

their accounts.

– Utilise opportunities for niche specialisation—banks specialise in

lending, and obtain financing through the interbank market.

– Arbitrage trades.

266

Page 270: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Bank interdependence

Because of the interbank lending, there is interdependence in the capital

markets: if one bank defaults other banks might default as well.

Some problems associated with banks:

– Information asymmetries. Depositors know little about the bank,

the bank has little knowledge of its debtors. Both the bank and

the final borrower might have incentive to take excess risk.

– Risk asymmetries. Depositors believe their deposits to be cov-

ered by deposit insurance or a central bank lender of last resort

function. Have little incentive to reduce risk taking in the bank.

– “Lender’s trap”. If you have borrowed a firm a large sum of money,

and the firm is on the edge of default, should you borrow it a little

more to let this firm avoid default?

– “Race to the bottom”. To increase profits banks can reduce the

bank capital. However, this makes them more vulnerable for loan

losses.

– If lending and borrowing is international, but regulations of capital

requirements is national ⇒ potential instability.

The structure of the banking business seems to imply that aggressive

banks get the upper hand. However, this seems to be the result of a

market failure where banks not fully internalises the cost of default in

the banking industry.

If we accept this reasoning, there is an argument for regulation of the

banking industry.

267

Page 271: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

If the industry has a global scope, and the costs of failure are of an

international character, then regulation should be international.

⇒ The Basel Capital Accord. Agreement on capital adequacy mea-

surement and standards. Defines

1. eligible capital elements,

2. variable risk weights applicable to several main categorises of on-

and off-balance sheet exposure,

3. set overall minimum capital ratio to 8 per cent of risk weighted

assets, and

4. set overall “core capital” to at least 4 per cent.

Agreement implemented in 1992. It imposed a substantial increase

in capital requirements for some banks. However, many problems re-

mained unsolved:

– Interbank lending was seen as low risk. However, as discussed

above interbank lending is not risk free.

– Many banks were able to take considerable risk within this accord,

e.g. as seen under the Asian crisis in 1997.

Currently discussions about “Basel 2”. Main changes from “Basel 1”:

– Risk will be measured with “value-at-risk” models. As banks often

have the best models of this kind, risk will be measured by the

banks own models.

– Ratings from rating agencies—like Moody’s or S&P—may be used

to assess the riskiness of the bank’s entire portfolio.

268

Page 272: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

New accord to be implemented in 2006. However, already much dis-

cussion of how this will work in practice.

The international bond market

– Foreign bonds : bonds issued by foreign corporations or countries

in the domestic capital market of another country. Normally sold

by a host-country investment bank, and traded in the host finan-

cial market. Subject to host country laws.

– Eurobonds : bond issued in a country that does not use the cur-

rency as domestic currency, e.g. USD denominated bond issued

in London. Usually issued by a syndicate of underwriters, and

issued in a number of countries simultaneously.

Annual new eurobonds run about twice the rate as new foreign bonds.

Why direct finance instead of finance through banks?

– Potential asymmetry problems in direct finance. Banks are sup-

posed to be able to generate superior information, and therefore

have an information advantage.

– However, for large companies this is less the case. Should expect

more direct finance.

– The easier to collect information, the more direct finance.

Information problems might be a problem for small and/or developing

countries when obtaining loans. International agencies, like the World

Bank, work as intermediaries in the bond market. People will rather

buy a World Bank bond than say, an Indian government bond.

Use of the international bond market. Why borrow in a currency dif-

ferent form the domestic currency?

269

Page 273: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

– Profit on risk premiums.

– Diversify risk. International business cycles are not perfectly cor-

related. Return is less correlated between countries than within

countries.

– Hedge currency risk, especially if costs and incomes are denomi-

nated in different currencies.

– Finance current account deficits. If state companies finance new

investments aborad, they reduce demand for capital at home. Im-

plicitly this takes pressure away from the foreign reserves.

– If local markets are illiquid, international borrowing might be the

only option.

– The foreign banking industry might be more efficient, and there-

fore offer better rates than the domestic industry.

– Tax adjustments and use of tax havens.

Government vs. national debt

(1) Balance of payment (BOP)= current account surplus + capital

account surplus = ∆F g (increase in foreign reserves)

(2) Capital account surplus = net long term private capital inflow +

government foreign borrowing - gross short-term capital outflow

Combine (1) and (2):

(3) Government foreign borrowing = current account deficit + ∆F g +

gross short-term capital outflow - net long term private capital inflow

Note: net national indebtness is determined only by current account

deficit.

270

Page 274: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Government indebtness will increase even if current account is zero if

large short term outflow of capital. What determines short-term capital

outflow? This was discussed in Lecture 8—the speculative portfolio.

Lender’s trap

Why do international banks continue to make loans to countries on the

verge of default?

Problem for the banks: either make new loans so the country can service

payments on old debt, or declare the borrower insolvent, and write off

the loan.

Expected benefit from lending:

E(B) = (P0 − P1)D. (9.5)

P0 = probability of default before new loan is made.

P1 = probability of default after new loan is made.

D = debt outstanding before new loan.

Expected cost of new loan:

E(C) = P1L. (9.6)

L = value of new loan.

Net benefit of new loan as percentage of outstanding debt:

N(B) =E(B)− E(C)

D= P0 − P1

(1 +

L

D

). (9.7)

Give new loan if N(B) > 0.

271

Page 275: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

9.4 Can a country default?

Many poor countries heavily indebted.

– African countries: mostly debt to foreign governments.

– Latin America: mostly debt to foreign banks.

1982: Debt crisis. Mainly caused by the rising cost of imports due to

OPEC 2 rise in oil prices. Many debtors de facto insolvent—debt for-

giveness necessary. Important ratio: debt payment to export earnings.

What happens if a country can not service its debts?

Problem: as a creditor your debt becomes more worth if other creditors

are willing to reduce their claims.

⇒ tragedy of the commons. No one has incentive to move first.

Search for agreement that is binding across different asset classes and

jurisdictions.

Possible solutions:

– International bankruptcy court

– Majority action clauses in debt contracts: allows a majority of the

creditors to agree on changes in the debt contract that affects all

creditors.

– Increase IMF power.

Current discussion:

– IMF: proposes to allow majority voting, overseen by the IMF.

60-70 per cent of creditors should be enough to determine restruc-

turing.

272

Page 276: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

– US Treasury: borrowing countries should add clauses to debt con-

tracts that describe what happen if the country gets into trouble,

like how a default will be initiated et.c. Introducing such clauses

should be condition for receiving IMF loans.

9.5 The role of the International Mone-

tary Fund (IMF)

When confronted with a member with a balance of payment deficit:

restore equilibrium. But how?

Role:

– “to promote the adjustment process”,

– “restore viability of balance of payment in the context of price sta-

bility and sustained economic growth, without resort to measures

that impair the freedom of trade and payments.”

Earlier: much emphasis on fiscal deficit.

Later years: take more country specific considerations, look more at

long term prospects and structural reform process.

Policy choices

– Monetary policy; usually setting ceiling on the rate of domestic

credit growth.

– Devaluation of fixed exchange rate.

– Reduce price distortions, e.g.

∗ by reducing subsidies,

273

Page 277: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

∗ eliminate interest rate ceilings, or

∗ by trade liberalisation.

– Freeze wages.

– Target the growth of net foreign indebtness.

“Demand management”. Important IMF policy:

Domestic absorption must be constrained to a level consistent with the

level of domestic production plus any sustainable net capital inflows,

otherwise the balance of payments deficit is unsustainable.

To assure a permanent solution to balance of payment problems:

– Improve resource allocation to lessen the constraint on the level

of domestic demand imposed by a given availability of resources.

Policies include:

∗ exchange rate adjustments,

∗ interest rate adjustments,

∗ reducing subsidies.

– Structural reform. If problem is high imports of expensive oil,

increase domestic energy production, reduce energy vast.

As pointed our above, there is a close connection between domestic

banks and international capital flows. This has been important factors

in recent financial crises, like in Asia 1997.

Should international financial stability be on the agenda of IMF?

IMF: much focus on the importance of reducing asymmetric informa-

tion. Elements:

274

Page 278: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

– Increased disclosure of information. Arrange common reporting

standards.

– Requirements for bank capital.

– Modification of creditor rights (as discussed above), so as to stop

“grab-races”, attempts to cash in, and therefore force insolvency

on an illiquid, but solvent debtor.

– Reduce short-term capital flows if such flows have negative exter-

nalities.

IMF can force compliance to international standards by conditioning

lending on such compliance.

Does the IMF create moral hazard?

IMF works like a lender of last resort for countries.

Reduce incentive to balance your own books, as the IMF will rescue

the government if balance of payment deficit becomes unsustainable.

Is the economy better of without a lender of last resort? Might be less

irresponsible behaviour. However, crisis will still exist. How large will

the cost of such crisis be without a lender of last resort?

For countries of strategic importance: Someone will step in anyway (?)

By setting conditions for loans, phase out payments, and have close

surveillance of results, the IMF seeks to reduce moral hazard.

The monetary approach

IMF:

– Balance of payments deficits tend to have a common cause.

275

Page 279: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

– The policies mentioned above are mostly sufficient to correct such

imbalances.

Argument: in developing countries money used to finance public deficits.

No “wall” between the government asset sheet and the central bank as-

set sheet

Budget deficit

⇒ increase in money supply

⇒ inflation

⇒ the public want to increase holdings of foreign currency, dishoard

domestic currency (as in lecture on portfolio choice)

⇒ foreign reserves fall, country must finance deficit by borrowing abroad.

The country experience a real appreciation because of the increase in

the domestic price level. To retain domestic production tariffs intro-

duced. Frequent devaluations might alleviate the problem for short

periods of time. However, if government deficit persists, the spiral con-

tinues.

When debt level no longer sustainable, IMF called in. Situation:

– Not able to service debt.

– Domestic economy distorted by trade restrictions.

– Financial markets distorted by “financial repression”, means used

to make domestic markets accept domestic government debt.

The IMF’s approach: adjustment requires a fundamental change in

economic and financial conditions. Budget deficit reduced, distortions

reversed. Main target: stop dishoarding of local currency.

276

Page 280: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Question: should change be gradual or rapid? Historically IMF has

favoured rapid reform. Has taken more flexible approach in later years.

The New Structuralist debate

Critique: IMF approach should be expected to work well in developed

countries. However, developing countries have different structure, need

different approach. There exists no “common cause”, and no singular

solution.

Examples:

– Reducing money supply could increase inflation if “interest cost

push” strong—lower money supply would push up interest rates,

higher interest rates might push up prices.

– Devaluation might be negative if

∗ the cost of necessary imports so much that domestic supply

will fall.

∗ the fall in the spending power of wages fall so much that

aggregate demand falls, leading to lower growth.

∗ if much of domestic debt is denominated in foreign currency,

leading to higher cost of debt servicing.

∗ if tariffs are measured in per cent, a devaluation, leading to

higher import prices, will at the same time mean higher taxes,

i.e. contractionary fiscal policy.

– Reduction of subsidies might decrease local demand, leading to

slower growth.

– If deficits have non-monetary causes, like recession in export mar-

kets, IMF strategy will be counterproductive.

277

Page 281: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

These arguments depend on assumptions of import dependence and

resource immobility.

Example: Asian crisis in 1997

IMF advice: increase interest rates to stop dishoarding of domestic

currency. Balance public deficits.

Problem: these countries were in recession. Increased interest rates

made could make this recession even deeper. Reducing fiscal deficits in

periods of recession is pro-cyclical, not counter cyclical policy.

Empirical evidence: not much support for one nor the other. IMF

policies stabilise the situation, but “sustainability” is not guaranteed.

However, most countries do not fully implement IMF policies. New

structuralist’s claims about devaluation not supported.

IMF and Argentina

IMF sceptical to currency board from the start. However: IMF focus

on “national adoption of policies”—the country must be presented with

alternatives and get to make a choice.

IMF tried to make Argentina leave the board in 1997-98. At this time

Argentina was doing well. Probably only small effects if board had

been changed. However, the board was very important as a symbol of

new brooms in Argentinean politics.

August 2001: IMF still supported Argentina. Damned if you do,

damned if you don’t...

Now IMF is stating requirements:

– Restore the confidence in the banking system. (But how?)

278

Page 282: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

– Change legal structure to protect creditors—current system favours

debtors.

– Reign in spending by the provinces.

9.6 Capital controls in Chile

History: Introduced in June 1991.

Initially: 20 per cent reserve requirement on portfolio investments to

be deposited in central bank at no interest. For maturities under one

year it applied for the whole period, for maturities over one year, it

applied for one year.

In July 1992: changed to requirement of 30 per cent for ne year, in-

dependent of maturity of investment. Extended to trade credits and

loans to FDI.

In June 1998 reduced to 10 per cent, and abolished in September 1998.

Intentions:

– Slow down volume of capital flowing into the country.

– change composition of flows to longer maturities.

– Allow the Central Bank to maintain a higher interest differential

between domestic and foreign interest rates.

– Reduce vulnerability to international financial instability.

Effects:

– Ratio of long term flows to short term flows increased.

– However, so did “residual flows”—there is some evidence of eva-

sion.

279

Page 283: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

– Some evidence of increased “independence” in monetary policy.

– However, measures of international vulnerability shows mixed re-

sults:

∗ Almost no reaction to the Mexican crisis in 1994,

∗ however, a more marked reaction to the Asian crisis than what

was felt in the rest of Latin America.

∗ Further, financial stability was restored in 1999, after the re-

serve requirements were abolished altogether.

In the end however, Chile probably remained stable because economic

policy as a whole was stable during the 1990’s.

Potential problems:

– Increases the cost of capital, especially for small and mid-sized

firms.

– Always the temptation to turn such measures into permanent poli-

cies.

– Policymakers might become overconfident, neglecting the needs

for more general reform.

280

Page 284: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 9.3: Capital inflows to Chile

50

Table 2 : Capital Inflows (gross) to Chile: Millions of US$

Year Short term

flows

Percentage

of total

Long term

flows

Percentage

of total

Total Deposits*

1988 916,564 96.3 34,838 3.7 951,402 --

1989 1,452,595 95.0 77,122 5.0 1,529,717 --

1990 1,683,149 90.3 181,419 9.7 1,864,568 --

1991 521,198 72.7 196,115 27.3 717,313 587

1992 225,197 28.9 554,072 71.1 779,269 11,424

1993 159,462 23.6 515,147 76.4 674,609 41,280

1994 161,575 16.5 819,699 83.5 981,274 87,039

1995 69,675 6.2 1,051,829 93.8 1,121,504 38,752

1996 67,254 3.2 2,042,456 96.8 2,109,710 172,320

1997 81,131 2.8 2,805,882 97.2 2,887,013 331,572

* Deposits in the Banco Chile due to reserve requirements.

Source: Edwards, 2000

281

Page 285: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 9.4: The tax equivalent of the Chilean reserve requirement

59

0.00

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98

TAX180 TAX1YR TAX3YRS

Figure 2: Tax Equivalent of Capital Controls:Stay of 180 days, 1 year and 3 years

Stay of 3 months, 1 year and 3 years. Source: Edwards, 2000

282

Page 286: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 10

Exercises

Lecture 1

1. Gresham’s law

(a) Gresham’s law states that bad money always will drive good

money out of circulation. People will choose to use the bad

money for transactions, and store the good money. Explain

why.

(b) Assume a system where two types of coins circulate in the

economy. Some coins are of silver, and some coins are of gold.

Discuss possible problems that can arise in such a system if

there is discovered a huge deposit of silver. Will silver or gold

coins dominate circulation? Will silver or gold dominate as a

store of value?

(c) Assume that one has a currency that is backed by a two-metal

standard. Assume that for 35 units of currency one can claim

1 ounce of gold or 35 ounces of silver at the central bank.

Assume gold supply increases three-fold, while supply of sil-

283

Page 287: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

ver remains constant. How will this affect the central banks

holdings of gold and silver? Will this currency be “stable”?

2. Fiat money and free banking...

(a) Assume that the Norwegian government allows everyone to

print Norwegian kroner on their own colour printers. What

would do you think would happen to the Norwegian money

supply? What will happen to the Norwegian price level?

(b) At the islands Yap in the Pacific Ocean people used large,

heavy round stones with a hole in the middle as currency. One

stone took two men approximately one week to make. These

stones worked as both unit of account, means of payment and

store of value. However, as they were difficult to carry, the

islanders did not care to carry them around. Instead they

issued legal titles to the stones. These legal titles were used

for trading.

Note that the stones only had value as currency. They had

no value as a commodity.

i. What is the difference between the stones on Yap and the

ability to print your own money?

ii. Explain the fact that inflation on Yap was stable.

iii. What would happen to the price level on Yap if the is-

landers got a new technology that would reduce the time

to make a new stone from one week to one day? Should

this have any effects for the real economy on Yap?

3. Seignorage

284

Page 288: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(a) Seignorage is given by

Seignoraget =Mt −Mt−1

Pt

. (10.1)

We know that real money demand can be written as

Mt

Pt

= Et

(Pt+1

Pt

)−η

. (10.2)

Assume perfect foresight. Further, assume that the central

bank can commit to a fixed rate of money growth for all fu-

ture, µ, so thatMt

Mt−1

= 1 + µ. (10.3)

Use this information to show that the rate of money growth,

µopt, that will maximise seignorage revenue is equal to 1η.

(b) Average growth in Norwegian M1 over the period from De-

cember 1992 to January 2002 has been 9.48 per cent on a

yearly basis. Assume that Norges Bank behaves according to

the rule of optimal seignorage. Find η.

(c) Assuming constant money growth, the formula for seignorage

can be written

Seignoraget = µ(1 + µ)−η−1. (10.4)

Calculate seignorage for Norway.

(d) We want to find seignorage as a percentage of public expendi-

ture. Note that in equation (11.4) seignorage is measured as

a fraction of the price level. For our purposes it is reasonable

to approximate the price level with the money stock in the

last period. In January 2002 Norwegian M1 was 382.6 billion

285

Page 289: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

NOK. The public expenditure for 2001 was expected to be

487.9 billion NOK. Calculate seignorage as a percentage of

government expenditure for Norway. Compare your number

with the numbers in Box 8.1 in Obstfeld and Rogoff, ch. 8.2.

Lecture 2

In its simplest form, a currency board is a money printing rule. We

will consider Argentina, where the domestic currency is the Argen-

tinean peso (ARP). The currency board arrangement says that (a) the

ARP/USD exchange rate is 1.00, and (b) for every peso in circulation

the currency board must hold USD 1.00 in reserve.

Figure 10.1 gives a simple example. Mark that all units are ARP.

The financial system are characterised by two key ratios:

1. The public’s deposit-to-cash ratio. Here that ratio is 12 (9000/750).

This reflects the optimal amount of ‘liquidity’ which the public de-

mands, relative to the size of their bank deposits. What ‘liquidity’

means here is ‘cash required to facilitate purchases of goods and

services.’ The ratio of 12 reflects a tradeoff. On the one hand, the

more cash held, the easier it is to transact. One the other hand,

the more cash held, the more is given up in foregone interest in-

come.

2. The banking system’s deposit-to-reserve ratio. Here that ratio is 60

(9000/150). This reflects a tradeoff which underlies good banking

practice. The banker needs some cash in the vault in order to

satisfy customer withdrawal demands (and prevent a bank run).

286

Page 290: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Fig

ure

10.1

:E

xam

ple

ofa

curr

ency

boa

rd

Car

neg

ieM

ello

nU

niv

ersi

tyG

radu

ate

Scho

olof

Indu

stri

alA

dmin

istr

atio

nC

hris

Tel

mer

Min

i4,

2002

Inte

rnati

onalFin

ance

Pro

ble

mSet

1

Thi

spr

oble

mse

tha

stw

opa

rts.

Inth

efir

styo

uw

illw

ork

thro

ugh

anu

mer

ical

exam

ple

ofho

wa

curr

ency

boar

dfu

ncti

onsin

conj

unct

ion

wit

ha

frac

tion

alre

serv

eba

nkin

gsy

stem

.In

the

seco

ndyo

uw

illth

ink

abou

tth

epr

osan

dco

nsof

acu

rren

cybo

ard

and

mak

ea

reco

mm

enda

tion

toth

e19

91A

rgen

tine

ango

vern

men

t(w

ith

the

bene

fitof

hind

sigh

t).

PA

RT

A

Init

ssi

mpl

est

form

,acu

rren

cybo

ard

isa

mon

eypr

inti

ngru

le.

We’

llco

nsid

erA

r-ge

ntin

a,w

here

the

dom

esti

ccu

rren

cyis

the

Arg

enti

nean

peso

(AR

P).

The

curr

ency

boar

dar

rang

emen

tsa

ysth

at(a

)th

eA

RP

/USD

exch

ange

rate

is1.

00,a

nd(b

)fo

rev

ery

peso

inci

rcul

atio

nth

ecu

rren

cybo

ard

mus

tho

ldU

SD1.

00in

rese

rve.

Her

eis

asi

mpl

eex

ampl

e.A

llun

its

are

AR

Pex

cept

the

asse

tsof

the

curr

ency

boar

d.

Pub

licC

omm

erci

alB

ank

Ass

ets

Lia

bilit

ies

Ass

ets

Lia

bilit

ies

Dep

osit

s9,

000

Loa

ns8,

850

Pes

os15

0D

epos

its

9,00

0Pes

os75

0N

etW

orth

900

Loa

ns8,

850

Net

Wor

th0

Cur

renc

yB

oard

Ass

ets

Lia

bilit

ies

USD

(cas

hor

secu

riti

es)

900

Pes

os90

0N

etW

orth

0

Wha

tch

arac

teri

zes

this

sim

ple

finan

cial

syst

emar

etw

oke

yra

tios

:

(i)

The

publ

ic’s

depo

sit-

to-c

ash

rati

ois

12.

Thi

sre

flect

sth

eop

tim

alam

ount

of‘li

quid

ity’

whi

chth

epu

blic

dem

ands

,re

lati

veto

the

size

ofth

eir

bank

de-

posi

ts.

Wha

t‘li

quid

ity’

mea

ns(h

ere)

is‘c

ash

requ

ired

tofa

cilit

ate

purc

hase

sof

good

san

dse

rvic

es.’

The

rati

oof

12re

flect

sa

trad

eoff.

On

the

one

hand

,th

em

ore

cash

held

,the

easi

erit

isto

tran

sact

.O

nth

eot

her

hand

,the

mor

eca

shhe

ld,th

em

ore

give

nup

info

rego

nein

tere

stin

com

e.

1

287

Page 291: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

However, the more cash in the vault the fewer loans made, which

in turn reduces interest income.

The balance sheets in figure 10.1 represents ‘equilibrium’ in that the

amount of deposits, cash and reserves are consistent with the two above

ratios—i.e. we assume by definition that these two ratios characterise

equilibrium. For more on a monetary equilibrium, see the appendix.

1. Here are two definitions:

– Money supply=currency held by the public plus deposits held

by the public.

– Monetary base=total currency in circulation plus commercial

bank reserve deposits held at the central bank (the latter are

zero here). This is called high powered money. It is also called

the liabilities of the central bank.

Note that the monetary base is what is exogenous in the above

system of balance sheets. That is, given the monetary base

and the two above ratios, everything else is determinate. This

will be clearer as we go along.

Given the data in figure 10.1, compute the values of the money

supply and the monetary base.

2. Next, assume that the Argentinean real exchange rate appreci-

ates vis-a-vis USD. Provide one or two sentences to say what this

means. This question should be answered abstractly, without ref-

erences to the above data. Your answer should be expressed in

intuitive terms, using plain, jargon-free language.

3. Now suppose that, because of the ARP real appreciation, an Ar-

gentinean importer wants to import some U.S. goods. Specifically,

288

Page 292: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

she wants to import 18 dollars worth of machines. This means that

she needs to obtain USD 18.

(a) First, suppose the importer goes to her commercial bank and

asks for USD 18. The commercial bank turns to a trader in an

American bank, and asks him to sell it USD 18 in return for

ARP 18. Assume the trade goes through, and the importer

receives USD 18 from its bank in return for ARP 18. What

is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base?

(b) Second, suppose that, because of the overvaluation, the trader

at the American bank will not sell USD for ARP at 1:1. He

might sell each USD for 1.2 ARP, but if he did then the fixed

exchange rate would have de facto collapsed. The good news

for the Argentinean importer is that the currency board is

obliged to sell her USD at 1:1. The commercial bank will

trade ARP 18 for USD 18 by sending a request to the currency

board.

What is the currency board supposed to do with the pesos it

receives for these USD? If the currency board does this, what

is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base?

(c) According to the quantity theory of money, money (M) times

the number of transactions conducted with money (velocity,

V ) should equal the price level, P , times the number of trans-

actions in the economy, T , or

M · V = P · T. (10.5)

We can simplify by assuming that velocity is constant, and

that T can be set equal to to total production in the economy,

289

Page 293: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Y .

Do you think the actions by the currency board described

above will alleviate the overvaluation of the Argentinean peso?

Why?

(d) What will happen if, for some reason, this process continues?

That is, what will happen if Argentineans try to convert all

their ARP-denominated bank deposits into USD?

4. Given the transaction by the Argentinean importer, what will hap-

pen to the Argentinean current account once this transaction oc-

curs? Will there be change in the direction of trade flows? How

will capital flows be affected?

5. Once the Argentinean importer has obtained the USD 18, you

should find that the system of balance sheets are no longer ‘in

equilibrium’. That is, the two ratios discussed above are no longer

12 and 60. Use the four linear equations described in the appendix

to compute the new equilibrium. What is the new money supply?

Is this new value for the money supply consistent with alleviating

the overvaluation problem?

6. The money multiplier is defined as the ratio of the reduction in the

money supply to the reduction in the monetary base. The money

multiplier tells us how fast the supply of money grows if another

unit of monetary base is created. What is the money multiplier

here? If the central bank prints one more piece of currency, how

much will the total money supply grow, and therefore how much

will the price level increase (if V and Y is constant)?

The important point in the example above is to show that a currency

290

Page 294: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

board has a ‘self-correcting’ aspect to it. Excessive inflation (relative

to the reserve country) and/or real exchange rate overvaluation should

be corrected if the currency board does what it is supposed to do. In

addition, the example points out that a county with a currency board

has effectively given up any sort of active monetary policy. Monetary

policy becomes a currency printing/burning robot.

Policy questions:

1. Look at attached reading and what you have learned above and

in class, and make a table which briefly outlines the pros and cons

of a currency board for a country like Argentina.

2. Pretend that you are an economic advisor to the Argentinean pres-

ident Carols Menem and his Minister of Finance, Domingo Cav-

allo, in 1991. With the befits of knowing what has happened up

to today (April 2002), make a recommendation to them regard-

ing the type of exchange rate mechanism which Argentina should

adopt.

Appendix

The essence of a ‘monetary equilibrium’ is that the the public’s deposit-

to-cash ratio must equal 12 and the banking system’s deposit-to reserve

ratio must equal 60. This, in addition to the accounting definitions

inherent in the balance sheets, imply the following system of linear

equations must hold:

291

Page 295: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

H = R + C

60 =R + L

R

12 =D

C

D + C = L + H,

where

– H≡the monetary base (number of pesos in circulation).

– R≡reserves of the banking system (cash in the vault).

– L≡loans.

– C≡currency held by the public.

– D≡deposits held by the public at commercial banks.

In a currency board H is given from outside the system, by market

forces. Given H, the above four equations are linear in 4 unknowns,

D, C, L and R.

Attached readings

(Included in separate file)

– Kurt Sculer: “Introduction to currency boards”,

(http://users.erols,com/kurrency/intro.htm)

292

Page 296: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

– “The ABC of currency boards”, The Economist, October 1997

– “Dollar mad?”, The Economist, October 2001

– “A decline without parallel”, The Economist, March 2002

Lecture 3

1. What do we mean with the n-1 problem in a multilateral exchange

rate system?

2. In the European Monetary System (EMS) a number of European

countries had agreed to fix their currencies to the European Cur-

rency Unit (ECU). ECU was defined as the value of a basket that

contained a weighted average of the currencies of the member

countries.

In the early 1980’s the EMS was a fairly flexible system, with

frequent adjustments. However, as a first step on the road towards

a common currency in the EU, it was in 1987 decided to let the

currencies be fixed to ECU, and to avoid adjustments.

After the opening of Eastern Germany in 1989, and the intro-

duction of DEM in the eastern territories in the summer of 1990,

Germany experienced an economic boom. To avoid inflation, the

Bundesbank responded to this growth by tightening money sup-

ply. A result was that German interest rates rose.

At the same time a number of other members of the EMS, includ-

ing France and Great Britain, experienced an economic slowdown.

These countries wanted a loser money supply to reduce interest

rates.

293

Page 297: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Assume that the UIP holds. Use the n-1 problem to illustrate

the strains put on the EMS-system. If possible, use diagrams to

illustrate the problem.

3. In a meeting in 1991 Germany suggested to revalue the DEM

inside the EMS system (increase the value of DEM relative to the

other currencies in the system). Could this have alleviated the

strains on the system?

4. France vetoed the German suggestion. Discuss why.

Lecture 4

From your former lessons in macro, you know the concept of a Phillips

curve. The Phillips curve implies a relationship between unemploy-

ment and inflation. In “modern macroeconomics” one thinks about the

Phillips curve as a fluctuations around a “non-accelerating-inflation-

rate-of-unemployment” (the NAIRU). The NAIRU is seen as the long-

run rate of unemployment. In the short term unemployment can be

higher or lower than the NAIRU, depending on whether inflation is

higher or lower than expected inflation. If we call unemployment for

u, the NAIRU for un and inflation for π, and we let πe be expected

inflation, we can express the Phillips curve as

u = un + a(πe − π). (10.6)

If inflation exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for

be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect inflation to

exceed expected inflation over time.

We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep inflation

294

Page 298: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the government has as a

goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un. This can be rationalised

if one think there are some sort of inefficiencies in the labour market

that lead to an increase in the NAIRU rate. As a second best policy

the government target an unemployment rate below the NAIRU. We

specifically assume that

u∗ = σun, (10.7)

where 0 < σ < 1.

The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these two

elements:

L = π2 + b[u− u∗]2, (10.8)

where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemployment at

u∗. If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and (11.86), we obtain

L = π2 + b[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)]2. (10.9)

1. Assume the PPP to hold, i.e.

et = pt − p∗t , (10.10)

where et is the exchange rate in period t, and p∗ is the foreign price

level. Assume that the foreign price level is fixed at p∗ = 0, and

that foreign inflation, π∗, is zero. Discuss the relationship between

domestic inflation, π, and the depreciation of the exchange rate,·e, under these assumptions.

2. We assume that the government focuses on the exchange rate in-

stead of the price level. Give some arguments for why a govern-

ment could choose to focus monetary policy on a stable exchange

295

Page 299: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rate instead of controlling the money supply.

3. Assume that the exchange rate is fixed, so that et = e. This

implies that·e = 0. If the government adjusts the fixed rate this

will have the cost of C. As long as the regime is fixed at et = e,

C = 0. If the rate is adjusted, C > 0. The loss function can now

be written as

L =·e2+ b[(1− σ)un + a(

·e

e− ·

e)]2 + C·e, (10.11)

where·e

eis expected depreciation. Explain why C might be posi-

tive.

4. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible and the govern-

ment does not adjust the exchange rate. Calculate the loss of the

government.

5. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible. Discuss un-

der which circumstances the government might have incentive to

change the exchange rate. What is the role of C?

6. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is not credible. Assume the

market expects the government to devalue the exchange rate, i.e.

assume·e

e> 0. How would this affect optimal government policy?

7. In the light of the above results, discuss the term “self-fulfilling

speculative attacks”.

Lecture 5

1. The Krugman model

Country A is a developing country with a long history of high

296

Page 300: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

inflation. The money demand is given by

mt − pt = −η(Etpt+1 − pt). (10.12)

Assume that PPP holds, so that the exchange rate on log-form,

e, is given by

et = pt − p∗t . (10.13)

For simplicity we set p∗ = 0, and assume that foreign inflation

is zero. If we assume perfect foresight, and use continuous time

notation, so that

et+1 − et =·e, (10.14)

we can write the money demand function as

mt − et = −η·e. (10.15)

Money supply, M (remember that m = log(M)) reflects the cen-

tral bank asset sheet. We remember that the central bank has

two main types of assets, foreign reserves and domestic govern-

ment bonds. We can therefore write M as

M = D + R, (10.16)

where D is domestic bonds, and R is foreign reserves. The central

bank only hold foreign reserves when the exchange rate is fixed.

The exchange rate is fixed at a level e = e. This implies that the

money supply is fixed at a level m = m. However, assume that

the central banks holdings of domestic bonds grow at a rate µ.

297

Page 301: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The size of domestic credit at time t will be given by

dt = d0 + µt. (10.17)

(a) If domestic credit grows at a speed µ and the exchange rate

shall remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply?

Which implication will this have for the level of foreign re-

serves, R?

Assume that domestic credit grows by 20 per cent a year, so

that µ = 0.2. Assume that initial domestic credit is D0 = 10

and initial foreign reserves are R0 = 90. At what time will

R = 0 if this policy is not changes?

(b) If we use the above model, and assume money supply growth

at a fixed rate µ, we find the following expression for the

exchange rate:

et = mt + µη. (10.18)

The “shadow exchange rate”, e, is defined as the exchange rate

that would have been the actual exchange rate if a speculative

attack had already happened. Assume that the government

continues the policy of fixed growth in domestic credit forever.

Identify the shadow exchange rate given our definition of M .

(c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will

happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals

the shadow exchange rate, or e = e. Illustrate the paths of e

and e. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T .

(d) Assume that η = 2. Find T .

2. Tobin tax

298

Page 302: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Assume that we have a fixed exchange rate. The rate is fixed at

1:1.

The economy fluctuates between three ‘states’—high output, in-

termediate output and low output. Assume that the government

believes the costs of a devaluation will be high. However, if there

is a speculative attack, the government will devalue the currency.

How much will depend on the state of the economy. In the low

output state the new exchange rate will be 1.5:1. In the interme-

diate state the exchange rate will be 1.25:1. In the good state the

government will not make a shift.

The central bank has committed 10 million domestic currency

units to defend the exchange rate. There are two traders in the

market. Each controls 5 million domestic currency units. If the

trader sells his domestic currency to the central bank he obtains

foreign currency at the rate 1:1. If there is a devaluation, he can

exchange back at the new rate. If there is no cost of speculation his

profit will be the amount of foreign currency times the change in

the exchange rate. Example: sell 4 million, exchange rate devalue

to 1.5:1. Profit: (1.5-1)*4=2.

(a) Assume that the cost of speculation is 1. Calculate the profit

of each trader if he sells and the other holds, and if he holds

and the other sells, and if both hold and both sell for all three

states of the economy. Organise your findings in three two by

two matrixes. Identify Nash equilibria for all three cases.

(b) Let the cost of speculation increase from 1 to 1.5. Will any

of the above Nash equilibria change? How? Discuss the con-

sequences.

299

Page 303: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(c) Discuss whether or not this is a good argument for introducing

a Tobin tax.

Lecture 6

1. Assuming no transaction costs, suppose GBP=USD 2.4110 in New

York, USD=FRF 3.997 in Paris, and FRF=GBP 0.1088 in Lon-

don. How could you take advantage of these rates?

2. The media frequently report that ”the dollar’s value strengthened

against many currencies in response to the Federal Reserve’s plan

to increase interest rates.” Explain why the dollar’s value is ex-

pected to appreciate, and why the rate may change even before

the Fed affects interest rates.

3. The following quotations are available to you. (You may either

buy or sell at the stated rates.)

Hong Kong Shanghai Bank: FRF/USD=4.8600

Dredsner Bank: DEM/USD=1.4200

Banque National de Paris: FRF/DEM=3.4400

Assume that you have an initial USD 1,000,000. Is triangular

arbitrage possible? If so, explain the steps and compute your

profit.

4. You plan to spend one month at the luxurious Nusa Dua Hotel

in Bali, Indonesia, a year from now. The present charge for a

suitable suite plus meals is Rps 28,800 per night or USD 800 at

the present exchange rate of INR/USD 36.

(a) The Nusa Dua Hotel tells you that next year’s charges will

increase with Indonesian inflation, which you expect to be 16

300

Page 304: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

per cent. U.S. inflation is currently 4 per cent per annum. You

believe implicitly in the theory of purchasing power parity.

How many U.S. dollars will you need one year hence to pay

for your 30-day vacation?

(b) The forward rate on a one year contract is INR/USD=40.

How many dollars do you need one year hence if you enter

into a forward contract today?

(c) On a one year instrument, the US rate of interest is 8 per

cent. What is the rate of interest on a similar instrument in

Indonesia?

5. The United States and France both produce Cabernet Sauvignon

wine. A bottle of Cabernet Sauvignon sell in the United States

for USD 18. An equivalent bottle sells in France for FRF 100.

(a) According to purchasing power parity, what should be the

U.S. dollar/French franc spot rate of exchange?

(b) Suppose the price of Cabernet Sauvignon in the US is ex-

pected to rise to USD 20 over the next year, while the price

of a comparable bottle of French wine is expected to rise to

FRF 118. What should be the one-year forward U.S. dol-

lar/French franc exchange rate?

(c) Given your answers to (a) and (b) above, and given that the

current interest rate in the United States is 6 per cent for

notes of one-year maturity, what would you expect current

French interest rates to be?

6. Suppose today’s spot exchange rate is USD/DEM=0.51. The

six-month interest rates on dollars and DM are 13 per cent and

301

Page 305: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

6 per cent respectively (these are annualised rates). The six-

month forward rate is USD/DEM=0.5273. A foreign exchange

advisory service has predicted that the DEM will appreciate to

USD/DEM=0.54 within six months.

(a) How would you use forward contracts to profit in the above

situation?

(b) How would you use borrowing and lending transactions to

profit?

7. In the 1950s and 1960s many influential economists like Milton

Friedman and Harry Johnson were in favour of floating exchange

rates. Johnson argued that floating exchange rates normally would

”move only slowly and fairly predictably.”

(a) Explain the reasoning behind such a statement.

(b) With the benefit of hindsight we know that exchange rate

fluctuations have been anything but slow and predictable, at

least in the short run. Explain.

Lecture 7

The starting point of the monetary equilibrium model is the real money

demand function, given as

mt − pt = −ηit+1 + φyt. (10.19)

From this we can derive an expression for the price level, given as

pt =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηis+1) + limT→∞

1 + η

)T

pt+T .

(10.20)

302

Page 306: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

If we assume PPP and UIP to hold at all times, and we assume perfect

foresight, we can obtain an expression for the the exchange rate:

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms−φys+ηi∗s+1−p∗s)+ limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T .

(10.21)

1. Define the real exchange rate, Q. What assumption do we make

about the real exchange rate when we assume PPP to hold?

2. Write the assumptions of the uncovered interest rate parity in

mathematical terms. Explain the intuitive argument behind the

UIP. If the PPP holds at all times, and expected depreciation

is zero, what are the implications for the relationship between

domestic and foreign interest rates?

3. Both equation (11.42) and (11.43) contain two elements. The last

element is on the form

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T . (10.22)

(a) What is the implication if

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T 6= 0? (10.23)

(b) Explain the term “rational bubbles”.

(c) One often assumes that

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T = 0. (10.24)

Explain why this is reasonable. Discuss.

303

Page 307: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

4. Assume that the price level is given by

pt =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηis+1), (10.25)

and that the exchange rate is given by

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s). (10.26)

Hold i∗, p∗ and y constant. Assume that m is fixed at m until

time t. At time t therei s an unexpected, permanent contraction

in the money supply. m falls to m′.

(a) What will be the effect to e and p? Illustrate.

(b) What is the effect to inflation? Illustrate.

(c) What is the effect to the interest rate? Illustrate.

5. In the Dornbusch model one assumes that prices are sticky. The

PPP does no longer hold at every point of time, although it does

hold in the long run. However, the UIP still holds.

(a) Making the assumptions of the Dornbusch model, illustrate

the effects to e, p and i of a contractionary shock to money

supply.

(b) Explain the term overshooting. Why does overshooting arise

in this model?

6. What is a chartist? How does the behaviour of a chartist differ

from the behaviour assumed in the monetary equilibrium model?

7. Read the enclosed article by J. Frankel and K. Froot. Explain the

possible role of chartist during the appreciation of the USD from

1980 to 1985.

304

Page 308: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Lecture 8

Domestic investors are assumed to hold two types of assets: domestic

currency, B, and foreign currency, F . Total real wealth, W , denomi-

nated in local currency will be

W =B

P+

εF

P, (10.27)

where ε is the exchange rate. The share of total wealth the investor

chooses to hold in foreign currency is

f =εF

PW. (10.28)

We treat f as the the choice variable of the domestic investor. Given

f , one can compute F = f PWε

and B = (1− f)PW .

Similar, foreign investors hold currency of the home country1, B∗, and

foreign currency, F ∗. Total real wealth held by foreigners, W ∗, denom-

inated in foreign currency will be

W ∗ =B∗

εP ∗ +F ∗

P ∗ . (10.29)

The share of total wealth the foreign investor chooses to hold in do-

mestic currency is

b∗ =B∗

εP ∗W ∗ . (10.30)

We treat b∗ as the the choice variable of foreign investors. Given b∗,

one can compute B∗ = b∗εP ∗W ∗ and F ∗ = (1− b∗)P ∗W ∗.

Expected real return on the portfolio of a domestic investor will be

1The home country is the same throughout the exercise—it is the country of the do-mestic investor, not the foreign investor.

305

Page 309: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

given by

π = (1− f)(i− ·p) + f(i∗ +

·e− ·

p) = (1− f)i + f(i∗ +·e)− ·

p, (10.31)

where i is the interest rate,·p=rate of inflation,

·e=rate of depreciation

and ∗ denotes foreign values. Expected real return on the portfolio of

a foreign investor will be given by

π = (1−b∗)(i∗−·

p∗)+b∗(i− ·e−

·p∗) = (1−b∗)i∗+b∗(i− ·

e)−·

p∗. (10.32)

We assume that·p is a stochastic variable with the distribution

·p ∼ N(µp, σpp). (10.33)

µp is the expected mean of a change in inflation, and σpp is the expected

standard deviation around the mean. Similar, we assume that

·p∗ ∼ N(µp∗ , σp∗p∗), (10.34)

and·e ∼ N(µe, σee). (10.35)

The correlation between·p and

·ee is σep, and the correlation between

·p∗ and

·ee is σep∗ . There is no uncertainty about the interest rate, as it

is observable today.

Last, define the risk premium, r as

r = i− i∗ − µe. (10.36)

306

Page 310: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

1. Investors maximise function of the form

U = E(π)− 1

2Rvar(π). (10.37)

We assume R to be the same for all investors. Find the optimal

f and b∗.

2. Explain the risks of holding a currency in this model.

As you have found, f and b∗ can both be written as two terms:

one that depends on r and one that does not depend on r. Give an

interpretation of these two terms. Explain how a fall in r affects

f and b∗. What is the effect for currency flows?

3. In addition to domestic investors and foreigners there is a domestic

central bank. The holdings of the central bank is denoted as Bg

and F g for domestic currency and foreign currency respectively.

Explain why we must have that

Bg + B + B∗ = 0, (10.38)

and

F g + F + F ∗ = 0. (10.39)

4. Start with the condition F g + F + F ∗ = 0. Insert your findings

for F and F ∗. Show that

δF g

δε> 0 (10.40)

if all investors have positive holdings of both currencies.

5. Draw a diagram with ε on the y-axis, and F g on the x-axis. In-

sert the equilibrium condition of F g using the assumption above.

Explain how F g will change with a change in f , assuming

307

Page 311: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(a) a fixed exchange rate, and

(b) a floating exchange rate.

6. Illustrate the effect of fall in r. Use three graphs:

(a) first assume a fixed exchange rate,

(b) second assume a floating exchange rate,

(c) then assume that the rate is fixed until the foreign reserves

reach a certain level F g. At this point the rate is allowed to

float.

Lecture 9

We are in a two-country world, where each country produce a single

good. The home country produces good H, and the foreign country

good F . Each good has the price of unity measured in the local cur-

rency. The relative price of the two goods, which is the same as the real

exchange rate, Q, will be measured as the price of one unit of foreign

good denominated in home currency,

Q =PF

PH

. (10.41)

A higher Q implies a real depreciation, a lower Q a real appreciation,

seen from the home country.

Total consumption in the home country of good H is CH , and total

consumption of good F is CF . Foreign consumption is C∗H and C∗

F .

Total production of the home country is Y = H, and total production

of the foreign country is Y ∗ = F .

The net capital inflow of the home country is B. B will equal the

308

Page 312: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

negative of the current account,

B = −CA, (10.42)

as we have that the capital account=the current account, and a current

account surplus must give a capital outflow. B reflects capital mobility.

If B is zero, there is no capital mobility. Note that there might still be

trade. However, the trade balance must always be zero.

The rate of absorption, A, is the total consumption and investment

in the home country. We assume no investment and no public sector.

Absorption will then be given as

A = C = Y − CA = Y + B. (10.43)

Similarly, we have that

A∗ = Y ∗ + B∗. (10.44)

Notice that

B∗ =−B

Q, (10.45)

as B∗ is measured in foreign currency, and capital inflow in one country

by definition must equal capital outflow in the other, as we have only

two countries.

There were some sources of confusion in the lecture held May 28. The

questions bellow should help you to resolve these...

1. The following was stated in the Lecture on May 28:

“We have two maximisation problems. For the home

309

Page 313: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

country we have

Max U = C1−mH (QCF )m s.t. A = Y + B = CH + QCF ,

(10.46)

and for the foreign country

Max U∗ =

(C∗

H

Q

)1−m∗

(C∗F )m∗

s.t. A∗ = Y ∗−B

Q=

C∗H

Q+C∗

F .′′

(10.47)

From these two maximisation problems we derived consumption

functions. For the home country we found

CH = (1−m)(Y + B), CF = mY + B

Q, (10.48)

and for the foreign country

C∗H = Qm∗(Y ∗ − B

Q), CF = (1−m∗)(Y ∗ − B

Q). (10.49)

The four consumption functions are correct. However, the max-

imisation problem for the foreign consumers is not. Given the

four consumption functions, make the necessary adjustment of

the maximisation problem.

2. Given what you find above, is it reasonable to assume that

1−m > m∗? (10.50)

3. Explain why

m∗Y ∗ =mY

Q(10.51)

will imply a trade balance of zero.

4. Using the consumption functions above, and the market clearing

310

Page 314: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

clearing condition of

CH + C∗H = Y, (10.52)

and inserting the consumption functions, we derive the market

clearing real exchange rate as

Q =mY

m∗Y ∗ −(1−m−m∗)B

m∗Y ∗ . (10.53)

Find the effect on Q of a change in Y ∗. What does this imply

for the welfare of the home country? Is a positive supply shock

abroad good or bad for the home country?

5. We want to illustrate the effect of a temporary shock in Y , and

how different capital flows affect Q differently.

Use the equation for Q stated above. Assume Y ∗ = 20, m = 1/3

and m∗ = 1/3 in all periods. Ignore the existence of interest on

debt.

We look at 4 periods. In period 0 Y is 20, debt is zero, and the

current account is zero. In period 1 output fall from 20 to 10.

In period 2 output bounces back to 20, and remains constant in

period 3 and 4.

Note that the results are not in line with what was presented

during the lecture...

(a) Assume no capital flows. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B

and total debt.

(b) Assume that the country does not allow A to change in period

1. However debt accumulated in period 1 is to be repaid with

equal amounts in period 2, 3 and 4. Illustrate the paths of Y ,

Q, A, B and total debt.

311

Page 315: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(c) Assume that the country adjusts absorption in period 1, but

with the goal of having the same absorption in period 1, 2,

3 and 4. In the end of period 4 total debt should be zero.

Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt.

Lecture 10

Solve the following problems:

1. Given

Seignoraget = (1− 1

1 + µ)(1 + µ)−η = µ(1 + µ)−η−1, (10.54)

findδSeignoraget

δµ. (10.55)

2. Given

L = π2 + b[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)]2, (10.56)

findδL

δπ. (10.57)

3. Given

L = C1−mH (QCF )m + λ (Y + B − CH −QCF ) , (10.58)

findδL

δCF

. (10.59)

4. Given

U = (1−f)i+f(i∗+µe)−µp−1

2R

[f 2σee + σpp − 2fσep

], (10.60)

312

Page 316: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

findδU

δf. (10.61)

Other questions

1. The Barro-Gordon model (45 %)

We can express the Phillips curve as

u = un + a(πe − π). (10.62)

Here u is the unemployment rate, un is the “non-accelerating in-

flation rate of unemployment”, or NAIRU. π is the observed rate

of inflation, and πe is the expected rate of inflation. If inflation

exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for a short

period be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect in-

flation to exceed expected inflation over time.

We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep

inflation stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the gov-

ernment has as a goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un.

We specifically assume that

u∗ = σun, (10.63)

where 0 < σ < 1.

The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these

two elements:

L = π2 + b[u− u∗]2, (10.64)

where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemploy-

ment at u∗. If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and

313

Page 317: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(11.86), we obtain

L = π2 + b[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)]2. (10.65)

(a) Assume that the government set π = 0, and that this is fully

credible—the public believes the government, so that πe = 0

as well. Show the loss of the government.

(b) Assume that all agents are rational and have perfect foresight.

Why can the government not achieve the loss in (1a)? What

will be the actual rate of inflation in this economy?

(c) Assume two countries have different values for b in their loss

functions. Why would this create a credibility problem if

the two countries tried to establish a fixed currency between

them?

2. The Krugman model (45 %)

Country A is a developing country with a long history of high

inflation. The money demand is given on logarithmic form as

mt − pt = −η(Etpt+1 − pt), (10.66)

where m is the log of the money supply, m = ln(M), p is the log

of the price level, and η is a parameter.

Assume that PPP holds, so that the exchange rate on log-form,

e, is given by

et = pt − p∗t . (10.67)

p∗ is the foreign price level. For simplicity we set p∗ = 0, and as-

sume that foreign inflation is zero. If we assume perfect foresight,

314

Page 318: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

and use continuous time notation, so that

et+1 − et =·e, (10.68)

we can write the money demand function as

mt − et = −η·e. (10.69)

Money supply, M , reflects the central bank asset sheet. The cen-

tral bank has two main types of assets, foreign reserves and do-

mestic government bonds. We can therefore write M as

M = D + R, (10.70)

where D is domestic bonds, and R is foreign reserves. The central

bank will support a fixed exchange rate as long as R > 0.

Three results:

– If the exchange rate is fixed at a level e = e, then·e = 0, so

we must have

e = mt. (10.71)

This implies that the money supply is fixed at a level mt = m.

– If the money supply, M , grows at a fixed rate µ, the exchange

rate is given as:

et = mt + µη. (10.72)

– Note that if a variable X grows at a given rate µ, the value

of ln(Xt) = xt can be stated as a function of the growth rate

and the initial value of x:

xt = x0 + µt. (10.73)

315

Page 319: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

In the following we assume that the exchange rate is initially fixed.

The exchange rate is fixed at e = e = m. We have that

M = D0 + R0. (10.74)

(a) Assume that the central bank’s holdings of domestic govern-

ment bonds, D, grows at a speed µ. If the exchange rate shall

remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply? Which

implication will this have for the level of foreign reserves, R?

Why can this policy be described as “inconsistent”?

(b) The “shadow exchange rate”, e, is given as

et = dt + µη. (10.75)

Explain the term “shadow exchange rate”.

(c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will

happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals

the shadow exchange rate, or e = e. Illustrate the paths of e

and e. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T .

(d) At p. 74 in “International Money”, in the discussion of the

Krugman model, De Grauwe states:

“The timing of the attack is independent of the

stock of international reserves the authorities start

with.”

Find the expression for T . Comment on this statement. What

is independent of the initial stock of reserves?

(e) Illustrate the path of foreign reserves and the money supply.

What happens to money supply at time T? How much does

316

Page 320: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

it change? Give an intuitive understanding of this result.

(f) If the central bank increases its holdings of domestic bonds

at a given rate, what might that tell you about fiscal policy

in this country?

Assume that the government is following the policy described

above. However, the central bank is not increasing its hold-

ings of domestic bonds. Instead the government is borrowing

money abroad. Would this make a difference for the results in

our model? Discuss consequences of the different strategies.

3. High volume—Is it a puzzle? (10 %)

The daily volume in the FX spot market in April 1998 was 600

billion USD. As a comparison, the daily volume in the New York

Stock Exchange in this period was 30 billion USD, and average

daily world trade in goods and services was about 15 billion USD.

Given your knowledge of how the FX-market works, discuss these

fact. What features of the FX market might explain the high

volume of the FX-market compared to other markets?

317

Page 321: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Chapter 11

Solutions

Lecture 1

1. Gresham’s law

(a) Question Gresham’s law states that bad money always will

drive good money out of circulation. People will choose to use

the bad money for transactions, and store the good money.

Explain why.

Solution The point here is that one asset (here currency) has

different value depending on how it is used. Assume that the

currency is in the form of gold coins. When this currency is

used for transactions one unit has a value set by the price

level. However, at the same time the coins has a commodity

value equal to its weight in gold.

The value of a coin as a commodity depends on the gold con-

tent of the coin. The value of a coin as a means of transaction

only depends on the denomination of the coin. If you have

two coins with the same denomination, but different gold con-

tents, you will store the one with more gold. The one with

318

Page 322: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

less gold you will use for transactions. If more bad coins are

introduced, these will be used for transactions, and the good

coins will be stored—bad money drive out good money.

(b) Question Assume a system where two types of coins circulate

in the economy. Some coins are of silver, and some coins are

of gold. Discuss possible problems that can arise in such a

system if there is discovered a huge deposit of silver. Will

silver or gold coins dominate circulation? Will silver or gold

dominate as a store of value?

Solution If supply of silver rise, the value of silver must be

expected to fall. If the relationship between the transaction

value of a silver and a gold coin is fixed, silver is now the bad

coin and gold is the good coin. Silver will drive gold out of

circulation, as people store gold and use silver. Over time the

relationship between the value of a silver and gold coin must

be readjusted if a two metal standard is to be reintroduced.

(c) Question Assume that one has a currency that is backed by

a two-metal standard. Assume that for 35 units of currency

one can claim 1 ounce of gold or 35 ounces of silver at the

central bank. Assume gold supply increases three-fold, while

supply of silver remains constant. How will this affect the

central banks holdings of gold and silver? Will this currency

be “stable”?

Solution In the short-term the exchange ratio in the central

bank remains fixed. However, an increase in the supply of

gold would lead to fall in the relative price of gold to silver

in the commodity markets. So people will bring their paper

319

Page 323: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

money to the central bank to get silver in return, take this

silver abroad and exchange it to gold, and return home and

exchange gold into currency at the central bank. This form

of arbitrage could return a handsome profit.

This is in effect a “silver-run” on the central bank. One should

expect the central bank to lose all its silver within a relatively

short period of time. At this point the central bank must

either change the exchange ratios, or convert to a unilateral

gold standard.

Bilateral currency standards was introduced because central

banks did not have enough gold, and needed a wider basis

for backing of a sufficient money supply. However, as long as

there is a risk of large swings in the relative value of the two

metals, such an arrangement must either be flexible—i.e. the

exchange ratios must be frequently adjusted, or the system

will be prone to currency runs.

2. Fiat money and free banking...

(a) Question Assume that the Norwegian government allows ev-

eryone to print Norwegian kroner on their own colour printers.

What would do you think would happen to the Norwegian

money supply? What will happen to the Norwegian price

level?

Solution The cost of printing notes on a printer is close to

zero. Everyone would expect that everyone else prints as much

as he or she can, so everyone will print as much as he or she

can as well. This can be illustrated by a simple game theoretic

approach (try to use the prisoners dilemma). The solution is

320

Page 324: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

evidently not welfare improving.

(b) At the islands Yap in the Pacific Ocean people used large,

heavy round stones with a hole in the middle as currency. One

stone took two men approximately one week to make. These

stones worked as both unit of account, means of payment and

store of value. However, as they were difficult to carry, the

islanders did not care to carry them around. Instead they

issued legal titles to the stones. These legal titles were used

for trading.

Note that the stones only had value as currency. They had

no value as a commodity.

i. Question What is the difference between the stones on

Yap and the ability to print your own money?

Solution At Yap it took one week of labour to get the new

note finished. There was real cost of producing currency.

ii. Question Explain the fact that inflation on Yap was sta-

ble.

Solution People would produce “currency stones” to the

point where the marginal return of producing one was

equal to the alternative value of labour. If the productiv-

ity growth in the rest of the economy is the same as the

increase in the ability to produce stones, people would

continue to produce the same ratio of stones to the econ-

omy as a whole.

iii. Question What would happen to the price level on Yap

if the islanders got a new technology that would reduce

the time to make a new stone from one week to one day?

321

Page 325: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Should this have any effects for the real economy on Yap?

Solution If productivity in producing stones increased

dramatically, it would be reasonable to produce a lot

more stones. This would induce inflation. The value of

all stones would fall. People who had all their assets in

“stones” would no longer be so rich, while people who had

“stone debts” could no repay these debts with a fraction

of the labour. If contracts are stated in nominal terms

(contracts are stated as the number of stones owed, not

as the number of stones owed as a fraction of the price

level) money will not be neutral in this system.

3. Seignorage

(a) Question Seignorage is given by

Seignoraget =Mt −Mt−1

Pt

. (11.1)

We know that real money demand can be written as

Mt

Pt

= Et

(Pt+1

Pt

)−η

. (11.2)

Assume perfect foresight. Further, assume that the central

bank can commit to a fixed rate of money growth for all fu-

ture, µ, so thatMt

Mt−1

= 1 + µ. (11.3)

Use this information to show that the rate of money growth,

µopt, that will maximise seignorage revenue is equal to 1η.

Solution The following list of equations go through the whole

322

Page 326: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

derivation:

St =Mt −Mt−1

Pt

St =Mt −Mt−1

Mt

Mt

Pt

Mt

Pt

=

(Pt+1

Pt

)−η

St =Mt −Mt−1

Mt

(Pt+1

Pt

)−η

St =

(1− Mt−1

Mt

) (Pt+1

Pt

)−η

Mt

Mt−1

= 1 + µ =Pt

Pt−1

St =

(1− 1

1 + µ

)(1 + µ)−η

St =

1 + µ

)(1 + µ)−η

St = µ (1 + µ)−1 (1 + µ)−η

St = µ (1 + µ)−η−1

∂St

∂µ= (1 + µ)−η−1 + µ (−η − 1) (1 + µ)−η−2 = 0

1− µ (η + 1) (1 + µ)−η−2

(1 + µ)−η−1 = 0

1− µ (η + 1) (1 + µ)−1 = 0

(1 + µ)− (µη + µ) = 0

1− µη = 0

µ =1

η

(b) Question Average growth in Norwegian M1 over the period

from December 1992 to January 2002 has been 9.48 per cent

323

Page 327: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

on a yearly basis. Assume that Norges Bank behaves accord-

ing to the rule of optimal seignorage. Find η.

Solution η = 1µ⇒ η = 1

0.0948= 10.55

(c) Question Assuming constant money growth, the formula for

seignorage can be written

Seignoraget = µ(1 + µ)−η−1. (11.4)

Calculate seignorage for Norway.

Solution Seignoraget = µ(1+µ)−η−1 = 0.0948(1+0.0948)−10.55−1 =

0.0333

(d) Question We want to find seignorage as a percentage of pub-

lic expenditure. Note that in equation (11.4) seignorage is

measured as a fraction of the price level. For our purposes it

is reasonable to approximate the price level with the money

stock in the last period. In January 2002 Norwegian M1 was

382.6 billion NOK. The public expenditure for 2001 was ex-

pected to be 487.9 billion NOK. Calculate seignorage as a

percentage of government expenditure for Norway. Compare

your number with the numbers in Box 8.1 in Obstfeld and

Rogoff, ch. 8.2.

Solution Seigniorage as per cent of public expenditure:

St ·M1t

Public expenditure=

0.0333 · 382.6

487.9= 0.0261. (11.5)

Our estimate is that seignorage amounts to 2.61 per cent of

public expenditure in Norway. As one can see from Box 8.1

in Obstfeld and Rogoff this is in line with estimates for other

industrialised countries.

324

Page 328: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Lecture 2

1. Given the data given in the exercise, compute the values of the

money supply and the monetary base.

Solution: Money supply: 9750, money base: 900

2. Next, assume that the Argentinean real exchange rate appreci-

ates vis-a-vis USD. Provide one or two sentences to say what this

means. This question should be answered abstractly, without ref-

erences to the above data. Your answer should be expressed in

intuitive terms, using plain, jargon-free language.

3. Now suppose that, because of the ARP real appreciation, an Ar-

gentinean importer wants to import some U.S. goods. Specifically,

she wants to import 18 dollars worth of machines. This means that

she needs to obtain USD 18.

(a) First, suppose the importer goes to her commercial bank and

asks for USD 18. The commercial bank turns to a trader in an

American bank, and asks him to sell it USD 18 in return for

ARP 18. Assume the trade goes through, and the importer

receives USD 18 from its bank in return for ARP 18. What

is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base?

Solution: This transactions does not involve the currency

board. The money base is not affected.

(b) Second, suppose that, because of the overvaluation, the trader

at the American bank will not sell USD for ARP at 1:1. He

might sell each USD for 1.2 ARP, but if he did then the fixed

exchange rate would have de facto collapsed. The good news

for the Argentinean importer is that the currency board is

325

Page 329: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

obliged to sell her USD at 1:1. The commercial bank will

trade ARP 18 for USD 18 by sending a request to the currency

board.

What is the currency board supposed to do with the pesos it

receives for these USD? If the currency board does this, what

is the effect on the Argentinean monetary base?

Solution: The currency board is supposed to burn the ARPs

it receive. To keep the balance sheet in balance, the amount

of ARP issued must match the reserve holdings of USD. If

reserves are reduced with 18, the amount of money issued

must be reduced by 18.

(c) According to the quantity theory of money, money (M) times

the number of transactions conducted with money (velocity,

V ) should equal the price level, P , times the number of trans-

actions in the economy, T , or

M · V = P · T. (11.6)

We can simplify by assuming that velocity is constant, and

that T can be set equal to to total production in the economy,

Y .

Do you think the actions by the currency board described

above will alleviate the overvaluation of the Argentinean peso?

Why?

Solution: According to the QTM a contraction of the money

base should lead to lower prices. It the Argentinean price level

falls, the real exchange rate of Argentina devalues. This will

alleviate the overvaluation.

326

Page 330: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(d) What will happen if, for some reason, this process continues?

That is, what will happen if Argentineans try to convert all

their ARP-denominated bank deposits into USD?

Solution: If the process continues, the currency board will

run out of USD. At this point Argentina must either float

the peso or impose capital controls. If the process continues

further the banks will collapse. The reason is that the hold-

ings of the currency board only back-up the currency, not the

entire monetary supply.

4. Given the transaction by the Argentinean importer, what will hap-

pen to the Argentinean current account once this transaction oc-

curs? Will there be change in the direction of trade flows? How

will capital flows be affected?

Solution: If the overvaluation in Argentina is alleviated, Argen-

tine goods become more attractive in foreign markets, and foreign

goods less attractive in Argentina. The Argentinean trade deficit

will be reduced. Capital flows that are necessary to finance the

trade deficit will abate.

5. Once the Argentinean importer has obtained the USD 18, you

should find that the system of balance sheets are no longer ‘in

equilibrium’. That is, the two ratios discussed above are no longer

12 and 60. Use the four linear equations described in the appendix

to compute the new equilibrium. What is the new money supply?

Is this new value for the money supply consistent with alleviating

the overvaluation problem?

327

Page 331: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Solution: The four equations can be expressed as:

C =60H

12 + 60

R = H − C

L = (60− 1)R

D = 12C.

H is given as 900− 18 = 882. We then find that

C = 735

R = 147

L = 8673

D = 8820.

The new money supply will be 9555, which is less than 9750. This

is consistent with alleviating the overvaluation. The money supply

has decreased, which will decrease prices and make the real value

of ARP fall.

The economics behind this might go as follows. Upon seeing re-

serves fall below a safe level, commercial banks start to call in

loans. This causes interest rates to rise. The increase in interest

328

Page 332: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rates induces a fall in the level of economic activity and a drop in

national income. The latter reduces the demand for goods, as well

as money, thereby pushing the domestic price level down. The re-

duction in domestic demand, in addition to the depreciation of

the real exchange rate, tends to push the current account balance

toward surplus.

6. The money multiplier is defined as the ratio of the reduction in the

money supply to the reduction in the monetary base. The money

multiplier tells us how fast the supply of money grows if another

unit of monetary base is created. What is the money multiplier

here? If the central bank prints one more piece of currency, how

much will the total money supply grow, and therefore how much

will the price level increase (if V and Y is constant)?

Solution: The money multiplier is

9750− 9555

18= 10.83 (11.7)

The important point in the example above is to show that a currency

board has a ‘self-correcting’ aspect to it. Excessive inflation (relative

to the reserve country) and/or real exchange rate overvaluation should

be corrected if the currency board does what it is supposed to do. In

addition, the example points out that a county with a currency board

has effectively given up any sort of active monetary policy. Monetary

policy becomes a currency printing/burning robot.

329

Page 333: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Lecture 3

1. Question What do we mean with the n-1 problem in a multilat-

eral exchange rate system?

Solution The n-1 problem relates to the fact that when two cur-

rencies have a fixed exchange rate, the ratio of the money supplies

in the two countries is fixed. Two currencies and one exchange

rate implies one monetary policy. If the money supply of one coun-

try changes, the money supply of the other country must change

as well. In a multilateral exchange rate agreements all countries

must agree on changes in the money supply. If two countries dis-

agree about the optimal money supply, the system can not survive

unless one of the parties is willing to compromise.

2. Question Assume that the UIP holds. Use the n-1 problem to

illustrate the strains put on the EMS-system by the German uni-

fication.

Solution See De Grauwe, ch. 2.2.

The German contraction of the money supply lead to a reduced

demand for e.g. the French franc. The “market rate” of DEM

appreciated, and the “market rate” of the FRF depreciated. To

assure that the system was held within the established target zone

either Germany had to increase its money supply or France had

to reduce its money supply.

In the early 1990’s the Bundesbank’s policy clearly did not fit sev-

eral of the other countries in the EMS. The system got a credibility

problem. The countries with a weak commitment to fix their rates

within the EMS left the system in 1992. However, France never

330

Page 334: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.1: Money supply shock in Germany...

DEM/ECU

MDEM

SoDEM

S1DEM

DDEM

The Bundesbank contracted the German money supply to contain inflationarypressure.

331

Page 335: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.2: And the consequences for France

FRF/ECU

MFRF

SFRF

D1FRF

D0FRF

A money supply shock in Germany decreased demand for FRF. To hold theexchange rate within the target zone France needed to contract their moneysupply as well.

332

Page 336: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.3: A change in the target zone

DEM/ECU

MDEM

SoDEM

S1DEM

DDEM New zone

A change in the target zone would have allowed the Bundesbank to contractthe German money supply without putting strains on the fixed exchange rate.

devalued its exchange rate. It was forced to widen the target zone

of exchange rate fluctuations in 1993, however.

3. Question In a meeting in 1991 Germany suggested to revalue the

DEM inside the EMS system (increase the value of DEM relative

to the other currencies in the system). Could this have alleviated

the strains on the system?

Solution A German appreciation would have shifted the target

zone up in the case of France, and down in the case of Germany.

This would have allowed Germany to decrease its money supply

without affecting the money supply of France.

4. Question France vetoed the German suggestion. Why would the

French do this?

333

Page 337: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Solution Some possible arguments:

– France believed that the fixed exchange rate was an important

symbol for European integration. Changing the rate could

endanger the credibility of the system.

– France probably wanted to put pressure on Germany to com-

promise. After all the EMS was a multilateral agreement, and

it was problematic that the Bundesbank acted without regard

to common European goals.

– It was not clear that the FRF was overvalued. In fact the FRF

remained relatively stable against the DEM over the period

from 1990 to 1998. A de facto devaluation of the FRF could

have lead to increased inflation in France.

Lecture 4

1. Assume the PPP to hold, i.e.

et = pt − p∗t , (11.8)

where et is the exchange rate in period t, and p∗ is the foreign price

level. Assume that the foreign price level is fixed at p∗ = 0, and

that foreign inflation, π∗, is zero. Discuss the relationship between

domestic inflation, π, and the depreciation of the exchange rate,·e, under these assumptions.

Solution If p∗ = 0 ⇒ et = pt, so we must have that·e = π.

2. We assume that the government focuses on the exchange rate in-

stead of the price level. Give some arguments for why a govern-

ment could choose to focus monetary policy on a stable exchange

334

Page 338: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rate instead of controlling the money supply.

Solution By focusing on the exchange rate the government can

achieve a number of things:

– In a fixed exchange rate regime money growth will be de-

termined by factors outside the central bank. This might

increase credibility in monetary policy.

– Unlike e.g. an inflation target, where the results of current

monetary policy can first be observed after some time, an

exchange rate is immediately observable in the market.

– A stable exchange rate might have positive implications for

trade.

3. Assume that the exchange rate is fixed, so that et = e. This

implies that·e = 0. If the government adjusts the fixed rate this

will have the cost of C. As long as the regime is fixed at et = e,

C = 0. If the rate is adjusted, C > 0. The loss function can now

be written as

L =·e2+ b[(1− σ)un + a(

·e

e− ·

e)]2 + C·e, (11.9)

where·e

eis expected depreciation. Explain why C might be posi-

tive.

Solution By adjusting the exchange rate the government might

indicate that it is not really committed to a fixed rate. There

might arise doubts about future monetary policy—i.e. the gov-

ernment loose credibility. One result might be higher interest rates

in the future, as the markets no longer trust the fixed exchange

rate.

335

Page 339: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

4. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible and the govern-

ment does not adjust the exchange rate. Calculate the loss of the

government.

Solution Here we have that·e = 0 and

·e

e= 0. So

L = b[(1− σ)un]2. (11.10)

5. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is credible. Discuss un-

der which circumstances the government might have incentive to

change the exchange rate. What is the role of C?

Solution The rate of depreciation that minimises the government

loss will be given by

δL

δ·e

= 2·e− 2ab[(1− σ)un + a(

·e

e− ·

e)] + C = 0. (11.11)

This gives us an optimal policy of

·e

opt=

ab(1− σ)un

1 + ba2+

ba2 ·ee

1 + ba2− C

1 + ba2. (11.12)

I this case·e

e= 0. It will only be optimal to set

·e > 0 if

ab(1− σ)un > C. (11.13)

The cost of adjusting the rate increases the credibility of the

regime.

6. Assume that the fixed exchange rate is not credible. Assume the

market expects the government to devalue the exchange rate, i.e.

assume·e

e> 0. How would this affect optimal government policy?

Solution In this case it would be optimal to change the exchange

336

Page 340: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

rate if

ab(1− σ)un + ba2 ·ee> C. (11.14)

Notice that in this case the left hand side is notably larger, as

ab(1− σ)un + ba2 ·ee> ab(1− σ)un. (11.15)

In words: the probability of devaluation being the optimal policy

has increased.

7. In the light of the above results, discuss the term “self-fulfilling”

speculative attacks.

Solution (Very short) The implication of the above results is

that the cost of devaluing depends on market expectations. If

the market expects a devaluation, this makes a devaluation a less

costly policy option.

Lecture 5

1. The Krugman model

(a) If domestic credit grows at a speed µ and the exchange rate

shall remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply?

Which implication will this have for the level of foreign re-

serves, R?

Assume that domestic credit grows by 20 per cent a year, so

that µ = 0.2. Assume that initial domestic credit is D0 = 10

and initial foreign reserves are R0 = 90. At what time will

R = 0 if this policy is not changes?

Solution If the exchange rate shall remain fixed, the money

supply must remain equal to M . This implies that an absolute

337

Page 341: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

increase in domestic credit must be reflected by an absolute

fall in foreign reserves. We have that M0 = 90 + 10 = 100.

So when D = 100, R must by definition be zero. When is

D = 100?

ln(100) = ln(10) + 0.2 · t ⇒ t = 11.5. (11.16)

With this policy foreign reserves will be zero in 11.5 years.

(b) If we use the above model, and assume money supply growth

at a fixed rate µ, we find the following expression for the

exchange rate:

et = mt + µη. (11.17)

The “shadow exchange rate”, e, is defined as the exchange rate

that would have been the actual exchange rate if a speculative

attack had already happened. Assume that the government

continues the policy of fixed growth in domestic credit forever.

Identify the shadow exchange rate given our definition of M .

Solution After a speculative attack foreign reserves goes to

zero. So the money supply will only consist of domestic credit.

We obtain

et = dt + µη = d0 + µt + µη. (11.18)

(c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will

happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals

the shadow exchange rate, or e = e. Illustrate the paths of e

and e. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T .

Solution Assume that the fixed exchange rate equals the

shadow rate at time T . Let the fixed exchange rate collapses

338

Page 342: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.4: Fixed vs. shadow rate

time

time

time

Tlog exchange rate

log foreign reserves

log money supply

Shadow floating rate

Fixed rate

Level of foreign reserves attime of attack

at a T + 2. In this case the shadow rate will exceed the fixed

rate. The fixed rate is terminated at this point, the exchange

rate must make a jump from e to e. A discrete jump in the

exchange rate will imply infinite profit opportunities for ratio-

nal speculators. As everyone have perfect foresight, everyone

will try to sell the domestic currency at time T + 1. Hence,

the speculative attack will take place at T + 1. However, at

T + 1 the jump will still be discrete. So everyone will sell at

T . Why not sell at T − 1? Simply because one would lose

money by doing so. If everyone sell at T − 1 the exchange

rate actually will appreciate, as the shadow rate at this time

is lower than the fixed rate.

(d) Assume that η = 2. Find T .

339

Page 343: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Solution We have that by definition e = ln(M) = ln(D0 +

R0). At T we have that

e = ln(D0 + R0) = d0 + µT + µη. (11.19)

We insert the information above to obtain

ln(10 + 90) = ln(10) + 0.2 · T + 0.2 · 2. (11.20)

We can then find T as

T =ln(D0 + R0)− d0 − µη

µ=

ln(10 + 90)− ln(10)− 0.2 · 20.2

= 9.5.

(11.21)

The fixed exchange rate will collapse after 9.5 years of this

policy, 2 years before the foreign reserves would have been

empty without a speculative attack.

2. Tobin tax

(a) Assume that the cost of speculation is 1. Calculate the profit

of each trader if he sells and the other holds, and if he holds

and the other sells, and if both hold and both sell for all three

states of the economy. Organise your findings in three two by

two matrixes. Identify Nash equilibria for all three cases.

Solution The following three illustration give the results in

the three cases. We have one Nash equilibrium (hold, hold)

in the case if output is high, and two equilibria [(hold, hold)

and (sell, sell)] in the case if output is low or intermediate.

(b) Discuss the consequence of an increase in the cost of specu-

lation from 1 to 1.5. Will any of the above Nash equilibria

change?

340

Page 344: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.5: High output

0,0

-1,-1-1,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

341

Page 345: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.6: Intermediate output

0,0

1/4,1/4-1,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

342

Page 346: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.7: Low output

0,0

3/2,3/2-1,0

0,-1

Hold

Hold

Sell

Sell

Trader 1

Trader 2

343

Page 347: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Solution The Nash equilibrium will change in the intermedi-

ate case. We move from two equilibria to one equilibrium with

(hold, hold). This increases the ability of the government to

hold the exchange rate stable over the business cycle.

(c) Discuss whether or not this is a good argument for introducing

a Tobin tax.

Solution Increasing the cost of speculation might reduce the

willingness of speculators to take speculative positions. How-

ever, there are some problems:

– To avoid speculation when investors expect a substantial

change in the exchange rate would imply that one needs

a very high tax. The higher the tax, the more stability

the tax will provide. However, the higher the tax, the

higher the potential problems of such a tax. It is not

certain that the cost of high tax can justify the potential

stability introduced by such a tax.

– A tax in only one country could lead to capital flight from

this country.

– With the use of financial derivatives speculators can use

other financial markets to do much of the same as they do

in the FX market. It is very difficult to have such control

over the financial markets that “tax avoidance” can be

efficiently stopped.

344

Page 348: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Lecture 6

1. Assuming no transaction costs, suppose GBP=USD 2.4110 in New

York, USD=FRF 3.997 in Paris, and FRF=GBP 0.1088 in Lon-

don. How could you take advantage of these rates?

Solution Assume the two dollar rates to be “correct”. Then the

GBP/FRF rate should be

GBP/FRF =GBP/USD

FRF/USD=

12.4110

3.997= 0.10377 6= 0.01088.

(11.22)

⇒ The FRF is expensive in London. Triangular arbitrage does

not hold. Strategy: use FRF 1,000,000 to buy GBP in London.

⇒ obtain GBP 108,800.

sell GBP 108,800 in New York

⇒ obtain USD 262319.

sell USD 262319 in Paris

⇒ obtain FRF 1048480.

⇒ Profit=FRF 48480.

2. The media frequently report that ”the dollar’s value strengthened

against many currencies in response to the Federal Reserve’s plan

to increase interest rates.” Explain why the dollar’s value is ex-

pected to appreciate, and why the rate may change even before

the Fed affects interest rates.

Solution Higher interest rates means a monetary contraction.

According to the monetary equilibrium model a monetary con-

traction should lead to an appreciation of the exchange rate, as

money supply, m, fall. According to the Dornbusch model we

should expect a monetary contraction to lead to an immediate

345

Page 349: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

appreciation, followed by a depreciation.

If the Federal Reserve signals a change in interest rates, investors

will update their expectations. As we have seen in the monetary

equilibrium model, the exchange rate depends on expectations

of the future values of fundamental variables. new information

should immediately be incorporated in the exchange rate, even

before the change has come into effect.

3. The following quotations are available to you. (You may either

buy or sell at the stated rates.)

Hong Kong Shanghai Bank: FRF/USD=4.8600

Dredsner Bank: DEM/USD=1.4200

Banque National de Paris: FRF/DEM=3.4400

Assume that you have an initial USD 1,000,000. Is triangular

arbitrage possible? If so, explain the steps and compute your

profit.

Solution The cross rates from Dresdner and BNP implies a FRF/USD

of

FRF/USD =FRF/USD

USD/DEM=

4.86001

1.4200

= 4.8848 6= 4.8600.

(11.23)

You should find that by investing FRF 100 you can make a profit

of FRF 0.51029.

4. You plan to spend one month at the luxurious Nusa Dua Hotel

in Bali, Indonesia, a year from now. The present charge for a

suitable suite plus meals is Rps 28,800 per night or USD 800 at

the present exchange rate of INR/USD 36.

(a) The Nusa Dua Hotel tells you that next year’s charges will

346

Page 350: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

increase with Indonesian inflation, which you expect to be 16

per cent. U.S. inflation is currently 4 per cent per annum. You

believe implicitly in the theory of purchasing power parity.

How many U.S. dollars will you need one year hence to pay

for your 30-day vacation?

Solution

800USD · (1 + 1.04) · 30 = 24, 960USD (11.24)

(b) The forward rate on a one year contract is INR/USD=40.

How many dollars do you need one year hence if you enter

into a forward contract today?

Solution In one year you need

28, 800 · (1 + 0.16) · 30 = 1, 002, 240INR (11.25)

If the forward contract is at 40 INR= 1 USD, you need

1, 002, 240

40= 25, 056USD (11.26)

in one year.

(c) On a one year instrument, the US rate of interest is 8 per

cent. What is the rate of interest on a similar instrument in

Indonesia?

Solution If you use numbers from (b):

F = ε1 + i

1 + i∗⇒ i = 1− 40 · 1 + 0.08

36= 0.2. (11.27)

5. The United States and France both produce Cabernet Sauvignon

wine. A bottle of Cabernet Sauvignon sell in the United States

347

Page 351: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

for USD 18. An equivalent bottle sells in France for FRF 100.

(a) According to purchasing power parity, what should be the

U.S. dollar/French franc spot rate of exchange?

Solution

ε =100FRF

18USD⇒ 1USD = 5.5556FRF. (11.28)

(b) Suppose the price of Cabernet Sauvignon in the US is ex-

pected to rise to USD 20 over the next year, while the price

of a comparable bottle of French wine is expected to rise to

FRF 118. What should be the one-year forward U.S. dol-

lar/French franc exchange rate?

Solution

F =118FRF

20USD⇒ 1USD = 5.90FRF. (11.29)

(c) Given your answers to (a) and (b) above, and given that the

current interest rate in the United States is 6 per cent for

notes of one-year maturity, what would you expect current

French interest rates to be?

Solution

5.90 = 5.55561 + i

1 + 0.06⇒ i = 0.1257. (11.30)

6. Suppose today’s spot exchange rate is USD/DEM=0.51. The six-

month interest rates on dollars and DM are 13 per cent and 6 per

cent respectively. The six-month forward rate is USD/DEM=0.5273.

A foreign exchange advisory service has predicted that the DEM

will appreciate to USD/DEM=0.54 within six months.

348

Page 352: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(a) How would you use forward contracts to profit in the above

situation?

Solution A forward contract implies that you get a certain

amount of currency at some time in the future. You will pay

the contract at delivery.

If you buy 100 DEM at the current forward rate, you will have

to have to pay out 100 · 0.5273 = 52.73 USD in 6 months.

However, if the advisory is correct, in 6 months 100 DEM will

give 54.00 USD. How to make a profit? Assume that the spot

rate in 6 months really will be 0.54. Contract to sell 52.73

USD in 6 months. You get 100 DEM. Exchange these back to

USD at the spot rate. You will now hold 54.00 USD. Profit

equals 54.00-52.73=1.27 USD.

(b) How would you use borrowing and lending transactions to

profit?

Solution Assume the spot rate in 6 moths will actually be

0.54. Borrow 51 USD at 13 per cent today. In six months you

will have to repay 54.32 USD. Exchange to DEM at current

rate, obtain 100 DEM. Invest in Germany at 6 percent for 6

months, in 6 months you obtain 103. Exchange back at the

rate USD/DEM=0.54. You will get 103∗0.54 = 55.62. Profit

will be 55.62− 54.32 = 1.30 USD.

7. In the 1950s and 1960s many influential economists like Milton

Friedman and Harry Johnson were in favour of floating exchange

rates. Johnson argued that floating exchange rates normally would

”move only slowly and fairly predictably.”

(a) Explain the reasoning behind such a statement.

349

Page 353: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Solution The market knows better than governments what

is the true value of the currency. Speculation would be sta-

bilising rather than destabilising. A speculator who increased

the magnitude of exchange rate fluctuations could only do so

by buying high and selling low, which is a recipe for going out

of business rather quickly.

(b) With the benefit of hindsight we know that exchange rate

fluctuations have been anything but slow and predictable, at

least in the short run. Explain.

Solution Lecture 6 discusses a number of avenues to under-

standing this “puzzle”. In fact, there is no good answer.

Lecture 7

The starting point of the monetary equilibrium model is the real money

demand function, given as

mt − pt = −ηit+1 + φyt. (11.31)

From this we can derive an expression for the price level, given as

pt =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηis+1) + limT→∞

1 + η

)T

pt+T .

(11.32)

If we assume PPP and UIP to hold at all times, and we assume perfect

foresight, we can obtain an expression for the the exchange rate:

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms−φys+ηi∗s+1−p∗s)+ limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T .

(11.33)

350

Page 354: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

1. Define the real exchange rate, Q. What assumption do we make

about the real exchange rate when we assume PPP to hold?

Solution

Q = εP ∗

P. (11.34)

where ε is the actual level of the exchange rate, P is the domes-

tic price level and P ∗ is the foreign price level. On logs this is

equivalent to

q = e + p∗ − p. (11.35)

In the PPP we assume that

ε =P

P ∗ . (11.36)

To exact, this is the absolute PPP. The implication of the absolute

PPP must be that Q = 1, or that the log of Q, q, equal 0.

2. Write the assumptions of the uncovered interest rate parity in

mathematical terms. Explain the intuitive argument behind the

UIP. If the PPP holds at all times, and expected depreciation

is zero, what are the implications for the relationship between

domestic and foreign interest rates?

SolutionEtεt+1

εt

=1 + it1 + i∗t

, (11.37)

or on log form as

Etet+1 − et = it − i∗t . (11.38)

The argument behind the UIP is that expected returns in two

similar assets should be the same. The expected uncovered return

of investing in foreign assets should equal the return of investing

351

Page 355: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

in a similar domestic asset.

If expected depreciation is zero, we must have i = i∗ at all times.

3. Both equation (11.42) and (11.43) contain two elements. The last

element is on the form

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T . (11.39)

(a) What is the implication if

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T 6= 0? (11.40)

Solution If the term is not zero, the value of (in this case e)

will diverge from the value implied by “fundamentals”, y, i∗,

p∗ and m.

(b) Explain the term “rational bubbles”.

Solution If the timing of the crash of the bubble is uncertain,

a bubble can exist even if everyone knows it is a bubble. If

we expect prices to rise in this period, and the next period,

and the period after that, we can make money by buying the

asset today. But doing so, we just fuel the bubble—the more

people who buy the asset, the more do prices rise. In fact

everyone find it profitable to let the bubble exist—although

everyone knows that a some time in the future the prices need

to revert to a lower level. “Rational bubbles” are models

where the there is much uncertainty about when the bubble

will collapse.

352

Page 356: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(c) One often assumes that

limT→∞

1 + η

)T

et+T = 0. (11.41)

Explain why this is reasonable. Discuss.

Solution If we assume perfect foresight, as we have done

above, it does seem unreasonable to think that we do not

know when a bubble will end. In other words a bubble can not

exist. However, under less strict assumptions about foresight,

it is less certain whether the assumption of no bubbles will

hold. In the end this is a question about how we believe

expectations to be formed.

4. Assume that the price level is given by

pt =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηis+1), (11.42)

and that the exchange rate is given by

et =1

1 + η

∞∑s=t

1 + η

)s−t

(ms − φys + ηi∗s+1 − p∗s). (11.43)

Hold i∗, p∗ and y constant. Assume that m is fixed at m until

time t. At time t therei s an unexpected, permanent contraction

in the money supply. m falls to m′.

(a) What will be the effect to e and p? Illustrate.

Solution See figure 11.8.

(b) What is the effect to inflation? Illustrate.

Solution There is of course no inflation before and after the

event—m is supposed to be stable in both periods. There will

be deflationary blip in period t.

353

Page 357: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.8: The equilibrium model vs. the disequilibrium model

e

timet

p

timet

i

timet

The whole lines give the solution to an unexpected negative monetary shockin the monetary equilibrium model. This is as discussed in lecture 1 and2. The dashed lines give the movements of e, p and i as is expected in theDornbusch model.

354

Page 358: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(c) What is the effect to the interest rate? Illustrate.

Solution See figure 11.8.

5. In the Dornbusch model one assumes that prices are sticky. The

PPP does no longer hold at every point of time, although it does

hold in the long run. However, the UIP still holds.

(a) Making the assumptions of the Dornbusch model, illustrate

the effects to e, p and i of a contractionary shock to money

supply.

Solution See figure 11.8.

(b) Explain the term overshooting. Why does overshooting arise

in this model?

Solution The UIP states that

Etεt+1

εt

=1 + it1 + i∗t

. (11.44)

We know the long term value of e. We know that i will rise

above i∗ in the period of the contractionary shock, and move

back to i∗ over time. We further know that e will fall in the

period of the shock. If e falls to the long term value of e, there

will be no appreciation over time, and UIP will not hold. So

must fall bellow the long term value of e. This is overshooting.

6. What is a chartist? How does the behaviour of a chartist differ

from the behaviour assumed in the monetary equilibrium model?

Solution A chartist is an investor who bases his investment strat-

egy on historic movements in the asset price. In the equilibrium

model we assume that all historic information is incorporated in

the current price, and that only new information can change this

355

Page 359: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

price. In the equilibrium model past prices should tell nothing

about future price movements.

7. Read the enclosed article by J. Frankel and K. Froot. Explain the

possible role of chartist during the appreciation of the USD from

1980 to 1985.

Lecture 8

1. Investors maximise function of the form

U = E(π)− 1

2Rvar(π). (11.45)

We assume R to be the same for all investors. Find the optimal

f and b∗.

Solution Domestic investors will maximise a function on the form

U = (1−f)i+f(i∗+µe)−µp−1

2R

[f 2σee + σpp − 2fσep

]. (11.46)

We optimse with regard to f , and obtain

δU

δf= −i + (i∗ + µe)−

1

2R [2fσee − 2σep] = 0. (11.47)

Solving (11.84) for f leaves us with

f =σep

σee

+1

Rσee

(i∗ + µe − i). (11.48)

If we substitute in for r we have

f =σep

σee

− r

Rσee

. (11.49)

356

Page 360: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Foreign investors will maximise a function on the form

U = (1− b∗)i∗ + b∗(i− µe)− µp∗ −1

2R [b∗2σee + σp∗p∗ + 2b∗σep∗ ] .

(11.50)

We optimse with regard to b∗, and obtain

δU

δb∗= −i∗ + (i− µe)−

1

2R [2fσee + 2σep∗ ] = 0. (11.51)

Solving (11.51) for b∗ leaves us with

b∗ = −σep∗

σee

− 1

Rσee

(i∗ + µe − i). (11.52)

If we substitute in for r we have

b∗ = −σep∗

σee

+r

Rσee

. (11.53)

2. Explain the risks of holding a currency in this model.

As you have found, f and b∗ can both be written as two terms:

one that depends on r and one that does not depend on r. Give an

interpretation of these two terms. Explain how a fall in r affects

f and b∗. What is the effect for currency flows?

Solution The risk of holding currency is the risk of inflation. If

inflation rise, the currency will lose value. The investor wants to

invest in foreign currency to hedge against inflation risk, and to

earn money on differences in return, reflected by the risk premium.

The term that does not depend on r is the minimum variance

portfolio. This gives the share of holdings of foreign (in the case

of domestic investors) or domestic (in the case of foreign investors)

currency that minimises the risk of inflation to the currency hold-

ings.

357

Page 361: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The term that does depend on r is the speculative portfolio. A fall

in r will lead to an increase in the domestic investors speculative

portfolio holdings of foreign currency. We see that a fall in r will

lead to a fall in the foreign investors holdings of domestic currency.

The implication is a flow from the domestic currency to the foreign

currency.

3. In addition to domestic investors and foreigners there is a domestic

central bank. The holdings of the central bank is denoted as Bg

and F g for domestic currency and foreign currency respectively.

Explain why we must have that

Bg + B + B∗ = 0, (11.54)

and

F g + F + F ∗ = 0. (11.55)

Solution A financial asset must by definition be the liability of

someone else. If I hold a bond, someone has issued that bond.

Money is the liability of the government that has issued it.

4. Start with the condition F g + F + F ∗ = 0. Insert your findings

for F and F ∗. Show that

δF g

δε> 0 (11.56)

if all investors have positive holdings of both currencies.

Solution We have that

F g = −[σep

σee

− r

Rσee

](B

ε+ F

)−

[1 +

σep∗

σee

− r

Rσee

](B∗

ε+ F ∗

).

(11.57)

358

Page 362: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

We want to identify the condition when δF g

δε> 0. This will hold if

δF g

δε=

[σep

σee

− r

Rσee

](B

ε2

)+

[1 +

σep∗

σee

− r

Rσee

](B∗

ε2

).

(11.58)

This can be rewritten as

δF g

δε= f

(B

ε2

)+ (1− b∗)

(B∗

ε2

)> 0. (11.59)

If B > 0 and f > 0 domestic investors hold both currencies, and

the first term is greater than zero. If (1− b∗) > 0 foreign investors

holdings of foreign currency is greater than zero. If B∗ > 0 their

holdings of domestic currency is greater than zero. The last term

must then be greater than zero, and the total must therefore be

greater than zero. The condition will always be satisfied if both

domestic and foreign investors hold a positive amount of both

currencies.

5. Draw a diagram with ε on the y-axis, and F g on the x-axis. In-

sert the equilibrium condition of F g using the assumption above.

Explain how F g will change with a change in f , assuming

(a) a fixed exchange rate, and

(b) a floating exchange rate.

Solution For diagrams, see below. In a fixed exchange rate regime

the central bank must adjust its foreign reserves as supply of for-

eign currency to the central bank changes. In a floating exchange

rate regime the central bank will not intervene in the foreign ex-

change market. In this case the exchange rate must change to

equilibrate the market.

6. Illustrate the effect of fall in r. Use three graphs:

359

Page 363: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(a) first assume a fixed exchange rate,

(b) second assume a floating exchange rate,

(c) then assume that the rate is fixed until the foreign reserves

reach a certain level F g. At this point the rate is allowed to

float.

Lecture 9

1. The following was stated in the Lecture on May 28:

“We have two maximisation problems. For the home

country we have

Max U = C1−mH (QCF )m s.t. A = Y + B = CH + QCF ,

(11.60)

and for the foreign country

Max U∗ =

(C∗

H

Q

)1−m∗

(C∗F )m∗

s.t. A∗ = Y ∗−B

Q=

C∗H

Q+C∗

F .′′

(11.61)

From these two maximisation problems we derived consumption

functions. For the home country we found

CH = (1−m)(Y + B), CF = mY + B

Q, (11.62)

and for the foreign country

C∗H = Qm∗(Y ∗ − B

Q), CF = (1−m∗)(Y ∗ − B

Q). (11.63)

The four consumption functions are correct. However, the max-

imisation problem for the foreign consumers is not. Given the

360

Page 364: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.9: Fixed exchange rate. Fall in r

e

Fg

Monetary policy,fixed rate

Supply of foreigncurrency to thecentral bank

Figure 11.10: Floating exchange rate. Fall in r

e

Fg

Monetary policy,floating rate

Supply of foreigncurrency to thecentral bank

361

Page 365: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

four consumption functions, make the necessary adjustment of

the maximisation problem.

Solution As a general rule we have that if the maximisation prob-

lem is formulated as

U = XnY 1−n s.t. A = X + pY, (11.64)

the solution will be on the form

X = nA, Y = (1− n)Y

p. (11.65)

If you take a closer look, all four consumption functions stated

above are on this form. However, if the maximisation problem for

the foreign country was correct as stated we should expect that

C∗H = (1−m∗)Q(Y ∗ − B

Q), CF = m∗(Y ∗ − B

Q). (11.66)

But I have stated that the consumption function given was cor-

rect, and the maximisation problem wrong. For the consumption

function to be correct, the maximisation problem must be formu-

lated

Max U∗ =

(C∗

H

Q

)m∗

(C∗F )1−m∗

s.t. A∗ = Y ∗ − B

Q=

C∗H

Q+ C∗

F .

(11.67)

2. Given what you find above, is it reasonable to assume that

1−m > m∗? (11.68)

Solution m reflects the share of foreign goods in home consump-

tion, and m∗ is the share of home goods in foreign consumption.

362

Page 366: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

The statement above claims that the share of home goods in home

country consumption exceeds the share of home goods in the for-

eign consumption. That sound reasonable.

3. Explain why

m∗Y ∗ =mY

Q(11.69)

will imply a trade balance of zero.

Solution m∗Y ∗Q is the foreign consumption of home goods in

home currency, or home exports denominated in home currency.

mY is the home consumption of foreign goods in home currency,

or home imports in home currency. If these to sums are equal, the

trade balance is by definition zero.

4. Using the consumption functions above, and the market clearing

clearing condition of

CH + C∗H = Y, (11.70)

and inserting the consumption functions, we derive the market

clearing real exchange rate as

Q =mY

m∗Y ∗ −(1−m−m∗)B

m∗Y ∗ . (11.71)

Find the effect on Q of a change in Y ∗. What does this imply

for the welfare of the home country? Is a positive supply shock

abroad good or bad for the home country?

Solution We find that

δQ

δY ∗ = −mY − (1−m−m∗)B

m∗Y ∗1

Y ∗ = − Q

Y ∗ < 0. (11.72)

A positive supply shock abroad will imply a real appreciation. A

real appreciation means that the value of the home currency has

363

Page 367: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

increased, consumers in the home country can consume more of

the foreign good than before. Should not a real appreciation also

mean less competitiveness? That is not a problem here: remem-

ber home output has not changed, and markets still clear, so all

home output is consumed. The foreign country is richer, and will

consume more of both home and foreign goods. A positive supply

shock in one country will in this case be to the advantage of both

countries.

5. We want to illustrate the effect of a temporary shock in Y , and

how different capital flows affect Q differently.

Use the equation for Q stated above. Assume Y ∗ = 20, m = 1/3

and m∗ = 1/3 in all periods. Ignore the existence of interest on

debt.

We look at 4 periods. In period 0 Y is 20, debt is zero, and the

current account is zero. In period 1 output fall from 20 to 10.

In period 2 output bounces back to 20, and remains constant in

period 3 and 4.

Note that the results are not in line with what was presented

during the lecture...

(a) Assume no capital flows. Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B

and total debt.

Solution See table 11.1.

(b) Assume that the country does not allow A to change in period

1. However debt accumulated in period 1 is to be repaid with

equal amounts in period 2, 3 and 4. Illustrate the paths of Y ,

Q, A, B and total debt at end of period.

Solution See table 11.2.

364

Page 368: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.11: Exchange rate fixed if F g > F g. Fall in re

Fg

Monetary policy,fixed rate

Supply of foreigncurrency to thecentral bank

Fgmin

Monetary policy,floating rate

Table 11.1: FirstPeriods 0 1 2 3 4

Y 20 10 20 20 20Q 1 0.5 1 1 1A 20 10 20 20 20B 0 0 0 0 0

debt 0 0 0 0 0

Table 11.2: SecondPeriods 0 1 2 3 4

Y 20 10 20 20 20Q 1 0 1.167 1.167 1.167A 20 20 50/3 50/3 50/3B 0 10 -10/3 -10/3 -10/3

debt 0 10 10/6 10/3 0

365

Page 369: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(c) Assume that the country adjusts absorption in period 1, but

with the goal of having the same absorption in period 1, 2,

3 and 4. In the end of period 4 total debt should be zero.

Illustrate the paths of Y , Q, A, B and total debt.

Solution See table 11.3. Q appreciate less in period 1 com-

pared to the result above. It also depreciates less in period 2.

Lecture 10

Solve the following problems:

1. Given

Seignoraget = (1− 1

1 + µ)(1 + µ)−η = µ(1 + µ)−η−1, (11.73)

findδSeignoraget

δµ. (11.74)

Solution

δSeignoraget

δµ= (1 + µ)−η−1 − µ(η + 1)(1 + µ)−η−2 = 0. (11.75)

2. Given

L = π2 + b[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)]2, (11.76)

findδL

δπ. (11.77)

Solution

δL

δπ= 2π − 2ab[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)] = 0. (11.78)

366

Page 370: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

3. Given

L = C1−mH (QCF )m + λ (Y + B − CH −QCF ) , (11.79)

findδL

δCF

. (11.80)

Solution

δL

δCF

= mQm(CF )m−1C1−mH −Qλ = 0, (11.81)

4. Given

U = (1−f)i+f(i∗+µe)−µp−1

2R

[f 2σee + σpp − 2fσep

], (11.82)

findδU

δf. (11.83)

Solution

δU

δf= −i + (i∗ + µe)−

1

2R [2fσee − 2σep] = 0. (11.84)

Other questions

1. The Barro-Gordon model (45 %)

We can express the Phillips curve as

u = un + a(πe − π). (11.85)

Here u is the unemployment rate, un is the “non-accelerating in-

flation rate of unemployment”, or NAIRU. π is the observed rate

of inflation, and πe is the expected rate of inflation. If inflation

367

Page 371: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

exceeds expected inflation, the unemployment rate can for a short

period be less than the NAIRU. However, one can not expect in-

flation to exceed expected inflation over time.

We assume that the government has two policy goals: to keep

inflation stable, and to keep unemployment low. In fact, the gov-

ernment has as a goal to keep unemployment at a level u∗ < un.

We specifically assume that

u∗ = σun, (11.86)

where 0 < σ < 1.

The government minimises a loss function, L, that contain these

two elements:

L = π2 + b[u− u∗]2, (11.87)

where b (assumed to be > 0) is the weight on holding unemploy-

ment at u∗. If we substitute in for the equations (11.85) and

(11.86), we obtain

L = π2 + b[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)]2. (11.88)

(a) Assume that the government set π = 0, and that this is fully

credible—the public believes the government, so that πe = 0

as well. Show the loss of the government.

Solution The the loss would be

L = b[(1− σ)un]2. (11.89)

(b) Assume that all agents are rational and have perfect foresight.

Why can the government not achieve the loss in (1a)? What

368

Page 372: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

will be the actual rate of inflation in this economy?

Solution The government can set π at will. If it minimises

its loss function, inflation would be set at:

δL

δπ= 2π − 2ab[(1− σ)un + a(πe − π)] = 0. (11.90)

or

(1+a2b)π = ab[(1−σ)un+a(πe)] ⇒ π =ab(1− σ)un

1 + a2b+

a2bπe

1 + a2b.

(11.91)

If πe = 0 the government would set π 6= 0—it would choose

to use the high credibility to “fool” the public. By setting

inflation¿0 it achieves a lower unemployment rate.

The public will understand the incentives of the government.

They will know the government loss function. Expected infla-

tion will therefore equal actual inflation, π = πe. The inflation

rate will be:

π = πe =ab(1− σ)un

1 + a2b+

a2bπe

1 + a2b⇒ π = πe = ab(1− σ)un.

(11.92)

(c) Assume two countries have different values for b in their loss

functions. Why would this create a credibility problem if

the two countries tried to establish a fixed currency between

them?

Solution If two countries shall fix their common exchange

rate, this implies that the two countries must follow the same

monetary policy over time. This implies that their inflation

rates must be approximately equal over time as well. To see

this, assume that PPP must hold over time. However, as we

369

Page 373: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

can see above, optimal inflation will depend on the parameter

b. If b is different, optimal inflation will not be the same.

One should expect that the country with high b has higher

inflation. This will strain the credibility of the regime.

2. The Krugman model (45 %)

Country A is a developing country with a long history of high

inflation. The money demand is given on logarithmic form as

mt − pt = −η(Etpt+1 − pt), (11.93)

where m is the log of the money supply, m = ln(M), p is the log

of the price level, and η is a parameter.

Assume that PPP holds, so that the exchange rate on log-form,

e, is given by

et = pt − p∗t . (11.94)

p∗ is the foreign price level. For simplicity we set p∗ = 0, and as-

sume that foreign inflation is zero. If we assume perfect foresight,

and use continuous time notation, so that

et+1 − et =·e, (11.95)

we can write the money demand function as

mt − et = −η·e. (11.96)

Money supply, M , reflects the central bank asset sheet. The cen-

tral bank has two main types of assets, foreign reserves and do-

370

Page 374: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

mestic government bonds. We can therefore write M as

M = D + R, (11.97)

where D is domestic bonds, and R is foreign reserves. The central

bank will support a fixed exchange rate as long as R > 0.

Three results:

– If the exchange rate is fixed at a level e = e, then·e = 0, so

we must have

e = mt. (11.98)

This implies that the money supply is fixed at a level mt = m.

– If the money supply, M , grows at a fixed rate µ, the exchange

rate is given as:

et = mt + µη. (11.99)

– Note that if a variable X grows at a given rate µ, the value

of ln(Xt) = xt can be stated as a function of the growth rate

and the initial value of x:

xt = x0 + µt. (11.100)

In the following we assume that the exchange rate is initially fixed.

The exchange rate is fixed at e = e = m. We have that

M = D0 + R0. (11.101)

(a) Assume that the central bank’s holdings of domestic govern-

ment bonds, D, grows at a speed µ. If the exchange rate shall

remain fixed, what must happen to the money supply? Which

371

Page 375: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

implication will this have for the level of foreign reserves, R?

Why can this policy be described as “inconsistent”?

Solution If the exchange rate shall remain fixed, the money

supply must remain equal to M . This implies that an absolute

increase in domestic credit must be reflected by an absolute

fall in foreign reserves. But when reserves go to zero, the

central bank can no longer sustain a fixed exchange rate.

(b) The “shadow exchange rate”, e, is given as

et = dt + µη. (11.102)

Explain the term “shadow exchange rate”.

Solution The shadow exchange rate is the exchange rate that

would have been the actual exchange if a speculative attack

had already taken place. This implies that the shadow ex-

change rate is the exchange rate assuming that R = 0. It will

only depend on the level of D.

(c) According to the Krugman model a speculative attack will

happen in the point T , when the fixed exchange rate equals

the shadow exchange rate, or e = e. Illustrate the paths of e

and e. Explain why a speculative attack must happen at T .

Solution Assume that the fixed exchange rate equals the

shadow rate at time T . Let the fixed exchange rate collapses

at a T + 2. In this case the shadow rate will exceed the fixed

rate. The fixed rate is terminated at this point, the exchange

rate must make a jump from e to e. A discrete jump in the

exchange rate will imply infinite profit opportunities for ratio-

nal speculators. As everyone have perfect foresight, everyone

372

Page 376: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

will try to sell the domestic currency at time T + 1. Hence,

the speculative attack will take place at T + 1. However, at

T + 1 the jump will still be discrete. So everyone will sell at

T . Why not sell at T − 1? Simply because one would lose

money by doing so. If everyone sell at T − 1 the exchange

rate actually will appreciate, as the shadow rate at this time

is lower than the fixed rate.

(d) At p. 74 in “International Money”, in the discussion of the

Krugman model, De Grauwe states:

“The timing of the attack is independent of the

stock of international reserves the authorities start

with.”

Find the expression for T . Comment on this statement. What

is independent of the initial stock of reserves?

Solution We have that by definition e = ln(M) = ln(D0 +

R0). At T we have that

e = m = ln(D0 + R0) = e = d0 + µT + µη. (11.103)

We can then find T as

T =ln(D0 + R0)− d0 − µη

µ. (11.104)

Clearly, the timing of T does depend on R0. The larger R0,

everything else given, the longer it takes before the speculative

attack takes place. However, note that no value of R0 could

stop a speculative attack from taking place—it will only affect

the timing of the attack. A speculative attack is a certain

outcome as long as there is a given growth in domestic credit.

373

Page 377: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

(e) Illustrate the path of foreign reserves and the money supply.

What happens to money supply at time T? How much does

it change? Give an intuitive understanding of this result.

Solution In the fixed exchange rate regime, the exchange rate

is given as

e = m. (11.105)

In the floating regime the exchange rate is given as

et = mt + ηµ. (11.106)

However, at time T we have that e = eT . So we must simul-

taneously have that

m = mT + ηµ. (11.107)

It follows that at time T money supply must fall by

mT −m = −ηµ. (11.108)

The point here is that the functions for the exchange rate

depends on expectations: if money supply is constant, e = m,

but if money supply is growing, e = m + ηµ. As we are

changing from one regime to the other, the money supply

must fall to assure that the arbitrage condition is fulfilled.

For illustrations, see figure 11.12.

(f) If the central bank increases its holdings of domestic bonds

at a given rate, what might that tell you about fiscal policy

in this country?

Assume that the government is following the policy described

374

Page 378: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Figure 11.12: Anatomy of a speculative attack

time

time

time

Tlog exchange rate

log foreign reserves

log money supply

Shadow floating rate

Fixed rate

Level of foreign reserves attime of attack

375

Page 379: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

above. However, the central bank is not increasing its hold-

ings of domestic bonds. Instead the government is borrowing

money abroad. Would this make a difference for the results in

our model? Discuss consequences of the different strategies.

Solution We probably have a case with a government run-

ning fiscal deficits—reflected in their issuance of government

bonds. The independence of the monetary authority form the

fiscal authority is however weak, as the monetary authority

evidently is forced to take up the fiscal debt. As there is

fixed exchange rate, the debt can not be monetised directly.

Instead the central bank builds down reserves.

If the central bank’s holdings of foreign reserves do not change,

then the fixed exchange rate regime remains viable for all fu-

ture. However, it is questionable whether it is possible to

borrow abroad of finance an eternal budget deficit. At some

point the ability to borrow aborad must be expected to dry

up. At this point of time the government must use the for-

eign reserves to repay old debt, and use the money supply

to finance the deficit. So unless policy changes, the result—a

speculative attack—would probably still follow.

3. High volume—Is it a puzzle? (10 %)

The daily volume in the FX spot market in April 1998 was 600

billion USD. As a comparison, the daily volume in the New York

Stock Exchange in this period was 30 billion USD, and average

daily world trade in goods and services was about 15 billion USD.

Given your knowledge of how the FX-market works, discuss these

fact. What features of the FX market might explain the high

376

Page 380: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

volume of the FX-market compared to other markets?

Solution As there are no given solution to this question, every

good discussion should be rewarded.

Two points:

(a) As exchange rate markets are used not only for trade of goods,

but also for the trade of assets between people in different

countries, and because the daily trade in assets are much big-

ger than the daily trade of goods, the turnover in the asset

markets is probably the most relevant comparison if we want

to understand the volume in the FX-market. However, trade

in assets alone is probably not enough to explain the volume

observed.

(b) In class we have presented the “hot-potato-hypothesis”: the

FX-market is a multiple dealer market with low transparency

and low transaction costs. Dealers do not sit long on large

currency positions (at least they tend to close out at night).

When customers approach a dealer with a large trade, the

dealer will try to reduce position by making transactions with

other dealers. Other dealers will be eager to make such deals

because this is the best way to obtain information about what

is going on. Currency will be traded between dealers like a

“hot-potato”.

377

Page 381: Lectures on International Money - Handelshøyskolen BIhome.bi.no/fgl00001/Int_money.pdf · Lectures on International Money Haakon O. Aa Solheim Norwegian School of Management, 2002

Table 11.3: ThirdPeriods 0 1 2 3 4

Y 20 10 20 20 20Q 1 0.125 1.125 1.125 1.125A 20 17.5 17.5 17.5 17.5B 0 7.5 -2.5 -2.5 -2.5

debt 0 7.5 5 2.5 0