lifetime achievement award 2012: bob...

7
2 JUDICATURE e MARCH / APRIL 2013 e VOL 96 NO 5 FOCUS Editor’s Note: Robert A. Kagan is the 2012 recipient of the Lifetime Achieve- ment Award of the Law and Courts Section of the American Political Science Association, recognizing his four decade career as professor of polit- ical science and law at the University of California-Berkeley. The award cites Kagan’s “elegant blend of legal, socio- legal, political, historical, and com- parative analysis” that “redefined the boundaries of the law and courts field.” We asked scholars in the law and courts field to introduce readers to some of the major themes of Kagan’s work and explain its significance for the study of law and public policy both in the United States and abroad. Kagan The Explorer by THOMAS F. BURKE and JEB BARNES Like a botanist in the tropics, intrigued but overwhelmed by a pro- fusion of flora, what Robert Kagan saw when he looked at law and society in the late 20 th and early 21 st Century was law growing everywhere, law pouring out of every institution, law seeping into the nooks and crannies of everyday life, law growing both in its reach and density. Kagan attrib- uted this profusion of law to “the relentless pressures of technological change, geographic mobility, global economic competition, and environ- mental pollution,” which generate new inequalities, new injustices, new risks, and new cultural challenges to old norms. 1 But what is the scholar to do when, as Kagan put it in one article, “there is too much law to study?” 2 What Kagan does, mostly, is to study law not in books or in court- rooms, but in the everyday world where it lives. Perhaps because of his pre-Ph.D. background as a business lawyer, Kagan often studies law in the world of commerce. From his dis- sertation, for which he was employed as a regulator implementing Richard Nixon’s wage and price freeze, to his latest work on pulp mills, diesel buses, and trucks, Kagan is truly a law in society scholar, investigat- ing the life of the law in ordinary, sometimes banal places--fast food restaurants that enforce smoking rules, shipping ports that struggle with labor and environmental rules, and factories that must contend with OSHA inspections. The settings and subjects of Kagan’s research are diverse, but each is part of a quest to understand legal authority and how it works in the world. In this quest Kagan is closely connected to Max Weber, the founder of sociolegal studies. Weber observed that systems of author- ity were changing: Rule by religious leaders, or by charismatic individu- als, was being replaced by “rational- legal” authority. But what would legal authority look like in practice? Weber’s answer, for the most part, was that law would be bureaucratic, centralized and hierarchical. Weber was the prophet of bureaucratic rationalization, the movement of society towards predictable, calcu- lable rules. The legal system’s job in such a society was merely to imple- ment and apply commands created elsewhere, in the political system. But of course much of American law does not look that way. It does much more than apply rules, and it is much more decentralized, more fluid, more unpredictable than Weber’s ideal type. 3 This is the step from 1. Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: The Amer- ican Way of Law (Cambridge: Harvard Univer- sity, 2001). 2. Kagan, What Socio-Legal Scholars Should Do When There Is Too Much Law to Study, 22 J. Law Soc. 140-148 (1995). 3. Indeed Weber struggled about what to make of English common law, which was decen- tralized, unsystematic, and unpredictable, thus in his terms irrational. Max Weber, Max Weber on Law in Economy And Society 315-318 (Edward Shils & Max Rheinstein trans., New York: Clarion, 1954) For a useful commentary, see Anthony Kronman, Max Weber 120-125 (Palo Alto: Stanford University, 1983). LIFETIME ACHIEVEMENT AWARD 2012: BOB KAGAN

Upload: lamtuyen

Post on 05-Oct-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

2 JUDICATURE e MARCH / APRIL 2013 e VOL 96 NO 5

FOCUS

Editor’s Note: Robert A. Kagan is the 2012 recipient of the Lifetime Achieve-ment Award of the Law and Courts Section of the American Political Science Association, recognizing his four decade career as professor of polit-ical science and law at the University of California-Berkeley. The award cites Kagan’s “elegant blend of legal, socio-legal, political, historical, and com-parative analysis” that “redefined the boundaries of the law and courts field.” We asked scholars in the law and courts field to introduce readers to some of the major themes of Kagan’s work and explain its significance for the study of law and public policy both in the United States and abroad.

Kagan The Explorerby Thomas F. Burke and JeB Barnes

Like a botanist in the tropics, intrigued but overwhelmed by a pro-fusion of flora, what Robert Kagan saw when he looked at law and society in the late 20th and early 21st Century was law growing everywhere, law pouring out of every institution, law seeping into the nooks and crannies of everyday life, law growing both in its reach and density. Kagan attrib-uted this profusion of law to “the relentless pressures of technological change, geographic mobility, global economic competition, and environ-mental pollution,” which generate new inequalities, new injustices, new risks, and new cultural challenges to old norms.1 But what is the scholar to

do when, as Kagan put it in one article, “there is too much law to study?”2

What Kagan does, mostly, is to study law not in books or in court-rooms, but in the everyday world where it lives. Perhaps because of his pre-Ph.D. background as a business lawyer, Kagan often studies law in the world of commerce. From his dis-sertation, for which he was employed as a regulator implementing Richard Nixon’s wage and price freeze, to his latest work on pulp mills, diesel buses, and trucks, Kagan is truly a law in society scholar, investigat-ing the life of the law in ordinary, sometimes banal places--fast food restaurants that enforce smoking rules, shipping ports that struggle with labor and environmental rules, and factories that must contend with OSHA inspections.

The settings and subjects of Kagan’s research are diverse, but each is part of a quest to understand legal authority and how it works in the world. In this quest Kagan is closely connected to Max Weber, the founder of sociolegal studies. Weber observed that systems of author-ity were changing: Rule by religious leaders, or by charismatic individu-als, was being replaced by “rational-legal” authority. But what would legal authority look like in practice? Weber’s answer, for the most part, was that law would be bureaucratic, centralized and hierarchical. Weber was the prophet of bureaucratic rationalization, the movement of society towards predictable, calcu-lable rules. The legal system’s job in

such a society was merely to imple-ment and apply commands created elsewhere, in the political system.

But of course much of American law does not look that way. It does much more than apply rules, and it is much more decentralized, more fluid, more unpredictable than Weber’s ideal type.3 This is the step from

1. Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: The Amer-ican Way of Law (Cambridge: Harvard Univer-sity, 2001).

2. Kagan, What Socio-Legal Scholars Should Do When There Is Too Much Law to Study, 22 J. Law Soc. 140-148 (1995).

3. Indeed Weber struggled about what to make of English common law, which was decen-tralized, unsystematic, and unpredictable, thus in his terms irrational. Max Weber, Max Weber on Law in Economy And Society 315-318 (Edward Shils & Max Rheinstein trans., New York: Clarion, 1954) For a useful commentary, see Anthony Kronman, Max Weber 120-125 (Palo Alto: Stanford University, 1983).

LIFETImE AChIEvEmEnT AwARD 2012: BOB KAgAn

WWW.AJS .ORG e JUDICATURE 3

which Kagan’s work on “adversarial legalism” begins.4 What gives Amer-ican law its open-ended character, Kagan observes, is that it is typically “party-centered” rather than hierar-chical, meaning that instead of some legal authority, it is the parties to a dispute that drive American law. The parties can argue not just about how a rule of law applies to the facts of their case, but also over the purpose and justness of the rules themselves, as well as the justice of the process used to resolve the dispute. In adver-sarial legalism, then, everything is up for grabs.

American law and legal institu-tions, Kagan argues, were suffused with adversarial legalism, with pow-erfully mixed consequences. Adver-sarial legalism’s open-endedness makes it capable of great heroism, as when it used to reform barba-rous prisons, stop police from tor-turing suspects, or recognize the ways in which sexual harassment abuses women. Litigant activism can be a powerful force, prying out the secrets of institutions that inflict asbestos, tobacco and pedophilic priests on society. Adversarial legal-ism made it possible for law to be, in the sociologists Philip Selznick and Philippe Nonet’s terms, “respon-sive,” that is, flexible and open to change in order to rectify social injustice.5 Further, Kagan argues that adversarial legalism is particu-larly attractive to American policy-makers because, in a nation whose political institutions were designed to frustrate governmental activism, it gives them an alternative mecha-nism for addressing social problems. In an age of divided government and

tight fiscal constraints, adversarial legalism appears to be government on the cheap, a way of building state capacity to resolve social problems without seeming to building the state. But Kagan was more struck by the flip side of adversarial legal-ism’s virtues: its costs, complexity, and unpredictability, features that result from its bottom up structure and endless opportunities for rule contestation. These downsides often create a system that works poorly both for would-be plaintiffs, who cannot afford to use it, and organi-zations, which struggle to manage uncertain legal threats.

Kagan came to his concept of adver-sarial legalism just as a cultural and political debate over “litigiousness” was ramping up. Did the U.S. have “too much” litigation? This is mostly a left-right debate, with conserva-tives taking the side of tort reform and curbs on many forms of litiga-tion favored by liberals (civil rights and liberties, due process, environ-mental). Kagan’s position in this debate doesn’t correspond neatly to either side. He is with conservatives in worrying about the consequences for business of adversarial legalism, but his worries extend as well to the plaintiffs and their concerns—he is not anti-regulatory. Kagan’s com-parative approach, and his evident appreciation for the social democra-cies of northern Europe, estranges him from today’s myopic and polar-ized policy debates over litigation and regulation.

Kagan’s focus has always been on good governance rather than academic theory building, and his engagement with public policy debates counts as one of his virtues as a social scientist. Sometimes though, the “pull of the policy audi-ence” 6 works against him, and we think this has been true with the concept of adversarial legalism. We worry that the term will be used, as Kagan himself sometimes seems to use it, simply as a kind of a short-hand for law’s pathologies, a disease with malign symptoms, rather than in the more Weberian sense, as a structure of authority with all kinds

of political consequences, empow-ering some actors and disempow-ering others. Using the term this way helps us to better understand the causes and consequences of dif-ferences in legal style both across and within nations—to explain, for example, why Kagan is skeptical that European law will become “Ameri-canized” or that affluent nations will converge in their legal styles.7

Kagan is unusual among academ-ics in that he works at both the macro and micro level, comfortable with making the big generalizations nec-essary for productive cross-national comparisons, but also with the more nuanced observations required for studies of the regulation of sites like ports and factories. Perhaps as a result, there is a tension in Kagan’s work between structure and process, or between the apparent tilt of the structures of authority and their actual consequences, as Kagan often discovered when he studied law in action. American criminal law gives defendants, in theory, all kinds of ways in which to contest their prosecution, yet an overwhelm-ing percentage of defendants forgo their rights and take a deal instead. Tort and civil rights law in theory promise all kinds of opportunities for injured plaintiffs, but most of those aggrieved “lump it”. Adversar-ial legalism in theory offers too much law; in practice it often delivers too little. Where the pathological view of adversarial legalism says “too much,” the facts on the ground suggest a more complicated picture.

This is also true in the larger part of Kagan’s work, on regulation. Reg-ulation, even in the United States, in structure looks more like Weber’s ideal type of “bureaucratic legal-ism,” with a hierarchical authority (OSHA, EPA, FDA) imposing rules and using the threat of punishment to elicit compliance. Kagan is part of a group of sociolegal scholars who have shown just how complicated the politics of regulation really are, and how little they correspond with this ideal type. Bureaucrats some-times act like, well, like stereotypi-cal bureaucrats, “going by the book,”

4. Kagan’s concept of adversarial legalism built on the work of Mirjan Damaska, whose connection to Weber is also quite clear. Mirjan Damaska, The Faces Of Justice And State Authority (New Haven, Yale University, 1986)

5. Nonet & Selznick, Law And Society In Transition: Toward Responsive Law (New York: Transaction, 1978).

6. Sarat & Silbey, The Pull of the Policy Audi-ence, 10 Law & Pol’y 97-166 (1988).

7. Kagan, Should Europe Worry about Adversar-ial Legalism?, 17 O.J.L.S. 165-183 (1997); Kagan, Globalization and Legal Change: The ‘American-ization’ of European Law?, 1 Regul. Gov. 99-120 (2007); Kagan, The ‘Non-Americanization’ of European Law, 7 Eur. Polit. Sci. 21-31 (2008).

4 JUDICATURE e MARCH / APRIL 2013 e VOL 96 NO 5

as Kagan and Eugene Bardach found in their study of federal regulatory agencies, and the regulated some-times respond as rational actors who worry only about the costs of punish-ment, but these are far from the only possibilities.8

The limits of the rational actor model are apparent when, as Kagan often demonstrates in his research, organizations facing roughly the same threat of punishment react quite differently to a new law. A key variable in explaining regulatory response, Kagan and his co-authors argue, is the perceived costs of responding, as not all organizations enjoy the same “economic license” to follow new legal mandates. But the response to law is more than just a matter of weighing costs versus benefits. An organization’s “man-agement style” can also have a sig-nificant impact on its response to regulations, with some organiza-tions acting as laggards who ignore the law, while others act as true believers who go well beyond com-pliance.9 Kagan highlights the slew of actors and institutions that figure into response to law. It matters, for example, whether the officers within an organization who are charged with responding to regulations have internalized the norms of new laws, and this means that part of the politics of regulation is within the professions, where new norms

are absorbed, translated, rejected and diffused. Communities sur-rounding organizations also play an important role. They can grant or deny what Kagan and his co-authors have called the “social license” of the company, its legitimacy, based on community beliefs about regula-tions and their associated norms. A company unmoved by the threat of punishment may still worry about the damage to its reputation when it is seen to violate norms about safety, the environment, and civil rights.

Political debates over “too much” or “too little” regulation, from this perspective, seem almost beside the point. For one thing, they center the action in government regulations. What Kagan and his colleagues have shown is that there is a much more complicated politics of norms in realms such as the environment, con-sumer protection, civil rights, and many others. Regulation is a field in which legal authority plays only a part. The corollary is that effective regulatory schemes have to go far beyond simply inducing compliance through fear of punishment. Poli-cymakers must consider the wider, more complex politics of regulation Kagan and his comrades have illus-trated.

As law continues to expand its reach both in the United States and abroad, we believe that more schol-ars will be drawn to the questions

Kagan has posed and the concepts he has developed in his research. Kagan’s distinctions between forms of legal authority give us a lens to view structural differences across countries and policies areas, orga-nizing the unwieldy landscape of modern law. And his insistence that structures are just the beginning of the story, that the “rule of law” is much more flexible and more cir-culatory than Weber’s ideal type would suggest, pushes us to look beyond the abstract, and account for how law actually happens in the world. The result is a deeper under-standing of the consequences, both heartening and disturbing, of the relentless march of law in contem-porary society, and what we might want to do about it. e

Kagan the Comparativistby r. Daniel kelemen

Einstein once said, “The formula-tion of a problem is often more essential than its solution, which may be merely a matter of math-ematical or experimental skill. To raise new questions, new problems, to regard old problems from a new angle, requires creative imagina-tion and marks real advances in

science.”1 Asking the right questions is as important in social science as in physics, and far too much work in contemporary political science and socio-legal studies fails on this fundamental score. Over the course of his career, Robert Kagan has demonstrated again and again an extraordinary ability to ask the right questions. Kagan’s work on Ameri-can law and regulation, from works like Going by the Book2 to Adversarial Legalism,3 poses fundamental ques-tions about the nature of regulation

in the United States. And fortunately for us, his work has not just asked the right questions, it has gone a long way toward answering them. In formulating and answering these

e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e

Thomas F. BurKE is Professor of Political Science at Wellesley College

JEB BarnEsis Associate Professor of Political Science at the University of Southern California.

1. Albert Einstein, The Evolution of Physics: The Growth of Ideas from Early Concepts to Rela-tivity and Quanta. (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1938).

2. Eugene Bardach and Robert Kagan, Going by the Book: The Problem of Regulatory Unrea-sonableness. (Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 1982).

3. R. A. Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: The Amer-ican Way of Law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, (2001).

8. Bardach & Kagan, Going By The Book: The Problem Of Regulatory Unreasonable-ness (Philadelphia: Temple University, 1982), reprinted with a new introduction (Transaction, 2002).

9. Gunningham, Kagan, and Thornton, Shades Of Green: Business, Regulation And Environ-ment (Palo Alto: Stanford University, 2003).

WWW.AJS .ORG e JUDICATURE 5

questions, three elements of Kagan’s approach stand out: his knack for formulating new concepts, his facil-ity for combining macroscopic and microscopic analysis and his empha-sis on viewing American law and pol-itics from a comparative perspective.

As Sartori4 and others have taught us, concept formation is a critical element of social science research. Many scholars of law and politics fail to ask the right questions because they lack the conceptual tools neces-sary to comprehend the phenomena of interest to them. Many scholars before Kagan recognized that there were distinctive features of the American legal and regulatory style, but Kagan surpassed others in his ability to formulate a concept that could capture these distinctive ele-ments. Kagan’s concept of adversar-ial legalism captures the distinctive features of the U.S. approach to poli-cymaking, and dispute resolution. It is a multi-dimensional, ‘thick’ concept, which can be described in terms of two primary features (formal legal contestation and liti-gant activism) or further unpacked to reveal a number of interrelated characteristics including 1) complex rules, 2) adversarial dispute resolu-tion, 3) costly legal contestation, 4) strong sanctions, 5) frequent judicial review of administrative actions, 6) political controversy over legal rules, 7) politically fragmented decision-making systems, and 8) legal uncer-

tainty and instability. Equipped with the concept of adversarial legalism, one could see better the common themes that link seemingly dispa-rate areas of law and policy.5 And prospectively, Kagan’s concept of adversarial legalism has provided a tool and a common vocabulary for a host other scholars of American and comparative law and politics.

But Kagan is not just a theorist, he is an empiricist who can “soak and poke”6 with the best of them. The signal strength of Kagan’s empirical work is the way it so effectively com-bines macroscopic and microscopic analysis. Kagan looks for the big picture and the fine grain. His work on adversarial legalism combines empirical analysis of broad trends affecting the structure of Ameri-can government and the American economy, political and legal culture and the legal profession with analy-sis of highly detailed developments in policy areas ranging from crimi-nal justice, to civil procedure, to tort law to social and environmental regulation. In doing so, he shows how phenomena ranging from punitive damage awards in personal injury cases, to class actions in anti-trust cases, to plea bargaining in crimi-nal cases, to litigation over envi-ronmental impact assessments are connected to deeply entrenched structures of the American political and economic system, and aspects of American legal culture and the legal profession.

In his work on American excep-tionalism, Seymour Martin Lipset famously said that he who knows only one country, knows no country.7 Unfortunately, parochialism domi-nates much of the study of American public policy. In analyzing fundamen-tal questions about the nature of law and regulation in the United States, Kagan has shown himself to be that rare sort of Americanist—one with an instinct and a vocation for com-parative politics. Like a handful of the great scholars of American politics—including the likes of Lipset, Robert Dahl and John Kingdon—Kagan understands that the distinctive fea-tures of the American polity can only

be understood against a compara-tive background. In short, the fields of American politics or public law are best understood as subfields of com-parative politics. While a number of Americanists acknowledge this, few actually let it inform their work. Kagan’s work, by contrast, is deeply comparative. This perspective has not only enriched Kagan’s work on the U.S., it has also allowed him to make major contributions to the study of law and regulation in poli-ties outside the U.S.—inspiring spe-cialists on law and regulation across Europe and Asia to wrestle with Kagan’s ideas.

I am one such specialist. My research on regulation in the Euro-pean Union has been deeply influ-enced by Kagan’s work. Indeed, a 1997 paper8 he wrote on the ques-tion, “Should Europe worry about adversarial legalism?”, more than any other single work, has inspired much of my research agenda over the past decade. Kagan asked a simple, yet highly prescient ques-tion: should European countries worry that adversarial legalism—with the pathologies that accom-pany it—might take root across the Atlantic?

Kagan and I have not agreed completely on the answer to this question. He has maintained that a variety of entrenched national legal cultures and institutions across Europe will forestall the develop-ment of adversarial legalism there.9 By contrast, I have argued that polit-ical and economic changes fostered by the process of European inte-gration are indeed encouraging the rise of a European variant of adver-sarial legalism—“Eurolegalism.” In my 2011 book, Eurolegalism, and in a series of articles, I argue that the economic liberalization and politi-cal fragmentation associated with the process of European integration have generated functional pressures and political incentives encouraging European Union (EU) policy-makers to rely on adversarial legalism as a mode of governance.10 I acknowledge that the legal cultures and insti-tutions highlighted by Kagan will

4. G. Sartori, Concept Misformation in Com-parative Politics, 64American Political Science Review 1033-53 (1970).

5. Kagan, Adversarial Legalism, p.8.6. R. Fenno, Observation, Context, and

Sequence in the Study of Politics, 80 American Political Science Review 3-15 (1986)

7. S. M. Lipset, American Exceptionalism: A Double-Edged Sword. New York: W.W. Norton (1997).

8. R. A. Kagan, Should Europe Worry About Adversarial Legalism? 17 Oxford Journal of Legal Studies 165-183 (1997).

9. R. A. Kagan, Globalization and legal change: The “Americanization” of European Law? 1 Reg-ulation and Governance 99-120 (2007).

10. R. D. Kelemen, Eurolegalism: The Transfor-mation of Law and Regulation in the European Union. (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2011); R. D. Kelemen, Suing for Europe: Adver-sarial Legalism and European Governance, 39 Comparative Political Studies 101-127 (2006); R. D. Kelemen and E. Sibbitt, The globalization of American law 58 International Organization 103-36 (2004).

6 JUDICATURE e MARCH / APRIL 2013 e VOL 96 NO 5

continue to channel and limit the development of adversarial legal-ism, such that its European variant—Eurolegalism—is more muted and sedate than adversarial legalism in the U.S. Nevertheless, I maintain that Eurolegalism is on the rise and that many of the traditional impedi-ments to ‘regulation through litiga-tion’ in Europe are crumbling under new pressures unleashed by the process of European integration. Recently, a number of other scholars have taken up the debate launched by Kagan and myself, and it appears that our engagement on this question

is sparking a fruitful line of research on a wide range of policy areas.11 It has been one of the great pleasures of my academic career to debate these questions with the master himself and to see our discussion spark new research by other scholars. e

r. DaniEl KElEmEnis Professor of Political Science, Jean Monnet Chair and Director of the Center for European Studies at Rutgers University.

robert a. Kagan: man of styleby Cary Coglianese

In recognizing Robert A. Kagan with its Lifetime Achievement Award, the American Political Science Associa-tion’s Section on Law and Courts has honored not merely a scholar of great distinction in the study of law—but also a man of style.

In referring to Kagan as a man of style, I am making no commentary on his choice of attire or office décor—both of which have always seemed perfectly fine to me but neither of which I could ever properly judge. Nor do I wish to be taken to suggest that Kagan has merely followed fash-ionable scholarly trends, something for which no scholar who started studying the intricacies of regula-tory behavior more than perhaps a decade ago, if even today, could be mistaken of doing. I also do not refer to Kagan’s exceptionally graceful and generous style of mentoring stu-dents and younger scholars, some-thing which I have long admired and appreciated.1

Rather, in characterizing Kagan as a man of style I mean to call atten-tion to a vital contribution his schol-arship makes to our understanding

of regulation. In study after study, Kagan has shown us how social phe-nomena and human behavior can cluster together, forming meaning-ful and recognizable patterns—or styles. He has contributed greatly to our understanding of legal styles, how they vary, and what difference they make, opening up for scholars of regulation—and law more gen-erally—significant new paths for further inquiry.

Even a breezy walk through Kagan’s canon shows his uncanny eye for style. His earliest book, Regu-latory Justice: Implementing a Wage-Price Freeze, comprised a study of the federal government’s implemen-tation of a temporary wage freeze.2 It remains one of the best ethno-graphic studies of regulatory imple-mentation ever written, offering an insightful account of how regulators go about securing compliance with their rules. Here, Kagan introduced the concept of legalism—a style of implementation characterized by the formal, mechanistic adherence to rules—that he found shaped the effectiveness of the government’s implementation of the wage freeze.

His subsequent book, written with Eugene Bardach, Going by the Book: The Problem of Regulatory Unreason-ableness, brought legalism even more

squarely into focus, documenting the formal, by-the-book enforcement tendencies of many health, safety, and environmental regulatory agen-cies throughout the United States.3 One of Bardach and Kagan’s central conclusions was that the style of regulatory enforcement can make a difference in how regulated enti-ties respond. Inspectors and other enforcement officials can interact cooperatively with the managers of regulated firms, or they can “go by the book” and penalize firms for each and every formal violation, regardless of importance. Such a legalistic enforcement style may seem necessary, especially today in light of disasters such as the finan-cial crisis or Gulf Coast oil spill, but Bardach and Kagan suggested it also can counterproductively engender resistance as firms’ managers view government behavior as downright unreasonable. In the years since Going by the Book, researchers have

e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e e

11. See for instance, F. Bignami, Coopera-tive Legalism and the Non-Americanization of European Regulatory Styles: The Case of Data Privacy, 59 American Journal of Comparative Law 411-61 (2011); J. Cioffi, Adversarialism versus legalism: Juridification and litigation in corporate governance reform. 3 Regulation & Governance,235-58 (2009); D Mabbett, A Rights Revolution in Europe? Regulatory and Judicial Approaches to Nondiscrimination in Insurance, LEQS Paper No. 38 (May 30, 2011). Available at

http://ssrn.com; A. Meyerstein, Global Adver-sarial Legalism: The Private Regulation of FDI as a Species of Global Administrative Law, The Internationalization of Public Contracts, M. Audit & S. Schill (eds.) (forthcoming, 2013); B. Rehder, “Adversarial legalism” in the German system of industrial relations? 3 Regulation & Governance 217-34 (2009); F Van Waarden, Power to the legal professionals: Is there an Americanization of European law? 3 Regulation & Governance 197-216 (2009).

1. In 2009, Kagan received the APSA Law and Courts Section’s Mentorship and Teaching Award as well as the Law and Society Associa-tion’s Stanton Wheeler Mentorship Prize.

2. Robert A. Kagan, Regulatory Justice: Implementing a Wage-Price Freeze (1978).

3. Eugene Bardach & Robert A. Kagan, Going by the Book: The Problem of Regulatory Unreasonableness (1982) (subsequently reprinted with new introduction in 2002).

WWW.AJS .ORG e JUDICATURE 7

doggedly studied the comparative effectiveness of cooperative and legalistic regulatory enforcement styles, sometimes with varying results but always with recognition of the ideas Kagan has developed.

Kagan moved beyond just the behavior of regulatory inspectors in his magnificent and provocative book, Adversarial Legalism: The Amer-ican Way of Law, in which he sought to understand the overall style of the American legal system.4 In Kagan’s writing, “adversarial legalism” became a shorthand for “the ram-bunctious, peculiarly American style of law and legal decisionmaking.”5 He drew inspiration for this char-acterization of American legal style from a monumental case study of seaport administration in Oakland, California he had published a decade earlier in the Journal of Policy Analy-sis and Management6—an article that has become one of the journal’s most frequently cited works.7 In his book, Adversarial Legalism, Kagan vastly extended his research to show that, in realm after realm, American pol-icy-making exhibited a frequent reli-ance on detailed rules and courts to manage and settle its large number of conflicts. Although observers of the American system since at least de Tocqueville had acknowledged the important role of the court system, Kagan argued that “the adversar-ial legalism that has pervaded the United States in the last few decades is both more extensive and more intense” than ever before.8

Appearing in print a year before Adversarial Legalism, Kagan’s co-edited volume, Regulatory Encoun-

ters: Multinational Corporations and American Adversarial Legalism, offered further evidence of Amer-ica’s distinctive regulatory style.9 Built around a cleverly designed set of comparative case studies of dif-ferent fields of business regulation, each of the book’s chapters focused on a different multinational corpo-ration’s encounters with regulators in different developed countries. Collectively, the chapters reinforced the conclusion that American regu-lation is more legalistic and adver-sarial than cooperative. Managers of U.S. operations generally reported filling out longer forms and being governed by more detailed and extensive permits. They required permission from a more diverse and fragmented set of governmental bodies at the local, state, and federal levels. They encountered the threat of greater resistance to their opera-tions from members of the public who have greater opportunities for participation in governmental deci-sion making. The combination of these factors resulted in both greater uncertainty and longer delays for the companies in overcoming regulatory hurdles in the United States. Reflect-ing on the findings from this series of case studies, Kagan observed that the fragmented and legalistic U.S. regulatory style can help check gov-ernmental abuses and offer other benefits to society; however, he ques-tioned whether these benefits fully justified the costly burdens and inef-ficiencies created by the American regulatory style.

More recently, Kagan shifted his attention from regulators’ style to the management style of regulated firms. His monumental, co-authored book, Shades of Green: Business, Regulation, and Environment, set out to explain the pollution control behavior of fourteen pulp and paper mills across four developed econo-mies: the U.S., Canada, Australia, and New Zealand.10 Some mills did a vastly better job at reducing pollu-tion than did others. Some even did better than they were required to do by law. Kagan and his co-authors showed how the variation in pollu-

tion control could be explained by variation in each mill’s license to operate, a metaphor for the com-bined effect of the external regula-tory, economic, and social pressures that bear down on a business organi-zation. Yet Kagan and his co-authors also emphasized the role of each firm’s internal “management style” in explaining its environmental per-formance. Drawing on extensive interviews with mill managers, they sought to identify management style based on each mill’s responsiveness to external forces, its environmen-tal “ethos,” its willingness to search for advantageous opportunities to reduce pollution, and its commitment to faithful implementation of inter-nal environmental policies. Kagan and his collaborators classified each mill’s management style into one of five ideal-types, ranging from the least committed “environmental laggards” to the highest performing “true believers.” By peering inside the black box of the firm to identify internal organizational character-istics that made up “management style,” Shades of Green blazed a new path for regulatory scholarship as well as regulatory policy reform. After all, if management style helps explain firms’ compliance behav-ior and social performance, then we need to study style more closely and seek to understand what might influ-ence firms’ styles.

Throughout his body of law and social science scholarship, Kagan has time and again found meaningful pat-terns worthy of his characteristically careful empirical scrutiny, and in so doing he has defined the contours of much research by other scholars. He has truly captured style—the style of regulatory inspectors, entire legal systems, and regulated busi-nesses—and he has taught us why and how style matters. It matters because how someone acts can be as meaningful to others as what actions they take. It matters because the combination of discrete actions can sometimes amount to a whole that is qualitatively distinct from the sum of each of the parts. It matters, we might say, because often people

4. Robert A. Kagan, Adversarial Legalism: The American Way of Law (2003).

5. Id. at ix. 6. Robert A. Kagan, Adversarial Legalism and

American Government, 10 J. Pol. Analysis & Mgt. 369 (1991).

7. Peter Reuter & Jeri Smith-Ready, Editor’s Note: Assessing JPAM after 20 Years, 21 J. Pol. Analysis & Mgt. 339, 346 (2002) (tab. 2).

8. Kagan, supra note 4, at 36.9. Robert A. Kagan & Lee Axelrad, eds., Regu-

latory Encounters: Multinational Corpora-tions and American Adversarial Legalism (2000).

10. Neil A. Gunningham, Robert A. Kagan & Dorothy Thornton, Shades of Green: Business, Regulation, and Environment (2003).

8 JUDICATURE e MARCH / APRIL 2013 e VOL 96 NO 5

think it matters.I remember a presentation Kagan

once gave at a workshop I organized in Washington, D.C. The workshop brought together both academic researchers and government regu-lators, and Kagan presented a paper on management style as part of the opening panel. For the rest of the day, I felt sorry for the other presenters who had to follow. Kagan’s typol-ogy of management styles resonated with the government regulators so much that his was just about the only paper they wanted to talk about for the remainder of the workshop.11 If the virtues of social science general-izations lie in their robustness, rep-licability, insight, and verisimilitude, Kagan’s work exhibits them all—but it sets the gold standard for verisi-militude. The legal, enforcement, and management styles Kagan has artic-ulated are not his idiosyncratic ways of fashioning together complex legal and behavioral phenomena. They are patterns that resonate with the individuals who inhabit the regula-tory world he has studied and that line up with how many of us scholars view the world too, even if we never articulated these patterns as distinct “styles.”

Of course, an emphasis on style does have its own limitations and challenges, a point that Kagan has forthrightly and repeatedly acknowl-edged. If style is like the proverbial elephant, how it “looks” can depend on which part of it one examines. “It is risky,” Kagan reminded us in Regu-latory Encounters, “to make sweeping generalizations about entire national legal systems, with all their internal complexity and variation.”12

In some of my own early research, I uncovered how seriously wrong scholars were about adversarial con-testation over environmental regu-lations in the United States. Instead of the prevailing wisdom holding that interest groups challenge eighty percent of all U.S. Environmental Protection Agency regulations, for example, a simple inspection of court records revealed that closer to eighty percent of these regulations escaped litigation altogether.13 Of course, no

single datum defines a national legal style, but if so many people can be wrong about such a basic fact about regulatory conflict in their own country, it is not unreasonable to raise at least a small flag of caution about judgments made about broader styles across countries, especially if those judgments are not fixed by intersubjectively valid metrics.

Furthermore, if styles are at least partly perceptual, they may be vul-nerable to the myriad of cognitive biases that psychologists and behav-ioral economics have documented.14 Researchers may “see” more conflict, for example, only because our brains are hard-wired to be more receptive to it. Undoubtedly it is harder to see potential conflicts that never erupt.

Styles can also change. Over the years, scholars have suggested a growing convergence in the Ameri-can style of regulation and the styles found in other developed countries.15 To my mind, this more recent work does not undermine Kagan’s earlier comparative analysis, although it does suggest the possibility that the differences in legal styles he observed are neither permanent nor based on rigid, structural dif-ferences. Kagan always accepted that such a possibility might exist; however, in recent work he has force-fully resisted the idea that countries in Europe will soon, if ever, become fully Americanized in their legal styles.16 Whatever side one takes in this debate, the point remains that styles can and do change, even if slowly, and social scientists must be ever on their guard for such changes. Indeed, dynamism in styles can itself be a worthy subject for empirical research, as Kagan’s work has itself taught us.

A final caution about styles arises when social scientists seek to use them as explanatory variables. Con-sider what would happen if social scientists coded a firm’s environ-mental management style based even partly on observations about the investments the firm has made in pollution control technology or other actions the firm has taken that might be indicative of an environmental

ethos. If actions forme the basis of judgments about style, it becomes circular to try to use style to explain why some firms perform better or act more responsibly than other firms. Style, in short, cannot explain everything.

Kagan has always proceeded with these cautions in mind. He has never sugar-coated the hazards—nor shirked from working his way around them as best as feasibly can be done. He richly deserves the recognition recently bestowed upon him by the APSA Law and Courts Section. His body of work, magisterial in its scope and insight, has proved a model of intellectual achievement. And, yes, of style too. e

Cary CoglianEsEis Edward B. Shils Professor of Law and Professor of Political Science; Director Penn Program on Regulation at the University of Pennsylvania Law School.

11. His paper was later published as Robert A. Kagan, Environmental Management Style and Corporate Environmental Performance, in Cary Coglianese & Jennifer Nash, eds., Leveraging the Private Sector: Management-Based Strategies for Improving Environmental Performance 31 (2006).

12. Kagan, supra note 9, at 2.13. Cary Coglianese, Assessing Consensus: The

Promise and Performance of Negotiated Rulemak-ing, 46 Duke L. J. 1255, 1296-1301 (1997). See also Cary Coglianese, Litigating within Relation-ships: Disputes and Disturbance in the Regulatory Process, 30 L. & Soc’y Rev. 735 (1996).

14. For an overview of cognitive heuristics, see Daniel Kahneman, Thinking Fast and Slow (2011).

15. See, e.g., R. Daniel Kelemen, Eurolegal-ism: The Transformation of Law and Regula-tion in the European Union (2011).

16. Robert A. Kagan, Globalization and Legal Change: The “Americanization” of European Law?, 1 Regulation & Gov. 99 (2007).