montalvo - general wisdom concerning 2008

Upload: nemanja-brkic

Post on 04-Jun-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/13/2019 Montalvo - General wisdom concerning 2008

    1/7

    General wisdom concerning the factors affecting the adoptionof cleaner technologies: a survey 1990e2007

    Carlos Montalvo*

    TNO Netherlands Organisation for Applied Scientific Research, Schoemakerstraat 97, P.O. Box 6030, 2600 JA Delft, The Netherlands

    Available online 26 November 2007

    Abstract

    Cleaner technologies (CT) have recently received much attention in diverse media and policy agendas. This comes out of the clear role they

    play in environmental protection and sustainability and the large potential to contribute to economic growth and competitiveness. The realization

    of both potentials depends on the level diffusion and exploitation achieved, today very low. This article presents a selective survey of papers that

    today represent the general wisdom concerning the factors affecting adoption as a primary condition to diffusion and exploitation of CT. The

    paper helps to clarify the challenges facing diffusion modelers and policy makers when dealing with policy design, assessing the levels of dif-

    fusion achieved as well as the factors affecting diffusion of a particular technology. The paper ends outlining further research need in the field.

    2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    Keywords: Technology adoption; Technology diffusion; Diffusion modeling; Technology policy; Environmental policy

    1. Introduction

    During the first years of the of the 21st century the attention

    given to the state of the environment e at both local and global

    level e has increased dramatically compared to concern in the

    last years of the 20th century. We are seeing not only popular,

    commercial films,1 but also national governments enacting

    policy directed to increasing awareness of issues, such as sys-

    temic pollution and climate change[1].2 It is only in the most

    recent years that governments have been regarding technolog-

    ical innovation as the solution to the challenge of environmen-

    tal degradation and a way of boosting the competitiveness of

    national economies[2,3]. Seeing technological innovation asthe main means of providing environmental sustainability

    presents two major policy issues. The first concerns the fact

    that despite the raised awareness of the environmental

    problems caused by production and consumption patternsthere is little acceptance that the current technological stock

    presents serious anomalies in terms of infringement of the ba-

    sic laws of thermodynamics, anomalies that extend to the new,

    so-called alternative technologies (e.g., photovoltaic cells, fuel

    cells, bio-fuels, etc.)[4,5]. The second issue relates to the myr-

    iad factors affecting the diffusion of new cleaner technologies

    and how these factors interact, which requires appropriate policy

    mixes in order to minimise negative synergies and conflicts.

    Often potentially relevant factors related to the adoption of

    new technologies have not been included in the analysis. The

    factors may differ between sectors but this has not been system-

    atically studied. Often the study focuses on one industry. Thislimits generalisations and insights for policy.

    In this paper, we address this second issue in an attempt to

    make the adoption of new technologies by individual users,

    and their diffusion across the economy, more transparent by

    showing the dependency between the various factors involved

    and their likely interrelation. The paper makes clear the diffi-

    culty to generate a dynamic diffusion model that includes all

    the relevant variables. The objective is to highlight the chal-

    lenge involved in generating policies that promote the diffu-

    sion of cleaner technologies at the aggregated level. If

    * Tel.: 31 15 269 5490.

    E-mail address: [email protected] See movie e An inconvenient truth http://www.climatecrisis.net/ and

    moviee The 11th hourhttp://wip.warnerbros.com/.2 See Environmental Knowledge Hub, http://ekh.unep.org/?q node/2042,

    visited 10.09.2007.

    0959-6526/$ - see front matter 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    doi:10.1016/j.jclepro.2007.10.002

    Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

    Journal of Cleaner Production 16S1 (2008) S7eS13www.elsevier.com/locate/jclepro

    mailto:[email protected]://www.climatecrisis.net/http://wip.warnerbros.com/http://ekh.unep.org/?q=node/2042http://ekh.unep.org/?q=node/2042http://ekh.unep.org/?q=node/2042http://ekh.unep.org/?q=node/2042http://www.elsevier.com/locate/jcleprohttp://www.elsevier.com/locate/jcleprohttp://ekh.unep.org/?q=node/2042http://wip.warnerbros.com/http://www.climatecrisis.net/mailto:[email protected]
  • 8/13/2019 Montalvo - General wisdom concerning 2008

    2/7

    diffusion is the outcome of the micro-decisions influenced by

    micro-, meso- and macro-contexts[6,7], in order to understand

    the diffusion process, we must ask what are the relevant adop-

    tion variables (stimuli, facilitating factors and barriers) and

    what changes in the adoption environment will induce firms

    to adopt an innovation at a particular moment in time? In other

    words, what drives or hampers the diffusion of innovations incleaner production at firm level?

    A number of authors have contributed to the debate over the

    barriers and drivers to innovation in cleaner technologies that

    has taken place in the last decade. However, despite this in-

    creased interest from scholars and policy-makers little system-

    atic and comprehensive work linking the drivers and barriers to

    actual adoption at firm level (see e.g., Ref.[8]) and diffusion at

    sector level (see e.g., Ref. [9]) has been done. These authors

    established causality links and explored the interactions be-

    tween drivers in order to prioritise and focus policy efforts to

    promote innovation in firms; however, they offer no insights

    about how to link adoption decisions to technology diffusion

    curves at sector level. The approach of Van Wijk et al. [9]pres-ents a similar structure (or clustering of drivers and barriers)

    focusing on the exploration of barriers at sector level. This ap-

    proach has not been validated; it does not explore interactions

    between drivers, but offers methodological insights about how

    to link drivers and barriers to diffusion patterns. Interactions

    between (clusters of) drivers are examined in Montalvo et al.

    [10], which empirically validated a model to explore and deter-

    mine the factors that could influence innovation in cleaner

    technologies at firm level, in the European context.

    This review follows the approach in Montalvo [11], which

    classifies factors affecting innovations in cleaner technologies

    at firm level. These are organisedalong the following dimensions:government policy, economics, markets, communities and social

    pressure, attitudes and social values, technological opportunities

    and technological capabilities and organisational capabilities.

    The structure of the present paper follows this classification.

    The survey shows some degree of overlap between the factors

    affecting the adoption of cleaner technologies at firm level.

    2. Public policy

    The literature on environmental policy recognises that one

    of the major drivers of environmentally responsible behaviour

    in industry is the intervention of public policy in the form of en-

    vironmental policy and enforcement of regulations, (e.g., Refs.

    [12e20]). The application of government policies has ranged

    from direct command-and-control to voluntary programmes

    to economic instruments [21,22]. The last traditionally includes

    charges and taxes, emission charges, user charges, product

    charges or taxes, administrative charges or fees, subsidies, de-

    positerefund schemes, marketable permit arrangements, finan-

    cial enforcement incentives or financial assistance [22].

    Economic instruments generally have been associated with

    standards limiting the amount of residuals or hazardous waste

    released to the environment through end-of-pipe technologies

    or waste management practices. There is no doubt that pollu-

    tion control has brought environmental improvements and

    that enforcement of the regulations has been the main means

    through which they have been achieved. This, and the fact

    that regulation in relation to technical change is frequently

    mentioned in the literature, can be misleading in the context

    of clean technologies (i.e., prevention of residuals and waste

    creation through organisational and technical change).

    Government intervention under the traditional policy ap-proaches mentioned above has not been successful in promot-

    ing pollution prevention at source[23e29]. This is commonly

    acknowledged at government level. It is also accepted that the

    way in which environmental policies have been designed and

    enforced does not particularly favour the development and

    adoption of cleaner technologies in industry (e.g., Refs.

    [30e33]). One of the main reasons for this is that emissions

    and discharge rate standards provide little or no incentive to

    go beyond the required standard reduction and, thus, they

    fail to promote and sustain research and development (R&D)

    and investment in innovation. Regulations might produce in-

    centives for firms to pre-empt future changes in regulations,

    stricter standards[20,34,35]or future liabilities[36], but expe-rience shows that they do little to promote and encourage

    development of continuous environmental performance im-

    provement through innovation.

    Innovation in products and processes aimed at reducing

    pollution at source are generally regarded as being one way to

    improve not only aspects of product and process performance,

    but also economic efficiency and competitiveness (e.g., Refs.

    [37,18,19,38]). It is also now received wisdom that technologi-

    cal change is critical to achieving long-term and cost-effective

    solutions to the environmental problems generated by industry

    (e.g., Refs.[39e45,20,32]). If innovation in cleaner technolo-

    gies brings so many benefits why is that covenants, eco-label-ling, intellectual property protection, eco-taxes, international

    agreements and law, etc., have had such limited success in pro-

    moting innovation? To date, there are no clear trends in the

    types of relationships among diffusion of cleaner technology

    and the levels and forms of public intervention [8,2].

    What about the effects of policies based on the notion of

    Best Available Techniques (BATs) such as the European Inte-

    grated Pollution Prevention and Control Directive (96/61/EC)?

    Unlike pollution control best available technologies and tech-

    niques are sector specific, which requires sector and possibly

    plant specific knowledge. This poses large and perhaps unreal-

    istic knowledge demands on authorities trying to regulate

    cleaner production [46]. This represents a major challenge

    for the regulatory authorities and government policy as the

    current regulatory schemes are designed to promote yester-

    days technologies. Furthermore, it has been argued that

    current regulations will gradually become obsolete and coun-

    terproductive, and unable to induce process embedded innova-

    tion[47]. Thus, the impact of regulation could be negative if

    the conditions required to apply certain schemes are not appro-

    priate. Conversely, if government intervention takes the form

    of providing the right conditions and stimuli for firms to

    change we could expect a positive relationship between regu-

    lation and the level of diffusion of cleaner technologies. The

    next sections provide some insights into other possible factors

    S8 C. Montalvo / Journal of Cleaner Production 16S1 (2008) S7eS13

  • 8/13/2019 Montalvo - General wisdom concerning 2008

    3/7

  • 8/13/2019 Montalvo - General wisdom concerning 2008

    4/7

    Experience has shown that external stakeholders play an

    important role in promoting sound environmental behaviour.

    In general, it seems that local communities are concerned

    not only about the environment but also about human health

    have in the past been strict watchdogs and are continuing

    to fulfil this function [51,74]. More broadly public pressure

    and demands from consumer groups, NGOs and the politicalGreen Parties are all promoters of environmental protection

    (e.g., Refs. [72,9,36,51,34,75,76,55]). It is important to men-

    tion that there is little empirical evidence concerning the

    role played by the various stakeholders in the promotion of

    cleaner production specifically. Huhtala [33]pointed out that

    one factor restricting a more decisive participation of diverse

    stakeholders (for example, in the financing community) is

    the lack of a clear understanding of what the concept of

    cleaner production entails and encompasses. In terms of the re-

    lationship between diffusion of cleaner production and the role

    of local and international communities and social pressure it is

    clear that we can expect this to be positive. The stronger the

    social demand for clean production the stronger the likelihoodthat diffusion will occur.

    6. Attitudes and social values

    Peoples attitudes have been defined as the predisposition to

    act based on the assessment of possible outcomes [77]. Simi-

    larly, social values have been seen as the criteria against which

    people justify their actions[78]. By their mere definition both

    concepts have the potential to play an important role in leading

    firms and industry to embrace innovation in cleaner technolo-

    gies. Positive attitudes are likely to arise from the perceived or

    expected good environmental and societal outcomes arisingfrom the adoption and diffusion of cleaner technologies. The

    literature linking attitudes and social values in decision-

    makers in industry is vast. Generally, it is believed that sus-

    tainable entrepreneurship lies mainly in the personality, ethos

    and position of high-ranking official and CEOs (e.g., Refs.

    [34,51,58,79e81]). Such entrepreneurship is believed to arise

    from an awareness of the salient environmental issues

    [82,46,50]and the perceived potential of cleaner technologies

    to abate risk and environmental impacts [71,83].

    All these factors are supposed to have the potential to influ-

    ence the predisposition of decision-makers in firms. This im-

    plies that the conduct and commitment of top management

    to cleaner production are of great relevance to the diffusion

    of cleaner technologies [52]. As attitudes change, based on

    the potential outcomes of the adoption and diffusion of cleaner

    technologies, it is likely that there will be a stronger relation-

    ship between the perceived economic benefits and the risks

    that investment in new technologies might entail for firms.

    Therefore, based on the above discussion, we can expect to

    find a positive relationship between the attitudes of decision-

    makers in industry and the level of adoption in individual

    sectors.

    A very positive attitude will indicate that there are condi-

    tions e within the firm and in its general context e promoting

    the diffusion of cleaner technologies. It should be noted also

    that a firm might have strong motivations (arising from gov-

    ernment policies, markets, economic opportunities, etc.) for

    pushing for the diffusion of cleaner production but still might

    not adopt new technologies, in either the short-term or the

    long-term.

    In the next section we try to provide some insight into the

    origins of such a dissonance between drivers, firm commit-ment and willingness to engage in cleaner production and final

    adoption of new technologies at firm level and diffusion at

    sector level.

    7. Technological opportunities and capabilities

    As mentioned above despite strong forces to induce industry

    to adopt new cleaner technologies, diffusion might advance at

    a very slow pace or not at all. This could be explained by the

    capacity at the industry level to innovate and to change. Factors

    mentioned in the literature explaining the capacity of a sector

    to change include the following. At a high level of aggregation

    there is dominance of specific technological paradigms andregimes bringing systemic technological path dependency

    [68]. The cost of replacing a complete production process in

    sectors, such as iron and steel, cement, and pulp and paper, is

    extremely high. Due to the size of investments and longevity

    of production processes it is very likely that the diffusion of

    new processes will occur in an incremental way [53,84,60].

    There are similar problems in the decommissioning of current

    stocks of artefacts and equipment at user and consumer levels

    (e.g., cars, fridges, electronic appliances, etc.).

    Closely linked to the above is the stock of technological op-

    portunities of cleaner technologies that is available. The level

    of awareness of the existence of such technological opportuni-ties and the degree of techno-economic attractiveness (i.e., ef-

    ficiency, quality, cost reductions, increased environmental

    performance, etc.) related to the natural cycle of technological

    stock replacement could be expected to play an important role

    in their uptake[62,82,51,20,34,85].

    Closely related to these technological opportunities are the

    firm and sector level capabilities needed to actually adopt new

    technologies[56,44,86,8]. It has been reported that insufficient

    availability of expertise in clean production (eco-design)[52],

    the current training and clean technology capacity building at

    the sector level[62,33]and the insufficient understanding and

    experience in cleaner production project development and im-

    plementation[63], play a role in the adoption of new cleaner

    production processes. These factors can be expected to be-

    come even more critical at the level of small- and medium-

    sized enterprises, where the firm strategy is frequently

    a one-man show and there is little R&D activity [46].

    Finally, firms face the challenge of technological risk [8].

    The gains promised by new technologies have yet to material-

    ise, a situation that contrasts strongly with the perceived reli-

    ability of current, familiar operating processes. In the literature

    on technology management it has been established that adop-

    tion or development of new production processes implies the

    capacity to integrate new knowledge and large organisational

    change[83].

    S10 C. Montalvo / Journal of Cleaner Production 16S1 (2008) S7eS13

  • 8/13/2019 Montalvo - General wisdom concerning 2008

    5/7

    8. Organisational capabilities

    Organisational capabilities refer to the firms endowments

    and capabilities to carry out innovation [84]. These include

    the level of knowledge and expertise in the specific new tech-

    nology[34,83]. The level of expertise might range from the

    presence of abilities to purchase the appropriate machineryand equipment [33] to their operation and maintenance.

    When the knowledge is not present in the firm adoption will

    depend on the firms capacity to overcome skill lock-in, and

    to unlearn and acquire new skills [86,66,60]. Conducting

    and promoting organisational change involves the principale

    agent problem. That is, committed CEOs must have a high de-

    gree of self-efficacy and leadership, not only to sell the notion

    to shareholders but also to orchestrate behavioural change at

    shop floor level [79,8].

    Another aspect related to the firms capabilities is the ca-

    pacity to engage in fruitful relationships across the production

    chain and among end-users and suppliers. The capacity to out-

    source new knowledge through collaboration with suppliers,and end-user involvement, has received wide attention in the

    literature [57,90,82,51,83,90]. Such collaborations at inter-

    firm level have been reported to be problematic in terms of

    threats to technology secrecy [46]. Finally, closely related to

    collaboration amongst firms is the notion of inter- and intra-

    trade across the supply chain and its inherent power relations.

    The capacity to engage with and influence suppliers of tech-

    nology, materials and inputs has been reported as a strong de-

    terminant of innovation. This is especially the case in

    industrial sectors close to large retail chains [91,61,82].

    From the discussion on capabilities we can expect to find

    positive relationships between the levels of technological op-portunities, and technological and organisational capabilities

    in firms, and the degree of cleaner technology adoption in

    firms and diffusion at sector level. We can expect a negative

    relationship between technological factors and perceived eco-

    nomic benefits and risks at firm level. Similarly, because

    a higher degree of control over the innovation process would

    reduce the level of technological risk and increase the chances

    of success, we can expect a positive relationship between tech-

    nological and green organisational factors and attitudes at the

    decision-making level.

    9. Remarks

    The factors affecting the uptake of cleaner technology pre-

    sented above are in line with the literature in the period 1993e

    2007. These factors are generic to all economic activities with

    the particularity that in the studies reported the unit of analysis

    has primarily been the firm, i.e., the analyses are at the micro-

    economic level. Most of the factors identified in the empirical

    literature could be drivers and barriers to innovation depend-

    ing on the circumstances, time and contexts in which they

    are considered. For example, regulatory frameworks are gener-

    ally seen as one of the main drivers of environmental technol-

    ogy adoption in industry in recent years. At the policy level it

    is being acknowledged that regulation based on prescriptions

    of technology rather than on environmental performance slows

    or hampers innovation related to radical innovation or changes

    in the production process. Similarly, the role of consumers is

    considered an important driver of innovation. On the one

    hand, consumer demands for environmentally friendly prod-

    ucts can be a strong driver. On the other hand, if a firm per-

    ceives that consumers have little willingness to pay for moreexpensive products, this might deter it from investing in

    cleaner technologies. The signals from the market must be

    the right ones.

    The large number of factors surveyed above and barriers

    and drivers identified, make the feasibility of modelling the

    decision to adopt in a dynamic fashion, a rather complex

    task. Most diffusion modelling exercises are conducted with

    a very few variables to describe the system being considered.

    The technology diffusion literature has for long been divided

    between two streams of research: those looking at the patterns

    of diffusion using as a backbone a logistic model or other ep-

    idemic model, and those looking at the structure and process

    of adoption decision-making. One of the big challenges of dif-fusion research is to unify both strands of research in a coher-

    ent model. The results of trying to deal with the two types of

    data in these different strands of research are problematic. The

    data are different in nature; the data drawn on to look at diffu-

    sion patterns consist of revealed preferences (levels of sales,

    investment levels, installed equipment, market penetration,

    etc.) e so-called hard data. The stream looking at the decision

    to adopt bases its quantitative analyses on expressed prefer-

    ences (opinions, judgements, rating and ranking, etc.) e so-

    called soft data. The problem of linking expressed preferences

    to actual technology adoption or investments in innovation has

    been solved recently[11,10], but the challenge of linking dif-fusion patterns requires further research and the availability of

    coupled longitudinal studies using both types of data remains

    a problem. Once such data and studies are available it should

    be possible to fully understand the patterns of technological

    diffusion and its origins.

    Acknowledgement

    This work was partly funded by the European Commission

    6th Framework Program. Contract no. SSPI-CT-2003-502487

    (Project POPA-CTDA).

    References

    [1] Morand F, Barzman M. European sustainable development policy

    (1972e2005): fostering a two-dimensional integration for more effective

    institutions. Working Paper (1), IDARI working paper, Eco Innovation

    (Galway, Ireland)/Humboldt University of Berlin, RTD project QLRT-

    2002-02718; 2006. p. 30.

    [2] EU COM stimulating technologies for sustainable development: an

    environmental technologies action plan for the European Union,

    COM(2004)138. Brussels: European Commission; 2004.

    [3] EU COM environment: commissioner Dimas sets out 2006 priorities

    building on momentum of landmark year 2005, Rapid Press Releases.

    Reference: IP/06/178, Date: 16/02/2006.

    [4] Georgescu-Roegen N. The entropy law and the economic process. Cam-

    bridge, MA: Harvard University Press; 1971.

    S11C. Montalvo / Journal of Cleaner Production 16S1 (2008) S7eS13

  • 8/13/2019 Montalvo - General wisdom concerning 2008

    6/7

    [5] Sartorius C. Second-order sustainabilitydconditions for the development

    of sustainable innovations in a dynamic environment. Ecological Eco-

    nomics 2006;58(2):268e86.

    [6] Metcalfe JS. The diffusion of innovations: an interpretative survey. In:

    Dosi G, Freeman C, Nelson R, Silverberg G, Soete L, editors. Technical

    change and economic theory. London and New York: Printer Publishers;

    1988. p. 560e89.

    [7] Rogers EM. Diffusion of innovations. New York: The Free Press; 1962.

    [8] Montalvo CC. Environmental policy and technological innovation: why

    do firms adopt or reject new technologies?. Cheltenham, U.K. and North-

    apton, MA: Edward Elgar; 2002.

    [9] Wijk JJvan, Engelen RFJM, Ros JPM. Model for effectiveness of policy

    instruments for the energy-saving in industry (MEI-Energy). Bilthoven:

    Dutch National Institute for Public Health and the Environment; 2001.

    RIVM Rapport 778011004.

    [10] Montalvo C, Sotoudeh M, Sartorius C, Stromberg D, Nemeskeri R, ten

    Brink P, et al. Policy pathways to promote eco-innovation I: assessment

    of barriers and drivers. Journal of Cleaner Production 2007. Special Issue

    on Cleaner Technology Diffusion.

    [11] Montalvo C. What triggers innovation and change? Technovation

    2006;26(3):312e23.

    [12] Battisti G. Innovations and the economics of new technology spreading

    within and across users: gaps and way forward. Journal of Cleaner Pro-

    duction 2008;16(1S1):22e31.

    [13] Luken R, van Rompaey F. Drivers and barriers to environmentally sound

    technology adoption by manufacturing plants in developing countries.

    Journal of Cleaner Production 2008;16(1S1):67e77.

    [14] Vig NJ, Kraft ME. Environmental policy in the 1990s. Washington DC:

    Congressional Quarterly Press; 1990.

    [15] Tietenberg TH. Environmental policy innovation. Aldershot: Edward

    Elgar; 1992.

    [16] Leveque F, editor. Environmental policy in Europe: industry, competition

    and the policy process. Cheltenham, UK and Brookfield, USA: Edward

    Elgar; 1996.

    [17] Garrod B, Chadwick P. Environmental management and business strat-

    egy: toward a new strategic paradigm. Futures 1996;28(1):37e49.

    [18] Howes R, Skea J, Whelan B. Clean and competitive? Motivating environ-

    mental performance in industry. London: Earthscan; 1996.[19] Langerak F, Peelen E, van der Veen M. Exploratory results on the ante-

    cedents and consequences of green marketing. Journal of Market Re-

    search Society 1998;40(4):323e35.

    [20] Clayton A, Spinardi G, Williams R. What shapes the implementation of

    cleaner technology?. In: Clayton A, Spinardi G, Williams R, editors.

    Policies for cleaner technology. London: Earthscan; 1999. p. 218e65.

    [21] Barde JP. Economic instruments in environmental policy: lessons from

    the OECD experience and their relevance to developing economies.

    Technical Papers No. 92. Paris: OECD Development Centre; 1994.

    [22] OECD. Economic instruments for environmental management in

    developing countries. Paris: OECD; 1993.

    [23] Rothwell R. Industrial innovation and government environmental

    regulations: some lessons from the past. Technovation 1992;12(7):

    447e58.

    [24] Irwin A, Hooper PD. Clean technology, successful innovation and thegreening of industry. Business Strategy and the Environment

    1992;1(2):1e12.

    [25] OTA. Green products by design. Washington, DC, USA: Office of

    Technology Assessment; 1992. OTAeEe541.

    [26] Jaffe AB, Palmer K. Environmental regulation and innovation: a panel

    data study. Review of Economics and Statistics 1997;79(4):610e9.

    [27] Kemp R. Environmental regulation and innovation: key issues and

    questions for research. Position paper for IPTS-DG III project Innova-

    tion and Regulation. MERIT/Maastricht University; 1998.

    [28] Sanchez CM, McKinley W. Environmental regulatory influence and

    product innovation: the contingency effects of organizational characteris-

    tics. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management 1998;15(4):

    257e78.

    [29] Granderson G. The impact of regulation on technical change. Southern

    Economic Journal 1999;65(4):807e

    22.

    [30] CSIS. The environmental protection system in transition. Washington,

    DC: Center for Strategic and International Studies, CSIS Press; 1997.

    [31] ELI. Barriers to environmental technology innovation and use. Washing-

    ton, DC: Environmental Law InstituteeEPA; 1998.

    [32] PCSD. Towards a sustainable America: advancing prosperity, opportu-

    nity and a healthy environment for the 21st century. Washington, DC:

    Presidents Council on Sustainable Development, US/Government Print-

    ing Office; 1999.

    [33] Huhtala A. Promoting financing of cleaner production investmentsdUNEP experience. Journal of Cleaner Production 2003;11(6):615e8.

    [34] Calleja I, Lindblom J, Wolf O. Clean technologies in Europe: diffusion

    and frontiers. The IPTS Report no. 69. Sevilla: JRCeIPTS; 2002.

    [35] Maxwell J, Rothenberg S, Briscoe F, Oye K. A comparison of environ-

    mental performance at US and Japanese automobile plants. Paper pre-

    sented at the GIN Conference, Santa Barbara, CA; 1997.

    [36] Dillon P, Baram MS. Forces shaping the development of product stew-

    ardship in the private sector. In: Fisher K, Schot J, editors. Environmental

    strategies for industry: international perspectives on research needs and

    policy implications. Washington, DC: Island Press; 1993. p. 329e42.

    [37] Porter ME, van der Linde C. Green and competitive: ending the stale-

    mate. Harvard Business Review 1995;70:73e93.

    [38] Norberg-Bohm V. Stimulating green technological innovation: an anal-

    ysisof alternative policy mechanisms. Policy Sciences 1999;32(1):13e38.

    [39] Fisher K, Schot J, editors. Environmental strategies for industry: interna-

    tional perspectives on research needs and policy implications. Washing-

    ton, DC: Island Press; 1993.

    [40] Kemp R. Technology andthe transitionto environmental sustainability: the

    problem of technological regime shifts. Futures 1994;26(10):1023e46.

    [41] Shrivastava P, Hart S. Creating sustainable corporations. Business Strat-

    egy and the Environment 1995;4:154e65.

    [42] Linnanen L, Bostrom T, Miettinen P. Life cycle management integrated

    approach: towards corporate environmental issues. Business Strategy and

    the Environment 1995;4:117e27.

    [43] OECD. Policies to promote technologies for cleaner production and

    products: guide for government self-assessment. Paris: OECD; 1995.

    [44] den Hond F. In search of a useful theory of environmental strategy: a case

    study on the recycling of end-of-life vehicles from the capabilities per-

    spective. Amsterdam: ML Brookman; 1996.[45] Fullerton D, Wu W. Policies for green design. Journal of Environmental

    Economics and Management 1998;36:131e48.

    [46] RathiAKA. Promotion of cleaner production for industrial pollution abate-

    mentin Gujarat (India).Journalof CleanerProduction2003;11(5):583e90.

    [47] Reijnders L. Policies influencing cleaner production: the role of prices

    and regulation. Journal of Cleaner Production 2003;11(3):333e8.

    [48] Dosi G. The nature of the innovative process. In: Dosi G, Freeman C,

    Nelson R, Silverberg G, Soete L, editors. Technical change and economic

    theory. London: Pinter Publishers; 1988. p. 221e38.

    [49] Kline SJ, Rosenberg J. An overview of innovation. In: Landau R,

    Rosenberg N, editors. The positive sum strategy. Washington, DC: Na-

    tional Academy Press; 1986.

    [50] Bhatnagar S, Cohen M. The impact of environmental regulation on inno-

    vation. Working paper. Vanderbilt: Owen Graduate School of Manage-

    ment; 1997.[51] Duffy N, Ryan B, Baas L, Boons F, Hansen OL, Spinardi G. Pharmaceu-

    tical sector. In: Clayton A, Spinardi G, Williams R, editors. Policies for

    cleaner technology. London: Earthscan; 1999. p. 107e29.

    [52] Tukker A, Haag E, Eder P. Eco-design: European state of the art. Part I:

    comparative analysis and conclusions. An ESTO project report prepared

    for the European Commission. Seville: Joint Research Centre e Institute

    for Prospective Technological Studies; 2000.

    [53] Schwarz HG. Technology diffusion in metal industries: driving forces

    and barriers in the German aluminium smelting sector. Journal of Cleaner

    Production 2008;16(1S1):37e49.

    [54] Baas L, Duffy N, Ryan B, Spinardi G, Williams R. Petrochemical sector.

    In: Clayton A, Spinardi G, Williams R, editors. Policies for cleaner tech-

    nology. London: Earthscan; 1999. p. 53e72.

    [55] Luukkanen J. Green paper with green electricity? Greening strategies of

    Nordic pulp and paper industry. Energy Policy 2003;31:641e

    55.

    S12 C. Montalvo / Journal of Cleaner Production 16S1 (2008) S7eS13

  • 8/13/2019 Montalvo - General wisdom concerning 2008

    7/7

    [56] Cagno E, Trucco P. Cleaner technology transfer in the Italian galvanic

    industry: economic and know-how issues. Journal of Cleaner Production

    2008;16(1S1):32e6.

    [57] Florida R. Lean and green: the move to environmentally conscious

    manufacturing. California Management Review 1996;39(1):80e105.

    [58] Steger U. The greening of the board room: how German companies are

    dealing with environmental issues. In: Fisher K, Schot J, editors. Environ-

    mental strategies for industry:internationalperspectives on research needs

    and policy implications. Washington, DC: Island Press; 1993. p. 63e78.

    [59] King A. Cooperative self-regulation in the chemical industry: impact and

    implications. Paper presented at the GIN Conference, Santa Barbara, CA;

    1997.

    [60] Murphy J, Gouldson A. Environmental policy and industrial innovation:

    integrating environment and economy through ecological modernization.

    Geoforum 2000;31:33e44.

    [61] Jurgen D, Holliday C. Innovation, technology, sustainability and society.

    World Business Council for Sustainable development. Hertfordshire:

    Earthprint; 2002.

    [62] Koefoed M, Buckley C. Clean technology transfer. A case study from the

    South African metal finishing industry, 2000e2004. Journal of Cleaner

    Production 2008;16(1S1):78e84.

    [63] Staniskis JK, Stasiskiene Z. Promotion of cleaner production invest-

    ments: international experience. Journal of Cleaner Production 2003;

    11:619e28.

    [64] Pearce DW, Turner RK. Economics of natural resources and the environ-

    ment. New York: Harvester Wheatsheaf; 1991.

    [65] Midgley DF, Dowling GR. A longitudinal study of product form innova-

    tion: the interaction between predispositions and social messages. Jour-

    nal of Consumer Research 1993;19:611e25.

    [66] Orsato R. The political ecology of organizations: a study of the greening

    of the European automobile industry. Paper presented at the GIN Confer-

    ence, Santa Barbara, CA; 1997.

    [67] Lenschow A. Greening of the European Union e are there lessons to be

    learned from international environmental policy? Global Environmental

    Change 2002;12:241e5.

    [68] Nill J. Diffusion as time-dependent result of technological evolution,

    competition, and policies: the case of cleaner iron and steel technologies.

    Journal of Cleaner Production 2008;16(1S1):58e

    66.[69] Zahra SA. Technology strategy and financial performance: examining the

    moderating role of the firms competitive environment. Journal of Busi-

    ness Venturing 1996;11:189e219.

    [70] Williams HE, Medhurst J, Drew K. Corporate strategies for a sustainable

    future. In: Fisher K, Schot J, editors. Environmental strategies for indus-

    try: international perspectives on research needs and policy implications.

    Washington, DC: Island Press; 1993. p. 117e46.

    [71] Montalvo C. Sustainable production and consumption systemsd

    cooperation for change: assessing and simulating the willingness of the

    firm to adopt/develop cleaner technologies. The case of the In-Bond indus-

    try in northern Mexico. Journal of Cleaner Production 2003;11:411e26.

    [72] Visser R, Jongen M, Zwetsloot G. Business-driven innovations towards

    more sustainable chemical products. Journal of Cleaner Production

    2008;16(1S1):85e94.

    [73] Morrison R. Sustainability and the role of financial institutions. Paper

    presented at the GIN Conference, Santa Barbara, CA; 1997.

    [74] Johnstone N, Karousakis K. Economic incentives to reduce pollution

    from road transport: the case for vehicle characteristic taxes. Transport

    Policy 1999;6:99e108.

    [75] Rondinelli D, Vastag G. International environmental standards and cor-

    porate policies. California Management Review 1996;39(1):106e22.

    [76] Hartman C, Stafford E. Green alliances: forging corporate e environ-

    mental group collaborative relationships. Paper presented at the GIN

    Conference, Santa Barbara, CA; 1997.

    [77] Ajzen I. The moderating effects of attitude in decision making. In:

    Gollwitzer PM, Bargh JA, editors. The psychology of action: linking cog-

    nition and motivation to behavior. New York: Guilford Press; 1996.

    [78] Schwartz SH, Bilsky W. Toward a theory of the universal content and

    structure of values: extensions and cross-cultural replications. Journal

    of Personality and Social Psychology 1990;58(5):878e91.

    [79] Everett M, Mark JE, Toward OR. Greening in the executive suite. In:

    Fisher K, Schot J, editors. Environmental strategies for industry: interna-

    tional perspectives on research needs and policy implications. Washing-

    ton, DC: Island Press; 1993. p. 68e78.

    [80] Albrecht J. Environmental issue entrepreneurship: a Schumpeterian per-

    spective. Futures 2002;34:649e61.

    [81] Andrews CJ. Environmental business strategy: corporate leaders percep-

    tions. Society and Natural Resources 1998;11:531e40.

    [82] Kerndrup S, Baas L, Nielsen U, Haas JS. Electroplating. In: Clayton A,

    Spinardi G, Williams R, editors. Policies for cleaner technology. London:

    Earthscan; 1999. p. 204e17.

    [83] Eder P. Expert inquiry on innovation options for cleaner production

    in the chemical industry. Journal of Cleaner Production 2003;11(4):

    347e64.

    [84] Kemp R. An economic analysis of cleaner technology: theory and evi-

    dence. In: Fisher K, Schot J, editors. Environmental strategies for indus-

    try: international perspectives on research needs and policy implications.

    Washington, DC: Island Press; 1993. p. 79e113.

    [85] Hart S, Ahuja G. Does it pay to be green? An empirical examination ofthe relationship between emission reduction and firm performance. Busi-

    ness Strategy and the Environment 1996;5:30e7.

    [86] Roome N. Business strategy, R&D management and environmental im-

    peratives. R&D Management 1994;24(1):65e82.

    [90] Van Dijken K, Prince Y, Wolters T, Frey M, Mussati G, Kalf P, et al.,

    editors. The adoption of environmental innovations by small and me-

    dium-sized enterprises. The dynamics of innovation as interplay between

    business competence, environmental orientation and network involve-

    ment. Dordrecht: Kluwer Academic Press; 1999.

    [91] Hall JK. Reducing environmental impacts through the procurement

    chain. Unpublished DPhil thesis. 1999, University of Sussex.

    S13C. Montalvo / Journal of Cleaner Production 16S1 (2008) S7eS13