notes on technology, demand, and the size distribution of firms

165
SALES AND MARKUP DISPERSION: THEORY AND EMPIRICS Monika Mr´ azov´ a Geneva and CEPR J. Peter Neary Oxford, CEPR and CESifo Mathieu Parenti ULB and CEPR DEGIT XXI University of Nottingham September 1, 2016 MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 1 / 62

Upload: truongdien

Post on 06-Feb-2017

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

SALES AND MARKUP DISPERSION:THEORY AND EMPIRICS

Monika Mrazova

Geneva and CEPR

J. Peter Neary

Oxford, CEPR and CESifo

Mathieu Parenti

ULB and CEPR

DEGIT XXIUniversity of Nottingham

September 1, 2016

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 1 / 62

Page 2: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Models of Heterogeneous Agents

Distributionof Agent

Characteristics

Distributionof

Outcomes

Model ofIndividualBehaviour

+

Income distribution theory

Optimal income taxation

Urban economics

International trade: Heterogeneous firms

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 2 / 62

Page 3: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Models of Heterogeneous Agents

Distributionof Agent

Characteristics

Distributionof

Outcomes

Model ofIndividualBehaviour

+

Income distribution theory

Optimal income taxation

Urban economics

International trade: Heterogeneous firms

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 2 / 62

Page 4: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Models of Heterogeneous Agents

Distributionof Agent

Characteristics

Distributionof

Outcomes

Model ofIndividualBehaviour

+

Income distribution theory

Optimal income taxation

Urban economics

International trade: Heterogeneous firms

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 2 / 62

Page 5: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Models of Heterogeneous Firms

ProductivityDistribution

SalesDistribution

Demands

Technology

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 3 / 62

Page 6: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Models of Heterogeneous Firms

ProductivityDistribution

SalesDistribution

Demands

Technology“Dixit-Stiglitz”

(f, c)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 4 / 62

Page 7: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Models of Heterogeneous Firms

ProductivityDistribution

SalesDistributionDemands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 5 / 62

Page 8: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

The Canonical Model of Heterogeneous Firms

ParetoProductivities

ParetoSales

CESDemands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 6 / 62

Page 9: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

The Canonical Result: HMY-Chaney

ParetoProductivities

ParetoSales

CESDemands+

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 7 / 62

Page 10: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Problems with The Canonical Model

Canonical Model:

Pareto distribution of productivities

CES demands

Pareto distribution of sales

Justified on the grounds that:

Distribution of firm sales is close to Pareto ... in the upper tail

Theoretical tractability

But:

Distribution of firm sales is not necessarily Pareto

Head, Mayer and Thoenig (2014) show the result holds for log-normal

CES implies a Dirac distribution of mark-ups (no competition effects)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 8 / 62

Page 11: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Problems with The Canonical Model

Canonical Model:

Pareto distribution of productivities

CES demands

Pareto distribution of sales

Justified on the grounds that:

Distribution of firm sales is close to Pareto ... in the upper tail

Theoretical tractability

But:

Distribution of firm sales is not necessarily Pareto

Head, Mayer and Thoenig (2014) show the result holds for log-normal

CES implies a Dirac distribution of mark-ups (no competition effects)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 8 / 62

Page 12: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Problems with The Canonical Model

Canonical Model:

Pareto distribution of productivities

CES demands

Pareto distribution of sales

Justified on the grounds that:

Distribution of firm sales is close to Pareto ... in the upper tail

Theoretical tractability

But:

Distribution of firm sales is not necessarily Pareto

Head, Mayer and Thoenig (2014) show the result holds for log-normal

CES implies a Dirac distribution of mark-ups (no competition effects)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 8 / 62

Page 13: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Beyond the Canonical Result: Head-Mayer-Thoenig

Log-normalProductivities

Log-normalSales

CESDemands+

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 9 / 62

Page 14: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Problems with The Canonical Model

Canonical Model:

Pareto distribution of productivities

CES demands

Pareto distribution of sales

Justified on the grounds that:

Distribution of firm sales is close to Pareto ... in the upper tail

Theoretical tractability

But:

Distribution of firm sales is not necessarily Pareto

Head, Mayer and Thoenig (2014) show the result holds for log-normal

CES implies a Dirac distribution of mark-ups (no competition effects)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 10 / 62

Page 15: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Empirical Evidence on Mark-Up Distributions I

Figure 3: Distribution of Prices in 1989 and 1997

01

23

Den

sity

−.4 −.2 0 .2 .4Log Prices

1989 1997

Sample only includes firm−product pairs present in 1989 and 1997.Outliers above and below the 3rd and 97th percentiles are trimmed.

Distribution of Prices

Figure 4: Distribution of Markups and Marginal Costs in 1989 and 1997

0.5

11.

52

Den

sity

−1 −.5 0 .5 1Log Markups

1989 1997

Sample only includes firm−product pairs present in 1989 and 1997.Outliers above and below the 3rd and 97th percentiles are trimmed.

Distribution of Markups

0.5

11.

5D

ensi

ty

−1 −.5 0 .5 1Log Marginal Costs

1989 1997

Sample only includes firm−product pairs present in 1989 and 1997.Outliers above and below the 3rd and 97th percentiles are trimmed.

Distribution of Marginal Costs

Appendix

A A Formal Model of Input Price Variation

This appendix provides a formal economic model that rationalizes the use of a exible polynomial

in output price, market share and product dummies to control for input prices. The model is a

more general version of the models considered in Kremer (1993) and Verhoogen (2008).

We proceed in the following steps. We rst show that under the assumptions of the model, the

51

From: de Loecker, Goldberg, Khandelwal and Pavcnik (2014)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 11 / 62

Page 16: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Empirical Evidence on Mark-Up Distributions II

From: Lamorgese, Linarello and Warzynski (2014)

Theory

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 12 / 62

Page 17: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Our Contribution

Characterize exact implications of alternative assumptions about:Demand

Distribution of firm productivities

. . . For:Distribution of firm sales

Distribution of mark-ups

Quantify the “goodness of fit” of inexact assumptions using:

Indian data on sales and markups (Thanks to Jan de Loecker)

French data on exports (Thanks to Julien Martin)

Applications:New family of distributions that nests Pareto, log-normal and Frechet

New demand function: “CREMR” - “Constant Revenue Elasticity ofMarginal Revenue”

Summary of Results

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 13 / 62

Page 18: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Our Contribution

Characterize exact implications of alternative assumptions about:Demand

Distribution of firm productivities

. . . For:Distribution of firm sales

Distribution of mark-ups

Quantify the “goodness of fit” of inexact assumptions using:

Indian data on sales and markups (Thanks to Jan de Loecker)

French data on exports (Thanks to Julien Martin)

Applications:New family of distributions that nests Pareto, log-normal and Frechet

New demand function: “CREMR” - “Constant Revenue Elasticity ofMarginal Revenue”

Summary of Results

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 13 / 62

Page 19: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Our Contribution

Characterize exact implications of alternative assumptions about:Demand

Distribution of firm productivities

. . . For:Distribution of firm sales

Distribution of mark-ups

Quantify the “goodness of fit” of inexact assumptions using:

Indian data on sales and markups (Thanks to Jan de Loecker)

French data on exports (Thanks to Julien Martin)

Applications:New family of distributions that nests Pareto, log-normal and Frechet

New demand function: “CREMR” - “Constant Revenue Elasticity ofMarginal Revenue”

Summary of Results

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 13 / 62

Page 20: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Why Should We Care?

Distributions of sales and mark-ups matter for:

Interpretation of trade elasticities

Chaney (2008), Arkolakis et al. (2013)

Granular origins of aggregate fluctuations

Gabaix (2011), Di Giovanni and Levchenko (2015)

Quantifying the misallocation of resources

Hsieh and Klenow (2009)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 14 / 62

Page 21: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Related Work I

Canonical Model:

Melitz (2003), Helpman-Melitz-Yeaple (2004), Chaney (2006)

Mark-Ups Increasing in Firm Size/Competition Effects:

ZKPT (2013), Bertoletti-Epifani (2014): Only with subconvex demand

Proliferation of subconvex alternatives to CES:

Quadratic preferences: Melitz-Ottaviano (2008)Stone-Geary LES: Simonovska (2010)Translog: Feenstra-Weinstein (2010)Negative exponential/CARA: Behrens-Murata (2007)Bulow-Pfleiderer: Atkin-Donaldson (2012)QMOR: Feenstra (2014)APT and Laplace Transform: Fabinger-Weyl (2015)Mrazova-Neary (2013)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 15 / 62

Page 22: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Related Work II

Size Distribution of Sales - Theory:

Pareto: Helpman-Melitz-Yeaple (2004), Chaney (2006)Log-normal: Head-Mayer-Thoenig (2014)Frechet: Eaton-Kortum (2002), Tintelnot (2014)

Size Distribution of Sales - Empirics:

Pareto: Axtell (2001), Corcos-del Gatto-Mion-Ottaviano (2012)Mixture of thin- and fat-tailed Pareto: Edmonds et al. (2015)Log-normal: Bee-Schiavo (2014)Piecewise log-normal-Pareto: Luttmer (2007), Eaton et al. (2011)Mixture of log-normal and Pareto: Combes et al. (2014)

Distribution of Mark-Ups:

Lamorgese, Linarello and Warzynski (2014)Edmonds et al. (2015)De Loecker, Goldberg, Khandelwal and Pavcnik (2015)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 16 / 62

Page 23: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Related Work III

Information theory: Shannon (1948), Kullback-Leibler (1951)

Economic applications of Shannon Entropy:

Inequality: Theil (1967)

Macro: Sims (2003) on rational inattention

Decision theory: Maccheroni-Marinacci-Rustichini (2006),Cabrales-Gossner-Serrano (2013)

Trade: Dasgupta-Mondria (2014)

Economic applications of Kullback-Leibler Divergence:

Econometrics: Vuong (1989), Cameron-Windmeijer (1997), Ullah(2002)

Consumer economics: Adams (2014)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 17 / 62

Page 24: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Introduction

Outline

1 Introduction

2 General Results

3 Backing Out Demands

4 Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

5 From Theory to Calibration

6 Empirics

7 Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 18 / 62

Page 25: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Outline

1 Introduction

2 General Results

3 Backing Out Demands

4 Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

5 From Theory to Calibration

6 Empirics

7 Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 19 / 62

Page 26: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 1: A General Characterization Result

Characteristicx G(x)

Characteristicy F(y)

Firm Behaviourx = v(y)

Proposition 1: Any two imply the third

Proposition 2 Section 3 Section 4 Sections 5 and 6

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 20 / 62

Page 27: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 1: Formal Statement

Assumption A1: i, x(i), y(i) ∈[Ω× (x, x)× (y, y)

], where Ω is the set

of firms, with both x(i) and y(i) monotonically increasing functions of i.

Proposition 1: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x is distributed with CDF G(x), where g(x) = G′(x) > 0;

2 y is distributed with CDF F (y), where f(y) = F ′(y) > 0;

3 x = v(y), v′(y) > 0;

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with F (y) = G[v(y)] and f(y) = g[v(y)]v′(y).

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with v(y) = G−1[F (y)].

Part (i) is standard; part (ii) is not, and requires Assumption 1.[Matzkin (2003)]

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 21 / 62

Page 28: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 1: Formal Statement

Assumption A1: i, x(i), y(i) ∈[Ω× (x, x)× (y, y)

], where Ω is the set

of firms, with both x(i) and y(i) monotonically increasing functions of i.

Proposition 1: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x is distributed with CDF G(x), where g(x) = G′(x) > 0;

2 y is distributed with CDF F (y), where f(y) = F ′(y) > 0;

3 x = v(y), v′(y) > 0;

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with F (y) = G[v(y)] and f(y) = g[v(y)]v′(y).

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with v(y) = G−1[F (y)].

Part (i) is standard; part (ii) is not, and requires Assumption 1.[Matzkin (2003)]

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 21 / 62

Page 29: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 1: Formal Statement

Assumption A1: i, x(i), y(i) ∈[Ω× (x, x)× (y, y)

], where Ω is the set

of firms, with both x(i) and y(i) monotonically increasing functions of i.

Proposition 1: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x is distributed with CDF G(x), where g(x) = G′(x) > 0;

2 y is distributed with CDF F (y), where f(y) = F ′(y) > 0;

3 x = v(y), v′(y) > 0;

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with F (y) = G[v(y)] and f(y) = g[v(y)]v′(y).

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with v(y) = G−1[F (y)].

Part (i) is standard; part (ii) is not, and requires Assumption 1.[Matzkin (2003)]

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 21 / 62

Page 30: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 1: Formal Statement

Assumption A1: i, x(i), y(i) ∈[Ω× (x, x)× (y, y)

], where Ω is the set

of firms, with both x(i) and y(i) monotonically increasing functions of i.

Proposition 1: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x is distributed with CDF G(x), where g(x) = G′(x) > 0;

2 y is distributed with CDF F (y), where f(y) = F ′(y) > 0;

3 x = v(y), v′(y) > 0;

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with F (y) = G[v(y)] and f(y) = g[v(y)]v′(y).

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with v(y) = G−1[F (y)].

Part (i) is standard; part (ii) is not, and requires Assumption 1.[Matzkin (2003)]

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 21 / 62

Page 31: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2

Characteristicx G(x; )

Characteristicy G[h(y); ]

Firm Behaviourx = x0h(y)E

Proposition 2: Any two imply the third

Proposition 1 Section 3 Section 4 Sections 5 and 6

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 22 / 62

Page 32: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Formal Statement

Proposition 2: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with θ′1 = Eθ1xθ20 and θ′2 = Eθ2.

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with E =θ′2θ2

and x0 =(θ2θ1

θ′1θ′2

) 1θ2 . KLD

“Generalized Power Function” [“GPF”] Family of Distributions:

Includes: Pareto, truncated Pareto, log-normal, Frechet, etc. Details

All with 2 free parameters

H(·), h(·): Completely general, except sgn(H ′) = sgn(θ1) and h′ > 0

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 23 / 62

Page 33: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Formal Statement

Proposition 2: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with θ′1 = Eθ1xθ20 and θ′2 = Eθ2.

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with E =θ′2θ2

and x0 =(θ2θ1

θ′1θ′2

) 1θ2 . KLD

“Generalized Power Function” [“GPF”] Family of Distributions:

Includes: Pareto, truncated Pareto, log-normal, Frechet, etc. Details

All with 2 free parameters

H(·), h(·): Completely general, except sgn(H ′) = sgn(θ1) and h′ > 0

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 23 / 62

Page 34: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Formal Statement

Proposition 2: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with θ′1 = Eθ1xθ20 and θ′2 = Eθ2.

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with E =θ′2θ2

and x0 =(θ2θ1

θ′1θ′2

) 1θ2 . KLD

“Generalized Power Function” [“GPF”] Family of Distributions:

Includes: Pareto, truncated Pareto, log-normal, Frechet, etc. Details

All with 2 free parameters

H(·), h(·): Completely general, except sgn(H ′) = sgn(θ1) and h′ > 0

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 23 / 62

Page 35: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Formal Statement

Proposition 2: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with θ′1 = Eθ1xθ20 and θ′2 = Eθ2.

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with E =θ′2θ2

and x0 =(θ2θ1

θ′1θ′2

) 1θ2 . KLD

“Generalized Power Function” [“GPF”] Family of Distributions:

Includes: Pareto, truncated Pareto, log-normal, Frechet, etc. Details

All with 2 free parameters

H(·), h(·): Completely general, except sgn(H ′) = sgn(θ1) and h′ > 0

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 23 / 62

Page 36: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Formal Statement

Proposition 2: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with θ′1 = Eθ1xθ20 and θ′2 = Eθ2.

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with E =θ′2θ2

and x0 =(θ2θ1

θ′1θ′2

) 1θ2 . KLD

“Generalized Power Function” [“GPF”] Family of Distributions:

Includes: Pareto, truncated Pareto, log-normal, Frechet, etc. Details

All with 2 free parameters

H(·), h(·): Completely general, except sgn(H ′) = sgn(θ1) and h′ > 0

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 23 / 62

Page 37: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Formal Statement

Proposition 2: Given A1, any two of (1)–(3) imply the third: Proof

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

where:

(i) (1) + (3) ⇒ (2) with θ′1 = Eθ1xθ20 and θ′2 = Eθ2.

(ii) (1) + (2) ⇒ (3) with E =θ′2θ2

and x0 =(θ2θ1

θ′1θ′2

) 1θ2 . KLD

“Generalized Power Function” [“GPF”] Family of Distributions:

Includes: Pareto, truncated Pareto, log-normal, Frechet, etc. Details

All with 2 free parameters

H(·), h(·): Completely general, except sgn(H ′) = sgn(θ1) and h′ > 0

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 23 / 62

Page 38: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Special Cases

Proposition 2:

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

Two special cases of h(y):

h(y) = y: “Self-reflection” → Distributions of sales and output

h(y) = y1−y : “Odds reflection” → Distributions of mark-ups Details

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 24 / 62

Page 39: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Special Cases

Proposition 2:

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

Two special cases of h(y):

h(y) = y: “Self-reflection” → Distributions of sales and output

h(y) = y1−y : “Odds reflection” → Distributions of mark-ups Details

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 24 / 62

Page 40: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

General Results

Proposition 2: Special Cases

Proposition 2:

1 x has CDF: G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0

2 y has CDF: F (y; θ′) = G [h(y); θ′] = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Fy > 0

3 x = x0h(y)E

Two special cases of h(y):

h(y) = y: “Self-reflection” → Distributions of sales and output

h(y) = y1−y : “Odds reflection” → Distributions of mark-ups Details

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 24 / 62

Page 41: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

Outline

1 Introduction

2 General Results

3 Backing Out Demands

4 Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

5 From Theory to Calibration

6 Empirics

7 Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 25 / 62

Page 42: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

Section 3: Backing Out Demands

Productivity G(; )

Salesr G[r; ]

Demand

Proposition 1 Proposition 2 Section 4 Sections 5 and 6

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 26 / 62

Page 43: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

Which Demands are Consistent with Self-Reflection?

GPFProductivities

GPFSales

CREMR: = 0rE

Corollary 1: Any two imply the third

Compare Corollary 3

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 27 / 62

Page 44: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

CREMR Demands

From Proposition 2: Self-reflection IFF ϕ = ϕ0rE

Implications for demand? We need more assumptions:

MR=MC ⇒ ϕ ≡ c−1 = (r′)−1

All firms face the same residual demand function: r(x) = xp(x)

These imply a simple differential equation:

ϕ = ϕ0rE ⇒ [r′(x)]−1 = ϕ0r(x)E

Hence “CREMR”: “Constant Revenue Elasticity of Marginal Revenue”

Integrate to get CREMR demand function: Details

p(x) =β

x(x− γ)

σ−1σ

Restrictions: 1 < σ <∞, x > γσ, β > 0

CES a special case: γ = 0 ⇒ p(x) = βx−1/σ

CREMR elasticity of demand: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ

Compare CEMR Demands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 28 / 62

Page 45: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

CREMR Demands

From Proposition 2: Self-reflection IFF ϕ = ϕ0rE

Implications for demand? We need more assumptions:

MR=MC ⇒ ϕ ≡ c−1 = (r′)−1

All firms face the same residual demand function: r(x) = xp(x)

These imply a simple differential equation:

ϕ = ϕ0rE ⇒ [r′(x)]−1 = ϕ0r(x)E

Hence “CREMR”: “Constant Revenue Elasticity of Marginal Revenue”

Integrate to get CREMR demand function: Details

p(x) =β

x(x− γ)

σ−1σ

Restrictions: 1 < σ <∞, x > γσ, β > 0

CES a special case: γ = 0 ⇒ p(x) = βx−1/σ

CREMR elasticity of demand: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ

Compare CEMR Demands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 28 / 62

Page 46: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

CREMR Demands

From Proposition 2: Self-reflection IFF ϕ = ϕ0rE

Implications for demand? We need more assumptions:

MR=MC ⇒ ϕ ≡ c−1 = (r′)−1

All firms face the same residual demand function: r(x) = xp(x)

These imply a simple differential equation:

ϕ = ϕ0rE ⇒ [r′(x)]−1 = ϕ0r(x)E

Hence “CREMR”: “Constant Revenue Elasticity of Marginal Revenue”

Integrate to get CREMR demand function: Details

p(x) =β

x(x− γ)

σ−1σ

Restrictions: 1 < σ <∞, x > γσ, β > 0

CES a special case: γ = 0 ⇒ p(x) = βx−1/σ

CREMR elasticity of demand: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ

Compare CEMR Demands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 28 / 62

Page 47: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

CREMR Demands

From Proposition 2: Self-reflection IFF ϕ = ϕ0rE

Implications for demand? We need more assumptions:

MR=MC ⇒ ϕ ≡ c−1 = (r′)−1

All firms face the same residual demand function: r(x) = xp(x)

These imply a simple differential equation:

ϕ = ϕ0rE ⇒ [r′(x)]−1 = ϕ0r(x)E

Hence “CREMR”: “Constant Revenue Elasticity of Marginal Revenue”

Integrate to get CREMR demand function: Details

p(x) =β

x(x− γ)

σ−1σ

Restrictions: 1 < σ <∞, x > γσ, β > 0

CES a special case: γ = 0 ⇒ p(x) = βx−1/σ

CREMR elasticity of demand: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ

Compare CEMR Demands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 28 / 62

Page 48: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

CREMR Demands

From Proposition 2: Self-reflection IFF ϕ = ϕ0rE

Implications for demand? We need more assumptions:

MR=MC ⇒ ϕ ≡ c−1 = (r′)−1

All firms face the same residual demand function: r(x) = xp(x)

These imply a simple differential equation:

ϕ = ϕ0rE ⇒ [r′(x)]−1 = ϕ0r(x)E

Hence “CREMR”: “Constant Revenue Elasticity of Marginal Revenue”

Integrate to get CREMR demand function: Details

p(x) =β

x(x− γ)

σ−1σ

Restrictions: 1 < σ <∞, x > γσ, β > 0

CES a special case: γ = 0 ⇒ p(x) = βx−1/σ

CREMR elasticity of demand: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ

Compare CEMR Demands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 28 / 62

Page 49: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

Properties of CREMR Demand Functions

σ: Elasticity parameter

Lower bound for demand elasticity (when γ > 0)

“REMR” E depends only on σ: E = 1σ−1 [Chaney: CES]

e.g.,

ϕ Pareto with shape k

CREMR

⇒ r Pareto with shape k

σ−1

“Normal” selection effects: Profit function “supermodular” IFF σ ≥ 2

γ: Markup parameter

CREMR nests CES when γ = 0

For any γ, CREMR converges to CES as x→∞Variable mark-ups: For any γ 6= 0

Competition effects: “Subconvex” IFF γ ≥ 0

Utility function is analytic and can be simulated Utility Function

Very different from standard demand functions

Illustrations CREMR Demand Manifold Other Corollaries

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 29 / 62

Page 50: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

Properties of CREMR Demand Functions

σ: Elasticity parameter

Lower bound for demand elasticity (when γ > 0)

“REMR” E depends only on σ: E = 1σ−1 [Chaney: CES]

e.g.,

ϕ Pareto with shape k

CREMR

⇒ r Pareto with shape k

σ−1

“Normal” selection effects: Profit function “supermodular” IFF σ ≥ 2

γ: Markup parameter

CREMR nests CES when γ = 0

For any γ, CREMR converges to CES as x→∞Variable mark-ups: For any γ 6= 0

Competition effects: “Subconvex” IFF γ ≥ 0

Utility function is analytic and can be simulated Utility Function

Very different from standard demand functions

Illustrations CREMR Demand Manifold Other Corollaries

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 29 / 62

Page 51: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

Properties of CREMR Demand Functions

σ: Elasticity parameter

Lower bound for demand elasticity (when γ > 0)

“REMR” E depends only on σ: E = 1σ−1 [Chaney: CES]

e.g.,

ϕ Pareto with shape k

CREMR

⇒ r Pareto with shape k

σ−1

“Normal” selection effects: Profit function “supermodular” IFF σ ≥ 2

γ: Markup parameter

CREMR nests CES when γ = 0

For any γ, CREMR converges to CES as x→∞Variable mark-ups: For any γ 6= 0

Competition effects: “Subconvex” IFF γ ≥ 0

Utility function is analytic and can be simulated Utility Function

Very different from standard demand functions

Illustrations CREMR Demand Manifold Other Corollaries

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 29 / 62

Page 52: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Backing Out Demands

Properties of CREMR Demand Functions

σ: Elasticity parameter

Lower bound for demand elasticity (when γ > 0)

“REMR” E depends only on σ: E = 1σ−1 [Chaney: CES]

e.g.,

ϕ Pareto with shape k

CREMR

⇒ r Pareto with shape k

σ−1

“Normal” selection effects: Profit function “supermodular” IFF σ ≥ 2

γ: Markup parameter

CREMR nests CES when γ = 0

For any γ, CREMR converges to CES as x→∞Variable mark-ups: For any γ 6= 0

Competition effects: “Subconvex” IFF γ ≥ 0

Utility function is analytic and can be simulated Utility Function

Very different from standard demand functions

Illustrations CREMR Demand Manifold Other Corollaries

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 29 / 62

Page 53: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

Outline

1 Introduction

2 General Results

3 Backing Out Demands

4 Inferring Sales and Mark-Up DistributionsMarkups with CREMR DemandsOther Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

5 From Theory to Calibration

6 Empirics

7 Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 30 / 62

Page 54: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

Section 4: Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

Productivity G()

Sales: r Fr(r)Markups: m Fm(m)

Demandp = p(x)

Proposition 1 Proposition 2 Section 3 Sections 5 and 6

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 31 / 62

Page 55: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR Demands

Mark-ups in general: m(x) ≡ pc = ε(x)

ε(x)−1

CREMR mark-up: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ ⇒ m(x) = x−γ

xσσ−1

With subconvex demands (γ > 0), larger firms have higher markups:

m(x) ∈[m, σ

σ−1

]as x ∈ [x,∞]

Define the relative mark-up: m ≡ mm = σ−1

σ m ∈ [m, 1]

So: m(x) = x−γx

Productivity and markups: Details

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

Satisfies Proposition 2’s conditions for “Odds Reflection” Recall

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 32 / 62

Page 56: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR Demands

Mark-ups in general: m(x) ≡ pc = ε(x)

ε(x)−1

CREMR mark-up: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ ⇒ m(x) = x−γ

xσσ−1

With subconvex demands (γ > 0), larger firms have higher markups:

m(x) ∈[m, σ

σ−1

]as x ∈ [x,∞]

Define the relative mark-up: m ≡ mm = σ−1

σ m ∈ [m, 1]

So: m(x) = x−γx

Productivity and markups: Details

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

Satisfies Proposition 2’s conditions for “Odds Reflection” Recall

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 32 / 62

Page 57: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR Demands

Mark-ups in general: m(x) ≡ pc = ε(x)

ε(x)−1

CREMR mark-up: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ ⇒ m(x) = x−γ

xσσ−1

With subconvex demands (γ > 0), larger firms have higher markups:

m(x) ∈[m, σ

σ−1

]as x ∈ [x,∞]

Define the relative mark-up: m ≡ mm = σ−1

σ m ∈ [m, 1]

So: m(x) = x−γx

Productivity and markups: Details

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

Satisfies Proposition 2’s conditions for “Odds Reflection” Recall

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 32 / 62

Page 58: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR Demands

Mark-ups in general: m(x) ≡ pc = ε(x)

ε(x)−1

CREMR mark-up: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ ⇒ m(x) = x−γ

xσσ−1

With subconvex demands (γ > 0), larger firms have higher markups:

m(x) ∈[m, σ

σ−1

]as x ∈ [x,∞]

Define the relative mark-up: m ≡ mm = σ−1

σ m ∈ [m, 1]

So: m(x) = x−γx

Productivity and markups: Details

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

Satisfies Proposition 2’s conditions for “Odds Reflection” Recall

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 32 / 62

Page 59: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR Demands

Mark-ups in general: m(x) ≡ pc = ε(x)

ε(x)−1

CREMR mark-up: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ ⇒ m(x) = x−γ

xσσ−1

With subconvex demands (γ > 0), larger firms have higher markups:

m(x) ∈[m, σ

σ−1

]as x ∈ [x,∞]

Define the relative mark-up: m ≡ mm = σ−1

σ m ∈ [m, 1]

So: m(x) = x−γx

Productivity and markups: Details

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

Satisfies Proposition 2’s conditions for “Odds Reflection” Recall

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 32 / 62

Page 60: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR Demands

Mark-ups in general: m(x) ≡ pc = ε(x)

ε(x)−1

CREMR mark-up: ε(x) = x−γx−γσσ ⇒ m(x) = x−γ

xσσ−1

With subconvex demands (γ > 0), larger firms have higher markups:

m(x) ∈[m, σ

σ−1

]as x ∈ [x,∞]

Define the relative mark-up: m ≡ mm = σ−1

σ m ∈ [m, 1]

So: m(x) = x−γx

Productivity and markups: Details

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

Satisfies Proposition 2’s conditions for “Odds Reflection” Recall

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 32 / 62

Page 61: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR and GPF Productivity

From Proposition 2:

GPF Productivity + CREMR demand ⇒ “GPF-Odds” markups

Examples:

1 Pareto productivity G (ϕ) = 1−(ϕ

ϕ

)k⇒ “Pareto-Odds” markups: F (m) = 1−

(m

1−m

)n′ (m

1−m

)−n′2 Log-Normal productivity G(ϕ) = Φ

[1s logϕ− µ

]⇒ “Log-Normal-Odds” markups: F (m) = Φ

[1s′

log m

1−m − µ′]

3 Frechet productivity ⇒ “Frechet-Odds” markups

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 33 / 62

Page 62: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR and GPF Productivity

From Proposition 2:

GPF Productivity + CREMR demand ⇒ “GPF-Odds” markups

Examples:

1 Pareto productivity G (ϕ) = 1−(ϕ

ϕ

)k⇒ “Pareto-Odds” markups: F (m) = 1−

(m

1−m

)n′ (m

1−m

)−n′

2 Log-Normal productivity G(ϕ) = Φ[

1s logϕ− µ

]⇒ “Log-Normal-Odds” markups: F (m) = Φ

[1s′

log m

1−m − µ′]

3 Frechet productivity ⇒ “Frechet-Odds” markups

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 33 / 62

Page 63: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR and GPF Productivity

From Proposition 2:

GPF Productivity + CREMR demand ⇒ “GPF-Odds” markups

Examples:

1 Pareto productivity G (ϕ) = 1−(ϕ

ϕ

)k⇒ “Pareto-Odds” markups: F (m) = 1−

(m

1−m

)n′ (m

1−m

)−n′2 Log-Normal productivity G(ϕ) = Φ

[1s logϕ− µ

]⇒ “Log-Normal-Odds” markups: F (m) = Φ

[1s′

log m

1−m − µ′]

3 Frechet productivity ⇒ “Frechet-Odds” markups

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 33 / 62

Page 64: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

Markups with CREMR and GPF Productivity

From Proposition 2:

GPF Productivity + CREMR demand ⇒ “GPF-Odds” markups

Examples:

1 Pareto productivity G (ϕ) = 1−(ϕ

ϕ

)k⇒ “Pareto-Odds” markups: F (m) = 1−

(m

1−m

)n′ (m

1−m

)−n′2 Log-Normal productivity G(ϕ) = Φ

[1s logϕ− µ

]⇒ “Log-Normal-Odds” markups: F (m) = Φ

[1s′

log m

1−m − µ′]

3 Frechet productivity ⇒ “Frechet-Odds” markups

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 33 / 62

Page 65: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Markups with CREMR Demands

The Log-Normal-Odds Distribution of Mark-UpsIntroduction From theory to data Empirics

Logit-normal

a.k.a. “Logit-Normal” [Johnson (1949), Mead (1965)]

Matches empirical mark-up distribution Recall

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 34 / 62

Page 66: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Other Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

Other Sales and Markup Distributions

p(x) or x(p) ϕ(r) or ϕ(r) ϕ(m) or ϕ(m)

CREMR βx (x− γ)

σ−1σ ϕ0r

1σ−1 ϕ0

(m

1−m

) 1σ

Linear α− βx 1α

(1

1−r

) 12 2m−1

α

LES δx+γ γδ

(1

1−r

)2γδm

2

Translog 1p (γ − η log p) ϕ0 exp

(rη

)m exp

(m− η+γ

η

)

Productivity as a Function of Sales and MarkupsFor Selected Demand Functions

Empirics 1 Empirics 2

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 35 / 62

Page 67: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions Other Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

Other Sales and Markup Distributions

p(x) or x(p) ϕ(r) or ϕ(r) ϕ(m) or ϕ(m)

CREMR βx (x− γ)

σ−1σ ϕ0r

1σ−1 ϕ0

(m

1−m

) 1σ

Linear α− βx 1α

(1

1−r

) 12 2m−1

α

LES δx+γ γδ

(1

1−r

)2γδm

2

Translog 1p (γ − η log p) ϕ0 exp

(rη

)m exp

(m− η+γ

η

)

Productivity as a Function of Sales and MarkupsFor Selected Demand Functions

Empirics 1 Empirics 2

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 35 / 62

Page 68: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration

Outline

1 Introduction

2 General Results

3 Backing Out Demands

4 Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

5 From Theory to Calibration“Goodness of Fit” for DistributionsThe Kullback-Leibler Divergence

6 Empirics

7 Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 36 / 62

Page 69: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration

Sections 5 and 6: Confronting Theory and Data

Data:Sales: r Fr(r)

Markups: m Fm(m)

Sales: r Fr(r)Markups: m Fm(m)

Productivity G()

Demandp = p(x)

Proposition 1 Proposition 2 Section 3 Section 4

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 37 / 62

Page 70: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration “Goodness of Fit” for Distributions

“Goodness of Fit” for Distributions

So far: Exact characterizations linking distributions and demands

BUT: Does this matter?

..... quantitatively?

How do we quantify the cost of predicting the wrong distribution?

We use the Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Plus the QQ estimator as a robustness check

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 38 / 62

Page 71: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration “Goodness of Fit” for Distributions

“Goodness of Fit” for Distributions

So far: Exact characterizations linking distributions and demands

BUT: Does this matter?

..... quantitatively?

How do we quantify the cost of predicting the wrong distribution?

We use the Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Plus the QQ estimator as a robustness check

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 38 / 62

Page 72: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration “Goodness of Fit” for Distributions

“Goodness of Fit” for Distributions

So far: Exact characterizations linking distributions and demands

BUT: Does this matter?

..... quantitatively?

How do we quantify the cost of predicting the wrong distribution?

We use the Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Plus the QQ estimator as a robustness check

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 38 / 62

Page 73: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration The Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Kullback-Leibler Divergence

KLD: Measures the “information loss” or “relative entropy” when onedistribution, F , is used to approximate another, F :

DKL(F ||F

)≡∫ r

r

log

(f(r)

f(r)

)f(r)dr

In our case:

F (r): Actual distribution of firm sales Empirics

F (r; θ): Distribution of firm sales implied by:G(ϕ): Distribution of firm productivities

ϕ(r; θ): Model of firm behaviour, parameterized by θ

Desirable features:

Axiomatic foundation in information theory Background

Statistical interpretation: Expected value of log-likelihood ratio

Links with Proposition 2: KLD can be decomposed to show that onecomponent depends on variations in the REMR Details

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 39 / 62

Page 74: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration The Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Kullback-Leibler Divergence

KLD: Measures the “information loss” or “relative entropy” when onedistribution, F , is used to approximate another, F :

DKL(F ||F

)≡∫ r

r

log

(f(r)

f(r)

)f(r)dr

In our case:

F (r): Actual distribution of firm sales Empirics

F (r; θ): Distribution of firm sales implied by:G(ϕ): Distribution of firm productivities

ϕ(r; θ): Model of firm behaviour, parameterized by θ

Desirable features:

Axiomatic foundation in information theory Background

Statistical interpretation: Expected value of log-likelihood ratio

Links with Proposition 2: KLD can be decomposed to show that onecomponent depends on variations in the REMR Details

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 39 / 62

Page 75: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

From Theory to Calibration The Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Kullback-Leibler Divergence

KLD: Measures the “information loss” or “relative entropy” when onedistribution, F , is used to approximate another, F :

DKL(F ||F

)≡∫ r

r

log

(f(r)

f(r)

)f(r)dr

In our case:

F (r): Actual distribution of firm sales Empirics

F (r; θ): Distribution of firm sales implied by:G(ϕ): Distribution of firm productivities

ϕ(r; θ): Model of firm behaviour, parameterized by θ

Desirable features:

Axiomatic foundation in information theory Background

Statistical interpretation: Expected value of log-likelihood ratio

Links with Proposition 2: KLD can be decomposed to show that onecomponent depends on variations in the REMR Details

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 39 / 62

Page 76: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics

Outline

1 Introduction

2 General Results

3 Backing Out Demands

4 Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

5 From Theory to Calibration

6 EmpiricsOperationalizing the KLDFrench Exports to GermanyIndian Sales and MarkupsRobustness: The QQ EstimatorRobustness to Truncation

7 ConclusionMNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 40 / 62

Page 77: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Operationalizing the KLD

Operationalizing the KLD

Discrete counterpart of continuous KLD: Compare QQ Estimator

DKL(F || F (· ;θ)) =

nb∑i=1

log

(∆Fi∆Fi

)∆Fi

∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b) ∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b)

nb: Number of bins of width b, dividing the support of F , [r, r]nb = 1, 000 in all cases (except nb = 40 in draft paper)French results not very sensitive to bin sizeIndian results are more sensitive

We report below DKL(F || F (· ; θ))

θ: Parameter vector that minimizes DKL(F || F (· ;θ))

Units of measurement:KLD usually measured in “bits” (log to base 2) or “nats” (natural logs)Here we present results relative to a uniform benchmark Details

Analogous to “dartboard” (Ellison-Glaeser (1997)) or “balls and bins”approaches (Armenter-Koren (2014))

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 41 / 62

Page 78: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Operationalizing the KLD

Operationalizing the KLD

Discrete counterpart of continuous KLD: Compare QQ Estimator

DKL(F || F (· ;θ)) =

nb∑i=1

log

(∆Fi∆Fi

)∆Fi

∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b) ∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b)

nb: Number of bins of width b, dividing the support of F , [r, r]nb = 1, 000 in all cases (except nb = 40 in draft paper)French results not very sensitive to bin sizeIndian results are more sensitive

We report below DKL(F || F (· ; θ))

θ: Parameter vector that minimizes DKL(F || F (· ;θ))

Units of measurement:KLD usually measured in “bits” (log to base 2) or “nats” (natural logs)Here we present results relative to a uniform benchmark Details

Analogous to “dartboard” (Ellison-Glaeser (1997)) or “balls and bins”approaches (Armenter-Koren (2014))

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 41 / 62

Page 79: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Operationalizing the KLD

Operationalizing the KLD

Discrete counterpart of continuous KLD: Compare QQ Estimator

DKL(F || F (· ;θ)) =

nb∑i=1

log

(∆Fi∆Fi

)∆Fi

∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b) ∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b)

nb: Number of bins of width b, dividing the support of F , [r, r]nb = 1, 000 in all cases (except nb = 40 in draft paper)French results not very sensitive to bin sizeIndian results are more sensitive

We report below DKL(F || F (· ; θ))

θ: Parameter vector that minimizes DKL(F || F (· ;θ))

Units of measurement:KLD usually measured in “bits” (log to base 2) or “nats” (natural logs)Here we present results relative to a uniform benchmark Details

Analogous to “dartboard” (Ellison-Glaeser (1997)) or “balls and bins”approaches (Armenter-Koren (2014))

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 41 / 62

Page 80: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Operationalizing the KLD

Operationalizing the KLD

Discrete counterpart of continuous KLD: Compare QQ Estimator

DKL(F || F (· ;θ)) =

nb∑i=1

log

(∆Fi∆Fi

)∆Fi

∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b) ∆Fi ≡ F (r+i∗b)−F (r+(i− 1)∗b)

nb: Number of bins of width b, dividing the support of F , [r, r]nb = 1, 000 in all cases (except nb = 40 in draft paper)French results not very sensitive to bin sizeIndian results are more sensitive

We report below DKL(F || F (· ; θ))

θ: Parameter vector that minimizes DKL(F || F (· ;θ))

Units of measurement:KLD usually measured in “bits” (log to base 2) or “nats” (natural logs)Here we present results relative to a uniform benchmark Details

Analogous to “dartboard” (Ellison-Glaeser (1997)) or “balls and bins”approaches (Armenter-Koren (2014))

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 41 / 62

Page 81: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

French Exports to Germany

French exports to Germany in 2005

Similar to data used by Head, Mayer, and Thoenig (2014)

We work with 161,191 firm-product observations on export sales

Produced by 27,550 firms: 5.85 products per firm

Results

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 42 / 62

Page 82: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

A First Look at the Data: Obviously Pareto?

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 43 / 62

Page 83: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

A Second Look at the Data: Obviously Log-normal?

(1) 50% of observations, 0.1% of sales

(3) 99.8% of firms, 50% of sales; (4) 411 ex 161,191 firms.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 44 / 62

Page 84: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

A Third Look at the Data: Pareto where it Matters?

(1)

(1) 50% of observations, 0.1% of sales

(3) 99.8% of firms, 50% of sales; (4) 411 ex 161,191 firms.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 45 / 62

Page 85: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

A Third Look at the Data: Pareto where it Matters?

(1) (2)

(1) 50% of observations, 0.1% of sales; (2) 77.9% of observations, 1.0% of sales

(3) 99.8% of firms, 50% of sales; (4) 411 ex 161,191 firms.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 46 / 62

Page 86: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

A Third Look at the Data: Pareto where it Matters?

(1) (2) (3)

(1) 50% of observations, 0.1% of sales; (2) 77.9% of observations, 1.0% of sales

(3) 99.8% of firms, 50% of sales

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 47 / 62

Page 87: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

A Third Look at the Data: Pareto where it Matters?

(1) (2) (3)

(4)

(1) 50% of observations, 0.1% of sales; (2) 77.9% of observations, 1.0% of sales

(3) 99.8% of observations, 50% of sales; (4) 411 ex 161,191 observations.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 48 / 62

Page 88: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

Best-Fit Pareto and Log-Normal

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4

x 109

(a) All Observations

0 1 2 3 4 5 6

x 107

(b) All Bar Top 89 Observations

KLD: Pareto (green): 0.0012; Log-normal (red): 0.0001Top 89 firms: 0.05% of observations, 32% of sales

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 49 / 62

Page 89: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

KLD for Different Specifications: French Exports

CREMR/CES Translog Linear and LES

Pareto 0.0012 0.3819 0.4711

[0.0012, 0.0013] [0.1600, 0.3826] [0.4704, 0.4715]

Log-Normal 0.0001 0.7315 0.8304

[0.0001, 0.0001] [0.4891, 0.7320] [0.7679, 0.8310]

(Bootstrapped 95% Confidence Intervals in Parentheses)

Recall Derivations KLD for Indian Data Bootstrapped Confidence Intervals Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 50 / 62

Page 90: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics French Exports to Germany

KLD for Different Specifications: French Exports

CREMR/CES Translog Linear and LES

Pareto 0.0012 0.3819 0.4711

[0.0012, 0.0013] [0.1600, 0.3826] [0.4704, 0.4715]

Log-Normal 0.0001 0.7315 0.8304

[0.0001, 0.0001] [0.4891, 0.7320] [0.7679, 0.8310]

(Bootstrapped 95% Confidence Intervals in Parentheses)

Recall Derivations KLD for Indian Data Bootstrapped Confidence Intervals Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 50 / 62

Page 91: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Indian Sales and Markups

Indian Sales and Markups

Indian sales and markups in 2001

As used by de Loecker, Goldberg, Khandelwal and Pavcnik (2015)

2,457 firm-product observations

Markups are estimated at firm-product level

Using the “production approach”: Assumes cost-minimization only

Measures markups by the deviation between the output elasticity of avariable input and that input’s share of total revenue

Does not impose assumptions on demand or market structure

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 51 / 62

Page 92: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Indian Sales and Markups

KLD: Indian Sales and Markups

KLD (Sales)

KLD(Markups)

0.18

0.20

0.22

0.24

0.26

0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80

All results relative to the uniform benchmark

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 52 / 62

Page 93: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Indian Sales and Markups

KLD: Indian Sales and Markups

0.18

0.20

0.22

0.24

0.26

0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80

Log-Normal Productivity

Pareto Productivity

KLD (Sales)

KLD(Markups)

CREMR

Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 53 / 62

Page 94: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Indian Sales and Markups

KLD: Indian Sales and Markups

0.18

0.20

0.22

0.24

0.26

0.00 0.10 0.20 0.30 0.40 0.50 0.60 0.70 0.80

Log-Normal Productivity

Pareto Productivity

KLD (Sales)

KLD(Markups)

CREMR

TranslogTranslog

LESLES

Linear

Linear

Recall Derivations KLD for French Exports Compare QQ Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 54 / 62

Page 95: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness: The QQ Estimator

Robustness Check: The QQ Estimator

[Kratz-Resnick (1996), Head-Mayer-Thoenig (2014), Nigai (2016)]

QQ Estimator: Compare actual and predicted quantiles:

QQ(F || F (·;θ)) =

n∑i=1

(log qi − log qi(θ))2

n = 100 quantiles

qi = F−1(i/n): i’th quantile observed in our data

qi(θ) = F−1(i/n;θ): i’th quantile predicted by the theory Details

We report below QQ(F || F (·; θ))

θ: Parameter vector that minimizes QQ(F || F (·;θ))

Uniform benchmark: 2, 420 (sales), 90.1328 (markups)

Compare KLD

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 55 / 62

Page 96: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness: The QQ Estimator

Robustness Check: The QQ Estimator

[Kratz-Resnick (1996), Head-Mayer-Thoenig (2014), Nigai (2016)]

QQ Estimator: Compare actual and predicted quantiles:

QQ(F || F (·;θ)) =

n∑i=1

(log qi − log qi(θ))2

n = 100 quantiles

qi = F−1(i/n): i’th quantile observed in our data

qi(θ) = F−1(i/n;θ): i’th quantile predicted by the theory Details

We report below QQ(F || F (·; θ))

θ: Parameter vector that minimizes QQ(F || F (·;θ))

Uniform benchmark: 2, 420 (sales), 90.1328 (markups)

Compare KLD

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 55 / 62

Page 97: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness: The QQ Estimator

QQ Estimator: Indian Sales and Markups

0.00

0.50

1.00

1.50

2.00

2.50

3.00

3.50

4.00

0.0 20.0 40.0 60.0 80.0 100.0 120.0 140.0

Log-Normal Productivity

Pareto Productivity

QQ (Sales)

QQ(Markups)

CREMR

Translog

Translog

LES

LES

Linear

Linear

Compare KLD Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 56 / 62

Page 98: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness to Truncation

Robustness to Truncation

Recall French versus Indian Results:

Results with French and Indian data very similar . . .

. . . except for CREMR + Pareto sales

Why? French data are for exports, Indian for production

So: presumptively, smaller firms have been selected out of French data

To explore this, we reestimate KLD for Indian sales dropping observations:

“CREMR vs. CREMR”: Pareto versus log-normal

“CREMR vs. the Rest”: Conditional on Pareto

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 57 / 62

Page 99: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness to Truncation

Robustness to Truncation

Recall French versus Indian Results:

Results with French and Indian data very similar . . .

. . . except for CREMR + Pareto sales

Why? French data are for exports, Indian for production

So: presumptively, smaller firms have been selected out of French data

To explore this, we reestimate KLD for Indian sales dropping observations:

“CREMR vs. CREMR”: Pareto versus log-normal

“CREMR vs. the Rest”: Conditional on Pareto

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 57 / 62

Page 100: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness to Truncation

Robustness to Truncation

Recall French versus Indian Results:

Results with French and Indian data very similar . . .

. . . except for CREMR + Pareto sales

Why? French data are for exports, Indian for production

So: presumptively, smaller firms have been selected out of French data

To explore this, we reestimate KLD for Indian sales dropping observations:

“CREMR vs. CREMR”: Pareto versus log-normal

“CREMR vs. the Rest”: Conditional on Pareto

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 57 / 62

Page 101: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness to Truncation

Pareto Does Better as We Drop Small Observations

KLD

Number of Observations Dropped

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0 200 400 600 800

Pareto + CREMR

Lognormal + CREMR

KLD for CREMR demands and Indian sales, dropping smaller observations

All KLD values relative to appropriate uniform benchmark

Pareto + CREMR dominates when we drop 663 or more observations

27% of observations, 1.2% of sales

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 58 / 62

Page 102: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness to Truncation

Pareto Does Better as We Drop Small Observations

KLD

Number of Observations Dropped

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0 200 400 600 800

Pareto + CREMR

Lognormal + CREMR

KLD for CREMR demands and Indian sales, dropping smaller observations

All KLD values relative to appropriate uniform benchmark

Pareto + CREMR dominates when we drop 663 or more observations

27% of observations, 1.2% of sales

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 58 / 62

Page 103: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Empirics Robustness to Truncation

Given Pareto, CREMR Also Does Better

KLD

Number of Observations Dropped

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200

Pareto + CREMR

Pareto + Linear

Pareto + Translog

Conditional on Pareto, CREMR dominates ...

Linear: When we drop 11 or more observations0.44% of observations, 0.0002% of sales

Translog: When we drop 118 or more observations4.80% of observations, 0.03% of sales

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 59 / 62

Page 104: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Outline

1 Introduction

2 General Results

3 Backing Out Demands

4 Inferring Sales and Mark-Up Distributions

5 From Theory to Calibration

6 Empirics

7 Conclusion

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 60 / 62

Page 105: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Conclusion

We characterize the demands that are consistent with particular distributionsof productivities, sales and markups (including Pareto, Log-normal andFrechet)

Most alternatives to CES are not

CREMR demands: Necessary and sufficient for productivity and salesto have the same distribution

CREMR + Log-normal productivity match empirical evidence ondistribution of mark-ups

Kullback-Leibler divergence allows us quantify how unrealistic is a givencombination of assumptions about productivity distribution and demands

Choice between Pareto and log-normal distributions less importantthan the choice between CREMR and other demands

Back to text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 61 / 62

Page 106: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Conclusion

We characterize the demands that are consistent with particular distributionsof productivities, sales and markups (including Pareto, Log-normal andFrechet)

Most alternatives to CES are not

CREMR demands: Necessary and sufficient for productivity and salesto have the same distribution

CREMR + Log-normal productivity match empirical evidence ondistribution of mark-ups

Kullback-Leibler divergence allows us quantify how unrealistic is a givencombination of assumptions about productivity distribution and demands

Choice between Pareto and log-normal distributions less importantthan the choice between CREMR and other demands

Back to text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 61 / 62

Page 107: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Conclusion

We characterize the demands that are consistent with particular distributionsof productivities, sales and markups (including Pareto, Log-normal andFrechet)

Most alternatives to CES are not

CREMR demands: Necessary and sufficient for productivity and salesto have the same distribution

CREMR + Log-normal productivity match empirical evidence ondistribution of mark-ups

Kullback-Leibler divergence allows us quantify how unrealistic is a givencombination of assumptions about productivity distribution and demands

Choice between Pareto and log-normal distributions less importantthan the choice between CREMR and other demands

Back to text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 61 / 62

Page 108: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Conclusion

We characterize the demands that are consistent with particular distributionsof productivities, sales and markups (including Pareto, Log-normal andFrechet)

Most alternatives to CES are not

CREMR demands: Necessary and sufficient for productivity and salesto have the same distribution

CREMR + Log-normal productivity match empirical evidence ondistribution of mark-ups

Kullback-Leibler divergence allows us quantify how unrealistic is a givencombination of assumptions about productivity distribution and demands

Choice between Pareto and log-normal distributions less importantthan the choice between CREMR and other demands

Back to text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 61 / 62

Page 109: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Thanks and Acknowledgements

Thank you for listening. Comments welcome!

The research leading to these results has received funding from the European Research Council under the European Union’sSeventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007-2013), ERC grant agreement no. 295669. The contents reflect only the authors’views and not the views of the ERC or the European Commission, and the European Union is not liable for any use that may bemade of the information contained therein.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 110: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Proof of Proposition 1

(i) To show that (1) and (3) imply (2): Back to Text

Let F (y) denote the distribution of y implied by (1) and (3): F (y) = Pr [y ≤ y].

From (1) and (3), G−1 [F (y)] is strictly increasing; so:

F (y) = Pr [y ≤ y] = Pr[x ≤ G−1 [F (y)]

]Therefore:

F (y) = G[G−1 [F (y)]

]= F (y)

So, the implied distribution of y is F (y), as was to be proved.

A similar proof shows that (2) and (3) imply (1).

(ii) To show that (1) and (2) imply (3):

Pick an arbitrary firm i with characteristics x(i) and y(i).

Because x(i) and y(i) are strictly increasing in i, the masses of firms withcharacteristics below x(i) and y(i) are equal:

|Ω|Pr(x ≤ x(i)) = |Ω|Pr(y ≤ y(i)),

where |Ω| is the measure of Ω, i.e. the total mass of firms.

This holds for any firm i, so G(x(i)) = F (y(i)), ∀i ∈ Ω.

Inverting gives x(i) = G−1[F (y(i))] as required.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 111: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Proof of Proposition 2

(i) To show that (1) and (3) imply (2): Back to Text

Given G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, Gx > 0, and x = x0h(y)E . Then F (y):

= Pr [y ≤ y] = Pr[x ≤ x0h(y)E

]= H

[θ0 + θ1

θ2

x0h(y)E

θ2] = H[θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

]where: θ′2 = Eθ2 and θ′1 = Eθ1x

θ20

(ii) To show that (1) and (2) imply (3):

Given G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

, F (y; θ′) = H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

), Gx, Fy > 0

From Proposition 1, x = G−1 [F (y; θ′) ; θ]

Inverting G (x; θ): θ0 + θ1θ2xθ2 = H−1 (G) → x =

[θ2θ1

H−1 (G)− θ0

] 1θ2

Now substitute F (y; θ′) for G:

x =[θ2θ1

H−1

(H(θ0 +

θ′1θ′2h(y)θ

′2

))− θ0

] 1θ2 = x0h(y)E

where: E =θ′2θ2

and x0 =(θ2θ1

θ′1θ′2

) 1θ2

Note: θ0 must be the same in G(x; θ) and F (y; θ′).

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 112: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Generalized Power Function Family of Distributions

G (x; θ) = H(θ0 + θ1

θ2xθ2)

Back to text

G (x; θ) Support H (z) θ0 θ1 θ2

Pareto 1−(xx

)−k[x,∞) z 1 kxk −k

Truncated Pareto1−xkx−k

1−xkx−k[x, x] z 1

1−xkx−kkxk

1−xkx−k−k

Log-normal Φ(

log x−µs

)[0,∞) Φ [log (z)] 0 1

se−µs 1

s

Uniformx−xx−x [x, x] z − x

x−x1

x−x 1

Frechet e−(x−µs

)−k[µ,∞) e−z

−k−µs

1s

1

Gumbel e−e−(x−µs

)(−∞,∞) e−e

−z−µs

1s

1

Weibull 1− e−(x−µs

)k[µ,∞) 1− e−z

k−µs

1s

1

Reversed Weibull e−(µ−xs

)k(−∞, µ] e−z

k µs

− 1s

1

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 113: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Properties of CREMR Demands

Back to text

p(x) = βx

(x− γ)σ−1σ

Proof that CREMR has Constant Revenue Elasticity of Marginal Revenue:

r(x) ≡ xp(x) = β (x− γ)σ−1σ

r′(x) = p(x) + xp′(x) = β σ−1σ

(x− γ)−1σ

⇒ r′(x) = βσσ−1

σ−1

σr(x)−

1σ−1

In terms of proportional changes, r ≡ d log r = drr (r > 0):

r = σ−1σ

xx−γ x

r′ = − 1σ

xx−γ x

⇒ r′ = − 1

σ − 1r

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 114: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Preferences

Back to text

CREMR demands can be rationalized by additively separable preferences:

U =

∫i∈Ω

ux(i) di

which implies that p(i) = λ−1u′x(i), where λ is the marginal utility of income.

u (x) =βσ

1− σ xσ−1σ 2F1

(−σ − 1

σ,−σ − 1

σ;

1

σ;γ

x

)+ C

where:

2F1 (a, b; c; z), |z| < 1, is the hypergeometric function:

2F1(a, b; c; z) =∞∑n=0

(a)n(b)n(c)n

zn

n!

(q)n is the (rising) Pochhammer symbol:

(q)n =

1 n = 0q(q + 1)...(q + n− 1) n > 0

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 115: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Preferences: Marginal Utility of Income

Back to text

In text, the marginal utility of income λ is set equal to one

We can eliminate λ by integrating over all demands

With additively separable preferences in general:∫i∈Ω

p(i)x(i) di = λ−1∫i∈Ω

x(i)u′x(i) di = I

⇒ p(i) = u′x(i)∫j∈Ωx(j)u′x(j) dj

I

So, with CREMR preferences:

λp (i) = u′ x (i) = β(i)x(i)

[x (i)− γ]σ−1σ

⇒ p(i) = 1x(i)

β(i)[x(i)−γ]σ−1σ∫

j∈Ωβ(j)[x(j)−γ]σ−1σ dj

I

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 116: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Demand Functions

Back to text

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(a) γ = 0: CES

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(b) γ > 0: Subconvex

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(c) γ < 0: Superconvex

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 117: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Demand Functions

Back to text

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(a) γ = 0: CES

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(b) γ > 0: Subconvex

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(c) γ < 0: Superconvex

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 118: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Demand Functions

Back to text

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(a) γ = 0: CES

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(b) γ > 0: Subconvex

x

p(x)

p

r'(x)

(c) γ < 0: SuperconvexMNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 119: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Very Different from Other Demands

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

Linear

CARAStone-Geary

TranslogCESSM

The Demand Manifold

Compare CEMR Demand Manifolds

Back to text

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

= 1.2

= 1.5

= 2 = 6 = 3SM CES

p(x) =β

x(x− γ)

σ−1σ

⇒ ρ(ε) = 2− 1

σ − 1

(ε− 1)2

ε

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 120: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Very Different from Other Demands

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

Linear

CARAStone-Geary

TranslogCESSM

The Demand Manifold

Compare CEMR Demand Manifolds

Back to text

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

= 1.2

= 1.5

= 2 = 6 = 3SM CES

p(x) =β

x(x− γ)

σ−1σ

⇒ ρ(ε) = 2− 1

σ − 1

(ε− 1)2

ε

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 121: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

A Firm’s-Eye View of Demand

Perceived inverse demand function:

p = p(x) p′ < 0

Two key demand parameters:

1 Slope/Elasticity:

ε(x) ≡ − p(x)xp′(x) > 0

2 Curvature/Convexity:

ρ(x) ≡ −xp′′(x)p′(x) R 0

Back to Text

4

4

3

2

11

0-2 -1 0 1 2 3

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 122: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

A Firm’s-Eye View of Demand

Perceived inverse demand function:

p = p(x) p′ < 0

Two key demand parameters:

1 Slope/Elasticity:

ε(x) ≡ − p(x)xp′(x) > 0

2 Curvature/Convexity:

ρ(x) ≡ −xp′′(x)p′(x) R 0

Back to Text

4

4

3

2

11

0-2 -1 0 1 2 3

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 123: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

A Firm’s-Eye View of Demand

Perceived inverse demand function:

p = p(x) p′ < 0

Two key demand parameters:

1 Slope/Elasticity:

ε(x) ≡ − p(x)xp′(x) > 0

2 Curvature/Convexity:

ρ(x) ≡ −xp′′(x)p′(x) R 0

Back to Text

4

4

3

2

11

0-2 -1 0 1 2 3

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 124: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

The Admissible Region

For a monopoly firm:

First-order condition:p+ xp′ = c ≥ 0 ⇒ ε ≥ 1

Second-order condition:2p′ + xp′′ < 0 ⇒ ρ < 2

4.0

4.0

3.0

2.0

1 01.0

0.0-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

Proposition: Any well-behaved demand function can be represented by its“Demand Manifold”: a smooth curve in ε, ρ space

Back to Text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 125: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

The Admissible Region

For a monopoly firm:

First-order condition:p+ xp′ = c ≥ 0 ⇒ ε ≥ 1

Second-order condition:2p′ + xp′′ < 0 ⇒ ρ < 2

4.0

4.0

3.0

2.0

1 01.0

0.0-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

Proposition: Any well-behaved demand function can be represented by its“Demand Manifold”: a smooth curve in ε, ρ space

Back to Text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 126: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CES Demands

In general, both ε and ρ vary withsales

Exception: CES/iso-elastic case:

p = βx−1/σ

⇒ ε = σ, ρ = σ+1σ > 1

⇒ ε = 1ρ−1 0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

CES

Cobb-Douglas: ε = 1, ρ = 2; just on boundary of both FOC and SOC

Back to Text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 127: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CES Demands

In general, both ε and ρ vary withsales

Exception: CES/iso-elastic case:

p = βx−1/σ

⇒ ε = σ, ρ = σ+1σ > 1

⇒ ε = 1ρ−1 0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

Cobb-Douglas

CES

Cobb-Douglas: ε = 1, ρ = 2; just on boundary of both FOC and SOC

Back to Text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 128: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Other Corollaries of Proposition 2

CEMR

r

CES

CREMR

x

Self-Reflection Corollaries of Proposition 2: Back to text

1 Pareto productivity and sales, CREMR demands

2 Log-normal productivity and sales, CREMR demands Details

Strictly: Range must include r = 0, which restricts CREMR to CES

3 Frechet productivity and sales, CREMR demands [Tintelnot (2014)]

4 Pareto productivity and output, CEMR demands Details

5 Log-normal productivity and output, CEMR demands, with restrictions

6 Pareto/Log-Normal/Frechet output and sales, CES demandsMNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 129: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Corollary 2: Log-Normal Productivity and Sales

Log-NormalProductivities

Log-NormalSales

CREMRDemands

Corollary 2: Any two imply the third

Back to Text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 130: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Corollary 3: Output Rather than Sales

ParetoProductivities

ParetoOutputs

CEMRDemands

Corollary 3: Any two imply the third

Back to Text Recall Corollary 1

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 131: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CEMR Demands

“Constant (Output) Elasticity of Marginal Revenue” demand function:

p(x) =1

x

(α+ βx

σ−1σ

)

CES a special case: α = 0 ⇒ p(x) = βx−1σ

“CEMR”:

r′(x) = βσ − 1

σx−

1σ ⇒ r′ = − 1

σx

Same as inverse “PIGL” demands[Muellbauer (1975), Mrazova-Neary (2011, 2013)]

σ → 1 ⇒ Inverse Translog: p(x) = 1x (α′ + β′ log x)

Back to Text Recall CREMR Demands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 132: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CEMR Demands

“Constant (Output) Elasticity of Marginal Revenue” demand function:

p(x) =1

x

(α+ βx

σ−1σ

)

CES a special case: α = 0 ⇒ p(x) = βx−1σ

“CEMR”:

r′(x) = βσ − 1

σx−

1σ ⇒ r′ = − 1

σx

Same as inverse “PIGL” demands[Muellbauer (1975), Mrazova-Neary (2011, 2013)]

σ → 1 ⇒ Inverse Translog: p(x) = 1x (α′ + β′ log x)

Back to Text Recall CREMR Demands

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 133: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CEMR Demand Manifolds

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

SM

SPT SC

= 0.25 = 1 = 0.5

= 4

= 2

p(x) =1

x

(α+ βx

σ−1σ

)⇒ ρ(ε) = 2− 1

σ(ε− 1)

(Similar to CREMR for large ε)

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

-2.0 -1.0 0.0 1.0 2.0 3.0

Linear

CARAStone-Geary

TranslogCESSM

Back to Text Recall CREMR Demand Manifolds

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 134: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Matching Moments is Not Enough

Predicted Size Distributions of Firms from CES and Linear Demands

Back to Text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 135: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Markups: Details

Back to text

m(x) = x−γx ⇒ x(m) = γ

1−m

Profit maximization implies: ϕ(x) = [r′(x)]−1 = 1β

σσ−1 (x− γ)

Combining ϕ(x) and x(m):

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 136: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Markups: Details

Back to text

m(x) = x−γx ⇒ x(m) = γ

1−m

Profit maximization implies: ϕ(x) = [r′(x)]−1 = 1β

σσ−1 (x− γ)

Combining ϕ(x) and x(m):

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 137: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Markups: Details

Back to text

m(x) = x−γx ⇒ x(m) = γ

1−m

Profit maximization implies: ϕ(x) = [r′(x)]−1 = 1β

σσ−1 (x− γ)

Combining ϕ(x) and x(m):

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 138: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Markups: Details

Back to text

m(x) = x−γx ⇒ x(m) = γ

1−m

Profit maximization implies: ϕ(x) = [r′(x)]−1 = 1β

σσ−1 (x− γ)

Combining ϕ(x) and x(m):

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 139: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Markups: Details

Back to text

m(x) = x−γx ⇒ x(m) = γ

1−m

Profit maximization implies: ϕ(x) = [r′(x)]−1 = 1β

σσ−1 (x− γ)

Combining ϕ(x) and x(m):

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 140: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

CREMR Markups: Details

Back to text

m(x) = x−γx ⇒ x(m) = γ

1−m

Profit maximization implies: ϕ(x) = [r′(x)]−1 = 1β

σσ−1 (x− γ)

Combining ϕ(x) and x(m):

ϕ(m) = ϕ0

(m

1− m

) 1σ

ϕ0 ≡1

β

σ

σ − 1γ

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 141: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Information and Shannon EntropyBack to Text

What is the information content of one draw from a known F (r)?

Should be: Additive; non-negative; and inversely related to probability

⇒ I(r) = − log(f(r))

Shannon Entropy: The expected value of information from a single draw:

SF ≡ EF [I(r)] = −∫ r

r

log(f(r)

)f(r)dr

S measures the unpredictability or uncertainty about an individual drawimplied by a known distribution F (r).

S = 0 when F is a Dirac distribution (i.e., all its mass concentrated ata single point): Knowing the distribution tells us everything aboutindividual draws, so an extra draw conveys no new information.

S is arbitrarily large when F is uniform: Knowing the distributionconveys no information whatsoever about individual draws.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 142: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Information and Shannon EntropyBack to Text

What is the information content of one draw from a known F (r)?

Should be: Additive; non-negative; and inversely related to probability

⇒ I(r) = − log(f(r))

Shannon Entropy: The expected value of information from a single draw:

SF ≡ EF [I(r)] = −∫ r

r

log(f(r)

)f(r)dr

S measures the unpredictability or uncertainty about an individual drawimplied by a known distribution F (r).

S = 0 when F is a Dirac distribution (i.e., all its mass concentrated ata single point): Knowing the distribution tells us everything aboutindividual draws, so an extra draw conveys no new information.

S is arbitrarily large when F is uniform: Knowing the distributionconveys no information whatsoever about individual draws.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 143: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Information and Shannon EntropyBack to Text

What is the information content of one draw from a known F (r)?

Should be: Additive; non-negative; and inversely related to probability

⇒ I(r) = − log(f(r))

Shannon Entropy: The expected value of information from a single draw:

SF ≡ EF [I(r)] = −∫ r

r

log(f(r)

)f(r)dr

S measures the unpredictability or uncertainty about an individual drawimplied by a known distribution F (r).

S = 0 when F is a Dirac distribution (i.e., all its mass concentrated ata single point): Knowing the distribution tells us everything aboutindividual draws, so an extra draw conveys no new information.

S is arbitrarily large when F is uniform: Knowing the distributionconveys no information whatsoever about individual draws.

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 144: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Back to Text

KLD: Measures the “information loss” or “relative entropy” when onedistribution, F , is used to approximate another, F : Illustration

DKL(F ||F

)≡∫ r

r

log

(f(r)

f(r)

)f(r)dr

“Relative entropy”: Relative to Shannon entropy:

DKL(F ||F

)= −

∫ r

r

log (f(r)) f(r)dr︸ ︷︷ ︸“Cross Entropy”

+

∫ r

r

log(f(r)

)f(r)dr︸ ︷︷ ︸

minus Shannon Entropy

Caveats:

Asymmetric: Measures divergence, not distance, of F (r) from F (r)Requires that f(r) > 0 ∀r ∈ [r, r]All draws equally weighted

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 145: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Back to Text

KLD: Measures the “information loss” or “relative entropy” when onedistribution, F , is used to approximate another, F : Illustration

DKL(F ||F

)≡∫ r

r

log

(f(r)

f(r)

)f(r)dr

“Relative entropy”: Relative to Shannon entropy:

DKL(F ||F

)= −

∫ r

r

log (f(r)) f(r)dr︸ ︷︷ ︸“Cross Entropy”

+

∫ r

r

log(f(r)

)f(r)dr︸ ︷︷ ︸

minus Shannon Entropy

Caveats:

Asymmetric: Measures divergence, not distance, of F (r) from F (r)Requires that f(r) > 0 ∀r ∈ [r, r]All draws equally weighted

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 146: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Kullback-Leibler Divergence

Back to Text

KLD: Measures the “information loss” or “relative entropy” when onedistribution, F , is used to approximate another, F : Illustration

DKL(F ||F

)≡∫ r

r

log

(f(r)

f(r)

)f(r)dr

“Relative entropy”: Relative to Shannon entropy:

DKL(F ||F

)= −

∫ r

r

log (f(r)) f(r)dr︸ ︷︷ ︸“Cross Entropy”

+

∫ r

r

log(f(r)

)f(r)dr︸ ︷︷ ︸

minus Shannon Entropy

Caveats:

Asymmetric: Measures divergence, not distance, of F (r) from F (r)Requires that f(r) > 0 ∀r ∈ [r, r]All draws equally weighted

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 147: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

KLD: Example with Normal Distributions

From: “KL-Gauss-Example” by T. Nathan Mundhenk, Ph.D thesis appendix C. Licensed under CC by SA 3.0 via Wikipedia.http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:KL-Gauss-Example.png#mediaviewer/File:KL-Gauss-Example.png

Back

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 148: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Decomposing the KLD

Back to Text Details Empirics

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)− log f (r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸

(1)

+

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′(r)

f(r)+ 1

−ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

E(r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸

(2)

− rE′(r; θ)

E(r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸(3)

]dr

Decomposing the information cost of using the wrong F :

1 Over-/under- predicting the mass of the smallest firms

2 Over-/under- predicting elasticities of density and REMR E(r; θ)

3 Non-constant REMR

i.e., failure of Proposition 2 assumption Recall

Estimation: Choose θ to miminize KLD ⇔ MLE (asymptotically)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 149: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Decomposing the KLD

Back to Text Details Empirics

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)− log f (r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸

(1)

+

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′(r)

f(r)+ 1

−ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

E(r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸

(2)

− rE′(r; θ)

E(r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸(3)

]dr

Decomposing the information cost of using the wrong F :

1 Over-/under- predicting the mass of the smallest firms

2 Over-/under- predicting elasticities of density and REMR E(r; θ)

3 Non-constant REMR

i.e., failure of Proposition 2 assumption Recall

Estimation: Choose θ to miminize KLD ⇔ MLE (asymptotically)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 150: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Decomposing the KLD

Back to Text Details Empirics

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)− log f (r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸

(1)

+

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′(r)

f(r)+ 1

−ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

E(r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸

(2)

− rE′(r; θ)

E(r; θ)︸ ︷︷ ︸(3)

]dr

Decomposing the information cost of using the wrong F :

1 Over-/under- predicting the mass of the smallest firms

2 Over-/under- predicting elasticities of density and REMR E(r; θ)

3 Non-constant REMR

i.e., failure of Proposition 2 assumption Recall

Estimation: Choose θ to miminize KLD ⇔ MLE (asymptotically)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 151: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

KLD with Pareto and CREMR

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

FGD~

Example: Pareto productivity and sales, CREMR demand: Details

DKL(F ||F ) = logn

n︸ ︷︷ ︸(1)

+n− nn︸ ︷︷ ︸(2)

, n = Ek =k

σ − 1

[k = 1, n = 2, σ = k+nn

= 1.5 ]

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 152: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

KLD with Pareto and CREMR: Decomposition

‐2.0

‐1.5

‐1.0

‐0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

KLD

Part 1

Part 2

= 1.5

Assuming a value of σ lower than the true value implies:

1 Over-predicting the mass of the smallest firms2 Under-predicting the mass of larger firms

Conversely if we assume a value of σ greater than the true value

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 153: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

KLD with Pareto and CREMR: Decomposition

‐2.0

‐1.5

‐1.0

‐0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

KLD

Part 1

Part 2

= 1.5

Assuming a value of σ lower than the true value implies:

1 Over-predicting the mass of the smallest firms2 Under-predicting the mass of larger firms

Conversely if we assume a value of σ greater than the true value

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 154: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

KLD with Pareto and CREMR: Decomposition

‐2.0

‐1.5

‐1.0

‐0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

KLD

Part 1

Part 2

= 1.5

Assuming a value of σ lower than the true value implies:

1 Over-predicting the mass of the smallest firms2 Under-predicting the mass of larger firms

Conversely if we assume a value of σ greater than the true value

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 155: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

KLD with Truncated Pareto and CREMR

‐2.0

‐1.5

‐1.0

‐0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

0.0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

KLD

Part 1A

Part 2A

TKLD

Part 1

Part 2

Example: Truncated Pareto productivity and sales, CREMR demand: Details

DKL(F ||F ) = logn

n+ log

1− λn

1− λn︸ ︷︷ ︸(1)

+n− nn

+ (n− n)λn

1− λnlog λ︸ ︷︷ ︸

(2)

[n = kσ−1

, λ ≡ rr∈ [0, 1]; λ = 0.1, k = 1, n = 2, σ = k+n

n= 1.5 ]

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 156: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Decomposing the KLD: Details

Back to Text

Given:

F (r): Actual distribution of firm salesF (r; θ): Distribution of firm sales implied by:

G(ϕ): Distribution of firm productivitiesϕ(r; θ): Model of firm behaviour, parameterized by θ

We want to use KLD to compare F (r; θ) with F (r):

1 Reexpress DKL(F ||F ) in terms of elasticities of densities: Derivation

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)−log f (r; θ)+

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′ (r)

f (r)− rf ′ (r; θ)

f (r; θ)

]dr

2 Relate F (r; θ) to G (ϕ) and ϕ(r; θ): Derivation

rf ′(r; θ)

f(r; θ)=

[ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

]E(r; θ)− 1 +

rE′(r; θ)

E(r; θ), E(r; θ) ≡ ϕ/r i.e., REMR

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 157: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Decomposing the KLD: Details

Back to Text

Given:

F (r): Actual distribution of firm salesF (r; θ): Distribution of firm sales implied by:

G(ϕ): Distribution of firm productivitiesϕ(r; θ): Model of firm behaviour, parameterized by θ

We want to use KLD to compare F (r; θ) with F (r):

1 Reexpress DKL(F ||F ) in terms of elasticities of densities: Derivation

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)−log f (r; θ)+

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′ (r)

f (r)− rf ′ (r; θ)

f (r; θ)

]dr

2 Relate F (r; θ) to G (ϕ) and ϕ(r; θ): Derivation

rf ′(r; θ)

f(r; θ)=

[ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

]E(r; θ)− 1 +

rE′(r; θ)

E(r; θ), E(r; θ) ≡ ϕ/r i.e., REMR

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 158: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Decomposing the KLD: Details

Back to Text

Given:

F (r): Actual distribution of firm salesF (r; θ): Distribution of firm sales implied by:

G(ϕ): Distribution of firm productivitiesϕ(r; θ): Model of firm behaviour, parameterized by θ

We want to use KLD to compare F (r; θ) with F (r):

1 Reexpress DKL(F ||F ) in terms of elasticities of densities: Derivation

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)−log f (r; θ)+

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′ (r)

f (r)− rf ′ (r; θ)

f (r; θ)

]dr

2 Relate F (r; θ) to G (ϕ) and ϕ(r; θ): Derivation

rf ′(r; θ)

f(r; θ)=

[ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

]E(r; θ)− 1 +

rE′(r; θ)

E(r; θ), E(r; θ) ≡ ϕ/r i.e., REMR

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 159: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Decomposing the KLD: Details

Back to Text

Given:

F (r): Actual distribution of firm salesF (r; θ): Distribution of firm sales implied by:

G(ϕ): Distribution of firm productivitiesϕ(r; θ): Model of firm behaviour, parameterized by θ

We want to use KLD to compare F (r; θ) with F (r):

1 Reexpress DKL(F ||F ) in terms of elasticities of densities: Derivation

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)−log f (r; θ)+

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′ (r)

f (r)− rf ′ (r; θ)

f (r; θ)

]dr

2 Relate F (r; θ) to G (ϕ) and ϕ(r; θ): Derivation

rf ′(r; θ)

f(r; θ)=

[ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

]E(r; θ)− 1 +

rE′(r; θ)

E(r; θ), E(r; θ) ≡ ϕ/r i.e., REMR

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 160: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Express KLD in terms of Elasticities of Densities

Back

Recall Shannon Entropy: SF ≡ −∫ rrf (r) log f (r) dr; F (r) = 0, F (r) = 1.

Integrate by parts:

u = log f (r) → du = f ′(r)f(r)

dr dv = f (r) dr → v = F (r) + C

→ SF = −[F (r) + C

log f (r)

]rr

+∫ rr

F (r) + C

f ′(r)f(r)

dr

= − (1 + C) log f (r) + C log f (r) +∫ rr

F (r)+Cr

rf ′(r)f(r)

dr

Now, set C equal to zero or −1:

SF = − log f (r) +

∫ r

r

F (r)

r

rf ′ (r)

f (r)dr = − log f (r)−

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

rf ′ (r)

f (r)dr

Repeat for the KLD:

DKL(F ||F

)= log f (r)− log f (r)−

∫ r

r

F (r)

r

[rf ′ (r)

f (r)− rf ′ (r)

f (r)

]dr

= log f (r)− log f (r) +

∫ r

r

1− F (r)

r

[rf ′ (r)

f (r)− rf ′ (r)

f (r)

]dr

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 161: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Elasticity of Density for a Derived Sales Distribution

Back

From Proposition 1(i):

Pr[ϕ ≤ ϕ < ϕ

]=∫ ϕϕg (ϕ) dϕ and r = r (ϕ)

⇒ Pr[r(ϕ)≤ r < r (ϕ)

]=∫ r(ϕ)

r(ϕ)g (ϕ (r)) dϕ

drdr

i.e., f (r) = g (ϕ (r)) dϕdr

Reexpress in terms of elasticities:

rf ′(r)

f(r)=ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)

rϕ′(r)

ϕ(r)+rϕ′′(r)

ϕ′(r)

Reexpress in terms of elasticity of marginal revenue with respect to total revenue:

E(r) ≡ rϕ′(r)ϕ(r)

⇒ rϕ′′(r)ϕ′(r) = E(r)− 1 + rE′(r)

E(r)

⇒ rf ′(r)

f(r)=

[ϕg′(ϕ)

g(ϕ)+ 1

]E(r)− 1 +

rE′(r)

E(r)

Special case when G(ϕ) is Pareto:

ϕg′(ϕ)g(ϕ)

= −(1 + k) ⇒ rf ′(r)f(r)

= −[kE(r) + 1] + rE′(r)E(r)

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 162: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

KLD with Pareto and CREMR

Back to text

When F and F are both Pareto with parameters n and n, the KLD is:

DKL(F ||F ) = logn

n+n

n− 1

When productivity is Pareto with parameter k and demand is CREMR:

E =1

σ − 1, E′ = 0, n =

k

σ − 1

Hence:

DKL(F ||F ) = logn

k+ log(σ − 1) +

k

n

1

σ − 1− 1

dDKLdσ = (σ − 1)2

(σ − k+n

n

)This is positive, i.e., DKL is increasing, if and only if σ ≥ k+n

n

d2DKLdσ2 = −(σ − 1)3

(σ − 2k+n

n

)This is negative, i.e., DKL is concave, if and only if σ ≥ 2k+n

n

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 163: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Uniform Benchmark for KLD

Back to text

An attractive candidate for an uninformative prior is the uniform distribution:

FU (r) =r − rr − r

fU (r) =1

r − r

The KLD between this and the observed distribution F is:

DKL(F ||FU ) = −SF + log(r − r)

SF is the Shannon Entropy of the data: SF ≡ −∫ rrf (r) log f (r) dr

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 164: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Bootstrapped Confidence Intervals for KLD

0 0.005 0.01 0.015 0.02 0.0250

5

10

15

20

25

30

(a) Pareto and CREMR

0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5 3 3.5 4

x 10−3

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

(d) Log-Normal andCREMR

1.3 1.32 1.34 1.36 1.38 1.4 1.42 1.44 1.46 1.480

5

10

15

20

25

30

(b) Pareto and Linear

3.55 3.6 3.65 3.7 3.75 3.80

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

(e) Log-Normal andLinear

0.19 0.195 0.2 0.205 0.21 0.215 0.22 0.225 0.23 0.2350

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

18

(c) Pareto and Translog

2.3 2.32 2.34 2.36 2.38 2.4 2.42 2.440

5

10

15

20

25

(f) Log-Normal andTranslog

Back to text

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62

Page 165: Notes on Technology, Demand, and the Size Distribution of Firms

Conclusion

Quantiles for the QQ Estimator: Details

Quantiles for Sales Back to text

Demand Pareto P(ϕ, k) Lognormal LN (µ, s)

CREMR r (1− y)−σ−1

k exp(µ + s · Φ−1 [y]

)Translog η ·

(W[e · (1− y)

− 1k

]− 1

)η ·(W[exp

(γη

+ 1 + s · Φ−1 [y] + µ)]− 1

)Linear/LES r

(1− (1− y)

12k

)r −

exp(−2(µ+s·Φ−1[y]

))4β

Quantiles for Markups

Demand Pareto P(ϕ, k) Lognormal LN (µ, s)

CREMRm·(1−y)

− 1k

m−1+(1−y)− 1k

m[1 + exp

(−µ− s · ζ

[y; 1s·(ln(

1m−1

)− µ

)])]−1

Translog W[e · (1− y)

− 1k

]W[exp

[s · ζ

[y;− 1

s·(γη

+ µ)]

+ γη

+ µ + 1]]

Linear 12

+ 12· (1− y)

− 1k 1

2+ α

2exp

[µ + s · ζ

[y;− 1

s· (ln (α) + µ)

]]LES (1− y)

− 12·k

√δγ· exp

(µ2

+ s2· ζ[y, 1s·(ln[γδ

]− µ

)])W: The Lambert functionΦ[z]: c.d.f. of a standard normalζ[y; z] ≡ Φ−1 [(1− Φ [z]) · y + Φ [z]]

MNP (Geneva, Oxford, ULB) Sales and Markup Dispersion DEGIT XXI: Sept. 1, 2016 62 / 62