new direct and spillover effects on health of increased income for … · 2019. 11. 26. · 1...

63
Direct and spillover effects on health of increased income for the elderly: evidence from a Chilean pension program * Enrico MiglinoNicolas Navarrete H.Gonzalo Navarrete H.Pablo Navarrete H.? Abstract We estimate the effect of a permanent income increase on health outcomes of the elderly poor and their relatives. Our regression discontinuity design exploits an eligibility cut-off in a Chilean basic pension programme that grants monthly payments to pensionless retirees. Using administrative data we find that, four years after applying, basic pension recipients are 2.5 percentage points less likely to die. We observe spillover effects on working-age relatives, who are more likely to have a newborn child. Results suggest that increasing the incomes of the elderly could reduce health inequalities across income groups and benefit younger relatives. Keywords: pension, elderly, spillover effects, mortality. JEL Classification: I14, I38, J14. * We thank the Chilean National Institute of Pensions and the Ministry of Health for the data provided. We also thank Cl´ ement de Chaisemartin, Sascha O. Becker, Dolores de la Mata, Gabriel Facchini and seminar participants at the University of Warwick, UCL, PSE, UAB, Universidad de Chile, Universidad Diego Portales, Universidad Al- berto Hurtado, and the Royal Economic Society for their useful comments. We would also like to thank Claudio Allende for his outstanding research assistance. The authors gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the De- velopment Bank of Latin America (CAF). Enrico Miglino: Department of Economics, University College London (email: [email protected]). Nicolas Navarrete H: Department of Economics, Paris School of Economics (email: [email protected]). Gonzalo Navarrete H: Department of Public Health, Universidad de Chile ([email protected]). ?Pablo Navarrete H: Department of Geography and Environ- ment, London School of Economics, and Center for Sutainable Urban Development, Pontificia Universidad Cat´ olica de Chile (email: [email protected]).

Upload: others

Post on 12-Oct-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Direct and spillover effects on health of increasedincome for the elderly: evidence from a Chilean pension

    program ∗

    Enrico Miglino† Nicolas Navarrete H.‡ Gonzalo Navarrete H.∓Pablo Navarrete H.?

    Abstract

    We estimate the effect of a permanent income increase on health outcomes of the elderly

    poor and their relatives. Our regression discontinuity design exploits an eligibility cut-off in a

    Chilean basic pension programme that grants monthly payments to pensionless retirees. Using

    administrative data we find that, four years after applying, basic pension recipients are 2.5

    percentage points less likely to die. We observe spillover effects on working-age relatives,

    who are more likely to have a newborn child. Results suggest that increasing the incomes of

    the elderly could reduce health inequalities across income groups and benefit younger relatives.

    Keywords: pension, elderly, spillover effects, mortality.JEL Classification: I14, I38, J14.

    ∗We thank the Chilean National Institute of Pensions and the Ministry of Health for the data provided. We alsothank Clément de Chaisemartin, Sascha O. Becker, Dolores de la Mata, Gabriel Facchini and seminar participantsat the University of Warwick, UCL, PSE, UAB, Universidad de Chile, Universidad Diego Portales, Universidad Al-berto Hurtado, and the Royal Economic Society for their useful comments. We would also like to thank ClaudioAllende for his outstanding research assistance. The authors gratefully acknowledge the financial support of the De-velopment Bank of Latin America (CAF). † Enrico Miglino: Department of Economics, University College London(email: [email protected]). ‡Nicolas Navarrete H: Department of Economics, Paris School ofEconomics (email: [email protected]). ∓Gonzalo Navarrete H: Department of Public Health,Universidad de Chile ([email protected]). ?Pablo Navarrete H: Department of Geography and Environ-ment, London School of Economics, and Center for Sutainable Urban Development, Pontificia Universidad Católicade Chile (email: [email protected]).

  • 1 Introduction

    In light of an ageing population, health inequalities amongst the elderly have received increased

    attention over the last two decades. Researchers and policymakers have documented large and

    ever-widening life expectancy inequalities across income groups in both developed and develop-

    ing countries [Hoffman, 2008; Brønnum-Hansen and Baadsgaard, 2012; Tarkiainen et al., 2012;

    OECD, 2017]. For instance, an OECD [2018] report shows that, at retirement age, high-income

    earners live longer than low-income earners: 1.6 years longer in the US, 3.6 in Chile, 3.25 in the

    UK, and 2.9 in South Korea.1

    Despite a large body of literature documenting that, at all ages, wealthier people live longer on

    average [Marmot, 2005; Braveman et al., 2010; Waldron, 2013; Chetty et al., 2016], substantial

    debate remains on whether an income increase in old age can partially reduce these life expectancy

    inequalities. It may be the case that unobserved characteristics, such as genetic factors, are able

    to explain both higher life expectancy and better health. Alternatively, better health in general,

    the underlying cause of higher life expectancy, could itself be the cause of higher income (reverse

    causality). Finally, differences in life expectancy may be the result of cumulative conditions related

    to income inequalities at earlier ages, such as different education levels or exposure to air pollution.

    The non-contributory pension programme in Chile provides an ideal regression discontinuity

    design (RDD) that allows us to identify the causal effect of a permanent income increase on the

    mortality rates of the elderly, and also on the number of days they spend hospitalised. Chile is

    a high-middle income country with a per-capita GDP (PPP) of US$24,644 in 2017,2 and a life

    expectancy at age 65 of 19.45 years (similar to the US).3 Since 2008, Chileans who are aged 65 or

    over and who do not have a contributory pension can apply to receive a non-contributory pension,

    which provides lifelong monthly payments of approximately 40 percent of the national minimum

    wage (basic pension). Upon receiving an application, the government calculates a specifically de-

    signed pension score and assigns a basic pension to applicants who fall below the 60th percentile

    (cut-off) of the score distribution.

    We obtained access to administrative information on the universe of basic pension applicants

    and their household members in 2011 and 2012, and matched it with their health history between

    1In the report, high-income earners are defined as those who earn more than three times the average wage andlow-income earners are defined as those who earn half of the average wage or less.

    2https://data.worldbank.org/indicator3https://data.oecd.org/healthstat/life-expectancy-at-65.htm

    2

    https://data.worldbank.org/indicator https://data.oecd.org/healthstat/life-expectancy-at-65.htm

  • 2011 and 2016.4 We first observed that the pool of applicants consists mostly of women without a

    regular employment history. As individuals can apply multiple times, we defined applicants whose

    first application score fell below the cut-off, and within a certain bandwidth, as our ‘treatment

    group’. Conversely, we defined applicants whose first application score was above the cut-off,

    and within a certain bandwidth, as our ‘control group’. We document that nearly all applicants

    in the treatment group obtained a basic pension, and that 18 percent of applicants in the control

    group submitted another application at a later time that was successful. Therefore, being in the

    treatment group increases the probability of receiving a basic pension within four years of the first

    application by 82 percent. We also show that density and balance tests cannot reject the hypothesis

    that the basic pension is as good as ‘locally’ randomly assigned between treatment and control

    group applicants. Following these findings, we implement a fuzzy regression discontinuity design

    to explore the causal effect of the pension on mortality and days of hospitalisation.

    We find that receiving a basic pension decreases the probability of dying within four years af-

    ter applying to the programme by 2.5 percentage points (pp.). This represents 33.8 percent fewer

    deaths for those who receive the pension. The decrease is statistically significant and remains

    unaffected when using nonparametric estimations, and different sets of controls, bandwidths, or

    polynomial orders. As the basic pension increases applicants’ income by 63.1 percent for those in

    the bandwidth, we are able to estimate a negative mortality-income elasticity of 0.54.

    A survival analysis shows that the effect on mortality becomes visible one year after the first

    payment and grows monotonically over time. Improvements in health outcomes appear to be driven

    by fewer acute incidents of circulatory and respiratory diseases associated with chronic conditions,

    such as heart attacks in patients with diabetes or acute respiratory problems in patients with se-

    vere asthma. We provide evidence suggesting that treatment group applicants spend their pension

    on goods that improve their overall health (e.g. nutritional food) and thus prevent acute medical

    episodes from occurring.5

    The heterogeneous analysis shows that applicants living alone or with only elderly household

    members are significantly less likely to die and spend fewer days hospitalised, while those living

    with working-age household members remain unaffected. An exploratory analysis suggests that

    the lack of effects for the latter might be explained by ‘crowding-out’ effects: there exist intra-4The programme did not systematically collect information on applicants and their household members prior to

    2011, making it unfeasible to conduct the analysis on earlier years.5In Chile, public health insurance grants free access to medical appointments, medication, and surgery for the

    most common diseases in the country. The coverage is almost universal amongst the elderly population without acontributory pension.

    3

  • household transfers of income from working-age household members to applicants in the absence

    of the pension, which then cease when applicants begin receiving the basic pension.

    We also document the presence of spillover effects on working age household members, who

    are 3.6 pp. more likely to have a newborn child nine months or later after the application was

    made. These results are also in line with the presence of ‘crowding-out’ effects that have been

    well-documented in the literature on government transfers [Cox and Jimenez, 1992; Jensen, 2003;

    Edmonds, 2006].

    Finally, we provide a ‘back-of-the-envelope’ computation showing that the basic pension may

    be able to correct around 29 percent of the life expectancy gap between the income group of treated

    applicants at the cut-off and the income group that they reach after receiving the basic pension. This

    suggests that a relevant part of life expectancy inequalities across income groups in old age are due

    to contemporaneous income inequalities.

    Our paper makes two main contributions. First, we provide causal evidence that a permanent

    income increase for the elderly can reduce their mortality rates at the present time. Salm [2011]

    finds that two pension increases that occurred in the early 1900s reduced the mortality rates of

    US veterans. This effect was driven by infectious diseases, decades before the medical revolu-

    tion of antibiotics [Hare, 1982]. Whether or not these results hold true a century later is unclear.

    Cheng et al. [2016] find that a Chinese rural pension scheme, which represents 12-17 percent of

    the average income per capita, leads to an insignificant reduction in mortality.6

    In contrast with these studies, Snyder and Evans [2006] estimate that a notch in US social secu-

    rity payments for the cohorts 1916-1917, which reduced the later cohort’s income by 4 percent on

    average, significantly reduced men’s mortality rates with respect to the wealthier cohort. They jus-

    tify this result by showing that the poorer cohort undertook more part-time work, suggesting that

    a later transition to retirement reduces social isolation and improves health. Feeney [2017, 2018]

    exploits the age eligibility cut-off and the staggered introduction of a Mexican non-contributory

    pension across small rural towns, finding that this pension increases recipients’ transition to re-

    tirement, consumption of ‘obesogenic’ food, and mortality rates; but reduces tobacco and alcohol

    consumption. Snyder and Evans’s and Feeney’s results can be reconciled with our findings, consid-

    6Lindahl [2005], Cesarini et al. [2016], and Schwandt [2018] show mixed results regarding the impact of increasesin wealth, such as lottery prizes, on mortality rates amongst the elderly. Jensen and Richter [2003] consider the effectof payment interruptions during the Russian pension crisis and found an increase in mortality. Although these studiesdo belong to a related literature, the effects of unexpected wealth increases or temporary income reductions might notmirror the effect of a permanent income increase guaranteed by the government.

    4

  • ering that the basic pension in Chile is given only to people without a regular employment history.

    Therefore, the Chilean basic pension does not cause a break from working routine that may prove

    detrimental to mental and physical health. Changes in consumption patterns when people exit the

    labour force could be relevant in explaining the different impacts found in this literature [Browning

    and Meghir, 1991; Zantinge et al., 2013].

    Our second contribution is to provide causal evidence that a permanent income increase for

    the elderly poor can have spillover effects on the fertility of working-age relatives. We are not

    aware of previous papers testing this directly using a regression discontinuity design and admin-

    istrative data. This result complements previous findings regarding the spillover benefits of non-

    contributory pensions on children’s height, weight, school enrolment, and attendance [Duflo, 2000,

    2003; Edmonds, 2006]; and on working-age relatives’ self-reported nutrition, sanitation, and em-

    ployment [Case, 2004; Case and Menendez, 2007; Ardington et al., 2009]. Finally, our discussion

    of ‘crowding-out’ effects suggests that the elderly poor can impose a financial burden on younger

    relatives. This could be one of the channels whereby poverty is transmitted across generations, and

    thus pension policies may have the potential to alleviate this transmission.

    The paper is organised as follows. Section 2 presents the basic pension programme and Sec-

    tion 3 describes the data used. Section 4 explains the empirical strategy and analyses the regression

    discontinuity validity. Section 5 presents the results, and Section 6 explores potential mechanisms.

    Section 7 presents our ‘back-of-the-envelope’ computation and Section 8 concludes.

    2 The basic pension

    Since 1980, Chile has had a fully funded individual capitalisation system, run by private pension

    fund companies, in which workers make monthly mandatory savings of 10 percent of their wage.

    Once retired, workers receive a pension that is dependent on the amount saved over the course

    of their working life (contributory pension). Until recently, those who had never undertaken paid

    work received no pension.

    During the 2005 presidential campaign, this pension system was judged to be particularly unfair

    to stay-at-home mothers, with their role being recognised as unpaid yet central to a fully function-

    ing society in Chile. As a result of this debate, most of the candidates, including future president

    Michelle Bachelet, agreed to grant a non-contributory government-funded pension to stay-at-home

    mothers in the poorest households.

    5

  • On March 11th, 2008, President Bachelet signed ACT 20255, which established that, not only

    stay-at-home mothers, but every citizen aged 65 or above with no retirement savings would be

    eligible for a pension consisting on lifelong monthly payments provided by the government (basic

    pension). The introduction of the basic pension took place across all of Chile simultaneously, and

    the first payments were delivered on July 1st, 2008. Between 2011 and 2016, our period of analysis,

    basic pension payments have been US$160 per month on average, which is equivalent to approx-

    imately 40 percent of the national minimum wage. This corresponds to a 63.1 percent increase in

    our treatment group’s income [OECD, 2011; Ministerio Trabajo y Previsión Social, 2011].7

    To obtain the basic pension, individuals must first apply to the Pension Institute (PI). The ap-

    plication process is free and involves filling in a form in the municipality where the applicant lives.

    Following the application, the PI calculates a pension score, specifically designed to assign the ba-

    sic pension. The pension score comprises two factors: household income from assets (e.g. contrib-

    utory pensions from household relatives) and labour income from all household members. Admin-

    istrative records show that these two factors account for 60 and 40 percent of total wealth, respec-

    tively. The pension score is then adjusted for household size and the number of disabled household

    members (for more details on the basic pension and score calculation, see Appendix Section A).

    To identify households, and compute the factors mentioned above, the PI follows the same

    definition of a household used by all Chilean government agencies: a group of people, whether

    relatives or not, who live in the same house and share income. Households are registered by the

    Ministry of Planning (MP). The MP ensures that every person belongs to one household only,

    and visits the residence of each household to verify that each registered person lives there. The

    household records are then provided to the PI, along with each person’s unique national identifier

    number, so that the PI can collect information about each household member and compute the

    factors affecting the pension score.

    The pension score uses a more comprehensive set of information, and is computed in a dif-

    ferent way, than other governmental indices such as the social security score.8 The pension score

    complements public agencies (e.g. Tax Service) and self-reported information, with administrative

    7To obtain applicants’ income, we divide each applicant’s household income by the number of household mem-bers. Household income per capita is equivalent to an applicant’s income under the assumption of perfect householdincome pooling. Every year, the government increases the basic pension payments to at least match inflation.

    8The social security score (“Puntaje de la Ficha de Protección Social”) is a proxy means test based on potentialand self-reported actual income, disability status, and household composition that allows the government to assignsocial benefits. The social security score does not use administrative data on labour income or income from othersources such as contributory pensions.

    6

  • data from private companies (e.g. pension fund companies and banks). As constructing the pen-

    sion score requires the coordination of several public and private offices, it is calculated only for

    people who apply.

    Following the assigning of pension scores, the PI uses an arbitrary cut-off to determine ba-

    sic pension recipients. This cut-off has changed progressively over time, with changes occurring

    simultaneously nationwide: it has increased from covering the poorest 40 percent of the elderly

    population in July 2008, to covering the poorest 60 percent since July 2011 (Appendix Table B1

    shows the cut-off by date). To determine the 60th percentile for the Chilean population in 2011, the

    PI used data from the national household survey and estimated a pension score for each household

    in the survey.9 The cut-off then corresponds to the 60th percentile of the estimated pension score

    for the sample of households in the survey. There have been no updates to the pension score cut-off

    since 2011, when it was estimated to be 1,206 pension score points.

    After the decision has been made, applicants know whether or not they will receive the basic

    pension, but they do not have access to the score assigned during the application process. The

    government considered reassessing recipients’ eligibility every two years. However, this proposal

    was never implemented, and virtually all of those who obtained the basic pension have continued

    receiving payments every month thereafter.10 Moreover, according to PI records, 96 percent of

    recipients in our sample collect their pension in person, by showing their identity card in a bank or

    PI office.

    Overall, the majority of the elderly population who do not receive a contributory pension apply

    to obtain a basic pension. In 2011, 64.5 percent of retirees without contributory pensions received

    a basic pension [Ministerio de Desarrollo Social, 2011], and 8 percent have submitted an unsuc-

    cessful application according to our records (for more details on the elderly Chilean population

    who do not have contributory pensions, see Appendix Table B10).

    9The PI could not use the population distribution of pension scores to set the cut-off, because pension scores arecomputed only for the fraction of households that apply for the basic pension. Therefore, data must be drawn fromthe national household survey to estimate the pension score associated with the 60th poorest percentile of the entirepopulation of Chilean households.

    10Less than 0.05 percent of recipients who obtained the basic pension between 2008 and 2015 stopped receiving itat some point [Subsecretarı́a de Previsión Social, 2015]. All of these were for reasons unrelated to the pension score(e.g. moving to another country).

    7

  • 3 Data and descriptive statistics

    3.1 Pension and health datasets

    Our analysis is based on administrative data provided by the Chilean government. First, we have

    access to all applications made in 2011 and 2012. For each applicant and each applicant’s house-

    hold member, the PI provided us with information on gender, age, town of residency, household so-

    cial security score, national unique identifier number (henceforth ID number), and national unique

    household identifier number. The applicant’s ID number allows us to observe who the pension

    applicant is in each household, whereas the household identifier number allows us to perfectly

    match each applicant with all of their household members. This dataset also includes application

    data, such as the pension score, application date, and the outcome of the application.11 All of the

    variables provided by the PI were collected at the moment of application. Unfortunately, we do not

    have access to applicants’ data from previous years, as it was not systematically recorded before

    2011.

    The second dataset we use is provided by the Ministry of Health and covers the health history

    of every Chilean citizen, for each year from 2011 to 2016. This dataset contains information about

    citizens who died, the date of death, and the cause of death (ICD-10 disease code).12 It also pro-

    vides information about any type of vaccinations given to each person and the date given, as well

    as any hospitalisation that occurred, together with its date, duration, and cause (ICD-10 disease

    code). The Ministry of Health also granted us access to the unique national ID number of each

    person recorded in this dataset. As all physicians and health centres have the legal obligation to

    report this information to the central government on a monthly basis, the dataset covers people

    receiving medical attention in both private and public health institutions.

    Finally, the Ministry of Health also granted us access to a dataset covering all births that oc-

    curred in Chile between 2011 and 2016. This dataset contains the date of birth, along with the

    weeks of pregnancy, height, and weight of each newborn, as well as the unique national ID num-

    ber of the mother. This data also covers births in public and private health centres.

    As all datasets contain the ID number of each person, we were able to merge the PI and the

    health data at the level of individuals. We performed several checks to ensure that no observation

    11We also have household-level data on the factors that determine the pension score for 2012, the year in which thePI started to systematically record them. Along with these, the PI also provided us with other household characteristicsthat they started to record systematically in 2012.

    12https://www.who.int/classifications/icd/icdonlineversions/en/

    8

    https://www.who.int/classifications/icd/icdonlineversions/en/

  • was lost in this process.

    We restrict our attention to applications submitted between July 1, 2011 and December 31,

    2012. We do not use applications from earlier in 2011 because the 60 percent cut-off point for

    eligibility was introduced by the government in July 2011 (Section 2). Given the fact that the most

    recent health data to which we have access is from December 2016, this allows us to measure

    health outcomes for up to four years from the date of application.

    We focus our main analysis on basic pension applicants and then conduct a separate analysis

    for their household members. In Chile, the minimum legal age to claim private pension benefits

    is 65 for men and 60 for women, and the minimum legal working age is 15. We thus define three

    exclusive groups of household members, based on household members’ age: 1) men above 64 and

    women above 59 years of age (elderly); 2) men aged 16-64 and women aged 16-59 years (working

    age); and, 3) individuals below 16 years of age (school-age children). Given the small number of

    observations in this last group of household members (931), we focus the analysis on the first two

    groups.

    Finally, we observe that 21.2 percent of those who did not receive the basic pension in their first

    application applied more than one time. To avoid multiple-counting that could potentially bias our

    estimates, we keep in the sample only the first application made by each applicant in our period

    of interest.13 Since the focus of our paper is to use the basic pension to analyse the effect of an

    income increase on mortality rates and days of hospitalisation of the elderly, we accommodate later

    changes in pension holder status using the ‘fuzzy’ regression discontinuity framework presented

    in the next section. In the final sample we have 49,552 applicants, 44,053 working-age household

    members, and 27,057 elderly household members.

    3.2 Descriptive statistics

    Table I reports descriptive statistics for applicants, working-age household members, and elderly

    household members at the moment of their first application. Columns (1), (2), and (3) report

    the mean of the covariates for all applicants, for those who received the basic pension in their

    13As those submitting more than one application are self-selected, counting each repeated application separatelycould bias our estimates of the treatment effect. First, it would give an excessive weight to applicants that appliedmore than one time. Second, if the type of applicants that submit more than one application are somehow differentfrom the rest (for example, more motivated), we would give an excessive weight to this particular type of applicant.Also, there could be multiple applicants within a household. We observe that less than 1 percent of applicants in ourworking sample share a household with another applicant.

    9

  • Table I: Characteristics of applicants, and their household members, at the moment of application

    All applications Bandwidthsample

    All Below cut-off Above cut-off P-value(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

    Panel A: applicants

    Female 0.758 0.738 0.889 0.000 0.871Age (years) 66.19 65.91 68.02 0.000 66.85Household size 2.482 2.460 2.629 0.000 2.643Elderly cohabitant 0.533 0.503 0.738 0.000 0.661Working-age cohabitant 0.532 0.534 0.515 0.005 0.571Social security score 6969.9 6475.5 10289.4 0.000 9385.7Days hospitalised 0.579 0.604 0.410 0.106 0.504Influenza vaccination 0.273 0.262 0.342 0.000 0.320Pneumonia vaccination 0.0635 0.0657 0.0494 0.000 0.0609Urban town 0.686 0.672 0.785 0.000 0.762Submitted >1 application 0.028 0.000 0.213 0.000 0.090Received a basic pension 0.882 0.999 0.0953 0.000 0.699Observations 49,552 43,129 6,423 8,499

    Panel B: working-age household members

    Female 0.410 0.414 0.385 0.000 0.363Age (years) 38.80 38.59 40.29 0.000 40.36Household size 3.726 3.720 3.768 0.015 3.685Elderly cohabitant 0.434 0.417 0.553 0.000 0.470Days hospitalised 0.261 0.256 0.292 0.458 0.249Observations 44,053 38,589 5,464 8,047

    Panel C: elderly household members

    Female 0.242 0.270 0.112 0.000 0.120Age (years) 71.22 71.11 71.73 0.000 71.07Household size 2.883 2.917 2.725 0.000 2.749Working-age cohabitant 0.459 0.469 0.409 0.000 0.434Days hospitalised 0.577 0.601 0.465 0.079 0.490Observations 27,057 22,234 4,823 5,722

    Notes: This table reports the mean of several covariates for applicants and their household members. Column (1)reports means for the whole sample, Column (2) reports means for applicants who received the basic pension intheir first application and Column (3) reports means for applicants who did not receive the basic pension in theirfirst application. Column (4) reports the p-value of the mean difference between Columns (2) and (3). Column(5) reports means for the working sample in the bandwidth. Health covariates are computed 6 months beforeapplicants submit their first application.

    10

  • first application (below cut-off), and for those who did not receive the basic pension in their first

    application (above cut-off), respectively. Column (4) reports the p-value of the mean difference

    between applicants below and above the cut-off, and Column (5) displays means for the applicants

    in a 500-score-point bandwidth from the cut-off.

    This table shows that 88.2 percent of applicants have their first application approved and 75.8

    percent of all applicants are female. This large share of female applicants could be the result of

    women being less likely to have private pension savings and suggests that the basic pension pro-

    gramme was successful in targeting women as its main beneficiaries. We also observe that the

    share of women above the cut-off is higher. A potential explanation for this pattern is that women

    with no retirement savings may be more likely to have a partner who has some source of income

    (such as a contributory pension) than men with no retirement savings, which would make women

    more likely to have a pension score above the cut-off.

    The average applicant’s age is around 66, which suggests that applications are submitted shortly

    after reaching the minimum application age (83 percent are 65 years old). Applicants above the

    cut-off are around 2 years older than those below. This could be explained by older people with

    unsuccessful applications deciding to reapply after the change in the threshold, only to receive the

    same result.

    The average pension applicant is below the 30th percentile of the social security score distri-

    bution, an indication that applicants are poorer than the median Chilean.14 Applicants above the

    cut-off are on average around the 40th percentile, and those below the cut-off are far lower than

    them in the distribution. Even though the pension score cut-off is set at the 60th percentile, the

    average social security score for applicants close to the cut-off (bandwidth sample) is well below

    the 60th percentile. This is likely to be caused by the pension score incorporating administrative

    information and factors that do not form the social security score, such as income from household

    relatives’ contributory pensions, which may constitute a significant portion of household income.

    Looking at the health characteristics of applicants we observe that, over the six months prior to

    their application, they spend approximately half a day hospitalised, with no significant difference

    between applicants below and above the cut-off.

    Applicants within the bandwidth have a higher social security score and are more likely to be

    female (87 percent), and to have an elderly and working-age household member (66 and 57 per-

    14According to the Ministry of Social Development [Ministerio de Desarrollo Social, 2010], the 20th percentileequates to 6,036 points, the 30th percentile to 8,500, and the 40th percentile to 10,320 points of the social security score.

    11

  • cent respectively) than the average applicant. In Section 4.4 we show that, within the bandwidth,

    applicants below and above the cut-off are comparable.

    There are slightly more male than female working-age household members and, on average,

    they are 39 years old, which could indicate that they are the applicants’ children. On the other

    hand, elderly household members are five years older than applicants, mostly male (75.8 percent)

    and, on average, spend half a day hospitalised. These characteristics seem to indicate that most

    elderly household members are the husbands of female applicants.

    3.3 Serial applicants

    Table I shows that a small fraction of applicants below the cut-off did not receive the basic pen-

    sion. This is explained by reasons unrelated to the pension score (e.g. not redeeming the pension

    in time). This table also shows that 21.3 percent of applicants above the cut-off submitted a further

    application (henceforth referred to as serial applicants), and 9.5 percent of applicants above the

    cut-off obtained a basic pension at a later time.

    To analyse the characteristics of serial applicants, we regress an indicator for whether the per-

    son is a serial applicant against baseline covariates. Column 1 of Table II presents a series of

    bivariate regressions in which each baseline characteristic is entered separately, while columns 2,

    3, and 4 show estimations that regress on multiple covariates simultaneously. This table shows that

    applicants above the cut-off who are older and have a higher social security score are less likely

    to be serial applicants, while those in a larger household are more likely. This could be because:

    1) older applicants might perceive a lower present value of basic pension income (they expect to

    live for a shorter time); and, 2) wealthier people see themselves as less likely to obtain the pen-

    sion. In contrast, people in larger families might be more likely to see changes in their household

    composition or income, which could affect their pension score and encourage them to reapply.15

    15In Appendix Table B2, we analyse the characteristics of serial applicants who eventually obtain the basic pension.We show that serial applicants with a higher social security score are less likely to eventually obtain the basic pensionfor the reasons mentioned above. Living with an elderly relative also reduces the probability of obtaining the basicpension later, likely due to elderly relatives having the least volatile source of income: a contributory pension.

    12

  • Table II: The effect of baseline covariates on the probability of applying multiple times

    (1) (2) (3) (4)

    Female -0.034 0.031 0.031 0.026(0.016) (0.016) (0.017) (0.015)

    Age (years) -0.012 -0.009 -0.009 -0.006(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

    Social security score -0.023 -0.021 -0.022 -0.019(0.001) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)

    Days hospitalised -0.001 0.001 0.001 0.001(0.002) (0.002) (0.002) (0.001)

    Received influenza vaccination 0.050 0.069 0.070 0.018(0.011) (0.011) (0.011) (0.011)

    Received pneumonia vaccination -0.034 -0.097 -0.098 -0.005(0.024) (0.024) (0.024) (0.021)

    Household size 0.014 0.021 0.023(0.005) (0.007) (0.006)

    Elderly cohabitant -0.055 -0.017 -0.012(0.012) (0.014) (0.012)

    Working-age cohabitant 0.037 -0.010 -0.021(0.010) (0.016) (0.014)

    Live with child under 16 0.074 0.004 -0.045(0.052) (0.051) (0.048)

    FIXED EFFECTS NO NO NO YESN 6,423 6,423 6,423 6,423

    Notes: Using the sample of all applicants above the cut-off, this table reports results fromOLS regressions of a binary indicator equal to 1 if the individual applied for the basicpension more than once (and 0 otherwise) on several covariates. Column (1) reports coef-ficients of bivariate regressions. Columns (2), (3) and (4) report coefficients of multivariateregressions on the specified variables. Fixed effects are at the month-of-application andthe health-district level. Standard errors are clustered at the province level. For ease ofinterpretation, the social security score is rescaled (divided by 1,000).

    13

  • 4 Empirical strategy and RD validity

    Since most applicants below the cut-off obtained their basic pension, and some applicants above

    the cut-off managed to obtain a basic pension at a later time, we can predict that the cut-off discon-

    tinuously changes the probability of receiving a basic pension, but not from zero to one hundred

    percent. Following this, we implement a fuzzy regression discontinuity (FRD) design to estimate

    the causal effect of a basic pension on health outcomes.

    4.1 Fuzzy regression discontinuity design

    To estimate the causal effect of the basic pension on each health outcome, we perform a two-stage

    least square regression. The set of equations is as follows:16

    Health Outcomei,h = f 0(Scoreh) + βLATEPensionh + Pensionh × f 1(Scoreh) + ui,h, (1)

    where Pensionh is instrumented using:

    Pensionh = g0(Scoreh) + βDh + Dh × g1(Scoreh) + vh, (2)

    and Dh is a dummy variable defined as follows:

    Dh =

    1 if Scoreh ≤ 00 if Scoreh > 0

    In this set of equations, Health Outcomei,h is one of the health outcomes described in Section

    3.1, four years after applying, for person i in household h. Pensionh is a dummy indicator equal to

    1 if the applicant of household h has received a basic pension within four years of the first applica-

    tion, and 0 otherwise. Dh is a dummy indicator equal to 1 if the applicant of household h obtained

    16Note that in these equations the score is centred at the cut-off to ensure that the treatment effect is the coefficientβLATE .

    14

  • a pension score below the cut-off in their first application, and 0 otherwise. Scoreh is the distance

    of the first application score from the cut-off point, for the pension applicant of household h. f j and

    gj , with j = 0, 1, are different functional forms of Scoreh. In our preferred specification, f j and

    gj , are polynomials of order 1 in Scoreh. We check the robustness of our results to different spec-

    ifications by estimating equations 1 and 2 using polynomials of order 2 in Scoreh, nonparametric

    estimations, logistic regression, and different sets of controls.

    In each regression, we use triangular kernels such that the weight of each observation decreases

    with the distance from the cut-off. The sample is restricted to a bandwidth of 500 points on either

    side of the threshold. As a robustness check, we also repeat our analysis using the mean-squared

    error optimal bandwidth approach as proposed by Calonico et al. [2014]. Standard errors are clus-

    tered at the province level.17

    In equation 1, βLATE captures the Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE) of a permanent in-

    crease in monthly income on the health outcomes of applicants and household members close to

    the cut-off.

    4.2 The effect of the pension score on receiving the basic pension

    Figure I displays the probability of receiving a basic pension in the four years following the first

    application, for various pension score distances from the cut-off (the ‘First Stage’). This figure

    shows that applicants in the bandwidth with a score below the cut-off in their first application

    (treatment group) are more likely to receive a basic pension in the following four years than those

    whose score is just above the cut-off (control group). Column (1) of Table III confirms this result,

    and shows that being in the treatment group increases the likelihood of receiving a basic pension

    in the next four years by 82 pp. (p-value< 0.001). For reasons explained in Section 3.3, Figure I

    also shows that some applicants did not obtain the basic pension in their first application, but still

    went on to receive it at a later time.17There are 33 health districts and 54 provinces in Chile. The standard errors are clustered at the province level in

    our preferred specification, because provinces serve as a good proxy of health districts, but their number is sufficientlyhigh to employ the law of large numbers and make correct use of clustered standard errors. Clustering at the health-district level does not change the results of our estimates.

    15

  • Figure I: First-stage graph

    0.2

    .4.6

    .81

    With

    in-b

    in a

    vera

    ge

    -500 0 500Distance of the pension score from threshold

    Mean bin Quadratic fit Confidence interval

    Notes: Each circle represents the average probability of obtaining the basic pension, four years after the firstapplication, for the applicants in each 50 score-point bin.

    4.3 Continuity of applicants’ frequency around the cut-off

    Identification of the treatment effect requires that applicants cannot manipulate their pension score

    in order to receive the basic pension. This assumption would fail if, for instance, more motivated

    applicants, who happened to be healthier, were able to adjust their pension score to fall below the

    cut-off.

    To formally confirm the absence of manipulation, we perform the test developed by McCrary

    [2008]. Here, we use the density of applicants in 10 score-point bins as the dependent variable in

    equation 2. As shown in Figure II, the test does not reject the null hypothesis of no discontinuity

    in the density of applicants (t-statistic of -1.019 and p-value of 0.309). Appendix Figure C1 also

    shows no discontinuity in the density of applicants’ working-age household members (t-statistic of

    -0.013 and p-value of 0.999) and elderly household members (t-statistic of -1.576 and p-value of

    0.115) at the cut-off.

    This result is not surprising given that the pension score is not computed until an individual

    16

  • Table III: First stage

    Variables RD Coef. S.E. t-stat P-value BW N Control(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

    Received a basic pension 0.820 (0.011) 72.946 0.000 500 8,499 0.181

    Notes: This table reports results from an OLS regression of a dummy indicator equal to 1 if the applicant receivesthe basic pension four years after their first application (and 0 otherwise) on a treatment dummy indicator anddeviation of the pension score from the cut-off. Column (1) reports the treatment indicator coefficient and Column(2) reports the standard error of this coefficient, clustered at the province level. Column (3) reports the t-statisticof the treatment dummy indicator coefficient, and Column (4) reports the p-value of this coefficient. Column(5) indicates the range of pension score points from the cut-off in which regressions are performed. Column (6)reports the number of observations used in the regression. Column (7) reports the fraction of control applicantsat the cut-off who received the pension.

    applies, so the applicant does not know the score beforehand. This piece of evidence suggests that

    applicants do not manipulate their first application score in order to receive the pension.

    4.4 Continuity of predetermined covariates around the cut-off

    In order to have comparable treatment and control groups in the RD design, a series of pre-

    determined characteristics that could affect applicants’ health should change smoothly at the cut-

    off [Lee and Lemieux, 2010]. Appendix Figures C2 and C3 graphically demonstrate that pre-

    determined covariates do indeed vary smoothly at the cut-off for applicants. Column (3) of Table

    IV reports the results of the t-test performed on the coefficient β, in equation 2, using as a de-

    pendent variable one of the 11 individual and household characteristics at the time of application.

    Panel A of this table confirms the results and shows that only 1 out of the 11 estimations (pneu-

    monia vaccinations) is significant at conventional levels for applicants. We do not believe that this

    represents a systematic difference between treatment and control groups around the cut-off: given

    the large number of estimations, it is common to have one significant estimation at this significance

    level. For the covariates used to compute the pension score, we only have data for applicants in

    2012. Appendix Table B3 reports balancing checks using these covariates, and shows that only

    1 out of 11 estimations is significant at the 10 percent significance level. The evidence presented

    above suggests that the basic pension is as good as (locally) randomly assigned, after conditioning

    on pension score deviations from the cut-off.

    As we also explore the effect of the pension on household members living with applicants at

    the moment of application, we examine whether the same covariates change smoothly at the cut-

    off for working-age and elderly relatives. Panel B of Table IV shows that 1 out of the 11 available

    17

  • Table IV: Balancing tests

    Variables RD Coef. S.E. t-stat P-value BW N Control(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)

    Panel A: applicants

    Female -0.016 (0.015) -1.016 0.314 500 8,499 0.890Age (years) -0.372 (0.236) -1.578 0.121 500 8,499 67.57Days hospitalised -0.131 (0.154) -0.851 0.399 500 8,499 0.458Influenza vaccination -0.025 (0.020) -1.281 0.206 500 8,499 0.357Pneumonia vaccination 0.017 (0.008) 2.019 0.049 500 8,499 0.043Household size -0.008 (0.040) -0.192 0.849 500 8,499 2.634Social security score 64.687 (181.386) 0.357 0.723 500 8,499 9737.Elderly cohabitant 0.016 (0.018) 0.872 0.387 500 8,499 0.693Working-age cohabitant -0.004 (0.018) -0.214 0.832 500 8,499 0.548Live with child under 16 0.002 (0.004) 0.396 0.694 500 8,499 0.006Municipal income -2.465 (4.250) -0.580 0.564 500 8,483 146.7

    Panel B: working-age household members

    Female 0.030 (0.024) 1.240 0.221 500 8,047 0.358Age (years) -1.090 (0.656) -1.661 0.103 500 8,047 40.96Days hospitalised -0.046 (0.062) -0.737 0.465 500 8,047 0.172Influenza vaccination -0.015 (0.012) -1.204 0.235 500 8,047 0.094Pneumonia vaccination -0.001 (0.003) -0.271 0.788 500 8,047 0.004Number of children born 0.006 (0.005) 1.062 0.293 500 8,047 0.008Household size 0.007 (0.060) 0.121 0.904 500 4,836 3.228Social security score 147.319 (261.230) 0.564 0.575 500 4,836 9857.Elderly cohabitant 0.047 (0.026) 1.767 0.084 500 4,836 0.525Live with child under 16 0.007 (0.006) 1.054 0.297 500 4,836 0.007Municipal income -8.321 (5.181) -1.606 0.115 500 4,828 150.0

    Panel C: elderly household members

    Female 0.032 (0.016) 2.016 0.049 500 5,722 0.097Age (years) -0.608 (0.358) -1.702 0.095 500 5,722 71.82Days hospitalised -0.038 (0.093) -0.404 0.688 500 5,722 0.312Influenza vaccination -0.026 (0.029) -0.899 0.373 500 5,722 0.364Pneumonia vaccination 0.001 (0.006) 0.083 0.934 500 5,722 0.019Household size 0.050 (0.050) 1.003 0.321 500 5,566 2.679Social security score 96.419 (199.801) 0.483 0.632 500 5,566 1.0e+Working-age cohabitant 0.027 (0.024) 1.147 0.257 500 5,566 0.412Live with child under 16 -0.000 (0.006) -0.044 0.965 500 5,566 0.009Municipal income -2.603 (5.244) -0.496 0.622 500 5,558 147.4

    Notes: This table reports results from OLS regressions of pre-determined variables on a treatment dummy indicatorand deviation of the pension score from the cut-off. Columns (1), (2), (3), and (4) report the treatment indicatorcoefficient, its standard error clustered at the province level, the t-statistic, and the p-value, respectively. Columns(5) and (6) report the range of pension score points from the cut-off and the number of observations in the regression,respectively. Column (7) reports the variable mean for control applicants at the cut-off. Health covariates are defined6 months before applying.

    18

  • Figure II: McCrary test of applicants

    0.0

    005

    .001

    .001

    5.0

    02D

    ensi

    ty

    -1000 -500 0 500 1000Distance of the pension score from threshold

    Notes: This figure shows the density of applicants in 10 score-point bins. The solid line plots fitted values from alocal linear regression of density on the pension score, separately estimated on both sides of the cut-off. The thin linesrepresent the 95% confidence interval.

    covariates (elderly cohabitant) is significant for working-age household members, which is in the

    expected range of significant coefficients at this significance level. However, Panel C of Table IV

    shows that 2 out of the 10 available covariates (female and age) are statistically significant among

    elderly household members. This is higher than the expected level. We address the implications of

    these imbalances in Section 5 by adding these variables as controls, and show that our results on

    elderly household members do not change.

    5 Results

    5.1 The effect of receiving a pension on applicants’ health

    The top left panel of Figure III shows the causal effect of receiving a basic pension from the first

    application on the probability of dying within four years after applying (henceforth referred to as

    19

  • Figure III: Effect of the basic pension on mortality, cumulative days of hospitalisation and medicalepisodes of applicants

    -.10

    .1.2

    With

    in-b

    in a

    vera

    ge

    -500 0 500Distance of the pension score from threshold

    Mean bin Quadratic fit Confidence interval

    Mortality rate

    .72.

    74.

    76.

    7W

    ithin

    -bin

    ave

    rage

    -500 0 500Distance of the pension score from threshold

    Mean bin Quadratic fit Confidence interval

    Days hospitalised

    .2.3

    .4.5

    With

    in-b

    in a

    vera

    ge

    -500 0 500Distance of the pension score from threshold

    Mean bin Quadratic fit Confidence interval

    Medical episode

    Notes: Each graph shows the average value of the corresponding variable conditional on the distance of the pensionscore from the cut-off. The circles represent averages across 50-point bins on either side of the threshold, while thesolid and dashed lines represent the predicted values and confidence interval, respectively.

    mortality). This panel indicates that applicants in the treatment group are less likely to die than

    applicants in the control group. Column (1) of Table V confirms this result and shows that receiv-

    ing a basic pension significantly decreases the probability of dying by 2.5 pp. (p-value=0.034).

    As the basic pension increases applicants’ income by 63.1 percent in our control group, and the

    average probability of dying for control group applicants at the cut-off is 7.4 percent (Column (8)),

    we obtain a negative mortality-income elasticity estimate of 0.54. Our elasticity measure is similar

    to those found in studies of US veterans in the early 1900s [Salm, 2011], which lie between -0.54

    and –0.32.

    Since the basic pension itself has an effect on the probability of dying, we cannot estimate its

    20

  • Table V: Applicants’ health outcomes over four years from application

    Variables 2sls S.E. 2sls RD Coef. S.E. P-value BW N Control(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    Mortality rate -0.025 (0.012) -0.021 (0.010) 0.034 500 8,499 0.074Days hospitalised -0.762 (0.770) -0.657 (0.640) 0.309 500 8,499 4.811Medical episode -0.050 (0.021) -0.042 (0.018) 0.024 500 8,499 0.342

    Notes: This table reports results, within four years from the date of the first application, from regressions of severaldependent variables on a treatment dummy indicator and deviation of the pension score from the cut-off. Column(1) reports the treatment coefficient adjusted by the first stage and Column (2) reports its standard error clusteredat the province level. Column (3) reports the treatment indicator coefficient and Column (4) reports its standarderror clustered at the province level. Column (5) reports the p-value of the adjusted treatment coefficient reportedin Column (1). Column (6) reports the range of pension score points from the cut-off and Column (7) reports thenumber of observations in the regression. Column (8) reports the mean of the outcome variable for control applicantsat the cut-off.

    causal effect on the days of hospitalisation: applicants on each side of the cut-off are not compa-

    rable as those above the cut-off have fewer days available to be hospitalised, due to their higher

    mortality rate. With this caveat, we still show the effect on the number of days that applicants spent

    in hospital, from the date of application to the last day that we are able to observe them (four years

    after applying, or the moment of death). Even though treated applicants have more potential days

    for hospitalisation, the point estimates in Column (1) of Table V suggest that, if anything, they

    spend fewer days in hospital, although the effect is not statistically significant.

    As a way to summarise treatment effects on health outcomes and circumvent the survival bias,

    we follow the medical literature and use as an outcome variable a dummy indicator equal to 1 if the

    applicant had either been hospitalised or died (medical episode) in the four years after applying.18

    Column (1) of Table V shows that treated applicants are 5.0 pp. (p-value=0.024) less likely to

    experience a medical episode in the four years after applying. Since more than one-third of con-

    trol group applicants at the cut-off experienced a medical episode in this period, the basic pension

    reduces the probability of medical episodes by around 16 percent.

    Column (2) of Table VI shows that the causal effect of the basic pension on mortality and med-

    ical episodes remains, whether we use logistic regressions, non-parametric estimations, different

    sets of controls, or polynomials of order two in Scoreh. This Table and Figure IV also show that

    the results do not change if we use different bandwidths around the cut-off.

    Figure V displays the share of surviving control and treatment group applicants, at each point

    18What we call a ‘medical episode’ is commonly referred to as a ‘primary outcome’ in the medical literature [Pittet al., 2014; Eikelboom et al., 2017].

    21

  • Table VI: Applicants’ health outcomes in four years from the first application using logit,non-parametric estimations, optimal bandwidth, controls, and quadratic functional form in Scoreh

    Variables Regression RD Coef. S.E. P-value BW N(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Mortality rate Logit -0.020 (0.009) 0.029 500 8,499Mortality rate Non-parametric -0.021 (0.010) 0.045 500 8,499Mortality rate Optimal bandwidth -0.028 (0.013) 0.027 306 5,048Mortality rate Controls -0.019 (0.010) 0.059 500 8,499Mortality rate Quadratic -0.033 (0.015) 0.024 500 8,499Medical episode Logit -0.041 (0.018) 0.018 500 8,499Medical episode Non-parametric -0.042 (0.023) 0.071 500 8,499Medical episode Optimal bandwidth -0.048 (0.021) 0.021 398 6,605Medical episode Controls -0.038 (0.017) 0.025 500 8,499Medical episode Quadratic -0.057 (0.028) 0.043 500 8,499

    Notes: This table reports results, within four years from the date of the first application, from regressionsof several dependent variables on a treatment dummy indicator and deviation of the pension score fromthe cut-off. Column (1) indicates the specification used. Logit reports estimations using a logistic regres-sion. Non-parametric reports non-parametric estimations using kernel local linear regressions. Optimalbandwidth estimates treatment effects using the optimal bandwidth proposed by Calonico et al. [2014].Controls employs our preferred specification, polynomial of order 1 in Scoreh, as well as 17 other controlslisted in Appendix Section B. Quadratic uses polynomial of order 2 in Scoreh. Column (2) reports thetreatment indicator coefficient and Column (3) reports the standard error clustered at the province level.Column (4) reports the p-value of the treatment coefficient. Column (5) indicates the range of pensionscore points from the cut-off and Column (6) reports the number of observations in the regression.

    in time after their first application, adjusted by the deviation of their score from the cut-off using a

    Cox proportional hazard model. This Figure suggests that the mortality effect manifests itself ap-

    proximately one year after the first payment and grows almost monotonically over time, reaching

    a maximum at the end of the studied period. This piece of evidence suggests that the beneficial

    effects of the basic pension tend to accumulate over time and cannot be ascribed to ‘instantaneous’

    mechanisms.

    Table VII shows the effect of the basic pension on different sub-groups of applicants. We start

    by following common practice in medical literature on ageing and mortality (e.g. Garre-Olmo

    et al. [2013]; Hawton et al. [2011]), exploring the heterogeneous effects depending on the house-

    hold structure of the applicants. Panel A of this Table shows that treated applicants living alone or

    with elderly household members (i.e. without a working-age household member) seem strongly

    affected, with a significant reduction in their mortality rate of 5.2 pp. (p-value=0.008). On the other

    hand, Panel B suggests that those living with at least one working-age household member remain

    22

  • Figure IV: Robustness of results for mortality and medical episodes using different bandwidths-.1

    -.05

    0.0

    5.1

    Coe

    ffici

    ent

    250 400 500 600CCTBandwidth

    point estimate using different bandwidthsMortality rate

    -.1-.0

    50

    .05

    .1C

    oeffi

    cien

    t

    250 300 500 600CCTBandwidth

    point estimate using different bandwidthsMedical episode

    Notes: Each graph shows the point estimate and the standard error of non-parametric estimation for the correspondingbandwidth. CCT is the optimal bandwidth using the approach proposed by Calonico et al. [2014]

    unaffected, with an insignificant reduction in their mortality rate of 0.02 pp. (p-value=0.954).19

    The same pattern arises when looking at the number of days of hospitalisation and the probability

    of having a medical episode. Here, treatment group applicants living without a working-age house-

    hold member spend 2.6 fewer days in hospital and are 11 pp. less likely to experience a medical

    episode (p-values of 0.001 and 0.012, respectively). These results suggest that the group of treated

    applicants most strongly affected by the basic pension is not only living longer, but also enjoying

    better health, at least in terms of fewer days spent hospitalised. These findings are also robust to

    the use of different specifications (see Appendix Tables B5 and B6).

    Not surprisingly, an analysis of survival rates shows that applicants living without working-age

    relatives are the main drivers of this dynamic effect across the whole sample, whereas applicants

    living with working-age relatives see virtually no improvement over time (Appendix Figure C11).

    5.2 The heterogeneous effects of receiving a pension on applicants

    We do not find evidence of heterogeneous treatment effects based on the gender of applicants.

    However, given that males constitute a small fraction of our sample, we cannot rule out the pres-

    19There is no evidence of score manipulation within any of these subsamples of applicants: test statistics for theMcCrary test are -0.486 and -0.976 for applicants living with and without working-age relatives, respectively (FigureC9). Moreover, the subsamples appear to be locally comparable at the baseline: none of the 10 available covariatesis significant for applicants living with working-age relatives, and only 1 out of 10 is significant for applicants livingwithout working-age relatives (Table B4).

    23

  • Figure V: Share of surviving applicants over 4 years from date of application, adjusted by thedeviation of pension score from the cut-off.

    1st payment

    .95

    .975

    1Sh

    are

    of s

    urvi

    vors

    0 1 2 3 4Years from application submission

    Control group Treatment group

    Notes: This figure presents the share of survivors in the treatment and control groups (500 score-point bandwidth),and at each point in time following the first application. Survival rates are computed using a Cox proportional hazardsmodel, adjusted for the deviation of the score from the cut-off and using triangular weights to give more weight to theapplicants closer to the cut-off.

    24

  • Table VII: Applicant’s health outcomes over four years from application: household structure andgender

    Variables 2sls S.E. 2sls RD Coef. S.E. P-value BW N Control(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    Panel A: applicants not living with a working-age household member

    Mortality rate -0.052 (0.019) -0.045 (0.016) 0.008 500 3,647 0.102Days hospitalised -2.632 (0.769) -2.250 (0.658) 0.001 500 3,647 5.773Medical episode -0.111 (0.042) -0.093 (0.036) 0.012 500 3,647 0.369

    Panel B: applicants living with working-age household members

    Mortality rate -0.002 (0.018) -0.001 (0.014) 0.954 500 4,852 0.050Days hospitalised 0.846 (1.313) 0.635 (1.061) 0.552 500 4,852 3.918Medical episode 0.001 (0.039) -0.000 (0.032) 0.998 500 4,852 0.317

    Panel C: female applicants

    Mortality rate -0.024 (0.010) -0.020 (0.008) 0.021 500 7,403 0.067Days hospitalised -0.808 (0.750) -0.703 (0.629) 0.269 500 7,403 4.791Medical episode -0.053 (0.024) -0.044 (0.020) 0.035 500 7,403 0.336

    Panel D: male applicants

    Mortality rate -0.051 (0.051) -0.039 (0.039) 0.318 500 1,096 0.141Days hospitalised -0.431 (2.275) -0.354 (1.726) 0.838 500 1,096 4.959Medical episode -0.042 (0.110) -0.033 (0.083) 0.694 500 1,096 0.391

    Notes: This table reports results, within four years from the date of the first application, from regressions of severaldependent variables on a treatment dummy indicator and deviation of the pension score from the cut-off. Column(1) reports the treatment coefficient adjusted by the first stage and Column (2) reports its standard error clusteredat the province level. Column (3) reports the treatment indicator coefficient and Column (4) reports its standarderror clustered at the province level. Column (5) reports the p-value of the adjusted treatment coefficient reportedin Column (1). Column (6) reports the range of pension score points from the cut-off and Column (7) reports thenumber of observations in the regression. Column (8) reports the mean of the outcome variable for control applicantsat the cut-off.

    25

  • ence of differential effects between genders.

    5.3 The effect of having a relative who receives a basic pension

    Table VIII: Health outcomes over four years from application: household members, by age

    Variables 2sls S.E. 2sls RD Coef. S.E. P-value BW N Control(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    Panel A: elderly household members

    Mortality rate 0.001 (0.016) 0.000 (0.013) 0.979 500 5,722 0.125Days hospitalised 0.511 (1.221) 0.443 (1.045) 0.673 500 5,722 5.236Medical episode 0.041 (0.035) 0.034 (0.030) 0.256 500 5,722 0.369

    Panel B: working-age household members

    Days hospitalised -0.345 (0.611) -0.242 (0.493) 0.625 500 8,047 2.132Newborn child 0.036 (0.009) 0.028 (0.007) 0.000 500 8,047 0.025

    Panel C: female household members in fertility age (16-40)

    Days hospitalised -0.188 (0.735) -0.137 (0.547) 0.804 500 2,058 1.764Newborn child 0.124 (0.039) 0.091 (0.028) 0.001 500 2,058 0.097

    Notes: This table reports results, within four years from the date of the first application, from regressions of severaldependent variables on a treatment dummy indicator and deviation of the pension score from the cut-off. Column(1) reports the treatment coefficient adjusted by the first stage and Column (2) reports its standard error clusteredat the province level. Column (3) reports the treatment indicator coefficient and Column (4) reports its standarderror clustered at the province level. Column (5) reports the p-value of the adjusted treatment coefficient reportedin Column (1). Column (6) reports the range of pension score points from the cut-off and Column (7) reports thenumber of observations in the regression. Column (8) reports the mean of the outcome variable for control applicantsat the cut-off.

    Panel A of Table VIII shows that elderly household members are more likely to die than ap-

    plicants (the average mortality rate of elderly relatives living with a non-recipient applicant at the

    cut-off is 12.5 percent), but this seems to be unaffected by having a relative who receives the basic

    pension.

    On the other hand, Panel B of Table VIII reveals that working-age relatives are 3.6 pp. (p-

    value

  • Mumford, 2013].20 Although the basic pension leads to significantly more children being born to

    fertility-age female household members, we do not find evidence that it affects the health of the

    newborn child (Appendix Table B7).

    Appendix Table B8 shows that the results for elderly and working-age household members do

    not change when we use logistic regressions, non-parametric estimations, the optimal bandwidth

    approach proposed by Calonico et al. [2014], all available controls, or when we control for a poly-

    nomial of order 2 in Scoreh. This also ensures that the null effect on elderly household members is

    not driven by the slight imbalance in this group shown in Section 4.4.

    6 Mechanisms

    In this section we provide evidence suggesting that the decrease in mortality and medical episodes

    reflect fewer cases of respiratory and circulatory diseases. This seems to be explained by the re-

    cipients of the basic pension having fewer acute episodes of chronic diseases. Finally, we provide

    evidence suggesting that the heterogeneous effects on applicants, as well as the spillover effects on

    working-age relatives, may be due to an intra-household transfer of income that ceases when basic

    pension payments begin.

    6.1 Why do applicants’ mortality and medical episodes decrease?

    To gain an insight into which diseases drive the observed effects, Table IX disaggregates medical

    episodes by cause. We look at the sub-group of applicants whose health outcomes are most strongly

    affected - applicants living without working-age relatives - and find that the effects are driven by

    a reduction in the probability of suffering from a circulatory or respiratory disease. Deaths or

    hospitalisations for these reasons often result from decompensations of a chronic condition. For

    example, medical episodes of circulatory diseases are often heart attacks due to uncontrolled di-

    abetes or hypertension, and medical episodes of respiratory diseases are often acute respiratory

    problems in patients with severe asthma. Circulatory an respiratory diseases are also the first and

    the third leading cause of deaths around the world [World Health Organization, 2011; European

    20Since goods with no substitutes are generally considered normal, children should be ‘normal goods’ and their‘consumption’ should increase with income. Our results, along with other recent empirical studies [Lindo, 2010;Lovenheim and Mumford, 2013], shed light on the long-term puzzle of the negative cross-sectional correlationbetween income and fertility that is present in many parts of the world (e.g. Jones and Tertilt [2008]).

    27

  • Respiratory Society, 2017], and 47 percent of elderly pension recipients in 2011 had at least one

    of the underling chronic conditions leading to them [Ministerio de Desarrollo Social, 2011].

    Table IX: Medical episodes by cause over four years from application

    Variables 2sls S.E. 2sls RD Coef. S.E. P-value BW N Control(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    Panel A: applicants

    Circulatory -0.015 (0.010) -0.012 (0.008) 0.142 500 8,499 0.057Respiratory -0.008 (0.007) -0.006 (0.006) 0.245 500 8,499 0.016Tumour -0.008 (0.011) -0.006 (0.009) 0.497 500 8,499 0.035Digestive or nutrional -0.014 (0.013) -0.012 (0.011) 0.254 500 8,499 0.060

    Panel B: applicants not living with a working-age household member

    Circulatory -0.047 (0.015) -0.040 (0.013) 0.002 500 3,647 0.082Respiratory -0.022 (0.008) -0.018 (0.007) 0.006 500 3,647 0.024Tumour -0.016 (0.011) -0.014 (0.009) 0.126 500 3,647 0.037Digestive or nutrional -0.009 (0.023) -0.008 (0.020) 0.685 500 3,647 0.056

    Notes: This table reports results, within four years from the date of the first application, from regressions of severaldependent variables on a treatment dummy indicator and deviation of the pension score from the cut-off. Column (1)reports the treatment coefficient adjusted by the first stage and Column (2) reports its standard error clustered at theprovince level. Column (3) reports the treatment indicator coefficient and Column (4) reports its standard error clusteredat the province level. Column (5) reports the p-value of the adjusted treatment coefficient reported in Column (1). Column(6) reports the range of pension score points from the cut-off and Column (7) reports the number of observations in theregression. Column (8) reports the mean of the outcome variable for control applicants at the cut-off.

    The decrease in respiratory episodes amongst applicants does not appear to be driven by an

    increase in the use of vaccinations. As we can see in Appendix Table B9, we do not find any

    significant effect of the basic pension on the number of vaccinations received for influenza or

    pneumonia in the four years after applying, for any of the sub-groups.21

    Two main mechanisms may explain the results so far. The first proposed mechanism is that re-

    cipients are putting part of their the income towards goods or actions that improve their health, such

    as vitamin-rich food [Bartali et al., 2006; Cederholm et al., 1995; Ortega et al., 1997; Fogel, 2004;

    Salm, 2011] or transport costs that allow them to attend medical check-ups regularly [Dahlgren

    and Whitehead, 1991; Jensen and Richter, 2003; Aguila et al., 2015]. This may help recipients to

    improve their ability to control chronic conditions and prevent acute episodes from occurring. This

    mechanism seems plausible, considering that basic pension recipients spend around 77 percent of

    their income on goods conducive to health, such as food, and only 13 percent on goods that impede21Since we observe a slight imbalance in pneumonia vaccination levels at baseline, we repeat the analysis using all

    available controls and observe that results remain unchanged. Therefore, this seems unlikely to account for our results.

    28

  • Table X: Health outcomes over four years from application: applicants by vaccination statusbefore applying

    Variables 2sls S.E. 2sls RD Coef. S.E. P-value BW N Control(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)

    Panel A: Applicants vaccinated before applying

    Mortality rate -0.046 (0.021) -0.037 (0.017) 0.033 500 2,819 0.101Days hospitalised -2.489 (1.287) -2.035 (1.002) 0.048 500 2,819 6.385Medical episode -0.131 (0.037) -0.104 (0.030) 0.001 500 2,819 0.428

    Panel B: Applicants not vaccinated before applying

    Mortality rate -0.014 (0.015) -0.011 (0.013) 0.376 500 5,680 0.060Days hospitalised 0.125 (1.147) 0.096 (0.978) 0.922 500 5,680 4.012Medical episode -0.008 (0.033) -0.006 (0.028) 0.823 500 5,680 0.297

    Notes: This table reports results, within four years from the date of the first application, from regressions of severaldependent variables on a treatment dummy indicator and deviation of the pension score from the cut-off. Column(1) reports the treatment coefficient adjusted by the first stage and Column (2) reports its standard error clusteredat the province level. Column (3) reports the treatment indicator coefficient and Column (4) reports its standarderror clustered at the province level. Column (5) reports the p-value of the adjusted treatment coefficient reportedin Column (1). Column (6) reports the range of pension score points from the cut-off and Column (7) reports thenumber of observations in the regression. Column (8) reports the mean of the outcome variable for control applicantsat the cut-off.

    health, such as alcohol [Ministerio Trabajo y Previsión Social, 2017]. This hypothesis would imply

    that the benefits of the income increase should be more pronounced for people who care more for

    their health. Unfortunately, we do not have a means of directly observing the health-consciousness

    of the applicants. However, we use as a proxy for health-consciousness whether the applicant had

    an influenza or pneumonia vaccination in the six months before applying. Table X shows that

    applicants with these vaccinations are more positively affected by the pension, showing a signifi-

    cantly larger drop in mortality. These pieces of evidence suggest that recipients using part of their

    income to buy health-conducive goods that prevent acute episodes from occurring is a mechanism

    that is likely to be at play.

    This explanation is also in line with what Salm [2011] finds for US veterans. However, Feeney

    [2017, 2018] finds that rural Mexicans receiving a non-contributory pension increase their tran-

    sitions into retirement, unhealthy food consumption, and mortality from cardiovascular diseases.

    One reason that might explain these contrasting results is differences in the characteristics of pen-

    sion recipients. In the case of the US veterans, as in our study, recipients had already moved out

    of the labour force, while in the Mexican study more than 40 percent of recipients were employed.

    Thus, changes in consumption patterns that occur when exiting the labour force may provide a rele-

    29

  • vant explanation of these seemingly contradictory results in food consumption patterns [Browning

    and Meghir, 1991; Zantinge et al., 2013].

    The second proposed mechanism is that the income increase allows pensioners to purchase

    health insurance or medical treatment that they could not have afforded in the absence of the ba-

    sic pension. Previous work has not found a clear relationship between health insurance coverage

    and mortality [Finkelstein and McKnight, 2008; Chetty et al., 2016]. Purchasing a more generous

    private health insurance does not seem to be the most relevant mechanism in our case, considering

    that 95 percent of basic pension holders in the Chilean population were and remained enrolled

    in public health insurance during the time of our study [Ministerio de Desarrollo Social, 2011,

    2015]. Furthermore, medicines and medical treatments in Chile are free of charge for all non-rare

    diseases, including the underlying chronic conditions that produce the circulatory and respiratory

    diseases driving the effects observed here.22

    6.2 Why is there no effect on pensioners living with a working-age relative,but there are spillover effects on these relatives?

    The null effect of the basic pension on treated applicants living with a working-age household

    member could be the result of some ex-ante transfer of income from working-age household mem-

    bers to applicants, which then stops when applicants start to receive pension payments. In this

    sense, the net income increase would be lower for this particular group of treated applicants, but it

    would also imply a positive income shock for their working-age household members. The further

    positive spillover effects on the fertility levels of these household members, presented in Table

    VIII, are in line with this hypothesis.23 Also consistent with this view is the fact that, according to

    a recent government survey, 65 percent of basic pension recipients consider that they could borrow

    money from a working-age relative, while only 17 percent could do so from an elderly relative

    [Ministerio Trabajo y Previsión Social, 2017]. These pieces of evidence do suggest that ex-ante

    intra-household transfers of income are a likely mechanism operating here.

    22Since 2005, the Chilean plan for universal access to treatment and drugs (‘Plan de Acceso Universal de GarantiasExplicitas’ or AUGE) granted free access to drugs and procedures for the most common diseases in the country. Thesystem covers virtually the entire population: only 1 percent of patients report that they suffer from a disease thatis not covered by AUGE and more than 90 percent report having access to a doctor when required [Ministerio deDesarrollo Social, 2011].

    23We are not able to disentangle the different alternative uses of this income shock. For instance, fertility-agewomen in recipient households may be continuing work after having a newborn child, or they may be exiting thelabour force. We see these alternative paths as variations of the same mechanism: a positive income shock forrecipients’ working-age household members.

    30

  • Findings in previous papers also support this ‘crowding-out’ hypothesis. In Peru and South

    Africa, Cox and Jimenez [1992] and Jensen [2003] find evidence that social security benefits and

    pensions ‘crowd out’ 20-30 percent of private transfers from younger generations to the elderly.

    Furthermore, Edmonds [2006] shows that working-age women tend to depart when their elderly

    household members start to receive a pension, whereas children and women of child-bearing age

    tend to move to live with the elderly. These changes in living arrangements could also potentially

    lead to a change in net transfers from the young to the elderly.

    A second possible mechanism for the null effect on this group is that, upon receiving the pen-

    sion, the elderly start transferring a substantial share of their basic pension to younger relatives.

    This would also diminish the positive impact of the pension on the income and health of the elderly,

    but it would increase working-age relatives’ income sufficiently to produce the observed spillover

    effects. Some evidence from previous research is line with this, as Duflo [2000, 2003] and Ard-

    ington et al. [2009] find that grandmothers in rural South Africa transfer some of their pension to

    their granddaughters and sons, respectively. However, this hypothesis does not seem very likely for

    Chilean grandparents: 82 percent of pension recipients do not share any money with their relatives

    or friends, and only 4 percent share more than one-fifth of their pension with others [Ministerio

    Trabajo y Previsión Social, 2017].

    Finally, a third explanation could be that living with working-age household members is a

    proxy for some other household characteristic. For example, families with working-age members

    may be larger, which may dilute the effect of the basic pension when household income is pooled;

    or the effect of the basic pension might be attenuated if applicants are already receiving proper care

    from younger relatives. This hypothesis is not supported by the data. In particular, when we repli-

    cate our results, controlling for a rich set of individual, household and residence characteristics, the

    heterogeneous results by household structure remain unchanged (Appendix Tables B5 and B6).

    7 Back-of-the-envelope computation: to what extent could thebasic pension close the gap in life expectancy?

    How far can the basic pension go in correcting health disparities across income levels in old age?

    To shed light on this question, we first calculate that treated applicants have an average income of

    US$221.04 at the time of application, which then increases to US$386.56 after receiving the basic

    pension. We denote the group of elderly people who do not receive a basic or contributory pension,

    31

  • Figure VI: Back-of-the-envelope computation: the effect of the basic pension on closing thesurvival gap over a four-year window

    1st payment

    .95

    .975

    1Sh

    are

    of s

    urvi

    vors

    0 1 2 3 4Years from application submission

    Control group Treatment groupCounterfactual control group

    Notes: This figure presents the share of survivors in the control group, treatment group and counterfactual controlgroup at each point in time following the first application and in a 500 score-point deviation bandwidth. Survival ratesare computed using a Cox proportional hazards model, adjusted for the deviation of the score from the cut-off.

    but who have the same income as pension recipients (US$386.56), as the counterfactual control

    group.

    Ideally, we would like to observe the income and mortality rates of the whole population of

    elderly people who are not receiving a contributory pension. We would then be able to calculate

    the following figures for the four years after applying for a basic pension: 1) the difference in

    life expectancy between the treatment and control groups at the cut-off; and, 2) the difference in

    life expectancy between the counterfactual control group and the control group at the cut-off. By

    dividing the first difference by the second, we could derive the ratio by which the basic pension

    income increase reduces the life expectancy gap between the people with an income equal to the

    control group at the cut-off (US$221.04) and the counterfactual control group (US$386.56). This

    would tell us to what extent the basic pension income increase can reduce health disparities across

    income levels, and to what extent these health disparities are permanent.

    32

  • Unfortunately, there is no data to compute the survival rates of elderly people by income level

    using the whole population. We circumvent this problem by first finding the pension score corre-

    sponding to the counterfactual control group income level in the pool of applicants. According to

    our records, applicants in the counterfactual control group received 585 points more than treated

    applicants at the cut-off. We then compute the share of survivors at the cut-off for the treated and

    control groups as in Figure V. As the characteristics of applicants and their households tend to

    change across the pension score distribution, we estimate the share of survivors for an applicant

    with the same characteristics as treated applicants at the cut-off, but with a pension score equal to

    the counterfactual control group.24 This allows us to compute the survival rates of the treatment

    and control groups at the cut-off and of the counterfactual control group.

    Figure VI shows the survival functions of each of these three groups at each observable point

    in time. The share of survivors drops by 7 percent for the control group, 5 percent for the treat-

    ment group and 2 percent for the counterfactual control group over the four-year window. The life

    expectancy of each group over the four years after applying is represented by the integral of each

    survival function. Taking the ratio of the differences in life expectancies noted above, we estimate

    that the basic pension closes 29 percent of the life expectancy gap between the control group at the

    cut-off and the counterfactual control group.

    8 Concluding remarks

    In this paper, we have explored the impact of a permanent increase of income for the elderly poor

    on their mortality and days of hospitalisations, as well as the spillover effects on their household

    members. By comparing applicants to a Chilean basic pension scheme, and their household mem-

    bers, in a narrow window around the eligibility threshold, the effects of this income increase have

    been disentangled in a regression discontinuity framework.

    This permanent increase in income sees a reduction in the mortality rates of basic pension re-

    cipients, at the point in time four years after they apply for the pension. This effect seems to be

    driven by higher consumption of goods that improve their health, such as vitamin-rich food, rather

    than by increased consumption of medicine or health insurance. This is in line with a wide range

    of literature that shows the impact of health-conducive goods on individuals’ health status [Bartali

    24We follow this approach, as we are interested in understanding by how much the basic pension income increasecan close the life expectancy gap between two persons with the same observable characteristics at two given incomelevels, rather than the ‘unconditional’ life expectancy gap between two persons at two given income levels.

    33

  • et al., 2006; Cederholm et al., 1995; Ortega et al., 1997; Fogel, 2004; Salm, 2011]. These results

    suggest that health inequalities in the elderly population are driven, at least in part, by contempo-

    raneous income inequalities.

    We also observe that the effect of the basic pension is concentrated on recipients who live alone

    or with another elderly person, while those who live with a working-age relative are not affected.

    An exploratory analysis shows that this last null effect is likely to be due to crowding-out effects:

    working-age relatives stop transferring a portion of their income to their elderly cohabitants once

    they start to receive the basic pension. In line with this hypothesis, we find that working-age rel-

    atives are more likely to have a newborn child nine months or later after the application is made.

    These results suggest that the financial burden imposed by the elderly poor on their younger rela-

    tives may be one of the channels through which poverty is transmitted, calling for further research

    in this area. Moreover, our results show that the effects of a non-contributory pension reach beyond

    the recipients to other household members. This is a relevant point for the optimal design of social

    pension policies, as the spillover effect can account for a significant share of the overall benefits of

    a pension.

    References

    Aguila, Emma, Arie Kapteyn, and James P Smith. 2015. “Effects of income supplementation

    on health of the poor elderly: The case of mexico”. Proceedings of the National Academy of

    Sciences 112(1), 70–75.

    Ardington, Cally, Anne Case, and Victoria Hosegood. 2009. “Labor supply responses to large

    social transfers: Longitudinal evidence from south africa”. American economic journal:

    Applied economics 1(1), 22–48.

    Bartali, Benedetta, Edward A Frongillo, Stefania Bandinelli, Fulvio Lauretani, Richard D Semba,

    Linda P Fried, and Luigi Ferrucci. 2006. “Low nutrient intake is an essential component

    of frailty in older persons”. The Journals of Gerontology Series A: Biological Sciences and

    Medical Sciences 61(6), 589–593.

    Becker, Gary S.. 1960. Demographic and Economic Change in Developed Countries, Chapter An

    Economic Analysis of Fertility, pp. 209–240. Princeton University Press.

    34

  • Braveman, Paula A., Catherine Cubbin, Susan Egerter, David R. Williams, and Elsie Pamuk.

    2010. “Socioeconomic disparities in health in the united states: what the patterns tell us”.

    American journal of public health 100(S1), S186–S196.

    Brønnum-Hansen, Henrik and Mikkel Baadsgaard. 2012. “Widening social inequality in life

    expectancy in denmark. a register-based study on social composition and mortality trends for

    the danish population”. BMC Public Health 12(1), 994.

    Browning, Martin and Costas Meghir. 1991. “The effects of male and female labor supply on

    commodity demands”. Econometrica 59(4), 925–951.

    Calonico, Sebastian, Matia D. Cattaneo, and Rocio Titiunik. 2014. “Robust Nonparametric

    Confidence Intervals for Regression-Discontinuity Designs”. Econometrica 82(6), 2295–2326.

    Case, Anne. 2004. “Does Money Protect Health Status? Ev