mergers, acquisitions and control of francesc trillas...

33
1 MERGERS, ACQUISITIONS AND CONTROL OF TELECOMMUNICATIONS FIRMS IN EUROPE Francesc Trillas [email protected] August 2000 Regulation Initiative (www.london.edu/ri) London Business School Sussex Place Regent’s Park London NW1 4SA U.K. Telephone: +44-(0)20-72625050x3362 Fax: +44-(0)20-74020718

Upload: others

Post on 15-Feb-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 1

    MERGERS, ACQUISITIONS AND CONTROL OF

    TELECOMMUNICATIONS FIRMS IN EUROPE

    Francesc Trillas

    [email protected]

    August 2000

    Regulation Initiative (www.london.edu/ri)

    London Business School

    Sussex Place

    Regent’s Park

    London NW1 4SA

    U.K.

    Telephone: +44-(0)20-72625050x3362

    Fax: +44-(0)20-74020718

  • 2

    MERGERS, ACQUISITIONS AND CONTROL OF

    TELECOMMUNICATIONS FIRMS IN EUROPE 1

    Francesc Trillas

    Abstract

    Evidence is presented on twelve large acquisitions by telecommunications firms in

    Europe. Although the average effect on acquirers’ shareholder value is not significantly

    different from zero, there is high dispersion in the results. This suggests that detailed

    studies may uncover important aspects of the constraints that exist in the corporate

    control market of telecommunications firms. A case study of the Spanish firm

    Telefonica suggests that corporate governance problems and political intervention are

    significant components of these constraints.

    1 I thank Len Waverman for his comments and encouragement. I received helpful suggestions by

    workshop participants at a Global Communications Consortium meeting in London and at a session in the

    Conference of the International Telecommunications Society in Buenos Aires. The usual disclaimer

    applies.

  • 3

    1. Introduction

    Mergers, acquisitions and corporate control issues have shaken European

    telecommunications in the recent past. The takeover of Telecom Italia by Olivetti in

    1999 and of Mannesmann by Vodafone in 2000 are examples of such developments.

    The objective here is to find patterns of transactions in the market of corporate

    control in this period of deregulation2 and technological change. Similar research has

    been undertaken for other industries (Kaplan, 2000), such as banking (see Houston

    and Ryngaert,1994) or the airline industry in the US (Kole and Lehn,1997).

    This paper3 tries to answer the following questions: Did the strategies of large

    telecommunications companies in the market for corporate control create value for

    their shareholders? Which are the constraints faced by telecommunications firms in

    the control market of and what is their impact?

    A preliminary answer is provided by presenting evidence on the 12 largest

    acquisitions made by European telecommunications firms up to June 2000, and by

    presenting a related case study of Telefonica. The case study sheds light on the

    corporate governance and political constraints suggested by the diversity of outcomes

    in the analysis of the 12 acquisitions. These constraints are difficult to perceive with

    2 Deregulation is a common trigger of takeover waves (see Mitchell and Muhlerin, 1996).

    3 Other papers analyze mergers and acquisitions from the point of view of antitrust policy. See for

    example, Cox and Portes (1998).This type of analysis is beyond the scope of my paper.

  • 4

    comparartive studies that use averaging techniques. Although there is a wide variety

    of cases, on average the acquisitions had an impact on shareholder value that does not

    significantly differ from zero.4 The Spanish firm shows that the incentives provided

    by stock markets and political constraints both interact in shaping the control

    structure of the sector.

    The structure of the remainder of the paper is as follows. Section 2 discusses the

    theoretical developments that may shed light on acquisitions and control of

    telecommunications firms, and it presents a typology of deals, as well as some of the

    constraints faced by the potential transactions. Section 3 shows the quantitative

    evidence on the effects of twelve large acquisitions on the shareholder value of

    bidding European telecommunication firms. Section 4 analyzes in depth the case of

    Telefonica. Conclusions are presented in Section 5.

    2. The Control Market of Telecommunications Firms: Theory, Typology and

    Constraints

    Deregulation of telecommunications in Europe has been characterized by the

    liberalization of entry since 1998, which coincided with rapid technological change,

    the creation of the single currency and the consolidation of the single market. These

    important changes in the environment of telecommunication firms change industry

    boundaries and the optimal scale and scope of activities (see Laffont and Tirole,

    2000). An important difference between Europe and the US is the absence in Europe

    4 Sirower (1997) shows how acquirers must face the almost impossible task of achiving synergy levels

    that more than compensate for the acquisition premium in order to create value for shareholders. The

    same book reviews the previous research on mergers and acquisitions.

  • 5

    of line of business restrictions. The American control market has been better studied,

    both through case studies (Lys and Vincent, 1995) and more general overviews

    (Ware, 1998).

    The main benefits of mergers and acquisitions in telecommunications are the

    achievement of scale through consumer base and scope through convergence or

    vetical integration. It may also be beneficial for shareholders, although socially

    inefficient, to increase market power. However, mergers and acquisitions may also be

    value destroying from the shareholders’ point of view for reasons that are well known

    to the empirical literature: agency problems, hubrys, lack of focus (see Oxera, 1995).

    Firms may grow beyond their original markets through a variety of transactions,

    which may be carried out nationally or internationally. The following is a non-

    exhaustive list of potential deals:

    -Acquisitions of non-controlling stakes.

    -Global Alliances.

    -Joint Ventures.

    -Spin-off (of the “new economy” segments or of the network assets) plus merger.

    -Mergers of equals.

    -Acquisitions of controlling stakes.

    The following general trend has been observed over time. Until the mid 90s the

    usual strategy for the largest companies was to seek Global Alliances. These were

    abandoned and in the middle of the decade the most usual deal was to acquire non-

    controlling stakes. In the second half of the nineties some attempted mergers of

    equals took place, but most of them were stopped for a variety of reasons, frequently

    of a political nature. In 1999 and 2000 it can be observed that the acquisition of

    controlling stakes has increased in the companies under study.

  • 6

    However, the market for corporate control of telecommunications firms in

    Europe faces significant constraints. Some large scale mergers that where announced

    at a time, were not completed due to different kinds of problems, in many cases

    derived from political constraints. Here are some examples of failed mergers in the

    last five years (that were announced or about which there were intense rumours

    according to the Financial Times database):

    ·Telewest/NTL.

    ·BT/C&W.

    ·BT/MCI.

    ·BT/Telefonica.

    ·Deutsche Telekom/Telecom Italia.

    ·Telia/Telenor.

    ·Mannesmann/Vivendi.

    ·KPN/Telefonica.

    Golden shares and partial public ownership

    Except Telecom Italia, British Telecom, Telefonica of Spain and Telecom

    Eirearn of Ireland, the remaining incumbent operators of fixed telephony in Western

    Europe still have the state as the controlling shareholder at the beginning of 2000.

    Spain and Italy, although they have fully privatized their telecommunications

    incumbent, still hold a golden share on the companies. This places a significant

    constraint on the market of corporate control.5

    5 In some cases, the antitrust authorities may place serious constraints on a merger or an acquisition.

  • 7

    Golden Shares prevent that bad bidders become good targets. In an

    unsconstrained control market an acquirer that failed to achieve synergy would run

    into difficulties and would become a prey of other acquiring companies. Golden

    shares protect potential bad bidders. Partial public ownership also protects potentially

    bad acquirers, since governments may value control of the company for political

    reasons more than the cash flows derived from selling ownership rights.

    There seems to be an asymmetry in that some firms still controlled by the

    public sector (through partial public ownership or golden shares) are active acquirers

    abroad while their governments keep important restrictions at home. The Spanish

    government vetoed the merger betweek KPN and Telefonica and the Italian

    government vetoed the merger between Telecom Italia and Deutsche Telekom. In the

    US, the market for corporate control also faces important political constraints derived

    from interest group mobilization. The constraints in the US, however, have not

    stopped a more rapid concentration of the telecommunications sector.6

    3. Acquisitions by Large European Telecommunications Companies

    Table 1 summarizes the evidence collected about the effects of acquisitions on

    the stock price of acquiring firms. For each deal, it shows when it did take place, the

    6 The example of DT trying to enter the US mobile telephony market with the acquisition of VoiceStream

    (see FT July 24 2000) shows however that political opposition to foreign public control is also present in

    the US (and the example is also an instance that some acquisitions by European firms may not be the best

    deals for shareholders).

  • 8

    value of the transaction, and the abnormal stock price return, computed following

    standard event study techniques.7

    (Table 1 about here)

    On average, these acquisitions produced an abnormal return of 2.71% on the

    stock price of the acquiring firms, which is not significantly different from zero.8

    The variance of the distribution of abnormal returns is high. There are two

    acquisitions with a significant negative abnormal return at the 99% level (the two by

    Telefonica) and one of them with a significant positive abnormal return, the

    acquisition of E-plus by KPN. In all other cases, the abnormal returns are not

    significantly different from zero. The t-statistics used to test for statistical

    significance are based on the standard deviation of the time series of market adjusted

    returns for each security in a way that is standard in the event study literature.

    As opposed to other studies that only take into account the announcement

    effects, the table reflects the impact on shareholder value of all information released

    7 See Fama et al. (1969), Armitage (1995) and Binder (1998).

    8 Zero or negative average bidder’s abnormal returns are consistent with two theories of managerial

    behaviour. The hubrys hypothesis argues that managers overestimate their abilities and overpay for the

    target. The agency hypothesis argues that acquisitions reflect that the optimal size of the firm from the

    manager’s point of view is larger than the optimal size from the shareholder’s point of view. See Weston

    et al. (1998). The agency hypothesis is further explored below for the case of Telefonica.

  • 9

    between announcement and completion of the deals, in a way similar to Houston and

    Ryngaert (1994).

    Dynamic issues

    The evidence analyzed reveals that many questions can only be answered taking

    a dynamic perspective. For example, some deals are the trigger for other deals. The

    takeover of Telecom Italia by Olivetti triggered the acquisition of Omnitel and

    Infostrada by Mannesmann. The takeover of Mannesmann by Vodafone triggered the

    takeover of Orange by France Telecom. Kaplan (2000) addresses the methodolical

    issues that are raised by this. The main implication is that evidence from individual

    deals are only partially revealing of the wealth effects on shareholder value.

    Two phenomena are worth mentioning in this respect:

    1)Bad bidders may become good targets (see Mitchell and Lehn, 1990). For

    example, Telecom Italia had accumulated several failed alliances, top management

    changes and a messy acquisitions policy before it was taken over by Olivetti in 1999.

    2)Firms that have been taken over by acquirers may be divested and the spun off

    segments may be important participants in the corporate control market both as

    bidders or as targets (e.g. Mannesmann). Viceversa, spin-offs may be subsequent to

    acquiring groups of firms in the same segment. For example, Telefonica acquired

    Internet companies and then decided to spin-off Terra as a global Internet company.

  • 10

    Takeovers (see Bhagat et al., 1990), privatization (Joskow and Schmalensee,

    1995) and regulation9 interact in determining the ownership structure of

    telecommunications firms and the industry structure of the whole sector. The

    influence of politics in the history of corporate finance is a well known phenomenon

    (see for example Cantillo, 1998).

    4. The Case of Telefonica

    It is interesting to analyze more in depth the case of Telefonica, because it has

    been deemed one of the examples of success in an acquisitions strategy (see de

    Figueiredo and Spiller, 2000). Also, because it was under a corporate governance

    regime that made it significantly different from other telecommunications operators

    in Europe, since it was fully privatized with a highly dispersed shareholding but was

    under a 10 year golden share. Telefonica is the first Spanish firm in profits, income,

    and equity value. As of 1999, it had 50 million clients in 11 countries (Europe and

    Latin America).

    I show the impact on shareholder value of its diversification strategy and the

    mechanisms of managerial discipline that constraned such strategy. The behaviour of

    the company is consistent with the hypothesis that the government was de facto the

    large blockholder.

    9 According to Sidak and Spulber (1997) the regulatory burdens on the incumbents imposed by the 1996

    Telecommunications Act in the US forced them to a spin-off strategy of the value creating segments,

    separating the network assets. Similarly, stringent regulation has forced British Telecom to study the spin-

    off of its network assets (FT, 28-7-00).

  • 11

    (Table 2 about here)

    Table 2 summarizes data on the three last privatizations tranches of the company. Just

    before the last tranch, the government appointed Juan Villalonga as Chairman of the

    company (June 1996). Villalonga has stayed in this position until July 2000. It offers

    thus an excellent time window to analyze the behaviour of this very significant firm.

    The remainder of this section focuses on this period.

    After complete privatization, Telefonica's shareholders base widened. A look at

    the technical design of 1995 and 1997 POs shows the mechanisms through which this

    happened. Both offers included discounts on the final price for small investors (4

    percent for general investors and 8 percent for employees). Also, both POs included

    fidelity bonuses for small investors: that is, the promise of getting 1 free share for

    every 20 shares bought provided that the investor did not sell the shares during one

    year after the PO). Rationing was needed in both POs, since small investors demand

    was largely in excess of the supply directed to them. The ratio demand/offer was 7.3

    in 1995 and 7.2 in 1997.

    The previous management of Telefonica had already started a very ambitious

    investment activity in Latin America, with controlling stakes in Chile, Argentina and

    Peru's largest telecommunications operators when they were privatized. The new

    management maintained this policy. However, it shifted international alliances,

    leaving Unisource to reach an agreement with WorldCom and MCI.

  • 12

    The activities of the new management in the media sector triggered accusations

    of collusion with the government in its aim to create a media holding to compete with

    Prisa, a dominant media holding with important stakes in radio, TV and newspapers.

    Beyond the operations of Lycos and Endemol analyzed above, the following table

    analyzes previous deals. The abnormal returns are computed using a three day event

    window and t-statistics have been computed using the standard deviation of the time

    series of residuals using a market model.

    (Table 3 about here)

    The picture that arises from the data is somehow contrary to expectations.

    Investors welcomed the new alliances strategy of Telefonica, namely its agreements

    with BT first10 and WorldCom/MCI later (the previous merger between MCI and

    WorldCom created the first world provider of Internet services). But they

    systematically reacted negatively although not always significantly to direct

    investments in Latin America, probably influenced by the turmoil in emerging

    markets in the last two years. Investors find more value creation in strategic alliances,

    while they discount negatively or at least not positively direct investments in risky

    regions that may be motivated by empire-building purposes. There is a positive

    reaction when deals (in these cases, not completed) implied control of Telefonica by

    10 When Telefonica signed its agreement with BT, this company was in merger talks with MCI. The

    takeover of MCI by WorldCom stopped this talks and BT reoriented its alliances strategy, hence

    announcing the end of its alliance with Telefonica in February 1998.

  • 13

    someone else: MCI, KPN. And there is a negative or zero reaction when it was

    Telefonica that tried to control.

    From this evidence, the most that can be said is that investors may value the

    scope economies in a frontier business such as media, but also that some of the moves

    into this sector may have been motivated by non-economic reasons. There is probably

    a trade off between productive synergies and private benefits from control (which are

    potentially substantial in a high profile industry such as media, where these benefits

    can additionally be shared collusively with politicians).

    In 1999, Telefonica was the first operator in Latin America, being present in

    Argentina, Chile, Peru, Puerto Rico, Venezuela, El Salvador, Guatemala and Brazil.

    In the media sector, it participates in Antena3TV and Via Digital in television, in the

    newspapers Expansion and Marca and in the radio network Onda Cero, among others.

    In the four years that Villalonga had been Chairman of the company (June 1996

    to July 2000), Telefonica had made the transition from being a Spanish telephony

    incumbent to become a global operator in the new economy. The company had

    international subsidiaries in the Internet sector, in mobile telephony and in media. As

    the floatation of the Internet subsidiary Terra in 1999 and its subsequent acquisition

    of US Lycos shows, its strategy was to spin off the value creating subsidiaries without

    losing control and establish alliances and mergers with the spun off segments.

    The fact that the specific acquisition events analyzed failed to create value for

    shareholders in a positive and significant way suggests two possible explanations.

    The first one is that the new borders of the company had been anticipated by the stock

    market participants and its final details did not add substantial new information. And

    the second one is that the motivation for most of the deals revealed an agency

    problem in the firm. In this case, the managerial team would be interested in

  • 14

    expansion projects that are not necessarily positive net present value projects for

    shareholders, but that may maximize some managerial objective. Next I probe the

    effectiveness in Telefonica of the usual mechanisms that the literature has identified

    to discipline managers. In case these mechanisms are proved to be ineffective, it will

    be evidence of a potential agency problem in the firm.

    -Takeovers.

    The government announced a 10 year Golden Share on Telefonica on 8/11/96.

    The golden share is a departure from the one share one vote rule that implicitly gives

    incentives to the government to behave as the main blockholder. On 24/6/97 an

    extraordinary shareholders meeting approved defensive measures according to which,

    1) a candidate for the Board of Directors must have held more than 1000 shares of

    Telefonica for at least three years before nomination, unless 85% of the members of

    the Board agree to remove such condition; 2) a candidate to become Chairman must

    have held a position in the Board of Directors for at least three years before

    nomination, also with the 85% rule; 3) independently of his holdings, no shareholder

    can issue votes for more than 10% of the total votes.11

    -Board of Directors.

    11 Given this restrictions, Crespi and Garcia-Cestona (1999) argue that

    “Given the existent dilution for this company, these measures create an added power for the managerial

    team. (…) Through these measures, we are breaking the one-share-one vote rule, giving more

    discretionary power to managers and seriously affecting the governance of the firm.”

  • 15

    The appointment of nine ''independent'' directors was also interpreted as a move

    to a more controlled Board by the Chairman, Juan Villalonga. In addition to that, a

    leaner hierarchy was achieved by eliminating the position of CEO. On 15/1/97

    Telefonica announced that coinciding with total privatization it would reduce to 18

    the number of Directors.

    -Hard core.

    Besides the enlargement of the shareholders base, a 'hard core' of financial

    investors had been constituted since the mid nineties, although it has been losing

    importance over time. Three financial institutions (two banks and one saving bank)

    held stakes around 5 percent of total capital: Banco Bilbao Vizcaya, Argentaria and

    La Caixa.

    The hard core of shareholders was kept in place after appointment of the new

    management and full privatization. However, these institutions remained passive in

    all the changes that undertook the company during these years. They did not show

    opposition to Villalonga until the government showed its own opposition in 2000,

    first with the KPN merger and subsequently with the forced departure of the

    Chairman.

    -Large block holders.

    The shareholding of Telefonica in 1996 was as follows (El Pais, 27-7-00). The

    state had 20.9% of shares. The bank BBV, 5%. The savings bank La Caixa, 5%. The

    (at that moment in the public sector) bank Argentaria, 3%. The bank Banco

    Santander, 2%. And the savings bank Caja Madrid, 3%. 61.1% of the shares were

    dispersed among stock market participants. In July 2000, the merged bank between

  • 16

    Argentaria and BBV (BBVA) had 9.1%. La Caixa, 5%. Chase Manhattan Bank,

    5.06%. Portugal Telecom 1.50%. 79.3% of the shares were dispersed among stock

    market participants. The new merged bank BBVA has become the largest private

    blockholder, and especially so since the alliance between BBVA and Telefonica to

    share products and services in the Internet. The company lacks a technological

    strategic investor. The stock market welcomed the alliance with MCI-Worldcom and

    the announced (and subsequently cancelled) merger with KPN in May 2000. This

    may be an indication that shareholder value would increase with a more active role by

    a strategic telecommunications investor. Such a strategic investor does not exist now,

    since the alliance with MCI-Worldcom has not have a significant impact in practice.

    As it will be seen when we analyze the forced departure of Villalonga, it is the

    government who acts as a blockholder in practice, using the threat to use the golden

    share and using its especial relationship with the hard core of shareholders.

    -The managers’ labour market

    When Villalonga was appointed, his background signalled a move to a strategy

    focused on the creation of shareholder value. Investors might also have welcomed the

    appointment because of political reasons: the close ties of the new Chairman with the

    government would be a guarantee for the firm's returns. The replacement by Alierta

    in July 2000 (see below) shows that potential alternative top managers must fulfill a

    very narrow set of characteristics: satisfy the government, the banks, and be coopted

    from the Board of Directors, due to the rules fixed in 1997. Hence, an open market

    for top executives in Telefonica does not exist, although predictably Villalonga was

    constrained by a broader managerial market that could allow him to pursue his career

    in the future.

  • 17

    -Institutional investors activism.

    The internationalization of the company had increased the participation of

    European and US mutual and pension funds. However, these funds have not been

    active in campaigns to change the strategy of the company or to replace the

    managerial team.

    -Best practice in corporate governance.

    Villalonga had pledged upon appointment to introduce corporate governance

    reforms ''including recommendations of the most prestigious reports''. However, the

    stock exchange regulator (Comision Nacional del Mercado de Valores) has failed to

    include Telefonica amongst the firms that fulfill the best practice corporate

    governance recommendations in Spain (Codigo Olivencia). However, Telefonica’s

    shares are traded in 11 different stock exchanges, including the NYSE. This suggests

    that the company is subject to an important degree of financial discipline and

    transparency.

    -Financial Policy

    The most significant change in the recent past has been the new dividend policy

    announced in 1998. Telefonica announced that it would not distribute dividends, with

    the objective of having more funds available for an aggressive investment policy.

    The stock prices reacted positively to the new dividend policy. Increasing cash-

  • 18

    flow for investment was deemed value-enhancing at that point.12 Telefonica ceased to

    be committed to regular payments to external investors to a significant degree. To

    this extent, it fits an important condition for the company to be analyzed under the

    lens of the “free cash flow theory” (see Jensen, 1986).13

    -Incentive pay.

    An incentive plan to reward 100 high executives with stock options was

    approved in 1997 and it was extended to 450 executives in 1997. All Telefonica’

    workers were promised similar plans in 2000, when the plans were being most

    controversial in the public opinion.

    12 The comparison between Telecom Italia and other European incumbents after TI was taken over by

    Olivetti illustrates the costs and benefits of acquisition strategies. TI has adopted a very different strategy

    from Telefonica or other incumbents. Its highly leveraged structure after the takeover has the virtue of

    instilling strict discipline at TI, not unlike that of a classic 1980s leveraged buy-out.

    TI's new management has cut costs, pruned wasteful investment, geared up and made

    great efforts to sweat the company's assets, achieving the highest return on capital of all

    the big European telecom com-panies. First quarter capital

    expenditure was 19 per cent lower than the year before - possibly too low.

    (FT: Lex Column: July 16 2000)

    13 See also Thompson (1999).

  • 19

    With the exception of the incentive pay and the pressure of several stock

    markets, most of the internal and external mechanisms to discipline the managers in

    Telefonica are largely ineffective.

    Some of the executives who have left the company argue (FT, 25July 2000) that

    “Mr Villalonga's compulsive deal-making and intoxication with success have led to

    strategic mistakes - notably, the costly acquisition of a stable of media companies

    which they believe could dent future profitability.” The final straw was his inability

    to mend fences with the government when Telefónica was negotiating internet

    connection charges, local telephone tariffs and liberalisation of the domestic market.

    Figure 1 compares Telefonica’s stock price since Villalonga was apponited as

    manager with a portfolio of other European telecommunications companies. The

    companies in the value weighted portfolio are British Telecom, Telecom Italia,

    Deutsche Telekom, Vodafone, KPN, France Telecom, Cable and Wireless.

    (Figure 1 about here)

    This is the relevant benchmark, since European companies face a similar regulatory

    context, which distinguishes them for example from their US counterparts. See de

    Figueiredo and Spiller (2000) on this. It can be seen that, on average, the Spanish

  • 20

    company’s performance outperformed the portfolio until 1998, but cannot be

    distinguished from other comparable firms in the recent past.

    However, it must be borne in mind that comparing stock price performance of

    regulated firms for a long period of time does not reflect only managerial ability, but

    also regulatory actions and national factors. Nevertheless, this similar performance

    suggests that there are more similarities than differences between Telefonica and

    other large European telecommunications firms. The incumbents are vertically

    integrated firms and they face similar political constraints. Although the specifics

    vary according to different institutional endowments, the nature and effects of the

    limits to best practice corporate governance are similar.

    The replacement of Villalonga14 is a clear example of the presence of political

    constraints in the company’s control. Villalonga eventually resigned on 26 July 2000.

    His forced replacement is similar to a typical management change forced by a block

    14 A few days before the Chairman’s resignation, the financial press argued that the campaign to remove

    Juan Villalonga, Telefonica's chairman, was unsettling investors and could harm the company. A coup by

    BBVA and La Caixa would signal that Telefonica had other masters to serve.

    Looking beyond personalities, the basic problem is that Telefonica has its roots as a Spanish company.

    Spain's government and national banks are unwilling to surrender their influence over what is

    increasingly a genuine multinational. But surrender they must if Spain's new breed of globally

    ambitious companies is to compete successfully on the world stage.

    FT: Lex Column: July 18 2000

  • 21

    shareholder, although in this case the block shareholder is de facto the government,

    through the threat to use its golden share and through its relationship with the core de

    iure shareholders (see Warner et al., 1988).

    Villalonga had been appointed by the Spanish government when the company

    had still the state as the largest shareholder in 1996. For a long time, the Chairman

    had been understood to be the government’s man in the company, and the hard core

    of shareholders did nothing to undermine his powerful position. However, since late

    1999, the high profile of Villalonga, the stock options plan and his unrelenting deal-

    making, were starting to be politically costly for his political principals. The

    government first let it know its disagreement with the stock option plan of Villalonga

    and his team, which had caused heavy political upheaval in the run-up to the March

    2000 general election. Then it forced changes in the alliance with BBVA in May

    2000, which also caused controversy in the run-up to the election, and which was

    seen by some as an attempt of Villalonga to protect his personal role in the company.

    Subsequently, the government blocked the merger with KPN on the grounds that this

    would place the Dutch government as the main shareholder of Telefonica. Finally, the

    government encouraged an inquiry by the Spanish stock exchange regulator to probe

    whether Villalonga could be charged with illegal insider trading for a minor stock

    options operations prior to the deal with WorldCom-MCI two years ago (the probe

    found no evidence of irregular dealing). There were rumours revealed by The Wall

    Street Journal that ministers were furious because Telefonica were having

    conversations with the media group PRISA. Villalonga was eventually replaced in a

    board meeting by Cesar Alierta, himself a member of the board of Telefonica and

    former Chairman of the privatized tobacco firm Altadis (see FT, 27 July 2000).

  • 22

    To summarize the constraints derived from the government’s influence, there

    was a system of bad corporate governance (too dispersed shareholding, inoperative

    board due to weak hard core and “independent” shareholders) driven by the wish to

    leave the managerial team a broad room of manoeuvre to pursue government-related

    objectives; the golden share prevented the operation of an efficient control market;

    the electoral cycle clearly interfered with the operations of the company. The policy

    of managerial discretion decided upon privatization eventually backfired to the

    government: the managerial team was so autonomous that it no longer served its

    political masters. The European Commission had made it clear its opposition to the

    golden shares, and the Spanish shareholders were a minority after completion of

    Latin American takeovers. The Spanish government wanted to reassert its control

    before it was too late.

    The company was still successful because it could use its very large customer

    base and generous cash flows in Spain and Latin American to pursue an ambitious

    expansion policy in the new economy (de Figueiredo and Spiller, 2000) but political

    factors still constrained its behaviour, as it has been shown. Such political constraints

    should amount to a heavier burden in other companies that do not start with such a

    solid starting point.

    5. Conclusions

    The costs and benefits of acquisitions compensate each other on average for

    the 12 largest telecommunications acquisitions in Europe in the recent past. The

  • 23

    variety of outcomes suggests that detailed company studies may uncover the

    constraints that the control market faces and that may prevent it from achieving

    results that have positive wealth effects for shareholders. The case of Telefonica

    reveals that political constraints play a crucial role in shaping the market for corporate

    control in European telecommunications.

    In practice, a golden share regime does not seem to be very different from a

    partial privatization regime, since the government still operates as the main

    blockholder. However, it is probably better some government control than no control

    at all.

    Newbery (2000) has suggested that public and private regulated firms with

    similar industrial structures deliver similar outcomes. First mover advantages (e.g.,

    being a vertically integrated incumbent, presence of Telefonica in Latin America) and

    regulation, e.g., line of business restrictions, are important determinants of the final

    boundaries of the firm and clearly affect the role of the corporate control market. De

    Figueiredo and Spiller (2000) convincingly attach a high importance to having a large

    customer base and being allowed to exploit it through vertical and horizontal

    integration.

    The results of this research suggest that:

    -There is no evidence of a significantly positive average effect on acquirers’ market

    value of the completed transactions in the market for corporate control of European

    telecommunications firms.

    -Some potentially positive net present value acquisitions are stopped for political

    reasons. Many deals that are not positive net present value projects are undertaken

    anyway because disciplinary mechanisms to control managers, especially in recently

    privatized firms, may be ineffective.

  • 24

    -The industry seems to be looking for its equilibrium structure in a context of high

    uncertainty. Although the overall concentration process may be efficient (due to scale

    and scope economies), this does not imply that individual transactions all create value

    for shareholders, given that there is a huge separation between ownership and control

    in these firms, and that some of them have flawed mechanisms of corporate

    governance. This is especially accute in firms that are still under state control or that

    have been recently privatized.

    European authorities face a trade-off between leaving the control market operate

    to better capture the efficiency gains of consolidation (subject to anti-trust policy) or

    maintaining some degree of control on telecommunications incumbents. While the

    European Commission seems to be pushing for a freer market, the national

    governments are still reluctant to give up some (formal or informal) key control

    mechanisms.

    References

    Armitage, S. (1995). Event Study Methods and Evidence of their Performance,

    Journal of Economic Surveys 9(1): 25-52.

    Bhagat, S., Shleifer, A., Vishny, R. (1990). Hostile Takeovers in the 1980s: The

    Return to Corporate Specialization. Brookings Papers: Microeconomics: 1-72.

  • 25

    Bel, G. (1999). Share Issue Privatization and Political Objectives: Do Governments

    Make a Difference, Universitat de Barcelona, mimeo.

    Binder, J. (1998). The Event Study Methodology Since 1969, Review of Quantitative

    Finance and Accounting 11(2): 111-137.

    Cantillo, M. (1998). The Rise and Fall of Bank Control in the United States: 1890-

    1939, American Economic Review, 88(5): 1077-93.

    Cox, A. J., Portes, J. (1998). Mergers in Regulated Industries: the Uses and Abuses of

    Event Studies, Journal of Regulatory Economics, 14 (3): 281-304.

    Crespí i Cladera, R., García-Cestona, M. A. (1999). Ownership and Control: a

    Spanish Survey. Mimeo.

    De Figueiredo, Rui J.P.; Spiller, P. (2000). Strategy, Structure and Regulation:

    Telecommunications in the New Economy, mimeo.

    Fama, E. F., Fisher, L., Jensen, M.C., Roll, R.C. (1969). The Adjustment of Stock

    Prices to New Information, International Economic Review, 10(1): 1-21.

    Houston, J. F.; Ryngaert, M. D. (1994). The Overall Gains from Large Bank Mergers.

    Journal of Banking and Finance, 18: 1155-1176.

  • 26

    Jensen, M.C. (1986). Agency Costs of Free Cash Flow, Corporate Finance, and

    Takeovers, American Economic Review, 76(2): 323-329.

    Joskow, P. L.; Schmalensee, R. (1995). Privatization in Russia: What Should Be a

    Firm? International Journal of the Economics of Business, 2(2): 297-327.

    Kaplan, S. N., ed., (2000). Mergers and Productivity. The University of Chicago

    Press and National Bureau of Economic Research.

    Kole, S., Lehn, K. (1997). Deregulation, the Evolution of Corporate Governance, and

    Survival, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 87(2): 421-425.

    Laffont, J.J., Tirole, J. (2000). Competition in Telecommunications. Munich Lectures

    in Economics. The MIT Press.

    Lys, T., Vincent, L. (1995). An analysis of Value Destruction in ATT's acquisition of

    NCR, Journal of Financial Economics, 39 (2/3): 353-378.

    Mitchell, M. L.; Lehn, K. (1990). Do Bad Bidders Become Good Targets? Journal of

    Political Economy, 98(2): 372-398.

    Mitchell, M. L. Mulherin, J. H. (1996). The Impact of Industry Shocks on Takeover

    and Restructuring Activity. Journal of Financial Economics, 41: 193-229.

  • 27

    Newbery, D. (2000), Privatization, Restructuring and Regulation of Network

    Utilities, Cambridge and London: The MIT Press.

    OXERA (1995), Acquisitions and Diversification. The Record of Privatised Utilities.

    The Oxera Press.

    Sidak, G. J.; Spulber, D. F. (1997). Deregulatory Takings and the Regulatory

    Contract, Cambridge University Press.

    Sirower, M. L. (1997). The Synergy Trap. How Companies Lose the Acquisition

    Game. The Free Press.

    Thompson, S. (1999). Increasingly Marginal Utilities: Diversification and Free Cash

    Flow in Newly Privatized Utilities. Review of Industrial Organization 15: 25-42.

    Ware, H. (1998). Competition and Diversification Trends in Telecommunications:

    Regulatory, Technological and Market Pressures, Journal of Regulatory Economics

    13: 59-94.

    Warner, J. B.; Watts, R. L.; Wruck, Karen H. (1988). Stock Prices and Top

    Management Changes, Journal of Financial Economics, 20: 461-492.

    Weston, J.F., Chung, K. S.; Siu, J. A. (1998), Takeovers, Restructuring and

    Corporate Governance, Second Edition, Prentice Hall.

  • 28

    Table 1

    Acquirer Target Dates Value Abnormal

    Returns

    (t-statistic)

    Mannesmann Orange 19-22/10/99 GBP

    19.86bn.

    -8.88%

    (-1.01)

    Vodafone Airtouch 6-15/1/99 USD 62bn. 14.29%

    (1.65)

    Vodafone Mannesmann 13/11/99-

    4/2/00

    USD 190bn. -10.78%

    (-0.51)

    Deutsche

    Telekom

    One2One 29/7-7/8/99 GBP 7.5bn. -1.61%

    (-0.17)

    Cable and

    Wireless

    IDC 8/3-10/6/99 USD 572m. -11.36%

    (-0.54)

    KPN E-Plus 8-11/12/99 USD 19bn. 33.35%

    (14.83)

    NTL CWC 15-27/7/99 USD 12.4bn. 13.47%

    (1.15)

    France

    Telecom

    Orange 24-30/5/00 GBP 31bn. 13.60%

    (1.62)

    British

    Telecom

    ESAT 11/1-30/3/00 USD 2.4bn. -7.62%

    (-0.37)

    NTL Cablecom 13/12/98 USD 3.7bn. 3.26%

    (0.66)

  • 29

    Telefonica Endemol 16-17/3/00 USD 5bn. -11.57%

    (-3.12)

    Telefonica Lycos 16-18/5/00 USD 12bn. -11.36%

    (-2.51)

    Note: the Abnormal Returns are computed using the standard market model technique with parameters estimated

    over the 250-day period beginning 290 days prior to the announcement of each event. The event window varies in

    each case, and goes from one day before the first announcement was made until one day after the deal was

    announced to be concluded. Sources: Financial Times database, Sequencer.

  • 30

    Table 2

    Privatization of Telefonica and Public Offerings

    Date Revenues

    ( 610 Euros)

    % capital sold % state-stake

    after PO

    June 1987 283.7 6 32

    October 1995 1,000.2 11 21

    February 1997 3,885.5 21 0

    Source: Bel (1999)

  • 31

    Table 3

    Date Event Description AR

    (t)

    8/11/96 Telefonica breaks up with Sogecable, with which it had a

    strategic agreement to operate in cable TV

    1.63

    (0.88)

    29/11/96 Telefonica reaches an agreement with other corporations,

    both public and private, to develop a new digital TV

    platform

    -2.36

    (-1.28)

    18/12/96 TISA obtains a 35% stake in Companhia Riograndense de

    Telecomunicacoes (CRT) of Brazil.

    -0.77

    (-042)

    18/4/97 Telefonica announces a strategic alliance with BT and

    reconsiders its participation in the European Alliance

    Unisource

    2.70

    (1.46)

    27/6/97 The European Union rules that the Spanish government's

    decisions on Digital TV violate the Treaty of Rome.

    **19.3−

    (-1.73)

    24/7/97 Telefonica informs that it is negotiating the acquisition of a

    participation in Antena 3

    -1.04

    (-0.56)

    29/7/97 Telefonica acquires 25% of Antena 3 TV 2.21

    (1.20)

    8/8/97 Telefonica announces that it will take control of Antena 3

    TV and through it of 40\% in the company that has the

    rights of the pay per view football games

    0.32

    (0.17)

    14/8/97 The Competition Policy authorities of the European

    Commission start an investigation about the participation of

    Telefonica in the TV sector

    0.04

    (0.02)

    24/9/97 Telefonica reaches a strategic agreement with the Group

    Recoletos/Pearson. Telefonica will acquire 20\% of

    Recoletos Compañia Editorial

    0.91

    (0.85)

    6/2/98 Telefonica sells its 39.83% in Compañia Celular de

    Colombia, S.A. to the controlling group

    -1.27

    (-0.69)

  • 32

    9/3/98 Telefonica reaches a strategic agreement with

    WorldCom/MCI

    **96.3

    (2.14)

    19/6/98 A consortium participated by Telefonica acquires the

    Brazilian company CRT for US$ 1.018 million

    -0.98

    (-0.53)

    22/7/98 Telefonica and Sogecable, the controlling groups of the two

    digital TV platform in Spain, reach an agreement to work

    for a common digital TV

    -0.70

    (-0.38)

    23/7/98 Telefonica wins the contest for 51% of voting shares of

    Compañia Intel from El Salvador

    -2.40

    (-1.30)

    30/7/98 In an auction that took place in the stock exchange of Rio de

    Janeiro, a consortium leaded by Telefonica obtains the

    operating companies Telesp, Telerj and Tele Sudeste

    Celular

    *56.3−

    (-1.93)

    8/9/98 Telefonica buys 100 hundred radio stations in Spain. -1.99

    (-1.08)

    Note: the abnormal returns have been computed using a market model with a three dayevent window (day before, announcement day and day after). The t-statistics arecomputed using the standard deviation of the time series of residuals.

  • 33

    Figure 1: Telefonica compared to other European telcos