milken institute review q4

100
Fourth Quarter 2010 GMO : Sorceror’s apprentice or savior? GMO : Sorceror’s apprentice or savior?

Upload: robert-sarkissian

Post on 09-Mar-2016

222 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

DESCRIPTION

GMO: Sorceror’s apprentice or savior? Sorceror’s apprentice or savior? Fourth Quarter 2010

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Milken Institute Review Q4

Fourth Quarter 2010

GMO: Sorceror’s apprentice or savior?

GMO: Sorceror’s apprentice or savior?

Page 2: Milken Institute Review Q4

the milken instituteMichael L. Klowden, President and CEO

Michael Milken, Chairman

publisherJoel Kurtzman

editor in chiefPeter Passell

art directorJoannah Ralston, Insight Design

www.insightdesignvt.com

design assistanceLinda Provost

managing editorLarry Yu

ISSN 1523-4282

Copyright 2010

The Milken Institute

Santa Monica, California

The Milken Institute Review is published

quarterly by the Milken Institute to

encourage discussion of current issues

of public policy relating to economic

growth, job creation and capital formation.

Topics and authors are selected to represent

a diversity of views. The opinions expressed

are solely those of the authors and do not

necessarily represent the views of the Institute.

Requests for additional copies should be sent directly to:

The Milken Institute

The Milken Institute Review

1250 Fourth Street, Second Floor

Santa Monica, CA 90401-1353

310-570-4600 telephone

310-570-4627 fax

[email protected]

www.milkeninstitute.org

Cover: JT Morrow

the milken institute review advisory boardRobert J. Barro

Gary S. Becker

Jagdish Bhagwati

George J. Borjas

Daniel J. Dudek

Georges de Menil

Claudia D. Goldin

Robert Hahn

Robert E. Litan

Burton G. Malkiel

Van Doorn Ooms

Paul R. Portney

Stephen Ross

Isabel Sawhill

Richard Sandor

Morton O. Schapiro

John B. Shoven

Robert Solow

The Milken Institute Review • Fourth Quarter 2010

volume 12, number 4

Today’s volatile markets and complex

challenges demand innovative thinking.

That’s exactly what you’ll find at the 2011

Milken Institute Global Conference, where

international leaders tackle the biggest

challenges in energy, finance, philanthropy,

health, government and education.

With renowned speakers and an influential

audience, Global Conference sells out every

year. Tickets are in short supply, but the

wisdom you’ll gain is unlimited.

Register today at

www.milkeninstitute.org

Insightful Inspiring Indispensable

2011May 2–4, 2011 • Los Angeles

Page 3: Milken Institute Review Q4

c o n t e n t s

1Fourth Quarter 2010

tk

page 48

69book excerptZombie EconomicsJohn Quiggin on dead ideas that hobble us.

resistance is fruitfulThe case for bioengineered crops. by Matin Qaim

goldA distraction or a warning?by Christopher Meissner

bursting the bubbleFixing what ails housing.by Lawrence J. White

overcoming myopiaAfter BP.by Howard C. Kunreuther and Erwann O. Michel-Kerjan

water woesMarkets can save us.by Gary D. Libecap

16

28

38

48

58

235

14

90

9596

from the president

editor’s note

trendsNorth Korea’s end-game.

by Robert Looney

charticleThe race-generation gap.

by William H. Frey

institute viewHollywood melodrama.

by Kevin Klowden, Anusuya Chatterjee and Candice Flor Hynek

institute news

lists

Page 4: Milken Institute Review Q4

2 The Milken Institute Review

This month, the Milken Institute hosts its 12th State of the State Con-

ference, an annual event that focuses on the future of California.

It’s no secret that the Golden State has lost some of its luster in re-

cent years, thanks to an increasingly dysfunctional state government,

a high cost of living, a struggling K-12 education system and other

woes that have been amply aired in the media. Several years ago, that

formidable list inspired us to establish the California Center within

the Milken Institute. Its mission is to analyze the state’s economy and

to make recommendations to policy leaders and the business com-

munity on ways to ensure that California is once again a model for the nation.

With Sacramento locked in its annual summer ritual – the supercharged partisan budget bat-

tle that may not even be resolved by the time you read this – we felt it was time to look for some

new solutions that would untie this Gordian knot. We have asked some of the state’s most re-

spected leaders, from business executives to elected officials, to offer their best ideas for restor-

ing California’s promise. With assets that are the envy of the world – everything from great

research universities to technology clusters to the entertainment industry to abundant natural

resources – surely we can find a way to break out of this malaise.

We’ve collected the ideas that we solicited on a Web site: www.californiaspromise.org. There

you’ll find video of dozens of interviews in which experts outline ways to get the state back on

track. We hope you will join the discussion – comments are welcome on the Web site.

Why should we care about California? If it were a country, it would be the eighth-largest

economy in the world. The ideas and trends (both good and bad) that take root here have a way

of spreading. As California goes, so goes much of the United States – and perhaps the world.

It’s going to take political will and no small measure of courage to restore the state to its former

glory. But it can be done. Indeed, if America is to thrive, it had better be done.

Michael Klowden, President and CEO

f r o m t h e p r e s i d e n t

Page 5: Milken Institute Review Q4

3Fourth Quarter 2010

©da

ve &

les

jaco

bs/a

ge f

otos

tock

Silly JG. Lake Wobegon is entirely a prod-uct of imagination. By contrast, California, where all the important news is about Lind-sey Lohan and all the state’s budget woes will be cured by the next governor, is reality-based. Speaking of reality, check out this very real preview of the articles awaiting you in the pages to follow.

Matin Qaim, an agricultural economist at the University of Göttingen in Germany, ex-amines the benefits – and stunning potential

– of genetically modified crops. GM crops “can increase productivity in agriculture, en-suring the availability of cheap food and other crop-based raw materials for a growing population with rapidly rising economic ex-pectations, even as the non-renewable natu-ral resource base dwindles,” he writes. And they “can reduce the negative environmental footprint of agriculture by reducing the de-mand for fossil fuels, toxic chemicals and water.

“Indeed, the biggest challenge posed by ge-netic modification is how to create a regula-tory framework that provides reasonable public oversight but resists the understand-able impulse to curb progress linked to these technologies.”

Chris Meissner, an economist at the Uni-versity of California (Davis), revisits the gold standard in search of a way to reduce the global economy’s dependence on the green-

back. “The gold standard functioned reason-ably well in a simpler time in which the hand-ful of rich industrialized nations that ran the global economy was able to make common cause to bring the system through periods of stress,” he concludes.

“Today’s policymakers won’t lock them-selves into a similarly rigid system in an era in which the forces driving the global economy are changing rapidly. Replacing today’s messy

Passadumkeag, Maine writes to ask whether we’ve ever considered moving

the Milken Institute from California to Lake Wobegon.

JG of

e d i t o r ’ s n o t e

Page 6: Milken Institute Review Q4

4 The Milken Institute Review

jona

than

twin

gley

and far from adequate system with a stan-dard linked to gold (or some other commod-ity) is just not an option.”

Larry White, an economist at NYU’s Stern School of Business (and a former mortgage

regulator), dreams of the day Washington eliminates virtually all the subsidies – and, with them, much of the waste and volatility – from the market for housing.

“Housing finance can’t be reformed overnight,” he concedes. “But the experience of the last few years (in which housing played a key role in triggering a terri-ble global recession), and the likely experience of the next few (in which the need for deficit re-

duction will be hard to ignore), could serve as the opening.”

Bob Looney, an economist at the Naval Postgraduate School in California, ponders the future of North Korea at a time when its economy is imploding and its dynastic lead-ership is in flux. “Ironically, no one (with the likely exception of the great majority of North Koreans) is eager to see North Korea collapse,” he writes. “China doesn’t want a flood of refugees; many South Koreans fear the consequences of the economic disloca-tion. And nobody wants to face the increased prospect of military conflict during the tran-sition, especially now that the North has nu-clear weapons. This doesn’t mean that the economy (and the government) won’t col-lapse one day. But the push will probably have to come from within.”

Howard Kunreuther and Erwann Michel-Kerjan of Penn’s Wharton School of Business analyze the sources of myopia that contrib-uted to the BP oil spill and other catastrophes.

“Human nature is ... human nature,” they ac-knowledge. “We cannot expect policymakers, investors, business executives and homeown-ers in the position to influence disaster miti-gation to act rationally without a financial nudge and/or clearly enforced obligations. Nor is it enough to wring our hands and talk loudly after each fresh outrage. We need to give people tangible incentives to do the right things.”

Gary Libecap, an economist at the Univer-sity of California (Santa Barbara), examines the colossal failure of the market to allocate water efficiently in the increasingly arid American West. “In an economic culture that generally bows to the goddess of property rights,” he writes, “one might have expected that excess claims on existing water would have forced a clarification of rights, followed by the use of market pricing both to encour-age conservation and to reallocate water to those who value it most. Indeed, just this sort of institutional evolution took place in the West with hard-rock minerals, oil and gas, timber and land. Yet that process is only be-ginning, and it is by no means certain that the market will come to the rescue.”

And, of course, we couldn’t resist packing in more, more, more. The Institute’s Kevin Klowden, Anusuya Chatterjee and Candice Flor Hynek summarize their research on how to save Hollywood from encroachment by Vancouver (and New York City and North Carolina). Institute demographer Bill Frey offers some troubling numbers on the race/generation gap. And in an excerpt from his new book, Zombie Economics, John Quiggin demolishes the myth of trickle-down growth. Happy perusing. — Peter Passell

e d i t o r ’ s n o t e

Page 7: Milken Institute Review Q4

t r e n d s

5Fourth Quarter 2010

©jo

yon

g-ha

k/re

uter

s/co

rbis

This outlaw behavior has typically met with international outrage and high-minded demands that North Korea be held account-able. In the end, however, the United States and the major regional players – China, Japan, South Korea and Russia – conclude they have little to gain and much to lose from confron-tation. Sanctions are watered down, and North Korea hints that it could be bribed to refrain from further bad behavior.

This time around is probably no different. But the stakes seem especially high because the economy – and the regime that has man-aged it so badly – once again seem to be tee-tering. There has been much speculation not only about the succession, but also about the ability of North Korea’s ruling gang to survive. Since the demise in 1994 of Kim Il-Sung (Great Leader, who had led the country since 1948), observers have periodically predicted

has been both a puzzle and an irritant to the interna-

tional community for more than half a century. This highly secretive autocratic state

possesses nuclear weapons, yet it depends on handouts to stave off mass famine. And

just when it seems to be inching toward a more rational relationship with its neigh-

bors, an incident like the March 2010 sinking of a South Korean navy ship, Cheonan,

reminds the outside world about how

little it knows about how North Korea

makes policy decisions.

North Korea

BoB Loon ey teaches economics at the naval Postgraduate School in California.

b y r o b e r t l o o n e y

Page 8: Milken Institute Review Q4

6 The Milken Institute Review

nk_x

ela/

alam

y

the sudden collapse of the government in the face of rumors that Kim Jong-Il (Dear Leader, who succeeded his father) was in failing health. However, as the regime has survived economic crisis after crisis while maintaining one of the dozen largest conventional mili-tary establishments in the world, such predic-tions have become increasingly guarded.

Optimists believe that concessions to North Korea (combined with pressure from China) can mute its rogue tendencies. Pessi-mists point to a long history of abominable behavior, from the bombing murder of most of the South Korean government’s cabinet in 1983, to its massive currency-counterfeiting and cigarette-smuggling operations, to its use of Japan as a missile-testing range. They insist that only relentless pressure through compre-hensive economic sanctions will modify the country’s belligerency.

Both camps, however, agree that progress in the economic and security arenas go hand in hand. Economic liberalization would im-prove economic performance and give the re-gime a bigger stake in the community of na-tions. By contrast, a retreat into ever-greater rigidity would put China, South Korea and Japan at greater risk of fallout – figurative and literal. A big question, then, in assessing North Korea’s impact on the region is how the economy will evolve in coming years.

organized crimeKorea was a colony of Japan from 1905 until the end of World War II, and the North was briefly under the direct control of the Soviet Union thereafter. So the history of an inde-pendent North Korea really only begins in 1948. It is relatively well endowed with miner-als, including coal and metal ores, though conspicuously lacking in oil and natural gas. By contrast, it has little arable land and highly

variable weather – a glaring weakness because the leadership is committed to self-sufficiency in food.

The work force is literate, and there seem to be no fundamental cultural barriers to making it far more productive. But as long as the economy is so poorly managed, the ques-tion is moot. Handicapped by infrastructure and industrial capital stock that are hope-lessly out of date, GDP per capita is a miser-able $1,900 annually in purchasing power terms – less than that of Sudan, Laos or Cam-

t r e n d s

Page 9: Milken Institute Review Q4

7Fourth Quarter 2010

mar

ka/a

lam

y

bodia, and only a tad more than Chad. The impact of adherence to a philosophy of

extreme self-reliance, combined with flat-footed central planning, has been devastating. From 1995 to 1998, famine killed as many as one million people. Even in the best of times North Korea operates its obsolete manufactur-ing sector at only a small fraction of capacity for lack of fuel and spare parts. Meanwhile, the leadership’s obsession with top-down control denies the economy the benefits of relatively cheap modern technologies. Mobile

Page 10: Milken Institute Review Q4

8 The Milken Institute Review

phones and Internet access are forbidden to all but the elite, and radio and television sets are manufactured to receive only government stations. Unauthorized travel within the country is banned.

Large segments of the population live in extreme deprivation. Goods available to a vast majority of North Korea’s 23 million citi-zens are mainly agricultural products – the sector employs about 40 percent of the popu-lation. The bulk of the country’s very limited resources go to maintaining a supersized army, developing and producing nuclear weapons and missile delivery systems, and providing a decent standard of living for the political and military elite.

Military control of so large a share of the na-tion’s resources – between 15 and 30 percent of GDP – stemmed from Kim Jong-Il’s early pri-orities. Instead of following China and other communist states toward market-based re-forms after the death of the nation’s patriarch, Kim Jong-Il invested heavily in the care and feeding of the military as a means of stabilizing his power. This strategy, dubbed “military-first politics” by Dear Leader himself, offered the bonus of protecting the regime against foreign threats, both real and imaginary.

Kim put forth an ingenious public ratio-nale for this approach, turning the traditional

“guns versus butter” trade-off on its head. He argued that defense would serve as the lead-ing sector to spur development in other sec-tors – even in agriculture and light industry. This isn’t quite as dumb as its sounds: in the post-Mao period, China permitted its armed force to develop its own diversified industrial base, which arguably served as an intermedi-ate step toward market-based decentraliza-tion by giving the officer corps a direct inter-est in industrial productivity. But there isn’t a shred of evidence that the approach has

worked in North Korea.Another leg to Kim’s strategy for regime

survival is what Charles Wolf of Rand calls the “court economy,” a patronage system of sorts that funnels consumer goods to the na-tion’s bureaucratic elite in return for support and a sense of legitimacy. Yet a third leg is the regime’s organized-crime strategy in eco-nomic dealings with the rest of the world, which Kim uses to pay for the first two.

After defaulting on international debt in the 1970s, North Korea was frozen out of foreign capital markets and came to rely increasingly on illicit activities like drug trafficking, cur-rency counterfeiting and insurance fraud to generate foreign exchange. Such crime-for-profit activities are reportedly orchestrated by a special office under the direction of the ruling Korean Workers Party. It is a surprisingly so-phisticated operation, equal to the best of orga-nized crime elsewhere. Indeed, there is consid-erable evidence that some of these activities involve complex transnational relations with various rogue-state and criminal networks.

North Korea’s “rent seeking” also includes extortion: international payments for “pro-tective services” – mainly promises to refrain from aggressive actions like the development of nuclear weapons and missile delivery sys-tems. Payments often take the form of foreign aid in hard currency or commodity deliveries of fuel or food. Overall, the scale of this activ-ity has been sufficient to provide a relatively comfortable life for North Korea’s elite in the midst of economic ruin.

Unless things change drastically, the forty-fold GDP disparity between South and North Korea can be expected to widen because of the vicious circle in which the North has be-come entrapped. The circle begins with the country’s economy in which state-planned and managed operations are inherently inef-ficient, a military-first policy drains resources

t r e n d s

Page 11: Milken Institute Review Q4

9Fourth Quarter 2010

nort

h ko

rea

pict

ure

libr

ary/

alam

y

from potentially productive sectors and the elite must be kept in the style to which it has grown accustomed. The resulting scarcities, in turn, prevent the country from improving infrastructure and investing in modern equipment, which leads to further deteriora-tion in industrial and agricultural productiv-ity. Low agricultural productivity leads to malnutrition, which diminishes labor force productivity. And since the elite’s position has been secured by policies that inhibit growth, there is little incentive to change.

the future as revealed by the pastThough the motives of North Korea’s leaders are open to interpretation, their past machi-nations do offer some insight into how the government will act in a period of economic

trauma and transition in leadership. Consider some scenarios.

Muddling Through

In the base-case scenario, North Korea will pursue the same strategies that have kept its rulers on top for decades. Probably the key factor here is maintaining trade and invest-ment flows from China and South Korea at levels adequate to satisfy the military and to generate survival rations for the masses.

The Special Economic Zone (SEZ) at Kae-song (some 50 miles from the South Korean border), created in 2003 and operated by the Hyundai Group, looms large here. It is used by some 120 South Korean manufacturers, who employ around 40,000 North Koreans at an average wage of about one-third of that

The bulk of the country’s very limited resources go to maintaining a supersized army, developing and

producing nuclear weapons and missile delivery

systems, and providing a decent standard of living

for the political and military elite.

Page 12: Milken Institute Review Q4

10 The Milken Institute Review

©vi

ew s

tock

/age

fot

osto

ck

paid for comparable work in the South. All told, South Korea has invested roughly $600 million in Kaesong’s infrastructure. Managers from the South run the factories, bringing in the necessary capital, equipment and technical expertise. South Korea even supplies the elec-tricity – straight across the demilitarized zone.

The SEZ is walled off from the rest of the city, with worker housing provided by the North Korean government. The government chooses the workers. And while the gross wage rate is about three times that of the av-erage North Korean worker, it’s not known how much is diverted to government (and government officials’) accounts.

Expansion of the SEZs would allow North Korea to bolster foreign exchange earnings without exposing the general populace to decadent Western influences. South Korea’s motives for maintaining the SEZ are more political than economic: low wages can go only so far in compensating for the ineffi-ciency of running an island economy in the

midst of a police state. But one would expect that North Korea would like to make the model sufficiently attractive to induce other companies (and other Asian countries) to outsource produc-tion to isolated zones.

Whether this is practical is anyone’s guess. Foreign investors would have lit-tle control over their work forces and no credible guarantee that their prop-erty wouldn’t be confiscated.

Muddling through would also re-quire North Korea to play its hand deftly, using a mix of extortion and promises of détente to keep the cash flowing. This may not be so difficult, though, as long as China’s first priority is preventing a flood of refugees from North Korea and as long as South Korea considers the price of the status quo to be a bargain.

Flirting with the Chinese Model

Many observers doubt that the muddle-through approach is sustainable in the long run. No matter how carefully the government tries to wall off the SEZs,

news of conditions beyond North Korea’s bor-ders are seeping through. And without some hope for a better life, North Koreans will in-creasingly question the regime’s legitimacy. In-deed, to judge by reports from refugees, this process has already begun.

At some point, then, the government might well opt for economic liberalization as a

t r e n d s

Page 13: Milken Institute Review Q4

11Fourth Quarter 2010

means of quieting discontent. It wouldn’t be the first time: North Korea initiated a number of such changes in its economic system in the late 1990s and early 2000s. It was widely hoped at the time that these changes were the start of a trial-and-error process akin to Chi-na’s reforms under Deng Xiaoping or Viet-nam’s more recent economic liberalization initiatives. But in contrast to China and Viet-nam, North Korea’s motives for reform smacked more of desperation than conviction that markets could legitimize the ruling elite.

In the 1990s, change was spurred by the collapse of the planned economy during the famine, when the public food distribution system designed to ensure survival rations ceased to function. As desperate North Kore-ans sought ways to feed their families, black markets (supplied by food smuggled from China or grown in private plots) sprang up. In hindsight, the government’s decision to tolerate these markets seems purely tactical, unrelated to any larger vision of reform.

Reforms initiated in 2002 looked a bit more promising. Planning was partly ceded to local governments and factories. Wages were raised and linked to performance; prices for commodities were allowed to fluctuate ac-cording to supply and demand. And it be-came legal for families to sell food and con-sumer goods in local markets.

Note, too, that this was the time that the Kaesong special economic zone was estab-lished, and the exchange rate significantly de-valued in what looked like an effort to posi-tion North Korea to compete in global markets. Eager to celebrate the opening of this bastion of autarky, analysts rushed to declare that the country had entered a new era. In the words of one, North Korea “crossed the Rubicon.”

But in light of the timing, it’s more likely that the reforms were simply another tactical lurch. In other economies that have transi-

tioned from planning to markets, the state took the lead and tried to buttress the re-forms by providing supporting institutions, like increased rule of law, property rights and regulatory reform. Marcus Noland of the Pe-terson Institute for International Economics and Stephan Haggard of the University of California at San Diego note that the North Korean case turned reform on its head, with change arising not out of a conscious top-down program, but as unintended (and in some respects, unwanted) byproducts of state failure. Comparisons have been made with the perestroika programs undertaken in des-peration by Mikhail Gorbachev.

With free markets and no real institutional framework, North Korean refugees have re-ported that the 2002 reforms benefit the elite who run and profit from them, while making ordinary citizens even more vulnerable to scarcities.

While most North Koreans must now ob-tain a portion of their food from private mar-kets, prices are typically 10 to 40 times higher than prices for state-rationed food (which is only sporadically available). And since just a tiny minority can afford to buy food on their official wages, the reforms effectively turned almost everyone into a scofflaw, hoarding, smuggling and demanding bribes on their own turf when they were able.

In 2005, the regime reversed course, ban-ning private trade in grain and seizing pri-vately held stockpiles in rural areas. Women under 40, the main cohort of traders, were barred from participating in the markets.

“Antisocialist conscience investigation teams” were deployed to shut down the remaining markets. And travel restrictions were strength-ened, especially along the relatively porous Chinese border. The government also ex-pelled a number of foreign aid agencies, in-cluding the World Food Program, whose job

Page 14: Milken Institute Review Q4

12 The Milken Institute Review

was to monitor the adequacy of food distri-bution in areas prone to shortages.

A similar sort of haphazard reform and re-versal was apparent in the currency “reform” initiated in November 2009. The government announced it would knock two zeros off its currency, the won, ostensibly to fight infla-tion. People had just one week to trade in their old money for new notes, with each family permitted to exchange a maximum of

100,000 old won for 1,000 new won – less than $30. Here’s the kicker: any cash in excess of the limit became invalid unless it was placed in bank accounts to which the deposi-tors were not guaranteed future access.

The life savings of what passes for a middle class in North Korea, along with merchants’ working capital, were wiped out with the stroke of a pen. Thousands of people frantically tried to convert soon-to-be-worthless money into something of value. Prices of some goods rose hundredfold before traders shut down, realiz-ing that their profits soon would be worthless, too. (Besides which, the reform would leave them without the money to restock.)

If there was any method to this apparent madness, the purpose of the currency reform was to destroy the budding private entrepre-neurial class and to return ebbing power to

those who live off the proceeds of govern-ment monopolies. While, in theory, virtually every adult works for the state, North Koreans do all they can to escape from its clutches. Farmers tend their own gardens as weeds overtake collective farms, and urban workers duck state assignments to peddle everything from metal scavenged from mothballed facto-ries to televisions smuggled from China. Iron-ically, to cushion the blow of the currency re-form, workers were promised that their salaries would be restored – in effect, giving them a large pay raise since old nominal sala-ries were now paid in the revalued currency.

All this implies that the Chinese model, however attractive it might appear to foreign-ers, does not mesh with the perceived inter-ests of North Korea’s rulers. Perhaps they are too isolated from the realities of the global economy to see the necessity of enduring eco-nomic reforms. Perhaps they know that they lack the technical skills to manage decentral-ized markets. Or perhaps their control over the levers of power is too insecure to give them the leeway to experiment.

But the country may once again be head-ing for a crisis in which business as usual sim-ply won’t cut it. Indeed, just a few months ago, the government tacked back toward freer ex-change, allowing local markets to stay open longer and to sell food without restriction in order to stave off the threat of mass starvation.

Sudden Collapse

The fundamental economic collapse of a country with a huge conventional military, along with nuclear weapons and the means to deliver them, is without precedent. No one really knows, then, what would happen if al-ready meager levels of production fell sharply, neighboring countries set conditions for helping that were unacceptable to North Ko-rea’s leadership, and control over the popula-

The purpose of the currency reform was to destroy the

budding private entrepre-

neurial class and to return

ebbing power to those who

live off the proceeds of

government monopolies.

t r e n d s

Page 15: Milken Institute Review Q4

13Fourth Quarter 2010

tion was lost. But it is possible to make an ed-ucated guess.

It is likely that large numbers of North Ko-rean refugees would flee to the borders of China and South Korea, as they did in the 1990s famine. North Korea’s rulers might be reduced to making side deals in which their safety and wealth would be protected in re-turn for assurance that the military would stay in the barracks. Ultimately, the process would lead to some form of union between North and South, as Southerners were moved to take on the burden of impoverished North-erners by a combination of family ties, na-tionalism, pressure from the West and eco-nomic self-interest in ending the chaos.

There is general agreement that whatever the terms on which the North was absorbed, the cost would be enormous. In the latest forecast, a South Korean government think tank estimated that the price of reunification would amount to 2 percent of GDP for the next 60 years. Another government study esti-mated that renovating the North’s dilapidated infrastructure would cost at least $1 trillion.

Foreign assessments are comparably daunting. In 2009, Credit Suisse estimated a cost of $1.5 trillion to raise North Korean in-comes to 60 percent of those in the South. Peter Beck of Stanford believes that even this figure is far too low. He argues that raising in-come levels in the North to 80 percent of those in the South would become a political necessity and would cost $2 trillion to $5 tril-lion over 30 years.

But as high as they are, such figures are probably manageable for a couple of reasons. First, because South Korea has prospered mightily over the last four decades: with a GDP of some $1.4 trillion in purchasing power terms and a future growth rate of per-haps 3 percent, South Korea could spend $40 billion on the North in 2011 without reduc-

ing its current living standard. And $40 bil-lion would double North Korea’s income. Second, because the collapse of the North would allow the South to reduce its military outlays: while the South Korean defense bud-get is a secret, according to the World Bank it amounted to 2.6 percent of GDP in 2006. If that percentage remained constant, the bud-get was on the order of $30 billion in 2010.

To put the issue in further perspective, consider western Germany, which has been subsidizing the former East Germany to the tune of $100 billion annually since 1991. While South Korea’s output is about half that of Germany, a comparable portion of the South Korean GDP would still amount to $50 billion this year. And, if the Korean economy grew at a modest 3 percent annually, the fig-ure would rise to $90 billion in two decades.

through a glass, darklyIronically, no one (with the likely exception of a great majority of North Koreans) is eager to see North Korea collapse. Too much is at stake. China doesn’t want a flood of refugees; many South Koreans fear the consequences of the economic dislocation. And nobody wants to face the increased prospect of military con-flict during the transition, especially now that the North has nuclear weapons.

So the best guess is that, in the end, the North Korean regime and state will be given every opportunity to muddle through, whether or not it is willing to negotiate away its nuclear option. This doesn’t mean that the economy (and the government) won’t col-lapse one day. Indeed, it is hard to imagine a state so incompetent and so lacking in popu-lar support surviving indefinitely. But the push will probably have to come from within. Sadly, we may have gotten to the point where there are no longer optimists when it comes to North Korea – only realists. m

Page 16: Milken Institute Review Q4

The Milken Institute Review14

b y w i l l i a m h . f r e y

of the fact that fewer whites than non-

whites will soon be born each year in the United States. Minorities, in general (and His-

panics in particular), are younger and more inclined to have children. Meanwhile,

older Americans are predominantly white and will remain that way for a long time.

Much has been made

c h a r t i c l e

Large Metros — greatest CuLturaL generation gaps

In the past, generations largely fought over values and lifestyles. This time around, the gap is also creating very visible divisions over

the use of public resources – think education, pensions and health care. And the differences have become especially sharp because the old

left

: oce

an p

hoto

grap

hy/v

eer;

rig

ht: c

reat

ista

/vee

r

austin, tx: -29%75%

46%

Lo

s angeLes, Ca: -32%53%

22%

tuCson, az: -40%79%

39%

MiLwaukee, wi: -29%87%

58%

Houston, tx: -31%64%

33%

daLLas, tx: -34%76%

42%

orLando, fL: -31%76%

45%

pHoenix, az: -41%85%

44%

san diego, Ca: -34%71%

37%

riverside, Ca: -40%67%

27%

Las vegas, nv: -34%72%

38%

san jose, Ca: -30%58%

28%

Page 17: Milken Institute Review Q4

15Fourth Quarter 2010

sour

ce: W

illia

m H

. Fre

y an

alys

is o

f 200

8 Am

eric

an C

omm

unity

Sur

vey

and

U.S.

Cens

us p

roje

ctio

ns.

have ever less in common with the young in terms of race, familial ties, national origins and language.

All told, whites comprise 56 percent of American children and 80 percent of seniors, a gap of 24 percentage points. But the differ-ence is far larger in the Sun Belt, which is a magnet to both white retirees and young His-panics. Arizona, with a chasm of 40 percent-age points, leads the states. And, not surpris-ingly, it has become ground zero on racially and economically charged immigration issues.

Watch politicians in Nevada, California, Texas, New Mexico, Florida and Colorado try to have it both ways (or choose sides with a vengeance) on a host of issues like the funding of schools. Candidates for local elections face

similar decisions – especially in Phoenix, Riv-erside, Tucson, Dallas, Las Vegas and Houston.

The irony is that the quality of life for re-tirees depends on the future productivity of younger, predominantly non-white Ameri-cans. Lower taxes, half-starved schools and less generous medical care for the young may work for seniors right now. But not far down the road, they will depend on a less healthy, less skilled, alienated workforce to cover the ballooning costs of Social Security, Medicare and Medicaid-funded nursing homes.

Good luck with that.

states — greatest CuLturaL generation gaps

Bi ll Frey is a senior fellow in demography at the Milken institute and senior fellow in metropolitan policy at the Brookings institution.

gap (differenCe)% of population

age 65+ that is white

% of population

under age 18 that is white

CoLorado: -24%84%

fLorida: -29%78%

49%

nevada: -34%77%

43%

iLLinois: -25%80%

55%

texas: -31%68%

37%

new MexiCo: -31%60%

29%

arizona: -40%

83%

43%

georgia: -25%75%

50% 60%

deLaware: -26%84%

58%

CaLifornia: -33%63%

30%

U.S. total: -26%80%

54%

Page 18: Milken Institute Review Q4

G16 The Milken Institute Review

Genetic modification of cultivated crops has widely been damned as the work

of the proverbial sorcerer’s apprentice, a looming threat to public health and

environmental stability. But in my view, the promise of genetic-modification

technologies is vast and the perceived risks are overblown.

The potential of genetically modified crops is manifold. They can increase

productivity in agriculture, ensuring the availability of cheap food and other

crop-based raw materials for a growing population with rapidly rising eco-

nomic expectations, even as the non-renewable natural resource base dwin-

dles. Genetically modified crops can reduce the negative environmental foot-

print of agriculture by reducing the demand for fossil fuels, toxic chemicals

and water. What’s more, new seed technologies are likely to play an impor-

tant role in alleviating poverty and income inequality by sustaining income

growth in developing countries. And finally, genetic modification could

transform staple sources of calories into far more balanced sources of nutri-

tion needed to reduce childhood mortality and enhance the quality of life.

Indeed, the biggest challenge posed by genetic modification is how to create

a regulatory framework that provides reasonable public oversight but resists

the understandable impulse to curb progress based on these technologies.

Resistance is Fruitful

by matin qaim

Genetically modified crops hold vast economic promise. Will politics mow down progress?

Page 19: Milken Institute Review Q4

17Fourth Quarter 2010

tim

bow

er (a

ll)

Page 20: Milken Institute Review Q4

18 The Milken Institute Review

first things firstA genetically modified plant is one in which bioengineering techniques have been used to insert one or more genes that code the plant for desirable traits. These genes may, of course, come from other plants, as well as from totally unrelated organisms. The basic technology was developed in the early 1980s, with the

first genetically modified crops becoming commercially available in the mid-1990s. Since then, genetically modified crop adop-tion has increased rapidly. In 2009, genetically modified crops were grown on almost 10 per-cent of the world’s arable land.

The crop traits sought through genetic en-gineering are not entirely novel: People have

searched for centuries (with some success) for ways to adapt crops to soil and climate condi-tions and to pest challenges. However, since genetic-modification technology allows di-rect gene transfer across species boundaries, some traits that were previously difficult or impossible to obtain can now be bred with relative ease.

Genetic-modification traits fall into three categories. First-generation genetically modi-fied crops involve improvements in tradi-tional agronomic traits like better resistance to disease. Second-generation genetically modi-fied crops involve enhanced quality traits – say, adding a valued nutrient to a food crop – and third-generation crops are plants designed to produce special substances for pharmaceuti-cal or industrial purposes. Whereas second- and third-generation technologies are still in the research pipeline, a few first-generation crops are already widely grown. Examples in-clude insect-resistant corn and cotton, and herbicide-tolerant soybeans and sugar beets.

frankenfood? In spite of the potential of genetically modi-fied crops, though, resistance to their devel-opment and use can be fierce. Reservations are particularly strong in Europe. But the consequences of European opposition have spilled over to other regions, thanks to a com-bination of trade regulation and active lobby-ing by public interest groups. Resistance is largely driven by the specter of environmental and health risks. But some people also argue that genetic-modification technology could disrupt traditional (and valuable) knowledge systems in developing countries – say, the way packaged baby formula displaced breast- feeding in Africa. Last but not least, critics argue that the increasing privatization of crop-improvement research, along with the broadening of intellectual property rights in

Mati n QaiM is a professor of agricultural economics and rural development at the University of Göttingen in Germany. Email: [email protected]

Global adoption of Genetically Modified crops

140

120

100

80

60

40

20

01995 2000 2005 2009

year

total

IndustrIalIzed countrIes

developIng countrIes

source: International Service for the Acquisition of Agri-Biotech Applications

Glo

bal

GM

cro

p a

rea

(Mil

lio

n h

a)

g e n e t i c m o d i f i c a t i o n

Page 21: Milken Institute Review Q4

19Fourth Quarter 2010

plants, will increase corporate market power in seeds at the expense of small farmers.

herbicide-tolerant cropsChemicals that kill weeds can often kill crops along with them. Genetically modified herbi-cide-tolerant crops coexist with specific broad-spectrum herbicides, like glyphosate or glufosinate, that are more effective, less toxic and usually cheaper than the more-selective herbicides needed to protect many unmodified plant spe-cies. The most successful of these in commercial terms today is an herbi-cide-tolerant soybean, which is now planted in more than half the total acreage devoted to genetically modi-fied crops. Herbicide-tolerant soy-beans are currently grown primarily in the United States and in Argentina, Brazil and other South American countries. Herbicide-tolerant corn, cotton and sugar beets are so far mostly confined to the United States, while herbicide-tolerant canola (the raw material for increasingly popular canola oil) is particularly important in Canada.

The big benefit, from farmers’ per-spective, is financial. In some, though not all, cases, herbicide-tolerant crops require less (as well as less-expensive) herbicide. Indeed, in Argentina, total herbi-cide use went up significantly after the adop-tion of herbicide-tolerant soybeans. This is largely due to the fact that, with these geneti-cally modified seeds, using herbicide sprays as well can be a satisfactory substitute for till-age – an age-old way to control weeds. The portion of Argentine soybean farmers using direct seeding without prior tillage has dou-bled, to almost 90 percent, since the introduc-tion of herbicide-tolerant technology.

At first glance, this suggests that herbicide-tolerant soybeans have the potential to be more environmentally problematic than con-ventional soybean cultivation. But, in fact, no-till farming helps to reduce soil erosion and generates less greenhouse gas emissions because mechanical tillage burns a lot of fuel and sets free carbon dioxide and nitrous ox-ides bound in the soil.

Herbicide-tolerant technology has also ex-panded the use of no-till practices in the United States and Canada, with little loss in average yields. In a few cases, where weeds were difficult to control with selective herbi-cides, the adoption of herbicide-tolerant seed and the switch to broad-spectrum herbicides have actually resulted in better weed control and higher crop yields.

Herbicide-tolerant technology can signifi-cantly reduce production costs by lowering

Page 22: Milken Institute Review Q4

20 The Milken Institute Review

expenditures for herbicides, labor, machinery and fuel. However, since herbicide-tolerant crops were developed and commercialized by private companies, the price of the seeds in-cludes royalty fees – and, of course, affects the financial incentives to switch to them. Re-search on the economic impact of herbicide-tolerant soybeans in the United States shows

that the owners of the genetic-modification technology have captured most of the eco-nomic surplus – that is, the fee is often equal to (and sometimes higher than) the reduction in production costs at the farm level. The calcula-tions for herbicide-tolerant cotton and canola cultivation in the United States generate simi-lar results. So, apparently the main reason these farmers prefer herbicide-tolerant tech-nology is that it saves management time and offers a more reliable way to control weeds.

But in South America, farmers have a clearer motive for using herbicide-tolerant seeds. While these farmers’ methods are simi-lar to those employed by farmers in the United States, their returns are larger because the royalties on seeds are lower – almost cer-tainly because the seed companies can’t count on either the protection or enforcement of patents on herbicide-tolerant technology. In-

deed, many soybean farmers in South America even use genetically modified seeds they reproduce from the seed companies’ versions. On average, Argen-tine farmers net an extra $25 per hectare (2.47 acres) by adopting herbicide- tolerant technology. Genetically modi-fied crops are apparently so profitable for growers that the seeds are now used for almost all soybean cultivation in the country. In Brazil and other South American countries, where the technology was commercialized more recently, adoption rates aren’t as high but are increasing rapidly.

Who gets the benefits of increased productivity matters a lot, of course, to farmers, seed companies and soybean consumers. But it’s worth remembering that the division has no direct effect on the total size of the gain to society in terms of resource savings. The best esti-mates suggest that herbicide-tolerant

soybeans are currently generating welfare gains of $5 billion annually, divided among farmers (in the form of higher profits), con-sumers (in the form of lower prices for soybean oil and meal), and herbicide-tolerant-technol-ogy owners (in the form of royalties). Compa-rable gains have also been generated by other commercialized herbicide-tolerant crops.

insect-resistant cropsBioengineering also makes it possible to create

g e n e t i c m o d i f i c a t i o n

Page 23: Milken Institute Review Q4

21Fourth Quarter 2010

insect-resistant genetically modified crops. The ones that have reached the stage of com-mercialization have employed genes from the soil bacterium Bacillus thuringiensis (Bt), which make the plants resistant to some pest species. The most widely used examples are Bt corn and Bt cotton.

In 2009, Bt corn was grown on almost 40 million hectares (about 100 million acres) in some 15 countries. The biggest Bt corn areas are found in the United States, Argentina, South Africa, Canada and the Philippines. Bt cotton was grown on roughly 15 million hect-ares (37 million acres) in that same year – most of it in India, China and the United States. But farmers in other countries are be-ginning to adopt the technology, too.

Where insect pests can be effectively con-trolled with chemicals, the main effect of switching to Bt crops is to reduce the need to apply insecticides. However, there are situa-tions in which insect control with chemicals is just not practical. Insecticides may be far too expensive to use, or too toxic to farm workers, or unavailable because of supply constraints or import restrictions. In those cases, Bt tech-nology represents the sole means for reducing crop damage and raising yields. Both insecticide-reducing and yield-increasing ef-fects of Bt crops can be observed in the table to the right.

With conventional cotton, large quantities of chemical insecticides are normally used to control the bollworm. Bt cotton generally eliminates this pest without resorting to chemicals. Accordingly, Bt cotton adoption has led to reductions in insecticide use of 30 to 80 percent, along with substantial increases in yields, especially in developing countries. In Argentina, for instance, conventional cot-ton farmers tend to use chemical insecticides at less-than-optimal levels, so the pests are not effectively controlled. In India and China,

chemical use is much higher. But the insecti-cides are not always very effective, due to low quality, resistance among the local pest popu-lations and, sometimes, incorrect timing of spraying. Similar effects have been observed with Bt corn.

Bt seeds are more expensive than conven-tional ones. But the economic advantages as-sociated with insecticide savings and higher effective yields more than offset the royalties in all the countries studied. As with herbi-

cide-tolerant crops, the farmers’ gains from using Bt crops varies from country to country, in large part because seed companies capture less of the surplus in economies where intel-lectual property is less protected.

The total gains accruing to farmers, con-sumers and technology owners through the use of Bt seeds amounts to several billion dol-lars annually – in the same range as the gains from herbicide-tolerant crops. The indirect benefits are substantial, too. Less use of insec-ticides generates benefits to human health and reduces environmental stresses associ-ated with farming. Furthermore, crop dam-age from insects leads to the proliferation of toxic funguses. So Bt crops are generally less

InsectIcIde Increase In Increase Incountry reductIon effectIve yIeld farm profIt (%) (%) (us$/ha)

Bt cottonArgentina 47% 33% $23Australia 48 0 66China 65 24 470India 41 37 135Mexico 77 9 295SouthAfrica 33 22 91UnitedStates 36 10 58 Bt cornArgentina 0 9 20Philippines 5 34 53SouthAfrica 10 11 42Spain 63 6 70UnitedStates 8 5 12

farM-level effects of bt crops

source: the author

Page 24: Milken Institute Review Q4

22 The Milken Institute Review

contaminated with mycotoxins than their conventional counterparts – a big advantage with corn, which ends up in animal feed as well as in myriad food products manufac-tured with corn syrup and corn oil.

next-generation applicationsA number of other Bt crops have been com-

mercialized recently or are likely to be mar-keted soon. Bt rice and Bt eggplant have al-ready been field-tested extensively in China and India, with the expected insecticide- reducing and yield-increasing impact. Genet-ically modified crops engineered to resist harmful funguses, viruses, nematodes and bacteria can be expected fairly soon. The im-pact on yields will likely be more pronounced in the tropics and subtropics, where pest pressure is often higher and farmers face

more severe financial constraints in control-ling pest damage.

By the same token, the effects of genetically modified crops engineered to cope with other kinds of environmental adversity will vary greatly with regional conditions. A genetically modified crop built to tolerate drought, for example, will have a far greater impact on yields in semiarid regions – especially in the

impoverished semiarid tropics where irrigation is not available. Likewise, engineered tolerance to heat, salinity, floods and other stresses will probably matter most to farmers in poorer countries. Climate change seems to be associated with more frequent weather extremes, so genetically modified crops could make a big difference in reducing the risks of crop failures and food crises as greenhouse gases accu-mulate in the atmosphere.

Researchers are also working on nutritionally enhanced genetically modified crops, like oilseeds with fats that are less likely to lead to cardiovas-cular disease and staple foods with enhanced mineral and vitamin con-tent, in poor countries. Enhancing nutritional content is called bio- fortification. For example, a bio-forti-fied crop called Golden Rice, which contains significant amounts of pro-

vitamin A, could become commercially avail-able in some Asian countries in 2012.

Golden Rice could prove to be a major health advance because vitamin A deficiency is widespread in poor households, reducing resistance to infectious diseases while increas-ing child mortality and blindness. Recent re-search suggests that Golden Rice could reduce the health burden of vitamin A deficiency by up to 60 percent – and at a far lower cost than getting vitamin A supplements to the people

g e n e t i c m o d i f i c a t i o n

Page 25: Milken Institute Review Q4

23Fourth Quarter 2010

in need. Significant health benefits can also be expected from other bio-fortified crops. Among the candidates are staple foods rich in iron, zinc, folate and essential amino acids.

Finally, a number of third-generation ge-netically modified crops are in the pipeline. These involve molecular farming, where the crop is used to produce pharmaceuticals like monoclonal antibodies and vaccines, or in-dustrial products like enzymes and biodegradable plastics. While con-cepts have already been proven for a number of such technologies, product development and regulatory issues are inherently more complex than for first and second-generation genetically modified crops. We need to be sure that the substances produced in the plants do not enter the regular food chain. Therefore, it is both likely and desirable that third-generation geneti-cally modified plants that are not used directly or indirectly as food will need to pass regulatory hurdles. It’s also likely that they will only be licensed for use under contained conditions.

What is clear at this point, though, is that the potential is enormous – and that the genetically modified crops commercially available so far represent only the first steps in a long technological march that could revo-lutionize the use of agriculture.

genetically modified crops and poverty reductionSeventy-five percent of all poor people in the world are small farmers or rural laborers in developing countries. Therefore, genetically modified crops might have important impli-cations for poverty and income distribution. If only rich farmers benefit, inequality will in-crease. Yet, if resource-poor farmers could

obtain genetically modified seeds suitable for their situations, the poverty and equity effects might well be positive – and large.

The way the technology evolves matters here, of course. But so, too, does what social scientists like to call the institutional setting. For instance, the strength of patents will have a major impact on the way the windfall from genetically modified crops is divided. So, too,

will the degree of competition in the seed markets (at both the wholesale and retail lev-els), the availability of credit to buy geneti-cally modified seeds, and the availability of information about which seeds work best under what conditions.

Herbicide-tolerant crops have so far not been widely adopted by small farmers. They often weed manually, so herbicide-tolerant crops are less advantageous unless labor be-comes more expensive. Not so with Bt crops,

Page 26: Milken Institute Review Q4

24 The Milken Institute Review

where brute-force labor is simply not a sub-stitute for chemicals or engineered insect re-sistance. In India, China and South Africa, Bt cotton is often grown by farmers with less than two hectares (five acres) of land. And in South Africa, many smallholders grow Bt white corn as their staple food.

Research shows that the advantages of Bt technology are of a similar magnitude for small farmers as for industrial farming – and

sometimes even greater. One recent study in-vestigated the broad impact of Bt cotton in India, including the effect on landless labor-ers and local sectors linked to agriculture. Each hectare of Bt cotton adds $250 more in-come than the marginal hectare of conven-tional cotton – an increase of 83 percent. For the total Bt cotton area in India, this trans-lates into an annual income gain of over $2 billion for rural households. All income classes benefit, including households below the poverty line. In fact, a remarkable 60 per-cent of the gains accrue to the poor. These re-

sults stand in stark contrast to claims by anti-biotech activists that Bt cotton is ruining peasant households in India and driving farmers to suicide.

The positive social effects from India can-not be extrapolated to other genetically mod-ified crops and other countries, as the impact depends on the conditions in a particular set-ting. But the example underscores the reality that genetic-modification technology has the potential to contribute to both poverty reduc-tion and to the growth of a rural middle class in developing countries, if the institutional setting gives a fair break to small farmers.

bio-safety and food-safety regulationGovernments have an important role in en-suring that novel foods are safe for human consumption and that novel agricultural in-puts do not damage the environment or im-pair agricultural productivity in the long term. Most countries, with the notable exception of the United States, consider any food that in-corporates genetically modified crops to be a novel food, no matter how far up the produc-tion chain one goes. Hence, new laws and in-stitutions to regulate potential bio-safety and food-safety issues have been established, re-quiring that genetically modified products be approved before they may be grown, im-ported or consumed. Since approval pro-cesses vary from country to country, regula-tion has become a major barrier to the spread of genetically modified crops and technolo-gies around the world. For example, the EU has not yet approved some of the genetically modified corn technologies that are used in the United States and Argentina, which ob-structs trade not only in the technologies but also trade in corn and corn products.

In the EU, the regulatory barriers seem to be a political reaction to popular sentiment. In

g e n e t i c m o d i f i c a t i o n

household incoMe effects of bt cotton in india

$600

500

400

300

200

100

0Extremely

poorAll

householdsModerately

poorNon-poor

$/h

ecta

re

bt cottonconventIonal cotton

source: Qaim et al. 2009

Page 27: Milken Institute Review Q4

25Fourth Quarter 2010

other parts of the world, however, the failure to approve genetically modified crops is often due to the reality that countries (and farmers) lack the expertise to set and enforce rational standards. Smaller developing countries have the most problematic records in this area.

In countries where there is a bio-safety system in place, most of the regulatory effort is put into preventing the commercialization of products that might harm people or the environment. Regulators typi-cally err on the side of caution, re-quiring arduous testing over long pe-riods. Such caution comes at a high price: it typically costs about $10 mil-lion to obtain regulatory approval of a new Bt or herbicide-tolerant corn technology in a single country.

Commercializing the same tech-nology in other countries requires seed vendors to jump through the same hoops yet again. And, beyond these direct regulatory costs, there are indirect costs in terms of delayed approvals and the risk that blanket moratoriums on new approvals of any sort will stop the process in mid-flight.

The biggest impact is on minor crops and small countries, where markets are not large enough to jus-tify the initial cost. Note, moreover, that regulatory barriers have a disproportion-ate impact on small firms that can’t afford to play the game. As a result, the genetically modified seed industry is highly concentrated

– a reality that reduces the pace of innovation and makes it less likely that competition will force down royalty rates.

If such lengthy and complex procedures were really necessary to ensure reasonable levels of safety, the outlays (and reduction in competition) involved would be justified. But

since there is no evidence that the use of first- and second-generation genetic engineering entails exceptional risks, it makes no sense to subject genetically modified crops to a much higher degree of scrutiny than conventionally bred crops. The regulatory complexity fol-lows from the lobbying success of non- governmental organizations opposed to the use of biotechnology in agriculture.

labeling and coexistenceMany countries have labeling systems for con-sumer foods. Mandatory labeling is often used to warn consumers of specific health risks (for example: cigarettes cause cancer), whereas voluntary labeling is more common to differ-entiate products with desirable characteristics for marketing purposes (like organic, low-salt or high-protein). Both approaches can pro-vide the same information. But in light of the fact that only genetically modified products

Page 28: Milken Institute Review Q4

26 The Milken Institute Review

considered safe by regulators are approved for market release in the first place, mandatory la-beling is deeply problematic.

Nonetheless, the EU requires labeling that may add significantly to costs – and certainly reinforces the notion that genetically modified products are inherently unsafe. Defenders of the EU’s choice of mandatory labeling say consumers have a right to know, a stance that in this context seems an invitation to use label-ing systems as a backdoor form of resistance to products that have already passed regulatory scrutiny. Note, moreover, that labeling forces producers to segregate genetically modified ingredients from non-genetically modified ones, which can be quite costly – especially if the products are sold in several countries with varying labeling rules.

Labeling and segregation are also related to what can be called the issue of coexistence. The EU has established rules to ensure the co-existence of genetically modified crops with conventional crops as well as those labeled or-ganic. To manage this, regulators must create detailed standards – everything from mini-mum distance requirements for cultivation to liability and insurance measures. The result-ing degree of complexity and uncertainty cre-ated by coexistence rules represent clear dis-incentives for EU farmers to plant genetically modified crops.

the patent perplexIn the United States and most other devel-oped countries, living organisms (and parts thereof) have been patentable since the 1980s. This has spurred a tremendous amount of private research. More than 75 percent of all patents related to genetically modified crops are held by the private sector, most of them by a handful of multinational corporations.

Note the fundamental economic tension

with genetic-modification patent protection (and intellectual property protection in gen-eral). While strong protection creates robust incentives for private investment in R&D, it leads to higher prices for the products that are created. More to the point, it inevitably cre-ates a gap between prices charged and the marginal cost of production. So the degree of intellectual property protection in a country affects the rate of genetically modified crop adoption, as well as the division of benefits between property owners on the one hand and farmers and consumers on the other. When royalties on genetically modified seed prices are high, poor farmers in particular may not adopt them. It follows that the opti-mal level of patent protection and enforce-ment (from the perspective of society as a whole) will be lower in developing countries.

The proliferation of patents on genes and technologies has also led to access and free-dom-to-operate problems within the bio-technology industry itself. Since the develop-ment of a single genetically modified crop may require the use of dozens of patented en-abling technologies, licenses have to be nego-tiated with multiple parties – a process that can generate high transaction costs. And since large corporations are better able to op-erate in this high-transaction-cost environ-ment, the freedom-to-operate problem may contribute to further industry concentration.

Public-sector research organizations are particularly at a disadvantage because they typically have little to offer in trade for li-censes from private companies. Even the larg-est individual public-sector patent holders, like the University of California and the U.S. Department of Agriculture, own less than 2 percent of total agricultural biotechnology patents; by comparison, Monsanto and Du-Pont each control more than 10 percent of biotech patents.

g e n e t i c m o d i f i c a t i o n

Page 29: Milken Institute Review Q4

27Fourth Quarter 2010

All told, though, public organizations hold 24 percent of these patents, and in some areas they could develop genetically modified crops without having to rely on patents from the private sector. Special clearinghouse mechan-isms to reduce transaction costs might facili-tate public-sector joint ventures. One exam-ple is the Public Intellectual Property Resource for Agriculture, which brings together intel-lectual property from over 40 uni-versities and public agencies and helps to make their technologies available to innovators around the world.

Such public-sector steps are im-portant, as some R&D challenges in genetic modification are unlikely to be addressed by private companies because of the limited size of poten-tial commercial markets – for exam-ple, technologies especially designed for poor farmers and consumers in developing countries. By the same token, more public-private partner-ships should be sought in order to harness the comparative strengths of both. Universities are typically better suited to basic research, whereas pri-vate companies have advantages in applied R&D.

the way forwardWith constraints on climate, energy and water increasingly impinging on the world’s capac-ity to expand agricultural output by conven-tional means, genetic-modification technolo-gies are likely to become ever more important in maintaining high living standards in the industrialized world and allowing billions of others to enjoy the fruits of economic devel-opment. No less significant, third-generation genetic-modification technologies have the potential to harness plant life in tasks ranging

from synthesizing antibiotics to cleaning up oil spills.

But ironically, just as genetic-modification technologies are beginning to deliver on their promise, opposition to these technologies is growing – especially in Europe. There are, of course, risks to virtually every technological change built on the manipulation of life forms. But every path to the future bears risk.

And the response to the risks generated by ge-netic-modification technologies has largely been unconstructive, slowing innovation, in-creasing industrial concentration and creat-ing biases against changes that would benefit the poor. This is not to say that zero regula-tion would be desirable. But it would be sad, indeed, if critical technologies that could help to overcome the daunting challenges faced by the planet were sacrificed on the altar of fear and ignorance. m

Page 30: Milken Institute Review Q4

28 The Milken Institute Review

goldgoldIts recent glitter might

be the portent of a nightmare

Page 31: Milken Institute Review Q4

29Fourth Quarter 2010

goldgoldBy Christopher

Meissner

Page 32: Milken Institute Review Q4

30 The Milken Institute Review

prev

ious

pag

e: da

j/ge

tty

imag

es

Ch ris Meissn er, an economist at the University of California (Davis), specializes in the history of the interna-tional economy.

Now, followers of the dismal science are generally not inclined to speculate on the timing of financial investments. Indeed, most economists assume that nobody has much to say that’s worth hearing on this subject. Ac-cordingly, I told her that her guess was as good as mine.

The rest, as they say way too often, is his-tory. The price of gold hit a 30-year high in 2010. A $100,000 bet on gold in 2005 would be worth, as I write this piece, about $300,000. If only I’d ignored all this “efficient market” nonsense.

It’s clear that the spectacular jump in the price of gold in the last few years is the mar-ket’s way of telling us something. Less clear is what. Not a few people feel that gold is an ex-cellent way of insuring against imminent fi-nancial turmoil and dollar depreciation. But there are other interpretations. John Maynard Keynes argued that asset and commodity prices are often driven by nothing more than guesses about other people’s guesses about other people’s guesses, etc. Investors may sim-ply be loading up on gold because they have made the calculation that others will con-tinue to buy gold – at least for a while longer.

But, as an economist, I like to think I still have some interesting things to say about the mystical metal – in particular, about its role, past and future, as a way to store wealth and

to facilitate exchange in a global economy that has apparently entered a period of con-siderable instability.

been there, done thatGold is quite scarce. In fact, if all the gold ever mined were spread over a football field, the pile would be only about five feet high. That’s why relatively small increases in demand can lead to big increases in the price. So, where has this price-destabilizing demand been coming from?

Gold does have significant commercial uses. It’s valued for its electrical conductivity, for its role as a catalyst in myriad chemical re-actions and, of course, for its color, malleabil-ity and resistance to discoloration when used for decoration and display. But these sources of demand have not changed much in recent years; nor are they expected to.

That leaves less tangible sources of de-mand to explain the jump in price. First, from those worried about the potential fall in value of other assets in a period of inflation, depre-ciation of the dollar, or widespread failure of financial institutions. Gold, in short, has al-ways been viewed as insurance against hard times. Second, from those who don’t share the doom and gloom outlook, but do want to ride the wave of a rising asset class – Keynes’ aforementioned speculators.

Is the first group (the worrywarts) right? Unlike the bank reserves and paper money that the Federal Reserve can create in almost unlimited quantities, the supply of gold

CCambridge University dons are widely respected (excessively, on occa-

sion) for their sagacity. In 2005, when I was one of them, a student’s

mother cold-called me: “Dr. Meissner, is this the time to buy gold?”

Page 33: Milken Institute Review Q4

imag

ebro

ker/

alam

y

changes relatively slowly and thus would be expected to gain value in relative terms in pe-riods of inflation. And this points to a broader question that people have been asking for centuries: Wouldn’t a gold “standard” that tightly limited the capacity of governments and private banks to create money be a way to make sure that financial assets remained a safe store of value?

Indeed, wouldn’t a gold standard have lim-ited the expansion of credit that led to the speculative boom and bust in the housing market over the past decade? If banks had been obliged to exchange gold (or currency backed by gold) on demand for bank deposits, wouldn’t they have been a lot more careful about the quality of the collateral that they accepted on loans? Last but not least, if a gold standard had been in place and if banks hadn’t been able to rely on the Federal Re-serve to bail them out in a crisis by creating more money, wouldn’t they have acted more prudently in the first place?

And what about the international role of the dollar? Booming demand for dollar- denominated financial assets from China (and a handful of other countries with mas-sive savings-investment imbalances) led to the easy credit regime of the last decade. With lending constrained in the United States, wouldn’t those global imbalances have been smaller, or at least have been channeled into less volatile assets?

The short answer to all these questions is that the potential gains from a commodity money regime would almost certainly have been outweighed by the damage, if and when the system broke under pressure. The Great Depression, perhaps the greatest financial and economic crisis ever, took place in spite of the gold standard – and the damage was made much worse by the constraints im-posed by the standard. We can’t write off the Great Depression as a special case. Banking crises were just as common in the 19th cen-tury, when much of the world was operating

31Fourth Quarter 2010

Page 34: Milken Institute Review Q4

32 The Milken Institute Review

on a gold standard. Nor, for that matter, did the gold standard succeed in stabilizing prices over long periods.

failure of the collective memory Government central banks, which largely de-termine the volume of liquid financial assets used as money, are the rocks on which the modern market system is built. The more eco-nomic actors who trust central bank money as a medium of exchange, a store of value and a unit of account, the more efficient the mon-

etary system. To this end, the primary task of an independent central bank, at least since the 19th century, has been to maintain the relative value of the currency (i.e., to avoid inflation and deflation) by making sure that neither too much (nor too little) money is created.

To this end, major economies all estab-lished commodity-based systems using gold or silver (or both) as “backing” for the local currency – a voluntary straightjacket of sorts. In the United States, the official parity for the dollar from 1873 to 1914 was $20.67 per troy ounce (about 1.1 avoirdupois ounces on the grocer’s scale) of gold. Private banks had strong incentives to extend credit judiciously under this regime because their depositors could al-ways ask for their money back in gold (or gov-ernment currency formally backed by gold).

By 1878, most leading economies outside Asia had adopted a gold standard. Their cur-rencies were convertible into gold, and hence

into other currencies at a fixed rate. In effect, the global economy had tied itself to a cur-rency union.

This reduced the one major source of un-certainty associated with international trade and investment: the risk that obligations would be paid in the depreciated currency of another country. Trade and cross-border cap-ital flows surged. And a virtuous circle emerged: Exchange rate stability allowed glo-balization to flourish, which encouraged lag-gards to join the gold standard. The pace of growth accelerated along with trade.

The conventional view is that the system worked automatically and smoothly to stabi-lize price levels and to correct global financial imbalances – that is, large current account surpluses and their counterpart deficits – by forcing price adjustments in countries prone to inflation or deflation. (This, of course, is in contrast to today’s apparently unsustainable imbalances, which persist in an atmosphere of political tension and mutual recrimina-tion.) But a closer look suggests that the gold standard was not all that stable.

From 1873 to 1896, industrialized coun-tries were forced to cope with an almost con-tinuous deflation. In the United States, prices declined on average by 1 percent annually for almost a quarter century, as growth in the quantity of commodity money (gold) failed to keep pace with growth in economic activ-ity and forced adjustment through falling prices. At the same time, Asian countries that

g o l d ’ s l a t e s t g l i t t e r

A commodity money standard can deliver on its promise

of stability only if participating countries are willing

and able to stick by the standard in periods of economic

and financial stress.

Page 35: Milken Institute Review Q4

33Fourth Quarter 2010

aspe

ndes

igns

.net

had adopted silver as commodity money faced inflation as the relative value of silver versus gold declined by half.

Then, gold discoveries in South Africa and Alaska in the 1890s, along with technical ad-vances that made it practical to produce gold from lower-grade ores, led to a rise in the sup-ply of gold – and to inflation in gold standard countries. In the United States, prices rose at an average rate of 2 percent annually from 1896 until 1914. The commodity monetary standard had effectively made prices hostage to the vicissitudes of the supply of the un-derlying commodity backing the money supply.

Unanticipated deflation or inflation can generate political tensions because it redis-tributes wealth and income. In the 1870s and 1880s, farmers in the American Mid-west, who perceived themselves as vic-tims of deflation (though the actual sources of their malaise seem to be more complex), formed a “soft money” coali-tion. They decried the gold standard as unfair to debtors who had to repay mortgages with ever more valuable dollars that were ever more difficult to earn by selling crops whose prices were falling. (In the words of the Democratic presidential candidate William Jennings Bryan: “You shall not crucify mankind [i.e., U.S. farm-ers and laborers] upon a cross of gold.” Re-publicans, who had ties to both banks that held the debt and to East Coast industrialists who believed they benefited from deflation, defended the system.

Consider, too, another fundamental draw-back of a commodity money standard: it can deliver on its promise of stability only if par-ticipating countries are willing and able to stick by the standard in periods of economic and financial stress. Europe’s industrialized

core did stay on the gold standard (and, ac-cordingly, their exchange rates remained sta-ble) for the duration of the Belle Époque. However, many countries on the periphery – Argentina, Brazil, Greece, Italy, Portugal – periodically fell off the wagon.

The United States remained true to the gold standard from 1879 to 1933. However, on numerous occasions banking panics led to local “suspensions of convertibility” in which depositors would receive private IOUs in lieu of gold-backed currency. And from 1891 to 1896, the United States Treasury came dan-gerously close to running out of gold reserves, as holders of dollars exchanged them for

Page 36: Milken Institute Review Q4

34 The Milken Institute Review

©sg

m/a

ge f

otos

tock

metal because they feared that Bryan would be elected president and devalue the currency. Uncertainty about the will and ability to de-liver on gold-standard promises – and occa-sional panics that followed – ended in the United States only with the introduction of government deposit insurance, regulation that made the retail banking business boring but profitable, and the creation of a true cen-tral bank (the Federal Reserve) to serve as a lender of last resort to illiquid (but solvent) banks.

The Bank of England, the watchdog and regulator of the 19th-century global financial system based in London, maintained the con-

vertibility of the pound into gold from 1821 until the start of World War I in 1914. But the gold standard did not make countries that played by the rules immune to the conse-quences of the behavior of countries that did not. In the Baring Crisis of 1890-91, a global fi-nancial meltdown reminiscent of the 2008 cri-sis, the eminent Baring Brothers bank in Lon-don was caught holding vast amounts of Argentine government debt. When Argentina defaulted and Baring Brothers found itself in a liquidity and solvency crunch, the Bank of England saved Barings by organizing several loans from abroad.

Why, then, did the gold standard endure as long as it did? For one thing, economic elites favored commodity money systems because they made it difficult for officials to act on

Page 37: Milken Institute Review Q4

35Fourth Quarter 2010

political incentives to make credit cheaper or to devalue the currency as a means of sup-porting export interests.

Contrary to the conventional view that the gold standard was a straitjacket, it acted more like a structure designed to survive an earth-quake by flexing with the strain. The gold standard managed to accommodate great stresses because governments temporarily suspended adherence in times of war or se-vere economic crisis. Britain and the United

States both managed to restore the credibility of their commitments by restoring gold con-vertibility after the Napoleonic wars and the American Civil War, respectively. By the same token, the system managed some flexibility within its rigid shell through international cooperation.

When national gold reserves fell below critical levels, it was not unknown for central banks to lend reserves to one another. For ex-ample, the Bank of Russia and the Bank of France came to the rescue of the Bank of En- gland in 1890 during the Baring crisis.

But the gold standard truly broke under the strain of deflation, bank illiquidity and export collapse in the Great Depression of the 1930s. Indeed, many economic historians blame the stubborn adherence to the gold standard for the severity of the Depression. In the United States, maintenance of gold con-vertibility at a fixed parity (which ended only in 1933 under Roosevelt) limited the Federal Reserve’s capacity to act as lender of last re-

sort during wave after wave of banking panic. Similarly, France waited (at great cost) until 1936 to devalue the franc and expand the money supply.

One reason that the gold standard col-lapsed in the 1930s was, of course, the sever-ity of the crisis. But the lesson of history had been pretty clear for quite a while by then: dropping convertibility allowed economies to recover more quickly. What, then, deter-mined the timing of its abandonment?

Democracy played a role. The newly enfranchised mass electorates

of the early 20th century had learned that cy-clical unemployment could be cured by growth in the money supply not possible under a gold standard.

Another reason was the erosion of cooper-ation among the major economic players in the harsh peace that followed World War I. During the 1930s, central banks proved reluc-tant to come to one another’s rescue. And

“beggar they neighbor” policies, in which cur-rency devaluation was used to make one country’s exports more competitive at the ex-pense of others, was no longer deemed an un-pardonable breach of diplomatic etiquette.

In the broadest sense, then, the virtues and drawbacks of the gold standard illustrate the tradeoff between a system that permits dis-cretionary monetary policy and one that is rigid and rule-based. When viewed from this perspective, there is a pretty strong case for opting for flexibility.

In the broadest sense, the virtues and drawbacks of the

gold standard illustrate the tradeoff between a system

that permits discretionary monetary policy and one that

is rigid and rule-based.

Page 38: Milken Institute Review Q4

36 The Milken Institute Review

And so our global financial system has adapted. What we have learned from two centuries of economic history is that discre-tionary monetary policy (one not tied to the quantity of a yellow metal held in govern-ment vaults) can go a long way toward stabi-lizing economic growth and employment. To do so, however, nations must summon disci-pline in other ways – through regulating the banking system and by operating an account-able and transparent central bank that has the capacity to act as a lender of last resort.

the dollar as the world’s reserve currency The purpose of the gold standard was to sta-bilize prices and to force automatic adjust-ments in price levels when international fi-nancial flows associated with trade and investment were not balanced. But gold also served as a medium of exchange and a store of value. And with the demise of the gold standard, the national currencies of eco-nomic powers with a commitment to stable prices effectively filled the vacuum.

The dollar has come to serve as the globe’s primary reserve currency. And, in spite of the fact that the recent financial cri-sis was driven by turbulence in the United States, demand for U.S. government debt as a store of value actually increased more sharply than its amazing increase in supply during the crisis. But it would be foolish to assume that the dollar will remain the global reserve currency.

Over the last decade, the excess savings in Asia and the Persian Gulf that poured into dollar assets financed enormous increases in government- and consumer-debt in the United States. Since no nation can expect for-eigners to subsidize its consumption indefi-nitely, many analysts worry that market senti-ments will shift abruptly at some point and that the dollar will collapse as businesses, funds and foreign governments attempt to trade dollars for other liquid assets – foreign currencies and commodities. Even in the best of scenarios, the international demand for

dollars is likely to dry up, forcing the U.S. Treasury to finance huge budget deficits in other ways.

In either situation, the United States would face the prospect of both high inflation and falling output. The rest of the world, which depends far too much on U.S. economic ac-tivity to sustain growth, might well follow America into deep recession.

Rapid depreciation of the dollar would spell the end of the greenback as the global fi-nancial anchor – and leave a very big part missing from the machinery of international finance. Nations with international balance of payments surpluses accumulate reserves that must be held in liquid form. By the same token, international banks and businesses need stable liquid assets as working capital. This demand for safe liquid assets is large and growing, both because the world economy is growing and because savings imbalances among economies are large and show no sign

g o l d ’ s l a t e s t g l i t t e r

Discretionary monetary policy — one not tied to the quan-

tity of a yellow metal held in government vaults — can go a

long way toward stabilizing economic growth and employment.

Page 39: Milken Institute Review Q4

37Fourth Quarter 2010

of shrinking. Indeed, the scarcity of suitable assets to fill this role probably explains why the dollar is still treated as a reserve currency in spite of the glaring weaknesses of the American fiscal and financial systems.

So where is there left to go? The obvious place is to other currencies. In theory, the euro ought to be a candidate. The market for high-quality euro-denominated securities is huge, as are the outstanding liabilities of Euro- zone central banks. But the Greek fiscal crisis, which underscored the fundamental prob-lems facing Europe’s monetary union, sug-gests that private and official investors aren’t about to create an unofficial euro standard.

Japan has plenty of outstanding debt to use as a liquid store of value and a record of stable (even falling) prices. But, because of slow growth and a rapidly aging population, Japan’s long-term economic prospects are problematic. And in any event, other Asian central banks running big surpluses are reluc-tant for political reasons to depend heavily on Japanese currency as a store of value.

Why not create a new international cur-rency to serve an increasingly integrated global economy? The International Monetary Fund already produces such an asset: Special Drawing Rights, which were introduced in 1969 in response to the perception that the world needed another reserve asset to supple-ment gold and U.S. Treasury liabilities. The exchange value of SDRs is determined by a formula that weights the value of dollars, euros, yen and British pounds. Central banks now hold some $320 billion worth of SDRs, which can be traded at any time for conven-tional reserve currencies at the daily posted value.

But an SDR-based system would face major governance issues. First, someone would have to decide how many SDRs to cre-ate, and when. In a dollar-based system, the

decision is effectively left to the Federal Re-serve and the U.S. Congress – hardly a delega-tion of authority that pleases other countries. But the dollar solution at least avoids the problems of collective decision-making.

Then, there’s the question of who gets the gravy. Under the current system, SDRs are al-located among member states in proportion to their IMF quotas – their commitments to participate in IMF loan programs. But when SDRs were first dreamed up, the Belgian-American economist Robert Triffin suggested that newly created SDRs should be allocated to poor countries as a form of collective for-eign aid. And with tens of billions or even hundreds of billions of SDRs being added to the system annually, the issue would surely arise once again.

* * *Gold has long been the foul-weather asset

of choice. And in an era of high financial vol-atility and no clear path to a stable future, it’s not surprising that the price of gold is push-ing record highs. Nor is it surprising that peo-ple who don’t look very closely may choose to view the era of the gold standard as a model for fixing the global financial system.

But nostalgia should not be confused with analysis. The gold standard functioned rea-sonably well in a simpler time in which the handful of rich industrialized nations that ran the global economy were able to make common cause to bring the system through periods of stress – stress, incidentally, that rarely translated into large changes in income or long periods of high unemployment. To-day’s policymakers won’t (and shouldn’t) lock themselves into a similarly rigid system in an era in which the forces driving the global economy are changing rapidly. Replac-ing today’s messy and far from adequate sys-tem with a standard linked to gold (or some other commodity) is just not an option. m

Page 40: Milken Institute Review Q4

TBursti

ng the Bubble

38 The Milken Institute Review

The financial crisis of 2007-09 was,

of course, triggered by the punc-

ture of a great housing bubble

that had been inflated by mort-

gage lenders and their agents. And

while the full story of this debacle

(like every story involving trillions of

dollars in capital) is complicated, its

outline is pretty straightforward.

When home prices began to slip after

peaking in mid-2006, a trickle and then a

flood of borrowers defaulted on their mortgage payments. This generated losses for

lenders and, in turn, the owners of securities that had been backed by those mortgages.

A few very large investment banks and commercial banks figured prominently among

the ranks of those owners. And their thin capital proved inadequate to absorb the losses,

bringing the global financial system to the brink of a true collapse that was prevented

only by massive government intervention.

The Dodd-Frank Act of 2010, signed by President Obama in July, addresses some of

It’s time for real change in housing finance

Page 41: Milken Institute Review Q4

Bursting t

he Bubble

39Fourth Quarter 2010

jona

than

twin

gley

(all

)

the weaknesses made plain by the crisis – notably by requiring lenders to

keep more capital on hand and giving regulators some tools to con-

tain the systemic risk created by lenders’ behavior. But

the law offered only half-measures with regard to the way

housing is financed. In particular, it didn’t settle the fate

of Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac, the quasi-governmental

sources of mortgage finance that have been left holding

by lawrence j. white

Page 42: Milken Institute Review Q4

40 The Milken Institute Review

the lion’s share of losses from the housing col-lapse. Nor did the new law touch the direct and indirect subsidies for homebuyers that helped fuel the speculative boom and have long di-verted capital from more productive uses.

Washington may be loath to revisit hous-ing finance any time soon. But it still makes sense to think through what ought to be done before the next crisis. And even without a cri-sis to force the issue, housing-finance policy

will surely resurface in any serious debate over federal deficit reduction. After all,

federal mortgage subsidies

Page 43: Milken Institute Review Q4

41Fourth Quarter 2010

cost hundreds of billions of dollars annually, much of which is frittered away in building oversized dwellings that savings-strapped America can ill-afford.

gilding the lilyHousing-finance policy is a creature of inter-est-group politics, designed to feed huge con-struction and finance sectors as well as to please voters by making homeownership cheaper. Consider this embarrassment of riches:

The deductibility of mortgage interest and property taxes from taxable income… The ex-clusion of the ongoing “services” – the equiv-alent of rent – provided by owner-occupied

housing from taxable income… The exclu-sion of much or all of the capital gain from selling a personal residence… Reduced costs for mortgages that are routinely insured by the government and government-supported companies for less than the cost… Tax credits for first-time home purchases (which come and go)… Rent subsidies for low-income households… Subsidies for the construction of rental housing… Direct government provi-sion of low-income housing… Myriad indi-rect subsidies to mortgage lenders…

Last year, the nonpartisan Congressional Budget Office estimated that these measures

cost Uncle Sam a whopping $290 billion – some $2,800 per American household. That figure, of course, doesn’t count the cost of reg-ulation that is largely devoted to protecting housing interests from the pain of competi-tion – like many local building codes, states’ effort to protect both full-service real estate brokers and title insurers, and restrictions on imports of building materials, notably lumber.

Housing policy is driven by a variety of motives. On the high-minded end, there’s the encouragement of homeownership on the grounds that owners are better citizens than renters and, thanks to the accumulation of home equity, less likely to become burdens on

the state or on their families. Another virtu-ous goal: redistribution of income (in the form of housing) to needy families in a coun-try that is otherwise reluctant to redistribute income to the poor. But the rock on which the policy is built is the sustenance of a vast commercial ecosystem – the care and feeding of everyone from specialized craft workers to homebuilders to earth-moving-equipment manufacturers to appliance makers.

swamped by technology Before the 1980s, residential mortgages were largely originated, financed, serviced and held

Page 44: Milken Institute Review Q4

42 The Milken Institute Review

to maturity by local deposit-taking institu-tions – usually savings-and-loan associations and occasionally commercial banks or credit unions. This “vertical integration” of housing finance made economic sense in an era of high-cost data processing and telecommuni-cations. Local lenders were best positioned to judge the creditworthiness of borrowers and to provide funds for and service loans.

But the information technology revolu-tion made it practical (and often remarkably profitable) to look to broader markets for mortgage finance and to specialize in compo-nent services like mortgage origination and mortgage servicing. The crowning glory of this transformed market: securitization. In 1970, the federally owned Ginnie Mae (the Government National Mortgage Association) first created residential mortgage-backed se-curities – RMBS, for short. The federally chartered Freddie Mac (the Federal Home Loan Mortgage Corporation) was just a year behind, while the federally chartered Fannie Mae (the Federal National Mortgage Associa-tion) entered the great game in 1981. Securi-tization grew modestly in the 1980s, and then took off in the 1990s as the privatized Fannie and Freddie saw gold in the business. [For a more extensive discussion of Fannie and Freddie, see White’s article in the Second Quarter 2008 issue of the Review.]

With securitization, home loans could be originated by specialized mortgage bankers, which immediately sold the mortgages to packager-securitizers, who bundled loans into pools with predictable risk characteris-tics. The routine servicing of individual mort-gages – collecting checks, dunning late payers,

managing defaults – could be done by yet an-other specialized party. And since investors no longer needed local knowledge to assess these mortgage-backed securities, institutions ranging from insurance companies in San Francisco to banks in China could participate. Meanwhile, cheap, fast information technol-ogy minimized the cost of the dauntingly complex process of creating and evaluating both the risks and the likely pace of amortiza-tion of RMBS.

One more invention was needed, though, to push securitization into hyperdrive: securi-ties insurance. Conservative investors needed to be assured that they would receive their in-terest and principal repayments in a timely fashion. This guarantee was provided by Gin-nie Mae (which had the explicit backing of the federal government and which securitized mortgages that were themselves individually insured by the Federal Housing Authority and the Veterans Administration) and by Fannie and Freddie (which, despite being publicly traded companies, had special and very reassuring ties to the federal govern-ment). In turn, these securitizers (along with the Federal Housing Administration and Vet-erans Administration) inherited the task of policing the accuracy of the credit-quality claims made by the mortgage originators.

Starting in the late 1990s “private label” se-curitization by both commercial banks and by investment banks began a rapid ascent. These issuers faced the same problem of how to convince distant, passive investors that they would get their money back. The banks solved this problem with combinations of overcollateralization (backing the mortgages with more than 100 percent of their value in property), reserve funds, and – most impor-tant – by slicing the securities into “tranches” with distinct risk characteristics. This last technique arrayed the cash flows from the un-

Lawrence J. wh Ite is a professor of economics at nYU’s Stern School of Business and a former regulator of the savings-and-loan industry.

h o u s i n g f i n a n c e

Page 45: Milken Institute Review Q4

After a few years of housing

price increases, too many peo-

ple came to believe that hous-

ing prices could only increase.

And this, in effect, made

credit quality irrelevant.

43Fourth Quarter 2010

derlying mortgages in payment priority, so that the most senior tranches would be the last to incur losses from any defaults in the pool, while the most junior tranches would be the first to absorb any losses. (Intermedi-ate tranches would absorb losses only after tranches junior to them had been wiped out by earlier losses.)

With the government not in the picture, investors in the private-label RMBS made use of credit-rating agencies to help assess risk. Indeed, prudentially regulated institutional investors like banks, insurance companies, pension funds, broker-dealers and money-market mutual funds were largely restricted to tranches with “investment-grade” ratings.

Securitization generated large, very real benefits. It allowed borrowers to draw capital from a vast market, increasing competition and lowering mortgage costs. It permitted greater specialization of functions (and thus efficiency) in creating, financing and servic-ing mortgages. And it managed mortgage risk more effectively through a combination of di-versification and tranche creation.

On the other hand, the complicated, verti-cally deintegrated chain of services in securi-tization opened the door to cheating – econo-mists prefer the more neutral term “moral hazard” – in which the agents at one or more stages had incentives to fudge on the credit-worthiness of the mortgages and make some extra loot in the transaction. Moreover, with private-label securitizations, the question of whether a servicer should make concessions to a defaulting borrower – a common prac-tice in simpler loan transactions – wasn’t re-ally addressed until it was too late.

pathological optimism and see-no-evil regulationFinancial bubbles are nothing new. What made this last housing bubble different is that

the combination of government subsidies, se-curitization and regulation magnified its size and spread the consequences far wider. After a few years of housing-price increases, too many people came to believe that housing prices could only increase. And this, in effect, made credit quality irrelevant: lenders would always be protected against losses in default by the rising value of the collateral.

By the same token, if mortgage defaults would never be a problem, neither would de-faults on mortgage-backed securities. So, in this world of ever-rising house prices, the ver-tical partners in the securitization process did not need to be vigilant.

These middlemen might fudge credit qual-ity or suck in borrowers with back-loaded re-payment terms that would eventually become unaffordable. But with all that collateral being created by rising house prices, default was no-body’s problem.

Just why a few years of rising housing prices convinces otherwise rational people that prices will never go down is a puzzle more likely to be solved by psychologists than by economists. Of course, housing prices did peak in mid-2006 and then began to fall, stripping away home-equity collateral that was supposed to protect owners of private

Page 46: Milken Institute Review Q4

44 The Milken Institute Review

label RMBS. The consequences were exacer-bated by the fact that large investment banks and commercial banks, along with their hold-ing companies, owned great quantities of RMBS. Their thin (though not illegally thin) capital buffers were inadequate to absorb the losses, and the term “too big to fail” became part of the American vernacular.

Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac were not im-mune. Although they had previously main-tained high underwriting standards on the mortgages that they bought and securitized, their standards slipped toward the middle of the decade as their executives sought a bigger piece of the profit from the housing boom. By mid-2008, losses had wiped out their capital, and both became wards of the federal govern-ment in September 2008.

Excess leverage wasn’t just a problem for the lenders. In the go-go years of the housing boom, homeowners were encouraged to min-imize down payments and to refinance as soon as possible with the goal of pocketing the cash from the inevitable gain in value. Thus, while one of the reasons for encourag-ing homeownership was to give households a way to build wealth by amortizing mortgages, the system encouraged them to minimize the equity in their homes. Why wait to renovate the bathroom or to take a cruise? Just cash in the “free money” buried in your house!

Note, too, that, the system created incen-tives to buy (or rent) too much housing. In part, of course, that followed from the relax-ation of credit standards and the rise of back-loaded mortgage-payment plans that arose during the inflation of the bubble. But it was also the consequence of all those housing subsidies discussed above. Research in the 1980s concluded that long before the housing boom, people were buying or renting 30 per-cent more housing than would have been the

case absent the financial incentives. So what’s the big deal? It’s that the re-

sources spent on all that housing had to come from somewhere – in particular, from indus-trial capital, education and social infrastruc-ture. All told, the capital diverted to excessive housing could have increased GDP by an es-timated 10 percent.

These findings don’t necessarily contradict claims that we have spent too little on low- income housing, where distorting housing markets with subsidies-in-kind (like rent vouchers) has been seen as one of the few po-litically palatable ways to redistribute income to the poor. But a disproportionate share of the subsidies has gone to affluent households

– people who were likely to buy anyway and who were in a position to get the most mile-age from the tax-deductibility of mortgage interest and property taxes. That largely ex-plains why homeownership rose just five per-centage points (from 64 percent to 69 per-cent) between 1975 and the peak in 2005, while the square footage of new houses grew by about a whopping 50 percent across the same period. It also helps to explain why new dwellings in Germany, France, Belgium and Sweden – countries with living standards and homeownership rates close to those of the United States – are roughly half the size.

Ironies pile on ironies. While subsidies and preferences reduce the cost of housing, re-strictive zoning, excessively stringent build-ing codes, import restrictions on building materials, and state protection of title insur-ers and full-service fixed-fee real estate bro-kers have served to keep housing prices high

– especially along the East and West Coasts.Though fraud perpetrated on borrowers

was not the major cause of the debacle, there clearly were such instances – especially among low-income, elderly and less-educated house-holds. Further, anyone who has bought a

h o u s i n g f i n a n c e

Page 47: Milken Institute Review Q4

45Fourth Quarter 2010

house and gone through a closing knows what a nightmare that process can be: stacks of documents that the buyer has not a clue about to be signed, multiple checks to be written, impenetrable statements on costs and obligations to be deciphered.

fixing the messAs this is being written, in the late summer of 2010, housing and mortgage markets have not fully recovered from the trauma of the bubble. Housing prices have not yet stabi-lized; mortgage lenders and residential mort-gage-backed securities investors have not ad-opted a comfortable stance toward the trade-off between risk and return in housing. Consequently, radical moves – like changing the structure of Fannie and Freddie, or elimi-nating the mortgage interest deduction – are not only politically unrealistic, but would also be unwise in the short run.

Nevertheless, it’s time – long past time – to think hard about the rationale for govern-ment intervention in housing markets:

homeownership is not for everyone. A house is a large, illiquid asset that often serves as an impediment to job mobility. Home-ownership is not an automatic route to build-ing wealth. Indeed, it can be a heavy burden for people with highly variable incomes and expenses.

Modest encouragement of homeownership is probably justifiable in economic and social terms. But subsidies should be modest and – equally important – limited to cash incentives for first-time homebuyers with modest in-comes. And government aid should be ac-companied by counseling with respect to the responsibilities and burdens of homeowner-ship. Subsidies of any sort to higher-income households serve no social purpose and divert resources from more-productive investments.

Using cheap loans to increase homeowner-

ship is bad policy. Borrowing means leverage; subsidized borrowing means excessive lever-age. Leveraging is the antithesis of building equity and makes defaults more likely in the event of house-price declines.

By contrast, lowering the cost of housing by making the inputs cheaper may make sense. That can be done by making land cheaper (by reducing or eliminating unwarranted zoning), by making materials cheaper (by allowing competition from imports), by making con-struction cheaper (by not using restrictive building codes as a way to protect favored contractors and workers) and by making sales transactions cheaper (by not protecting full-service real estate brokers, title insurers and other providers of closing services).

Using government supported agencies like Fannie and Freddie to mediate housing mar-kets is a mistake. They haven’t made much difference in homeownership rates. But they have distorted mortgage markets, indirectly subsidizing credit and leaving taxpayers hold-ing the bag.

Direct government intervention, with the Fha and Va insuring mortgages, and Ginnie Mae packaging them as securities, constitutes a problematic subsidy, even though it has not generated comparable financial losses. His-torically, this route was restricted to lower-priced homes (the maximum FHA/VA in-sured loan was in the vicinity of 65 percent of the maximum Fannie/Freddie loan), so mod-erate-income buyers were the primary benefi-ciaries. But when the FHA/VA mortgage limit was raised above $700,000 in 2008, the ratio-nale for such insurance evaporated.

Deductions (as opposed to credits) are an in-herently inferior means of providing subsidies, because the benefits are higher for higher- income taxpayers and only go to those who itemize deductions on their tax returns.

Page 48: Milken Institute Review Q4

46 The Milken Institute Review

Subsidies for housing do create jobs, but so does pretty much any other form of govern-ment spending. It’s especially hard to justify permanent housing-subsidy programs when the nation faces large and growing budget deficits.

In light of all this, here’s how I would re-form housing policy:

1. Phase out tax preferences. The deduct-ibility of mortgage interest and local property taxes and the exclusion of capital gains on home sales will reduce government revenue by about $160 billion next year. In five years, the cost will be pushing $235 billion annually. It would be unfair (and politically impossible) to eliminate the deduction for existing home mortgages. But a 10-year phaseout, in which the interest deduction on new mortgages would become progressively less valuable, might be palatable. Better yet would be a re-form that transformed these deductions into refundable tax credits, so the benefits would not go disproportionately to the affluent.

2. truly privatize Fannie and Freddie. Once mortgage markets stabilize, securitization can and should become a matter for private mar-kets – and securities regulators who compel transparency. If the brand names, systems and personnel of Fannie and Freddie still have value, they should be able to survive as wholly private entities; if not, then the market will pull the plug. In any event, alas, the accu-mulated losses of the two companies ($145 billion, and counting) must simply be ab-sorbed by the federal government. Even if true privatization proves to be a political nonstarter, the scope of their mission could be scaled back. One straightforward way: gradually (say, over 10 years) reduce the size of the maximum mortgage that they can pur-chase and securitize, perhaps to $200,000 or maybe to the median house price.

3. Private mortgage insurers could pick up the slack. Although private insurers were damaged by the debacle, they appear to be healing, and others will likely arise. The need for Ginnie Mae would also disappear.

4. Focus remaining subsidies. My preference here would be to strip down the subsidies to a flat $10,000 check for moderate-income first-time homebuyers. The goal should be to en-courage purchases by households that can af-ford and benefit from homeownership, but are short on the down payment.

5. encourage competition. The elimination of protection against lumber imports from Canada would make a material difference in construction costs. The larger and more per-vasive restraints on competition – everything from interest-group-driven building codes to laws protecting incumbent brokers and title insurers – are creatures of state and local gov-ernments. This makes them tough nuts to crack. But one could imagine a combination of mandates and financial incentives from Washington that would induce reforms.

6. Keep the door open to innovative finance. The goal, as with securitization, is to reduce the cost of capital. Take the case of “covered bonds,” which are bank-issued debt instru-ments that use pools of mortgages as collat-eral and are widely used in Europe. The bond investor’s first claim is on the issuing bank. But if the bank becomes insolvent, the inves-tor has a direct claim on the collateral. This collateralized form of borrowing is already used in the United States, in the form of banks’ very-short-term repurchase arrange-ments (“repos”) with securities dealers and banks’ short- and medium-term advances from the Federal Home Loan Bank System. But it has never been tried for long-term bank debt. The Federal Deposit Insurance Corpo-ration has discouraged such secured borrow-ing, because it gives lenders priority over it

h o u s i n g f i n a n c e

Page 49: Milken Institute Review Q4

47Fourth Quarter 2010

when banks fail. There is, however, a way to reconcile the FDIC’s legitimate interests with those of the issuers: let the secured lender (or the borrowing bank) pay a fee to the FDIC to compensate it for the loss of seniority.

7. revive prepayment fees. The option to prepay a fixed-rate mortgage – especially the option to refinance when interest rates de-crease from the levels at which the mortgage was originally extended – is valuable to bor-rowers and costly to lenders. If lenders are not permitted to charge explicitly for the exercise of the option, they can (and surely do) add the expected option cost into the interest rates that they charge on mortgages generally. As a result, borrowers who do not refinance pay part of the costs of those who do. Better, then, to have an explicit fee for the exercise of the option. Note, moreover, that explicit pricing of the prepayment option would make invest-ments in residential mortgage-backed securi-ties more attractive to life insurance compa-nies and pension funds, which need long-term assets to offset their long-term liabilities.

8. Make originators more responsible for mortgage decisions. Most buyers are clearly at a disadvantage in obtaining a mortgage. The transaction is infrequent and unfamiliar; the sums are large; the options can be many. Stockbrokers have an obligation not to bam-boozle their customers by selling them invest-ments that are inappropriate for them – say, by selling pork-belly options to retirees with modest incomes. Mortgage originators should have a parallel obligation to steer bor-rowers away from, say, back-loaded payment structures that they won’t be able to afford.

9. Make closings consumer-friendly. Be-cause there are likely to be multiple – and un-

familiar – services provided at a closing, with multiple fees, homebuyers are in a poor posi-tion to shop around. Far better to encourage one-stop shopping through “aggregators,” who would work like general contractors, competitively bidding to provide all closing services. Aggregators, in turn, would have in-centives to pressure subcontractors to deliver specialized closing services at competitive prices. By the same token, buyers deserve something better than an incomprehensible heap of paper outlining the mortgage terms. It is quite possible to devise a one-page state-ment in reasonably sized print that lays out the basics of the mortgage and the closing costs. Indeed, this should be “job one” for the new Bureau of Consumer Financial Protec-tion that has been established by the Dodd-Frank Act.

* * *Housing finance can’t be reformed over-

night. But the experience of the last few years (in which housing played a key role in trigger-ing a terrible global recession), and the likely experience of the next few (in which the need for deficit reduction will be hard to ignore), could serve as the opening. Eight decades of housing preferences heaped on preferences must be gradually stripped away, with sub-stantial savings for the federal budget. Regu-lators must focus on creating a competitive private mortgage market – one in which lenders are less likely to destabilize the whole financial system and consumers are protected from abuse.

In that world, Americans would likely buy less housing. But grass would not grow in the streets of America as a consequence. Indeed, successful reform could free hundreds of bil-lions of dollars of capital annually for more productive uses – which might even include more parks in which to grow grass. m

Page 50: Milken Institute Review Q4

48 The Milken Institute Review

Overcoming Myopia

Page 51: Milken Institute Review Q4

T49Fourth Quarter 2010

The 2010 oil spill on the Gulf Coast is just the lat-

est disaster that highlights a general problem: Deci-

sion makers often regard catastrophic events as

below their threshold of concern until they occur.

This seems to be true for all decision makers – busi-

ness professionals, homeowners and public officials

in charge of minimizing disaster damage. Read the

questions below, and ask yourself if you would really,

truly answer them differently:

Q: Could my company be responsible for a mis-

hap that would have major enduring social, eco-

nomic and environmental impact?

A: It’s not going to happen to us!

Q: Would I have the financial resources to rebuild

my house after a hurricane?

A: The government would bail me out.

Q: Could a cyberattack paralyze our infrastruc-

ture for several days?

A: Science fiction!

by howard c. kunreuther and erwann o. michel-kerjan

Learning From the BP Oil Spill and Other Catastrophes

Page 52: Milken Institute Review Q4

50 The Milken Institute Review

prev

ious

and

this

pag

e: as

soci

ated

pre

ss

Howard Ku n reutH er is Cecilia Yen Koo professor of decision sciences and public policy at the wharton School of the university of Pennsylvania and co-director of the wharton risk Management and decision Processes Center. erwan n MiCH el-Kerjan teaches at wharton and is managing director of the wharton risk Center. they are co-authors of At War With the Weather: Managing Large-Scale Risks in a New Era of Catastrophes (Mit Press).

Accordingly, oil companies underinvest in measures to decrease the likelihood of a major spill as well as in ways to limit the dam-age if one does occur. Many property owners decide to buy flood insurance only after their houses are under water – and then cancel them a few years later if they haven’t experi-enced further damage. Public officials won’t burn political capital by imposing costly, but economically justifiable, regulations on bank exposure to financial risk in advance of a cri-sis because they don’t see how it would help them get re-elected.

Yet as the economy becomes larger, more complex and arguably more vulnerable to a wide variety of catastrophes, the potential con-

sequences of such myopic behavior grow. Not addressing them will simply make the impact of future events more devastating.

a new era of catastrophesLarge-scale disasters are low-probability events – but the probability is not as low as it once was. Indeed, such disasters have come with startling frequency in the last decade:

Terrorist attacks in New York and Wash-ington (September 2001) killed thousands and forced wrenching changes in security ef-forts around the world… The Northeast blackout (August 2003) demonstrated how human error and short-term competitive pressure could deprive more than 50 million people of electricity in the United States and Canada... The great Indian Ocean tsunami (December 2004) killed some 300,000 peo-ple… Hurricane Katrina (August 2005) dev-astated New Orleans and overwhelmed emer-gency services capacities… An earthquake in Sichuan province in China (May 2008) killed

WorldWide evolution of Catastrophe insured losses, 1970–2009

$100

80

60

40

20

0

Bill

ion

s o

f do

llar

s, 200

9 pr

iCes

1970 1980 1990 2000 2009Year

source: Kunreuther and Michel-Kerjan, At War With the Weather (MIT Press, 2009)

9/11/2001 loss (liaBilitY and life)

9/11/2001 loss (propertY and Bi)

natural Catastrophes

man-made Catastrophes

Page 53: Milken Institute Review Q4

51Fourth Quarter 2010

asso

ciat

ed p

ress

nearly 70,000, just a few weeks after a major cyclone killed more than 100,000 in Myan-mar... A massive earthquake in Haiti (January 2010) killed 230,000, and a few weeks later another one in Chile caused multi-billion dollar property damage... The collapse of the mortgage bubble (mid-2008) triggered the longest and deepest global economic down-turn since the Great Depression… And, of course, the recent BP oil spill (April 2010) cost the U.S. economy billions and damaged the ecology of the Gulf of Mexico in ways not yet fully known.

The severity of these events suggests that the world is changing and that we have en-tered a new era of catastrophes. Of the 25 most costly insured catastrophes in the world since 1970, 17 occurred since 2001. From 1970 to the mid-1980s, annual insured losses from natural disasters (including forest fires) were in the $3 billion to $4 billion range. In fact, be-fore Hurricane Hugo in 1989, the insurance industry had never suffered a single loss over

$1 billion. But these losses radically increased in the 1990s and that trend has continued.

The principal reason is that more people are residing in hazard-prone areas and, as a result, more property is at risk. Take Florida. The population was 2.8 million in 1950; today, it is close to 19 million. So a Category 3 hur-ricane that would have had limited economic impact 60 years ago is likely to do multibil-lion dollar damage today. By one estimate, the damage from Hurricane Andrew, which occurred in 1992, would be more than twice as great if it occurred in 2010. Today, there are nearly $10 trillion of insured assets on the coast running from Texas to Maine (private and public insurance), all of it at risk from major hurricanes.

behavioral biasWhat explains our unwillingness to look ahead and act? Findings from lab experiments and field studies by psychologists and behav-ioral economists reveal a variety of biases that

Bt CottonConventional Cotton

Page 54: Milken Institute Review Q4

52 The Milken Institute Review

cause decision makers to ignore both the like-lihood and the potential consequences of large-scale disasters.

Misperceptions of the risk. We often under-estimate the likelihood and consequences of extreme events, either by failing to imagine the scenarios in which they might occur or by sim-ply assuming that “it will not happen to me.”

ambiguity of experts. Estimates of the likelihood and consequences of low probabil-ity events often differ, given the limited his-torical data and considerable scientific uncer-tainty. Decision makers often choose to use the estimates from experts that provide justi-fications for their preferred actions.

Short horizons for valuing protective mea-sures. Businesses (and households) look only a few years ahead (if not just months) in de-ciding whether to spend money on loss- reducing measures like strengthening struc-tures to reduce hurricane damage. As a result, risk-reducing measures that could be justified financially when comparing costs and expected returns over the long run are often rejected.

disregarding interdependencies. The value of some investments for disaster protection depends on the willingness of others to un-dertake parallel actions. For example, bank regulation or anti-terrorism measures are far less effective if other nations aren’t on board. Thus, individual countries or companies are reluctant to be first movers, lest they waste political and financial capital.

Failure to learn from past disasters. There is a tendency to discount past unpleasant ex-periences. Emotions are high when we expe-rience a catastrophic event, or even view it on television or the Internet. But those emotions fade, making it difficult to recapture these concerns about the event as time passes.

Mimetic blindness. Decision makers often imitate the behavior of others without ana-

lyzing whether the action is appropriate for them. By doing what other firms do in their industry (or imitating the behavior of friends and neighbors), decision makers can avoid the psychological stress of thinking indepen-dently. There is also a tendency to favor the status quo – to not change current practice.

In addition to behavioral biases, there are economically rational reasons that firms and individuals in hazard-prone areas don’t un-dertake risk-avoidance measures. Consider MonkeySee, a hypothetical firm in an indus-try in which its competitors do not invest in

o v e r c o m i n g m y o p i a

Page 55: Milken Institute Review Q4

53Fourth Quarter 2010

©di

nodi

a/ag

e fo

tost

ock

loss prevention. MonkeySee might under-stand that investment can be justified when considering how it reduces the risks and con-sequences of a future disaster. However, in the near term, the firm may be at a competi-tive disadvantage because it must bear the higher costs of risk avoidance.

Or consider the equally hypothetical Safelee family, which is deciding whether to invest in disaster prevention – say, in a non-flammable roof for the house. If they plan to move in a few years and doubt that potential buyers would appropriately value such a roof,

they may find that the short-term benefits are less than the cost of the improvement.

theory made real Many recent catastrophes can be tied in part to behavioral biases.

the BP oil Spill

BP’s behavior in recent years is puzzling. On the one hand, the giant oil company has in-vested heavily in green technologies, a seem-ingly long-term view of the company’s future prospects. BP Solar has become one of the

Page 56: Milken Institute Review Q4

54 The Milken Institute Review

world’s largest developers and manufacturers of solar power equipment. And since 2005, the company has invested in wind power as well.

On the other hand, BP’s behavior in its core business suggests that the company is myopic with respect to risk, and adapts poorly to past mistakes. A 2005 explosion at BP’s Texas City plant killed 15 people and injured more than 170 others in one of America’s worst industrial accidents in a generation. The government subsequently identified

more than 300 safety violations, and BP agreed to pay $21 million in fines.

There have been other BP accidents since the Texas City explosion. A BP oil platform in the deepwater Gulf of Mexico almost sank in Hurricane Dennis in 2005, and the company was responsible for a significant oil spill in Alaska in 2006.

BP exhibits several of the decision biases we discussed above, including maintaining the status quo and mimetic blindness. Appar-

Page 57: Milken Institute Review Q4

55Fourth Quarter 2010

asso

ciat

ed p

ress

ently no one else in the industry had an ade-quate plan for a deepwater failure. It is likely that BP could not imagine the scale of the di-saster that occurred last April in the Gulf Coast or the impact it could have on so many others – and in the end, on its own reputation.

Challenger and Columbia Shuttle accidents

The destruction of the space shuttle Chal-lenger shortly after takeoff on Jan. 28, 1986,

was caused by a failure of a simple engine part – the now-infamous O-rings. Diane Vaughan of Boston University concluded that this trag-edy was due to an organizational culture in which production costs took priority over safety. NASA had flown previous shuttles de-spite recurring O-ring damage. And agency officials were intent on flying the shuttle to maintain financing for the space program and viewed the likelihood of such a disaster as below their threshold of concern.

Strikingly, NASA behaved similarly with the Columbia shuttle in February 2003. De-spite warning signs and reports that foam de-bris could cause deadly damage to the aging Columbia, the agency decided to launch – a decision apparently driven by NASA’s focus on making sure that shuttles were launched on time after a history of repeated delays. Eighty-two seconds into the flight, foam de-bris damaged the shuttle’s thermal protection system, causing the craft to break up upon re-entry. Flight operations were delayed for two years after the catastrophe.

terrorism insurance Markets Before and after 9/11

Even risk analysis experts demonstrate behav-ioral biases. Before 9/11, insurers operating in the United States viewed potential losses from terrorism as so improbable that the risk was neither explicitly mentioned nor priced in any standard policy. Moreover, terrorism was not excluded from so-called “all risk” insur-ance with the exception of some marine cargo, aviation and political risk policies. The first World Trade Center attack in 1993 (which cost insurers more than $700 million) and the Oklahoma City bombing in 1995 were thus not seen as foreboding enough for insurers to revise their view of the terrorist risk. The actuarial models that insurers used to set premiums included no explicit estimate

Page 58: Milken Institute Review Q4

56 The Milken Institute Review

of the expected cost of terrorism. Most tell-ingly, there was no change in the way risk was evaluated in the wake of these incidents.

Insurers and reinsurers paid $35 billion for the 9/11 attacks – at that time the most costly event in the history of insurance. After that, most of them swung to the other extreme, re-fusing to offer coverage against terrorism at any price, even though the likelihood of an-other successful attack on U.S. soil was pre-sumably lower, given the renewed security ef-forts by governments and private companies.

non-enforcement of Building Codes

Our Wharton colleague Robert Meyer has studied the devastation of Pass Christian, Miss., by Hurricane Katrina in 2005. The storm wiped out all structures on the coast. But apparently no lessons were learned: an apartment complex was rebuilt in 2007 – on the same vulnerable site.

Ironically, this was not the first time that apartments had been rebuilt in this area after a disaster. Hurricane Camille destroyed the coastal buildings in Pass Christian in 1969. Although building codes had been in place since 1957, they were not enforced. And they were not enforced again after Camille. Indeed, the obligation to obtain a building permit was initially waived. As a result, homes and businesses built after Camille were wiped out by Katrina.

Failure of individuals to Purchase Flood insurance

Since 1968, flood insurance has been pro-vided at relatively inexpensive rates in haz-ard-prone areas by the federal government through the National Flood Insurance Pro-gram (NFIP). Still, many people who live in flood-prone areas don’t buy coverage. Many behavioral biases apply here: residents misper-

ceive the degree of risk, or simply don’t be-lieve a flood could happen to them. Others have short-term horizons. Accordingly, if they have not collected on their insurance policies after a few years, they cancel them.

Based on an analysis of the 10-year data set of the entire portfolio of the NFIP, we found that, on average, people let their flood insur-ance policies lapse after just three or four years. Interestingly, this average tenure hasn’t changed since Hurricane Katrina, when flood insurance claims exceeded $16 billion – a re-cord for this program, which covers more than five million households. While many more people bought flood insurance imme-diately after the disaster, attention faded a year or two later.

The evidence of such imprudent behavior is illuminating. For instance, The New York Times reported that six out of 10 residents in Orleans Parish had no flood insurance when Katrina hit. Or consider the flood in August 1998 that damaged property in northern Ver-mont. FEMA found that 45 percent of those who resided in designated flood hazard areas had evaded their obligation to maintain in-surance coverage.

what to do As these examples show, we excessively dis-count future returns by focusing on short-term rewards. That is, we don’t invest in costly mitigation measures because the upfront ex-penses exceed the short-run benefits. Those concerned with managing extreme events thus need to recognize the importance of providing incentives to offset this myopia.

To that end, regulations designed to re-duce the likelihood of catastrophic events and to ensure preparedness for recovery need to be tightly enforced. It is important that fi-nancial incentives be structured so decision makers’ interests mesh with those of society.

o v e r c o m i n g m y o p i a

Page 59: Milken Institute Review Q4

57Fourth Quarter 2010

For example, executive pay needs to be linked to the long-term performance of a firm, rather than being based on what happened during the past 12 months. It would also make sense to figure out ways to create more immediate rewards for investments in disas-ter prevention – say, by reducing insurance premiums for homeowners who meet mini-mum standards. By extending the time hori-zon and creating appropriate economic in-centive systems, we may be able to nudge individuals into taking steps to reduce their own risk exposure while reducing the costs to society in the process.

As a concrete example, consider the case of flood risk. One idea we have proposed would be to move from the traditional one-year flood insurance contract and adopt multi-year contracts attached to the property, not to the owner. This would give houses in flood-prone areas a fixed, inflation-corrected an-nual premium for a designated period (for example, 5 or 10 years).

In addition, if long-term loans for flood mitigation were offered by banks, households with multiyear flood insurance policies would be encouraged to invest in loss reduction measures. If the measures were cost-effective, the discounts in annual insurance premiums would be greater than the annual cost of the loans. So homeowners would see an immedi-ate advantage in investing in such loss- reduction measures. Should the owner sell the property before the end of the policy pe-riod, both the insurance and the loan would automatically be transferred to the new owner.

Under such a program, millions of house-

holds that are uninsured today would be fi-nancially protected, banks would have more secure assets, and the general taxpayer would assume a lower cost of disaster relief after fu-ture floods and water-related damage from hurricanes. A win-win-win for all!

* * *Human nature is… human nature. We

cannot expect policymakers, investors, busi-ness executives, homeowners and others in positions to influence disaster mitigation to act rationally without a financial nudge and/or clearly enforced obligations. Nor is it enough to wring our hands and talk loudly after each fresh outrage. We need to give people tangible incentives to do the right things.

Happily, these seem to be ideas whose time has come. Two examples from our own expe-rience: The World Economic Forum has begun an initiative on global risks in partner-ship with the Wharton Risk Center and pri-vate industry. The project evaluates expert views on the severity and interdependencies of 20 risks over the next 10 years and suggests strategies to manage them using private-public partnerships. Similarly, the Organiza-tion for Economic Cooperation and Develop-ment established an International Network on the Financial Management of Catastrophes in 2006 (again, in partnership with the Wharton Risk Center). The goal is to develop strategies for financing recovery after major man-made and natural disasters that will also encourage investments in risk-reducing measures.

Fortune, reminded Sophocles, cannot aid those who do nothing. m

Many people who live in flood-prone areas don’t buy

coverage. Residents misperceive the degree of risk,

or simply don’t believe a flood could happen to them.

Page 60: Milken Institute Review Q4

58 The Milken Institute Review

Water Woes Using Markets

to Quench the Thirst of the

American Westby gary d. libecap

Page 61: Milken Institute Review Q4

I59Fourth Quarter 2010

oppo

site

pag

e: ©

robe

rt d

ayto

n/ag

e fo

tost

ock;

this

pag

e: as

soci

ated

pre

ss

Those halcyon days are over. Rapid popula-

tion growth and expanded economic activity

have pushed existing capacity to the limit. Mean-

while, the region’s notorious drought cycles,

which many believe will be exacerbated by cli-

mate change, have made supply more problem-

atic. Now add to that picture two other concerns

– evidence that more water is needed to protect

the environment and a scarcity of capital for expanded storage and transport

capacity – and it has become clear to almost all the stakeholders that mud-

dling through has become a very high-risk option.

In an economic culture that generally bows to the goddess of property

rights, one might have expected that excess claims on existing water would

have forced a clarification of rights to that water, followed by the use of mar-

ket pricing both to encourage conservation and to reallocate water to those

who value it most. Indeed, just this sort of institutional evolution took place

in the West with hard-rock minerals, oil and gas, timber and land. And

there is every reason to believe that markets would narrow price differences

between uses and among localities, freeing water for higher-value uses. Yet

that process is only beginning, and it is by no means certain that the market

It goes without saying that modern civilization turns on the

availability of clean, fresh water at reasonable cost. So it is

not surprising that in the semi-arid American West, complex

institutions evolved to determine who got access. And while

these rights were often vaguely defined, until the 1990s

there was enough water available through government

infrastructure that had been bought and paid for decades

earlier to satisfy burgeoning demand.

Page 62: Milken Institute Review Q4

60 The Milken Institute Review

GAry Li becAp teaches in the economics depart-ment at the bren School of environmental Science and Management at the University of california (Santa barbara) and is on the property rights Task Force at the Hoover institution.

will come to the rescue. Here, I explore why water is such a tough case and what might be done to speed the process.

the water-rights maze For a whole host of reasons – everything from the fact that it is both a private and public good, to the reality that it can be consumed by multiple parties simultaneously – water fits uneasily in textbook models of market al-location. Indeed, the interconnected, overlap-ping nature of water demands and uses ex-plains in part why various stakeholders have resisted letting markets work their magic. I ask your forbearance in sitting still for a brief (as possible) enumeration of the arcana that stand between business-as-usual and rational allocation that would effectively solve the re-gion’s water problems for decades to come.

Appropriative Surface-Water rights

In Western states, rights to flowing water (i.e., surface water) are largely based on the prior-appropriation doctrine, which allows rights-holders to withdraw specific amounts from a natural water course to use where they choose to – in some cases, places far from the source. The prior-appropriation doctrine emerged in the 19th century in response to the opening of rich opportunities in mining and agricul-ture far from rivers and streams, and the need to support the people arriving to exploit those opportunities. The appropriative sys-tem opened the door to using infrastructure

– everything from ditches to massive dams to aqueducts – to create great wealth.

By law, earlier claimants to appropriative

rights have priority over later ones. Rights are retained in perpetuity unless claimants fail to put the water to “beneficial” use. And in what amounts to a use-it-or-lose-it mandate, rights revert to the state and can be claimed by oth-ers after a specified period of nonuse. Appro-priative rights can be traded and, during droughts, senior rightsholders can (and often do) lease water to junior parties. Because lower-priority claims carry greater risk that water won’t be available when it is needed most, they are, of course, of less value.

Appropriative rights are measured in terms of quantities diverted from the source. And in many Western watersheds, water has been overallocated because diversions have not been carefully measured and because rights were granted in times of unusually large stream flows. Overallocation can be addressed through mediation or court action. But, not surprisingly, the process can be contentious.

Typically, much of the water used by a se-nior rightsholder seeps back to the stream or percolates down to an aquifer, creating access for junior rightsholders. Thus, market trans-fers that change the point of diversion, the timing of diversion or the way the water is used – and thereby threaten access for other rightsholders – are regulated to minimize the effects on third parties.

riparian Surface-Water rights

In the Eastern states, by contrast, water rights are attached to the land through which the water naturally runs, and cannot be separated from it. “Riparian” landowners have rights to this water for reasonable use, including fish-ing and navigation, and can utilize it as long as doing so does not harm riparian claimants downstream. In cases of drought, all parties share in the reduced flow.

Only a handful of the wettest states in the West recognize riparian rights. But when

w a t e r w o e s

Page 63: Milken Institute Review Q4

61Fourth Quarter 2010

©co

rbis

prior-appropriation and riparian systems do function in the same place, there can be ques-tions of the priority of claims if diversion under the appropriative system reduces ac-cess for riparian owners.

Groundwater Rights

Groundwater rights vary across the West and are generally not as well defined as surface rights are. They are also assigned via prior ap-propriation, granting landowners access to

“reasonable use.” With multiple landowners sitting on top of the same pool, many ground-water basins are subject to competitive with-drawal and classic tragedy-of-the-commons conditions in which users bear only a fraction of the full cost of their pumping decisions in

terms of land subsidence, saltwater intrusion, quality degradation and higher lifting costs – and thereby have inadequate incentive to conserve.

Some states (notably Arizona) that depend heavily on groundwater have enacted legisla-tion to define groundwater rights more clearly and to manage its sources better. Oth-ers, notably California, are far behind. Indeed, even though about 30 percent of California’s water comes from wells, of the 431 ground-water basins in the state, only 22 have had their water rights clearly defined.

Rights definition is a costly process, and it should be no surprise that most of the places where the legal and technical issues have been thrashed out are in the arid southern part of

Page 64: Milken Institute Review Q4

62 The Milken Institute Review

the state. But as groundwater becomes more important throughout the West, it is likely that linkages between surface and ground-water will be defined more precisely.

beneficial Use, Diversion requirements, preferential Uses

Appropriative rights are legally conditioned on placing the water into beneficial use with-out undue waste. Most Western states define beneficial uses fairly clearly as agriculture, in-dustry, municipal supply, power generation and navigation. But the definition is flexible. For example, leaving water in streams for habitat preservation has recently been ac-cepted as a beneficial use – though the rules vary from state to state. Typically, one can see a symbiosis at work here: private owners shift water rights into instream rights that are non-appropriative in order to protect their own rights from loss due to nonuse.

Historically, the requirement to use or lose water motivated farmers to irrigate low-value water-intensive crops, like alfalfa for cattle

feed. Indeed, the failure to dump water on growing plants of one sort or another could be interpreted as evidence of a lack of benefi-cial use, opening it to claims by others.

No injury rules

If a senior rightsholder sells water or in-creases consumption, the amount available for subsequent users may drop. The prospect of such third-party impairments has led Western states to create procedures that must be followed before water use can be altered or rights transferred. Although these proce-dures vary, they typically allow changes in use or transfers only if there is no harm to other rightsholders – i.e., those states effec-tively created a no-injury rule.

Before water can be sold or leased, the owner must get permission from the relevant state agency, with the burden of proof of no injury usually resting on the applicant. Ob-jections from users down the line may be re-solved by adjustments in the amount of water, timing or allowable uses in the exchange – or

Page 65: Milken Institute Review Q4

63Fourth Quarter 2010

©ed

dar

ack/

scie

nce

fact

ion/

corb

is

with cash. But the resolution of other third-party complaints may not be so straightfor-ward. If, for example, substantial amounts of land are taken out of agriculture when water is diverted, all the stakeholders in local farm economies may be affected. And here, figur-ing out who owes what to whom is no easy matter. Moreover, the uncertainty created by such claims undermines the potential for using markets to allocate water to its highest-valued use.

One way to finesse these claims is to shift the burden of proof of harm to those who protest water transfers. But that does not ad-dress fairness concerns in rural communities where equity issues loom large in local politics. Nor does it offer a way to win over other stake-holders – everybody from farm-equipment dealers to tax collectors – whose interests are indirectly linked to agricultural output. Luck-ily, though, only modest amounts of water (the proverbial low-hanging fruit) need be traded to generate major gains in efficiency.

Regulation overseeing trading varies. Cali-

fornia has an especially tortuous system, with the state’s Water Resources Control Board and Department of Water Resources, as well as the Federal Bureau of Reclamation, getting in on the act. The control board has legal au-thority to veto transfers that would “unrea-sonably affect the overall economy of the area from which the water is being transferred.”

Further, 22 of California’s 58 counties have asserted rights to restrict the extraction and export of groundwater. These county ordi-nances also can limit surface-water transac-tions if they appear to diminish groundwater resources. Indeed, there is little doubt that the whole point of the ordinances is to preserve the status quo, to prevent reallocation to urban or environmental uses.

Ironically, California (unlike many other states) already has an elaborate physical infra-structure in place for transferring water from wetter places (in the north) to drier, more populous areas. However, the north-south flow goes through the Sacramento-San Joa-quin Delta, home to the endangered delta

Page 66: Milken Institute Review Q4

64 The Milken Institute Review

peac

e po

rtal

pho

to/a

lam

y

smelt and other species protected by federal law. And the courts have not looked kindly on trades through the delta.

Public Resource, Public Interest, Public Trust

Some people argue that water is too important to be left to markets – that it should be owned and allocated by public agencies. But the re-cord of government involvement is problem-atic at best. In the case of ocean fisheries, for example, public ownership and management has generally led to overuse, while privatiza-tion through the creation of tradable catch permits has resulted in both lower fishing costs and significant rebounds of stocks.

A less extreme means of second-guessing private allocation is to require that water be used in the “public interest.” But that notion is vague. And the broader the interpretation, the more difficult it is to use market incen-tives to encourage conservation or to channel the resource to higher-valued uses.

It is true that some societal values are not reflected in market prices freely determined by private contract. But these values can be incorporated by allowing markets to price water and then acquiring the water needed for public purposes with government funds or charitable contributions. This approach has been used in purchases and leases of water for instream flows by organizations that

Page 67: Milken Institute Review Q4

65Fourth Quarter 2010

include the Oregon Water Trust, the Montana Water Trust and Trout Unlimited. Such trans-actions make the real value of water more transparent, creating incentives for more effi-cient use.

Consider, too, the related doctrine of “pub-lic trust,” which is a common law principle giving the public a claim on certain lands and waters, like tidewaters, navigable rivers and other natural resources with high amenity or public-goods values. It was applied in a far-reaching ruling by the California Supreme Court in 1983 involving Los Angeles’ claims to the water in streams leading to Mono Lake. And it may be applied retroactively to roll back existing appropriative rights that are deemed inconsistent with the public trust.

There need be no compensation under the public-trust doctrine. Accordingly, compro-mise is difficult. In the Mono Lake case, the litigants battled for 20 years before Los Ange-les was forced to relinquish its rights to bring water down the Los Angeles Aqueduct. A ne-gotiated purchase of the rights, perhaps under the threat of condemnation, would likely have been timelier and much less costly.

the decision makersAs noted above, numerous third parties can play key decision-making roles, adding per-plexing complexity to this stew of interest groups.

State Regulators and Water-Supply Organizations

Some 1,100 water-supply organizations, ranging from irrigation districts to municipal water districts to private water companies, may have leverage over trading decisions, and their incentives to facilitate market transfers vary widely. For example, the governing boards of irrigation districts may effectively be controlled by farmers who could make a

lot of money selling water, or the boards may be elected by the whole community, which has nothing to gain and much to lose from sales that take land out of farming.

The experiences of the Palo Verde and Im-perial Irrigation Districts in California illus-trate the differences. The Palo Verde district’s board is elected by property owners. It reached agreement quickly and smoothly in 2004 to let between 7 and 29 percent of its members’ land lie fallow on a rotating basis in return for cash from the Metropolitan Water District, the huge agency that delivers most of the water to Southern California.

By contrast, the board of the Imperial Irri-gation District, which has a claim to about two-thirds of all the Colorado River water di-verted to California, is elected by all registered voters. Beginning in the 1990s, there were ef-forts to transfer some of that water to San Diego and other cities. A tentative agreement was reached in 2002, but it collapsed when local officials protested the likely losses in jobs and taxes. The deal was only resurrected after the U.S. Department of the Interior (which administers Colorado River water) in-tervened – and only after more money was included for community compensation.

The Bureau of Reclamation

The Federal Bureau of Reclamation is the largest wholesaler of water in the country, capturing water in some 600 dams and reser-voirs, and selling it to 140,000 farms covering millions of acres in 17 states – often at far below market value. And its policies with re-gard to transfer, official and unofficial, have varied greatly with time and place. One con-sequence: it reduces farmers’ incentives to re-sell water because they fear they may lose ac-cess to federal largesse.

This maze of institutional barriers sug-gests that selling water is hardly like selling

Page 68: Milken Institute Review Q4

66 The Milken Institute Review

other real property. And the resulting ineffi-ciency is reflected in the low level of transac-tions and seemingly permanent price differ-entials between localities and among uses.

Water price Differentials, 1987-2008

Few Western states keep systematic records of water transactions. My own analysis is based on 4,220 transactions from a 22-year period from 1987 through 2008, as compiled at the Bren School at the University of California, Santa Barbara from reports in the trade jour-nal Water Strategist.

The table above shows average and median prices per acre-foot (the amount of water it takes to cover one acre a foot deep, or approx-imately 325,000 gallons) for the 12 Western states. The prices for sales and multiyear leases are given as the value per acre-foot of the committed flow of water. Where multi-year contracts are involved, the quantities are discounted in a process analogous to deter-mining the present value of a bond. Because most water has been consumed in agriculture (at prices set by historical cost) but most new demand is for urban and environmental uses, the trades reported are mostly for transfers out of agriculture.

The findings confirm the obvious: agricul-ture-to-urban prices are far above those for agriculture-to-agriculture trades. A bit of the difference may be associated with the higher costs of moving water to cities, but not much: the market for water is grossly inefficient, im-

plying there is much opportunity to increase the value of water through trading. Because sales (as opposed to leases) create a perpetual (and there-fore more valuable) claim on water flows, sales prices are naturally higher.

Prices also differ sharply by state, with averages for one-year leases ranging from $8 per acre-foot in

Idaho to $87 in Arizona and averages for sales ranging from $113 acre-foot in Idaho to $6,592 (!!!) in Colorado. These price gaps un-derscore the inefficient segmentation of water markets.

In theory, one could get a clear sense of the potential gains from unimpaired water trad-ing from these price differences. Unfortu-nately, water markets are too thin to make this easy. But one example is illustrative. Groundwater for farming cotton near Ma-rana, Ariz., costs approximately $27 per acre-foot. The same water supplied to Tucson, which is about 25 miles away, will cost urban customers $479 to $3,267 per acre-foot.

WestWater Research, a water broker, offers more illustrations. Nevada’s Truckee River Basin has been one of the most active markets in the Western United States, thanks largely to urban growth in the Reno-Sparks area. Be-tween 2002 and 2008, there were 1,025 water sales to urban users, with a median price of $17,685 per acre-foot, as compared to only 13 sales to agricultural users, with a median price of $1,500.

By contrast, the market built around the Colorado-Big Thompson project in northern Colorado yielded much narrower differences. And no wonder. Within this large water- supply project, each user has an identically defined claim to water units that are tradable, and there are no return-flow considerations that could lead to third-party impairments. Water trades occur smoothly and frequently.

source: author’s calculations

Agriculture- Agriculture- Agriculture- Agriculture- to-urbAn to-Agriculture to-urbAn to-Agriculture leAses leAses sAles sAles

Median Price $74 $19 $295 $144Average Price $190 $56 $437 $246Number of Trades 204 207 1,140 215

Water transfer Prices by sector, 1987-2008 (2008 dollars Per acre-foot)

Page 69: Milken Institute Review Q4

67Fourth Quarter 2010

For example, in October 2008, an agriculture-to-agriculture trade took place at $9,152 an acre-foot, just $53 less than an agriculture-to-urban trade that same month. Unfortunately, the Colorado-Big Thompson market is a very unusual one. But it provides a template for what might be possible elsewhere.

Welfare Gains from Greater Trading

Differences in water values across sectors in-dicate that moving water from agriculture to urban and industrial uses can yield enor-mous returns. As I have noted, the calculation of the benefit is complicated. Nevertheless, we can use price data for different types of trades and United States Geological Survey estimates of the amount of water applied in irrigation to perform a simple exercise that il-lustrates the potential for trading. Transfer-ring a relatively small amount of Western water – 3 percent of water currently used for surface irrigation – from agriculture to urban use would generate $98 million per year in net benefits.

patterns of Water Trading, 1987-2008

All Western states allow for transfers of water under terms ranging from short (one-year) leases to long (35-year) ones. Some are simple transfers between agricultural users in the same locality. Some involve transfers among uses from a common source, while others in-volve long-distance exchanges. As the figure at right shows, volumes in agricultural-to-urban and agricultural-to-environmental transfers are increasing, while ag-to-ag trades suggest no discernable trend.

But the pattern varies greatly by state. Col-orado dominates in terms of total market transactions, reflecting the institutional ad-vantages of the Northern Colorado Conser-vancy District and the Colorado-Big Thomp-son Project, where the costs of trading are low

and most involve sales of relatively small amounts of water. Other active-market states are California, Texas, Arizona and Nevada. California’s institutional and regulatory envi-ronments explain the focus on short-term leases. In Arizona and Nevada – both rapidly urbanizing, dry states – sales are common, But – not surprisingly – Montana and Wyo-ming, the least urban of the 12 Western states, have the fewest water sales.

There are also important differences in the parties involved in the transactions. In Colo-rado, Nevada and Washington, agriculture-to-urban trades account for most of the water, reflecting rapid urbanization. In California, single-year leases within agriculture dominate, with a few large multiyear leases from ag-to-urban use in Southern California.

Most transfers are within states, limiting the potential gains associated with transfer to higher-value uses. Even so, the numbers are fairly impressive, offering a hint of the oppor-tunities for addressing growing problems of regional scarcity.

number of transfers in 12 Western states

350

300

250

200

150

100

50

01987 2000 2009

year

totAl

Ag-to- environmentAl

Ag-to-Ag

Ag-to-urbAn

source: author’s calculations

Page 70: Milken Institute Review Q4

68 The Milken Institute Review

Farmers are often eager to engage in water trades; the financial benefits can be quite a lure. For example, consider a sale of 1,200 acre-feet of groundwater in California from agriculture-to-urban use. At a sale price of $275 an acre-foot, plus a processing fee of $20,000, the total revenue to the farmer was $350,000. In spite of pumping costs of $50 to $75 per acre-foot, consulting fees of $25,000 to gather needed hydrological information for regulatory review and $70,000 in legal fees for the regulatory process, the net income was still $165,000. A bonanza, compared to, say, the economics of growing alfalfa to feed ani-mals. The big question, then, is how to re-move unreasonable hurdles from the process.

the way forwardTo create reasonably efficient markets with low transactions costs, a variety of changes are needed:

Surface-water rights must be better de-fined and quantified, and recorded in state registries. Groundwater rights must be simi-larly defined, with withdrawals monitored by local water masters. Meanwhile, the links be-tween ground- and surface water need to be recognized in defining rights.

private water rights need to be endorsed as a basis for use and exchange by state legisla-tures. And the ownership of water within supply organizations like irrigation districts needs to be clarified, with decision-making assigned to owners – not boards controlled by ancillary groups.

private water banks need to be encouraged. These would involve virtual deposits of excess water, whereby owners could offer specific amounts for sale or lease at specified prices. These banks would standardize terms of transfer, like other commodity exchanges do. Such banks have been used in the past, but

the prices have been heavily regulated and the administrative fees imposed have exceeded real costs.

The no-injury harm rule for assessing water trades should be defined precisely and the range of objectors limited to those with a di-rect stake in the process. “The public interest” should be defined clearly and narrowly to re-duce uncertainty. Similarly, area-of-origin re-strictions on trading should be limited to ac-tual hydrological effects of trading – and not used to mitigate pecuniary effects of transfers.

The public-trust doctrine should be invoked only as a last resort. Instead, water should be purchased for environmental use by state agencies or nonprofit groups, and the possi-bility of condemnation of water for public uses employed as a lever in bargaining. This threat would work much the way it works in land condemnation to overcome the holdout problem in public infrastructure investments.

retail urban water pricing needs to be re-formed to promote efficiency. Some cities, in-cluding Sacramento, do not meter water use at all; others charge flat unit prices that don’t reflect the high cost of adding new supplies. Consider two Arizona desert cities. Tucson’s water rates rise steeply with consumption, and in 2007, annual use per capita was 140,800 gallons. By contrast, Phoenix has flat rates, and consumption was 75 percent greater.

* * *The West’s water policy is a minefield in

which policymakers and politicians are in-clined to step gingerly – or not at all. But with urban and environmental demand for water growing at a prodigious rate and supply growth constrained by a host of factors, the path of least resistance is no longer an option. The region’s fabled quality of life turns on easy access to water, and only well-functioning markets can offer the prospect of delivering that water at reasonable cost. m

w a t e r w o e s

Page 71: Milken Institute Review Q4

69Fourth Quarter 2010

b o o k e x c e r p t

J

*Published by Princeton University Press. All rights reserved.

i l l u s t r at i o n s b y e d w a r d k i n s e l l a

John Quiggin, an economist at the Univer-

sity of Queensland and a prolific blogger, is

not as well-known as he should be outside

Australia. But we suspect this is about to change. Quiggin’s book, Zombie Economics:

How Dead Ideas Still Walk Among Us, to be published this

fall, is a devastating critique of the conventional economic

wisdom that brought us to the precipice in the financial

crisis and stands in the way of the fundamental reforms

needed to revivify market capitalism. ¶ The chapter

excerpted here explores what’s often called the “trickle-

down” hypothesis – the notion that we all have a common

interest in the success of the wealthiest among us and,

accordingly, that inequality in incomes and wealth should not be a concern. Quiggin,

a social democrat in the mold of a Paul Krugman or a Joe Stiglitz, offers a scathing

analysis, arguing … well, let’s let him speak for himself. — Peter Passell

Zombie EconomicsHow Dead Ideas Still Walk Among Us

Page 72: Milken Institute Review Q4

70 The Milken Institute Review

The money was all appropriated for the top in the hopes that it would trickle down to the needy. Mr. Hoover didn’t know that money trickled up. Give it to the people at the bottom and the people at the top will have it before night, anyhow. But it will at least have passed through the poor fellow’s hands. – Will Rogers

As long as there have been rich and poor people, or powerful and powerless people, there have been advocates to explain that it’s better for everyone if things stay that way.

The hymn “All Things Bright and Beauti-ful,” one of the favorites of my youth is, for the most part, a paean to the beauties of cre-ation. Sadly, the real message comes in the verse, “The rich man in his castle, the poor man at his gate, God made them high and lowly, and ordered their estate.”

Many of the greatest economists, includ-ing Adam Smith, John Stuart Mill and John Maynard Keynes have supported income re-distribution through progressive taxation, and the great majority of economists do so today. Nevertheless, there has always been a plentiful supply of economists and others will-ing to argue that it is better to let the rich get richer, and wait for the benefits to trickle down.

This idea seemed dead in the years after 1945, when a massive reduction in inequality went hand in hand with full employment and prosperity. The outcome, unique in history, was a society that was overwhelmingly mid-dle class in terms of living standards. The Marxist critique of capitalism, still issued reg-ularly by Soviet propagandists, came to seem quaint and old-fashioned.

But as inequality returned in the 1980s, so did its intellectual defenders. Advocates of lower taxes on the rich argued that, sooner or later, everyone would be better off if their policies were adopted. For a while their prom-ises seemed on the verge of fulfillment, as

most people seemed to share in the prosper-ity of the 1990s. The failure of this promise in the 2000s has been accompanied by the death of most of the theoretical ideas that sup-ported it. But trickle-down economics lingers on in zombie form.

Like most labels, “trickle-down” is a pejo-rative term, used mainly by critics. The trickle-down idea has been summed up more positively in the aphorism “a rising tide lifts all boats” attributed to John F. Kennedy, and a favorite of Clinton advisers Gene Sperling and Robert Rubin.

One important version of trickle-down economics is the “supply-side” school of eco-nomics, which came to prominence in the 1980s. The extreme claims made by some supply-siders threw this school into disrepute. However, more restrained versions, referred to by terms such as “dynamic efficiency” and

“new tax responsiveness,” were widely ac-cepted during the years of the Great Modera-tion of the 1990s – years of stable prices and solid economic growth.

This didn’t happen in a vacuum. The re-newed popularity of trickle-down economics coincided with a resurgence of the political right, and with financial globalization, which constrained the ability of governments to re-distribute income from capital to labor.

It was also, no doubt, influenced by the fact that most economists were among the beneficiaries of this process. That was true, in part, because most economists are in the top 20 percent of the income distribution, which

Page 73: Milken Institute Review Q4

71Fourth Quarter 2010

tk

Page 74: Milken Institute Review Q4

72 The Milken Institute Review

received most of the growth in income over this period. More important, perhaps, the huge growth in the financial sector, and in the incomes of those who worked there, had a flow-on effect to related professions. For econ-omists, at least, trickle-down really worked.

birth: from supply-side economics to dynamic scoringRegardless of nomenclature, the near-univer-sal prosperity of the postwar boom seemed to constitute a refutation of trickle-down eco-nomics every bit as decisive as the refutation of pre-Keynesian economics by mass unem-ployment in the 1930s. Throughout the de-veloped world, the growing prosperity of the years after 1945 was accompanied by reduc-tions in income inequality and a softening of the differences between classes.

The experience of the United States was particularly striking. Emerging as the unchal-lenged economic leader of the world after 1945, U.S. firms were in a position to pay manual workers at rates that propelled them into the middle class. And the middle class it-self grew and prospered to an extent that seemed to portend the end of class conflict – and even the end of class itself. The American middle class enjoyed living standards that, in many respects, outstripped the best that had been enjoyed by the rich in any other time and place.

All of this was achieved under policies that are, in retrospect, hard to believe were ever politically possible. Income taxes, then still a novelty, were steeply progressive. Top mar-ginal rates often exceeded 90 percent. Inheri-tances were also heavily taxed, while ordinary people benefited from a variety of new wel-fare measures, such as Social Security in the United States, which provided protection against the risks of old age, unemployment and disability. Economic historians Claudia

Goldin (Harvard) and Robert A. Margo (Bos-ton University) called the resulting period of high equality the Great Compression.

The Great Compression ended almost as suddenly as it began. From the early 1980s onward, the gains in equality were reversed. This occurred partly as result of the changes in the distribution of market incomes: profits grew at the expense of wages, and the distri-bution of wages became more unequal. But changes in market income were reinforced by public policy. The steeply progressive income tax rates of the postwar era were replaced by a flatter tax system. Maximum rates were cut to 40 percent or less.

Initially, and to some extent even today, these measures were presented as providing tax relief to the “middle class.” This is an elastic term, but one that is typically taken to include families with incomes ranging from the me-dian to the 90th percentile of the income distri-bution, or sometimes even higher. Increasingly, however, tax reductions were focused on those in the top 10 percent of the income distribu-tion – people who could not be called middle class, even on the broadest use of the term.

The pattern set by the United States in the 1980s was followed, to a greater or lesser de-gree, by other English-speaking countries as they embarked on the path of market liberal-ism. The most striking increases in inequality were in Britain under the Thatcher govern-ment, where the widely used measure of in-equality called the Gini coefficient rose from 0.25, a value comparable to that of Scandina-vian social democracies, to 0.33, which is among the highest (that is, most unequal) values for developed countries.

New Zealand started a few years later, but chose even more radical reforms, cutting the top marginal rate of income tax from 66 per-cent in 1986 to 33 percent by 1990. Not surpris-ingly, this pushed New Zealand’s Gini coeffi-

Page 75: Milken Institute Review Q4

73Fourth Quarter 2010

cient from an initial value of 0.26 to 0.33 by the mid-1990s. Canada and Australia both fol-lowed a similar path, as did Ireland in the 1990s. Most countries in the European Union resisted the trend to increased inequality through the 1980s and 1990s, but recent evidence suggests that inequality may be rising there, also.

The increase in inequality did not go un-noticed. By the 1980s, economists including Katharine Bradbury (Federal Reserve Boston), Gary Burtless (Brookings) and Paul Krugman (Princeton) were pointing with alarm to the

disappearance of the middle-class America in which they had grown up. This concern has since increased, as the growth of inequality has become ever more visible.

On the other hand, many other commen-tators regarded the growing inequality of the market-liberal years with complacency or positive approval, typically focusing on its supposed consequences, such as economic dynamism. The growth of inequality at-tracted attention only briefly, when it was blamed on politically controversial policies favored by market liberals such as free trade and expanded immigration. A flurry of stud-ies demonstrated that these factors were un-likely to be important. It was concluded, by default, that technological change must be the driving force.

Supply Side

As inequality increased, so did the demand for theoretical rationalizations of policies bene-fitting the wealthy – and in particular for re-

ductions in taxation. A variety of ideas of this kind were put forward under the banner of

“supply-side” economics.The term dates back to the 1970s, when it

was popularized by Jude Wanniski, then an associate editor of The Wall Street Journal and later an economic adviser to Ronald Reagan. Wanniski, a colorful figure, did not let his lack of academic credentials deter him from tak-ing on big names in the economics profession, including not only Keynes and his followers, but also Milton Friedman.

The central idea followed directly from the negative conclusions of the then-in-vogue New Classical economics regarding the possi-bility of successful demand management. If, as the New Classical school believed, such de-mand-side policies were bound to be ineffec-tual or counterproductive, the only way to improve economic outcomes was to focus on the supply side – that is, to increase the pro-ductive capacity of the economy. Although many policies, such as improved education, might be advocated as ways to improve pro-ductivity, Wanniski focused on the kinds fa-vored by market liberals, including reduced regulation and lower income taxes.

Wanniski started the process with his “Two Santa Claus” theory of politics. This was the idea that, in a contest between one political party (the Democrats) favoring higher public expenditure, and another (the Republicans) favoring lower spending, the high-spending party would always win. So, the correct politi-cal strategy for conservatives was to campaign

In the years after 1945, the American middle class

enjoyed living standards that, in many respects,

outstripped the best that had been enjoyed by the

rich in any other time and place.

Page 76: Milken Institute Review Q4

74 The Milken Institute Review

tk

Page 77: Milken Institute Review Q4

75Fourth Quarter 2010

for tax cuts, without worrying too much about budget deficits. Any problems with budget deficits would be resolved by the higher growth unleashed by improved incen-tives and reduced regulation.

This idea was the starting point for a fa-mous lunch meeting between Wanniski, Don-ald Rumsfeld, Dick Cheney and University of Southern California economist Arthur Laffer. These four, relatively obscure figures at the time, were to play a central (and disastrous) role in the economic and political events of the next 30 years.

Everyone knows the story of how Laffer drew a graph on a napkin, illustrating the point that tax rates of 100 percent would re-sult in a cessation of economic activity and therefore yield zero revenue. Since a tax rate of zero will also yield zero revenue, there must exist some rate of taxation that yields a maximum level of revenue. Increases in tax beyond that point will harm economic activ-ity so much that they reduce revenue.

Wanniski christened this graph the “Laffer Curve.” But as Laffer himself was happy to concede, there was nothing original about it; it can be traced back to the 14th century Ara-bic writer Ibn Khaldun. Laffer credited his own version to the nemesis of supply-side economics, John Maynard Keynes. And while few economists had made much of the point, that was mainly because it seemed too obvi-ous to bother spelling out.

What was novel in Laffer’s presentation was what might be called the “Laffer Hypothesis” – namely, that the United States in the early 1980s was on the descending part of the curve, where higher tax rates produced less revenue.

Unfortunately, as the old saying has it, Laf-fer’s analysis contained a mixture of correct-ness and originality. The Laffer Curve was correct but unoriginal. The Laffer Hypothesis was original but incorrect.

More sophisticated market liberals could also see that the Laffer Hypothesis repre-sented something of an “own goal” for their side. (In soccer, an own goal is one acciden-tally kicked by a player on the defending side, and counts as a goal for the other side.) If the debate over tax policy turned on whether tax cuts produced higher revenue, and were there-fore self-financing, the advocates of lower taxes were bound to lose – at least in policy circles where empirical evidence was taken se-riously. Embarrassingly for their more sophis-ticated allies, supply-siders made, and con-tinue to make, obviously silly arguments.

Fairly typical is the claim that, despite cut-ting taxes, Ronald Reagan doubled U.S. gov-ernment revenue, a claim derived from the work of right-wing think tanks such as The Heritage Foundation. Leaving aside the fact that revenues did not, in fact, double under Reagan, such claims ignore the reality that tax revenues, and the cost of providing any given level of government services, rise automati-cally with inflation, population growth and in-creases in real wages. Even with cuts in tax rates, revenues are bound to rise over time as the nominal value of national income increases.

For the Laffer Hypothesis to be supported, tax cuts would have to increase revenue more rapidly than would be expected as a result of normal income growth. In fact, as Richard Kogan of the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities has shown, income tax receipts grew noticeably more slowly than usual after the large cuts in individual and corporate in-come tax rates in 1981.

To the extent that there was an economic response to the Reagan tax cuts (and to those of George W. Bush 20 years later), it seems largely to have been a Keynesian demand-side response, to be expected when governments provide households with additional net in-come in the context of a depressed economy.

Page 78: Milken Institute Review Q4

76 The Milken Institute Review

In fact, some supply-siders, happy to push any argument for tax cuts, ended up embrac-ing the most simplistic forms of Keynesian-ism, much to the disgust of more consistent market liberals.

The Dynamic Trickle-Down Hypothesis

Mainstream market liberals were generally disdainful of the “voodoo economics” of the Laffer Hypothesis. They nonetheless accepted the central postulate of trickle-down eco-nomics, that policies favorable to the wealthy will in the long run produce benefits for ev-eryone, compared to the alternative of pro-gressive taxes and redistributive social welfare policies. Rather than rely on the simplistic and easily refuted Laffer Hypothesis, market liberals claimed that the trickle-down effect would work through so-called dynamic ef-fects of free-market reforms.

The appeal of this argument depended in large measure on conflating the ordinary lan-guage meaning of “dynamic” with the techni-cal economic meaning. In technical terms,

“dynamic” effects are those realized over time – in this case, as the capital stock in an economy changes. But in political discussion, it is easy to slide from this technical use into rhetoric about dynamism (and its opposite, sclerosis) that relies on the ordinary language meaning.

This analysis formed the basis of a number of “dynamic scoring” exercises aimed at esti-mating the effects of the Bush tax cuts of 2001. Supporters of the Laffer Hypothesis hoped that these exercises would show tax cuts paying for themselves in the long run.

Dynamic scoring analyses found some positive effects on capital accumulation, but they were too small in terms of their effect on incomes and tax revenues to offset the initial costs of the tax cuts. The most optimistic study, undertaken by Greg Mankiw, former chairman of President George W. Bush’s

Council of Economic Advisers, and Matthew Weinzierl (Harvard University), found that dynamic effects would offset about 17 per-cent of the initial cost of a cut in taxes on labor income and about 50 percent of the cost of a cut in taxes on capital income.

However, as subsequent analysis showed, these results depended critically on technical assumptions about how the tax cut was ini-tially financed. Mankiw and Weinzierl as-sumed that tax cuts were associated with ex-penditure cuts sufficient to maintain budget balance, and that the expenditure that was cut was a pure transfer rather than investment in something productive.

Eric Leeper (Indiana University) and Shu- Chun Susan Yang (IMF) examined the case when, as actually happened, the cuts were ini-tially financed by higher debt. In this case, it turns out that dynamic effects can actually in-crease the initial cost of a tax cut.

A further difficulty was that, since the in-creased income was the result of additional savings (and therefore, less consumption), it could not be regarded as a pure economic benefit. The relevant measure of economic benefit, netting out costs from benefits, is the change in the present value of current and fu-ture consumption, which is much smaller than the final change in income. Even for large tax cuts, the net dynamic benefit is rarely more than 1 percent of national income.

The same point may be made in terms of the effects on the government budget. Even if tax cuts eventually generated enough extra reve-nue to match the annual cost of the cuts (and, of course, they never do!) the budget would still be in long-term deficit because of the need to ser-vice the debt built up in the transition.

The implications for the trickle-down hy-pothesis are even worse. Under standard as-sumptions about the way the economy works, all the benefits of additional investment go to

Page 79: Milken Institute Review Q4

77Fourth Quarter 2010

those whose savings finance that investment. That is, cutting taxes for the rich may lead them to save and invest more, thereby making themselves still richer. But there is no reason to expect any benefit for the rest of the com-munity except to the extent that the cost of the original tax cut is partially defrayed.

Finally, and most importantly, the neoclas-sical model used to derive estimates of dy-namic benefits implicitly assumes that the extra investment generated by more favorable tax treatment is allocated efficiently so as to produce higher rates of long-term economic growth. Until the financial crisis, the experi-ence of countries that cut taxes on capital in-come appeared to validate this assumption. Iceland, Ireland and the Baltic states, among others, experienced rapid economic growth as a result of high domestic investment and strong capital inflows.

But the economic crisis proved that this apparent success was built on sand. Much of the extra investment went into real estate, or into speculative ventures that collapsed when the bubble burst.

Another version of the argument was put forward by economists associated with the Republican Party, notably Martin Feldstein (chairman of the Council of Economic Advis-ers and chief economic advisor to Ronald Reagan) and Lawrence Lindsey (director of the National Economic Council under George W. Bush). Feldstein and Lindsey presented ar-guments referred to as the “new tax respon-

siveness” theory, suggesting that tax cuts for the very rich would lead them to reduce their efforts at tax avoidance and thereby raise ad-ditional revenue. Subsequent work found that the results of Feldstein and Lindsey were overstated, and led to the common-sense conclusion that the best way to minimize tax avoidance was to tighten up on tax loopholes and tax havens.

life: excuses for inequalityDefenders of the trickle-down hypothesis fre-quently employ what blogger John Holbo calls “the two-step of terrific triviality,” which is to “say something that is ambiguous be-tween something so strong it is absurd and so weak that it would be absurd even to mention it. When attacked, hop from foot to foot as necessary, keeping a serious expression on your face.”

The self-evident and weak version of the trickle-down theory starts with the observa-tion that we all benefit, in all kinds of ways, from living in an advanced industrial society with access to modern medical care, con-sumer goods, the Internet and so on. Stretched widely enough, the term “capitalism” includes all advanced industrial societies, from Scan-dinavian social democracies to the Hong Kong version of laissez-faire. So, in this sense, the benefits of capitalism have trickled down to everyone.

The strong version of the claim is obtained by shifting the meaning of capitalism to

Defenders of the trickle-down hypothesis frequently

employ what blogger John Holbo calls “the two-step of

terrific triviality,” which is to “say something that

is ambiguous between something so strong it is absurd

and so weak that it would be absurd even to mention it.”

Page 80: Milken Institute Review Q4

78 The Milken Institute Review

mean the free-market version of capitalism favored by market liberals. And relatively few of the benefits mentioned above can be traced directly to this form of capitalism.

Many advances in medical care have come from publicly funded research and from in-novations developed in the public health sec-tor. The contributions of for-profit pharma-ceutical companies, though important, have been modest by comparison. Similarly, the Internet was developed by the publicly funded

university sector. Even now, the most exciting developments are nonprofit innovations like Wikipedia.

The crucial question is not whether techno-logical progress and economic development yield benefits to everyone. Clearly they do, at least in material terms. What matters is whether market-liberal policies generate more progress than more egalitarian alternatives – so much more that everyone is better off in the end. It is this strong claim that was made repeatedly during the era of market triumphalism in the 1990s and was repeated, though with some-what less conviction, through the 2000s.

The growth in U.S. inequality during the Great Moderation was undeniable (though that didn’t stop some commentators and think tanks trying to deny it). Optimistic assess-ments of economic performance during the period appeared to support the claim that ris-ing inequality must be good for, or at least consistent with, economic growth that would ultimately benefit everybody. Now, in the wake of the global financial crisis, this claim can be seen to be unambiguously false.

Income, Inequality and TaxationThe most obvious implication of the trickle-down hypothesis is that inequality in market incomes is not only harmless but positively de-sirable, producing benefits for everyone in the long run. The general idea is that, the greater the rewards given to owners of capital and highly skilled managers, the more productive they will be. This will lead both to the provi-sion of goods and services at lower cost and to higher demand for the services of less-skilled

workers who will therefore earn higher wages.In the abstract language of welfare eco-

nomics, the central implication of the trickle-down hypothesis is that policy should be aimed at promoting efficiency rather than eq-uity since in the long run, equity will take care of itself. Put in terms of a more homely metaphor, we should focus on making the pie bigger, rather than sharing it out more equally.

In reality, things are not that simple. It is easy to suggest that tax and other policies should apply neutrally to all sectors of the economy, but harder to define how this should actually work. It might seem that a “flat” tax system in which all forms of income are taxed at a low, uni-form rate would satisfy the efficiency criterion. But advocates of trickle-down argue that in-come from capital should not be taxed at all.

Going further, market liberals have claimed that, since everyone benefits from many of the services provided by government, the most ef-ficient and equitable form of taxation is a poll [head] tax. A poll tax was, in fact, introduced by the Thatcher government in Britain to fi-nance local government services, but was

It is easy to suggest that tax and other policies should

apply neutrally to all sectors of the economy, but harder

to define how this should actually work.

Page 81: Milken Institute Review Q4

79Fourth Quarter 2010

abandoned in the face of massive protests.Once we turn from theoretical policy de-

bate to the details of design, implementation and enforcement, the well-off invariably do better than theory would suggest and the poor do worse. This was true, to some extent, dur-ing the postwar Great Compression. Although the tax system appeared steeply progressive, the deductions, loopholes and tax minimiza-tion schemes meant that it was, at best, only moderately progressive. Under the systems in force since the 1980s, which are only margin-ally progressive in their design, the actual out-come has been that many high income earn-ers pay a smaller proportion of their income in tax than the population as a whole.

The absence of substantial progressivity in the tax system is obscured by the focus, in the United States and elsewhere, on the fact that high income earners pay the bulk of income tax. A good deal of the material appearing on this topic in The Wall Street Journal and else-where gives the impression that income tax is the only tax in the system. In reality, income tax is not even the sole tax imposed on in-come. Most countries, including the United States, levy payroll taxes on labor income. Unlike the progressive income tax, which falls most heavily on high income earners, payroll taxes are regressive.

In most taxation systems, capital gains are accorded concessional treatment or not taxed at all. Unsurprisingly, a large share of capital income is taken in the form of capital gains, moving the tax system closer to the trickle-down ideal where all taxes fall on wage-earners.

That’s not all. Taxes on income and wealth only account for about half of government rev-enue in most tax systems. Consumption taxes make up about half of all government revenue, and these taxes are regressive. That is, those with low incomes typically pay a higher pro-portion of their incomes in consumption taxes

than do those with high incomes. There are a number of reasons for this. Low-income earn-ers generally don’t save very much, so the ratio of consumption to income is higher for these groups. Taxes on items such as tobacco, alcohol and gambling are levied at very high rates, and these items tend to make up a larger share of the expenditure of the poor (though absolute expenditure is higher only for tobacco).

Finally, there is tax avoidance and minimi-zation. A vast industry of lawyers and ac-countants exists solely to ensure that no one with sufficient means should pay any more tax than the minimum they are obliged to pay under the most creative possible interpreta-tion of the law.

History shows that, no matter how favor-ably the well-off are treated, there will always be arguments to suggest that they should re-ceive even better treatment. Trickle-down theory offers no limit to the extent to which the burdens of taxation and economic risk can or should be shifted from the rich to the poor. In the end, according to the trickle-down story, that which is given to the rich will always come back to the rest of us, while that which is given to the poor is gone forever.

The Role of the Financial Sector

The financial sector is the crucial test case for trickle-down theory. During the era of mar-ket liberalism, incomes in the financial sector rose more rapidly than in any other part of the economy and played a major role in bid-ding up the incomes of senior managers as well as those of professionals in related fields such as law and accounting. According to the trickle-down theory, the growth in income accruing to the financial sector benefitted the U.S. population as a whole in three main ways.

• The facilitation of takeovers, mergers and private buyouts offered the opportunity to increase the efficiency with which capital was

Page 82: Milken Institute Review Q4

80 The Milken Institute Review

used, and the productivity of the economy as a whole.

• Expanded provision of credit to house-holds allowed higher standards of living to be enjoyed, as households could ride out fluctu-ations in income, bring forward the benefits of future income growth and draw on the capital gains associated with rising prices for stocks, real estate and other assets.

• Thanks to the classic trickle-down effect in which the wealth of the financial sector generates demands for luxury goods and ser-vices of all kinds, workers in general, or at least those in cities with high concentrations of financial sector activity, such as London and New York, earned higher incomes.

The years from the early 1990s to 2007 gave some support to all of these claims. Mea-sured U.S. productivity grew strongly in the 1990s, and moderately in the years after 2000. Household consumption also grew strongly, and inequality in consumption was much less than inequality in income or wealth. And, al-though income growth was weak for most households, rates of unemployment were low by post-1970 standards.

Very little of this is likely to survive the fi-nancial crisis.

At its peak, the financial sector (finance, insurance and real estate) accounted for around 18 percent of GDP and a much larger share of GDP growth in the last two decades. With professional and business services in-cluded, the total share of financial sector out-put in GDP was greater than 30 percent. The finance and business services sector is now contracting, and it is clear that a significant part of the output measured in the bubble years was illusory.

Many investments and financial transac-tions made during this period have already proved disastrous, and many more seem likely to do so in coming years. In the process,

the apparent gains generated through the ex-pansion of the financial sector will be lost.

Equality of Outcome and Equality of Opportunity

The trickle-down hypothesis is closely related to the distinction between equality of out-comes, like life expectancy, and equality of opportunity. This distinction has long been a staple of debates between market liberals and social democrats. Many market liberals argue that as long as society equalizes opportunity, for example by providing good schools for all, it’s not a problem if outcomes are highly un-equal. Even though some people may do badly, it’s claimed their children will benefit from growing up in a dynamic society where everyone has a chance at the glittering prizes.

Writing in The Wall Street Journal, Wiscon-sin Republican Paul Ryan attacked President Obama’s first budget saying, “In a nutshell, the president’s budget seemingly seeks to re-place the American political idea of equaliz-ing opportunity with the European notion of equalizing results.”

A year earlier, following his victory in the Republican primary in South Carolina, John McCain said, “We can overcome any chal-lenge as long as we keep our courage, and stand by our defense of free markets, low taxes and small government that have made America the greatest land of opportunity in the world.”

As these quotations suggest, the trickle-down hypothesis relies on the claim that equality of opportunity and equality of out-come are not only distinct concepts but stand in active opposition to each other. By remov-ing disincentives to work, such as high tax rates and elaborate social welfare systems, it is claimed, an economic system that tolerates highly unequal outcomes will also provide those at the bottom with the incentives and

Page 83: Milken Institute Review Q4

81Fourth Quarter 2010

tk

Page 84: Milken Institute Review Q4

82 The Milken Institute Review

opportunities to haul themselves up into the middle class and beyond.

The idea that the United States is a “land of opportunity” and “the most socially mobile society the world has ever known” (as conser-vative blogger Scott Norvell put it in a piece calling for patriotic consumer spending in the wake of 9/11) is central to the American national self-image. The belief that this high social mobility derives from free markets is widely shared.

Empirical studies of social mobility do not support such beliefs. But most economists are not engaged in studies of social mobility, and many of them share these popular as-sumptions. This is true not only of self-satis-fied American economists promoting the merits of the status quo and calling for more of the same, but also of European critics of the welfare state who accept the characteriza-tion of their own societies as rigid and scle-rotic by comparison with the dynamic and flexible United States.

death: the rich get richer and the poor go nowhereAlthough the trickle-down hypothesis never had much in the way of supporting evidence, empirical testing was difficult. In particular, its proponents never specified the period over which the benefits of growth were supposed to percolate through to the poor. But the global financial crisis marks the end of the era of finance-driven market liberalism. And to the extent that any assessment of the distribu-tional effects of market liberal policies will ever be possible, it is possible now.

The data on income distribution for the United States show that households in the bottom half of the income distribution gained nothing from the decades of market liberal-ism. Apologists for market liberalism have of-fered various arguments to suggest that the

raw data leave the wrong impression, but none stand up to scrutiny. All the evidence supports the common-sense conclusion that policies designed to benefit the rich at the ex-pense of the poor have done precisely that.

The United States Since 1970

The GDP of the United States grew solidly during the decades of market liberalism since the 1970s, if not as rapidly as during the Keynesian postwar boom. More relevant to the trickle-down hypothesis, the incomes and wealth of the richest Americans grew spectac-ularly. Real incomes in the top 5 percent of the income distribution doubled and those of the top 0.1 percent quadrupled.

By contrast, the gains to households in the middle have been much more modest. Real median household income rose from $45,000 to just over $50,000 between 1973 (the last year of the long postwar expansion) and 2008. Real incomes for the lower half of the distri-bution have stagnated.

The same picture emerges if we look at wages. Median real earnings for full-time year-round male workers have not grown since 1974. For males with high school educa-tion or less, real wages have actually declined. The average annual earnings of 25- to 29-year-old high school graduates, expressed in 2005 dollars, fell from $30,900 in 1970 to $25,900 in 2000, and have stagnated since.

One result can be seen by looking at the proportion of households living below the poverty line. The poverty rate declined steadily during the postwar Keynesian era. But it has remained essentially static since 1970, falling in booms but rising again in recessions.

The United States has an official poverty line fixed in terms of absolute consumption levels and based on an assessment of a pov-erty-line food budget undertaken in 1963. The proportion of Americans below this fixed

Page 85: Milken Institute Review Q4

83Fourth Quarter 2010

poverty line fell from 25 percent in the late 1950s to 11 percent in 1974. Since then it has fluctuated, reaching 13.2 percent in 2008, a level that is certain to rise further as a result of the recession. And since the poverty line has remained unchanged, the real incomes accruing to the poorest 10 percent of Ameri-cans have fallen over the last 30 years.

These outcomes are reflected in measures

of the numbers of Americans who lack access to the basics of life: food, shelter and ade-quate medical care. In 2008, the U.S. Depart-ment of Agriculture classified 49.1 million Americans as “food insecure,” meaning that they lacked access to enough food to meet basic needs at all times. Some 17 million more lived in households with “very low food security,” meaning that one or more people in the household were hungry over the course of the year because of the inability to afford enough food. This number had doubled since 2000 and has almost certainly increased fur-ther as a result of the recession.

The number of people without health in-surance rose steadily over the period of market liberalism, both in absolute terms and as a pro-portion of the population, reaching 46 million, or 15 percent of the population. Among the in-sured, an increasing proportion was reliant on government programs. The traditional model of employment-based private health insur-ance, which was developed as part of the New Deal eroded to the point of collapse.

More on Inequality

Homelessness is almost entirely a phenome-

non of the era of market liberalism. During the decades of full employment, homeless-ness was confined to a tiny population of transients – mostly older males with mental health and substance abuse problems. By contrast, in 2007, 1.6 million people spent time in homeless shelters and about 40 per-cent of the homeless population were families with children.

The experience of the United States in the era of market liberalism was as thorough a refutation of the trickle-down hypothesis as can reasonably be imagined. The well-off have become better off, and the rich have be-come super-rich. Despite impressive techno-logical progress, those in the middle strug-gled to stay in place, and those at the bottom became worse off in crucial respects.

There have been plenty of attempts to deny the evidence presented above, or to argue that things are not as bad as they seem. Some can be dismissed out of hand. Among the most popular and the silliest is the observation that even the poor now have more access to con-sumer goods than they had in the past.

For example, Michael Cox (Federal Re-serve Dallas) and Richard Alm (The Dallas Morning News) observe in their book Myths of Rich and Poor that, in spite of the rise in in-equality, “a poor household in the 1990s was more likely than an average household in the 1970s to have a washing machine, clothes dryer, dishwasher, refrigerator, stove, color television, personal computer or telephone.”

The common feature of all these items is that their price has fallen dramatically relative

The experience of the United States in the era of market liberalism was as thorough a refutation of the trickle-

down hypothesis as can reasonably be imagined.

Page 86: Milken Institute Review Q4

84 The Milken Institute Review

to the general price level. This means that, even if incomes were exactly the same as in 1970, we would expect to see a big increase in consumption of these items. Unfortunately, if these items have become relatively cheaper, others must have become relatively dearer – and therefore less accessible.

It’s not hard to find examples of expendi-ture items that have become more expensive.

Unsurprisingly, access to health care for poor households has become worse, as has the gap in health outcomes between the rich and the poor.

College education provides another im-portant example. The cost has risen dramati-cally, particularly for the elite institutions that provide the pathway to the best jobs. In this case, it is the middle class who have suffered the biggest losses. Only the brightest children from poor backgrounds ever made it into elite colleges, and for this group, financial aid has remained accessible. The middle class, on the other hand, have been faced with a com-bination of higher fees and reduced aid.

As a result, between 1985 and 2000, the proportion of high-income (top 25 percent) students among freshmen at elite institutions rose steadily, from 46 to 55 percent. The pro-portion of middle-income students (between the 25th and 75th percentiles) fell from 41 to 33 percent.

Some adjustments should be made to measures of household income that make the picture look a little better than suggested by the statistics cited above. Household size has

decreased. The average household contained 1.86 equivalent adults in 1974 and 1.68 equiv-alent adults in 2007. Income per equivalent adult rose at an annual rate of 0.7 percent over this period.

Note, too, that women have done a little bet-ter than men. The median earnings for women who were full-time workers rose by about 0.9 percent per year over this period. By no coin-

cidence, the main factors sustaining growth in incomes for American households outside the top 20 percent has been an increase in the labor force participation of women.

Finally, until the 1990s the consumer price index took inadequate account of changes in product quality, so the decline in real wages was somewhat overstated. The Boskin Com-mission, appointed by the U.S. Senate in 1995, introduced a number of changes that lowered the estimated annual rate of inflation by about one percentage point. So, while the stagnation of median incomes in the 1970s and 1980s might be overstated, that of the 1990s and 2000s is not.

The myth of trickle-down was sustained, in large part, by the availability of easy credit. Now that the days of easy credit are gone, pre-sumably for a long time to come, reality has reasserted itself.

With sufficiently optimistic assumptions about social mobility (that low-income house-holds were in that state only temporarily) and asset appreciation (that the stagnation of me-dian incomes would be offset by capital gains on houses and other investments) increases in

The myth of trickle-down was sustained, in large part, by the availability of easy credit. Now that the days of

easy credit are gone, presumably for a long time to come,

reality has reasserted itself.

Page 87: Milken Institute Review Q4

85Fourth Quarter 2010

debt used to sustain consumption could be made to appear manageable. Once asset prices stopped rising, they were shown to be unsus-tainable. The contradiction has been resolved for individual households by a massive in-crease in bankruptcy and other forms of fi-nancial breakdown.

In normal times, the renewed surge in bankruptcy would have been a major issue. In the recent crisis, however, the upward trend has been overshadowed by foreclosures on home mortgages. During the boom, when overstretched householders could normally sell at a profit and repay their debts, foreclo-sures were rare. From 2007 onward, however, they increased dramatically. Banks foreclosed 2.3 million houses in 2008 and 2.8 million in 2009. In hard-hit areas of California, more than 5 percent of houses went into foreclo-sure in a single year.

Econometric Studies

The relationship between inequality and eco-nomic growth has been the subject of a vast number of econometric studies, which have, as so often with econometric studies, yielded conflicting results. Early studies focused on the relationship between initial levels of in-equality and subsequent levels of economic growth. These studies consistently found a negative relationship between initial levels of inequality and subsequent growth. On the other hand, increases in inequality appeared to be favorable to growth.

This apparent contradiction may be ex-plained by the observation that the initial im-pact of an increase in inequality should be fa-vorable to economic growth, but that the long-run effects are mainly harmful. In the era of market liberalism, growth in inequality was closely associated with financial deregu-lation and the growth of the financial sector. The short-term effects of financial deregula-

tion have almost everywhere been favorable. The negative consequences take years or even decades to manifest themselves. So, it is un-surprising to observe a positive correlation between changes in inequality and changes in economic growth rates in the short and medium term.

It is only relatively recently that studies of this kind have explicitly examined the trickle-down hypothesis. Perhaps the most directly relevant work is that of Dan Andrews and Christopher Jencks of the Kennedy School of Government at Harvard and Andrew Leigh of the Australian National University. Andrews, Jencks and Leigh found no systematic rela-tionship between top income shares and eco-nomic growth in a panel of 12 developed na-tions observed for between 22 and 85 years in the period 1905 to 2000. After 1960, there is a small, but statistically significant relationship between changes in inequality and the rate of economic growth. However, the benefits to lower income groups flow through so slowly that they may never catch up the ground they initially lose.

Social Mobility

The United States is characterized by highly unequal economic outcomes compared to other developed countries. The fact that these outcomes have grown more unequal during the era of market liberalism is undeniable. That hasn’t stopped people denying it, though, especially when they are paid to do so. But at least such denials must be presented, in con-trarian fashion, as showing that “everything you know about income inequality is wrong.”

By contrast, the belief that this inequality is offset by high levels of social mobility is widely held in and outside the United States. In the late 19th century, the United States was indeed a land of opportunity compared to the hierarchical societies of Europe, and many

Page 88: Milken Institute Review Q4

86 The Milken Institute Review

believe that this is still the case. But the evi-dence is clear: among the developed coun-tries, the United States has the lowest social mobility on nearly all measures, and the Eu-ropean social democracies the highest.

Ron Haskins and Isabel Sawhill of the Brookings Institution analyzed social mobility by looking at the life chances of men whose fa-thers were in the bottom fifth of the income distribution. In a world of equal opportunity, we might expect that 20 percent of them would end up in the same group as their fathers.

In fact, Haskins and Sawhill found that 42 percent of American men with fathers in the bottom fifth remain there, compared to 25 percent in Denmark, 26 percent in Sweden, 28 percent in Finland and Norway, and 30 percent in the United Kingdom. As the well-off have drawn away from the rest of the community in terms of income share, they have pulled the ladder up behind them, en-suring that their children have better life chances than those born to poorer parents.

The evidence suggests that the alleged ten-sion between equality of outcomes and equal-ity of opportunity, a central theme in market-liberal rhetoric, is inconsistent with empirical reality. More equal opportunities make for more equal outcomes, and vice versa.

It’s not hard to see why this should be so. The highly unequal outcomes of market- liberal policies are often supposed to be offset by an education system available to all, and by laws that prevent discrimination and encour-age merit-based employment. That might work for a generation, but in the second gen-eration the rich parents will be looking to buy a head start for their less-able children – for example, by sending them to private schools where they will be coached in examination skills and equipped with an old school tie.

One generation more, and the wealthy will be fighting to stop their tax dollars from

Page 89: Milken Institute Review Q4

87Fourth Quarter 2010

being wasted on public education from which they no longer benefit. Those who remain in the public system will lobby to get their own children into good public schools and ensure that these schools attract and retain the best teachers, benefit from fund-raising activity, and so on. As a result, both the importance of ability as a determinant of educational attain-ment and the importance of educational at-tainment as a source of social mobility have declined over time.

The inequalities are even more evident in higher education. Thanks to scholarship pro-grams, a handful of able students from poor backgrounds make it into Ivy League colleges like Harvard and Yale every year. But their numbers are far outweighed by students from the top quarter of the income distribution whose families have the financial resources to afford hefty fees and the cultural capital to navigate the complex admissions process.

Those with old money, but less than stellar intellectual resources, have their own highly effective affirmative action program: the (for-mal or informal) legacy admission system by which the children of alumni gain preferential admission. In 1998, William G. Bowen, a for-mer president of Princeton, and Derek Bok, a former president of Harvard, estimated that

“the overall admission rate for legacies was al-most twice that for all other candidates.”

While education is critical, high levels of in-equality naturally perpetuate themselves through other, more subtle channels, like health status. While the problem is worse in the United States than elsewhere because of highly unequal access to health care, high levels of in-equality produce unequal health outcomes even in countries with universal public systems.

There are other factors at work. A widely dispersed income distribution means that a much bigger change in income is needed to move the same distance in the income distri-

bution – say from the bottom quintile to the middle, or from the middle to the top. So, un-equal outcomes represent a direct obstacle to social mobility.

The evidence that, under market liberal-ism, social mobility is low and declining should not surprise anyone. On the other hand, it is disappointing that the myth of equal opportunity continues to be believed so many decades after it has ceased to have a basis in fact.

The Unhealthiness of Hierarchies

Some of the most compelling evidence against the trickle-down hypothesis has come from studies of social outcomes such as health status, crime and social cohesion. It is commonly thought that, while it is better to be at the top of the hierarchy than at the bot-tom, there are some offsetting disadvantages

– particularly in relation to health. While the poor suffer from lack of access to good medi-cal care, the rich are supposed to suffer from diseases of affluence like heart disease, com-pounded by the stresses of life at the top.

But epidemiologist Michael Marmot’s book The Status Syndrome documents that people at the top of status hierarchies live longer and have better health than those at the bottom.

Marmot’s work began with a study of Brit-ish civil servants, which is an interesting pop-ulation for two reasons. First, it excludes ex-tremes of wealth and poverty. The civil service is not a road to riches, but even the lowest-ranking civil servants are not poor. Second, the public service provides a clear-cut status hierarchy with very fine gradations.

Marmot found that senior public servants at the top of the status hierarchy were health-ier than those at the bottom. More surpris-ingly, he found that, throughout the hierarchy, relatively small differences in pay and status

Page 90: Milken Institute Review Q4

88 The Milken Institute Review

were associated with significant differences in life expectancy and other measures of health.

The finding has been replicated across all sorts of status hierarchies. As you move from the slums of southeast Washington, DC, to the leafy suburbs of Montgomery County, Maryland, life expectancy rises a year for every mile traveled. Among actors, Academy Award winners live, on average, four years longer than their Oscarless co-stars.

Along the way, Marmot demolishes the myth of executive stress. Despite their busy lives, Type A personalities and so on, senior managers are considerably less likely to die of heart attacks than the workers they order around.

Marmot, along with others who have stud-ied the problem, concludes that the crucial benefit of high-status positions is autonomy – that is, the amount of control people have over their own lives. There is a complex web of relationships between health status and au-tonomy, both self-perceived and measured by objective job characteristics. Low levels of au-tonomy are associated not only with poorer access to health care, but with more of all the risk factors that contribute to poor health, from homicide to poor diet.

In The Spirit Level, epidemiologists Rich-ard Wilkinson and Kate Pickett build on Mar-mot’s work and other statistical evidence to produce a comprehensive case for the propo-sition that inequalities in income and status have far-reaching and damaging effects on a wide range of measures of social well-being – effects that are felt even by those who are rel-atively high in the income distributions.

First, in all countries, there is a strong rela-tionship between social outcomes and social rank, much greater than can be explained by income differences alone. Second, greater in-equality within a country is associated with a steeper social gradient.

The United States is the obvious outlier in almost all studies of this kind. It is the wealthi-est country in the world and the most unequal of the rich countries. The United States is dis-appointing on a wide range of measures of so-cial well-being, from life expectancy to serious crime, and even on average height. [Height is a valuable proxy for childhood nutrition.]

These poor performances cannot be ex-plained by the continuing black-white divide or by poor outcomes for immigrants. All but the very richest groups of Americans do worse on most measures of social well-being than people with a comparable position in the income distribution in more equal coun-tries. These bad outcomes occur even though the average income of the non-Americans in these groups is much lower than that of the corresponding Americans.

after the zombies: economics, inequality and equityThe longer-run implications of the current economic crisis have yet to be fully compre-hended. Even when economic activity recov-ers, consumer credit will be more restricted than in past decades. As a result, there will be no escape from the implications of decades of stagnant wages for workers at the median and below. The traditional avenues of upward so-cial mobility, both through higher education and through promotion within large organi-zations, are being closed off. With good jobs increasingly depending on an education at a good university, the chances of climbing the ladder diminish all the time.

There does not yet exist a political move-ment ready and willing, let alone able, to mo-bilize popular support for a program of in-come redistribution. Rather, revulsion against the willingness of politicians to bail out the banking system has been reflected most clearly in the confused and angry demagogu-

Page 91: Milken Institute Review Q4

89Fourth Quarter 2010

ery of the Tea Party movement, which has been manipulated to serve the very interests that have generated the feelings of injustice that drive it.

But measures to protect individuals and families against the risks and inequities of mar-ket liberalism are gaining more acceptance. The prescription drug benefit introduced under the George W. Bush administration pro-vides one example. Another positive develop-ment has been the continued extension of un-employment benefits in response to the depth and duration of the current recession.

The most critical test for developments in the United States will be the success or failure of health care reform legislation. At the time of writing, its fate remains unclear. However, other reforms of this kind, controversial at the time, have come to be generally accepted.

Rather than consider questions of political strategy, however, I will focus on the way in which the failure of the trickle-down hypoth-esis should change the questions economists ask, and the way in which they should seek to answer them.

* * *The failure of the trickle-down hypothesis

provides economists with plenty of challeng-ing research tasks. A crucial problem is to un-derstand why and how inequality increased so much under market liberalism, and why it increased so much more in the English-speaking countries.

The idea that growing inequality was a nat-ural market response to unspecified changes in the structure of the economy no longer ap-pears tenable. The huge increases in remuner-ation in the financial sector (and for senior managers more generally) has not produced a more efficient and productive economy, with benefits for all.

In fact, the crisis has undermined the view that incomes accruing to different groups in

the community are an accurate reflection of their marginal contribution.

The policies and institutional changes that took place under market liberalism have al-most all pushed in the direction of greater in-equality. Corporations have been deregulated while the full power of the state has been turned against unions. Tax schedules have been flattened. The main income sources of the wealthy, including capital gains, inheri-tance and dividends have been given progres-sively more favorable treatment. Corpora-tions have competed with each other to pay ever larger amounts to their CEOs. And, at the very top, there is, indeed, a trickle-down effect. Stratospheric CEO salaries encourage huge increases for other top executives and substantial increases in payment for senior professionals, even as wages stagnate or fall for ordinary workers.

It remains unclear, though, which feature of market liberalism contributed most sub-stantially to the growth of inequality, and how those policies interacted with other social de-velopments. The importance of the links be-tween inequalities in income, health, educa-tion and political power is evident from the work of Marmot and others. But the links between economic variables like income in-equality and personal and social outcomes re-alized over generations are inherently complex. It seems clear enough that inequal-ity is bad for us, but much harder to say how and why.

All this is merely a preliminary to the big question: how can the growth in inequality be reversed and the more egalitarian society of the Great Compression be restored? Some steps, such as restoring progressivity to the tax system, seem obvious. But even the obvi-ous steps must confront the political realities of a system in which political power has shifted overwhelmingly to the wealthy. m

Page 92: Milken Institute Review Q4

90 The Milken Institute Review

Make no mistake: motion picture and tele-vision production in California remains strong. Hollywood is still the clear leader in terms of economic output and innovation, and California’s entertainment-industry em-ployment levels far exceed those of the rest of North America. In 2008, 160 movies and 320 television programs were filmed in the state. The two employment categories that make up the entertainment industry (motion picture and video recording – which also encom-passes post-production – and independent artists, writers and performers) together gen-erated $25 billion in output and sustained 167,000 jobs. California’s robust infrastruc-ture and critical mass of talent, supported by a variety of strong allied industries, have con-tributed to maintaining its supremacy.

But the state’s mantle is slipping. The high costs of living and doing business have prompted producers to look elsewhere. Pro-ducers are finding it more cost-effective to

film in other locations, despite the fact that most of the industry talent lives in California. Smaller films made for limited release are rarely filmed in California, and even large-budget films have achieved significant savings by going out of state – or out of the country.

Forty-one other states and the District of Columbia are currently vying for a piece of the $57 billion United States film-production industry by offering tax incentives. New York, North Carolina, Louisiana and New Mexico have all made significant inroads in attracting this commerce, and Georgia is coming on strong. Although other locations, including Michigan, have been aggressive in providing tax breaks and other incentives to film locally, the four states mentioned above have now built a true critical mass of production and post-production activity that can sustain on-going work, rather than just landing one-shot projects. New York, in particular, has the built-in appeal of being a hub of the enter-tainment industry and a major cultural capi-tal, with a strong concentration of television, radio and theater talent.

Competition, moreover, does not come just from inside the United States. Many other

shot in studios in Burbank to cutting-edge

special effects and animation conjured up by digital artists in the San Francisco Bay

area, film and television production is a significant part of the California economy –

as well as a bedrock element of the state’s identity and image. But past dominance is

no guarantee of future prosperity.

From programming

Kevi n Klowden is a managing economist at the Milken institute, where he serves as director of the institute’s California Center. An usuyA ChAtterj ee and CAn diCe Flor hyn eK are senior research analysts in the institute’s regional economics group.

b y k e v i n k l o w d e n , a n u s u ya c h at t e r j e e a n d c a n d i c e f l o r h y n e k

i n s t i t u t e v i e w

Page 93: Milken Institute Review Q4

91Fourth Quarter 2010

©as

p/kl

/age

fot

osto

ck

countries have long had successful local film industries. But thanks to Hollywood’s vast marketing reach and superior filmmaking technology, most film-based revenue has his-torically been captured by the United States. However, the size of the pie that’s up for grabs has prompted several countries to intensify their effort to lure American productions to augment their indigenous film industries.

Countries vying for a piece of the Ameri-can-based industry include Canada, Australia, New Zealand, Britain, Germany and India. A

combination of financial incentives and the existence of the quality infrastructure that had already been established for their own national movie and television industries have made them increasingly successful in landing American productions.

Canada, where film production is a lead-ing industry, is the most striking example. Film contributed nearly $8 billion (U.S.) to Canada’s economy in 2008. Vancouver, Mon-treal and Toronto are now considered top lo-cations for filming, approaching the caliber

Page 94: Milken Institute Review Q4

92 The Milken Institute Review

of Los Angeles and New York.Although Canada had been home to the

occasional film and television production in the 1970s and 1980s, the industry really took off in the late 1990s. Canada’s concerted push also coincided with a period of favorable ex-change rates against the American dollar, which made Canada a relatively cheap place to do business in general. But the key to Can-ada’s ongoing success has been a potent com-bination of financial incentives, lower labor costs, skilled English-speaking workers and short flying time to the United States.

After 2002, Canada found itself faced with increased competition from a number of lo-calities in the United States that adopted their own financial incentives and launched aggres-sive marketing campaigns. Its provinces re-sponded both by introducing a second layer of incentives on top of those offered by the federal government, and by bolstering their local infrastructure. Vancouver’s capabilities are now so sophisticated that the city has be-come the main center for television filming in North America outside of Los Angeles and New York.

As noted, California still leads the nation in production, turning out 160 films in 2008. It’s worth considering, though, that the num-ber of movies either wholly or partially filmed in California has fallen sharply: 272 were made in the state in 2000.

Employment in California’s movie and video industry (encompassing production, post-production and independent artists) reached its peak in 1997. The state’s share of North American employment in the industry has since declined from 40 percent (1997) to 37.4 percent (2008). Our research concludes that if California had managed to retain the 40 percent share it once enjoyed, some 10,600 jobs, paying an average wage of about $92,000, would have been preserved.

California has acknowledged the drain, and in July 2009, introduced a tax credit for projects filmed in state with budgets of $75

million or less. The credit is designed to offset lower costs (and government subsidies) of-fered elsewhere.

While this is a positive first step, it makes little sense to exclude big-budget films (which have the most impact on jobs and incomes) from the incentive program. This became ap-parent recently as filming got under way for the latest installment of the Transformers film franchise: While Los Angeles captured much of the production, it lost six weeks of shoot-ing to Michigan and Illinois, with producers citing the subsidies offered there. Due to its $200 million budget, this film did not qualify for tax credits in California.

An onerous permit process, increased re-strictions and city-imposed moratoriums on location filming driven by residents’ com-plaints, along with a lack of highly functional

An onerous permit process, increased restrictions

and city-imposed moratoriums on location filming

driven by residents’ complaints, along with a lack

of highly functional industrial space, are further

eroding California’s appeal to filmmakers.

i n s t i t u t e v i e w

Page 95: Milken Institute Review Q4

93Fourth Quarter 2010

industrial space, are further eroding Califor-nia’s appeal to filmmakers. Faced with rising costs, increased competition, lower profits, and, in the case of some publicly traded com-panies, increased pressure from shareholders, executives of studios in the United States have had to find innovative ways to cut costs. A growing number of states and foreign coun-tries are courting these producers with com-petitive tax breaks, even establishing offices in Los Angeles to market themselves.

The places most successful in attracting filmmakers offer incentives with less restric-tive qualification criteria. And they have been able to adopt innovative policies to ensure the availability of high-quality infrastructure and labor, cut the red tape in getting permits, provide adequate security and address local concerns about noise, traffic and other issues.

Data from FilmL.A., a nonprofit organiza-tion that coordinates permits for on-location shooting, shows a strong increase in produc-tion days in Los Angeles for the first two quarters of 2010, which the group largely at-tributes to the new state incentives. While this is an early positive sign, the battle isn’t won yet. We conclude that to expand film and tele-vision production, California will also need to take the following steps:

track film production data more effectively to determine how many days of production are spent within the state versus other loca-tions, along with the utilization rates of stu-dio soundstages and similar facilities.

Create a balanced two-tier film incentive program, with one set of benefits to engage big-budget studio films that are not covered under the current incentive program and an-other to attract smaller independent produc-tions, including those intended for cable TV.

expand the current tax credit for television production to encompass network and pre-mium cable shows.

Make the tax incentive programs perma-nent, signaling a long-term commitment to retaining the industry.

Consider a new digital media tax credit to attract and retain developers of digital ani-mation, visual effects and video games.

encourage long-term investments in infra-structure by implementing tax credits for building or upgrading studio and post-pro-duction space.

improve the ability of local film commis-sions to coordinate with local authorities in expediting the film-permit process.

Create proactive marketing and outreach strategies to communicate new incentives and programs.

establish cooperative relationships with civic and industry leaders beyond the state’s borders to attract foreign-funded productions.

One route to implementing several of these recommendations would be to provide the California Film Commission (which is part of the state’s Business, Transportation & Housing Agency) with more staff and mar-keting resources. The commission could then take on the task of comprehensive data col-lection, establishing the capacity to monitor the health and development of a crucial in-dustry, and to gauge the effectiveness of pub-lic policy. Industry data is currently inconsis-tent and often incomplete – a problem that needs to be corrected, given the importance of film to the state’s economy.

In addition to measures carried out at the state level, some promising initial steps have recently been taken by the City of Los Angeles. It does not have its own tax-credit program, but the City Council did recently pass film-friendly initiatives to “keep Hollywood home.” The program extended the free use of city-owned buildings, added more access for film producers to city-owned parking spaces, del-egated the Department of Water and Power

Page 96: Milken Institute Review Q4

And the guy on the spine is...simon johnson, a macroeconomist who now teaches at MIT’s Sloan School of Business. Formerly the low-profile (but very competent) chief economist at the IMF, Johnson morphed from Clark Kent to the Superman of center-left economics – a

public intellectual in the same league as Paul Krugman – when he returned to academia in 2008. He is probably most famous for his

2009 article in The Atlantic Monthly. There, he explained how well-connected investment bankers had taken control of U.S. economic

policy in a “quiet coup” that culminated in the Great Recession. Today, it’s hard to surf the Web without bumping into his well-

reasoned arguments in defense of tougher regulation of the financial services industry, and in opposition to deficit hawks willing to risk the

economic recovery in order to put Washington’s fiscal house in order. For a proper dose of Johnsonomics, check out his blog, BaselineScenario

.com (written with James Kwak), his contributions to the Economix blog at The New York Times, or his book, Thirteen Bankers: The Wall Street

Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown (also with Kwak).

94 The Milken Institute Review

davi

d sm

ith

to install energy nodes around the city to ac-commodate filming equipment and reduce energy-related costs to filmmakers, and man-dated the creation of a film coordinator within the Recreation and Parks Department.

But Los Angeles could go further by giving the film industry an all-purpose ombudsman in city government. With one person installed in City Hall to serve as a liaison to FilmL.A., the city would be better able to cut through the bureaucracy to obtain filming permits from various city and county agencies.

* * *Given the state’s gaping budget deficit,

there is no denying that California can barely afford to provide tax breaks. But in this case,

it can’t afford not to. The state can’t squander opportunities to retain and add significant numbers of high-paying jobs. And the long-term payoff to be realized in shoring up a major industry far outweighs the short-term cost in revenues.

That said, the state should not attempt to match incentives from other locations that provide large upfront cash advances and un-sustainably large film credits. However, by providing somewhat more generous and more effectively targeted credits that lower the cost of production to a reasonably com-petitive level, California will position itself to win over producers based on its strengths in human capital and facilities, as well as its rep-utation for excellence. m

i n s t i t u t e v i e w

Page 97: Milken Institute Review Q4

95Fourth Quarter 2010

i n s t i t u t e n e w s

california dreamin’California may be down, victim to its failure to confront its daunting economic and social problems. But we think the Golden State is far from out of the running as the place where dreams can be realized. The Milken Institute’s California Center is building a library of ideas from leaders across the state on how to get California back in the game. Videos, along with an interactive idea slate can be found at www.californiaspromise.org. The contents will be a focus of our annual State of the State Conference, held October 19 at the Beverly Hilton in Los Angeles. For more on the con-ference (including how to attend if you are reading this before 10/19), visit www.milken-institute.org/sos2010.

the show must go on Everybody wants to be a star these days. Cal-ifornia now competes with 41 states and a gaggle of other countries for a piece of the action in the $57-billion U.S. film production industry. And the battle has been bloody: The Milken Institute’s report, “Film Flight: Lost Production and Its Economic Impact on California,” found that California has lost 10,600 entertainment industry jobs, $2.4 bil-lion in wages and $4.2 billion in total eco-nomic output since 1997. Additional changes to the state’s financial incentives, plus a healthy dose of cooperation from local governments, could make a big difference. Download the full report at no cost from www.milkeninsti-tute.org, or read a synopsis on page 90 of this issue.

something completely differentFor the bad news on the U.S. econ-omy, just keep turning that dial. For his part, Ross DeVol, executive di-rector of economic research at the Insti-tute, takes issue with conventional wisdom. In “From Recession to Recovery: Analyzing Am erica’s Return to Growth” (download free at www.milkeninsti-tute.org), he sees a light at the end of the tun-nel, citing positive upticks in business equip-ment and software, low interest rates and growing exports. Or read the highlights, pub-lished in The Wall Street Journal (online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748703995104575389041193020822.html).

partnering for curesFasterCures, the DC-based medical solutions center of the Milken Institute, is convening the second annual Partnering for Cures meet-ing December 13-15 in New York City. Join research leaders, policymakers and advocates from a host of public and private organiza-tions in their quest for ways to expedite med-ical R&D. For more about the program and the opportunity to register, go to www.part-neringforcures.org.

Ross C. DeVol

From Recession to Recovery

Analyzing America’s Return to Growth

July 2010

Page 98: Milken Institute Review Q4

96

l i s t s

MMedicare is rightly considered the monster most likely to chew through the federal bud-

get in coming decades. But Social Security will soon be in need of beaucoup bucks, too.

If Congress does nothing, the difference between the system’s revenues and its outlays

will top $1 trillion annually around 2050.

But, unlike Medicare, the Social Security deficit could be tamed (for a long while,

anyway) with increases in revenues or cuts in benefits totaling a relatively modest 1.6

percent of predicted GDP over the next 75 years. Consider some options:

OptiOn AppROXiMAtE%OfGApClOsEd

Increase payroll tax by one percentage point (starting in 2012) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .50%Eliminate the $106,000 cap on taxable wages (starting in 2012) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 100%Cut initial benefits to offset the cost of rising life expectancy (starting in 2017) . . . . . . . . . .33%Raise age for full retirement benefits from 67 to 70 (starting in 2022) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .50%Index full retirement age to longevity (starting in 2012) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .33%Reduce cost-of-living benefit adjustments by V percentage point (starting in 2012) . . . .50%

source: Congressional Budget Office (2010)

BudgetBuster

©im

ages

.com

/cor

bis

Page 99: Milken Institute Review Q4

the milken instituteMichael L. Klowden, President and CEO

Michael Milken, Chairman

publisherJoel Kurtzman

editor in chiefPeter Passell

art directorJoannah Ralston, Insight Design

www.insightdesignvt.com

design assistanceLinda Provost

managing editorLarry Yu

ISSN 1523-4282

Copyright 2010

The Milken Institute

Santa Monica, California

The Milken Institute Review is published

quarterly by the Milken Institute to

encourage discussion of current issues

of public policy relating to economic

growth, job creation and capital formation.

Topics and authors are selected to represent

a diversity of views. The opinions expressed

are solely those of the authors and do not

necessarily represent the views of the Institute.

Requests for additional copies should be sent directly to:

The Milken Institute

The Milken Institute Review

1250 Fourth Street, Second Floor

Santa Monica, CA 90401-1353

310-570-4600 telephone

310-570-4627 fax

[email protected]

www.milkeninstitute.org

Cover: JT Morrow

the milken institute review advisory boardRobert J. Barro

Gary S. Becker

Jagdish Bhagwati

George J. Borjas

Daniel J. Dudek

Georges de Menil

Claudia D. Goldin

Robert Hahn

Robert E. Litan

Burton G. Malkiel

Van Doorn Ooms

Paul R. Portney

Stephen Ross

Isabel Sawhill

Richard Sandor

Morton O. Schapiro

John B. Shoven

Robert Solow

The Milken Institute Review • Fourth Quarter 2010

volume 12, number 4

Today’s volatile markets and complex

challenges demand innovative thinking.

That’s exactly what you’ll find at the 2011

Milken Institute Global Conference, where

international leaders tackle the biggest

challenges in energy, finance, philanthropy,

health, government and education.

With renowned speakers and an influential

audience, Global Conference sells out every

year. Tickets are in short supply, but the

wisdom you’ll gain is unlimited.

Register today at

www.milkeninstitute.org

Insightful Inspiring Indispensable

2011May 2–4, 2011 • Los Angeles

Page 100: Milken Institute Review Q4

Fourth Quarter 2010

The M

ilken In

stitute Review • Fou

rth Q

uarter 2010 • volume 12, n

umber 4

$16.00

matin qaim On genetically engineered crops.

Progress can be scary.

robert looney On North Korea’s economy.

Truth really is stranger than fiction.

larry white On housing markets.

First, we kill the subsidies.

chris meissner On reviving the gold standard.

It never worked very well, anyway.

howard kunreuther and erwann michel-kerjan

On making economic sense of disasters. The rising cost of myopia.

gary libecap On water shortages in the American West.

Getting serious about free markets.

kevin klowden, anusuya chatterjee and candice flor hynek

On the flight from Hollywood. Money trumps location.

In this issue

GMO: Sorceror’s apprentice or savior?

GMO: Sorceror’s apprentice or savior?