oil and national development in ghana

176
OKOYE, ANTHONY CHUKWUEBUKA PG/M.Sc/09/51664 OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA POLITICAL SCIENCE A THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, FACULTY OF SOCIAL SCIENCES, UNIVERSITY OF NIGERIA, NSUKKA Webmaster Digitally Signed by Webmaster’s Name DN : CN = Webmaster’s name O= University of Nigeria, Nsukka OU = Innovation Centre MARCH, 2011

Upload: others

Post on 26-Apr-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

OKOYE, ANTHONY CHUKWUEBUKA

PG/M.Sc/09/51664

PG/M. Sc/09/51723

OIL AND NATIONAL

DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

POLITICAL SCIENCE

A THESIS SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, FACULTY

OF SOCIAL SCIENCES, UNIVERSITY OF NIGERIA, NSUKKA

Webmaster

Digitally Signed by Webmaster’s Name

DN : CN = Webmaster’s name O= University of Nigeria, Nsukka

OU = Innovation Centre

MARCH, 2011

Page 2: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

2

OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT

IN GHANA

BY

OKOYE, ANTHONY CHUKWUEBUKA

PG/M.Sc/09/51664

A PROJECT REPPORT SUBMITTED TO THE DEPARTMENT

OF POLITICAL SCIENCE, UNIVERSITY OF NIGERIA,

NSUKKA, IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF THE

REQUIREMENTS FOR THE AWARD OF MASTER OF

SCIENCE DEGREE (M.Sc) IN POLITICAL SCIENCE

(POLITICAL ECONOMY)

SUPERVISOR: ONUOHA, JONAH I.

(PROFESSOR OF POLITICAL SCIENCE AT

UNIVERSITY OF NIGERIA, NSUKKA)

MARCH, 2011

Page 3: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

i

TITLE PAGE

OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT

IN GHANA

Page 4: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

ii

APPROVAL PAGE

This Project Report has been approved on behalf of the Department of Political Science,

University of Nigeria, Nsukka.

BY

-------------------------------- ----------------------------

Prof. Onuoha, Jonah I. Prof. Obasi, Igwe

Project Supervisor Head of Department

----------------------------

External Examiner

Page 5: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

iii

DEDICATION

This work is in the ab ovo, dedicated to God Almighty for his innumerable

blessings, which he showered on me in particular and my family at large times without

number.

Page 6: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

iv

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

It is a truism that no man is an island unto himself. Therefore a study of this

nature could have hardly succeeded without the tangible and intangible contributions

from others.

In this regards my invaluable gratitude go to my Supervisor, Prof. Onuoha,

Jonah., for his invaluable cum immeasurable assistance in the supervision of this study. It

was his intellectual inputs that served as motivating factors for me as well as in giving

this work it intellectual and academic outlook; since it is the organisation and not the idea

that is the hallmark of intellectualism. Special thanks goes to my Head of Department,

Prof. Obasi, Igwe for his fatherly concern and advice. Also, the Departmental Post-

Graduate Coordinator, Prof. Ikejiani-Clark; Prof. O. Ibeanu,, Prof. E. O. Ezeani and my

former and ebullient undergraduate lecturer, Prof. H. A. Asobie (current Chairman of the

Nigerian Extractive Initiative Transparency Initiative, NEITI); all of the Department of

Political Science University of Nigeria, Nsukka deserve special mention for their

encouragements in completing this study especially through their priceless lectures.

Though without such appellation that goes with the former group Dr. Ogban-Iyam, whose

unsuken ocean of intellectual ingenuity flows into my little river of intellectualism and

academic radicalism deserves no less kudos.

Other members of staff in the Department of Political Science, University of

Nigeria, Nsukka, to whom my gratitude must be expressed are: Ken, Ifesinachi, (P.hD),

Okolie A. M. (P.hD), Edeh, H. (Ph.D) and Abada, M.I. (P.hD) for their assistance in

getting some of the initial materials for this work ; in addition to their academic input

during my ‘short’ but meaningful and eventful intellectual sojourn in the department.

I also wish to acknowledge the efforts of my mentor, in the person of Ezirim,

Gerald E. of the Social Science Unit, School of General Studies, University of Nigeria,

Nsukka and Chukwu Quentin for their moral supports.

Page 7: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

v

Special appreciation equally extends to the entire members of my family, namely

My Beloved and Caring Parents Mr. and Mrs. P. N. Okoye, for the moral and financial

deposits they made in me. My humble sense of gratitude equally worships at the altar of

my brothers; Iyke, Chidi, Nnaemeka, Nnamdi, Ugochukwu and Divine as well as my

sisters; Ifeoma, Chigozie, Chinwe and Rejoice, all of whom in their deft and astute sense

of understanding have to stand in for me, in one way or the other during my academic

years as an undergraduate. The prayers and goodwill gestures of every Okoye-Onyeguili

and Emebo families are equally acknowledged and appreciated; since time and space

permits me not to mention your names and contributions individually.

Particular debts of gratitude are owed to these wonderful friends of mine; Onah

Chukwumuanya (Muasky), Mbonu, Chinedu (Edu Yaweh), Anozie Gordon, Asadu

Godwin (JP), Doffe Benedeth S., Chioma, Oluchi and Ogbodo Tochukwu.

Lastly, I am profoundly grateful to all the proprietors of the Schools, Extra-mural

Centres and my students in Nsukka where I taught as well as my classmates and friends

both within and outside “the den” with whom I exchanged great ideas throughout this

academic pilgrimage.

I once more thank them all, but above all the Almighty Father takes all glory for

in him lays our hope and salvation.

OKOYE ANTHONY B. C.

2011

Page 8: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

vi

LIST OF MAPS

1: Ghana’s Hydrocarbon Exploration ….. ….. ….. 48

2: Detailed Map of the Jubilee Field off the West Coast of Western Ghana …. 49

Page 9: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

vii

LIST OF TABLES

1: Offshore Oil Blocks in Ghana ….. ….. ….. 51

2: Implication of Projected Oil Revenue for Fiscal Consolidation in Ghana …. 56

3: Variables ‘Reach’ of Initiatives on Resource Revenue Transparency,

Accountability and Participation ….. ….. ….. 60

4: Distribution of FDI inflow among Selected (Well and Less Natural

Resource Endowed) African Countries in billion US$ ….. ….. 118

Page 10: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

viii

LIST OF FIGURES

1: Comparison of Economic Performance between Resource Rich and Resource

Poor Countries. ….. ….. ….. ….. 21

2: Projected Oil Revenue for Ghana 2010 – 2015 ….. ….. ….. 55

3: Oil Production Chain and Intervention ….. ….. ….. 71

4: Benchmark for the Government Petroleum Fund-Global ….. ….. ….. 77

5: Governance Structure of the Norwegian Pension Fund-Global ….. ….. 77

6: EITI Civil Society Validation Grid ….. ….. ….. 91

7: Ghana Exports 1992 – 2015 ….. ….. ….. 99

8: Foreign Direct Investment Inflow in Ghana ….. ….. ….. 122

9: Ghana’s FDI as Percentage of GDP and Total World FDI Inflow ….. 123

Page 11: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

ix

LIST OF ABBREVIATIONS

OFID OPEC Fund for International Development

ISODEC Integrated Social Development Centre

UNDP United Nations Development Programme

IMF International Monetary Fund

GNPC Ghana National Petroleum Corporation

EPA Environmental Protection Agency

FPSO Floating, Production, Storage and Offloading Vessel

EITI Extractive International and Transparency Initiative

GEITI Ghana Extractive International and Transparency Initiative

MNC’S Multi-National Corporations

NOC’s National Oil Companies

TNC’s Trans-National Corporations

IOC’s International Oil Companies

GLSS Ghana Living Standard Surveys

SME’s Small and Medium Scale Enterprises

GSGDA Ghana Shared Growth and Development Agenda

FDI Foreign Direct Investment

PWYP Publish What You Pay

UNCTAD United Nations Conference on Trade and Development

Page 12: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

x

ABSTRACT

Natural resource discovery in a country can be the beginning of the country’s economic

growth. The wealth from the resources if well managed could promote sustained

economic development. The exploration and exploitation of natural resources is usually

accompanied with the paradox of development and challenges. The discovery of oil in

commercial quantity in Ghana in June 2007, has raised the hope of Ghanaians as it

regards better days to come. However, oil has its own effect on an economy. While it is

supposed to be a blessing, empirical evidence reveals that it has frequently become a

curse in most countries of the Third World, especially in the African Continent, where it

usually produces and reproduces renting seeking, conflict, patronage, Dutch disease and

resource curse. The study seeks to investigate the interface between oil and national

development in Ghana. The thrust of the study however, was to interrogate the possibility

of oil serving as the pillar of the socio-economic development and transformation of the

country; while at the same time avoiding the perennial problem of resource curse and the

Dutch disease that characterize most other oil producing African states. On the account of

this, we examined the ways through which Ghana can transform its oil natural resources

into a blessing rather than a curse by devising transpraent and accountably oil oil

governance best practices. We hypothesised that Ghana can avoid the resource curse

conundrum through the formulation of strong oil sector policies and the adoption of oil

governance best practices and that there is a positive relationship between Oil discovery

and production and the rate of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) inflow into Ghana. The

institutional theory of resource curse was used as our framework of analysis. We argued

that it is not the natural resources that determines its effect on an economy rather that it is

the operational underpinnings of the institutions in place and the legal regimes that

determines the management, regulations and uses of the oil revenue and wealth that

actually dictate whether the resource will be a blessing or curse within an economy. The

study make use of observation method of secondary sources of textbook, journals,

magazines, conference papers, official documents and Internet sources. It also adopted the

qualitative descriptive method of analysis as our method of data analysis. Through which

we, found that Ghana will escape the resource curse conundrum by adopting and

implementing oil governance best practices as is the case with Alaska, Norway and

Botswana. It was also discovered that with the right management and use of oil revenue

that will manifest in macro-economic stability in addition of other factors that oil

discovery and production will continue to attract Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) into

Ghana. Drawing from this, the work argues that the development of institutions and

policies that pursue prudent macroeconomic and fiscal policies will save Ghana from

resource curse.

Page 13: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

xi

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Title Page ….. ….. ….. ….. ….. i

Approval Page ….. ….. ….. ….. ….. ii

Dedication ….. ….. ….. ….. ….. iii

Acknowledgement ….. ….. ….. ….. ….. iv

List of Maps ….. ….. ….. ….. ….. vi

List of Tables….. ….. ….. ….. ….. vii

List of Figures….. ….. ….. ….. ….. viii

List of Abbreviation ….. ….. ….. ….. ix

Abstract ….. ….. ….. ….. ….. x

Table of Contents….. ….. ….. ….. ….. xi

CHAPTER ONE: INTRODUCTION

1.1. Introduction ….. ….. ….. ….. 1

1.2. Statement of the Problem ….. ….. ….. 3

1.3. Objectives of the Study ….. ….. ….. 4

1.4. Significance of the Study ….. ….. ….. 4

1.5. Literature Review ….. ….. ….. 5

1.6. Theoretical Framework ….. ….. ….. 37

1.7. Hypotheses ….. ….. ….. 40

1.8. Method of Data Collection ….. ….. ….. 40

1.9. Method of Data Analysis ….. ….. ….. 40

CHAPTER TWO: HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENT OF OIL EXPLORATION

AND PRODUCTION IN GHANA

2.1: Brief History of Ghana ….. ….. ….. 44

2.2: History of Oil and Gas Exploration in Ghana ….. ….. 45

2.3: Developing the Oil Jubilee Oil Field ….. ….. ….. 49

2.4 Projected Ghana’s Oil Revenue ….. ….. ….. 53

2.5 The Role of the Ghana National Petroleum Corporation….. 56

CHAPTER THREE: OIL GOVERNANCE AND AVOIDANCE OF RESOURCE

CURSE IN GHANA

3.1: Natural Resource Governance Initiatives ….. ….. 59

3.2: Oil Governance Best Practices….. ….. ….. 68

3.3: Case Studies of Oil Governance ….. ….. ….. 71

3.4: Accountability and Transparency in Ghana Public Sector… 78

3.5: Civil Society and the Management of Ghana’s Oil Wealth…. 85

3.6: Ways of Maximizing Transparency in the Oil Sector ….. 93

3.7: Analysis of Ghana’s Petroleum Revenue Management Act… 94

Page 14: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

xii

3.8: Estimated Contribution of Oil to Ghana’s Economy ….. 97

CHAPTER FOUR: OIL AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN GHANA

4.1: Introduction ….. ….. ….. 103

4.2: Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment….. ….. 105

4.3: Factors that Determines Foreign Direct Investment

inflow in Ghana ….. ….. ….. ….. 110

4.4 Ghana’s Policy Environment for FDI ….. ….. ….. 113

4.5: FDI and Its Relationship with Natural Resources ….. 117

4.6: Applying Findings in Case Studies to Ghana ….. ….. 119

4.7: Oil and Foreign Direct Investment in inflow in Ghana ….. 122

4.8: Impact of the Oil Induced FDI to Ghana ….. 125

CHAPTER FIVE: SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATIONS

5.1: Summary ….. ….. ….. 128

5.2: Conclusion ….. ….. ….. 120

5.3: Recommendations ….. ….. ….. 131

BIBLIOGRAPHY ….. ….. ….. 133

Page 15: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

1

CHAPTER ONE

INTRODUCTION

1.1 BACKGROUND OF STUDY

Ghana’s development path has not been an easy one. From the time of

colonial rule to independence Ghana has not developed the way it

should have. Ghana and Malaysia had independence almost at the

same time. However, Malaysia has developed far more than Ghana.

Whilst Malaysia is counted among middle income nations, Ghana is

struggling to come out of the category of low income nations. To

know whether a nation is a developing or low income one, factors like

Human Development Index, poverty level, unemployment rate, levels

of physical development, per capita income, distribution of wealth

and structure of the economy among other things must be considered.

http://news.myjoyonline.com/features/201011/55056.asp

The citation above captures the situation that characterizes the Ghanaian economy and its

fate in terms of the country’s quest and attempt at economic growth and development over the

years. However, with the coming of oil into the country’s litany of natural resource, it appears

that its story is about to change. This is so because “oil fever” has gripped Ghanaians since the

first major oil discovery in the country’s history was announced in June 2007. Since that time,

Ghana has rapidly emerged as an oil industry hotspot. While there has been some oil exploration

over the past century, with a trickle of oil produced in the Saltpond field, it has only been in the

past decade that serious efforts have been made.

Ghana is on the verge of becoming a major oil-producing and exporting country based on

its proven reserves. Oil production in the country started on 17th December, 2010 however, this

will quickly decline over the following decade as field capacity is tapped. Ghana has an enviable

record of good governance and stability. Despite this progress, Ghana is still a poor country of 23

million people that depend largely on primary commodity exports such as cocoa, gold and timber,

with almost 80 percent of Ghanaians living on less than $2 a day (ISODEC, 2010:7).

However, with the recent discovery of oil and its maiden exportation; it is suggested that

billions of dollars will be flowing into the government treasury, but Ghanaians are all too familiar

with corruption, poor development outcomes in the country’s mining communities, and the

tragedy of Nigeria’s squandered oil wealth. For the international oil industry, the 2007 “Jubilee”

finds called one of the largest recent finds in Africa, has generated enormous interest in the

country’s hydrocarbons potential. It is estimated that in 2011, that Ghana will be producing

approximately 120,000 barrels of oil per day, along with significant quantities of gas. The

International Monetary Fund has predicted that government revenues from oil and gas could

Page 16: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

2

reach a cumulative US$20 billion over the production period of 2012–30 for the Jubilee field

alone. Now, as in many countries before it, Ghana’s recent discovery of a major offshore oil field

has created a mixture of exuberance and trepidation.

Over the past 20 years, Sub-Saharan Africa has been experiencing a large ramp-up in

investment and production of oil and gas. This surge in production has had profound impacts for

the people and political economy of nations in Africa’s Gulf of Guinea region and elsewhere

(Gary and Karl,, 2003; Ricardo, 2007; Shaxson, 2007; and Ghazvinian, 2007).

However, Ghana is no stranger to extractive industries or development strategies built on

primary commodity exports. Ghana is the second-largest gold producer in Africa; such that

during the era of British colonialism it was called the “Gold Coast” and the country also produces

bauxite, manganese, and diamonds. A large part of the rural population depend on cocoa

production and exports in earning their living. Timber is also an important export. With the

arrival of oil, some are concerned that this could hamper and not aid development strategies that

are working to move the country away from being a producer and exporter of basically primary

commodity.

The country’s Gross National Income per capita is $590, with about 78.5 percent of the

Ghanaians living on less than $2 a day. Life expectancy is 59.1 years, and the infant mortality

rate is 112 deaths per 1,000 live birth (World Bank, 2008,

http://go.worldbank.org/C9GR27WRJ0). Regional income disparities abound, with those in rural

areas and the northern part of the country not experiencing as much reduction in poverty.

According to the UN Development Program’s “Ghana Human Development Report 2007,” 45

percent of those living in the rural savannah area of northern Ghana lived in extreme poverty in

2006, compared with 5.4 percent in Accra, the capital, and a national rate of 18 percent

(www.govindicators.org.). Opposition candidates have jumped on these figures and claimed that

Ghana’s stability and economic growth have left many behind.

Ghana’s former President, John A. Kufuor, (2008) were of the view that the country’s

new “black gold” will be the boost that Ghana needs to become an “African tiger.” During the

euphoric days of June 2007 when the oil discovery was announced, President Kufuor said: “Oil is

money, and we need money to do the schools, the roads, the hospitals; if you find oil, you

manage it well, can you complain about that? Even without oil, we (Ghana) are doing so well,

already. Now, with oil as a shot in the arm, we’re going to fly.” (http://news.bbc.co.uk/go/pr/fr/-

/2/hi/business/6764549.stm.).

Paradoxically, it is now almost conventional wisdom that natural resources (oil) are a

curse for currently developing countries. This claim is supported both by some basic facts, for

example, for OPEC as a whole GDP per capita on average decreased by 1.3% each year from

Page 17: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

3

1965 to 1998 (Gylfason, 2001), and by cross country empirical work (Sachs and Warner, 1995,

1999; Busby et al., 2004; Mehlum et al., 2006). Moreover, numerous case studies of resource

dependent economies have linked resource abundance to poor development (Gelb, 1988; Karl,

1997; Ross, 1999, 2001).

It is therefore on this background that this study seeks to critically and systematically

assess the chances and possibilities of Ghana in avoiding the seeming intractable resources curse

syndrome, which has bedeviled other oil producing nations.

1.2 STATEMENT OF PROBLEM

Since the discovery of oil in large quantity in Ghana in June 2007, considerable attentions

have been directed to the Ghanaian Petroleum sector. But only little attention has been given to

the study of how to utilize the oil revenue to stimulate the economic growth and development of

the Ghanaian economy. However, this body of literatures has suffered from important

shortcomings. Even in terms of the modest accomplishment of the study of the oil and gas sector

of the Ghanaian economy, research in the area have not adequately articulated the

interconnections between the new found oil in Ghana and its national development.

Generally commentators on Ghana’s new found oil wealth, have variously and

exclusively concentrated either on the use of the oil revenue as a collateral for foreign loans and

borrowing (Adei 2010:1), consolidation of the fund, stashing away of the oil fund in special and

dedicated account, adoption of state policy of capital accumulation and formation (Asenso-

Okyere, 2010:4), or should go the way of Alaska by establishing the policy of cash in hand for

the citizens of the country (Moss, 2010), another group basing their analysis and conclusion on

the negative effect of oil windfall on the economy of other countries; out rightly condemned

Ghana to debased status of resource curse and Dutch disease.

More importantly, these analyses have not adequately clarified the organic

interconnections between oil revenue and Ghana development crises. Emphasis is, placed on the

use the oil revenue to build-up stock of wealth for the nations. Therefore, not much effort is

directed on the systematic analysis of how the general receipt and activities of the new found oil

and gas, will determine the developmental thrust and orientation of the overall socio-economic

development and progress of the Ghanaian economy, through the formulation of efficient oil

sector policies.

Deriving from the above, there has not been an adequate systematic treatment of the

establishment of the right institutions, formulations of practical oil and gas sector revenue

management and regulation laws and policies, that will determine and shape the nature of the

outcome and uses of the Ghana oil windfall for positive impacts and contributions of the oil

towards the economic and inter-sectoral progress (development) of Ghana. Thus, the impact of

Page 18: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

4

the country’s petroleum sectors on the ability of the nations to break away from its beggar

mentality, diversify its economy, shift from the producer and exporter of primary commodity and

the development of the human person through the enhancement of the nations Gross Domestic

Product (GDP), the quality of life of the people, the country’s preparedness to manage its oil

wealth in addition to attracting the much needed foreign capital in the form of Foreign Direct

Investment, (FDI) has not brought into clear focus.

It is therefore, against this background that an attempt is made to go beyond the façade of

‘journalistic’ rhetoric’s on the use of Ghana’s oil revenue to the critical analysis and assessment

of the organic interconnections between the Ghanaian petroleum sector (in terms of the fiscal

regimes governing the exploration, exploitation, production and marketing, especially the

revenues that guzzles therein) and its implications on her political economy, in terms of its ability

at attracting foreign capital and investment into the country that will directly and indirectly

contribute to the growth and development of the nations economy. In this connection, the

definition and redefinition of the place and role of oil in consonance with the socio-economic

growth and development of Ghana elicits such pertinent research questions as:

1. Given the experiences of other Sub-Saharan African oil producing countries, is it possible

for Ghana to avoid the resource curse conundrum?

2. Has oil discovery and production in Ghana, led to an increase in the rate of Foreign Direct

Investment (FDI) inflow into the country?

1.3 OBJECTIVE OF STUDY

The broad objective of this study is to critically assess the expected role that the new

found oil (wealth) in Ghana can play towards the socio-economic and political development of

the Ghanaian economy.

Specifically, the study has been designed to achieve the following detailed objective:

1. To determine if Ghana can avoid the resource curse conundrum through the formulation

of strong oil sector policies and the adoption of oil governance best practices.

2. To ascertain if oil discovery and production in Ghana has directly or indirectly led to an

increase in the rate of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) into the country.

1.4. SIGNIFICANCE OF STUDY

Ideally, every social science research possesses two levels of significance; the theoretical

and the practical. In keeping with this ideal, this study is of both theoretical and practical import.

At the theoretical level, the study will attempt to add to the existing body of knowledge

that attempts to explain the role of oil to national development especially as it concerns Ghana; in

its generic sense and specifically on the methods and ways through which it can escape the oil

induced resource curse. This, it is hoped, would enhance the understanding of the issue area. It is

Page 19: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

5

also hoped that the findings of this study would help to stimulate further discussion on and

research into the subject matter.

At the practical level, the study hopes to serve as a resource material for Ghana’s policy

makers, general public, businessmen, investors as well as other oil producing countries in Africa

especially those in the Gulf of Guinea that is presently suffering from the debilitating conundrum

of the Dutch disease and resource curse syndrome in general. The empirical significance is of

utmost importance as it will direct the Ghanaian diplomats, policy and decision makers towards

the formulation of policies and programme that will practically lunch Ghana into developmental

path, while at the same time avoiding the pitfalls that comes with oil discovery and production

that has manifested in rent seeking, paradox of plenty, oil induced conflict et cetera in other oil

rich countries in the Sub-Saharan Africa. In this way, we will be contributing to the better

appreciation of the way forward in Ghana new found oil industry as well as in its multilateral

relations with the outside world as represented in the Multinational Oil Corporations and Foreign

Direct Investments, that is already competing for the soul of the Ghanaian State [oil industry] (see

Onuoha, 2008:10).

1.5 LITERATURE REVIEW

The focus of this literature review is in the areas of development, resource curse, Foreign

Direct Investment and issues relating to the oil discovery in Ghana the development, resource

curse, role and use of oil in Ghana. In so doing, attempt will be made to conceptualise the term

development. In the process concepts of economic development and development perspectives

will be exhaustively examined. More significantly, we shall categorise the basic propositions of

the distinct strands of thought in development economics and then explore alternative views in

the explanation of underdevelopment in peripheral socio-formations such as Ghana. The review

will also identify, discuss and present the various strands in the resource curse argument, in

addition to its various causes. It will also consider the propositions on the Foreign Direct

Investment and economic growth and development nexus. Finally, we shall evaluate the

propositions, positions and recommendations of commentators on Ghana’s new oil found with a

view to determining their strength and weaknesses as guide-post towards the socio-economic

advancement of the Ghanaian economy that will directly and indirectly enable it to escape the

resource curse conundrum.

Arising from the various literatures that have attempted explanation of the term is the fact

that development as a term that suffers from problems of definition. Hence, it assumes vastly

different meanings to scholars and political actors whose appreciation and application of the term,

reflect and manifest their distinct and diversifying methodological, epistemological and material

foundations and twists. In fact, so confused had the situation becomes that Seers (1969:12)

Page 20: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

6

wondered whether “instead of worrying about brushing aside the web of fantasy and

shipshoddedness surrounding the word ‘development’, we should not simply abolish its use and

look for a better and less debased word”. However, he proposed a redefinition of the term.

Generally, the term is often used to describe the process of economic and social

transformation within countries. This process often follows a well-ordered sequence and exhibits

common characteristics across countries. Meanwhile, Todaro (1992) perceives development as a

multi-dimensional process involving the reorganisation and re-orientation of entire economic and

social systems. He maintained that development must represent the entire gamut of changes by

which an entire social system, tuned to the diverse basic needs and desires of individuals and

social groups within that system, moves away from a condition of life widely perceived as

unsatisfactory and towards a situation or condition of life regarded as materially and spiritually

better. Nevertheless, Todaro’s analysis underplayed the vital role played by human factors and

the process through which development is actualized and sustained. Besides, his analysis was

anchored on immeasurable situational factors.

Perhaps, a much more concrete analysis was that adduced by Seers (1969:3). He

succinctly noted that:

The questions to ask about a country’s development are three: what

has been happening to poverty? What has been happening to

unemployment? What has been happening to inequality? If all these

three have declined from high levels, then beyond doubt this has been

a period of development for the country concerned.

Subsequently (Seers, 1977:12) added self-reliance as one of the cardinal ingredients of

development. He nonetheless, failed to provide measurement instruments and/or criteria for the

prescribed cardinal ingredients of development and like most writers glossed over the role of

human factors in the process of development.

In fact, Cairncross (1961:250) correctly observed that “the key to development lies in

men’s minds, in the institutions in which their thinking finds expression and in the play of

opportunities on ideas and institutions”. Therefore, development embraces the major economic

and social objectives and values that societies strive for. Thus Goulet (1971:87-94) and Thirlwall

(1989:9) argue that development occurs when there are improvement in life sustenance, self-

esteem and freedom and when material advancement has expanded the range of choice for

individuals. In the same vein, Mabogunje (1981:46) underscores the primacy of human factors.

He noted among others that development is essentially a human issue, a concern with the capacity

of individuals to realize their inherent potential and effectively cope with the changing

circumstances of their lives. He also noted that development involves the total and full

mobilization of a society towards a self-centered and self-reliant position with regards not only to

Page 21: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

7

the process of decision-making, but more importantly the pattern and style of production and

consumption.

Meanwhile, social science literatures are inundated with writings, which conceive

development in terms of economic growth and modernisation. Specifically, western-orientated

scholars encourage underdeveloped states to model their societies in line with the international

and structural arrangements and orientations reminiscent of advanced capitalist states. These

scholars include: Pye (1966), Rostow (1960), Coleman (1968), Huntington (1965) et cetera. They

churn out a checklist of artifacts which they perceive as indicators of development; these include

industrialization; economic affluence; military hegemony; advanced technology; urbanization,

and the parliamentary political process (Nnoli:1981:21).

However, Frank (1969), Amin (1973), Baran (1967), Ake (1996), Nnoli (1981), Gana

(1989), et cetera have in their various writings unleashed a deserved and unmitigated critique of

the modernization theorists. They among others noted that the modernizations persuasion

abstracted from history and concluded by presenting logically inconsistent analysis. Hence, their

suggestion and prescriptions are not only theoretically inadequate, but empirically untenable and

policy-wise ineffective.

In particular, Nnoli (1981), Ake (1972) and Rodney (1982) observed that development is

multifaceted and man-centred. It derives from the material conditions of the people concerned

and hence it is neither imposed nor hoisted. In fact, Ate (1972) warned that ‘development that

commits us to a wholesome imitation of others leads to a wholesale reputation of our being”.

Similarly Nnoli (1981) conceives development as “a dialectical phenomenon in which the

individual and society interact with their physical, biological and inter-human environment

transforming them for their own betterment and that of humanity at large and being transformed

in the process”. The above conceptualization appears comprehensive but were not anchored

something concrete, precise and measurable.

Development should better be perceived as man-directed phenomenal socio-economic

and political transformation of self and entire structure of a given political system. These involve

acquisition of new and relevant ideas, skills, propensities, preferences and predispositions which

are directed towards improvement of the living conditions and existentialities of the concerned

population. The above subsequently translate into improvement in man’s potentials and

capabilities; elimination or rather reduction of poverty, inequality, unemployment and thus

improvement in life sustenance, self-esteem, freedom and value-orientations.

As a corollary of the above, development refers to anything that advances the individual

through the qualitative transformation of his or her immediate environment, a transformation of

which the main purpose is simply to provide him or her in due course with a better standard of

Page 22: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

8

living in economic or human terms. The development process must first and foremost make room

for an awakening of the potentials of the beings who are both its initial protagonists and its

ultimate targets; human beings (Mayor, 1996:87). The conceptualization above will provide a

good framework with which we can realistically put the underdeveloped countries (Ghana

inclusive) back on the trajectory of development.

Nevertheless, development is usually perceived essentially as an economic phenomenon.

But this is rather parochial. Development has political, economic and social ramifications. It is a

comprehensive and integrative phenomenon which must be appreciated as such and applied

accordingly. Hitherto, liberal writers state that economic development concentrates primarily on

economic growth as reflected by increases in Gross National Product (GNP), industrialization,

capital formation, welfare services, the development of infrastructure such as roads, electricity

and railways and increased economic efficiency (Nnoli, 1981:29). However, using GNP as a

parameter for measuring levels of development is not only dubious but misleading. As Webster

rightly observes, it does not account for activities like smuggling, domestic labourers and network

of families engaged in subsistence food production (Webster, 1990:29).

In fact, an analysis of economic development should concentrate on the process by which

various economic activities appear, grow in importance, and in some cases, decline or disappear.

Basically, literature on economic development has been dominated by three major strands of

thought:

1. the ‘stages of economic growth’ theories of the1950’s and early 1960’s;

2. the ‘international dependency’ theories of the late 1960s and the 1970’s; and

3. the ‘free market’ theories of the 1980s and 90’s (Todaro, 1992:29).

In 1950s, development was conceptualized from the perceptive of the modernisation

persuasion. The modernisation theory was the dominant mode of analysis and it attributes the

causes of underdevelopment to factors sui generis and endogenous to the less developed

countries. Thus, the theory advocates a total transformation of traditional or pre-modern entities

approximating the technologies and organisation of the advanced capitalist societies.

The chief proponents who included, Rostow (1960), Hoselitz (1971), McClelland (1971)

and Hagen (1980) et cetera, compartmentalized the world into the traditional and modern

societies. The former is seen as backwards, primitive, and technologically deformed. They also

argued that traditional societies are held down by certain inhibiting factors that usually undermine

realistic and sustained economic development. On the other hand, they classified modern

societies as the advanced capitalist societies that are technologically advanced, politically stable

and governed by pragmatism and oriented to development. Thus they encourage underdeveloped

Page 23: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

9

societies to imbibe imitative attitudes, and remodel their societies after the advanced capitalist

societies.

However, the apparent failure of the modernisation prescription to stimulate sustainable

development lead to the emergence of international dependence school of thought, which brewed

the dependency theory. The theory has Latin American origin. The movement emerged as a

critique of modernisation paradigm, especially as a critique of import substitution

industrialization, which failed to accomplish industrial development in Latin America.

The dependency paradigm attempts an understanding and explanation of socio-political

and economic variables that re-enforce underdevelopment by focusing on the historical

circumstances surrounding the underdeveloped countries. It argues among others, that the

conditions and circumstances of the Third World Countries would be concretely appreciated if we

examined the experiences of the underdeveloped countries in terms of the mode of their

incorporation into the capitalist economy, their performances within it, and the mechanism for

sustaining the conditions of underdevelopment. Notable among the advocates of the dependency

paradigm are Cardoso (19: 83-95). Frank (1969), Furtado (1976), Santos (1970), Baran (1967),

and Sunkel (1973:132-76) et cetera.

As a direct corollary to the above, underdevelopment is here perceived in terms of

international and domestic power relationships, institutional and structural economic rigidities,

and the resulting proliferation of dual economies and dual societies both within and among the

nations of the World. They maintain that the less developed countries could only develop if they

repudiate Western oriented development strategies and simply adopt internally stimulated

development strategies, simply put, if they first delink.

However, by emphasizing more of exogenous variables rather than the entire structure of

the socio-economic system, to explain underdevelopment and the dynamics of international

political economy, the dependency theory presents a picture of absolute fatalism; condemning the

underdeveloped countries to unalterable deteriorating position; almost irreversibly determined by

neo-colonialism and offering no hope of escape from the stranglehold of underdevelopment.

Moreover, by prescribing delinking as an alternative option for development, the dependentistas

glossed over the internal conditions of the less developed countries, including the leadership

factor, which obviously cannot sustain the demands of their prescription.

Thus, in the 1980s through the new millennium, emphasis shifted to free market and less

government intervention in the economy; in order to promote competition and stimulate rapid

growth and development. Through the much propagated and re-invigorated globalisaition and its

processes, developing states are practically coerced into imbibing the market economy doctrine.

Developing Countries are inveigled into accepting and swallowing the pill of trade liberalization,

Page 24: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

10

foreign direct investment (FDI), privatization, deregulation et cetera. However, these have not put

the economies of underdeveloped countries back on the trajectory of sustainable development.

Instead this new surge of World Capitalism is introducing even greater distortions into the

polities of Third World States.

The above concretely demonstrates that the developing states have been wallowing from

one development fad to another. This results basically from the different perceptions of

development, both as a fact-situation, and a process. Hence in the attempt to grasp the substantive

and methodological features of development, and use same for public administration and a basis

for political action, successive political leaders in developing countries, adopt specific

development models ranging from the state-centric perspective to the models which emphasize

the expansion of the market from the domestic to the interdependent.

Nevertheless, the adoption of any of the models of development has not practically

translated into remarkable development. Various explanations have been adduced for the

prevailing and persisting economic conditions of distinct underdeveloped states. These, though,

appears to melt under the boiling pot of the nature and character of international political

economy which sustains an asymmetrical relationship between the developed and developing

states.

Therefore, while Prebisch (1950), Singer (1950) and Baldwin (1972) blame

underdevelopment on terms of trade; Okishio (1963) and Emmanuel (1992) anchors their

explanation on unequal exchange; all these however centers on the nature and character of

international trade. Nevertheless, the structuralists, among whom is Rodriques (1980) based their

analysis on the structure of the mode of production. They criticized the conventional theory of

international trade and maintain that the problem can be located on the international division of

labour which they argue was of much greater benefit to the centre than the periphery. To break

this yoke, the structuralists prescribe rapid and massive industrialization. Nonetheless, they gave

no consideration to the social relations of production which are at the base of the process of

import-substituting industrialization and of the transformation in other structures of society that

this brings to/in its wake. This however, is not under-playing the fact that the international

economic system is characterised by inequality and lop-sided development.

Arguing further on this, Nweke (1984:7) observes that underdevelopment is sustained by

global inequality and distorted development. This, he argues, is a largely unavoidable

consequence of their colonial past. This is not stating that colonialism is a singular cause of

underdevelopment. Global inequality is a natural phenomenon. It is a consequence of differing

levels of development of productive forces in the constituting political units. Hence, global

equality negates the cosmic order. Of course, uneven development is an intrinsic or inherent

Page 25: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

11

property of the economic process. Far from being merely transitory, it seems to be a pervasive

and permanent condition (1989:335). The present economic configuration in the international

economic relations is essentially a product of differential growth of the productive potentials

and/or pattern of production.

The international economic order is analytically classified into two poles, the ‘centre’ and

the ‘periphery’. Although the classification is not mutually exclusive, the two poles are closely

bound together, and are mutually and reciprocally conditioning. Nevertheless, the periphery is

subordinated by the international division of labour, to a status of ‘hewer of wood and drawer of

water’. Most of the underdeveloped countries come from Africa.

Most African states are bedeviled by retarded economic growth spiraling inflation,

currency devaluation, trade deficits, external debt burden, poverty, illiteracy, disease, inadequate

socio-economic infrastructure, political instability amidst intractable population explosion and

low life expectancy. The question that at remains at this point therefore is how Ghana’s new

found oil can assist it in addressing this developmental anomaly.

Oil and National Development in Ghana

There is a vast literature that looks at the impact of oil windfalls and natural resources in

general on a small open economy (Collier and Gunning, 1999:20). The oil-price shocks first

sparked discussions on the harmful side effects of oil windfalls, due to the observation that oil

producing countries under-performed relative to other developing countries despite the

unprecedented increase in wealth following the oil-price hikes (Gelb, 1989:23).

Wijinberger (1984:41-55) and Krugman (1987:41-55) centering their studies on the issue

of ”Dutch Disease” phenomenon, which refers to the negative effects that an export boom may

have on traditional export sectors and overall productivity growth, maintained that most oil based

economies are usually trapped in learning-by-doing effects in their tradable sectors.

Majid (1960:12) in his study of the contribution of the oil sector to Arab Economic

Development maintained that the role of oil sector in an economy usually pass through various

stages and forms; that are in themselves a function of (dependent on) the developments in the oil

markets and flow of revenues. He however went on to assert that the peculiar roles of the oil

sector generated revenues varies across and among nations depending on the political,

institutional and fiscal relations between the oil sectors as represented by the National Oil

Companies (NOCs) and their respective governments.

Scott (1970:156) in his study of the Nigerian petroleum industry, its operations, effects

and implications, opined that there are basically four methods and/or strategies by which a

technologically less advanced country (in this case Ghana) can tap on potential extractive mineral

reserve; which in include the following:

Page 26: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

12

Invite foreign concessionaire to form local subsidiaries and thereby supply management

and technology, capital and market.

Undertake joint venture in which foreign investors supply managements, technology and

market as well as a portion of the capital with the remaining capital furnished by the host

country supplies the capital and tries to find the market.

Institute management contracts whereby experienced foreign firms offer managements

and technology only and the host country supplies the capital and tries to find market.

Do without foreign participation altogether and furnish management, technology, capital

and market itself.

He went to state that the colonial governments around the 3rd world countries usually

adopts the first options, the colonial governments adopted the first options while the post-colonial

states usually opt for the latter. The situation is occasioned by the fact that these countries lack

equipment and expertise needed in the sector. He conclude by arguing that the general unresolved

question of development that, confronts such an economy namely rivalry, large and increasing

urban unemployment, proper degree of government intervention in the industry.

Tugendhat (1968:5) gives a most brilliant account of the history of international oil

industry from 1859 when Edwin L. Drake drilled the first oil well near Titusville in Pennsylvania,

USA to 1960 when the OPEC was formed in Baghdad and recounted the struggle over reduction

of posted price of oil between the companies and host governments. He recounted the events that

eventually led to the formation of OPEC, which turned the table in favour of oil producing states

in the sense that they now control both economic and political powers. Thus:

As practical executives with experience of the international

oil industry, these men understand why the companies had cut

their prices, and some of their public statements not

withstanding, they knew that the reduction would not be

rescinded. Their aim was to make unilateral action impossible

in future and to ensure that the companies always kept the

product government’s interest rather that those of anybody

else in the forefront of their minds… The result of their

deliberation was the formation of the Organisation of

Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC)… The wheel had

turned full circles since Achanacarry and the companies have

never since tried to reduce the posted price.

In effect this means that oil producing countries such as Ghana are in position to

determine at what price their petroleum sells and what quantity to produce. As a result of this

hard-won power, Ghana as an oil producer will soon experience tremendous increase in its

revenue in the years ahead starting from 2011 when it starts oil exportation. A situation that will

Page 27: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

13

enable the country to disentangle itself from the socio-economic morass that presently

characterizes it.

Addotey (2010:1) observes that the oil industry do actually generates lots of money;

however it does not create an economy, since it is a narrow industry that does not employ a lot of

people. Buttressing his point he opined that:

Moscow has more millionaires than any other city in the

world with their source of wealth traceable to Russia’s oil

industry but Russia’s economy is short of pride. ...it (oil)

creates layers of difficulties to economic development than it

helps. The Middle Eastern countries provide us with further

insight where oil money has led to misplaced priority and

continuous arm race. The situation becomes more acute for

economies that heavily produce crude for export. Apart from

a quick sight of barrels been loaded into ships for export the

ordinary person would have no idea of what goes on in the

industry.

In furtherance he maintained that in Saudi Arabia, that continuous inflow of oil money

means that there is more money in the country but fewer jobs for the people. The economy for

ages remains less diversified. The scenario gets worse when populist sentiments begins to set in,

that is when the people begin to feel that the oil is in fact being used against them. Describing the

situation in Nigeria, he states that the Nigeria’s oil grinding machine has been grinding for

decades but oil receipt has never manage to turn the economy round let alone provide a decent

life for the local people on whose land the black stuff is produced.

Abbey (2010: 1-2) posited that for Ghana to actually enjoy the benefits of the expected oil

windfall that Ghana must avoid the mistakes of other oil drilling countries, where oil has turned

out to be a curse rather than a blessing. He also noted that in other to avoid such mistakes and

make Ghana’s oil find beneficial to the citizenry that there is a need to assess the country’s socio-

economic situation.

Moreover, he stressed that Ghanaians are neither more brainy nor luckier than citizens of

other countries that are suffering the ravages of oil conflicts. He therefore advocated for the need

for consensus building as a means of maximizing the profits of oil revenue, thus:

Let us prepare well. Let the oil be a facilitator. Let it be the thing

that broke our beggar mentality; the oil find should be a call to

action, particularly for those who have the capacity and skill to

advise government on the way forward.

Page 28: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

14

He went on to state categorically that the Jubilee oil field discovery and its expected

revenue and Ghana’s status as an oil producer have several implications for the country, which

the country’s policy and decision makers should concern themselves with in order to circumvent

possible negative consequences that may come with the country’s new socio-economic status.

We should by now have sat down to ascertain how much money

donors are likely to hold back as a result of our oil producing

status and determine how much of the oil money we plan to

spend or set aside for future generations.

On the proposition that the revenue from the crude oil production should be saved for

future use, he maintained that stashing the oil money away rather than put them into economic

use on the mere pretence of saving for the future is tantamount to inefficiency and utter lack of

vision on the path of the nation in terms of the developmental path or strides the nation wishes to

achieve, which by implication is an admission that the country is obviously confused about what

to do with the oil revenue. Thus he contends that:

It is when you are incapable of using your talents that you bury it.

“In fact, the bigger the amount we want to set aside, the louder we

announce to the world that we don’t trust we’ll use this resource

judiciously and that we are not prepared to plan our future.

…about entering into something that could ignite or stall the

country’s development and yet have no idea exactly what to do

with the expected oil wealth.

Moreover, he opined that the questions as to how much (money) the country is to put in

an endowment or stabilisation fund among others, must hinge on the basis of where the country is

and where it want to go. The basis for determining the rate of distribution of the projected

revenue must in turn hinge on knowing where we are. He described these as fundamentals for

determining what levels of investments to make in meeting Ghana’s present developmental needs

and what to set aside for future use.

Asenso-Okyere (2010:4) posited that the only way through which Ghana can practically

benefits and ensures sustainable development of its economy on the basis of the oil revenue is by

adopting a state policy of capital accumulation and formation. A situation in which the country

will build up stock of oil wealth and stash it away in bank vault for the future generations of

Ghanaians rather that utilizing all of the entire money. Hence he opined:

We must avoid the Nigerian and Dutch … He explained that

Nigeria, for instance, was estimated to have gained some

US$600 billion in oil benefits but the country still remained

one of the 20 poorest countries in the world because it did not

save some of that wealth against the future.

Page 29: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

15

In the case of the Dutch, the economy evolved around their

natural gas to the detriment of all other sectors of the

economy and that mistake resulted in the infamous Dutch

Disease characterised by a near collapse of that economy.

He was also of the view that deep sea oil exploration and extraction is expensive and so a

lot of the revenue that would be generated would be reinvested, hence there exists that dire need

and frugality on the part of the country as to the wise use of the little that would be left. As a

result he maintained that the current trend of events around the world in terms of natural resource

use and management posed a threat to future generations; because of the crave for immediate

survival other than the future, was the cause of indiscriminate depletion of natural resource,

resulting in climate change and its resultant disasters, conflicts over extractive mineral revenue,

corruption, crime and disease. In fact, he attributed the behaviour of the present generation

towards natural resources to greed, insatiable and careless consumption and blatant disregard for

the needs of the yet unborn.

Sunnu-Atta (see, Ato Kobbie, 2010:1) asserted that Ghana has the requisite human

resource to make local content work in the oil and gas industry, citing successes chalked in the

country taking over the leadership of such mega-projects like the Tema Oil Refinery (TOR) and

the Volta River Authority (VRA), stating that “those entities are running and expanding and have

not failed,” though not without some hitches here and there. Hence “It will take hard work, a lot

of innovative brainwork and, above all, strong willpower to make it a success; we have no choice

other than to make oil a blessing for Ghana”. In furtherance, he advocated for joint venture,

which will involve the Ghanaian government and some foreign companies, a situation he believes

will enhance both transfer of technology, research and development (R and D) in addition to local

content.

Huno and Konda (2010:3-5) commenting on the attendant joy and jubilation that

accompanied the discovery of oil in commercial quantity in Ghana opined that the oil find is a

very welcomed piece of news; since Ghana has always been noted to have oil deposits but what

was not known was the commercial viability of the deposits. The joy was due to the fact that

Ghanaians are aware that oil generates a lot of revenue for a country and very soon the oil

revenue will begin to trickle in. This means a lot to a poor country like Ghana that is in desperate

want of development and socio-economic transformation. The problems with this type of

assertion is that if fails to tell us what actually that needs to be done with the so-called oil mega

wealth that oil brings in order for it to help in the transformation of the Ghanaian economy.

Adei (2010:1) the former Rector of the Ghana Institute of Management and Public

Administration (GIMPA), on his part advocated that Ghana should use its oil revenue as a

collateral for foreign loans and borrowing, which according to him is in the national interest for

Page 30: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

16

national development. And that “There is nothing wrong with that since the country (Ghana) has

been into collateralisation all these years, hence the oil is not different.” He, however, indicated

that the move should be backed by a comprehensive, non-partisan national development agenda

and the process made more transparent.

What we must not forget is that anytime a country takes a

loan, it is backed by collateral. The question, therefore, should

be, how is it done? It is the process that should be transparent,

not the collateralisation itself.

He concluded by pointing out categorically that the country had, over the years, been

collateralising cocoa and other resources for loans. Despite the plausibility of this proposition,

what Adei failed to take cognizance of, is the fact that it is the human factor in the political class

are the single most important variable and element that will decide the end into which the money

borrowed or loaned will be put into. Besides this may result to a situation in which a cabal may

ride on their positions and connection to not only plunder the state treasury but equally deepen

the debt problem of the country that will in turn derail the development focus and quest of the

nation.

On the other hand, Yaa (2010:1-2) was in total dissonance with the apostles of

collateralization; he on the contrary held the opinion that without a cogent National Development

Plan indiscriminate borrowing on the basis of the country’s expected oil revenues will tie the

hands of Ghanaians. Hence they should be careful how they approach the use or lack thereof of

the oil revenues in the country because it is too early in the game to think of using future oil

revenues as collateral for loans, bearing in mind that the country is yet to receive a dime from the

new found national resource and they are already all over themselves about mortgaging the future

earnings. He therefore asserts:

We are all aware of how loans are procured for the Nation and

the potential of individuals greed to sell off the country, As a

country we have shown a lack of sophistication in

procurement of loans and we have shown a lack of an ability

to monitor or police these loans to ensure that they are used

for whatever they are intended for.

Continuing he argued that Ghana's petroleum wealth at any point in time is held in three

assets: the proven reserves, the revenues in the transitory petroleum account, and finally the

savings in the funds. Whereas the entire Clause 5 of Petroleum Revenue Management Bill seeks

to protect two things. First, the potential securitization of the proven reserves which includes the

entitlements of the private oil companies as well as the savings for the future generations. To the

extent that only portion of the reserves would finally be converted into government revenues.

Page 31: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

17

Hence, pledging the reserves in whole or in part can be a hazardous exercise. Besides, how will

the people ascertain how much of the reserves successive governments can borrow against and

for how long.

He stressed that throwing caution to the wind and thinking that the only way Ghana can

develop as a nation is through the acquisition of loans is dangerous. Since according to him the

nations have no clear national development agenda, rather what the country has been witnessing

is a situation in which loans are procured in a knee jerk fashion without a clear understanding of

how each loan fits in the overall national development plan. He goes on to outline number of

reasons why Ghana should at least for the present moment shun collateralization of the its oil on

the account of the nations experiences from its other natural resources and the conditionalities

that are usually attached to these loans that are basically in no way to the favour of the borrower.

Thus:

Loans are not gifts they subject the borrower to all kinds of

terms and conditions depending on the loan structure. We

should hold off collaterizing our oil reserves, see how

production goes and the trend thereof , see what kind of

revenue streams will come through, …and above all lets do all

of these in a transparent fashion.

This oil belongs to all of us. We should be prudent about how

we use it. Those shouting from the roof top about using our

future oil revenues as collateral for loans should not forget we

have had other natural resources and have made nothing of

them. What has happened to our revenues from our timber,

gold, bauxite, diamond, cocoa to mention a few. What is our

experience from the manipulation of these other national

assets? Today our gold industry is owned by foreign

companies. Our cocoa is smuggled to Ivory Coast and we

pardon companies who do the smuggling. The oil will go the

same way if we are not careful.

He however, conceded to the fact that there are certain conditions under which it can be

rational to use the oil for loan but, it must be strictly in line with the national developmental

projects that the country is pursuing rather than serving as a pawn in the hands of a rent seeking

and comprador political class and their allies. That is to say that even at this that the need and

importance of such a loan will be thoroughly scrutinized and debated upon before the country

embarks upon it in order to ensure that it will actually serve the proposed national interest. This

not withstanding he posited that Ghana should as a matter of fact desist from borrowing within

the next five or thereabout years, a period in which the country must have actually understand not

Page 32: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

18

just the line the oil industry is going but must understood the revenue yielding capacity of the oil

in addition to what the developmental needs of the country really are.

Is there a place for using future oil revenues for loans? Yes

there is. But it must be within the context of a National

Development Plan and not based on the whims and caprices

of any group of people or of political persuasion. There must

not be a blanket statement in the oil bill about using future

revenues as collateral. Instead each consideration of a loan

must be individually debated, viewed in the broad context of

national development, its urgency debated before a

consideration of whether that particular loan qualifies for such

a waiver. I propose that in the next five years we should

refrain from using future oil revenues as collateral for loans.

This period will at least give us breathing space to understand

the industry and see what revenues will accrue, have an

understanding of how to apply the revenue to our

development. Ghana will not perish from the surface of the

earth if we apply caution and learn now to crawl before

running. Ghana is poised for greatness but this greatness will

elude us if we are arrogant and mindless of our future.

Amin (see, Akli, 2010:2) in collaboration with the view enunciated above by Yaa (2010)

advised that the Ghanaian government should take a cue from Nigeria, which resorted to the same

collaterisation of its oil revenue, and ended piling up debts to the tune of over $32 billion. Since

prices of oil sometimes fluctuate on the international market; therefore, if revenue from the sector

is used as collateral, re-payment of the debt would become problematic if the prices tumble, a

situation that severely hampers and derails the developmental agendas of such a country. Hence

he asserted that the government of Ghana and its policy makers and formulators should do away

with the idea of collaterisation of the oil revenue.

Osabutey (2010:7) expressed regrets that though the first Sub-Saharan African country to

gain independence with a bright lift, Ghana could be rated low in terms of development, thus,

“given Ghana’s rich endowment in human and natural resources, her development experience

may succinctly be described as one of missed opportunities.” Thus he stressed that Ghana’s oil

find, that is expected to generate about one billion dollars a year, falls short of over 1.4 billion

donor assistance the country receives every year, and “if donor assistance, which far surpasses the

expected revenue from the oil, have proven inadequate in tackling the nations developmental

challenges, then it is important for the country to properly manage the political and social

expectations of the many Ghanaians, who expect the oil discovery to all of a sudden translate to

economic prosperity and reflect directly in their pockets.”

Moss (2010, n.p) in his analysis of how to ensure that the oil receipts is ploughed back

into national development for the benefit of the people posited that Ghana should go the way of

Alaska’s by establishing the policy of cash in hand for the citizens of the country. Under which

Page 33: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

19

an account will be opened for every Ghanaian into which the annual proceed made from oil be

reimbursed as a share of the national revenue. On one side the idea may sound informed. The

principle is to avoid the old age government indigestions and to make way for the people to have

a connection with the oil revenue in their lives as a safeguard to the potential divisive element of

oil resources. The problem is that the position is not supported by economic prudence and the

policy becomes even less desirable if you work in specificities

Moreover, Alaska is part of the federal state (United States) and receives a wider national

budget support. More to that Alaska is a unit of the leading economy in the world. Economic

interplay among the 50 states of America alone is enough to keep Alaska going strong. Ghana on

the other hand, as a single economic unit by itself does not have any of those luxuries. And even

more revealing is the point which other observers have equally pointed out, its remotely less clear

how an approximate amount of 500 dollars a year – as predicted - can adequately incentivize an

angry natives who believe oil exploration on their soil is not providing enough for their well

being to desist from been violent. We therefore observed that what the people of Ghana need is

not a daily “meal allowance” as Moss appears to suggest but to be born and live in an

environment that provides for development and opportunity.

(http://www.danquahinstitute.org/news/1222-oil-receipts-and-national-development.html)

Twumasi (2010:1) commenting on the history of natural resource extraction and

(mis)management in Ghana’s economic past states that the present generation of Ghanaians is

anxious of the crude oil discovered, and holds the perception that, the entire economic challenges

facing the nation would varnish into thin air as Ghana would soon attain the Organisation of

Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC) status.

However, he holds that despite years of extracting natural and human resource, Ghana

still has to source budgetary support from the World Bank, which showcased inefficiency and

corruption on the part of the managers. The query therefore is, how judicious have funds from

these extractive resources been managed, including those still being exploited, which then raises

questions on how prepared the country is to succeed with the black gold. In order to drive home

his point he maintains inter alia:

…gold exploitation at Obuasi began almost at the same time

with Johannesburg in the Republic of South Africa (RSA).

But, undoubtedly the rate of development at Johannesburg is

worthy a tale to tell. However, the story of Obuasi is that of

despise and desperation. The inhabitants of Obuasi are almost

all the time splitting hair, with Anglo gold Ashanti, either

ignoring its social responsibility of exposing the inhabitants to

one health hazard, or the other. This calls on the Ghana Police

Service, which often simply represents the calm before the

storm.

Page 34: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

20

Natural Resources (Oil) and the Phenomena of the Resource Curse

The literature on the resource curse has presented considerable evidence to suggest that

natural resources are bad for development. This section reviews this evidence. It is organised

according to sub-literature for the sake of clarity.

Economic performance: A large number of studies have presented evidence to suggest that

natural resource abundance, or at least an abundance of particular natural resources, reduces

economic growth. Wheeler (1984), for instance, found that within sub-Saharan Africa, countries

that were rich in minerals grew more slowly than those that were not rich in minerals during the

1970s. Similarly, Gelb and Associates (1988) found that mineral economies experienced a more

serious deterioration in the efficiency of domestic capital formation during the boom period of

1971–1983 than non-mineral economies, leading to negative growth in hard mineral economies

and dramatically reduced in oil exporting economies (see also Auty 1993). Sachs and Warner

(1995) examined the experiences of a large and diverse set of natural resource economies

between 1970 and 1989 and found that natural resource abundance was negatively correlated with

economic growth. Leite and Weidmann (1999) and Gylfason et al. (1999) produced similar

results, also using large datasets. Auty (2001a) found that the per capita incomes of resource-poor

countries grew at rates two to three times higher than resource abundant countries between 1960

and 1990. Neumayer (2004) examined whether natural resource abundance had a negative effect

on economic growth if one measured growth in terms of ‘genuine income’ – that is, GDP minus

the depreciation of produced and natural capital – rather than GDP. He found that it did.

Other scholars have presented evidence to suggest that the economic problems of

resource abundant countries have gone beyond poor levels of economic growth. Nankani (1979),

for instance, found that mineral economies performed relatively poorly in terms of agricultural

growth, export diversification, and inflation compared to non-mineral economies and were more

likely to be characterised by poor savings performance, greater technological and wage dualism,

high unemployment, high external indebtedness, and high export earnings instability. Wood and

Berge (1997) found that resource abundant countries were less likely to export manufactured

goods than resource poor countries. Leite and Weidmann (1999) found that natural resource

abundance tends to worsen corruption. Atkinson and Hamilton (2003) found that savings rates are

on average lower in resource abundant countries than in resource poor countries. Finally, Ross

(2003a) found that oil wealth and non-fuel mineral wealth are associated with bad outcomes for

the poor in terms of poverty and human development levels. The figure below illustrates the

economic performance and growth between resource rich countries and resource poor countries.

Page 35: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

21

Fig. 1: Comparison of Economic Performance between Resource Rich and Resource Poor

Countries

Source: Auty, 1997 cited in ODI, 2008:9

Civil war: The literature also contains numerous studies that suggest that natural resource

abundance is associated with the onset of civil war and influences the duration and intensity of

civil war – that is the number of battle-related deaths. After examining the experiences of 98

countries and 27 civil wars, Collier and Hoeffler (1998), for instance, found that natural resource

abundance, defined in terms of the ratio of primary exports to GDP, is a strong and significant

determinant of the onset of civil war, although they also found that the relationship between these

variables was curvilinear: initially, natural resource wealth increased the risk of civil war but after

a certain level of exports, it reduced this risk. In a subsequent study, they confirmed this finding

using a better data set (Collier and Hoeffler 2000). In a third study, they examined the effect of

natural resource abundance on different types of civil wars.

They found that natural resources increased the risk of both secessionist and

nonsecessionist civil wars, but that the former were three times more likely to be associated with

natural resources than the latter (Collier and Hoeffler 2002).

Reynal-Querol (2002) conducted a similar study, focused on examining the association

between natural resources and the onset of ethnic and non-ethnic civil wars. Using data from a

sample of 138 countries between 1960 and 1995, she found that natural resource abundance was

an important variable in explaining the incidence of non ethnic civil wars and other forms of

political violence but not the incidence of ethnic civil wars. In their most recent paper, Collier and

Hoeffler (2005) report on work showing that natural resource wealth continues to exhibit a

curvilinear relationship with the onset of civil war even if a rent-based measure of natural

resource abundance is substituted for their original export-based measure. However, they note

that this result is less significant than their earlier finding and that the rent-based measure of

natural resource abundance becomes insignificant, when the original measure of natural resource

wealth is included in the regression analysis as well.

Page 36: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

22

Some researchers have also suggested that natural resource abundance may lengthen the

duration of civil wars. Collier and Hoeffler (1998), for instance, found that natural resource

abundance and the duration of civil wars also had a curvilinear relationship.

Similarly, Doyle and Sambanis (2000) found that natural resource wealth was

significantly and negatively correlated with the success of peace-building initiatives. As Ross

(2004a: 341) has noted, in so far as there is a link between the failure of such initiatives and the

duration of civil wars, this finding suggests that natural resource wealth is associated with longer

wars. Fearon (2004) found that countries that are rich in contraband resources such as opium,

diamonds, or coca tend to experience longer civil wars and Ballantine (2003) found that natural

resources served to prolong civil wars in a selection of resource rich developing countries.

Finally, as Ross (2004b: 45) has noted, several observers of Africa’s civil wars, have

suggested that natural resources worsen the intensity of civil wars ‘by causing combatants to fight

for territory that would otherwise have little value’. Ross (2004b) himself found only very modest

support for this idea: of the thirteen cases of civil war he examined, natural resources only clearly

increased the intensity of conflict in two cases; in the eleven others, natural resources either had

no effect or a mixed effect on civil war intensity.

Regime type: The resource curse literature also contains a number of studies that suggest that

natural resource abundance is associated with low levels of democracy. Wantchekon (1999), for

instance, examined data related to 141 countries between 1950 and 1990 and found that a one per

cent increase in natural resource dependence, as measured by the ratio of primary exports to

GDP, increased the probability of authoritarian government by nearly 8 per cent. He also found

that countries that were rich in natural resources were more likely to experience failed or slow

transitions to democracy. Jensen and Wantchekon (2004) presented similar findings in relation to

Africa, concluding that resource abundant countries in this region were more likely to be

authoritarian and experience breakdowns in democracy after the democratic transition. Ross

(2001a) investigated whether there was any variation in regime outcomes across different types of

resource economy and different regions. After examining data from 113 states between 1971 and

1997, he concluded that ‘a state’s reliance on oil or mineral exports tends to make it less

democratic; that this effect is not caused by other types of primary exports; that it is not limited to

the Arabian peninsula, to the Middle East, or to sub-Saharan Africa; and that it is not limited to

small states’.

While there is thus considerable evidence to support the notion of a resource curse, there

are several reasons to treat this evidence with caution. First, some scholars have suggested that

the findings of studies such as those cited above may not be robust to differences in the

measurement of natural resource abundance. In general, researchers have measured natural

Page 37: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

23

resource abundance in terms of either the ratio of countries’ natural resource exports to GDP or

the ratio of countries’ natural resource exports to total exports. When they have used different

measures of natural resource abundance, their results have been less clearly supportive of the

notion of a resource curse.

Stijns (2001), for instance found that when natural resource abundance was measured in

terms of levels of production and reserves rather than exports, it did not have a significant

influence on economic growth. Similarly, Herb (2003) found that when natural resource

abundance was measured in terms of the percentage of rents in government revenues rather than

levels of natural resource exports, there is little support for the idea that there is a negative

relationship between natural resource abundance and the occurrence of democracy.

De Soysa (2000) found that when natural resource abundance was measured in terms of

the level of natural resource stock per capita, there was no relationship between the incidence of

civil war and the overall level of natural resource abundance. Auty (2001a: 5) has pointed out that

a number of studies have used non-export based measures of natural resource abundance

including Gylfason et al. (1999) (who used labour force in the primary sector) and Auty (2001a)

(who used crop land per head), suggesting that the findings of these studies may be more robust

than critics of the resource curse hypothesis have suggested. But the question of whether these

findings are robust to broader changes in the measure of natural resource abundance remains

unresolved.

Second, it is not clear that the ratio of natural resource exports to GDP or the ratio of

natural resource exports to total exports are appropriate measures of natural resource wealth. As

we will see below, most studies that attempt to explain the resource curse suggest that the main

problem with natural resource abundance is not that it leads to economic dependence on natural

resources or a skewed export structure per se but that it creates rents – that is, excess earnings

above normal profits. The existence of these rents is in turn variously seen as contributing to

negative development outcomes by encouraging myopia and over-exuberance on the part of

political elites, promoting damaging rent seeking behaviour by political elites and/or social

actors, weakening state capacity to regulate and supervise the economy, empowering social

elements that are opposed to growth-promoting policies, or encouraging foreign intervention. As

such, it could be argued that rent-based measures of natural resource abundance provide a more

useful basis for making judgements about the existence or non-existence of a resource curse. Yet

studies that have used such measures – such as Herb (2003) and Collier and Hoeffler (2005) –

have so far provided only mixed support for the notion of a resource curse.

Third, the finding that there is a strong relationship between natural resource abundance

and the onset and duration of civil war seems to be contingent on the use of a particular civil war

Page 38: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

24

database. As Ross (2004a: 347–8) has pointed out, the studies that have presented this finding

have all used Collier and Hoeffler’s list of civil wars, yet scholars who have used alternative lists

of civil wars have generally come to different conclusions. He suggests several reasons for this

related to the way in which civil wars are coded and civil war duration is measured. In short,

however, he suggests that Collier and Hoeffler’s database ‘may be biased in a way that overstates

the impact of primary commodities’ (2004a: 342).

Fourth, a number of scholars have presented evidence that suggests that the main problem

vis-à-vis development outcomes in resource abundant countries is not natural resource abundance

per se – as many of the aforementioned studies suggest – but an abundance of particular types of

natural resources. At the same time, there is some disagreement, at least in relation to civil war,

about which natural resources are the main problem. Many researchers have pointed to ‘point

source’ natural resources – for instance, oil, minerals, and plantation crops – as being particularly

problematic. Isham et al. (2002), for instance, found that countries that are rich in point source

natural resources grew much more slowly during the 1980s and 1990s than countries that are rich

in ‘diffuse’ natural resources – for instance, wheat and rice – and countries that are rich in cocoa

and coffee. Similarly, Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian (2003) found that an abundance of point

source natural resources was significantly correlated with poor economic growth but that an

abundance of diffuse natural resources was not. Leite and Weidmann (1999) found that fuel and

ores had a more negative effect on growth than agriculture (although a less significant negative

effect than food production). Ross (2003a) found that oil wealth and non-fuel mineral wealth are

associated with bad outcomes for the poor but not agricultural resources. De Soysa (2000) found

that, while the incidence of civil wars was not related to total natural resource wealth, it was

strongly related to the level of mineral wealth, suggesting that point source resources (specifically

mineral resources) rather than natural resources in general are the main problem as far as the

onset of civil war is concerned. In a subsequent study, he found that, among mineral-rich

countries, oil exporters were particularly prone to civil war (De Soysa 2002).

Fearon and Laitin (2003) have presented similar evidence on this point, showing that the

size of countries’ primary commodity exports is not a significant determinant of the onset of civil

wars but that their level of oil wealth is. Fearon (2005) has provided further evidence to this

effect. Finally, Ross’ (2001a) findings on the relationship between oil wealth and democracy are

also consistent with the emphasis on the negative effects of point source resources.

His findings in relation to civil war, however, are not. In Ross (2003b), he presents

evidence to suggest that it is ‘lootable’ resources such as diamonds (particularly alluvial

diamonds) and drugs (particularly opium and coca) rather than point source resources that are the

most likely to produce civil war. After analysing 12 civil wars and three minor conflicts that

Page 39: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

25

occurred between 1990 and 2000, he found that, once income per capita was accounted for, there

was little difference in civil war rates between resource abundant countries in the four main

categories of natural resources – oil and gas, minerals, food crops, and non-food crops. By

contrast, he found that diamonds and drugs were strongly associated with the incidence of civil

war. Humphreys (2005) has also presented evidence to suggest that point source resources are not

the main problem vis-à-vis the onset of civil war, although his findings also challenge Ross’s

findings concerning lootable resources. According to his evidence, the main problem vis-a-vis the

onset of civil war is the extent to which countries are dependent on agricultural production. This

effect, he notes, is independent of a country’s endowment of oil and diamonds, suggesting that

the problem of resource dependence is not simply one of the availability of point source or

lootable resources but also economic structure and how this shapes social relations (2005: 524–

5).

These findings stand in marked contrast to those of Fearon, Fearon and Laitin, and De

Soysa and suggest that the issue of which types of natural resources are most likely to lead to the

onset of civil war has not yet been resolved.

Fifth, there is some evidence, albeit very limited, that natural resource wealth may in fact

have a beneficial, or at least neutral, effect on development performance. Davis (1995), for

instance, has shown that, by certain economic and social measures, mineral economies

outperformed non-mineral economies between 1970 and 1991. These measures include average

GNP per capita and improvement in various social indicators such as infant mortality, life

expectancy, calorie supply per capita, and the UN’s human development index. None of this

evidence is necessarily inconsistent with the findings of the aforementioned studies because it

focuses on social indicators rather than economic indicators such as growth. But it does raise the

question of whether economic growth in particular is the only measure that we should examine in

judging the economic performance of resource abundant countries. In addition, some scholars

have produced evidence to suggest that natural resource abundance may not have a negative

effect on the onset, duration or intensity of civil war. In a study of the effects of oil dependence

on regime failure and conflict in 107 developing countries between 1960 and 1999, Smith (2004),

for instance, found that oil wealth is associated with lower levels of civil war and anti-state

protest.

Similarly, Sørli et al. (2005) found that oil dependence has not exercised a significant

influence on the onset of civil war in the Middle East in recent decades. In respect of the duration

of civil war, Humphreys (2005) has presented evidence to suggest that natural resource conflicts

are more likely to end quickly while Ross (2003b) has presented evidence to suggest that while

lootable resources may serve to prolong non-separatist conflicts, nonlootable resources serve to

Page 40: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

26

reduce non-separatist conflicts (see also Collier et al. 2004). In respect of the intensity of civil

war, Ballantine (2003) has suggested that natural resource abundance has, in some cases, reduced

the number of battle-related deaths during civil war.

Finally, while the studies above provide evidence that natural resource abundance – or at

least an abundance of particular types of natural resources – and various development outcomes

are correlated with one another, they do not prove that the former causes the latter. Those arguing

in favour of the notion of a resource curse have merely inferred causality from the evidence of

correlation. However, the direction of causation may in fact run the other way. That is, it may be

that civil war, for instance, causes economic dependence on the natural resources sector by

making it difficult for countries to attract manufacturing investment. As Schrank (2004) puts it,

natural resource dependence may be a symptom of underdevelopment rather than the cause.

Alternatively, the relationship between natural resource dependence and various development

outcomes may be entirely spurious – that is, their correlation with one another may simply reflect

the influence of an unidentified third variable. Just as ice cream sales and the number of sunburn

cases are highly correlated because of changes in the seasons, rather than because ice cream

consumption causes sunburn or vice versa, so it may be that natural resource abundance and civil

war, for instance, are correlated because a third variable (say, the weak rule of law) both increases

the risk of civil war and the difficulties countries face in attracting manufacturing investment

(Ross 2004a: 338). It will only be by examining more closely the causal mechanisms surrounding

the resource curse that scholars will adequately resolve these issues.

What Causes The Resource Curse?

Notwithstanding the inconclusive nature of the evidence in support of the notion of a

resource curse, many researchers have taken it as read that natural resource wealth leads to bad

development outcomes and have focused on trying to explain why this is the case, either in

general or in respect of particular regions or countries. The perspectives they have offered vary

considerably in terms of the causal mechanisms that they emphasise but can be broadly grouped

into seven categories: (i) economistic perspectives that emphasise economic mechanisms; (ii)

behaviouralist perspectives that emphasise emotional or irrational behaviour on the part of

political actors; (iii) rational actor perspectives that emphasise self-interested behaviour on the

part of political actors; (iv) state-centred perspectives that emphasise the nature of the state; (v)

social capital perspectives that emphasise the degree of social cohesion in countries; (vi)

structuralist perspectives that emphasise the role of social groups or socio-economic structure;

and (vii) radical perspectives that emphasise the role of foreign actors and structures of power at

the global level. Explanations from all of these categories feature in the sub-literature on natural

resources and economic performance, with more limited sets of explanations featuring in the sub-

Page 41: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

27

literatures on natural resources and civil war and natural resources and regime type, reflecting

greater academic engagement with issues in the first sub-literature.

Economic performance/Perspective

Much early work on the economic performance of resource abundant countries suggested

that the causal mechanisms linking natural resource abundance and economic performance were

essentially economic in nature. Singer (1950) and Prebisch (1950), for instance, argued that

resource abundant countries had suffered from declining terms of trade over time, in turn

constraining their prospects for economic growth and development. Other scholars such as

Nurske (1958) and Levin (1960) argued that the problem for resource abundant countries was that

international commodity markets were inherently unstable and that any instability within them

could easily be transferred to domestic economies, in turn affecting the reliability of government

revenues and foreign exchange supplies and dramatically increasing risks for private investors.

Hirschman (1958) suggested that the problem was the ‘enclave’ nature of natural resource

activities and the fact that multinational enterprises in these sectors tended to repatriate profits

rather than reinvest them in the local economy. This, he said, made development difficult by

restricting opportunities for the development of backward and forward linkages between these

activities and the rest of the economy.

Finally, in the early 1980s, several commentators argued that resource abundant countries

were susceptible to the so-called ‘Dutch disease’ – a condition whereby a resource boom leads to

appreciation of the real exchange rate and in turn damages manufacturing and other tradable

sectors (Corden and Neary 1982; Bruno and Sachs 1982).

Most of these explanations are now regarded with some scepticism. Subsequent studies of

trends in international commodity prices have suggested that while in overall terms international

commodity prices have declined during the twentieth century, this has been due largely to

declines in the prices of commodities that are exported exclusively by developed countries or

more or less exclusively by relatively successful developing countries – the prices of

commodities exported primarily by other developing countries have not declined severely during

this period. Similarly, several studies have suggested that export price instability may be

beneficial to exporters in so far as it can encourage higher levels of private investment as

exporters seek to protect themselves against future price shocks.

Other studies have suggested that export price instability does harm exporters but have

not clearly demonstrated that it harms exporters of primary commodities. There has been more

support in subsequent studies for Hirschman’s argument regarding economic linkages and for the

Dutch disease hypothesis. But these studies also suggest that governments can take action to

Page 42: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

28

address these problems, in turn suggesting that these negative effects may operate more through

political than economic mechanisms.

For this reason, most recent work on the relationship between natural resource abundance

and economic performance has given much greater attention to the role of political variables in

mediating this relationship. On the one hand, economists have increasingly incorporated ideas

from political science into their work on the resource curse, particularly, although not

exclusively, ideas from neoclassical political economy and the new institutionalism (Eifert et al.

2003; Rodrik 2003; Isham et al. 2002; Auty 2001c, 2001d; Torvik 2002). On the other hand,

political scientists have entered debates on the resource curse, bringing with them analytical

frameworks such as behaviouralism, public choice theory, Marxism, instititutionalism/statism,

dependency and world systems theories, and fiscal sociology, all of which give central attention

to the role of political factors in shaping economic outcomes. For the most part, both economists

and political scientists have agreed that the immediate cause of poor economic performance in

resource abundant countries has been poor economic management. In particular, they have

pointed to fiscal profligacy, overvalued exchange rates, excessive protection, and inefficient use

of resource windfalls as being the main problems in this respect (Usui 1997; Anderson 1998;

Mitra 1994; Karl 1997; Ascher 1999). However, the broad consensus that poor economic

management has been the immediate cause of poor economic performance has not reflected

consensus about the underlying causes of this poor performance. Generally speaking, five main

sets of perspectives have emerged on this issue:

Behaviouralist perspectives: These perspectives have suggested that natural resource

abundance leads to various types of emotional or irrational behaviour on the part of political

elites, in turn contributing to poor economic policy-making and institutional deterioration. In

particular, it is argued, resource booms induce myopia, sloth, and/or over-exuberance in political

elites. Such arguments featured in the work of great political and economic theorists such as

Machiavelli, Montesquieu, Smith and Mill and in the work of economists such as Wallich (1960),

Levin (1960), Nurske (1958) and Watkins (1963). More recently, they have appeared in the work

of economists such as Mitra (1994) and political scientists such as Krause (1995) (Ross 1999:

309). Mitra (1994: 295) has argued that resource booms produce a ‘tendency to optimism’ in

countries that benefit from such booms, in turn leading to excessive government spending.

Similarly, Krause (1995: 322) has suggested that natural resources lead to ‘wishful

thinking’ among policy-makers in resource-rich countries. Behaviouralist ideas have also featured

in commentary on the resource curse in the popular media (e.g. Useem 2003).

Rational actor perspectives: In contrast to behaviouralist perspectives, these perspectives

portray political actors as rational utility-maximising individuals. Accordingly, they have

Page 43: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

29

suggested that the problem with natural resource abundance is not that it leads to irrational

behaviour on the part of political actors but that it provides them with an opportunity to line their

own pockets by engaging in rentseeking.

Most scholars have suggested that members of the political elite are the main problem in

this respect. Ross (2001b), for instance, argues that when governments receive windfalls from a

resource boom, rational political elites will take the opportunity to either directly seize the rents

created by resource booms or gain control over the right to allocate them – a process he calls

‘rent-seizing’ (Ross 2001b).

In a similar vein, Ascher (1999) has suggested that resource abundant countries have

generally wasted their natural resources because political elites have tended to use them to pursue

various programmatic and political objectives including financing controversial development

programs, providing economic benefits to particular groups, capturing rents for the government

treasury, creating rent-seeking opportunities in order to secure private sector cooperation in

relation to other objectives, gaining control over rent allocation, and evading accountability.

Robinson et al. (2002) have suggested that such rent-seeking behaviour is most likely to lead to

negative economic outcomes when resource booms are perceived to be temporary because

political elites will focus on maximising the rents that they can extract in the short-term. Where

resource booms are perceived to be permanent, they argue, political elites will be less interested

in short term rent-maximisation because permanent booms increase the likelihood that they will

stay in power and hence the gains that they can make by promoting long-term economic

development. Even where booms are perceived to be permanent, however, Robinson et al. (2002)

suggest that economic outcomes are likely to be negative because political elites will still have an

incentive to engage in inefficient redistribution of economic resources in order to influence

elections. Other scholars, however, have suggested that social actors are more to blame for the

increased rent-seeking. Torvik (2002), for instance, has argued that natural resource abundance

increases the rewards that social actors can gain from rent-seeking, and in turn provides them

with greater incentive to engage in such behaviour.

State-centred perspectives: These perspectives suggest that natural resource abundance

leads to poor economic performance not by influencing the behaviour of political elites or social

actors but by influencing the state’s capacity to promote economic development. Numerous

scholars, for instance, have pointed to the problems associated with so-called ‘rentier’ states –

that is, states that receive regular and substantial amounts of ‘unearned’ income in the form of,

for instance, taxes on natural resource exports or royalties on natural resource production

(Mahdavy 1970; First 1974; Skocpol 1982; Beblawi 1987; Luciani 1987; Tanter 1990; Chaudhry

1994; Vandewalle 1998; Gunn 1993). Because these states have large amounts of unearned

Page 44: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

30

income to spend, it is argued, they tend to develop greater capacity in distributive functions such

as social welfare, education, and health and productive functions – state-owned enterprise sectors

are typically quite large in rentier states – than in functions related to the regulation and

supervision of the economy and domestic taxation (Garaibeh 1987; Chaudhry 1994). As Luciani

(1987: 74) has put it, rentier states do ‘not need to formulate anything deserving the appellation of

economic policy: all [they need] is an expenditure policy’. Karl (1997), Moore (2000, 2004),

Auty (2001c, 2001d), and Auty and Gelb (2001) have presented similar analyses to rentier state

theorists using slightly different terminology and concepts. Karl (1997: 16) for instance, has

argued that dependence on oil revenues leads to the emergence of ‘petro-states’, that is, states that

are geared towards the ‘political distribution of rents’ rather than promotion of private

investment, production and economic growth. The emergence of petro-states, she suggests, is

particularly likely where oil’s domination of the economy coincides with the process of state

formation (see also Vandewalle 1998: 33–8). In these cases, the domination of oil gives the state

a distributive character from its inception, which, given the stickiness of institutions, becomes

locked in. Moore (2000, 2004) has suggested that natural resource abundance leads to ‘bad

governance’ in developing countries because states’ financial autonomy means that they have

little accountability to their citizens. Auty (2001c, 2001d) and Auty and Gelb (2001) have argued

that natural resource abundance significantly increases the likelihood that countries will develop

predatory or factional oligarchic states rather than developmental ones for four main reasons: (i)

the relative abundance of land and the existence of natural resource rents in these countries

creates a relatively high tolerance by the poor majority for inequitable asset distribution and

predatory rent extraction, in turn decreasing the chances that the state will promote asset

redistribution; (ii) resource abundant countries are more likely to adopt protective trade policies

rather than developmental export-oriented policies because they are affected by the Dutch

disease; (iii) the large size of the resources sector means that it can support inefficient inward-

looking industrial sectors with transfers from the resources sector; and (iv) resource abundant

countries are more prone to ‘cumulative policy error’ (Auty and Gelb 2001: 128–9).

Historico-structuralist perspectives: These perspectives have suggested that natural

resource abundance has pernicious economic effects not because of its effects on the behaviour of

political elites or the institutional capacity of the state but because of its effect on the relative

power of different social groups or classes. One group of researchers, for instance, has suggested

that natural resource abundance strengthens well-connected business groups, in turn increasing

pressure on governments to pursue economic policies that serve the interests of these groups

rather than the common economic interest or the interests of the poor (Urrutia 1988; Broad 1995).

In a similar vein, several writers have suggested that one of the main reasons that Latin America

Page 45: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

31

has performed less well than East Asia in terms of economic growth and poverty reduction in

recent decades is the effect of the two region’s natural resource endowments on their industrial

policies. In Latin America, it is argued, natural resource abundance led to the social and political

dominance of landed and business elites that had a vested interest in import-substitution

industrialisation (ISI), hence preventing the development of an externally competitive industrial

sector, while in East Asia, resource poverty meant that such elites did not exist, or at least did not

exercise significant political and social power, in turn making it easier for governments to shift

away from ISI towards export-oriented industrialisation and the development of an externally

competitive industrial sector (Mahon 1992; Auty 1995).

Social capital perspectives: These perspectives have suggested that the problem with natural

resource abundance, particularly an abundance of point source resources, is that it undermines

social cohesion and in turn limits the capacity of governments to manage economic shocks.

Ownership of point source resources resources, it is argued, is typically concentrated in the hands

of a few well-connected individuals or families, a situation that creates severe social tensions.

While these tensions may be masked during periods of economic prosperity they come to the

surface at times of economic crisis. The result, it is argued, is that it is difficult to generate a

social consensus around a reformist strategy for coping with the crisis. In this context, powerful

vested interests typically win out and economic reform is stymied (Isham et al. 2002: 18–19; see

also Rodrik 1999 and Hausman 2003).

country a target for forced incorporation into the global capitalist system – a system in which the

interests of poor developing countries are subordinated to those of wealthy developed countries –

in turn impairing their ability to pursue autonomous programs of economic development.

Perelman (2003: 200), for instance has argued: ‘a rich natural resource base makes a poor

country, especially a relatively powerless one, an inviting target – both politically and militarily –

for dominant nations. In the case of oil, the powerful nations will not risk letting such a valuable

resource fall under the control of an independent government, especially one that might pursue

policies that do not coincide with the economic interests of the great transnational corporations’.

The result, dependency theorists suggest, is that governments in resource abundant developing

countries are permitted to engage in corrupt and economically damaging activities so long as they

remain loyal to the dominant nations and allow the natural resource wealth within their borders to

be looted by firms from wealthy countries (see also Bellamy et al. 2004 and Amin 2001).

Page 46: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

32

The Inflow of FDI Enhances Economic Growth and Development

Renewed research interest in FDI stems from the change of perspectives among policy

makers from “hostility” to “conscious encouragement”, especially among developing countries.

FDI had been seen as “parasitic” and retarding the development of domestic industries for export

promotion until recently. However, Bende-Nabende and Ford (1998) submit that the wide

externalities in respect of technology transfer, the development of human capital and the opening

up of the economy to international forces, among other factors, have served to change the former

image.

Caves (1996) observes that the rationale for increased efforts to attract more FDI stems

from the belief that FDI has several positive effects. Among these are productivity gains,

technology transfers, the introduction of new processes, managerial skills and know-how in the

domestic market, employee training, international production networks, and access to markets.

Borensztein et al. (1998) see FDI as an important vehicle for the transfer of technology,

contributing to growth in larger measure than domestic investment. Findlay (1978) postulates that

FDI increases the rate of technical progress in the host country through a “contagion” effect from

the more advanced technology, management practices, etc., used by foreign firms.

On the basis of these assertions governments have often provided special incentives to

foreign firms to set up companies in their countries. Carkovic and Levine (2002) note that the

economic rationale for offering special incentives to attract FDI frequently derives from the belief

that foreign investment produces externalities in the form of technology transfers and spillovers.

Curiously, the empirical evidence of these benefits both at the firm level and at the

national level remains ambiguous. De Gregorio (2003), while contributing to the debate on the

importance of FDI, notes that FDI may allow a country to bring in technologies and knowledge

that are not readily available to domestic investors, and in this way increases productivity growth

throughout the economy. FDI may also bring in expertise that the country does not possess, and

foreign investors may have access to global markets.

In fact, he found that increasing aggregate investment by 1 percentage point of GDP

increased economic growth of Latin American countries by 0.1% to 0.2% a year, but increasing

FDI by the same amount increased growth by approximately 0.6% a year during the period 1950–

1985, thus indicating that FDI is three times more efficient than domestic investment.

A lot of research interest has been shown on the relationship between FDI and economic

growth, although most of such work is not situated in Africa. The focus of the research work on

FDI and economic growth can be broadly classified into two. First, FDI is considered to have

direct impact on trade through which the growth process is assured (Markussen and Vernables,

1998). Second, FDI is assumed to augment domestic capital thereby stimulating the productivity

Page 47: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

33

of domestic investments (Borensztein et al., 1998; Driffield, 2001). These two arguments are in

conformity with endogenous growth theories (Romer, 1990) and cross country models on

industrialization (Chenery et al., 1986) in which both the quantity and quality of factors of

production as well as the transformation of the production processes are ingredients in developing

a competitive advantage. FDI has empirically been found to stimulate economic growth by a

number of researchers (Borensztein et al., 1998; Glass and Saggi, 1999). Dees (1998) submits

that FDI has been important in explaining China’s economic growth, while De Mello (1997)

presents a positive correlation for selected Latin American countries. Inflows of foreign capital

are assumed to boost investment levels.

Blomstrom et al. (1994) report that FDI exerts a positive effect on economic growth, but

that there seems to be a threshold level of income above which FDI has positive effect on

economic growth and below which it does not. The explanation was that only those countries that

have reached a certain income level can absorb new technologies and benefit from technology

diffusion, and thus reap the extra advantages that FDI can offer. Previous works suggest human

capital as one of the reasons for the differential response to FDI at different levels of income.

This is because it takes a well-educated population to understand and spread the benefits of new

innovations to the whole economy. Borensztein et al. (1998) also found that the interaction of

FDI and human capital had important effect on economic growth, and suggest that the differences

in the technological absorptive ability may explain the variation in growth effects of FDI across

countries. They suggest further that countries may need a minimum threshold stock of human

capital in order to experience positive effects of FDI.

Balasubramanyan et al. (1996) report positive interaction between human capital and

FDI. They had earlier found significant results supporting the assumption that FDI is more

important for economic growth in export-promoting than import-substituting countries. This

implies that the impact of FDI varies across countries and that trade policy can affect the role of

FDI in economic growth. In summary, UNCTAD (1999) submits that FDI has either a positive or

negative impact on output depending on the variables that are entered alongside it in the test

equation. These variables include the initial per capita GDP, education attainment, domestic

investment ratio, political instability, terms of trade, black market exchange rate premiums, and

the state of financial development. Examining other variables that could explain the interaction

between FDI and growth, Olofsdotter (1998) submits that the beneficiary effects of FDI are

stronger in those countries with a higher level of institutional capability. He therefore emphasized

the importance of bureaucratic efficiency in enabling FDI effects.

The neoclassical economists argue that FDI influences economic growth by increasing

the amount of capital per person. However, because of diminishing returns to capital, it does not

Page 48: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

34

influence long-run economic growth. Bengos and Sanchez-Robles (2003) assert that even though

FDI is positively correlated with economic growth, host countries require minimum human

capital, economic stability and liberalized markets in order to benefit from long-term FDI

inflows. Interestingly, Bende-Nabende et al. (2002) found that direct long-term impact of FDI on

output is significant and positive for comparatively economically less advanced Philippines and

Thailand, but negative in the more economically advanced Japan and Taiwan. Hence, the level of

economic development may not be the main enabling factor in FDI growth nexus. On the other

hand, the endogenous school of thought opines that FDI also influences long-run variables such

as research and development (R&D) and human capital (Romer, 1986; Lucas, 1988).

FDI could be beneficial in the short term but not in the long term. Durham (2004), for

example, failed to establish a positive relationship between FDI and growth, but instead suggests

that the effects of FDI are contingent on the “absorptive capability” of host countries. Obwona

(2001) notes in his study of the determinants of FDI and their impact on growth in Uganda that

macroeconomic and political stability and policy consistency are important parameters

determining the flow of FDI into Uganda and that FDI affects growth positively but

insignificantly. Ekpo (1995) reports that political regime, real income per capita, rate of inflation,

world interest rate, credit rating and debt service explain the variance of FDI in Nigeria. For non-

oil FDI, however, Nigeria’s credit rating is very important in drawing the needed FDI into the

country.

Furthermore, spillover effects could be observed in the labour markets through learning

and its impact on the productivity of domestic investment (Sjoholm, 1999). Sjoholm suggests that

through technology transfer to their affiliates and technological spillovers to unaffiliated firms in

host economy, transnational corporations (TNCs) can speed up development of new intermediate

product varieties, raise the quality of the product, facilitate international collaboration on R&D,

and introduce new forms of human capital.

FDI also contributes to economic growth via technology transfer. TNCs can transfer

technology either directly (internally) to their foreign owned enterprises (FOE) or indirectly

(externally) to domestically owned and controlled firms in the host country (Blomstrom et al.,

2000; UNCTAD, 2000). Spillovers of advanced technology from foreign owned enterprises to

domestically owned enterprises can take any of four ways: vertical linkages between affiliates

and domestic suppliers and consumers; horizontal linkages between the affiliates and firms in the

same industry in the host country (Lim, 2001; Smarzynska, 2002); labour turnover from affiliates

to domestic firms; and internationalization of R&D (Hanson, 2001; Blomstrom and Kokko,

1998). The pace of technological change in the economy as a whole will depend on the

Page 49: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

35

innovative and social capabilities of the host country, together with the absorptive capacity of

other enterprises in the country (Carkovic and Levine, 2002).

Other than the capital augmenting element, some economists see FDI as having a direct

impact on trade in goods and services (Markussen and Vernables, 1998). Trade theory expects

FDI inflows to result in improved competitiveness of host countries' exports (Blomstrom and

Kokko, 1998).

TNCs can have a negative impact on the direct transfer of technology to the FOEs,

however, and thereby reduce the spillover from FDI in the host country in several ways.

They can provide their affiliate with too few or the wrong kind of technological

capabilities, or even limit access to the technology of the parent company. The transfer of

technology can be prevented if it is not consistent with the TNC’s profit maximizing objective

and if the cost of preventing the transfer is low. Consequently, the production of its affiliates

could be restricted to low-level activities and the scope for technical change and technological

learning within the affiliate reduced. This would be by limiting downstream producers to low

value intermediate products, and in some cases “crowding out” local producers to eliminate

competition. They may also limit exports to competitors and confine production to the needs of

the TNCs. These may ultimately result in a decline in the overall growth rate of the “host country

and worsened balance of payment situation” (Blomstrom and Kokko, 1998).

Among the many theories trying to explain FDI, Dunning (1993) proposes a framework

that synthesizes the explanations and suggests that three conditions are required to motivate a

firm to undertake FDI. This has become known in the FDI literature as the OLI paradigm because

it explains the activities of MNCs in terms of ownership (O), location (L) and internalization

advantages (I). When selling its products abroad, a firm is at least initially disadvantaged relative

to local producers. Thus, in order to compete effectively with indigenous firms, a foreign

producer must possess some ownership advantages. They can take the form of a superior

production technology or improved organizational and marketing systems, capacity to innovate,

trademarks, reputation, or other assets. Ownership advantages assure a firm’s ability to enter the

host country’s market, but do not explain why the foreign presence should be established through

production rather than exports. This issue is, in turn, addressed by location advantages that arise

due to differences in factor quality, costs and endowments, international transport and

communication costs, overcoming trade restrictions, and host government policies. The last

advantage, internalization, explains why a foreign firm prefers to retain full control over the

production process instead of licensing its intangible assets to local firms. This decision may be

attributable to high transaction costs involved in regulating and enforcing licensing contracts.

Page 50: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

36

Gap in the Literature

Having rigorously and systematically x-rayed what scholars have said and what they had

did not adequately addressed in the extant literatures reviewed above; as it concerns Oil and

National Development in Ghana. It therefore become evident to note that most scholars and

commentators on the resource thesis in which it was argued that the abundance of natural

resource in an economy fuels authoritarianism, conflict, corruption, rent-seeking,

underdevelopment and harms the other non-oil tradable sectors of the economy especially

agriculture and manufacturing. However, they fail to account for the reasons why such resource

rich countries like Alaska, Norway, and Botswana have been experiencing continued growth rate

and resource blessing rather than curse. Hence the explanation of the nature of implication oil can

bring to an economy lies elsewhere outside the resources.

Again, FDI as was presented in the literature is appears to promote and engender

economic growth and development of the economy that witnesses its inflow, however, as has

already been mentioned most, if not all of the case studies was not conducted in the Sub-Saharan

African countries rather they were mainly drawn from the experiences of the Latin American and

Asian countries. Besides, none of the study attempted to show if there is a positive relationship

between discovery and production of oil and the rate of Foreign Direct Investment inflow into

any of the economy.

Finally, most of the commentators on the Ghana oil and gas industry concentrates their

effort on the amount of revenues that the sector is likely to generates or rake into the Ghanaian

economy. While other basing their analysis on the experiences of some other oil producing

countries, especially in the Sub-Saharan African simply concludes that oil will be a curse rather

than a blessing to Ghana, starting with authoritarian reversal and hurting of the countries enviable

democratic records. However, they fail to understand and address in concrete terms the specific

ways and strategies through which oil can actually develop the country’s economy. Through the

adroit enactment of oil and gas laws and fiscal policy regimes that will ensure the efficient and

transparent accountability and management of the oil and gas revenues in such a manner that the

revenue generated from the oil has both immediate and long-term benefit to the entire economy.

Moreover, Ghana’s oil discovery and production can well place it among the leading economies

in the world, if it adopts and subscribes to the internationally acclaimed oil governance good

practices and initiatives, as was the case with Norway and Alaska. In so doing, the nations oil

sector will in turn serve as an instrument of national development by attracting foreign direct

investments into the country that will not oil complement the local industries both will bring with

it other benefits. It is therefore the lacuna in knowledge that this study is set to fill.

Page 51: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

37

1.6 THEORETICAL FFRAMEWORK

There exist plethora of theoretical perspectives which scholars utilize in the explanation

of the role and place of oil in a country’s quest for development. However for us to empirically

and analytically succeed in our present task, we shall employ some propositions emanating from

the resource curse theory.

Studies in Political Science and Economics (social sciences writ large) unequivocally

accept the general proposition that abundance of mineral resources is more often a curse than a

blessing, particularly for developing countries. According to Malomo (2008), the idea that

natural resources might be more an economic curse than a blessing began to emerge in the

1980s. In this light, the term ‘resource curse thesis’ was first used by Richard Auty in 1993 to

describe how countries rich in natural resources were unable to use that wealth to boost their

economies and how, counter-intuitively, these countries had lower economic growth than

countries without an abundance of natural resources. Numerous studies by Jeffrey Sachs and

Andrew Warner have shown a link between natural resource abundance and poor economic

growth. Looking at any example from any of the oil-producing countries, one can see the

disconnection between natural resource wealth and economic growth.

Accordingly, Luong and Weinthal (2006) argue that the widely accepted contention that

an abundance of mineral resources and the influx of external rents generated from these resources

during boom periods are to blame for the so-called ‘resource curse’, should be revisited. Instead,

they offer a new research agenda for studying the problem of resource-rich states that shifts the

locus of study away from the ‘paradox of plenty’ to a more appropriate paradox – that the

concentration of wealth impoverishes the state whereas the dispersion of wealth enriches the

state. This agenda, according to them, focuses on three interrelated issues: the structure of

ownership over mineral resources, the importance of strong institutions, and the relative influence

of domestic versus international factors.

This study thus unfolds from the resource curse theory whose proponents argue that

extraction of resources lowers the wealth of a country unless the funds generated are invested in

other forms (Stiglitz, 2005: 13-19; Karl, 2005:21-26). It refers to countries that are

overwhelmingly dependent on oil revenues, which is generally measured by the extent to which

oil revenues dominate total exports or by the ratio of oil export to GDP.

The resource curse theory has different perspectives. According to Rosser (2006), the

Behaviouralist perspective asserts that natural resource abundance can lead to emotional or

irrational behaviour on the part of political elites, which fosters poor resource management. The

Rational-Actor perspective points to the problems caused by rent-seeking political actors in

contexts of resource wealth. The state-centered theorists propose that states, which rely on

Page 52: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

38

unearned income, avoid developing sound economic policies or public accountability by relying

on rent-distribution politics. The historico-structuralist perspective argues that natural resources

can empower elites, which then influence government policies in their favour against other social

groups. Finally, the social capital perspective professes that natural resources create social

tensions between those who have access to the resources and those who do not, which prevents

societal cooperation and enables powerful vested interests to dominate. These different

perspectives of the theory show more or less that developing petro-states tend to over-reach

themselves in terms of what they expect from the oil resources at their disposal, while not making

efforts to utilize these resources to the optimal benefits of the people in terms of good

governance.

Application of the Resource Curse Theory

The resource curse theory links corruption to the gross story of the underdevelopment of

the oil producing states, especially with regards to mismanagement and misappropriation of her

natural resources, which is mis-governance.

We have noted earlier that the term ‘resource curse’ was first coined by Auty (1993) to

explain why resource-rich countries fail in the abundance of plenty as opposed to resource poor

countries. The study has however gain popularity among scholars. Though popular, the concept is

not a proven phenomenon (Wright et al, 2004 and Alexeev et al, 2008) and remains contestable

within the academic literature. The theoretical debate however is divided into two namely

economic interpretation and politico-institutional analysis.

This thesis surveys the theoretical strands within the resource curse and narrows the

debate to politico-institutional analysis. Under this framework, the institutionalist school that

suggests that quality institutions interaction with resources produces a blessing rather than curse

will occupy this research (Tornell and Lane 1999; Mehlum et al, 2006 and Karl, 1997). It

however highlights opposing schools of thoughts that neutralizes the role of institutions in

resource curse (Sachs and Warner, 2000 and Murshed, 2003) and those that views quality

institutions as negatively affected by resources (Collier and Hoeffler, 2004 and Ross 2001).

We argued that the economic ontological interpretation of the resource curse is limited in

its explanatory force. It pays little attention to politico-institutional analysis which is central to

explaining the resource curse. The resource addresses this slippage through the prospect of

Ghana’s oil find.

Furthermore, the generalization of the models results is problematic and misleading. This

is evident in the time bound and methodological limitation of the research. Yet, apostles of the

resource curse advocate a universal identity with strong empirical evidence to support the

assertion that a causal relationship exist between natural resources and underdevelopment. On the

Page 53: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

39

contrary, there is compelling empirical evidence of natural resources leading to industrialization

and economic boom. This is succinctly captured by Maloney (2002) who argues “…there is little

long term evidence that natural resources abundant countries generally underperform… [Rather]

natural resources have played an integral role in the success of many successful industrialised

countries” [Alaska and Norway for instance](Maloney, 2002:1). This thesis argues for context

specific approach which tackles issues on case-by-case basis.

This brings into perspective the suggestion for a change of name from ‘resource curse’ to

‘resource impact’. The ‘impact’ is the outcome that determines whether resources has become a

‘blessing or a curse’ (Stevens, 2003). This is all-encompassing and will harmonise the various

theoretical strand within the literature. It can be concluded that the problem is not with natural

resource per se but the arrangement that surrounds its extraction and how it is used.

With the above exposition, we therefore accept the theory as a good explanatory

framework for analysis in this research as it explains the developmental prospects that natural

resources such as oil holds in addition to inexplicable accountability and transparency issues in

the management of the oil windfall revenue that will be accruing to the government over the

years, and in spite of various seeming corrupt practices roadblock that may appear inherent in the

oil sector. It becomes more pertinent given the enormous revenues that have accrued to the

Ghanaian State over the past decades through its mining sector and for which the leadership of

the country has been managing and using over the years in sterling the affairs of the state, which

today is regarded as one of the best performing and promising country in Africa. In addition to its

stable political atmosphere and the absence of resource based wars and conflicts, which attests to

the effective and efficient management of the nations natural resources as an instrument of

effectuating national development. The theory explains the two problematiques we have in this

study which are that Ghana will avoid the debilitating effects of the resource curse conundrum, if

it adopts the oil governance best practices on revenue transparency and accountability in the

management of its oil revenue as well as the development of strong oil revenue management law;

moreover, when the country manages its revenue well, such that it gains the trust and confidence

international finance and investors that will draw and attract the much needed Foreign Direct

Investment into the country, history has shown that, foreign direct investment has developmental

drive and macro-economic benefits towards the development of the FDI recipient country

through forward and backward linkages into the other sectors of the economy. It therefore, the

institutional underpinning of the polices making processes and its implementation in the

management and use of oil revenues that determines its net effects an economy; and not just on

the natural resource itself. As history and experience has shown countries that have shown

commitment to accountability and transparency in the management of its public and natural

Page 54: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

40

resources has always ended up turning its natural resources into blessing than curse. These we

believe will the lot of Ghana.

1.7 HYPOTHESES

The hypotheses which this works sets to explore are as follows:

1 Ghana can avoid the resource curse conundrum through the formulation of strong oil

sector policies and the adoption of oil governance best practices.

2 There is a positive relationship between Oil production and the rate of Foreign Direct

Investment (FDI) inflow into Ghana.

1.8 METHOD OF DATA COLLECTION

The method of data collection adopted in this study is based on content analysis of

documentary and other secondary data sources. The documentary sources include institutional

and official documents from international organizations such as the UNDP, IMF, ISODEC and

World Bank etc on the Ghanaian economy, information on the use of oil revenue, management of

offshore oil exploration and exploitation, the contribution of oil sector economic development

and on the international best practices in the oil industry. Also official documents, statistics and

tables were sourced from the Internet, as well as the libraries of the University of Nigeria, Nsukka

(UNN) and the Centre for American Studies (CAST).

Apart from institutional and official documents, this inquiry was based on such secondary

data sources as textbooks, journals and magazines, articles and other written works dealing with

Ghana’s national development and it’s oil and gas sector. When we speak of secondary data

sources, what we make reference to, is any information originally collected for a purpose other

than the present one (Black and Champion). The advantage of secondary data is that it saves time

and money through purposive and random selection of recorded materials in order to investigate

the problem and test hypotheses. There is also the possibility of using the work of others to

broaden the base from which scientific generalizations can be made.

The use of documents and other secondary data sources was complemented by the

technique of non-participant observation of the researcher who has been an active observer of the

trends in Ghana’s development of its oil and gas sector since its discovery of oil in commercial

quantity in June 2007.

1.9 METHOD OF DATA ANALYSIS

For the purpose of analyzing our secondary data, we adopted the qualitative

descriptive method of data analysis. According to Asika (1991), qualitative descriptive

analysis is used to verbally summarize the information gathered in the research.

Page 55: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

41

Through, qualitative descriptive analysis, descriptive explanation is given to statistical

data gathered on our research work, in order to establish the relationship between the

variables under study. Thus, the use of this method of analysis is informed by the simplicity

with which it summarizes, exposes and interprets relationship implicit in a given data by

giving a qualitative description or explanation to a statistical information.

Research Design

A research design is simply a plan that specifies how a data should be collected and

analyzed. Data in this sense is information gathered by investigations with the aid of their

instruments, techniques and other means and they have meaning only in relation to the particular

problems being investigated (Obasi, 1999). For our research purpose, the One-Group Pretest-

Post-test design will be used in carrying out our study. This design involves taking a careful

measurement of a phenomenon before a causal event occurs and then after the causal event

occurs (Legge and Francis, 1974). The difference in scores from t1 to t2 is attributed to the causal

event.

The One-Group Pretest-Post-test design is one of the most commonly used research

design in political science literature and often explained as the O1 X O2 research design. X refers

to the experimental treatment (independent variable) while O1, 2…… refers to the time order of

observations, the subscript indicating the order. Through the One—Group Pretest-Post- test

design, our X variable(Food Security in Nigeria) is carefully examined before and after the causal

event (dependence on oil) in order to establish a link between the change in our experimental

variable and the causal event. O1 in the research work shows the nature and character of the

Ghanaian economy before the Jubilee field oil discovery and its consequent production and

export (sale) while O2 (post-jubilee oil field discovery , 2007 to date) provides a valid scenario of

the chances and preparedness of Ghana towards avoiding the oil resource curse conundrum ,

since it joins the league of oil producing states in 2010.

Also, using the One-Group Pretest-Post-test design, the pattern of Foreign Direct

Investment (FDI) inflow into Ghana, is examined both before and after oil was discovered in the

country, as a veritable grounds for establishing causal relationship between oil discovery, its

production and increase in the volume of Foreign Direct Investment inflow into Ghana.

The systematic use and application of the One-Group Pretest-Post-test research design in

our study no doubt provides a formidable mechanism tool for validating our hypothesis that

Ghana will avoid the resource curse conundrum through the formulation of strong oil sector

polices and the adoption of oil governance best practices; as well as that there exist a positive

relationship between oil production and the rate of Foreign Direct Investment inflow into Ghana.

Page 56: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

42

Logical Data Framework

Hypotheses Variables Main indicators Data source Method of

Data

Collection

Method of

Data Analysis

(Hypothesis 1)

Ghana can

avoid the

resource curse

conundrum

through the

formulation of

strong oil

sector policies

and the

adoption of oil

governance

best practices

(X)

Ghana can

avoid the

resource

curse

conundrum

Signatory to

the EITI

Adoption of oil

governance

best practices

Formulation of

Petroleum

revenue

management

law.

Establishment

of Ghana

petroleum

regulatory

authority.

Textbooks

Journals

Newspapers

Articles and

conference

papers

Internet sources

Official

documents

Qualitative

method of

data

collection,

through

reliance on

documentar

y sources

like

textbooks,

journals,

articles,

newspapers

et cetera.

One-Group

Pretest-Post-test

design and the

theory of the

resource curse;

qualitative

descriptive

analysis

(y)

The

formulation

of strong oil

sector

policies and

the adoption

of oil

governance

best practices

Disclosure of

Petroleum

Sector

Contracts and

agreement.

Disclosure of

revenues and

rents received

from oil

companies.

Oil revenue

accountability

Establishment

of oil fund.

Textbooks

Journals

Newspapers

Articles and

conference

papers

Internet sources

Official

documents

Qualitative

method of

data

collection,

through

reliance on

documentar

y sources

like

textbooks,

journals,

articles,

newspapers

et cetera.

One-Group

Pretest-Post-test

design and the

theory of the

resource curse;

qualitative

descriptive

analysis

(Hypothesis 2)

There is a

positive

relationship

between oil

discovery and

production in

Ghana and the

rate of FDI

inflow into the

Country

(X)

There is a

positive

relationship

between oil

discovery

and

production

Oil and gas

sector in Ghana

account for the

recent increase

in the volume

of FDI in the

economy

Increase in the

number of oil

MNCs

applications for

hydrocarbon

exploration and

production in

Ghana

Oil alone

attracted in FDI

Textbooks

Journals

Newspapers

Articles and

conference

papers

Internet sources

Official

documents

Qualitative

method of

data

collection,

through

reliance on

documentar

y sources

like

textbooks,

journals,

articles,

newspapers

et cetera.

One-Group

Pretest-Post-test

design and the

theory of

resource curse;

qualitative

descriptive

analysis

Page 57: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

43

approximately

$2.5 billion in

early 2011

(Y)

Increase in

the rate of

FDI inflow

into the

Country

Over 100%

increase in the

stock FDI in

Ghana in the

first quarter of

2011

About 70%

annual FDI

increase

between 2009

and 2010.

Textbooks

Journals

Newspapers

Articles and

conference

papers

Internet sources

Official

documents

Qualitative

method of

data

collection,

through

reliance on

documentar

y sources

like

textbooks,

journals,

articles,

newspapers

et cetera.

One-Group

Pretest-Post-test

design and the

theory of the

resource curse;

qualitative

descriptive

analysis

Page 58: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

44

CHAPTER TWO

HISTORICAL DEVELOPMENT OF OIL EXPLORATION IN GHANA

This chapter will among others, examine the history of oil exploration and production

activities in Ghana. We shall however, begin by appraising the fact that right from the time of its

independence in 1957 it has been part of every Ghanaian government's policy to explore Ghana's

hydrocarbon deposits. Between 1898 to the late nineties an estimated hundred exploration wells

had been drilled in Ghana with no significant discovery except for the Saltpond oil find in 1970

(Ghana Oil Watchdog, 2009). The chapter will equally evaluate the location, size, and quantity of

the hydrocarbon that are contained in the Jubilee oil field as well as its implication for national

development in Ghana, in terms of how much revenue that it is expected to contribute into the

coffers of the Ghanaian Government. Finally, effort will also be made to study and understand the

major structure and agency that controls, regulates and represents the interest of the government

of Ghana in the petroleum sector (Oil and Gas). However, before venturing into the analysis of

oil exploration in Ghana, it is pertinent and germane that we first and foremost introduce our

country of study, which is Ghana.

2.1 BRIEF HISTORY OF GHANA

Ghana is a country located in West Africa. The country spans an area of 238,500 km2

(92,085 sq mi). It is bordered by Côte d'Ivoire (Ivory Coast) to the west, Burkina Faso to the

north, Togo to the east, and the Gulf of Guinea (Atlantic Ocean) to the south. The word Ghana

means "Warrior King" (Jackson, 2001:201) and is derived from the ancient Ghana Empire.

Ghana lies between latitudes 4° and 12°N, and longitudes 4°W and 2°E. The Prime

Meridian passes through the country, specifically through the industrial city of Tema. Ghana is

geographically closer to the "centre" of the world than any other country even though the notional

centre, (0°, 0°) is located in the Atlantic Ocean approximately 614 km (382 mi) south of Accra,

Ghana, in the Gulf of Guinea (http://wikipedia.org.htm).

The country encompasses flat plains, low hills and a few rivers. Ghana can be divided

into five different geographical regions. The coastline is mostly a low, sandy shore backed by

plains and scrub and intersected by several rivers and streams while the northern part of the

country features high plains. Southwest and south central Ghana is made up of a forested plateau

region consisting of the Ashanti uplands and the Kwahu Plateau; the hilly Akuapim-Togo ranges

are found along the country's eastern border.

The country Ghana has a population of about 24 million people. It is home to more than

100 different ethnic groups. Ghana as an independent country has not seen the kind of ethnic

Page 59: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

45

conflict that has created internecine civil wars in many other African countries. The official

language is English; however, most Ghanaians also speak at least one local language.

The ethnic groups in Ghana are the Akan (which includes the Fante, Akyem, Ashanti,

Kwahu, Akuapem, Nzema, Bono, Akwamu, Ahanta and others) that made up 49.3% of the

countries population, Mole-Dagbon 15.2%, Ewe 11.7%, Ga-Dangme (comprising the Ga,

Adangbe, Ada, Krobo and others) 7.3%, Guan 4%, Gurma 3.6%, Gurunsi 2.6%, Mande-Busanga

1%, other tribes 1.4%, other (Hausa, Zabarema, Fulani) 1.8% (2000 census). According to the

CIA World Factbook, Ghana’s religious divisions indicates that while about 68.8% of the entire

population are Christians; 15.9% are Muslim adherents and 8.5% are of Traditional African

belief.

Ghana achieved independence from the United Kingdom in 1957, becoming the first sub-

Saharan African nation to do so, (see, Stearns and Langer, 2001: 813,

http://encarta.msn.com/encyclopedia_761570799/Ghana.html and

http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/africa/country_profiles/1023355.stm). The name Ghana was chosen for

the new nation to reflect the ancient Empire of Ghana, which once extended throughout much of

West Africa. Ghana is a member of the United Nations Organisation, South Atlantic Peace and

Cooperation Zone, the Commonwealth of Nations, the Economic Community of West African

States, the African Union, and an associate member of La Francophonie. Ghana is the second

largest producer of cocoa in the world and is home to Lake Volta, the largest artificial lake in the

world by surface area (Geography.about.com.

http://geography.about.com/library/cia/blcghana.htm) and is signatory to host of international

charters, treaties and protocols.

2.2 CONCISE HISTORY OF OIL AND GAS EXPLORATION IN GHANA

Ghana has a fairly checkered history of petroleum exploration dating back over 100 years.

In 1896, the West Africa Oil and Fuel Company (WAOFCO) became on record, the first oil

company to pioneer oil exploration in the then Gold Coast (now modern day Ghana). Though

there is scarcely much corroborative primary data available on this company, it is however

contended that, WAOFCO's arrival was most remarkable as inadequate if any trusted data had

accumulated on the prospects of uncovering commercially viable hydrocarbon reserves in the

Tano fields.

Nonetheless, WAOFCO's chief ambition at the time was directed at the rich onshore Tano

fields in Ghana's Western Region. Between 1896 and 1903, WAOFCO drilled a total of five (5)

wells. Only one of these, the (WAOFCO-2) well, resulted in the very first documented oil

discovery. Between 1909 and 1913, Societe Francaise de Petrole (SFP) a French oil company

also followed WAOFCO's pioneering lead into the Gold Coast prospecting for oil. SFP on its

Page 60: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

46

own drilled a total of six (6) wells. Its first well, the SFP-1 struck oil at a depth of 10-17 meters

and produced 7 barrels of oil per day (bopd). Four (4) out of its remaining five (5) wells also had

promising oil indications. Between 1923 and 1925 the African and Eastern Trade Corporation

(AETC), a subsidiary of United African Company (UAC) join in the early oil exploration and

drilling rush in the onshore Tano area and it encountered oil and gas. Subsequently, Gulf Oil

Company also acquired the Onshore Tano license and drilled four (4) more deep wells in the area

between the periods 1956 to 1957.

Consequent upon this, the news of promising oil discoveries made Ghana an attractive

site to foreign interests. For instance diverse groups of Soviet and Romanian geo-scientists in the

early to mid 1960's (1960 - 1967) joined in the rush for petroleum resources in the Volta and

Accra/Keta Basins. Their exploratory activities and its resulting geophysical data however led to

a very important operational shift; a shift from onshore to offshore shallow waters exploration.

Even though the period following 1967 saw the exit of the Soviets and Romanians, new

and ambitious expatriate companies came onboard, who carried out further offshore drilling

activities. It was during this period that the discoveries of hydrocarbons were made for the very

first time in the Saltpond Basin, in Ghana.

In 1971, under the Busia government, R.R. Amponsah, with a sample of oil collected

from one such successful exploratory well headed to Parliament and made public exhibition of

locally discovered oil. The first offshore commercial hydrocarbon production in the Saltpond

Basin however started in 1975 under the regime of General Kutu Acheampong from a plant

operated by Agripetco. Up to the late 1970's management of the petroleum sector was under

Petroleum Department of the Ministry of Fuel and Power.

Ghana's first petroleum law, Ghana National Petroleum Corporation (GNPC) Law, 1983,

(PNDCL 64) was passed in 1983. Under section 26 of that Law, suitable staffs of the Petroleum

Department were transferred to form the core of the GNPC. From 1984, exploration activities

took a new turn with the enactment of PNDCL 64 which provided new statutory and legal

framework that would accelerate exploration and production (E&P) efforts.

Between 1983 and 1989, GNPC concluded several agreements with a number of foreign

firms. One of the most notable of these agreements permitted US-based oil company Amoco, to

prospect in ten offshore blocks between Ada and the western border with Togo. In 1989 three

companies, two American and one Dutch, spent US$30 million drilling wells in the Tano basin.

On June 21, 1992, an offshore Tano basin well produced about 6,900 barrels of oil daily.

It has been argued that for a time, especially during the early 1990s, there were domestic

attempts at appraising earlier oil and gas discoveries to determine whether a predominantly local

operation might make exploitation more commercially viable. GNPC at then wanted to set up a

Page 61: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

47

floating system for production, storage, off-loading, processing, and gas-turbine electricity

generation, hoping to produce 22 billion cubic feet per day, from which 135 megawatts of power

could be generated and fed into the national and regional grid. GNPC also won a contract in 1992

with Angola's state oil company, Sonangol, which provided for drilling and, production at two of

Sonangol's offshore oilfields. GNPC in return was to be paid with a share of the oil.

In 1989, the country's first and only refinery at Tema underwent its first major

rehabilitation. The second phase of rehabilitation work also commenced in April 1990 at an

estimated cost of US$36 million and it was expected that as soon as its rehabilitation is

completed, distribution of liquefied petroleum gas will be improved, and the quantity supplied

will rise from 28,000 to 34,000 barrels a day. Construction on the new Tema/Akosombo oil

products pipeline, designed to improve the distribution system was further, made in January

1992. The pipeline is to carry refined products from Tema to Akosombo Port, where they will be

transported across Lake Volta to the northern regions of Ghana. Distribution continues to be

uneven, however. Other measures to improve the situation include a US$28 million project to set

up a national network of storage depots in all regions.

In 1992, the Tema Lube Oil Company commissioned a new oil blending plant, designed

to produce 25,000 tons of oil per year. The plant it were estimated and expected will satisfy all of

Ghana's requirements for motor and gear lubricants and 60 percent of the country's need for

industrial lubricants, or, in all, 90 percent of Ghana's demand for lubricant products. The

shareholders of this company include Mobil, Shell, and British Petroleum (together accounting

for 48 percent of equity), Ghana National Petroleum Corporation, and the Social Security and

National Insurance Trust.

Moreover, in order to accelerate deepwater oil exploration, the GNPC funded the

acquisition, processing and interpretation of the first 3-D seismic data over the South Tano Field

and other areas between 1989 and 1991. The GNPC subsequently drilled several wells that

established the viability of three fields in the Tano area namely:

1. The North Tano (Gas) Field with estimated reserves of over 73 billion cubic feet of

gas;

2. The Tano South (Oil and Gas) Field with estimated reserves of over 14 million barrels

of oil and about 120 billion cubic feet of gas;

3. The West Tano (Oil) Field bearing heavy crude oil estimated at over 4.0 million

barrels. GNPC produced over 62,000 barrels of oil in the South Tano fields in 1992.

This production of oil was refined at TOR.

In addition to the above, the GNPC attracted several companies to conduct exploration

activities in the offshore basin of the country, which among other include:

Page 62: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

48

a. Dana Petroleum;

b. Nuevo Energy;

c. AGIP;

d. Diamond Shamrock;

e. Devon Energy;

f. Santa Fe Energy; and

g. Fusion Oil.

The activities of these multi-national oil companies resulted in the accumulation of a

large volume of valuable data that was to become useful in future operations in the country’s

prospect and search for oil.

MAP 1: Ghana’s Hydrocarbon Exploration

Source: African Energy

As corollary to the above, on June 18, 2007 Kosmos Energy, a relatively small Dallas-

based exploratory company in a press release announced that its exploration well offshore the

Republic of Ghana in the rich West Cape Three Points Block has discovered significant oil

accumulation based on the results of drilling and wire-line logs, and a sample of the reservoir

fluid; which is today known and designated the Jubilee Oil Field. The jubilee field find is

reputed to be one of the largest discovery in Africa and contains significant oil and gas reserve.

Page 63: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

49

The oil and gas reserve are estimated between 600milion and 1.2 million and 80 billion

respectively (Oxfam, 2007:25).

The discovery of the jubilee field has opened the floodgate for further positive findings in

Ghana such as the Mahogany 3 and Hyedua 2 wells located within the deepwater Tano Block

(See map 2, for detailed outlay of the block). Leading oil companies include Kosmos Energy and

Tullow oil companies, while others include Anadorko Petroleum corporation, E.O. Group,

GNPC, Ker Corporation (Norway) Sabre oil and Gas Ltd (Source: African Energy, Upstream.

Available at http://www.gnpcgahana.com/home/), with an upsurge rush in application for

exploratory licensing (African Energy, No 147, October 4, 2008:3).

The offshore discovery however is presumed to be capitally intensive and expensive. The

IMF predicts that it will cost $2.7 billion to start-up the Jubilee (Oxfam, 2008:26). This presents a

challenge to the survival of the oil companies in Ghana.

MAP 2: Detailed Map of the Jubilee Oil field off the coast of western Ghana

Source: Tullow Oil cited in ISODEC, (2008: 19),

2.3 DEVELOPING THE JUBILEE FIELD

Developing an offshore field such as Jubilee take years, the involvement of several

companies and many contractors, and several billions of dollars in financing. Scarce and

expensive drilling rigs will be moved into place, costing $600,000 to $1 million or more per

Page 64: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

50

day—and a floating production, storage, and offloading (FPSO) vessel will be manufactured and

put into place to gather, store, and load oil onto tankers for the export market.

The four main companies involved in the field are Kosmos, Tullow, Anadarko, and the

GNPC , negotiated a unitization agreement during mid- to late 2008 and worked together to

present a field development plan to the Ghanaian government for approval. Originally scheduled

for presentation in September 2008 for sanctioning by the government. Potential conflicts of

interest exist in that the government, through GNPC, is in the position of both participating in the

development of and evaluating the field development plan. A formal review by the Ministry of

Energy was conducted in December 2008 with outside assistance from experts from Norway and

Britain but the Ministry of Energy will rely on GNPC, where the government’s petroleum

expertise is concentrated. Barring any objection, the consortium may assume approval. According

to the 2004 petroleum agreement with Kosmos for the West Cape Three Points block, 30 days

after submission of a development plan by the companies to the minister of energy, the

“development plan shall be deemed approved as submitted, unless the minister has before the end

of the period” given notice to the companies that the plan has not been approved or that revisions

are proposed (ISODEC, 2008).

Page 65: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

51

Table 1: Offshore Oil Blocks in Ghana

Source: ISODEC (2008:22).

Disclosures by GNPC have stated that royalty, carried interest, and petroleum income tax

terms are identical, with differences in the additional oil entitlement and additional interest

While there are some rivalries the CEO of Kosmos said that “Tullow followed us here.

When we came in 2003, we had the pick of any block. … Tullow doesn’t have the technical

expertise to carry out a deepwater development program of this size” there is strong interest from

all parties to settle disputes and move forward quickly to develop the field (“Kosmos seeks more

credit for Jubilee,” African Energy, Oct. 17, 2008).

Page 66: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

52

The field development plan has not been made public, but some details have been

reported. An Interdisciplinary Production Team including the four companies had regular

meetings in Dallas during 2008 to develop the plan. Tullow has been named the “unit operator”

of the field, with Kosmos the “technical operator of the integrated project team,” while Anadarko

contributes its deepwater drilling experience. Tullow is responsible for the FPSO, shore base

operations, and community and government relations (News in Brief, Petroleum Economist,

October 2008).

Field development plans, based on data about the field and engineering studies, may

include the following:

i. Details on how the development and production of the field will be financed Details on

the drilling and completion of wells and the production, storage, transportation, and

delivery facilities for petroleum, including a timetable

ii. Method for disposal/use of associated gas

iii. Onshore installations required

iv. Production profiles for oil and gas from the field

v. Economic feasibility studies of alternative methods of developing the field

vi. Measures to be taken to protect the environment

vii. Proposals or requirements for procurement of staff, goods, and services from the national

market

The field development plan can have important impacts on technical, financial,

environmental and other aspects regarding how the field, and Ghana’s petroleum industry,

develops. Early decisions that are taken as part of the plan can narrow options for companies and

the government down the road. There have been difficult negotiations regarding gas utilization

and environmental management.

The consortium pursued a fast-track field development plan, in which the filed started

producing for just over three years from the date of discovery. (In many other countries, fields

may take five to seven years to bring into production.). Former Triton executives, now with

Kosmos, brought the Ceiba field in Equatorial Guinea into production in 17 months. (An action

plan published by Kosmos Energy in December 2008 sets a target of November 1, 2010, as the

date of first oil production.)

According to a report published in Upstream magazine, “Brian Maxted, chief operating

officer for Kosmos, says a strategic decision was made to pursue a parallel, fast-track appraisal

and development strategy due to a combination of factors, including the size of the discovery, the

project’s importance to the partners, and ‘strong encouragement from Ghana’s government.’ ”

Some concerns have been privately expressed that the government, eager for cash, was pushing

Page 67: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

53

the consortium to do a “quick and dirty” plan that would cut corners to exploit the field as quickly

as possible.

Without a careful plan in place, the field could be damaged and oil recovery rates would

diminish. Says Kosmos CEO Musselman, “We’re working in 4,000 feet of water, and the design,

pre-planning, and engineering have to be done absolutely right.” Most West African oil fields

experience peak production early with a relatively quick decline. If an oil company—or

government—has financial incentives to pump oil quickly, that could reduce field life. (Industry

experts estimate that globally, on average, 30 percent of oil in place is recovered. Norway’s

recovery rate is around 40 percent.)

The development plan has the Jubilee field being developed in phases. The first phase

will have 17 wells drilled—nine production wells, three wells to reinject associated gas, and five

wells to reinject water to maintain pressure on the field. Four drilling rigs will arrive in Ghana by

the first quarter of 2009. Tullow has signed a contract with MODEC, a Japanese company, for an

FPSO for the first phase of the project. The FPSO, with a capacity of 2 million barrels, can

process 120,000 bpd of oil, 160 million cubic feet of gas per day, and 100,000 bpd of water and

will be installed in 3,609 feet of water. The FPSO is the Ohdoh, a second-hand single hulled

tanker that will be converted into the FPSO. Shuttle tankers will off-load from the FPSO every 10

days. A subsea gathering system will be built by French contractor Technip, and Norway’s Aker

Solutions will provide umbilicals. Approximately $300 million will be spent in the first phase on

support infrastructure, including support facilities and pipe yard at Takoradi. (These plans have

created a “gold rush” mentality in the town and have locals complaining about rising prices.)

The Jubilee field will average 60,000 bpd in the first year (starting in the second half of

2010 or early 2011), ramping up to a peak of 120,000 bpd during the first phase. Later phases will

be developed as partners discover more reserves through appraisal drilling. The second phase—

starting perhaps in 2013—could include a second FPSO to possibly increase production to

240,000 bpd, with 2.6 billion cubic meters of gas per year.

2.4 PROJECTED GHANA’S OIL REVENUES

The estimations of Ghana’s future revenues inevitably depend on a number of variables:

the size and production rate of the Jubilee field and other potential finds, assumptions regarding

exports of oil versus import substitution, the highly volatile world oil price, production costs and

the internal rate of return of the oil consortium, the outcomes of negotiations for future oil blocks,

and other factors (ISODEC, 2008).

IMF predicted that government revenues from oil and gas could reach a cumulative

US$20 billion over the production period of 2012–30 for the Jubilee field alone, or about 4–5

percent of GDP per year. This would equal 160 percent of 2008 GDP estimates (IMF, 2008). In

Page 68: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

54

an internal document reported by the Financial Times, the IMF says that the government’s take

could be $1.3 billion in 2013, more than cocoa and gold earnings combined (Financial Times,

2008).

GNPC in its estimates issued in July 2008, using a 100,000-bpd production rate and a

$60-per-barrel oil price, forecasted $836 million per year. At a 200,000-bpd production rate,

“which could be achieved five years after commencement of production,” the total annual

revenue to the state would be over $1.6 billion per year.

Moreover, the German technical cooperation organization, GTZ estimates issued in early

2008 put it thus:

… in the most conservative scenario with 40,000 barrels

produced at an oil price of US$50, annual government

revenues from taxes, royalties, and the participating interest

of the (GNPC) would amount to at least US$200 million per

annum. At a daily production of 150,000 bpd, Ghana would

become an oil exporter. Again, assuming an oil price of

US$50 per barrel, ... annual government receipts from the

sector would total more than US$1 billion. In the latter

scenario, our estimates suggest that annual government

revenues will be composed roughly as follows: royalties,

US$135 million; interest (carried and additional), US$300

million, and petroleum income tax, US$630 million. For

comparison ... government receipts from the mining

sector—royalties, taxes, and dividends—totaled US$27

million in 2004.

The following simplified assumptions can be made to estimate the revenue that will

accrue to Ghana based on current discoveries.

Production began in December, 2010 with the number of barrels produced per day

estimated to be around 120,000. The 2010 production level is around 48% of the targeted

total of 250,000 barrels/day.

The number of working days in the year is 365.

The projection of the proportion of revenues that will come to the Government of Ghana

is 40%. This is based on the GNPC projection that the government is to get 40%-50% of

the total oil revenue based on the agreements signed with the oil producing countries.

The number of barrels produced increases by around 44% annually from 2010 so that by

2012 the total number of barrels/day is almost 250,000.

The price of oil is assumed to average around US$70 per barrel under scenario 1 and

US$100 per barrel under scenario 2 over the entire period.

Page 69: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

55

Based on these conservative assumptions we obtain a projected revenue from oil of the

range of US$1.22 billion to US$1.75 billion in 2010, under scenarios 1 and 2, respectively. This

is expected to reach between US$2.54 billion to US$3.62 billion by 2012 under scenario two (as

indicated in the figure below). Clearly these are quite significant inflows compared to the total of

grants and loans of around US$1.34 billion in 2007.

Figure 2: Projected Oil Revenue for Ghana, 2010-15

Source: Osei and Domfe, 2008

Implications of the Projected Oil Revenue for Fiscal Consolidation in Ghana

There is no doubt that the estimated oil revenue will help fiscal consolidation in Ghana.

The overall budget deficits over 2006-07 were in the range of 7%-8% of GDP. From Figure 4

above, it can be seen that, even under scenario 1, the oil revenues can cover a significant portion

of these deficits. Furthermore, projected oil revenues far exceed the 2007 level of grants, loans,

cocoa exports and gold exports. Indeed, at the projected levels, oil revenue will become the most

important export earner for the country, contributing over 60% of exports by 2012. We estimate

GDP and domestic revenue levels for 2010-15 based on an annual growth of around 21% (the

average for 2004-07). Based on these estimates, the projected oil revenue will constitute around

19% of domestic revenue in 2007 and reach a peak of around 27% in 2012.

Page 70: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

56

Table 2: Importance of Projected oil Revenue for Fiscal Consolidation in Ghana

US$ million 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015

Projected oil revenue

(scenario 1)

1,223 1,761 2,536 2,536 2,536 2,536

Projected oil revenue

(scenario 2)

1,747 2,516 3,623 3,623 3,623 3,623

Loans (2007 level) 480 480 480 480 480 480

Grants (2007 level) 857 857 857 857 857 857

Domestic revenue 6,547 7,893 9,516 11,473 13,831 16,675

Total exports (2007 level) 4,027 4,027 4,027 4,027 4,027 4,027

Cocoa exports (2007

level)

1,103 1,103 1,103 1,103 1,103 1,103

Gold exports (2007 level) 1,734 1,734 1,734 1,734 1,734 1,734

GDP 25,245 30,435 36,692 44,235 53,330 64,294

Oil rev (scenario 1) % of

Loans (2007 level) 255 367 528 528 528 528

Grants (2007 level) 143 205 296 296 296 296

Domestic revenue 19 22 27 22 18 15

Total exports (2007 level) 30 44 63 63 63 63

Cocoa exports (2007

level)

111 160 230 230 230 230

Gold exports (2007 level) 71 102 146 146 146 146

GDP 5 6 7 6 5 4

Source: Osei and Domfe, 2008.

2.5 THE GNPC AND ITS ROLES

The GNPC (Ghana National Petroleum Corporation) is established during the military

regime of Flt. Lt. Rawlings, the GNPC was created to undertake exploration, development, and

production of petroleum, either on its own or in association with foreign oil companies, and to

kick start the petroleum industry in Ghana. By holding exclusive rights to Ghana’s onshore and

Page 71: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

57

offshore petroleum basins, GNPC became the channel through which any foreign oil company

can gain access to petroleum exploration and production rights, in the country.

GNPC's corporate mission was to promote, explore and develop the hydrocarbon

resources of the nation (Ghana) through lean, efficient and technology-driven investments so as

to enhance the economic development of Ghana. Its vision was to become a world-class

corporation capable of making Ghana a fast growing destination for upstream petroleum

investments in West Africa.

In line, with its operational vision and mission, the GNPC performs the following

functions and roles:

i. Undertaking geological data acquisition and management;

ii. Promoting Ghana’s exploration potential;

iii. Evaluating potential investors;

iv. Negotiating petroleum agreements;

v. Participating through equity in field development;

vi. Approving development plans;

vii. Monitoring petroleum costs.

viii. Monitoring activities of oil and gas companies.

As a participant in and chair of the Joint Management Committee for the Jubilee field, it

oversees the consortium’s work plans and operational budgets and has a role in determining and

monitoring production and production costs—vital determinants for revenue calculations and

payments to the state. According to GNPC’s chief legal officer, the petroleum agreements

empower GNPC to effectively monitor and control operations of oil companies and apply

sanctions where necessary through the minister of energy. As one GNPC staff member

commented, the GNPC wears “a lot of hats” and does “a lot of things we are not supposed to do”

(ISODEC, 2008:38).

For much of the GNPC’s life, very little interest was expressed by international oil and

gas companies and very little petroleum sector activity occurred. But at present it has become the

locus for government expertise in the sector and dreams of oil riches that seemed until very

recently to be a mirage. With the GNPC now serving as both a de facto regulator and a participant

in a commercially viable field, there have been calls by donors, including the World Bank and the

German government aid agency GTZ, and others to unbundle the GNPC and split the roles of

regulator and commercial entity.

However, the management of the GNPC were reluctant to cede functions and expressed

resistance to the idea during the national forum in February 2008. Manu (2008:n.p.), director of

operations at GNPC, once argued in a presentation that GNPC’s current combination of

Page 72: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

58

commercial, regulatory, and noncommercial functions at this stage of our developmental life

cycle is more beneficial than if these roles were split. He also argued that the GNPC gained

valuable insights into the company operations and could therefore better regulate the sector and

that limited human resources in Ghana meant the GNPC should play all roles for the time being.

But the consensus of the international experts at the workshop, who had seen the

problems of other countries, such as Angola, where the national oil company had become an

unaccountable state within a state, was that the commercial and regulatory roles should be split

and that transparency and accountability were vital elements in natural resource management

institutions.

It is therefore, in response to this clarion calls that the Ghana Oil Revenue Management

law unbundled these various functions of the GNPC through the establishment of the Ghana

Petroleum Regulatory Authority (GPRA) in 2011.

Page 73: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

59

CHAPTER THREE

OIL GOVERNANCE AND THE AVOIDANCE OF RESOURCE CURSE CONUNDRUM

IN GHANA

Ever since commercial oil discovery was made in Ghana,

there have been several suggestions urging the government to

use the oil and gas resources of the country for the economic

transformation of the country. The combined manifestos of

the NPP, NDC and CPP running for presidential elections in

late 2008 expressed intentions to apply oil revenue to priority

areas of infrastructure, agriculture and food processing, ICT,

education, health, rural development, housing, water and

sanitation, among others. (Nana, 2010:1).

For Ghana, one of the most peaceful and relatively prosperous

countries in West Africa, the start of oil production in late

2010 appears to come as good news. With the peaceful

transition of power from the New Patriotic Party (NPP)

government to the National Democratic Congress (NDC)

government in 2009, Ghana hopes that its star will continue to

shine and that oil revenues will help accelerate the country’s

effort to meet the UN Millennium Development Goals by

2015. (ISODEC, 2010:2)

In this chapter, we shall evaluate the various strands of natural resources and oil

governance initiatives that have been globally accepted as best practices in combating the

negative effects of natural resources in the economy of rich natural resource endowed countries.

However, our primary focus will be on the chances and strategies through which Ghana can

escape the phenomena of resource curse, in addition to its efforts in transforming and in ensuring

that its oil found into blessing rather than curse. We shall nonetheless, begin by assessing the

resource governance initiatives and best practices and conclude by identifying and scrutinizing

Ghana’s oil revenue policy, that regulates, controls and guides both the collection and use of oil

revenue in the country.

3.1 NATURAL RESOURCE (OIL) GOVERNANCE INITIATIVES

Many of the more recent initiatives that have to do with natural resource revenue

management have focused on issues of transparency, ‘downward’ accountability and public

participation. In this study, we will discuss a number of them such as:

1. Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative

2. Global Reporting Initiative

3. Publish What You Pay

4. IMF Code on Good Practices in Revenue Transparency

Page 74: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

60

5. Aarhus Convention

Other initiatives and methodologies of relevance include:

1. OECD Best Practices for Budget Transparency

2. Promoting Transparency in the African Oil Sector – Centre for Strategic and International

Studies

3. Proposed Economic Assistance Conditionality Act – US House of Representatives

4. Bank Track – NGO coalition

5. OECD Guidelines for Multi-National Enterprises

6. Proposed IAS Accounting Standards – Association for Accounting and Business Affairs

7. FTSEGOOD Indices

8. Dow Jones Sustainability Indexes

9. Africa Governance report – UNECA

10. Bribe Payers Index – Transparency International

11. Corruption Perceptions Index – Transparency International

12. Democracy Index – Institute for Democracy in South Africa

13. Global Integrity Report – Centre for Public Integrity, Washington DC

14. Worldwide Governance Indicators – World Bank

In addition, the efforts of some international donors with sector-wide and general budget

support and in facilitation of Poverty Reduction Strategies Papers (PRSP) for highly indebted

countries, have also contributed to greater transparency, accountability and participation in

revenue management, though not necessarily directed only at natural resource revenues.

The need to focus attention particularly on these three elements of the resource revenue

management is built around the growing evidence that:

1. where the government is the only shareholder, the national oil companies are subject to

little pressure to be transparent in their operations. Few national oil companies publish

accounts that are either consistent with International Accounting Standards, or

independently or externally audited (Olsen, 2002: 6) and

2. where public revenues come from a small number of concentrated sources, such as a few

foreign oil companies or a public mining enterprise, it is relatively easy for revenue and

expenditure to be hidden from view. If a legislature exists, it has limited capacity to

exercise oversight over the state because it has very incomplete knowledge of (let alone

control over) the myriad ways in which state and quasi-state agencies raise and spend

money. The official “budget” may represent a mere shadow of the true fiscal situation

(Moore, 2004:306).

Page 75: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

61

There is however also criticism that transparency initiatives are possibly overrated204. It

is noted that large portions of revenues accrue to national resource companies, middle men or

intermediary agents rather than the government or the operating companies directly.

Table 2 below summarises the main initiatives around resource revenue transparency,

accountability and civil society participation, and assesses them in terms of their reach against a

continuum of transparency, accountability and participation activities. Some highlights are given

below.

IFC Code of Good Practices on Fiscal Transparency

An updated ‘Code of Good Practices on Fiscal Transparency’ was approved by the

Executive Board of the IMF in 2001. Notably, the code is the only formal instrument that appears

to offer a fully comprehensive approach, covering all of the main features of effective revenue

management (see Table). Most other initiatives are predominantly piece-meal in comparison. The

IMF code thus offers a possible template for undertaking a ‘gap analysis’ to determine the best

role to be played by donors (including UNDP) and others in supporting resource revenue

management.

Page 76: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

62

Table 3: Variable ‘Reach’ of Initiatives on Resource Revenue Transparency, Accountability and

Participation

IMF Revised Code of Good Practices on Fiscal Transparency (IMF, 2005)

1. Clarity of Roles and Responsibilities

a. Clear mechanisms for the coordination and management of budgetary and extra budgetary

activities should be established.

b. Government involvement in the private sector (e.g., through regulation and equity

ownership) should be conducted in an open and public manner, and on the basis of clear

rules and procedures that are applied in a non-discriminatory way. Any commitment or

Page 77: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

63

expenditure of public funds should be governed by comprehensive budget laws and

openly available administrative rules.

c. Taxes, duties, fees, and charges should have an explicit legal basis. Tax laws and

regulations should be easily accessible and understandable, and clear criteria should guide

any administrative discretion in their application.

d. Ethical standards of behaviour for public servants should be clear and well publicized.

2. Public Availability of Information

a. The public should be provided with full information on the past, current, and

projected fiscal activity of government.

b. The budget documentation, final accounts, and other fiscal reports for the public

should cover all budgetary and extra budgetary activities of the central government,

and the consolidated fiscal position of the central government should be published.

c. Where sub-national levels of government are significant, their combined fiscal

position and the consolidated fiscal position of the general government should be

published.

d. The publication of fiscal information should be a legal obligation of government.

3. Open Budget Preparation, Execution, and Reporting

a. The budget documentation should specify fiscal policy objectives, the macroeconomic

framework, the policy basis for the budget, and identifiable major fiscal risks.

b. The annual budget be prepared and presented within a comprehensive and consistent

quantitative macroeconomic framework, and the main assumptions underlying the budget

should be provided.

c. Major fiscal risks should be identified and quantified where possible, including variations

in economic assumptions and the uncertain costs of specific expenditure commitments

(e.g., financial restructuring).

d. Budget data should be reported on a gross basis, distinguishing revenue, expenditure, and

financing, with expenditure classified by economic, functional, and administrative

category. Data on extra budgetary activities should be reported on the same basis.

e. A statement of objectives to be achieved by major budget programs (e.g., improvement in

relevant social indicators) should be provided.

f. Procedures for the execution and monitoring of approved expenditure and for collecting

revenue should be clearly specified.

g. Procurement and employment regulations standardized and accessible to all interested

parties.

Page 78: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

64

h. Budget execution should be internally audited, and audit procedures should be open to

review.

i. The national tax administration should be legally protected from political direction and

should report regularly to the public on its activities.

j. There should be regular fiscal reporting to the legislature and the public.

4. Assurances of Integrity

a. Budget data should reflect recent revenue and expenditure trends, underlying

macroeconomic developments, and well-defined policy commitments.

b. A national audit body or equivalent organization, which is independent of the executive,

should provide timely reports for the legislature and public on the financial integrity of

government accounts.

c. Independent experts should be invited to assess fiscal forecasts, the macroeconomic

forecasts on which they are based, and all underlying assumptions.

d. A national statistics agency should be provided with the institutional independence to

verify the quality of fiscal data.

Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative

The Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI) programme is managed by the

UK Department for International Development and the World Bank. Presently eight countries are

implementing the EITI principles: Azerbaijan, DRC, Ghana, Kyrgyz, Nigeria, Sao Tomé , Timor

L’Este and Trinidad and Tobago. Another twelve countries have endorsed the initiative (see -

http://www.eitransparency.org/).

Central to the initiative is commitment by governments to:

(i) voluntarily disclosure independently reconciled audits of revenues (received by governments)

and payments (made by companies to governments); and

(ii) initiative a multi-stakeholder process to design, monitor and evaluate the transparency

commitments.

EITI is now expanding into skills training for national level public sector. For example

the Nigerian EITI chapter recently commissioned a training programme on petroleum industry

economics, tax policy and revenue management, a move which takes EITI beyond just

transparency. ETIT is thus at a cross-roads. Two clear choices face the initiative, either develop a

"narrower but deeper" strategy, focused on only a few countries, but extending activities into

national expenditure monitoring and reconciliation of payments/revenues at sub national levels of

government; versus a "shallower but wider” approach which would remain focused on

transparency and bring into the initiative countries such as China, India and Russia.

It is recommended that UNDP continue to discuss with EITI how to align their strategies.

Page 79: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

65

Guiding Principles of the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI)

EITI implementation rests on six guiding principles namely:

1. Publication of payment/receipt in a publicly and readily accessible form;

2. Independent audit of payments/receipts by a reputable audit firm applying

international auditing standards;

3. Payments and receipts are reconciled by a credible, independent administrator, with

publication of the administrator’s opinion regarding that reconciliation;

4. Extension of the above to all companies including national resource companies;

5. Active engagement of civil society in the design, monitoring, and public debate

around the implementation process; and

6. Commitment to a work plan and timeline for implementation.

Source: Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative, 2003

Good Practice Examples of the EITI

Azerbaijan – the Government’s State Commission on the EITI (responsible for overseeing the

implementation of the Initiative) is a ‘proactive and sophisticated’ local NGO transparency

coalition. All operating companies have signed a “Memorandum of Understanding” to provide

guidance to stakeholder groups as to their responsibilities within the tri-partite process and how

disputed issues will be addressed. The MOU guarantees that the local NGO coalition will play a

fundamental role in the design and monitoring of EITI implementation and in selecting an

independent auditor to verify published data.

Sao Tomé e Príncipe – a National Forum was established by President Fradique de Menezes in

order to inform citizens about the potential impact of the oil industry on the country and to seek

advice on how revenues should be spent. Various ‘popular information bulletins’ were generated

for participants in the forum as well as several questionnaires to get their feedback directly.

Timor L’Este – consultations were held with local civil society organisations, remote

communities, universities and schools during the development of the country’s oil revenue

management legislation (PWYP, 2005).

Publish What You Pay

Publish What You Pay (PWYP) is a coalition of 250 international and national NGOs.

The coalition actively gathers and reports information the disclosure of payments by companies

to host governments, highlighting deficiencies as a means to encourage improved performance.

The grouping also advocates for:

a. mandatory disclosure of payments by companies, and argue that this serve as a substitute

for reporting of income by governments that do not supply such information;

Page 80: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

66

b. transparency in the extractive industries to be made a condition of all lending,

development and technical assistance programmes by international financial institutions

like the International Monetary Fund and World Bank Group;

c. an amendment to the rules for all oil, gas and mining companies listed on stock markets,

which would require the disclosure of payments (taxes, fees, royalties and other

d. transactions) made to governments for all countries of operation;

e. an International Financial Reporting Standard for the extractive industries to include a

requirement that extractive industry companies disclose in their accounts all payments

that they make to the governments of countries in which they extract resources, and to

agencies or representatives of those governments;

f. export credit agencies to require the public disclosure of all payments (taxes, fees,

royalties and other transactions) as a condition of their support to extractive industry

companies seeking loans, guarantees and risk insurance;

g. all private, commercial and retail banks to require transparency of revenues from

extractive industries as a condition for all resource-backed loans to developing countries,

meaning loans which are secured against future resource revenues;

h. country governments to:

i. remove legal and extra-legal obstacles to transparent disclosure of company

payments and government revenues from the extractives sector, including

removing non-disclosure clauses in production sharing agreements;

ii. collaborate with citizen groups monitoring the management and allocation of

resource wealth including the development of revenue oversight mechanisms

involving both government and civil society;

iii. publish the results of regular independent audits of national resource companies;

iv. identify resource revenues in the national budget.

A toolkit has recently been published by PWYP. The resource cites four key success

factors for effective participation of civil society in monitoring revenue management:

1. a capacity to gather the right information through formal and informal channels, and

analyse and translate the material into an understandable form for the public, the media,

and policymakers;

2. building and maintaining effective advocacy positions;

3. working with the media; and

4. engaging public officials and ‘push’ them in the direction of civil society’s agenda.

Page 81: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

67

OTHER TRANSPARENCY INITIATIVES

Other organisations in the somewhat crowded field of revenue transparency,

accountability and participation include: the Global Reporting Initiative; IMF - Code on Good

Practices in Revenue Transparency; Open Society Institute; International Budget Project (IBP) of

the Centre on Budget and Policy Priorities; OECD Best Practices for Budget Transparency. A

number of international conventions are also relevant to this topic: the UNECE Aarhus

Convention; UN Convention Against Corruption; African Union Convention Against Corruption;

and SADC Protocol Against Corruption.

Working with Parliament, the Media and NGOs

A key component of accountability in NRNR management is an effective role for

parliamentary institutions, the media and established key civil organisations. The aim here is to

foster an enhanced scrutiny and oversight capacity explicitly targeted at how NRNR revenues are,

or are not, being linked to development goals. This may involve strengthening the capacity of

parliamentarians, supporting civil servants on Public Accounts and other relevant parliamentary

sub-committees, as well as working with key journalists and editors of the newsprint and

broadcast media, and with faith groups and key non-governmental organisations.

Specialist training packages, technical advice and consultancy management expertise

already lies with a number of international transparency initiatives, including the International

Budget project (IBP) programme, the recommendations of the World Bank Extractive Industries

Review (EIR), the IMF Code on Good Practices in Revenue Transparency, the Publish What You

Pay (PWYP) toolkit and the programmes of the Open Society Institute. Building on these

initiatives, UNDP could offer to co-ordinate or implement a wide range of initiatives, including:

a. oversight of a process of natural resource revenue laws formulation;

b. oversight of interagency co-ordination among Central Bank, Ministry of Finance,

Ministry of Energy/Petroleum/Minerals and the national oil company;

c. oversight of production and royalty negotiations with foreign extractive industry

investors;

d. interpretation of reports on resource production, payments and revenue receipts;

e. review of auditors reconciliations;

f. oversight of state mineral or oil stabilisation and savings funds;

g. contribute to public expenditure policy formulation on NRNR revenue stabilisation,

intergenerational savings, productive investment and economic policy;

h. review of budgets, revenue distribution and public expenditure management; and

i. oversight of public sector procurement.

Page 82: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

68

3.2 OIL GOVERNANCE BEST PRACTICES

The oil industry has several stakeholders: the multi-national companies (MNCs) that

pump the oil; the government who receive part of the profits; the citizens who should benefit

from resource wealth and often, international donors who contribute financing for production.

Two of these groups namely the oil MNCs and the government have direct access to and control

over oil revenues. It is typically citizens and donors, however, who have the strongest interest in

averting the resource curse. Citizens suffer directly from the poverty, inequality, and violence that

accompany failed oil policies (Ross, 2003). Multinational donors increasingly condition their

support on institutional reform and democracy promotion (World Bank, 2007: 1-7). Oil

companies, in the other hand, simply want to maximize profit they have little interest in whether

they promote wealth or poverty, democracy or authoritarianism (Frynas, 2005:581). In fact, they

will be happy to support authoritarian governments; if it facilitates oil production (the case of

Nigeria during the military rule and Bashir’s Sudan are typical examples). In theory,

governments represent the needs of their constituents, but officials and the electorates often have

divergent interests. Officials benefit personally from corruption and often use oil money to

consolidate power (Ross, 2003). To keep companies and the government in check, therefore,

stakeholders must be able to hold them accountable; monitor their actions, demand and receive

explanations for decisions made, and impose sanctions if they fail to conform to established

agreements and priorities (Robinson, et al, 2006 and Bannon and Collier 2003).

Of course, creating accountability is no easy task. But that has not stopped the

international community from trying. Over the years, experts have come up with a litany of

governance best practices that, if adopted and implemented, should result in more responsive and

effective oil management (see, IMF, 2005, World Bank, 2006 and World Bank, 2008). These

practices revolve around three key concepts namely transparency, oversight and enforcement.

Transparency is paramount. If details about production, revenues and spending are publicly

available, interested parties can monitor what is happening and bring to light abuses or policy

failures (Humphreys, et al, 2007:326-327). With production, the government must, at a minimum

publish all production contracts it enters into with MNCs; ideally, it should auction off production

blocks through an open competitive bidding or application process that publicises all proposals

and final agreements (IMF, 2005). Once production begins, the law must require oil companies to

produce regular reports on production levels, revenues, and royalties paid, the government must

publish companion reports that detail royalties it received, where they were deposited and how

they were spent.

Transparency facilitates the second aspect of accountability, which is oversight.

Information permits concerned citizens to scrutinize oil activities, determine whether they support

Page 83: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

69

national interests, and advocate for change where they do not. Simply disseminating information

to the public at large, however, might not engender sufficient oversight (Shultz, 2005: 7-8).

Individual citizens may not be motivated to pour through thousands of pages of government

report and civil society groups may not pick up the slack. This is especially true in developing

countries, where civil society is still consolidating and significant capacity constraints exist

(IDSA, 2007: 22-30). Therefore, effective oil governance frameworks also set up formal

oversight mechanism to review and evaluate government and industry activity. These include

annual internal and external audits, and independent committees comprised of government

officials, business representatives, and private citizens that oversee the production process or

monitor and even authorize spending (IMF, 2005:59-63).

Providing formal oversight of government spending is particularly important in

developing democracies. Ideally, spending oil revenues through the regular budgetary process

would provide sufficient oversight of government decision-making. In a perfectly democratic

world, these procedures should be transparent, easily monitored, and subject to legislative debate

and approval. Unfortunately, democracy is usually far from perfect and budget processes often

lack requisite accountability (Alexander and Gilbert, 2008). Independent committees charged

with reviewing or even authorizing spending provide an important additional layer of oversight.

Finally, even in the most robust democracies there will be times when public scrutiny and

press will be insufficient to change industry or official conduct. In such situations, strong

enforcement mechanisms are necessary to sanction wrongdoing and force action. This requires

building the capacity of existing legal institutions to investigate and prosecute oil industry

misconduct (IMF, 2005:60-63). Oversight committees should also have investigatory and

adjudicatory power in the areas they monitor, to create an independent layer of enforcement

(Gary and Reisch, 2005:58-64). Laws must establish clear channels through which the public can

bring problems to the attention of enforcement agencies, so that informal oversight feeds into the

legal system. Meaningful sanctions provide an accountability backstop that forces players to

respect national interests, even when the pressures to subvert them are exceptionally strong.

Many experts also promote oil funds as a means of moderating and monitoring spending

(World Bank, 2006). Oil funds are special accounts set up to receive all or a portion of oil

revenues. Most funds are created to save and invest part of the country’s oil wealth; this prevents

overheating and guarantees that future generations will benefit from the country’s resources. In

places where there are serious concerns about corruption or wasteful spending, funds are also

used to force the government to spend money on development priorities (Alexander and Gilbert,

2008). For a fund to work, however, it must meet the same standards of transparency, oversight

and enforcement as the rest of the oil sector (World Bank, 2006). There must be clear rules for

Page 84: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

70

depositing and withdrawing funds. Parliament might be allowed to request funds through the

regular budget process, but rules can also contain more substantial checks on withdrawals,

perhaps requiring multiple officials or an oversight committee to sign off on spending request.

Saving fund regulations should establish who will manage investments and set financial goals or

targets. And, of course, the law must set-up spending and investment oversight mechanism

including independent committees and audit.

Clearly, then there are many ideas about what countries should do to manage oil

revenues. Unfortunately, how to get countries to enact the right policies and ensure that they work

is more than a little murky (Carvnar, 2008:4).

Fig. 3: Oil Production Chain and Interventions

Source: Moss and Young, 2009:12

3.3 CASE STUDIES OF OIL GOVERNANCE

3.3.1 Case Study One: Alaska

Alaska became a major oil producer in 1969, when oil companies struck “gold” in

Prudhoe Bay. Within a year, the Prudhoe Bay find had flooded the state’s treasury with $900

million in new revenue and Alaska was pumping hundreds of thousands of barrels of oil a day.

Alaska production peaked in 1998 at two million barrels a day, today, it produces around one

million. Oil dominates Alaska’s economy, contributing 40 percent of annual revenues.

Laws and Regulations Covering Oil Production and Royalties

Alaska’s oil and gas laws contain strong standards on transparency accountability. The

state lease production blocks through a competitive bidding process where interested companies

submit licensing proposals to the Licensing Commissioners; who (the commissionr) makes all

proposals available to the public for analysis and comment (Alaska Statute, 2007). He awards the

Page 85: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

71

lease on the “best interest determining,” which must take into consideration public comment

(Alaska Statute, 2007). The final contract and the Commissioner’s decision-making process are

published (Alaska Statute, 2007). Affected groups or individuals can challenge the

Commissioner’s “best interest determination” in court if they believe he abused his authority

(Alaska Statute, 2007).

Once production is underway, the laws impose substantial reporting and auditing

requirements on oil companies and state agencies. Companies must submit monthly royalty

reports accounting for production, revenues received, and royalties paid to the government

(http://www.dog.dnr.state.ak.us/oil/product/publications/annual/report.htm). The Alaska Division

of Oil and Gas reports revenue received monthly. The public can demand review of these reports

by the Alaska Royalty Oil and Gas Development Advisory Board, which is comprised of

government commissioners and public members; the Board can sanction officials if it reveals

wrongdoing. The Oil and Gas Division also release annual reports providing details on all

exploration, leasing, revenues and expenditures for the year

(http://www.dog.dnr.state.ak.us/oil/production.publications/annual/report.htm). All reports are

subject to regular internal audits carried out by the Royalty Accounting Section, and the

legislature can order the state auditing agency to audit the entire Division

(http://www.dog.dnr.state.ak.us/oil/programs/royalty/royalty.htm).

Alaska law also sets up the Alaska Oil and Gas Conservation Commission (AOGCC),

responsible for overseeing the oil and gas production process. The AOGCC is an independent,

quasi-judicial body that is supposed to provide an independent check on relations between the

government and oil companies and ensure that all contracts comply with rules and regulations.

The Commissioners are from government and the private sector and are appointed by the

Governor.

Overall, Alaska’s regulatory framework permits significant monitoring of the oil

production and payment processes. In much of the world, such robust processes would be

exceptional. In the American context, however, Alaska’s focus on transparency is hardly unique.

Since the 1930s, when President Franklin Roosevelt launched the New Deal, state and federal

administrative agencies-such as the Alaskan Oil and Gas Division-have regulated or run vast

swaths of American economic and social life (Breyer, et al 2001). Over the decades, strong legal

and regulatory standards have developed to ensure accountability in these agencies. Soliciting

public comment, holding public hearings, and releasing information on decision-making criteria

is routine, as are legal challenges to agency decisions. These standards have developed, in part,

through the legal system-transparency, public participation, and legal reviews are anchored in

Page 86: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

72

Supreme Court and other legal precedent. Given this, it is unlikely that Alaska could, legally,

have created an oil regulatory regime without strong accountability.

Despite a high-level of transparency, however, Alaska has not been free of oil scandals,

most involving oil companies lobbying government officials. Most recently, from 2004 to 2006

several members of the AOGCC resigned after government investigations prompted by

complaints from one of the Commission members, Sarah Palin, now the Governor of Alaska

found that they were receiving bribes and other favours from oil companies (Rosen, 2007). In the

aftermath, the government changed the tax laws to eliminate a number of loopholes favouring oil

producer and tightened lobbying regulations. Unlike in other parts of the world, Alaska’s

government troubles have not resulted in the widespread theft of oil revenues or an explosion of

oil related violence. And the government’s reaction to them shows that strong laws can help root

out corruption, even if they cannot completely prevent it. Nonetheless, Alaska’s troubles server as

a reminder that effective oil governance is a difficult task, even in the most favourable

circumstances.

The Alaska Permanent Fund

Alaska’s oil fund, known as the Alaka Permanent Fund (APF), is one of the world’s

largest savings fund. It has assets of just under $35 billion and experts routinely cite it as one of

the best managed. The APF was established through an amendment to the Alaska Constitution

requiring the government to deposit 25 percent of all oil revenues into a permanent fund that

would channel it into income-producing investments (http://www/pdf.state.ak.us/). The principal

of the Fund is invested permanently; further spending requires the approval of a majority of

Alaskan voters. The APF’s investment earnings are distributed directly to Alaskans through an

annual dividend program (Alaska Statue, 2007). Every year around Christmas, the Permanent

Fund Division Program mails resident dividend checks for an amount based on a five-year

average of the Fund’s earnings. The dividend program is popular with Alaskan residents; many

rely on the checks to supplement their income.

The APF is managed by the Alaska Permanent Fund Corporation (APFC), a public

corporation that is responsible for the investment strategy and monitoring of the Fund’s

operations. A six-member independent board of trustees oversees the APFC’s. The Governor

appoints all board members. The board releases regular’s public reports on the Fund’s

investment, finances, and earnings. A group of the internal and external asset managers are

responsible for day-to-day investing

(http://www.apfc.org/home/Content/investments/managers/cfm). The APFC has a second layer of

investment advisors, the Investment Advisory Council, made up of the three private citizens with

Page 87: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

73

investment experience. It reviews report and advises on the APFC’s investment decisions. The

Corporation has an audit committee, and the Governor or legislature can order external audits.

The APF emerged in the decade following Alaska’ entry into commercial oil production

in 1969. when Alaska received its first injection of oil money, state legislators had no idea how to

deal with it. As quickly as the money flowed in, it flowed out – the legislature authorized $900

million of spending proposal in less than twelve months

(http://www.apfc.org/home/Content/reportpublications/tp5.cfm). The rapid disappearance of such

large sum startled Alaskan citizens, sparking inquiries into what the legislature was doing with its

new resource. Facing public anger over wasteful spending, legislators took up the idea of creating

a fund. The idea went nowhere for five years, however, ostensibly because legislators did not

know if Alaskan law permitted a permanent savings mechanism, but also because of resistance to

spending restriction. In 1976, to get the fund off the ground, the governor proposed a

constitutional amendment that would provide a clear legal basis for the fund; he carried out a

state-wide public education campaign on the fund and Amendment (Rasmussen, 1993 and World

Bank, 2006). The public embraced his proposal, and the Amendment passed over

overwhelmingly.

After the Amendment’s passage, the legislature was tasked with creating a legal

framework to manage and govern the fund. House and Senate committees studied the issue and

developed competing proposals; the committees included members of government, the business

community, civic groups, and the general public. The legislature and committees organised a

number of public hearing and debates on the fund throughout the state. In 1980, the legislature

passed a bill establishing the APF along the lines outlined above.

In the years since its creation, the APF has consistently accumulated capital; while voters

could approve expenditures from the fund’s capital, they never have (World Bank, 2006). This is

partly because after more than two decades of public education, discussion and debate over the

Fund, the Alaskan public appears to have fully embraced the need to prudently manage and save

revenues. More importantly, however, the dividend program has made residents extremely

reluctant to raid the APF’s coffers. Dividend payments are an important source of income for

many Alaskans and they are loath to approve spending that might lower the Fund’s capital and

thus its potential earnings and the size of their checks.

The dividend program is the most direct illustration of an important aspect of the APF;

the public is deeply invested in the Fund’s success. Dividends give Alaskans a direct stake in the

APF and are credited with increasing public interest in and scrutiny over how the Fund and oil

revenue in general are managed. But Alaskan’s stake in the APF goes beyond dividend checks.

Thanks to the constitutional amendment, the legislative committees, and public debates, they

Page 88: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

74

have been involved with the Fund’s operations from the beginning. Today, because capital

expenditures require voter approval, spending proposal result in public campaigns and debates

which help maintain interest in the Fund’s operations. Because of the dividend program, attempts

to change APF legislation also spark serious public discussion.

Experts who have studied the Fund often point to public involvement as one of the key

factors to its successes. Combined with the APF’s strong transparency provisions which, as

discussed, stem from basic U.S. legal and political principles, public investment has helped

promote effective management, minimize corruption, and ensure responsiveness to the needs and

interests of Alaskan residents. The Fund’s sound investment policies are most directly

responsible for the $35billion it currently has in the bank. Its high level of accountability however

has undoubtedly played a role in ensuring that that $35billion has not disappeared into a black

hole or wasteful spending or petty corruption.

3.3.2 Case Study Two: Norway

Norwegian oil production took off in the 1980s, and the country is now one of the world’s

top 10 oil producers and top three market suppliers. It produces close to three billion barrels per

day. Oil contributes hundreds of millions of dollars per year to the Norwegian treasury, but the

country has a strong and diversified economy so oil accounts for only about 20 percent of

government revenues.

Laws and Regulations Covering Oil Production And Royalties

Norway’s oil laws and regulations contain strong transparency provisions. They are very

similar to Alaska’s except that Norway does not have the same administrative law tradition as the

United States. Therefore, the laws contain fewer requirements of public notice-and-comment

periods and citizens cannot challenge all agency decisions in national courts. Nonetheless, the

country makes huge amounts of information on the oil industry available to the public and there

are many legal avenues for prosecuting official or private corruption.

The Ministry of Petroleum is responsible for leasing production blocks through a

competitive application process, and all applications, decisions, and justifications of decisions are

made public. Norwegian law imposes a number of “reasonableness” requirements on the

Ministry’s decision-making. Oil companies must publish regular, detailed reports on royalties,

taxes, and other fees paid to the government, and the government releases reports tracing the

receipt and deposit of those funds (see, Norway Act 29 No 72 and Royal Decree 27, Chapter 7).

Government auditing agencies conduct annual audit of the government’s and oil companies’

reports; Parliament or the President can order external audit.

Unfortunately, as with Alaska, there is little to say why Norway has adopted strong

transparency rules except that Norway has a long democratic history, and its citizens expect, and

Page 89: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

75

its laws demand, that the government conduct business openly

(http://www.regjeringen.no/en/dep/ud/press/2007/Norway-at-the-forefront-ofextractive-

in.html?id=481866). Domestic civil society groups monitor the government’s actions and there is

significant public awareness of and interest in the oil industry. As Norway’s profile as an oil

producer has risen, it has also become something of a global transparency champion. The

government regularly consults with developing countries on formulating oil regulations

(http://www.norad.no.defualt.asp?v_ITEM_ID=10094). The country’s effort have garnered it

significant praise and raised it international profile, undoubtedly putting pressure on the country

to ensure that its own operations are truly open and accountable. Nonetheless, Norway was a

model oil producer before the world recognised it as such, and it is really the Norwegian political

tradition, and not international pressure, that has helped it remain one in the years since.

The Government Pension Fund of Norway

While Norway receives recognition for its general commitment to transparency, it is the

country’s oil fund the Government Pension Fund of Norway (GPF) that garners the lion’s share

of international attention, praise, and envy. With assets of nearly $350 billion dollars, the GPF is

the world’s second largest sovereign wealth fund. The laws establishing the GPF requires the

government to deposit all oil production revenues into the Fund each year (Norway, Act Relating

to the Government Petroleum Fund, art 1-2, 1990). From there, the funds are invested overseas;

investment earning are added to principal and reinvested.

Strictly, speaking, the GPF is not a saving fund. Every year the Norwegian Parliament

passes the country’s annual budget. If it exceeds government non-oil revenues, parliament

authorizes withdrawals from the GPF to cover the deficit (World Bank, 2006). This means that

Parliament could pass a budget authorizing spending large portions, or even all, of the GPF’s

principal. The fact that it has not compared to the Fund’s size annual withdrawals are very small

is a testament of an incredible self-restraint attributable to several factors. The Norwegian

economy is strong and annual budget deficits are low, so there is little pressure to use oil revenue

to cover needed spending. Further, there is deep-rooted public support for using the GPF as a

saving fund. Because the Fund is so well-known and popular, a move by Parliament to increase

spending would spark significant debate (Business Week, 2008). This is not to say that increased

future spending will never happen; the country is currently debating what to do with the Fund’s

ballooning assets. However, if spending does pick up, it is likely that public pressure and

government priorities will lead to reasonable and measured outlays.

The Ministry of Finance has overall control of the GPF and establishes all regulations

governing the Fund. The Ministry consults Parliament on this process, but retains ultimate

responsibility for their content and implementation. Financial managers at the Norwegian central

Page 90: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

76

bank, Norges Bank are responsible for day-to-day asset management. The Fund also has external

asset managers responsible for a portion of its portfolio; this diversifies risk and provides a

benchmark against which to measure internal investment return.

The Ministry of Finance and Norges Bank are subject to significant reporting

requirements. The Ministry releases an annual report that details the Fund’s operations and

returns, movement of money into and out of accounts

(http://www/regjeringen.no/upload/FIN/Statens%20pensjonsfond/PF-summary-aug08.pdf).

Norges Bank publishes quarterly reports on the Fund’s return, market risk, investment

composition, and compliance with ethical investment guidelines. The ethical guidelines were

introduced in 2004 for The Fund. It has two instruments being used which are; the right of

ownership and the exclusion of companies from The Fund. The right of ownership being the

obligation to ensure that financial returns are such that future generations too, would benefit from

the oil wealth. The exclusion of companies from The Fund has to do with the obligation to

respect the fundamental rights of persons who might be affected by companies due to The Funds

investment in those companies. In addition, the exclusive mechanism is a defensive measure

aimed at avoiding situations where The Fund runs the risk of being complicit in ethically

unacceptable practices.

The benchmark for The Fund serves as a risk control mechanism for The Fund and also

assesses the performance of the Norges bank with regards to its management of „The Fund‟ by

comparing actual returns with the returns on the benchmark portfolio. Going by the benchmark,

The Fund is only invested in the international finance market spreading over various countries

and companies abroad. 60 percent of The Fund is invested in equities while the 40 percent is

invested in bonds. This allows the investment to be diversified thus reducing risk while

maximizing expected returns that accrues on The Funds investments. Investing The Fund abroad

also promotes exchange rate stability in the Norwegian economy. Figure 4 below shows the

benchmark of The Fund:

Page 91: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

77

Fig. 4: Benchmark for the Government Petroleum Fund-Global

Source: Norwegian Ministry of Finance

The government auditing agency conducts annual, publicly-available audits on all reports.

The Ministry can also order an external audit. It did so in 2002, and the audit found no problems

with the Fund’s regulatory compliance or management (Carvnar, 2008).

Fig 5: Governance Structure of the Norwegian Pension Fund –Global

Source: Norwegian Ministry of Finance

The fact that Norway’s oil fund structure gives considerable discretion and power to the

Ministry of Finance reflects a technocratic bent in the country’s original approach to revenue

management. During Norway’s first decade of oil production, there was no talk of an oil fund.

However, as revenue grew, the typical economic problems began to take hold inflation increased;

other sectors of the economy began to decline sparkling concern over oil impact. Separately, the

government began to worry about how to provide pensions for a rapidly aging population. In the

late 1980s, the President proposed to address both the pension issue and the mounting economic

Page 92: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

78

problems by setting up an oil fund to manage and save excess revenue. In 1990, Parliament

passed a broad law establishing the Pension Fund’s basic principles: It would safeguard long-term

use of oil revenues, manage the government’s net cash flow oil, and transfer money to the fiscal

budget to cover the non-oil deficit (Carvnar, 2008).

After passing the 1990 law, Parliament basically handed responsibility for the Fund to the

Ministry of Finance. As Parliament would return authority over spending oil money, there were

few worries about creating mechanisms to manage spending. Norway’s governmental institutions

do not suffer from excessive corruption. The Fund was only responsible for ensuring that oil

revenues were managed efficiently. As the Ministry of Finance had the most experience with

revenue management, it made sense to charge it with creating the Fund’s rules and regulations

and overseeing its operations (World Bank, 2006). The Ministry of Finance is a highly efficient

and professional operation.

In the years since the Fund’s creation, the Ministry has more than earned the trust placed

in it. Its initial regulations established strong reporting requirement and it has carried out its

operations with exemplary openness and transparency. There have been few, if any, serious

complaints about management or corruption. The Fund’s massive assets are a testament to the

Ministry and Norges Bank investment skills. Norway’s success at managing and growing its oil

wealth has made it an oil governance model and the envy of government around the world.

3.4 ACCOUNTABILITY AND TRASPARENCY ISSUES IN GHANA’S REVENUE

The growing international focus on transparency is amply demonstrated by the

proliferation in recent years of initiatives aimed at directly and indirectly promoting and

enforcing transparency practices. These include the United Nations (UN)’s Convention Against

Corruption, the International Monetary Fund (IMF)’s Code of Good Practices on Fiscal

Transparency, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD)’s Best

Practices for Budget Transparency, the Global Reporting Initiative, and the Global Transparency

Initiative. Other initiatives are engaged primarily in transparency in extractive industries and

include the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI), the ‘Publish What You Pay’

NGO coalition (by Save the Children UK), the George Soros’ Open Society Institute, the Global

Witness, the Catholic Agency for Overseas Development (CAFOD), the OECD Project on

Revenue Transparency in the Democratic Republic of the Congo (DRC) and the IMF Guide on

Resource Revenue Transparency.

Furthermore, there are also country initiatives and benchmarks such as the UN Economic

Commission for Africa’s African Governance Project, the Democracy Index of the Institute for

Democracy in South Africa and the Worldwide Governance Indicators Dataset of the World Bank

(ECA, 2005).

Page 93: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

79

The transparency specificity hinges on ultimate objectives. Thus, on the one hand,

objectives aimed at eliminating corruption, money laundering and fighting the financing of

terrorism, such as those of the UN, tends to be stated in broad language incorporating a number of

other issues besides transparency, to achieve the ultimate objective. On the other hand, objectives

such as those of IMF, OECD and EITI that are aimed at promoting sound financial management

and accountability tend to contain narrower and more specific recommendations or prescriptions.

The IMF published a Manual on Fiscal Transparency as a guide to implementing the Code. Non-

country initiatives tend to be broadly articulated, allowing countries to generate specific

initiatives suited to their own individual circumstances in line with these broad initiatives (ECA,

2005).

The IFC acknowledges that the potential emergence of a large oil and gas sector does

pose new political, regulatory, and governance challenges for the country. These risks will have

to be carefully managed, and the World Bank Group and a number of other donors are actively

engaged in supporting the country (Ghana) in this process. It is in recognition of this that the

Economic Commission for Africa, ECA (2005) asserts that:

Against the backdrop of heightened realization that economic

development and the fight against poverty can effectively be

enhanced under an environment of good governance, and that

fiscal (inclusive of budget) transparency is one of the key

instruments for achieving good governance, a sharp focus is now

on fiscal transparency. For poorer countries, donors, international

financial institutions and civil society organizations (CSOs) are

demanding transparency in the budgeting processes of recipient

countries, emphasizing their right to know and, to some extent,

determine how public and donated funds are collected and spent.

Ghana is one of the most democratic and transparent countries in Sub-Saharan Africa.

While regulations and oversight continues to be improved on, Ghana has shown that lessons

learned from its mining experience make it well-prepared for additional revenues from oil and

gas development compared to its peers in the region, especially its oil rich neighbour to the east.

Ghana has made substantial strides in improving its democratic governance and transparency and

is currently one of the best performing countries on governance indicators in Africa; thus:

1. Ghana has witnessed two peaceful transitions of power in elections that have been

widely observed as fair.

2. On the World Bank’s Country Policy and Institutional Assessment (CPIA), Ghana

ranks 5th among IDA countries.

Page 94: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

80

3. The World Bank Group’s “Doing Business 2009” report ranks the country 6th in

Sub-Saharan Africa among 46 countries (3rd on protecting investors and 5th on

enforcing contracts).

4. According to the 2008 Transparency International Corruption Perception Index

(CPI), Ghana is ranked 67th

out of 180 countries, and is 6th

in Sub-Saharan Africa.

The country has been improving on the corruption perception ground, having gained

3 positions in the past 2 years.

5. Ghana was the first country to submit to the NEPAD African Peer Review

Mechanism process, and is an early signatory to EITI for mining revenues. The

country is also in the middle of an active debate about the use of revenues and is well

supported by advice from donors and others in this respect.

As a country that was producing about 6,000 barrels of oil per day (“bopd”), prior to the

Jubilee oil field discovery; Ghana has in place a basic legal and regulatory structure for the oil

and gas sector. However, the Jubilee discovery promises to be a precursor to the potential

establishment of a significant oil basin offshore Ghana as this initial discovery attracts further

investor interest, and as the potential of Ghana’s offshore blocks is further established. In its

preparation for a larger oil sector, Ghana took a number of concrete steps toward improved

governance, including preparation of the Ghana Petroleum Regulatory Authority (“GPRA”) bill,

expansion of EITI beyond mining to cover oil and gas, and consideration of other mechanisms

such as stabilization and heritage funds to help manage potential larger revenues from the oil and

gas sector.

Revenue Transparency

In 2003, Ghana signed on to the Extractive Industry Transparency Initiative (EITI), a

positive indicator of the country’s commitment to growth through transparent development of its

resource sectors. While initially applied only to the mining sector, the Mills government on

assumption of office stated an interest in extending the EITI process to the oil sector. Although

Ghana missed the initial March 2010 validation deadline, the EITI Board granted an extension

until September. With this extended deadline met, the EITI Board deemed Ghana an EITI

Compliant country at its October meeting in Dar es Salaam, Tanzania.

The first audited EITI report, covering Ghana's mining revenue from January to June

2004, was published in February 2007 and included sub-national reporting from district

assemblies. In 2008, two more EITI reports were published, which covered transactions between

July-December 2004 and January-December 2005 respectively.

Page 95: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

81

Ghana also published another report in September 2010 covering data from 2006, 2007

and 2008. This report reflected some improvements in the sector, for example in the tracking of

disbursements to the sub-national level. The Ghanaian government is at present considering the

introduction of a fiscal responsibility law to expand the existing Financial Administration Act of

2003. This would anchor fiscal expectations by crafting long-term strategic plans for resource

usage regardless of short-term political changes.

Expenditure Transparency

Ghanaian authorities are making progress in improving expenditure transparency, and the

country has introduced targeted legislation in recent years designed to ensure accountability,

transparency and efficiency in public resource management, including:

i. The Financial Management Act of 2003, which regulates the public sector to ensure

transparent and effective management of state revenues and expenditures

ii. The Public Procurement Act of 2003, which aims to foster competition, efficiency,

transparency and accountability in procurements

Further efforts in expenditure transparency include the 2007 launch of Public Expenditure

Tracking Surveys (PETS) in the education and health sectors, and Ghana’s inclusion of a

requirement in its EITI framework that district, municipal and metropolitan assemblies report

royalty receipts and how they are used. Ghana's Publish What You Pay (PWYP) coalition is

supporting an ongoing community capacity-building exercise to track these disbursements.

An evaluation conducted by Public Financial Management (PFM) in 2006 under the

auspices of the World Bank and the Department for International Development (DFID)

concluded that, "the PFM system in Ghana is based upon a solid legal and regulatory

framework." Thus, the civic engagement on the budget process has increased, and Ghana has

climbed higher on the Open Budget Survey in recent years, moving from 49% in 2008 to 54% as

of 2010.

Contract Transparency

As in many countries, secrecy surrounding mining and oil contracts is an issue in Ghana.

Before Ghana endorsed the EITI in 2003, all discussion of contract transparency was branded as

anti-business. The first EITI report, however, recommended that all of Ghana's mining contracts,

including investment agreements, be made public.

On the issue of contract transparency, the GNPC, which is the institutional agency that

represents the Government of Ghana in the bidding process and transaction in the nation’s oil

industry, has distinguished itself creditably through proactive publication of important summary

information regarding the petroleum sector in Ghanaian newspapers since 2008. A gesture that is

in tandem with the calls and demand made by the Ghana Catholic Bishop’s Conference: Dialogue

Page 96: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

82

and Advocacy Office for Good Governance in December 2008, in which they argued that “for

meaningful and constructive public oversight and input that the public has the right to know the

details of oil contracts, [but] such agreements are not placed in the public domain” (ISODEC,

2008:47).

Furthermore, the contracts are based on a model contract available on GNPC’s website

which is aimed at ensuring uniformity in the documents and facilitating both negotiation and

evaluation. IFC has reviewed both the model contract and the actual executed petroleum

agreements, and is satisfied with their conformity and that clauses of public interest have been

disclosed. Moreover, the Project’s executed petroleum agreements have been ratified by

parliament and as such are accessible to the public. Going forward, the draft GPRA bill contains

disclosure requirements which should further improve transparency.

It is IFC’s view, on balance, that Ghana’s fundamental building blocks for good governance are

in place and that our engagement at this point will improve implementation of this and future oil

and gas projects in Ghana (Republic of Ghana – proposed IFC investments in Kosmos & Tullow:

briefing on the jubilee project (n.d).

However, a key challenge for the government is to reconcile the gains and commitments

made through the EITI process for the traditional mineral industries with the euphoria

surrounding the Jubilee Field discovery. To this end, the government submitted two bills to

Parliament in 2010 with major implications for oil-sector governance. The first addresses

governance of petroleum exploration and production, including the relationship between the state

and international oil companies. The second sought to establish two transparently operated oil

funds to guard Ghana against economic volatility and provide a heritage for future generations.

Besides, the standard of the IFC, require the companies to disclose payments to the

government of Ghana on an annual basis. For “significant” extractive industries projects, the IFC

requires the disclosure of “relevant terms of key agreements that are of public concern” (IFC,

2006:4). The IFC deems an extractive industries project to be “significant” when a project is

expected to account for 10 percent or more of government revenues. It is likely that the Jubilee

field, when fully operational, will contribute over 10 percent of Ghana’s government revenues.

Similarly, the Ghana Petroleum Revenue Management Act (2011) in its effort at

entrenching and enhancing the fundamental principles of transparency through accountability,

and public oversight in the governance of country’s oil wealth provides under its section 49 as

follows that:

1. The management of petroleum revenue and savings shall always be carried out

with the highest internationally accepted standards of transparency and good

governance.

Page 97: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

83

2. The duties concerned with ancillary matters of petroleum revenues and savings

shall be discharged with the highest internationally accepted standards of

transparency and good governance.

3. Information or data, the disclosure of which could in particular "' prejudice

significantly the performance of the Ghana Petroleum Fund, may be declared by

the Minister as confidential, subject to the approval of Parliament.

4. The declaration of confidentiality shall provide a clear explanation of the reasons

for treating the information or data as classified, taking into account the principles

of transparency and the right of the public as regards access to information.

5. The declaration of confidentiality shall not limit access to information by

Parliament and the Public Interest Accountability Committee established under this

Act.

6. Any information that is classified at the time when it could have been published, as

well as the reason for it being treated as classified, shall he made available to the

public upon request three years after the date on which it could have been

published unless the reasons for it being classified are still valid.

7. Parliament, the government, the Minister, the Bank of Ghana and the Advisory

Committee in the performance of their functions and competencies under this Act,

shall take the necessary measures to entrench transparency mechanisms and free

access by the public to non-classified information.

8. The Minister shall ensure that this Act, the Regulations and any instructions related

to the Ghana Petroleum Funds, the Operations Management Agreement and the

annual reports are readily available to the public.

In order to ensure strict compliance to the words and letters of the Petroleum Revenue

Management Act, especially in relation to the issue of transparency and accountability. The Act

also outlined under its section 50 a number of penalty and punishment that awaits anyone; who

fails to or hinders the publication of information regarding to oil revenue and its management.

Thus:

A person who fails to comply with any obligation to publish

information provided for in this Act, or causes another person to

fail to comply with, or in any manner hinders or causes another

person to hinder the compliance with these obligations, commits

an offence and is liable on summary conviction to a fine not

exceeding two hundred and fifty penalty units.

The Ghana Petroleum Revenue Management Act, provides a strong framework for the

collection and management of the country's expected petroleum revenues is an improvement in

Page 98: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

84

several respects to the pre-existing laws in the sector and it established a clear system of controls

for the collection of oil revenues and their allocation to the budget and the proposed stabilization

and savings funds; a clear division of responsibilities among authorities; reasonable rules for

managing the investments of the funds and strong oversight and transparency provisions. It is for

this reason that the Act provides inter alia:

Petroleum revenue management legislation is necessary if

Ghana is to avoid the costs associated with the alternative

options of leaving the revenue to be collected and accounted

for as part of conventional revenue, or in the hands of the

national oil company. The lessons from oil producing

countries are that these options for the collection and

management of petroleum revenue risk excessive waste,

potential loss of control of public expenditure, and most

importantly, weaken the purpose of the national budget as the

primary instrument to manage all the resources of this

country. Most oil-producing countries have therefore seen it

fit to put in place a legislative framework to guide the

collection, use and management of their petroleum revenue.

International best practice is that the revenue management law

should be simple, transparent, and flexible yet rules-based

with the view to ensure greater fiscal discipline. (Ghana

Petroleum Revenue Management Act, 2011)

The bill (draft version of the Act) puts much more emphasis on deploying a larger portion

of current revenues for investment to promote long-term growth and economic diversification

rather than permanently holding such funds in foreign savings as part of the "Heritage" fund.

Such domestic investment could provide greater benefits to both present and future generations of

Ghanaians than the returns to the savings fund and improve the government's ability to respond to

market volatility or other economic changes (Revenue Watch Initiative, 2010).

In addition, Ghana has to date actively sought and received assistance on various facets of

its regulatory and sectoral development from such Development Partners as Norway (NORAD),

the UK (DFID & BHC), Germany (GTZ), Canada (CIDA), the Netherlands, International

Monetary Fund, the World Bank and others. These have included, among others, supporting the

review of the Plan of Development for the Jubilee field. The World Bank has been helping in

EITI implementation (including through support for an oil and gas-specific scoping paper) and

through the Natural Resources Environmental Governance Project. Ghana also undertook a

national dialogue and a series of regional consultations in the first half of 2008 to allow

discussion with stakeholders and other segments of society regarding the implications of its new-

found resource.

Page 99: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

85

3.5 CIVIL SOCIETY AND THE MANAGEMENT OF GHANA’S OIL REVENUE

The Ghanaian civil society has profound roles to play in sustaining democracy and good

governance in the country especially now that the country has entered the league of oil producers;

in order to help checkmate official corruption, money laundering and abuse of office by ensuring

that official transactions that relates to oil exploration, exploitation, production and contract

biddings are conducted within the public domain as well as within dictates of the rule of law.

These are roles that civil society has played historically in all societies, which have succeeded in

becoming mature democracies, as well as all societies which are striving to consolidate their

fledgling transition to democracy (Schmitter, 1997).

However, the concept of civil society, like most social science concepts, is highly

contentious; so it is important to, at the outset, state which notion one subscribes to. It is therefore

for this fact, that we adopt Schmitter (1997:240) view of the concept in which he perceived it as:

… a set or system of self-organised intermediary groups that:

1. are relatively independent of both public authorities and private units of production,

that is of firms and families;

2. are capable of deliberating about and taking collective actions in defense or

promotion of their interests or passions;

3. do not seek to replace either the state agents or private (re)produces or to accept

responsibility for governing the polity as a whole; and

4. agree to act within pre-established rules of a civil nature, that is, conveying mutual

respect.

But it should be noted that the extent to which civil society contributes to the

sustainability or consolidation of democracy is related to the extent to which its members have a

democratic conduct and practices. For, there is a wide range of all types of civil society groups;

and in particular, there are many ostensibly non-governmental civil society groups, which are

either manipulated by public or private vested interests, or are not inclined towards democracy in

any fundamental respect. Such groups cannot in any meaningful way contribute to democracy,

much less to democratic consolidation and sustainability. If anything, their roles may simply

facilitate authoritarian reversals or obstruct the evolution of a desirable political culture in the

context of a striving for democratic sustainability (Jega, 1998). That is to say that, civil society

can positively contribute to sustainability of democracy by legitimizing and entrenching

institutions, processes and the culture of democracy, as well as by contesting, de-legitimising and

opposing authoritarian, undemocratic and uncivil practices and dispositions. It is as result of this

that Seong (2000:95) observed that they play these roles either by practicing internal democracy

Page 100: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

86

or by ensuring that its formal institutions and processes operate optimally in accordance with the

established rules and best practices.

The Role of Civil Society in Ensuring Accountability in Ghana’s Oil Sector

Civil society is vibrant in Ghana. According to a 2008 European Commission study, there

are approximately 3,800 registered civil society organizations, with the largest concentration in

the capital of Accra (USAID, 2010: 1). Small rural organizations operate throughout the country

with varying degrees of effectiveness. The challenges facing civil society in Ghana include a lack

of technical capacity and inadequate financial resources. Civil society groups at the local level,

peer educators and others have been sensitizing and mobilizing the people over the years on a

number of issue of common concern.

Ezeala (2010:1) observed that the Ghanaian citizens have been insisting vehemently on

the entrenchment of transparency and accountability mechanisms that will serve as failsafe in the

country’s oil regime in order to ensure that the oil proceeds are efficiently managed. Thus under

the auspices of the Civil Society Platform on Oil and Gas; civil society organizations in Ghana

during the formation of the nations oil and gas bill raised serious concerns about Ghana’s ability

to ensure transparent, accountable, and sustainable management of its petroleum resources. In this

wise the civil society organizations are working to keep the expected economic boom from

pushing Ghana into poverty and corruption-- what is known as the “oil curse” of many

developing countries rich in resources yet suffering in poverty. This synchronized the views

expressed by the Conference of Catholic Bishops in the Congo, net-effect of ill-management and

administration of oil resource and revenue on the citizens thus:

How can one understand that during the last three

decades, the frequent startup of oil wells, always

important, has not been accompanied by any kind of

visible sign of economic transformation or rectification

of the social situation of our population? Our oil must be

an instrument for the life and not the death of our people.

Catholic Bishops of Congo (Brazzaville), 1999

Moreover, Oxfam America an international Non-governmental organization (NGOs) has

been supporting watchdog groups in Ghana to help ensure that Ghana’s recent democratic and

development gains are not threatened by a sudden influx of oil wealth. Since Ghana is set to

receive more than $1 billion in oil revenues in 2011.

The Civil Society Platform has been engaging with government to influence legislation

that ensures transparent management of Ghana’s new oil wealth; such that many of the civil

society recommendations were gainfully incorporated into the bill that was presented to the

Ghana’s parliament. Fearing that key provisions could be stripped out and during the

parliamentary debate and discussion on the bill; the civil society activists matched their words

Page 101: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

87

with actions by mounting an unprecedented petition campaign aimed at the parliament. Using text

messages, Facebook, email action alerts, radio and television advertisements and other tools,

activists in Ghana gathered over 41,000 names of Ghanaians within the country and abroad.

Armed with these names and signatories that resonate the democratic and Lockian

principle of popular sovereignty, the group on November 2010 marched to the parliament to

submit the petition. The convener of the groups, Mohammed Amin Adam, said that they are

particularly concerned with the proposed amendments to the law “that provide for a citizens-

based transparency and accountability framework for ensuring transparent management of

petroleum revenues,” he in addition assert that “they are equally disturbed about the absence of

transparency provisions in the bill which does not provide for competitive bidding process for oil

blocs”. However, the group welcomed a provision of the bill for a Public Interest and

Accountability Committee (PIAC) as serving as a big relief to many Ghanaians as it tends to

gives the citizens not just a say in the industry, but the much needed constituent capacity to

observe, monitor, analyse and equally demand changes and explanations on the activity in both

the oil sector and its revenue.

It is as a result of the provisions of the Act on Public Accountability Commission, that a

tribal Chief in the Western region of Ghana while availing himself of the opportunity teasingly

warned a GNPC official of what is to come, should they ever engage in corrupt and sharp

practices; in the following words:

I am going to have a man on the beach in Takoradi

watching the oil leave [western Ghana] and a man in

Tema [the location of an oil refinery in east Ghana]

watching it arrive. And if it doesn't, I'm going to come

looking for you. (Smith, 2010)

In early 2011 the civil society platform in Ghana insisted that the parliament must include

provision for disclosure of petroleum agreements in the proposed law, open and competitive

bidding process for acquiring oil licenses, and timelines for the establishment of an Independent

Petroleum Regulatory Authority as opposed to the limitless powers enjoyed by the minister of

energy, among others. Thus:

Only ‘commercially sensitive information’ shall be held

confidential. Further the determination of ‘commercial

sensitivity’ must be done with approval from parliament. The

bill should provide for the publication of contracts signed

between the state and contractors in respect of any petroleum

operations.

According to Richard Hato-Kuevor, an extractive industries advocacy officer for Oxfam

America, “the contribution of civil society organizations to the evolution of the oil industry in

Page 102: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

88

Ghana has been positive and significant.” He noted that, “had it not been for their intervention,

we would have had a very weak bill, which would have translated into a weak law and an oil

industry that has set off on the wrong footing.” (http://www.oxfamamerica.org/articles/civil-

society-groups-in-ghana-insist-on-transparency)

Moreover, the Civil Society Platform on Oil and Gas, that was formed in Ghana with the

objective of creating a forum for civil society engagement on oil and gas issues in the country

petitioned parliament on some provisions of the Petroleum (Exploration and Production) Bill, that

was presented to the house for consideration. On the grounds that many stakeholder inputs were

made into the bill before it was finally tabled before the Parliament. The platform, after its

examination of the bill concluded that though the bill is positive in many ways; it also has many

flaws that must be addressed if the purpose of the law is to be achieved (Kingson, 2010:1).

In the document, the platform complained about a number of things which such poor

transparency and accountability, the (dual) role of the Ghana National Petroleum Corporation

(GNPC), ministerial oversight responsibility, as well as the absence of a regulatory authority to

check spillage. Thus it opined that:

The bill does not address very important issues which are

fundamental to the sustainable management of petroleum

resources. These include ‘no gas flaring policy’, the allowable

flaring limits and penalty for violations; the issue of resource

ownership when a contractor exploring for crude oil discovers

natural gas instead; safeguard for incorporation of local companies

to discourage ‘fronting’ or ‘shadowing’; the status of Ghanaians in

the development of marginal fields; remedies for third party

financing of petroleum operations in the event of a default by

contractor during development phase; the issue of delayed rental

fees in the event of deliberate delay in exploration and

development; and the mortgage of the bill to too much ministerial

discretion, negotiations and bargaining in a country with little

experience in the petroleum industry (Kingson, 2010).

Arising from the above, it recommended that the bill should provide for an independent

regulatory authority to regulate petroleum operations and that timeliness must be defined for the

temporary responsibility of the minister of energy in the regulation of the petroleum industry.

They also sought for adequate protection to be provided for property owners whose social and

economic activities are ‘being or will be’ interfered with by petroleum operations, especially

when the state exercises the power of compulsory acquisition.

In order to ensure adequate response to emergency situations resulting from the

production activities of the oil companies, the Civil Society Platform stated that not-withstanding

that the polluter (Oil Company) pay principle provided for in the bill, there should be other

national level measures to deal with safety and environmental issues. It said the bill should

Page 103: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

89

provide for the establishment of Oil Spill Responsive and Advisory Group (OSRG) and National

Oil Spill Detection and Responsive Agency (NOSDRA).

It said, in line with the Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI), there should be

transparency about safety performance of the industry and vigilance of the public authorities.

“Payment terms of domestic supply of crude oil by contractors should be clearly stated to build

confidence in investors, and that oil backed transactions must be avoided in line with the

provisions of the Ghana Revenue Management Bill 2010” (Kingson, 2010).

The platform said penalties for violating the law and all other regulations as provided for in the

bill should constitute minimum penalties and the maximum could reach any levels to prevent rich

international oil companies from violating the laws of the country with impunity.

It maintained that the development of appropriate policies, legislations and institutional

mechanisms for managing the petroleum resources in its opinion are essential for transparent,

accountable and sustainable management of Ghana’s oil and gas for the benefit of citizens.

In the view of the Civil Society Platform on Oil and Gas, the Opacity that covered the

development of the bill until it was formerly laid before parliament has affected the quality of

debate and the participation of many citizens in the process. They claimed that in comparison to

that of the Petroleum Revenue Management Bill which was published and thoroughly debated by

a wider section of Ghanaians the process of the Exploration and Production Bill has been too

secretive.

The consortium of CSO’s in Ghana in early 2011 evaluated the government’s

performance in the 10 thematic areas of: Transparency, Independent Regulation of the Sector /

Role of GNPC, Licensing and Contracts, Citizen Participation / Public Oversight, Petroleum

Revenue Collection, Oil Revenue Management / Oil Funds, Linking Oil Revenue Spending to

Development Planning, Budget Openness and Public Financial Management, Social and

Environmental Issues and Local Content. It also evaluates the cumulative performance of

Ghana’s parliament, donors, oil companies and civil society itself. Performance is set against

recommendations made in the February 2009 report, issued by the Integrated Social Development

Centre (ISODEC) and Oxfam America.

Performance was also measured against urgent recommendations made by a broad range

of civil society groups and concerned citizens in a communiqué issued after the “Citizens Summit

on Oil and Gas” held at the Accra International Conference Centre in June 2010, wherein it

observed as follows:

We endorse these recommendations and observations,

convinced that, it is only through effective coordination of our

efforts, national consensus around the critical decision areas,

continuous vigilance by Ghanaians on the sustainable

Page 104: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

90

management of petroleum resources, revenues and the

environment, in pursuant of our rights as citizens to

participate in the governance processes of our country, as

enshrined in the constitution of Ghana, that the petroleum

resources of Ghana can be used for sustainable national

development and thereby avoid the temptations of following

the path of ‘resource management curse.

http://zotomelo.blogspot.com/2011/05/findings-and-

observations-in-ghanas-oil.html

The report was found that on the part of Government of Ghana, that significant efforts

have been made to entrench transparency with regards to petroleum management, a fact, the

report says is further re-enforced by the extension of the Extractive Industries Transparency

Initiative (EITI) to the oil and gas sector. The passing into law of the Petroleum Revenue

Management Bill according to the report is aimed at introducing a strong and clear legal

framework for managing petroleum revenues.

The Petroleum Commission Bill has also been laid before parliament in addition; it notes

that, government is developing the Petroleum (Exploration and Production) Bill and the Local

Content Bill to be laid before parliament. The report observes that, in developing the legal

framework, government allowed citizens’ participation through public forums and consultations.

On the account of this, Ahovi (2011) noted that the civil society organizations (CSOs) in

Ghana, contributed immensely to the development of the policies and legislation for the

petroleum sector. Their input, it notes, have led to very important provisions in the legislations

such as the Public Interest and Accountability Committee; a citizen based oversight body to

monitor petroleum revenue inflows and outflows. It underscores the need for continuous capacity

building of civil society actors to hold public officers accountable. As a veritable and

formidable means of integrating as well as empowering the capacity of the civil society

organizations role of monitoring oil revenue towards effective use, the EITI produces and

distributes its validation grid which, members of the civil societies uses in reporting the

government activities in relations the oil sector as presented in the figure below.

Page 105: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

91

Fig. 6: EITI Civil Society Validation Grid

Page 106: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

92

Source: Goldwyn, D. L. (2008:173-174)

Page 107: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

93

3.6 MAXIMISING TRANSPARENCY IN THE OIL SECTOR

In order to minimise leakages and wastage of oil revenues, it is important to take steps to

maximise transparency to increase opportunities for communication and checks and balances

between government agencies, as well as to provide an oversight role for parliamentarians, civil

society organisations, journalists and the public. To reiterate the issues, monitoring state revenues

from oil production is a difficult task for citizens and civil society groups to undertake in many

countries because of the lack of basic information on contracts and revenues, the complexity of

contract terms and the complexity of recipient institution arrangements. Such oversight, though,

is ultimately to the benefit of all if leakages of revenues can be minimised and useful spending for

development maximised.

Several steps can be taken by governments to maximise transparency, and there are

examples of this practice to draw on from around the world:

Disclose contract information – Since contracts are the basis for revenue generation from the

sale of a public resource, monitoring revenues is extremely difficult without contract disclosure.

Governments do, in some cases, publish model contracts, but most often in the developing world

these contracts are modified in secret negotiations and do not sufficiently correspond to the final

agreement.

According to the IMF:

…many important elements of contract language

are subject to case-by-case adjustment.

Publication of model contracts may thus be of

limited value in defining the fiscal regime, unless

governed by clear policy statements or limitations

in legislation regarding the variability of contracts.

Publication of actual contracts will provide more

definitive information… (IMF, Draft Guide on

Resource Revenue: 23).

While companies have concerns about proprietary information – such as proprietary

technology – general arguments against contract transparency cannot be sustained. Countries as

diverse as Azerbaijan and Congo-Brazzaville have published contracts on the Web, and in São

Page 108: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

94

Tomé and Bolivia, for example, contract publication is required by law. The IMF strongly

supports publication of signed contracts:

Good practice for transparency…would require publication of all

signed contracts. An often-expressed concern with regard to open

tendering processes is that both government and companies may

lose their competitive advantage by public disclosure of winning

contracts. For reasons of commercial confidentiality, therefore,

negotiated contracts with non-disclosure clauses are the practice in

a number of countries. The reason usually advanced by

governments (and to some extent by companies) is that disclosure

would erode their bargaining power for future contracts. In

practice, however, the contract terms are likely to be widely

known within the industry soon after signing. Little by way of

strategic advantage thus seems to be lost through publication of

contracts. Indeed, it could be argued that the obligation to publish

contracts should in fact strengthen the hand of the government in

negotiations, since the obligation to disclose the outcome to the

legislature and the general public increases pressure on the

government to negotiate a good deal (IMF, Guide on Resource

Revenue Transparency, 2007: 17).

Disclose determinants of revenues – In addition to disclosing contracts, disclosing determinants

of revenues would be important. This would include production figures, sales figures for crude

oil, and information on the marketing of government profit oil, for example. Nigeria has made

important steps on disclosing this information through audits conducted under the Extractive

Industries Transparency Initiative (EITI) (http://www.eitransparency.org).

3.7 ANALYSIS OF GHANA’S PETROLEUEM REVENUE MANAGMENT ACT

(LAW)

Ghana achieved a landmark success through the enactment of its Petroleum Revenue

Management Bill in spite of the delay and highly partisan debate on the bill. The bill which

received significant contributions from civil society particularly from the Civil Society Platform

on Oil and Gas, re-iterated the country’s extension of the EITI to the new oil and gas sector, and

further demonstrates the commitment of the people to make Ghana a model of sustained

democracy founded on transparency and accountability.

The Petroleum Holding Fund

The bill outlines clear rules for petroleum revenue inflows and outflows. It provides for

the establishment of a Petroleum Holding Fund to which all petroleum receipts will be deposited,

a Stabilization Fund to account for the effects of revenue volatility through expenditure

smoothing; and a Heritage Fund to ensure intergenerational equity and create an alternative

source of income for the future. Disbursements of the Holding fund are further provided in the

bill as:

Page 109: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

95

70% of benchmark annual revenues to the budget

21% to the Ghana Stabilization Fund and

9% to the Ghana Heritage Fund

This model is close to the ‘hand-to-mouth’ rule but also has a feature of the ‘bird-in-hand’

rule when the oil fields are depleted. However, the controversies that surround the law center on

two main provisions – the establishment of the Ghana Heritage Fund and the collateralization of

petroleum revenues.

What engaged the attention of most Ghanaians is the appropriateness of the Heritage

Fund at a time the country is faced with serious developmental challenges. The question that

remains unanswered in the literature on Future Generations Funds is whether the objective is

sustainable income or sustainable impacts. That is, if petroleum revenues were invested in

projects that would have sustainable impacts on future generations, could that be said to have

achieved intergenerational equity? Whiles this question remains unanswered, most citizens in

Ghana supported the establishment of the Heritage Fund because of the emotional attachment of

Ghanaians to their future generations; and also to give meaning to the sense of preparing oneself

against the future. Then comes clause 5, the most debated and politicized of all. The original

provision prohibited collateralization of petroleum revenues. The amendment to this clause which

has been passed however provides that the annual budget funding amount can be collateralized.

Both government and supporters of the collateralization argument cited reasons such as

the security of development financing and the need to finance the annual infrastructural finance

deficit of about US$1.6 billion. However, the proponents of this view forgot one thing – the

absorptive capacity of the Ghanaian economy, which in clause 19(2) of the bill constitutes an

important determinant of the annual budget support. The failure of the economy to absorb both

the petroleum revenues and loans contracted by the government on the back of collateralized

petroleum revenues could likely harm the economy.

The fear of heavy indebtedness associated with high appetite for borrowing in resource

rich countries, the weak public financial management system in the country and the persistent

large fiscal deficits may weaken the resilience of the economy under a collateralized petroleum

revenue regime. This perhaps is why Ghana needs a long-term national development plan to

guide spending priorities, the pace of spending and to match the economy’s absorptive capacity

with resource needs

(http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=204394).

However, Ghana no doubt has laid one of the highest standards for transparency in the

management of her petroleum revenues as spelt out in the law. Some of the clauses that address

specific and broad transparency concerns are:

Page 110: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

96

1. Clause 8 requires the publication of records of petroleum receipts in the newspapers

and online.

2. Clause 16 requires the Minister of Finance to reconcile quarterly petroleum receipts

and expenditures and submit reports to Parliament as well as publish the reports in at

least two (2) national newspapers.

3. Clauses 46 to 48 provide for four different types of audits of the petroleum accounts–

internal audits, external audits, annual audits and special audits. The procurement of

the services of an independent auditor shall be in accordance with the Public

Procurement Act 2003 (Act 663).

4. Clause 50 requires the Minister of Finance to submit an annual report on the

Petroleum Account and the Ghana Petroleum Funds as part of the annual presentation

of the budget statement and economic policies to Parliament. The report shall also be

made ‘readily adaptable for dissemination to the public’ and shall contain:

(a) Audited and certified financial statements comprising;

i. the receipts and transfers to and from the Petroleum Account,

ii. the deposits and withdrawals to and from the Ghana Heritage Fund and the Ghana

Stabilization Fund, and

iii. a balance sheet, including a note listing the qualifying instruments of the Ghana

Petroleum Funds;

(b) A report signed by the Minister describing the activities of the Ghana Petroleum Funds in the

fiscal year of the report, including the advice provided by the Investment Committee, any reports

prepared by the Auditor-General drawing attention to particular issues or matters that may be of

concern or interest to Parliament;

(c) The income derived from the investment of the Ghana Heritage Fund and the Ghana

Stabilization Fund during the fiscal year compared with the income of the previous two fiscal

years;

(d) A comparison of the income in paragraph (c) with;

(i) the benchmark performance indices provided to the Minister, and

(ii) the income of the previous two fiscal years after adjusting for inflation;

(e) The liabilities of government borrowings shall be reflected in the presentation of the annual

report so as to give a true representation of the past and expected future development of the net

financial assets of government and the rate of savings; and

(f) A list of names of persons holding positions relevant for the operation and performance of the

Ghana Heritage Fund and the Ghana Stabilization Fund, including;

(i) the Minister,

Page 111: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

97

(ii) the chairperson and members of the Advisory Committee,

(iii) the Governor of the Bank of Ghana, and

(iv) the investment manager, if any.

5. Clause 51 provides that information or data, the disclosure of which could in

particular prejudice significantly the performance of the Ghana Petroleum Fund, may

be declared by the Minister as confidential, subject to the approval of Parliament. It

further requires detailed explanations on why the information should be held

confidential and that confidentiality shall not limit access to information by

Parliament and the Public Interest Accountability Committee.

6. Clause 52 criminalizes the failure by a person to comply with the obligation to

publish information under the bill.

7. Clause 53 provides for the establishment of a Public Interest and Accountability

Committee, a citizens’ based committee responsible for independent oversight of the

management of petroleum revenues as well as consulting the public on priority setting

for spending petroleum revenues.

These provisions no doubt put Ghana ahead of the requirements of the EITI, which in its

current state does not cover public expenditure transparency. Therefore, the bill provides a

stronger framework for public accountability through disclosures of public expenditures and the

regular scrutiny by the proposed Public Interest and Accountability Committee. The multiplicity

of audits of the petroleum accounts is expected to prevent abuse of the petroleum wealth and the

corruption of the institutions responsible for managing and investing petroleum funds. This is

necessary to ensure value for money in all petroleum revenue related investments, procurements

of fund managers and control of management costs (Amin, 2011).

3.8 ESTIMATED CONTRIBUTION OF OIL TO GHANA’S ECONOMY

Government revenue

Based on the fiscal regime in place, and a price assumption of US$ 75 per barrel, the

World Bank’s central estimate puts potential government revenue at US$ 1 billion on average per

year between 2011 and 2029. By way of comparison, government revenue in 2008 reached

US$3.7 billion (excluding grants) and GDP US$16.1 billion.

The oil revenue estimate is subject to a large sensitivity. A number of parameters could modify

this central estimate. Given fixed costs of extraction, higher/lower oil prices would

disproportionally affect revenue. At US$ 50 per barrel, government revenue would go down to an

average of US$ 0.4 billion per year; at US$ 100 per barrel, government revenue would conversely

go up to an average of US$ 1.6 billion per year. Besides, higher cost of extraction could also

significantly impact revenue. A 25 percent overrun in cumulated capital costs (estimated at

Page 112: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

98

US$3.4 billion over the period 2009-12) would reduce government revenue by 14 percent. A two-

year production peak (instead of a five-year peak) could also reduce government revenue to US$

0.4 billion per year (The World Bank Africa Region report, 2009).

Phase II of the Jubilee field development would be based on a higher proven reserve base

than Phase I and could be launched some two to three years after completion of Phase I. The

production rate could be double that of Phase I resulting in a peak level of gross revenues of

about US$ 7 billion over some five years from as early as 2015. No cost estimates have been

provided by the oil consortium but economies of scale and sunk appraisal costs would imply

higher pre-tax returns than for Phase I. Because of the progressive structure of the fiscal regime

for any price level, the Government share of net cash flow would be higher under Phase II than

Phase I (The World Bank Africa Region report, 2009).

With oil comes gas. Gas would be produced in association with oil at a rate of 1000 cubic

feet of gas per barrel of oil. Thus, at peak Phase 1 Jubilee production, Ghana could produce 120

million cubic feet of gas per day. Given Ghana’s non-flaring policy, Jubilee production facilities

include capacity to re-inject gas. However, plans underway to build pipelines and processing

facilities would result in streams of dry processed gas for use in power generation and natural gas

liquids (NGL) for export and domestic use. At current world market NGL prices and a dry gas

price of US$ 2 per thousand cubic feet, gross revenues would be roughly US$ 260 million per

year, that is, less than a tenth of oil gross revenue. In turn, the combination of corporate taxation

and an assumed 50 percent equity ownership for GNPC in the gas infrastructure would generate

US$ 120 million per year for the Government. To this figure could be added an implicit rent of

US$ 140 million originating from the difference between a dry gas market value of US$ 6 per

thousand cubic feet (as measured by the delivered price of gas from the West Africa Gas Pipeline,

WAGP) and that of US$ 2 reflecting the cost of extracting, transporting and processing the gas.

When all or about 80% of the expected revenue above is gained by the government of

Ghana and channeled into productive sectors of the economy with majority going to develop non-

oil sectors of the economy, a moderately sustainable long term economic development could be

achieved without ad hoc use and over-dependence on oil revenue to finance government budget

deficit, a phenomenon common with some African oil-rich countries.

In fact, gold and cocoa have been the mainstay of Ghana’s economy for more than a

century, but oil will soon surpass both of these commodities as a percentage of governments

revenue and export as indicated in the figure below:

Page 113: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

99

Fig.7: Ghana Exports, 1992-2015

Source: Moss and Young, 2009:15.

Capital flows and wealth accumulation

Partners to the oil exploration agreements commit capital mostly in relation to the share

of interest in a particular basin. The development of “Jubilee field” alone (phase I and II) is

expected to cost about US$ 6-8 billion. With the current composition of ownership interests in the

field, about 80% or more foreign capital will be invested in the country thus increasing FDI

inflows. The result however is that there is the risk of only 20% of returns on these investments

being retained in the country with 80% accruing to foreign investors. Recent agreements however

saw the proportion accruing to the state, represented by GNPC, increase marginally to about

12.50%.

According to the GNPC’s Jubilee field report, some local investors have also been given

the go-ahead to construct dedicated shore base facilities (offshore ports) to support all offshore

exploration and production operations. This will enable local investors to commit capital to such

investments with the hope of reaping returns later in the future leading to wealth accumulation.

More earning in the hands of local investors gives more room for further investments in same

sector or other sectors of the economy thereby ensuring economy-wide impact of oil related

earnings.

Fiscal

Ghana spent about US$ 1.3 billion at the end of October (only for 2009) to finance its oil

import bill. This, as we argued, has the potential of exposing the country to imported inflation in

times of price hikes in foreign oil markets. Another observation in Ghana is the disproportional

positive relationship between fuel prices and costs of goods and services. An increase of 1% in

fuel prices leads to a more than 1% increase in the prices of goods and services. This significantly

raises both the consumer (CPI) and producer (PPI) price indices thereby contributing to high

inflation rates. Ghana does not control international crude oil prices. However, the haulage and

other costs associated with the importation of crude oil could be significantly reduced with

Page 114: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

100

domestic exploration. This could (not necessarily) lead to reduced end-user prices since the

intermediaries would be able to recover costs at lower per unit prices. The effects would be lower

CPI and PPI thus providing better control over inflation rates.

Oil booms could lead to exchange rate appreciation and influence the strength of the

Ghana cedi in relation to other major foreign currencies. This has both positive and negative

effects. A positive effect could be an improvement in the country’s balance of trade and/or

balance of payment “ceteris paribus”. The appreciation could also negatively affect the

exportation of agricultural products which have been one of Ghana’s highest contributors to

export earnings.

Jobs and Infrastructural Development

The GNPC reports that there is a recruitment committee made up of GNPC and the unit

operators (Tullow in the case of Jubilee field) to recruit the staff for the operations. About 60-

70% of available places will be filled by Ghanaians. A plan is expected to be drawn up to

generally increase the Ghanaian component to about 90% in the next 5-10 years. Jobs will

provide incomes to local labour and thus improve living standards of citizens.

Takoradi, the coastal town serving as the host to some of the oil fields, has experienced

swift infrastructural developments in terms of roads to sites, office buildings, etc. Social and

economic benefits accompany infrastructural development and these are expected to have

positive impacts on the living standards of Ghanaians.

Social responsibility activities of firms operating in Ghana especially in the extractive

sector have come under strict public scrutiny because of the environmental impact of their

activities. The mining companies in Ghana have thus been actively involved in supporting

education, health, sanitation, etc especially in their local environment. Firms within the emerging

oil and gas sector are also expected to contribute their quota to social development in terms of

social responsibility activities.

Ghana has for some time been suffering from cyclical fluctuating power supply. This has

been as a result of the country’s over-reliance on the Akosombo hydro electric dam and Takoradi

thermal plant for its electricity needs. The thermal plant uses light crude or natural gas as fuel and

astronomical fuel prices significantly increase the cost of production and thus affect supply of

electricity. The production of oil and gas would mean that the plant, which is nearer to the oil

blocks in the Western region of Ghana, would receive a more consistent and cheaper supply of

crude and gas for its operations thus ensuring a more relatively sustainable power supply to

ensure regular flow to commercial (production) and domestic consumers.

According to The World Bank, recent drops in Ghana’s fiscal recurrent balance

undermines its ability to use oil revenue for financing investment. The report states that in the last

Page 115: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

101

four years, Ghana’s recurrent balance declined from 8.3 to 2.1 percent of GDP, mostly as a

consequence of increased public sector wages and energy subsidies. The promised single spine

payroll reform, pending issues related to payroll management, and the absence of cost-recovery

mechanism in the energy sector are all threatening to bring this balance further down. With a

recurrent balance at 2 percent and concessional borrowing historically at 5 percent of GDP,

Ghana with Development Partners can now finance 7 percent worth of investment expenditure,

far below the 10-11 percent needed to rapidly close its infrastructure gap.

Ghana’s reserves are relatively modest by international standards, and will thus not

radically transform Ghana’s economy into one where oil becomes the major sector. Nonetheless,

they are already large enough to deeply affect the future of the non-oil economy, positively or

negatively (The World Bank Africa Region Report on Ghana, 2009).

Fortunately, there is a sober awareness within Ghana that oil in itself will not shift the

core structure of the economy. Capturing the gas released with oil extraction, however, could

provide the necessary backbone to a sound industrial policy framework - one that will catalyse

economic diversification. Oil exports have a tendency to falsely inflate the value of a country’s

currency and so undermine the export competitiveness of other sectors (also known as ‘Dutch

Disease’). With agriculture as the primary export earner and the largest employer, the

implications of such a scenario are devastating. Thus, careful management is called for to ensure

that gas improves the yield of the agricultural sector and that economic diversification builds on

agri-business rather than undermining it.

Arising from our investigation and observation of the preparedness of Ghana towards the

effective and efficient management of its petroleum sector in addition to the proper utilization of

the oil windfall as a necessary strategy in ensuring that the country not only escapes the oil

induced conundrum of resource curse and Dutch disease but to foster transparency, good

governance and accountability; we discovered that the country had in place practical mechanisms

and institutions that are entrusted with these responsibilities in addition to the country being a

signatory to the international EITI programme that monitors and ensure transparency in the

extractive industries around the world; especially in the oil sector revenue management,

monitoring and evaluation. We also find that Ghana appears to have learnt from the mistakes of

other oil producing nations in the Gulf of Guinea, judging from the manner it has been adopting

and formulating oil production and revenue regulatory policies that are symptomatic of best

practices of governance initiatives of transparency, disclosure and accountability, which enabled

us to validate our first hypothesis.

Page 116: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

102

Our subsequent discussion will now, focus on the role of oil as driver and attractor of

Foreign Direct Investment into Ghana. Emphasis will be placed on the rate of increase on FDI

inflow into Ghana since oil discovery and its production in the country.

Page 117: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

103

CHAPTER FOUR

OIL AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN GHANA

4.1 INTRODUCTION

Crude oil can attract a lot of investments and development into a country but when not

managed well, it could cause a lot of destruction and conflict. Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)

refers to an investment made to acquire lasting interest in enterprise operating outside of the

economy of the investor (IMF, 1993). FDI is playing an increasingly vital role in the development

efforts of most developing economies. Inflows to developing countries increased from 2002 to

2008 recording $114.30 per head for 2008 whilst that of developed countries amounted to

$944.89 per head. In percentage terms, the share of developing countries increased somewhat, to

37% of global FDI inflow. Africa received its largest ever share of world FDI inflows in this

same year amounting to US$ 87.65 billion (UNTAD, 2008). Global inflows of FDI fell by 39%

from US$ 1.7 trillion in 2008 to a little over US$ 1.0 trillion in 2009 (UNCTAD, 2009).

The decline in FDI was widespread across all major groups of economies. According to

the UNCTAD Report (2009), as a result of the global financial and economic crisis, FDI flows to

developing and transition economies, which had increased in 2008, declined in 2009 to 35% and

39%, respectively.

Although Africa has succeeded in attracting some percentage of total world FDI flows,

the continent’s share still lags behind that of other developing economies. For instance, in 2008,

developing economies in Africa received about 14.12% of total FDI inflows to developing

economies worldwide compared with 23.26% for developing economies in America and 62.48%

for developing economies from Asia (UNCTAD, 2008). Even when African states do attract

Multinational Companies (MNCs), it is principally because of their (abundant) natural resources

and the size of their domestic market. According to UNCTAD (2008) figures, four natural

resource endowed countries namely Angola, Egypt, Nigeria and South Africa accounted for more

than half (61.99%) of total FDI inflows to Africa in 2008.

Until the mid 1990s, Sub-Saharan Africa (SSA) received only a small share of FDI

relative to other developing regions of the world. Nigeria and Angola have been two of the most

successful countries because of their comparative locational attraction in oil. The role of natural

resources in the location decision of Transnational Companies (TNCs) is apparent through the

sectoral allocation of FDI inflows within the region. Traditionally, about 60 per cent of FDI in

Africa is allocated to oil and natural resources (UNCTAD, 1999). The strong reliance of African

countries on their natural resources and market size as a means of attracting FDI has been well

evidenced by many studies (Pigato, 2000).

Page 118: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

104

African states have in the recent years, taken initiatives other than just relying on natural

resources and size of market to attract FDI. Initiatives such as Fiscal Incentives, Financial

Incentives, Rules-based incentives, Investment treaties and other Investment Promotion activities

such as the establishment of Investment Promotion Agencies (IPAs) to serve as a one stop centre

for investors to deal with regulatory and administrative requirements, etc all aimed at boosting the

image of the countries as well maintaining an investor friendly environment.

Ghana is no exception when it comes to the implementation of initiatives to attract FDI

into the country. FDI inflows constituted about 36% (US$ 5,755 billion) of the country’s GDP

(US$ 16,004 billion) for the 2008 fiscal year (UNCTAD report, 2009), an increase of 115 per

cent from 2002. Ghana discovered oil in 2007 and the country expects about 1 billion US dollars

as revenue from the oil and gas exploration in respect of royalties, income tax and interest

payment with an anticipated unit price of 60 US dollars a barrel per day. According to the

Ministry of Energy’s estimate, 120,000 barrels per day is expected in the first phase of the

exploration until 2015 (Anticipated Volume of Production-AVP).

A country can attract as much FDI with its natural resources, and can accumulate as much

revenue as possible from the exploration of these resources but when the revenue is not well

utilised, it becomes a curse rather than a blessing to the country (i.e. resource curse). Even in

some cases, especially in Africa, a perceived disproportionate allocation of oil wealth results in

armed conflicts. Government policies go a long way to ensure the future economic success of a

resource endowed country. This is particularly important when the resource is exhaustible (e.g.

oil, gold, etc). Appropriate government policies and the establishment of relevant institutional

structures (as in the case of Norway) could ensure the appropriate utilization of resource revenues

for a sustained economic growth. There are many fiscal policy choices available to oil-producing

countries to choose from in an attempt to make the best use of oil revenues for sustained growth.

Over the past decades, there has been a significant increase in Foreign Direct Investment

(FDI) to developing countries. The role of FDI as a source of private external finance to

developing countries has become increasingly important. This stems from the fact that income

levels (revenues) and domestic savings in these countries are very low and negligible. Therefore,

external capital is needed to supplement domestic savings so as to spur and growth development.

Again, most of these developing countries do not have access to the international capital market.

They therefore have to fall back on other sources of foreign finance like official loans from

multinational organizations such as the IMF/ World Bank, portfolio investment and FDI.

However, official lending to most developing nations especially in Sub Saharan Africa

(SSA) has considerably declined over the years (Asiedu, 2002). Foreign aid per capita declined

from an average of $35 over 1989-92 to about $28 over 1993-97 (World Bank, 2000b) and even

Page 119: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

105

further down in the 21st century. As a result of this, developing countries find it very necessary to

attract and increase their share of FDI in order to compensate for the decline in official lending

(Foreign direct investment in the developing world is on the rise, with flows excluding portfolio

investment and private bank lending) reaching $238 billion in 2005 (UNCTAD, 2002).

4.2 THE DETERMINANTS OF FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT: A

CURSORY GLIMPSE

A number of studies examine the determinants of capital flows to developing countries.

These studies tend to look first at capital flows generally and then to focus specifically on foreign

direct investment. In general, the studies divide the factors influencing capital flows into

developing countries into push and pull factors. The push factors, which are external to

developing countries, focus on growth and financial market conditions in industrial countries.

Looking at these factors, Calvo et al. (1993) concluded for emerging markets that total

flows are driven primarily by push factors, mainly growth and interest rates in industrial

countries.

Mody and Murshid (2001) found that developments within an individual developing

country tend to raise capital to that country by increasing the share of total flows allocated to that

country. These studies suggest that the push (external) factors determine the pool of funds

available to LDC, while the pull factors determine their allocation among less developed

countries (Collins, 2002).

The pull factors depend on a long list of domestic policies and characteristics of potential

host countries. Among the various indicators are:

a. Macroeconomic policy and performance (growth, the external balance, real exchange rate

over-valuation and exchange rate regime, financial market development).

b. Indicators of current and capital account openness.

c. Tax levels and existence of incentives to encourage capital inflows.

d. Measures of the quality of legal and other institutions (including corruption).

e. Conflict measures.

f. Political regime.

g. Size of domestic markets and natural resource base.

In the literature on FDI there are four main motives for seeking to invest abroad. These

are broadly described as resource seeking, market seeking, strategic asset seeking and efficiency

seeking. In the case of resource seeking, investors locate abroad in order to secure cheaper

supplies of raw materials or inputs that are not available at home. Such resources may be natural

resources like oil and gas or low-cost input such as labour. The basic reason is to lower

production costs and enhance competitiveness in both local and foreign markets. Most resource

Page 120: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

106

seeking FDIs are usually export-oriented. Market-seeking FDI opens up new markets in the host

country or neighbouring countries. The main motive is to bring about a reduction in the cost of

supplying a market. Efficiency-seeking FDI attempts to produce in as few countries as possible,

with each one having advantages in terms of location, endowment and government incentives.

Strategic-asset-seeking FDI, on the other hand, locates in a place in order to take advantages of

what is available in terms of research and development and other benefits.

What Then Are the Major Determinants of FDI in General?

There is no unanimously accepted single factor determining the flow of investment. The

literature is replete with information on the full range of factors that are likely to induce the flow

of foreign direct investment anywhere. It is often claimed that those factors that are favourable to

domestic investments are also likely to propel foreign direct investment.

These are the various factors that propel the flow of FDI into a given geographical

location, say a country or a region. In making decisions to invest abroad, firms are influenced by

a wide constellation of economic, political, geographic, social and cultural issues

(http://www.asiapacificresearch.ca/caprn/FDI_and_Economic_Growth-CEA-May_2002.pdf). It

is important to note that while the list of factors is fairly long, not all determinants are equally

important to every investor in every location at all times. It is also true that some determinants

may be more important to a given investor at a given time than to another investor.

While it is difficult to determine the exact quantity and quality of FDI determinants that

should be present in a location for it to attract a given level of inflows, it is nevertheless clear that

a critical minimum of these determinants must be present before FDI inflows begin to occur

(Ngowi, 2001). One would rationally expect that investors would choose a location in accordance

with the profitability of that location. The profitability of investment is expected to be affected by

specific factors, however, including country characteristics as well as the types of investment

motives. As pointed out by Campos and Kinoshita (2003) market-seeking investors, for example,

will be attracted to a country that has a large but fast growing market, while resource-seeking

investors will search for a country with abundant natural resources.

The factors influencing the flow of FDI thus range from the size of markets to the quality

of labour, infrastructure and institutions, to the availability of resources. These and others are

discussed below.

• A number of studies emphasize the importance of the size of the market and growth in attracting

FDI. Market size and growth have proved to be the most prominent determinants of FDI,

particularly for those FDI flows that are market seeking. In countries with large markets, the

stock of FDI is expected to be large since market size is a measure of market demand in the

Page 121: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

107

country. This is particularly true when the host country allows the exploitation of economies of

scale for import-substituting investment.

• The costs as well as the skills of labour are identified as the major attractions for FDI. The cost

of labour is important in location considerations, especially when investment is export oriented

(see Wheeler and Mody, 1992; Mody and Srinivasan, 1998). Lower labour cost reduces the cost

of production, all other factors remaining unchanged. Sometimes, the availability of cheap labour

justifies the relocation of a part of the production process in foreign countries. Recent studies,

however, have shown that with FDI moving towards technologically intensive activities, low cost

unskilled labour is not in vogue. Rather, there is demand for qualified human capital (Pigato,

2001). Thus, the investing firm is also concerned about the quality of the labour force. It is

generally believed that highly educated personnel are able to learn and adopt new technology

faster, and the cost of retraining is also less. As a result of the need for high quality labour,

investors are most likely to target countries where the government maintains a liberal policy on

the employment of expatriate staff. This is to enable investors to bring in foreigners to their

operation in order to bridge the gap in the skill of local personnel wherever it exists.

• That the availability of good infrastructure as crucial for attracting FDI is well documented in

the literature, regardless of the type of FDI. It is often stated that good infrastructure increases the

productivity of investment and therefore stimulates FDI flows (Asiedu, 2002).

A study by Wheeler and Mody (1992) found infrastructure to be very important and

dominant for developing countries. In talking about infrastructure, it should be noted that this is

not limited to roads alone, but includes telecommunications. Availability and efficiency of

telephones, for example, is necessary to facilitate communication between the host and home

countries. In addition to physical infrastructure, financial infrastructure is important for FDI

inflow. A well-developed financial market is known from available evidence to enable a country

to tap the full benefits of FDI. Alfaro et al. (2001), using cross-section data, find that poorly

developed financial infrastructure can adversely affect an economy’s ability to take advantage of

the potential benefits of FDI.

• Country risk is very important to FDI. Several studies have found FDI in developing countries

to be affected negatively by economic and political uncertainty. There is abundant evidence to

show the negative relationship between FDI and political and economic stability.

In a study on foreign owned firms in Africa, Sachs and Sievers (1998) conclude that the

greatest concern is political and macroeconomic stability, while Lehman (1999) and Jaspersen et

al. (2000) find that countries that are less risky attract more FDI. Perception of risk in Africa is

still very high and continues to hinder foreign direct investment.

Page 122: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

108

• Openness of an economy is also known to foster the inflows of FDI. The more open an

economy is, the more likely it is that it would follow appropriate trade and exchange rate regimes

and the more it would attract FDI.

• The institutional environment is an important factor because it directly affects business

operations. In this category is a wide array of factors that can promote or deter investment.

The first of these is the existence of corruption and bribery. Corruption deters the inflow of FDI

because it is an additional cost and because wherever it exists, it creates uncertainty, which

inhibits the flow of FDI. The second is the level of bureaucracy involved in establishing a

business in a country. Complex and time-consuming procedures deter investment. The third

institutional factor is the existence of incentives in the form of fiscal and financial attractions.

This last factor is only useful to the extent that other favourable factors are already in place.

Fourth, there is also the institution of the judiciary, which is key to protecting property rights and

law enforcement regulations. A frequent measure of this is the rule of law, which is a composite

of three indicators (Campos and Kinoshita, 2003): sound political institutions and a strong court

system; fairness of the judicial system; and the substance of the law itself. It is expected that

countries with better legal infrastructure will be able to attract more FDI. Related here is the

enforceability of contracts: The lack of enforceability in many African countries raises risk of

capital loss and hinders FDI.

• The availability of natural resources is a critical factor in attracting FDI. This is particularly so

in Africa where a large share of FDI has been in countries with abundant natural resources.

In some cases, the abundance of natural resources has been combined with a large

domestic market. African countries that have been able to attract most FDI have been those with

natural and mineral resources as well as large domestic markets. Traditionally about 60% of

Africa’s FDI is allocated to oil and natural resources (UNCTAD, 1999a/b). The Africa region

possesses not only large reserves of oil, gold, diamonds and copper, but also more than half of the

world’s cobalt and manganese, one-third of bauxite, and more than 80% of chromium and

platinum. A number of countries, including Angola, Nigeria, Côte d’Ivoire, Botswana and

Namibia, have been host to FDI because of this advantage.

• Foreign investors may be attracted to countries with an existing concentration of other foreign

investors. In this case, the investment decision by others is seen as a good signal of favourable

conditions. The term “agglomeration economies” is often applied to this situation (Campos and

Kinoshita, 2003). The clustering of investors leads to positive externalities.

Three types of such externalities have been identified in the literature. The first is that

technological spillovers can be shared among foreign investors. Second, they can draw on a

shared pool of skilled labour and specialized input suppliers. Third, users and suppliers of inputs

Page 123: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

109

cluster near each other because of the greater demand for a good and the supply of inputs, which

is provided by the large market.

• Return of investment is another major determinant of FDI flows. In general, FDI will go to

countries that pay a higher return on capital. For developing countries, testing the rate of return

on capital is difficult because most developing countries do not have a well functioning capital

market (Asiedu, 2002). What is often done is to use the inverse of real GDP per capita to measure

the return on capital. The implication of this is that all things being equal, investments in

countries with higher per capita income should yield lower return and therefore real GDP per

capita should be inversely related to FDI (Asiedu, 2002).

The empirical result of the relationship between real GDP per capita and FDI is mixed. In

works by Edwards (1990) and Jaspersen et al. (2000), using the inverse of income per capita as

proxy for the return on capital, they conclude that real GDP per capita and FDI/GDP are

negatively related. Results of studies by Schneider and Frey (1985) and Tsai (1994) are different

as they find a positive relationship between the two variables. This is based on the argument that

a higher GDP per capita implies better prospects for FDI in the host country.

• Macroeconomic and other policies also play a role. Macroeconomic policy errors resulting in

exchange rate misalignment and the lack of convertible currencies constrain FDI flows.

In cases where policies are not sustainable, FDI flows are hindered. A look at Africa

reveals compelling evidence that FDI may have been attracted by one or more of the following

four categories of considerations (Basu and Srinivasan, 2002):

• Investment that is intensive in natural resources: Given the abundance of natural resources in

Africa, a large share – almost 40% – has been in the primary sector. For a number of countries,

including Angola, Botswana, Namibia and Nigeria, the oil and mineral sectors have been

targeted.

• Investment driven by “specific” locational advantages: During the apartheid era, a number of

investors wishing to capture the large market in South Africa located in Lesotho and Swaziland.

These countries therefore at that time benefited from inflows of FDI.

• Investment driven by host country policies that actively target foreign investment: A few

countries have tailored their policies to target foreign direct investment by ensuring political and

economic stability. Such policies provided specific tax incentives and created export-processing

zones. These countries include Mauritius and Seychelles.

• Investment in response to recent economic and structural reforms: A few countries that were

shunned by investors in the past are now the darlings of investors in response to the far-reaching

economic and structural reforms. Uganda and Mozambique, whose economic reforms have been

fairly successful, have attracted FDI inflows.

Page 124: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

110

4.3 FACTORS THAT DETERMINES FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT IN

GHANA

A study by Tsikata, Asante and Gyasi (2000) showed that the following factors were

significant determinants of FDI to Ghana; trade regime, democratic governance, investment

climate, economic uncertainty and raw material availability (because the mining sector is over

dependent). The relative influence of the various determinants of FDI will also vary with the type

of FDI.

Ghana, being a small developing African country, has attracted the non-market seeking

type of FDI. The major categories of FDI attracted into Ghana have been lured by natural

resources and active promotional campaigns, plus structural reforms and privatizations.

Investments to Exploit Natural Resources

The mining sector, mainly gold, has become almost synonymous with FDI in Ghana, but

it had gradually deteriorated prior to the Economic Recovery Programme (ERP). The several

reasons identified for this include shortages of foreign exchange to maintain and rehabilitate the

mines; lack of capital investments for exploration and development; poor management and lack

of mining skills; infrastructure deterioration, particularly shortage of rail capacity for manganese

and bauxite; mining company financial problems due to the over-valued currency and spiraling

inflation; a declining grade of gold ore; and smuggling of gold and diamonds (Tsikata et al.,

2000). FDI could therefore have played a major role in arresting several of the problems

identified, especially the dual problems of foreign exchange strangulation and shortage of the

requisite mining expertise. For example, in the gold mining industry, long distances had to be

travelled underground to reach work sites due to lack of investment in existing and new shafts.

But it was the fiscal policy regime that imposed the severest strain on the development of

investment flow to the sector, in particular the gold mining subsector. Three main fiscal changes

affecting the sector were implemented during the ERP era: reduction in minimum royalties from

6% to 3%; reduction in corporate tax from 55% to 35%; and tax exemption for imported plant

and equipment. The privatization of AGC by the government was also presumably aimed at

sending signals that it was prepared to encourage the participation of the private (including

foreign) sector. There is no doubt that policies and funding under the ERP have enabled a strong

upturn in the mining sector.

Investments Resulting from Ghana’s Active Policies to attract FDI

A number of measures have been taken to improve the investment climate. These include

investment incentives spelled out in a range of investment codes. The first was the Pioneer and

Companies Act of 1959. This was followed by the Capital Investment Act of 1963 (Act 172),

which sought to encourage foreign investment. The 1973 Investment Decree (NRCD 141) and

Page 125: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

111

Investment Policy Decree NRCD 329 of 1975, unlike the 1963 Act, was to encourage both local

and foreign investors. The 1981 Investment Code (Act 437) sought to centralize investment

promotion functions at the Capital Investment Board and consolidate all investment legislation.

The 1985 Investment Code (PNDCL 116) established the Ghana Investment Centre as the

Central Investment Promotion Agency. All these investment codes attempted to provide a

favourable investment climate by offering incentives to boost private investment. The incentives

generally provided included tax holidays, accelerated depreciation allowances, exemption for

import duties on machinery and equipment, investment allowances, and arrangements for profit

repatriation. The need for constant review of the codes reflects the lack of the expected response

to the various codes. Inflows remained sluggish, averaging US$4 million per annum between

1983 and 1988.

Other measures taken in recent years to improve the investment climate include gradual

removal of administrative and other bottlenecks and review of the tax structure as it relates to

private investment, e.g., reduction of corporate tax to 45% maximum (1991) from 55%

previously, for some enterprises. Retention accounts (and foreign accounts) were established for

individual companies for retention of a portion of revenues earned from exports to finance

imports of essential spare parts and raw materials or machinery, while credit expansion in 1987

and 1988 aimed to ensure adequate financial support for the priority sectors of the economy.

Finally, a major step was the liberalization of the financial system. On 29 April 1988,

Ghana ratified the convention establishing the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency

(MIGA) of the World Bank. MIGA intends to encourage equity investment and other forms of

foreign direct investment (FDI) in developing countries by reducing noncommercial risk. In

effect, the MIGA Convention seeks to provide an insurance cover for foreign investors who

participate in eligible investments in the productive sectors of the economy of developing

countries. Despite the assurance of Ghana’s investment guarantee under the Investment Code and

the MIGA Convention, some countries still insist on bilateral investment promotion and

protection agreements (IPPAs) with Ghana. Thus, the government has entered into bilateral

IPPAs with a number of countries to further enhance the protection and security of the investment

regime. (see Ghana Investments Centre, 1991). Ghana has also expanded the scope for FDI by

reducing the number of industries closed to foreign investors.

The Ghana Investments Promotion Centre (GIPC) was set up under the GIPC Act of 1994

with the main objective of encouraging and promoting investment. The Act revised and

consolidated the 1985 Investment Code to place more emphasis on private sector investments as

an important element of accelerated economic growth. According to the Act, the existing code

was oriented towards regulation and did not encourage the investment centre to engage in

Page 126: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

112

promotional activities. Also, the attitude of government has changed over time with a more

favourable climate now than in the early 1980s. As part of the measures taken to make credit

more readily available to the private sector, Ghana began a process of liberalizing its financial

system. Specifically, a financial sector adjustment programme (FINSAP), was initiated and a

number of institutional and policy reforms were carried out that culminated in the liberalization

of the financial sector by the beginning of 1989. The response was a moderate inflow between

1989 and 1992 and a significant inflow between 1993 and 1996 – with the inflow reaching

US$233 million in 1994 when the GIPC was set up and the Government put Ashanti Goldfields

(AGC) on the market (partial sale of AGC to the South African mining company, Lonmin).

The Free Zones Scheme and FDI Flows

In September 1995, the Ghanaian Parliament promulgated the Free Zones Act in order to

accelerate the exploitation of the country’s general export potential. The Ghana Free Zones Board

(GFZB) was accordingly established to assist and monitor the activities of export processing

zones (EPZs) to be set up in the country. EPZs provide buildings and services for manufacturing,

i.e., transformation of imported raw and intermediate materials into finished product, usually for

export but sometimes partly for domestic sale subject to the normal duty. The EPZ is thus a

specialized industrial estate located physically and/or administratively outside the customs

barrier, oriented to export production. Its facilities serve as a showcase to attract investors, and as

a convenience for their getting established, and are usually associated with other incentives.

A key objective of the Act was the attraction of FDI. To this end, an extensive package of

incentives was offered, including the following:

• Exemption of free zone developers from income or profit tax for 10 years;

• Income tax after ten-year tax holiday, not to exceed a maximum of 8%;

• Exemption from withholding taxes on dividends emanating from free zone investments;

• Freedom for a foreign investor to hold a 100% share in any free zone enterprise; and

• Various guarantees in respect of repatriation of profits and against unreasonable nationalization

of assets.

Since 1995, the non-traditional exports (NTEs) have increased from US$159.7 million in

1995 to US$417.5 million in 2001. This could be partly attributable to establishment of the EPZs.

Given the importance of increasing market size and providing scale to attract FDI to Africa,

efforts at regional integration continue to be important. The New Partnership for Africa’s

Development (NEPAD) could be important in this direction. Since the new government assumed

power in 2001, Ghana has set up a Ministry for Regional Integration and NEPAD.

Page 127: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

113

4.4 GHANA’S POLICY ENVIRONMENT FOR FDI

Ghana began courting FDI long before it moved towards a market economy. As far back

as 1963 the importance of FDI was recognized, as demonstrated by the Capital Investment Act of

1963. However the wide range of fiscal and other concessions offered to potential foreign

investors was accompanied by various conditions that served as deterrents to investment.

Subsequent revisions to the investment code have substantially improved the climate for foreign

investment. Attracting FDI remains a key objective of Ghana’s economic recovery programme,

which started in 1983 under the auspices of the World Bank and the IMF. The Ghana Investment

Promotion Centre Act of 1994 set up the GIPC as a promotional agency providing a wide range

of investment incentives. In addition to these incentives, ongoing privatization of State owned

enterprises provide profitable investment opportunities. A number of other policy developments,

such as those relating to SMEs, international trade, the exchange rate and infrastructure linkages

with other West African countries, have also favourably influenced the environment for FDI in

the country.

1. FDI Policies

Responsibility for investments in various sectors has been divided up among different

agencies of the Government of Ghana. The five main agencies are the Minerals Commission and

the Ghana National Petroleum Corporation for investments in the mining and petroleum sectors,

respectively; the Divestiture Implementation Committee for investments in companies sold by the

Government; the Ghana Free Zones Board (GFZB), for investments exporting 70 per cent or

more of their products, and the GIPC, which deals with all other investments. All these

institutions offer generous incentives to prospective investors.

(a) The Ghana Investment Promotion Centre Act

Under the GIPC Act 1994 investors are entitled to tax holidays, accelerated depreciation

allowances, exemptions from import duties on machinery and equipment, investment allowances

and remittance of dividends. Tax holidays of up to five years are applicable for investments in

general farming, fisheries, aquaculture, livestock and real estate, and up to 10 years for rural

banking and cattle ranching. Firms exporting non-traditional exports are entitled to a reduced tax

rate of 8 per cent, and licensed hotels to a reduced tax rate of 25 per cent. Besides the import-duty

exemptions on machinery and equipment, the GIPC is empowered to grant additional incentives

or special investments, with approval from the President.

The GIPC Act accords national treatment to foreign investors and reserves only a few

activities for Ghanaians, such as petty trading, operation of taxi-fleet services of less than 10,

pool betting, lotteries, beauty salons and barber shops. Furthermore, Ghana does not impose

performance and local content requirements on foreign investors.

Page 128: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

114

Last, but not least, foreign investors with paid-up capital of $10,000 but less than

$100,000 or its equivalent in cedis, shall be entitled to an initial automatic maximum immigrant

quota of one person.

With the creation of the GIPC, the Government of Ghana has greatly eased the

administrative requirements for foreign investments and facilitated processes for investors.

Registering with the GIPC takes a maximum of five days, is inexpensive, and offers companies

registered with it exemption from an approval process. There is little doubt that the GIPC is a

serious and dedicated promotion agency. Even though the Government has not spelt out specific

policies in the Act for Asian FDI, encouraging these investors to take advantage of Ghana’s

investment incentives seems to be high on the agenda of its promotional activities.

(b) Incentives in the minerals sector

Similarly, generous incentives are offered to FDI in the minerals sector via the Minerals

and Mining Law of 1986 and the Amendment of the 1994 Act 475. These seek to provide a more

conducive environment for private investment in the mining sector. Ghana has abundant mineral

resources, including gold, bauxite, manganese, diamonds and limestone, which are governed by

the Mining and Minerals Act. Incentives provided under the revised Minerals Act include a

reduction in the minimum royalties payable and in the corporate tax (from 55 per cent to 35 per

cent), as well as tax exemptions for imported plant and equipment. Companies are allowed to

capitalize all expenditures during the reconnaissance, prospecting and development stages. Since

reforms, the mining sector has been rejuvenated, with gold exports currently overtaking cocoa as

Ghana’s leading export earner. The inflow of private investment through these improved

incentives has undoubtedly played a role.

(c) Ghana Free Zones Programme

One of the key initiatives to attract FDI into non-traditional exports (i.e. excluding

minerals, cocoa and timber) has been the promulgation of the Free Zones Act in September 1995.

The Act offers even more generous incentives than the GIPC Act, 1994. The incentives package

includes exemptions for free zone developers from revenue or profit tax for 10 years, income tax

after the 10-year holiday is not to exceed 8 per cent, and there is an exemption from withholding

tax on dividends.

Under the Free Zones Act, investors are spared various bureaucratic restrictions and other

statutory requirements. There is an expedited investment approval process (not exceeding 28

days), unimpeded issue of expatriate work and residence permits, and accelerated on-site customs

inspection. Furthermore, a policy of free ports and open skies is in place to further reduce

bureaucratic impediments. The Gateway Project complements the Free Zones Programme as it

seeks to improve upon Ghana’s infrastructure facilities at the ports,

Page 129: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

115

With a view to making Ghana the trading hub for West Africa. The Free Zones

Programme adopts an innovative approach through the establishment of enclaves and single

factory zones. This enables access to a vast array of resources around the country as well as

providing focused enclaves, within which firms can benefit from agglomeration economies.

(d) Investment guarantees

Guarantees against expropriation and nationalization are enshrined in the provisions of

Ghana’s constitution and investment legislation. Ghana has also ratified the convention

establishing the Multilateral Investment Guarantee Agency (MIGA) of the World Bank, which

reduces noncommercial risks of FDI in developing countries.

The State may only acquire an enterprise if it is in the national interest for a public

purpose, on payment of fair and adequate compensation. Disputes are to be resolved by reference

to the rules of arbitration of the United Nations Commission on International Trade Law or,

where relevant, to bilateral investment agreements. Asian countries with which Ghana currently

has bilateral agreements are China, India and Malaysia.

2. Other related policies

(a) Privatization

An important component of Ghana’s economic reforms has been the divestiture of State

owned enterprises, which commenced in 1988. The privatization programme has resulted in the

sale of more than 300 of approximately 350 State-owned enterprises.40 It has been carried out

through sales of shares, joint ventures, leases, sales of assets and liquidations. Major divestitures

have included selling government shares in the Ashanti Goldfields ($462 million), various State-

owned banks ($65.2 million), and Ghana Telecom ($38 million) which was purchased by

Malaysian investors.

The privatization timetable until 2003 included four wholly-owned large and strategic

enterprises and several medium-sized enterprises. The divestiture process is open to foreign

investors, and deferred payments for up to three years may be negotiated. The Divestiture

Implementation Committee cites several success stories, including West African Mills and

GAFCO, but there have also been some failures such as Ghana Telecom.

(b) Small and medium-sized Enterprises

Currently, there is no comprehensive policy on SMEs in Ghana. However, over the years

various Governments have initiated projects to support the SME sector, recognizing it as an

important employer and producer in the domestic economy. There has thus been both financial

support – via the recently terminated Businesses Assistance Fund – and through various training

programmes organized by government and quasigovernment institutions, such as the National

Board for Small Scale Industries and EMPRETEC Ghana.

Page 130: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

116

The most recent initiative, implemented by the Export Development and Investment

Fund, seeks to encourage the SME sector to venture into exports. Specifically, the Ghana

Investment Fund was established to help finance small and medium scale agro-processing and

export-oriented companies in Ghana.41 Since these initiatives are non-discriminatory, both

indigenous and foreign SMEs can access these funds, including Asian SMEs investing in Ghana.

(c) Trade policy

Liberalization of the trade regime has been pursued through substitution of quantitative

instruments with price instruments, increased transparency and a gradual reduction of import

tariff rates. Thus by 1989, the import-quota system had been abolished, and by 2000, tariff levels

had fallen to 0, 5, 10 and 20 per cent from their 1982 levels of 35, 60 and 100 per cent. The

simple average tariff rate has been levied at 14.7 per cent since February 2000, reduced from over

30 per cent.

It is noteworthy that companies in the free trade zones enjoy a ten-year tax holiday and a

zero duty on imports (United States, Department of State, 2006). Ghana’s liberalized trade regime

thus affords opportunities for both existing and potential investors, including Asian investors, to

access essential materials at competitive prices. These benefits are even greater for firms

registered in the EPZs, since they are exempt from duty and enjoy various tax breaks.

Ghana is party to several multilateral and regional institutions and agreements on

international trade. These include the WTO, the Cotonou Agreement and ECOWAS. Bilateral

agreements also exist with the Czech Republic, Egypt, Malaysia, South Africa, Trinidad and

Tobago, Turkey and the United States, among others. The current focus of trade policy is

continued liberalization of the trade regime, and, more importantly, a higher degree of economic

integration within the West African sub-region. To this end, there is a Ghana/Nigeria fast-track

approach to sub-regional economic integration, which offers market opportunities in both

countries and in others in the sub-region. By intensifying efforts towards sub-regional integration,

Ghana hopes to become the gateway for Asian investors interested in accessing the West African

market.

(d) Exchange rate policy

The ostensible objectives of exchange rate policy reforms in Ghana have been to increase

the overall availability of foreign exchange and to improve foreign exchange allocation

mechanisms.

This has been pursued through gradual liberalization of the foreign exchange market,

from a system of export bonuses financed by import surcharges and systematic quarterly

devaluations in the early 1980s, to the current free-floating exchange rate regime with the

operation of foreign exchange bureaus and the inter-bank market. These policies have enabled the

Page 131: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

117

Ghanaian currency, the cedi, to depreciate in value from 30 cedis per dollar in 1983 to 9,073

cedis per dollar in 2005.

While there are concerns about its rate of depreciation and the impact this has on

macroeconomic stability, the current administration is committed to a floating exchange rate as

well as preventing nominal depreciation that induces macro-instability. These objectives are

being pursued through continued adoption of a flexible exchange rate regime and a tight fiscal

and monetary policy stance. Increased liberalization of the exchange rate regime within a stable

macroeconomic environment offers Asian investors attractive possibilities to establish export-

oriented units of production in Ghana. All the more so since Ghana’s liberalized regime enables

its exports to be more competitive on world markets, barring other domestic capacity and external

market access constraints.

4.5 FDI AND ITS RELATIONSHIP WITH NATURAL RESOURCES (OIL)

Countries that can offer a large domestic market and/or natural resources have inevitably

attracted foreign investors in Africa. South Africa, Nigeria, Ivory Cost, and Angola have been

traditionally the main recipients of FDI within the region (Morisset, 2000). For instance, Chevron

Texaco, a California based oil and natural gas company, has invested about US$ 4 billion in

Angolan development projects as at 2008 (mBendi).

Over the years, Nigeria and Angola have been two of the most successful countries

receiving FDI because of their comparative locational attraction in oil despite their unstable

political and economic environments. The 1999 World Development Report of the World Bank

ranked Angola as fourth among African countries with the highest average FDI inflows for the

years 1996 and 1997. In 2008, as per UNCTAD records, Angola is the second largest recipient of

FDI inflow in Africa. On average, resource endowed countries in Africa ceteris paribus have

attracted more FDI inflows than their counterparts with less natural resources. The table below

samples the distribution of FDI flows among abundant natural resource-endowed and less

resource endowed countries in Africa.

Empirical evidence of distribution of investments (in different provinces) in Angola as

reported by Banco de Desenvolvimento de Angola’s, Boletim de Conjuntura, (2009) shows that

on average, provinces near the oil blocks register higher rates of investment than other provinces.

Luanda, which doubles as the capital as well as a province with vibrant oil activities such as oil

refinery etc recorded about US$ 10.59 million investments with more than 50% accruing to the

oil and gas sector.

Dunning (1981) argues that natural resources and market size are components in the

locational attraction that attract FDI into a country. Our sample of eight countries, four well-

endowed in natural resources (e.g. oil, gold, etc) and four less-endowed in natural resources

Page 132: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

118

reveals that average FDI inflows per head to the four resource endowed countries amounted to

US$ 193.83 in 2008 compared with that of less resource-endowed countries at US$ 4.67 per

head. The same disparity in the distribution of FDI inflow can be observed for the entire periods

under consideration. In fact, the growth in FDI distribution per head grew on average by about

1,117% for the four resource-endowed countries and by only 2.41% for the four less-resource

endowed countries from 2000 to 2008. It was also realised that among the four resource endowed

countries, the countries with oil wealth (Nigeria and Angola) on average recorded higher FDI

inflows than those without oil (Ghana and South Africa. Note: Ghana classified under countries

without oil in this context because it is yet to start oil production by the time the study was

conducted).

Although both groups of countries have recorded growth in FDI inflows per head, the gap

between resource-endowed and less resource-endowed countries widened with the former

experiencing growth about 463 times more than the latter. The distribution among only resource-

endowed countries does not represent a normal distribution either. In 2008, Angola recorded the

highest inflow per head at US$ 862.77 with US$ 181.38, US$ 134.11 and US$ 90.79 accruing to

South Africa, Nigeria and Ghana respectively.

Table4: Distribution of FDI inflows among selected (well and less natural resource endowed)

African Countries in billion US$

Page 133: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

119

Another trend that could be realised from the inflow figures is the level of influence that

the two components within Dunning’s locational attraction factor (i.e. natural resources and

market size) have on the distribution of FDI inflows among the two groups of countries. From our

observations, a more positive relationship could be established between natural resources and FDI

inflows than between market size and FDI inflow. The more natural resources available in a

country, the more FDI it is able to attract “ceteris paribus”. A comparison among resource-

endowed as well as between resource-endowed and less resource-endowed countries with varying

population sizes confirms this assertion. Among the four resource-endowed countries, Angola

recorded higher inflows relatively per head throughout the observed period. In 2008 for instance,

Nigeria with a population 8.39 times more than Angola received FDI inflows only 1.30 times

more than Angola. Ghana and South Africa, all with populations more than Angola and with

relatively stable economic and political environments received lower shares of FDI inflows for

the observed period.

The same trend can be observed between Kenya (less resource-endowed) and Angola

(resource-endowed). Kenya’s population in 2008 was about double that of Angola but the country

attracted FDI inflows 161.96 times less than Angola did for the same year. Similar trends can be

observed during the entire period under observation. Our observation does not attempt to

establish causality because a host of other factors such as political and economic environment,

among others, all play a role in attracting FDI.

It must also be noted that although market size is a subset of a country’s population, other

factors such as purchasing power, determined by factors such as income levels, inflation and

interest rates among others are the actual determinants of market size. A country with a large

population size but with low income levels (e.g. Kenya) might provide a smaller market size for

products than another with small population size but with higher income levels (e.g. Sweden).

4.6 APPLYING FINDINGS IN CASE STUDIES TO GHANA FDI

Evidence emanating from the link between natural resources and FDI and FDI literature

(e.g. Morisset, 2000) suggest that in Africa, countries with abundant natural resources attract

more FDI than those with fewer natural resources. Ghana already possesses a lot of natural

wealth which have served as bait for foreign investments. Watts, (2006) states that U.S. oil

companies alone have invested more than $40 billion in Africa over the last decade (with another

$30 billion expected between 2005 and 2010). Oil investment now represents over 50 percent of

all foreign direct investment (FDI) in the continent (and over 60 percent of all FDI in the top four

FDI recipient countries), and almost 90 percent of all cross-border mergers and acquisition

activity since 2003 has been in the mining and petroleum sector.

Page 134: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

120

With the oil discovery and exploration, FDI is expected to rise in the oil and gas industry

and other related sectors of Ghana’s economy. For instance, two multi-national oil field service

providers namely Africa Oilfields Service Limited (AOS) and Orwell International (Oil & Gas)

Limited, have committed US$ 5 million worth of equipment to Ghana’s oil and gas industry. The

two corporate entities plan to grow the investment to US$ 15 million, subject to demand

expansion in Ghana.

Ghana’s oil potential is relatively small. Analysts have quoted varying oil reserves in

Ghana ranging from 1.8 to 5 billion barrels. Putting Ghana’s estimated reserve at an average of

2.5 billion barrels, the benefits accruing to Ghana in terms of FDI inflows and economic

development will be 3.6 times less than that accruing to Angola ceteris paribus. What this means

is that, if US$ 3.6 is invested in Angola as a result of its oil wealth, only US$ 1 worth of

investment will accrue to Ghana in that regard. The implication is this;

If quantity of oil reserves would be a major determinant of the amount of FDI inflows to

the oil sector, a 50% or so would mean that, about 14% of all FDI inflows in Ghana would accrue

to the oil sector. This would mean that the current average growth of 130% in FDI from 2000 to

2008 (as per UNTAD records) is expected to increase to about 144% for the coming years as a

result of the extra 14% oil led investments expected.

Ghana’s positions on the IFC and The World Bank’s “ease of doing business rankings”

from 2006 to 2010 are 102nd, 94th, 87th, 87th and 92nd respectively. A simple interpretation of

the trend observed in these rankings is that it is relatively easier to do business in Ghana in 2010

than in 2006. This may be as a result of Ghana improving its business environment compared

with other countries or as a result of business environments in other countries getting worse.

Ghana’s rankings have been consistently lower than that of most other Sub-Saharan African

countries for the same period. This means that it is relatively easier to conduct business in Ghana.

It is therefore expected that more FDI flows will be received by Ghana “ceteris paribus” as a

result of the oil exploration.

Accra and Tema have traditionally been the recipients of most FDIs in Ghana because

Accra is the capital city and Tema is an industrial city and also hosts one of the country’s two

major habours. This trend is however expected to change in favour of the towns near the oil

blocks. The twin cities of the Western region of Ghana, Sekondi and Takoradi, are the nearest

cities to most of the oil blocks and are thus expected to play host to a lot of oil related

investments. Accra on the other hand is the commercial and administrative nerve centre of Ghana

and is also expected to benefit directly and indirectly from oil led FDI inflows.

Page 135: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

121

TRENDS IN FDI FLOWS TO GHANA

Since the 1970s, Ghana has had a long, though modest, history of FDI. In the 1970s, FDI

was mainly in import-substitution manufacturing. In 1970, annual inflows were as high as US$68

million but declined to US$11.5 million in 1972. The decline in 1972 was probably due to the

negative economic growth rate of 2.1% in 1972 from a positive growth rate of 5.6% in 1971. FDI

increased from then to US$71 million in 1975 only to sink to -US$18.3 million in 1976 (a decline

of 125.8%). This decline followed the world FDI downturn of 21% (UNCTAD, 2003). An

important feature of FDI is the three-way nexus of economic growth, investment and political

stability that has emerged since 1972.

Fig.8: FDI Inflow into Ghana

In 1979, when Rawlings first seized power and adopted a radical and anti-business stance,

economic growth fell to -3.2% and there was an FDI outflow of US$2.8 million. Since the advent

of the Economic Recovery Programme (ERP) in 1983, four phases of FDI flows can be

distinguished:

• 1983–1988 was a period of sluggish inflows, averaging US$4 million per annum, the highest

and lowest inflows being US$5.6 million in 1985 and US$2 million in 1984, respectively.

• 1989–1992 recorded moderate inflows averaging US$18 million per annum, the highest and

lowest being US$22.5 million in 1992 and US$14.8 million in 1990, respectively.

• 1993–1996 was a period of significant (remaining in three digits) inflows, which reached

US$233 million in 1994 (with the privatization of Ashanti Goldfields Company – AGC), but slid

to US$106.5 million in 1995 before coming back to US$120 million in 1996.

• 1997–2003 saw flows oscillating, decreasing from US$82 million in 1997 to US$56 million in

1998 (the lowest over the 1993–2003 period), then peaking at US$267 million in 1999 before

Page 136: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

122

falling to US$115 million the following year. FDI dropped further to US$89 million and US$50

million, respectively, in 2001 and 2002 owing to the effect of the September 2001 attack on the

United States (and the consequent global FDI drop of 41% in 2001 and 21% in 2002; UNCTAD,

2003). In 2003, the FDI recovery to US$137 million was due to a massive boost in FDI with the

merger of Ashanti Goldfields and Anglogold and the beginning of a US$400 million gold mine

investment by the US firm, Newmont (ISSER, 2004).

The growth remained positive throughout the rest of the period (i.e. 2003-2008) with the

highest annual growth of about 338.62% in 2006 compared with 2005. Ghana received its highest

FDI inflow in 2008 with US$ 2.120 billion and received its lowest flow in 2002 with US$ 59

million. From 2000 to 2008, Ghana’s share of total world FDI inflow remained inconsistent. The

figure below presents a graphical representation of Ghana’s share of total world FDI and FDI as a

percentage of GDP.

Fig.9: Ghana’s FDI inflow as percentage of GDP and total world FDI inflow

Source: Dah, K. F. and Khadijah, M. S. (2010:47)

4.7 OIL AND FOREIGN DIRECT INVESTMENT INFLOW INTO GHANA

Ever since oil was discovered in Ghana in June 2007, there has been a steady and

consistent increase in the inflow of foreign capital and investments injections into the economy of

the nations, especially since oil production started during December 2010. In fact, according to

Quandzie (2010:1) Foreign Direct Investments (FDIs) into Africa as at the end of 2010 stood at

$32 billion. While the World Bank, asserts that inflows of FDIs into the continent increased by

6% from 2008 due to price increases of commodities such as metal, oil and mineral exports. It is

in response to this that Okonjo-Iweala, Managing Director, World Bank said in a speech she

delivered at the MIT-Sloan School Africa Business Conference, in the US recently stated that:

Page 137: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

123

The external drivers of growth in 2010 included increased

commodity prices — particularly for metal, mineral and oil

exporters; increased inflows of foreign direct investment – the

region (Africa) attracted $32billion in FDI in 2010, a 6

percent increase from 2008

For Ghana, it was recorded that the inflows of FDIs as at early December 2010, at a time

the country was gearing up for the commencement of its oil production in the middle of the

month; were estimated at over $1.3 billion of which the oil sector accounted for a significant

portion of $550 million, reported the Bank of Ghana at its Monetary Policy Committee (MPC)

meeting on December 10, 2010 (http://ghanaoilonline.org/2011/04/fdis-into-africa-rise-32b-on-

oil-metals-exports-%E2%80%93-world-bank/).

Moreover, the Ghana Investment Promotion Centre (GIPC), reported that Foreign Direct

Investment (FDI) into Ghana in the first quarter of 2011 grew by over 100% compared to what it

was in 2010 (Quartey, 2011:1).

On average, Ghana’s Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) increased considerably by

approximately 70 percent annually between 2009 and 2010. For the first quarter of 2011, the

Centre, which coordinates and monitors investment activities in the west African country,

registered a total of 109 projects with an estimated value of GH¢567.66 million (US$378.44

million).

Compared to the corresponding quarter of 2010, the estimated value of registered projects

grew by 101.31%, while FDI component of the projects shot up by 118.02%. The initial capital

transfer also increased significantly by 363.66%. In addition, jobs expected for Ghanaians

increased by 18.80% whereas that for non-Ghanaians decreased by 22.36%.

Launching this year’s “Invest in Ghana, 2011” Seminar and the Ghana Club 100, 2010

edition in the country’s capital, Accra, Aboagye, the Chief Executive Officer of GOPC, said the

event would create the platform to bring investors and projects together to explore public private

partnerships. The event, which opens under the theme: “Partnerships for Sustained Economic

Growth: The Role of the Domestic Investor”, according to Aboagye, will “…facilitate business

partnerships, which support the economic growth required to enable Ghana prosper in the

emerging global economy of the 21st century.” In furtherance, he maintained that “Partnering

domestic investments with FDI, is one of the major interventions by which the country can build

the capacity and grow its domestic investors”.

(http://www.theafricareport.com/archives2/business/5141660-ghanas-fdi-inflow-registers-70-

percent-increase.html).

In a separate and more detailed study, Sarpong (2011) opined that The Ghana Investment

Promotion Centre (GIPC) recorded an increase of 92.95% in Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)

Page 138: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

124

inflows into the country between January to March of 2011. He said that during the period, the

centre had GH¢527.63 million in FDI inflows into the country compared to GH¢225.88 million

recorded for the same period in 2010.

The local currency component also amounted to GH¢40.02 million, representing an

increase of 6.61% over the local component of GH¢37.54 million recorded in 2010.

The total number of projects registered by the GIPC for the three months period this year was 109

with a total estimated value of GH¢567.66million compared to 108 projects registered for the

same period in 2010 with a total estimated value of GH¢263.42 million. The initial capital

transfer for the newly registered projects during the quarter under review amounted to

GH¢103.35 million as against GH¢20.81 million, representing a 360% increase.

Out of the 109 registered projects, 66 (60.55%), were wholly-owned foreign enterprises

valued at GH¢175.07 million and the remaining 43 (39.45%) being joint ventures between

Ghanaians and foreign partner valued at GH¢392.58 million. A further breakdown of the FDI

inflow into Ghana within the period in terms of country of origin indicated that India, with 19

projects, topped the list of countries with the highest number of projects registered in Ghana for

the first three months of 2011. Britain/Belize, with a US$70.50 million investment, also topped

the list of countries with the largest value of investments registered in the country within the same

period. Lebanon followed with US$59.94 million and Mauritania with US$56.00 million.

Arising from this increase in the inflow of FDI into Ghana, it was expected that a total of

7,004 jobs will be created from these registered projects, an increase of 14.41% compared to the

6,122 expected jobs to be created in the corresponding quarter of 2010. About 6,497 of the total

jobs will be for Ghanaians and the remaining 507, for expatriates (Sarpong, 2011).

Projecting the oil sector as the single major determinant of FDI into Ghana in the recent

past, the 2011 World Investment report, indicated that Ghana is both at present and for the first

time the 7th largest recipient of foreign direct investments (FDIs) in Africa, in which investors

brought into the country, an amount of $2.5 billion (Quandzie, 2011:1). The report, prepared by

the United Nations Conference on Trade and Development (UNCTAD) and released on July 26,

2011, proved that FDIs inflow into Ghana increased largely because of Trans-National

Corporations’ (TNCs) attraction to the oil discovery in the country. The report went on to proffer

reasons for such a trend, thus:

As for Ghana, the start of major oil production has

attracted the interest of TNCs, some of which are

seeking an alternative sub-regional source of oil to

Nigeria

(http://www.ghanabusinessnews.com/2011/07/27/ghan

Page 139: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

125

a-receives-2-5b-becomes-7th-largest-recipient-of-fdis-

in-africa-as-oil-attracts-investors/ ).

The report notes that Ghana as an alternative for these TNCs for FDIs is due to Nigeria’s

uncertainty over the “Petroleum Industry Bill-1 which is perceived as unfavourable for TNCs,

and the unresolved political problem in the Niger Delta discouraging foreign investors which

allegedly led Shell to sell a number of its onshore licences” in the country. It accounted for the

rise of Ghana as a major FDI host country, as well as for the declines of inflows to Angola and

Nigeria. Though Angola was the largest earner of inflows in Africa with an amount of $9.9

billion, followed by Egypt, Nigeria and Libya all earning $6.4 billion, $6.1 billion and $3.8

billion respectively. While DR Congo had $2.9 billion, Congo Brazzaville $2.8 billion; Ghana

received $2.5 billion while Algeria, Sudan and South Africa received $2.3 billion, $1.6 billion

and $1.6 billion from the continent’s FDI inflows share.

4.8 IMPACT OF THE OIL INDUCED FDI IN GHANA

As earlier on mentioned in this study, Ghana’s portion of FDI inflows is almost

negligible, although it has risen in recent years. Ghana, like many other African countries, relies

heavily on natural resources in its attraction of FDI inflows and is thus able to attract flows to

only few sectors within the economy. The impact of FDI is therefore felt in those specific sectors

and in few other areas, mostly in the areas of capital formation, employment generation and

technology transfer (GIPC, 2007).

Capital Formation

FDI contribution to Ghana in terms of capital formation has been about 5 per cent from

1996-1999 (UNCTAD, 2002), still low compared to the average for SSA. By and large, ODA

inflows formed about 50 per cent of the formation of capital in Ghana between the periods 1990-

1999 (UNCTAD, 2002). Most of these ODAs were linked to FDI projects as long term loans and

grants. These funds also contributed to infrastructural development and not only that but also the

establishment of FTZs and customs rehabilitation. Then came a period, 1993-1998, when there

was a rise in portfolio investment complementing FDI flows in the area of privatization in the

formation of capital (UNCTAD, 2002).

Local industry

Local industries will equally receive a boost as a result of these expected oil led

investments. Firms in the transport and haulage sector, energy, building and construction,

hospitality, food and beverage, etc sectors will provide complementary services to the

multinational oil companies. This is expected to revamp some sections of the dormant local

energy industry.

Page 140: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

126

Banking and insurance activities are also expected to see a major boost since oil related

investments involve huge amounts of financial (capital) transfers and risks. The Bank of Ghana

raised the capital requirement of banks in Ghana in order to provide them with the necessary

capital base to deal in huge financial transactions. The Ghana National Insurance Commission

has followed suit by increasing the capital requirement of insurance companies. Insurance is a

vital component of the oil industry due to the risks associated with exploration, production and

transportation. International insurance companies have started opening up in Ghana and local

insurance companies are expected to compete with as well as learn best international practices

from these international insurance companies.

GDP

Taking that about 50% of all FDIs accrue to the oil sector in Ghana, then about 3% of

Ghana’s nominal GDP could as well accrue from oil related investments if such investments

would make up about 50% of future FDI inflows.

With average growth rate of nominal GDP (from 2000-2008) being approximately

24.81% as per UNCTAD records, an additional 3% from oil related FDI inflows would result to

about 27.81% growth in nominal GDP for future periods. With government of Ghana’s

determination to keep inflation rates low, average inflation rate of 18% (i.e. average inflation rate

for Ghana as per IMF records from 2000-2008) would in simple terms mean that real GDP

growth would amount to about 9.81% as against the current average of about 5.63% from 2001-

2008 as per IMF 2009 World Economic Outlook figures.

The IMF however estimates that real GDP growth is expected to be about 5.8 by 2014. As

a compromise between our estimated real GDP growth rate figure of 9.81% and the 5.63% of the

IMF (using simple average), we postulate that real GDP growth by 2014 would amount to about

7.8% taking into consideration the expectation that domestic oil production would reduce (to

some extent) imported inflation associated with Ghana’s oil import bill and also on condition that

the government would work assiduously towards maintaining low inflation rates.

However, as per our analysis using simple proportion based on oil reserves, about only

14% of total FDI to Ghana is expected to accrue to the oil sector. If total FDI inflow as a

percentage of nominal GDP is 13.25% in 2008, then oil related FDI inflows as a percentage of

nominal GDP would be about 1.86%. With average rate of nominal GDP growth of 24.81 as

quoted above, an additional 1.86% would result to about 26.67% for future periods. With an

average inflation rate of 18% (as quoted above) would in simple terms result to about 8.67%

growth in real GDP. A simple average of this growth rate and that estimated by the World Bank

(5.63%) for 2014 would amount to 7.15% expected real GDP growth rate by 2014 “ceteris

paribus”.

Page 141: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

127

Employment generation, technology and skills transfer

In terms of job creation, technology and skills transfer, FDI has played an enormous role

in Ghana and this also has a multiplier effect in the economy. According to the GIPC estimates of

registered projects, FDI has generated about 72,384 jobs for the Ghanaian population and about

4,652 for non-Ghanaians between the periods of 1994-2002. An UNCTAD survey of small and

medium sized enterprises (SMEs) with linkages to foreign firms or export activity shows that

firm size has increased in the last five years (2003-2008). Out of 83 projects registered during the

second quarter 0f 2009 alone, 56 (67.47%), were wholly-owned foreign enterprises and 27

(32.53%) were joint ventures between Ghanaians and their foreign partners with about 4,457 jobs

believed to have been created. 92.15% (4,107) of the total jobs to be created will be for

Ghanaians and the remaining 7.85% (350) for expatriates (GIPC, 2009).

FDI has also aided significantly to the increase in the stock of technology in Ghana by

providing machinery and equipment and at the same time helped in the build-up of local

industrial capabilities by contributing to skills formation. This is particularly evident in the area

of natural resources exploration such as mining, where the use of capital-intensive technology has

developed a pool of trained labour. Product improvement, constituted the most relevant support to

local firms, followed by training, provision of machinery and equipment together with

information on market opportunities (UNCTAD).

Our observation and findings in this chapter on the trends and trajectories in the rate of

inflow of inward Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) into Ghana indicated that the discovery in oil

in Ghana in June 2007 and its subsequent production in December, 2010 has led to an increase in

the rate of inflow of Foreign Direct Investment into the country. We therefore on the basis of this,

validate our second hypothesis.

Page 142: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

128

CHAPTER FIVE

SUMMARY, CONCLUSION AND RECOMMENDATION

5.1 SUMMARY

The study examined the expected role of oil (that is, oil windfall and/or revenue) towards

the development of the Ghanaian economy. We were basically concerned with the effects of the

oil production (natural resources) towards instigating national development of the country by

being more of a blessing than a curse to the nation. To carry out this study, two specific issues

were selected and empirically studied so as to determine the actual implication of the oil find and

production on the country.

In more specific terms, the study sought to determine the strategies, methods, ways and

practices that can help Ghana to avert the resource curse syndrome and place it on the right path

to development, through the effective and efficient management and regulation of its oil industry

and the revenue that comes therefrom, for the betterment of every Ghanaian both in the present

and in the future. This becomes necessary in view of the fact that oil exploration and production

in most of the Third World countries (Africa to be precise) has been more of a curse than

blessing, a phenomena that is usually described by social scientist as Dutch disease, resource

curse and paradox of plenty; all of which is known for their negative and anti-developmental

effects on the economies of these oil producing states. When in fact, oil and the numerous

opportunities it brings are considered to be among the economically near-omnipotent resources,

of which adequate management such as in the case of Norway and some other countries have

enhanced and promoted the development of the country. Thus, the study sought to provide

plausible and valid answers to the questions stated below:

1. Given the experiences of other Sub-Saharan African oil producing countries, is it possible

for Ghana to avoid the resource curse conundrum?

2. Has oil discovery and production led to an increase in the rate of Foreign Direct

Investment (FDI) into Ghana?

The above questions enabled us to arrive at the hypotheses stated below:

1 Ghana can avoid the resource curse conundrum through the formulation of strong oil

sector policies and the adoption of oil governance best practices.

2 There is a positive relationship between Oil discovery and production and the rate of

Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) inflow into Ghana.

Meanwhile, to adequately address the above, we focused our study on the effects of oil

find on the developmental quest of Ghana; the challenges that its exploration, extraction and

production is likely to bring upon the country and the managerial institutions and mechanisms

Page 143: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

129

that the country need to put in place and adopt towards the effective and efficient control,

regulation and management of the petroleum sector of the economy (revenue and proceeds) to

ensure that every citizen of the country benefits from the oil windfall. The study was divided into

five chapters.

Chapter one concentrated on introduction. We articulated the general socio-economic

atmosphere in Ghana especially since the discovery of oil offshore of the country’s western

region in relations to the expectations and fears that public opinions both within and outside the

country reflects as to whether the oil will be a blessing or curse to the country’s developmental

quest and subsequently, we arrived at some viable problems. We equally reviewed relevant

literatures and finally dwelt on methodological issues. These enable us to articulate an

appropriate framework of analysis, which was derived from the resource curse theory.

Specifically, the framework analysed the relationship between a country’s natural

resource endowment and the institutional arrangements and processes (policies and fiscal

regimes) that the nation put in place for the control and management of both the activities that is

going on in the sector (hereunder refers to oil) and the likely revenues that it will generate

towards the betterment of every member of the society; that determines the outcome and

implication of the natural resources on the economy.

Moreover, chapter two assessed the historical development of oil exploration in Ghana.

Efforts were made to study and understand the history of the Ghanaian state. In addition we

studied and identified the various ways through which the oil sector contributes to the economic

development of the oil producing states, which strategically comes in form of linkages both

forward and backward as well as the historical trajectories of oil exploration in Ghana. We also

analysed the structure and functions of the Ghana National Petroleum Corporation that oversees

the activities of the oil industry and/or sector on behalf of the Ghanaian Government. In chapter

three, we evaluated the issue oil governance best practices and equally conducted case study

samples it with Alaska and Norway as resource success stories due to their respective oil

governance best practices. The issue of accountability and transparency in the management of

the Ghana’s resources were equally evaluated; through stylized sub-themes on transparency. The

role of Civil Society Organisations (NGO’s) towards the efficient, transparent and accountable

management and use of Ghana’s oil revenues were equally elucidated and analysed. Mentioned

were also made of the attempts of the Ghanaian government at instilling transparency in the oil

revenue by extending the platform to the oil sector. Finally we assessed and analysed Ghana’s

Petroleum Revenue Management Act (law) in terms of its provisions on oil governance best

practices in addition to the expected contribution of oil to towards the development of Ghana’s

economy.

Page 144: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

130

In chapter four, we focused on the relationship between the oil discovery, its production

and exploitation and the inflow of FDI into Ghana. In doing, this considered the determinants of

FDI in developing countries. Ghana’s policies on FDI were at the same time evaluated and

commented upon. In order to understand the if whether there will be a link between the flow of

FDI and oil while controlling for other variables, we assessed the relationship between FDI and

natural resources. Arising from our study of the said relationship we applied the finding to Ghana,

from where we studied the trend of FDI inflow into Ghana. In furtherance, we interrogated the

synergy between the discovery and production of oil and inflow of FDI into Ghana. finally, we

analysed the impact of FDI inflow on the Ghana’s economy.

The above, not only validated our hypotheses but opens new vistas in the study of oil and

the socio-economic development in the Ghana and the problems associated therein.

5.2 CONCLUSIONS

Lessons through the analysis have revealed that Ghana stands to overcome the ‘curse of

natural resource’ that comes from oil if it strengthens its institutional –capacity, pursue growth-

led policies and remain unwavering in its democratic governance. Empirical evidence has pointed

out that the development of strong institutions and policies that are in tandem with the

international acclaimed oil governance best practices will determine the extent to which political

ideology and effective policies translate into economic growth and development.

The political economy of oil and the oil sector play pivotal role in the social, political an

economic transformation of the Ghanaian economy. The oil sector contribute to the economic

development of Ghana through five linkages of; fiscal, forward, backward, consumption and

socio-political. The oil revenue that is to accrue to the state will enable the public sector to make

expenditures and investment outlays. Besides the exhaustibility of oil and state ownership of the

resource make the allocation and use of oil revenues across generations, state intervention in the

economy, andthe latters response to government initiatives and policies, central to economic

growth and development.

From the findings of the study, we conclude that the new found oil in Ghana will

contribute positively towards the development of the Ghanaian economy. Furthermore, the

discovery, exploitation and revenue which will the marketing of the oil will go a long way in

correcting and reversing the trends in the country’s external debt profile.

Moreover, Ghana unlike many other oil producing African states has through its policy on

local content and public participation bill and the Petroleum Revenue Management Act proved

that it is ready and capable of managing its oil windfall for greater benefit of every Ghanaian

citizen through transparency and accountability in the utilization of the oil proceeds and

agreement. A situation that will ensure the prompt and adequate deployment of the oil windfall

Page 145: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

131

through the fiscal instruments, most especially the national budgets to areas of needs and

priorities that will place Ghana on the right path of development rather than the debilitating twin

effects resource curse and Dutch disease. Hence Ghana’s oil find will be more of a blessing than

a curse as the experiences of some other oil producing African states such as Angola, Sudan and

Nigeria have proved.

Deriving from the above is the fact that the puzzle which necessitated the study has been

addressed.

5.3 RECOMMENDATIONS

Institutionalizing Accountability and Transparency: Ghana should ensure that it goes beyond

the rhetoric’s by subjecting the oil sector to EITI scrutiny and provide it with legal codes to make

it mandatory for public disclosure. There should be regular publication and disclosure of all

transactions, agreements and petroleum – gas payment. The Freedom of Information Act should

be given operational wing, such that it will offer the public access to government information and

bolster public confidence in the state. Institutions of transparency and accountability should be

resourced and strengthened to function independent of government.

Improving the Capacity of Anti-Corruption Institution: Anti-corporation institutions in

Ghana such as CHRAC, Serious Fraud Office, the BNI, the Police and the Judiciary should be

financially and humanly resourced and independent to be effective in the discharge of their

duties. The Judiciary should perform their duties impartially and the legislative laws should

provide appropriate punishment for corruption. The Whistle Blower Bill should be passed into

law to allow individuals to report cases of corruption to appropriate institutions for action to be

taken on them. The media should monitor and actively report on government activities. The anti-

corruption institutions should possess more powers to prosecute corrupt practices.

Establishing Legal and Regulatory Framework: Ghana must move away from the ad-hoc and

piecemeal legal and regulatory laws on the petroleum sector. It should develop robust legal and

regulatory laws to fill the gaps in upstream and midstream sectors and govern production and

exploration. A moratorium on new exploration licenses should be enacted as government

strengthens it legal and regulatory laws. GNPC should be an autonomous entity to enhance its

functions and duties.

Strengthening Civil Society and Other Third-State Actors: Civil society groups and other

third-state actors should actively monitor and engage the government by promoting national

dialogue. It should criticize, suggest, publish government dealing and activities and keep the

public updated on events in the oil sector. Civil society groups should build capacity and develop

expert knowledge to effectively functions well in the oil sector.

Page 146: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

132

Deepening Governance and Building State-Capacity: Government should sustain the current

multi-party democratic gains and strengthen the process of governance. The capacity of

government agencies, ministries and departments should be developed through periodic

workshops and seminars to keep them updated to the task. Parliament should be institutionally

enhanced to have sufficient oversight responsibility over government spending and expenditure.

It should develop expertise in the appropriate oil committees to keep the House well-informed

and activity plays their role well.

Trade Liberalization and Diversification Policies: Ghana should adopt better policies that

minimize the concentration of Dutch disease, and crowding out effect and contract other sectors

of the economy. Such policies should improve competition and avoid trade restrictions, fight

exchange rate appreciation and accumulate budget surpluses, reduce the number of days for

setting up business and divert investors and FDIs into non-oil sector. It should sustain its

diversification programme and improve on its investment laws to attract private investment and

donor funds. In this regard, Ghana Investment Promotion Centre (GIPC) should be institutionally

equipped and resourced to play an active role.

Public Financial Reforms and Re-inventing State Revenue Agencies: Ghanaian Government’s

attempt to computerize the Public Financial System through the public Financial Management

Reform (PFMR) has been lying ideal for over decades. The reform however, is urgent in the

advent of the oil boom to inject fiscal and monetary discipline into the public financial system. It

will strengthen revenue collection agencies, promotes transparency and accountability, improves

public expenditures and avoid wasteful spending. Government should therefore be committed to

these reforms to build the capacity of state agencies to meet the demand of the commercial

market.

Page 147: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

133

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Books

Ake, C. (1996) Democracy and Development in Africa. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings

Institution.

Amuzegar, J. (2001) Managing the Oil Wealth: OPEC’s Windfalls and Pitfalls. London: I. B.

Tauris.

Asante, Y. (2006) “Foreign Direct Investment in Ghana’ in S. I. Ajayi (Ed) (2006) Foreign Direct

Investment in Sub-Saharan Africa: Origins, Targets, Impact and Potential. Nairobi:

African Economic Research Consortium.

Ascher, W. (1999) Why Governments Waste Natural Resources: Policy Failures in Developing

Countries, Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.

Asika, N. (1991) Research Methodology in Behavioural Sciences, Ikeja: Longmans.

Askari, H. et al (1997) Economic Development in the GCC: The Blessing and the Curse of Oil.

London: JAI Press.

Auty, R. (1993) Sustaining Development in Mineral Economies: The Resource Curse Thesis,

London: Routledge.

Auty, R. (1990). Resource-based Industrialization: Sowing the Oil in Eight Developing

Countries, New York: Oxford University Press.

Auty, R. (1998). “Resource Abundance and Economic Development: Improving the Performance

of Resource-rich Countries”, The United Nations University World Institute for

Development Economics, Helsinki.

Auty, R. and Miksell, R. F. (2000) Sustainable Development in Mineral Economies. Oxford:

Oxford University Press.

Auty, R. (2001), (Ed). Resource Abundance and Economic Development, Oxford: Oxford

University Press.

Auty, R. and Gelb, A. (2001) ‘The Political Economy of Resource-Abundant States’, in R. Auty

(ed.), Resource Abundance and Economic Development, Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Auty, R. (2001a) Resource Abundance and Economic Development. Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Auty, R. (2001b) ‘Conclusions: Resource Abundance, Growth Collapses, and Policy’, in R. Auty

(ed.) Resource Abundance and Economic Development, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Auty, R., and Evia, J. L. (2001) “A Growth Collapse with Point Resources: Bolivia”. In R.M.

Auty eds. Resource Abundance and Economic Development, Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Page 148: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

134

Ballantine, K. (2003) ‘Beyond Greed and Grievance: Reconsidering the Economic Dynamics of

Armed Conflict’, in K. Ballentine and J. Sherman (eds), The Political Economy of Armed

Conflict: Beyond Greed and Grievance, London: Lynne Riener.

Bannon, I. and Collier, P. (2003) ‘Natural Resources and Conflict: What We Can Do’, Chapter 1

in I. Bannon and P. Collier (eds), Natural Resources and Violent Conflict: Options and

Actions, Washington, DC: World Bank.

Baran, P. (1967) The Political Economy of Growth. New York: Monthly Press.

Beblawi, H. (1987) ‘The Rentier State in the Arab World’, in H. Beblawi and G. Luciani (eds),

The Rentier State: Volume II, London: Croom Helm.

Beblawi, H. and Luciani, G. (Eds.) (1987) The Rentier State in the Arab World. New York:

Croom Helm.

Blomström, et al (2000) Foreign Direct Investment: Firm and Host Country Strategies. London:

Macmillan.

Brohman, J. (1996) Popular Development: Rethinking the Theory and Practice of Development.

Oxford: Blackwell.

Carcovic, M and Levine, R (2002) Does Foreign Direct Investment Accelerate Economic

Growth? Mimeo. Minneapolis, University of Minnesota.

Caves, R. (1996) Multinational Enterprise and Economic Analysis, 2nd edition. New York:

Cambridge University Press.

Coleman, J. (1968) “Modernisation: Political Aspects”, The International Encyclopedia of the

Social Sciences. Vol. iv. New York: The Macmillan Co. and the Free Press.

Collier, P. and Gunning, J.W. (1999) Trade Shocks in Developing Countries. New York: Oxford

University Press.

Dunning, J.H. (1993) Multinational Enterprises and the Global Economy. Pearson Education.

Wokingham, UK, and New York: Addison-Wesley Publishing.

Eke, O. A. (2010) Oil, Politics and Development in Nigeria: 50 Years of Drilling. Abakaliki:

WillyRose and Appleseed.

First, R. (1974) Libya: The Elusive Revolution, Harmondsworth: Penguin.

Frank, A. G. (1969) Capitalism and Underdevelopment in Latin America. New York: Monthly

Review Press.

Gana, A. T. (1989) “Reflections on the Structural Adjustment Programme”, in R. Omotayo and

C. Nweke, (eds) SAP in Nigeria: The Impact of SFEM on the Economy. Lagos: National

Institute of International Affaris.

Garaibeh, H. (1987) ‘Government Income Sources and the Development of the Taxation System

– The Case of Jordan, Egypt and Kuwait’, in H. Beblawi and G. Luciani (eds), The

Rentier State: Volume II, London: Croom Helm.

Page 149: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

135

Gelb, A. (1988) Oil Windfalls. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Gelb, A. and Associates (1988) Oil Windfalls: Blessing or Curse, New York: Oxford University

Press.

Gelb, A.H. (1986). “Adjustment to Windfall Gains”, in Neary, J.P. and Van Wijnbergen, S. (Eds.)

Natural Resources and the Macroeconomy, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.

Gelb, A.H. et al (1988). Windfall Gains: Blessing or Curse? New York: Oxford University Press.

Ghazvinian, J. (2007) Untapped: The scramble for Africa’s oil. New York: Harcourt Books.

Goulet, D. (1971) The Cruel Choice: A New Conception on the Theory of Development. New

York: Atheneum.

Gunn, G. (1993) ‘Rentier Capitalism in Negara Brunei Daussalam’ in K. Hewison et al. (eds),

Southeast Asia in the 1990s: Authoritarianism, Democracy, and Capitalism, Sydney:

Allen and Unwin.

Hagen, E. E. (1980) The Economic of Development. Homewook, III: R. D. Irwin.

Hausman, R. (2003) ‘Venezuala’s Growth Implosion: A Neoclassical Story’ in D. Rodrik (ed.),

In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth, Princeton: Princeton

University Press.

Higgins, B. (1968) Economic Development: Problems, Principles, and Policies, New York: WW

Norton and Company.

Hirschman, A. (1958) The Strategy of Economic Development, New Haven: Yale University

Press.

Hirschman, A.O. (1958). The Strategy of Economic Development, New Haven Connecticut: Yale

University Press.

Hoselitz, B. (1971) Sociological Aspect of Economic Growth. New York: Free Press.

Humphreys, M. et al (eds.) (2007) Escaping the Resource Curse. Irvington, NY: Columbia

University Press.

Jaspersen, F., et al (2000) “The effects of risks on private investment: Africa Compared with

Other Developing Countries”. In P. Collier and C. Pattillo, eds. Investment and Risk in

Africa. New York: St. Martins Press.

Jega, A.M. (2007) “Civil Society and Sustainability of Democracy in Nigeria: Challenges of

2003 Elections” in A.M. Jega, Democracy, Good Governance and Development in

Nigeria- Critical Essays. Ibadan: Spectrum Book Limited.

Karl, T. L. (1997) Paradox of Plenty: Oil Booms and Petro-States. Berkeley, CA: University of

California Press.

Page 150: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

136

Krause, L. (1995) ‘Social Capability and Long-term Economic Growth’ in B.H. Koo and D.

Perkins (eds), Social Capability and Long-term Economic Growth, Basingstoke:

Macmillan.

Leege, D. and Francis, W. (1974) Political Research Design, Measurement and Analysis, New

York: Basic Books Inc.

Levin, J. (1960) The Export Economies: Their Pattern of Development in Historical Perspective,

Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Lewis, A. (1955) The Theory of Economic Growth, Homewood, Illinois: R.D. Irwin.

Luciani, G. (1987), ‘Allocation vs. Production States: A Theoretical Framework’, in H. Beblawi

and G. Luciani (eds), The Rentier State: Volume II, London: Croom Helm.

Mabogunje, A. L. (1981) The Development Process: A Spatial Perspective. New YorkL Holmes

and Meier Publishers.

Mahdavy, H. (1970) ‘The Patterns and Problems of Economic Development in Rentier States’ in

M. Cook (ed.), Studies in the Economic History of the Middle East, London: Oxford

University Press.

Mayor, F. (1996) “Learning: The Treasure Within, Report to UNESCO of the International

Commission on Education for the 21st Century” cited in the Delors Report, UNESCO.

Paris.

McClelland, D. C. (1971) The Achieving Society. Princeton, N.J. Van Nostrand.

Mehlum, et al (2005). “Institutions and the Resource Curse”. Mimeo. Norwegian University of

Science and Technology, Trondheim.

Mitra, P. (1994) Adjustment in Oil-Importing Developing Countries: A Comparative Economic

Analysis, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Nnabugwu, M. (2006) Methodology of Political Inquiry: Issues and Techniques of Research

Methods in Political Science, Enugu: Quintagon Publishers.

Nnoli, O. (1981) Path to Nigerian Development. Coderisa: Dakar, Senegal.

Obasi, I.N. (1999) Research Methodology in Political Science, Enugu: Academic Publishers.

Olawale, E. O. and Afeikhena J. (2006) Foreign Direct Investment in Nigeria: Magnitude,

Direction and Prospects in S. I. Ajayi (Ed) Foreign Direct Investment in Sub-Saharan

Africa: Origins, Targets, Impact and Potential. Nairobi: African Economic Research

Consortium.

Onuoha, J. (2008) The State and Economic Reform in Nigeria: An Exploratory Note on the

Capture Theory of Politics. Nsukka: Great AP Express Publishers Ltd.

Osuala, E.C. (1982) Introduction to Research Methodology. Onitsha: Africana-Feb Publishers.

Page 151: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

137

Prebisch, R. (1950) The Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems,

Lake Success, NY: United Nations.

Pye, L. (1966) Aspect of Political Development. Boston: Little Brown.

Regan, A. (2003) ‘The Bouganville Conflict: Political and Economic Agendas’, in K. Ballentine

and J. Sherman (eds), The Political Economy of Armed Conflict: Beyond Greed and

Grievance, London: Lynne Riener.

Ricardo, S. (2007) Oil and Politics in the Gulf of Guinea. Irvington, NY: Columbia University

Press.

Rodney, W. (1982) How Europe Underdeveloped Africa. Enugu Ikenga Publishers.

Rodrik, D. (2003) (ed.), In Search of Prosperity: Analytic Narratives on Economic Growth,

Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

Rodriquez, O. (1980) La Teoria Del Subdesarrollo De La Cepal. Mexico: Siglo XXI Editores.

Ross, M (2001b) Timber Booms and Institutional Breakdown in Southeast Asia, Ann Arbor:

University of Michigan.

Ross, M (2003b) ‘Oil, Drugs and Diamonds: The Varying Role of Natural Resources in Civil

War’, in K. Ballentine and J. Sherman (eds), The Political Economy of Armed Conflict:

Beyond Greed and Grievance, Boulder: Lynne Reiner Publishers.

Ross, M. (2001) Extractive Sectors and the Poor. Boston: Oxfam America.

Rostow, W. (1961) The Stages of Economic Growth: A Non-communist Manifesto, Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. (1999b). “Natural Resource Intensity and Economic Growth”, in

Meyer, J., Chambers, B. and Farooq, A. (Eds), Development Policies in Natural Resource

Economies, Cheltenham, Edward Elgar.

Schimitter, P.C. (1997) “Civil Society East and West”, L. Diamond, et al (eds), Consolidating the

Third Wave of Democracies. Baltimore and London: The John Hopkins University Press.

Scott, R. P. (1970) Petroleum and the Nigerian Economy. California: Standard Press.

Seong, K.R. (2000) “Civil Soceity and Democractic Consolidation in South Korea: Great

Achievements and Problems”, in L. Diamond and B. Kim, (Ed) Consolidating

Democracy in South Korea. Boulder Colorado: Lynne Rinner Publishers, Inc.

Shaxson, N. (2007) Poisoned Wells: The Dirty Politics of African Oil. New York: Palgrave

Macmillan.

Stijns, P. (2001), Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth Revisited. Berkeley:

University of California.

Page 152: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

138

Tanter, R. (1990) ‘Oil, IGGI and US Hegemony: The Global Preconditions for Indonesian

Rentier-Militarization’, in A. Budiman (ed.), State and Civil Society in Indonesia,

Melbourne: Centre for Southeast Asian Studies, Monash University.

Todaro, M. P. (1992) Economics for A Developing World: An Introduction to Principles,

Problems and Policies for Development, (3rd ed). London: Longman Group.

Tungendhat, C. (1986) Oil: The Biggest. London: Eyre and Spottiswooded.

Urrutia, M. (1988) ‘The Politics of Economic Development Policies in Resource Rich States’, in

M. Urrutia and S. Yukawa (eds), Economic Development Policies in Resource Rich

Countries, Tokyo: United Nations University.

Vandewalle, D. (1998) Libya Since Independence: Oil and State-Building, Ithaca and London:

Cornell University Press.

Walde, T.W and Ndi, G.K., (Eds) (1994) International Oil and Gas Investment, Moving

Eastward? London: Graham &Trotman/Martinus Nijhoff.

Wallerstein, I. (1999) The End of the World As We Know It: Social Science for the Twenty-First

Century, Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

Wallich, H. (1960) Monetary Problems of an Export Economy, Cambridge: Cambridge

University Press.

Wantchekon, L. (1999), Why Do Resource Dependent Countries Have Authoritarian

Governments? (12 December), New Haven, CT: Yale University

Websters, A. (1990) Introduction to the Sociology of Development (2nd ed). Houndmills:

Macmillan Press.

White, L. E. (1989) Political Analysis Techniques and Practice. California: Books/Cole

Publishers.

Winters, J. (1996) Power in Motion: Capital Mobility and the Indonesian State, Ithaca: Cornell

University Press.

Woolcock, M., Pritchett L. and Isham, J. (2001) ‘The Social Foundations of Poor Economic

Growth in Resource-Rich Countries’, in R. Auty (ed.), Resource Abundance and

Economic Development, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Wright, G. and Czelusta, J. (2002). Resource-based Economic Growth, Past and Present.

Stanford University.

Journals

Aitken, B. and A.E. Harrison. 1999. “Do Domestic Firms Benefit From Direct Foreign

Investment?” American Economic Review, Vol. 89.

Aitken, B., et al (1997) “Spillovers, Foreign Investment and Export Behaviour”. Journal of

International Economics, Vol.43, Nos. 1-2.

Page 153: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

139

Amin, S. (1973) Accumulation on A World Scale: A Critique of Theory of Underdevelopment.

New York: Monthly Review.

Amin, S. (2001) ‘Imperialism and Globalization’, Monthly Review 53.2 (June).

Anderson, K. (1998) ‘Are Resource Abundant Countries Disadvantaged?’, The Australian

Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics 42 (March)

Asiedu, E., 2002, 'On the Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment to Developing Countries: is

Africa different?', World Development, 30 (1).

Atkinson, G. and Hamilton, K. (2003) ‘Savings, Growth and the Resource Curse Hypothesis’,

World Development 31.

Auty, R. (1994). “Industrial Policy Reform in Six Newly Industrializing Countries: The Resource

Curse Thesis”, World Development, Vol. 22. No. 1.

Auty, R. (1995) ‘Industrial Policy, Sectoral Maturation and Postwar Economic Growth in Brazil:

The Resource Curse Thesis’, Economic Geography Vol.71, No.3.

Auty, R. (2001c) ‘The Political Economy of Resource Driven Growth’, European Economic

Review Vol.45 No.4.

Auty, R. (2001d) ‘Transition Reform in the Mineral-Rich Caspian Region Countries’, Resources

Policy Vol. 27.

Auty, R. (2004) ‘Natural Resources and Civil Strife: A Two-Stage Process’, Geopolitics Vol. 9

No.1.

Balasubramanyam, et al (1996) “Foreign Direct Investment and Growth in EP and IS Countries”.

Economic Journal, Vol.106.

Banco de Desenvolvimento de Angola, 2009, Boletim de Conjuntura, No. 1-MAIO 2009S.

Basedau, M. & LAY, J. (2009) “Resource Curse or Rentier Peace? The Ambiguous Effects of Oil

Wealth and Oil Dependence on Violent Conflict”. Journal of Peace Research, Vol. vol.

46, No. 6.

Bende-Nabende, A. and Ford, J.L. (1998) “FDI, Policy Adjustment and Endogenous Growth:

Multiplier Effects from a Small Dynamic Model for Taiwan 1959–1995”. World

Development Vol. 26, No.7.

Bende-Nabende, A., et al. (2002) “Foreign Direct Investment in East Asia: Trends and

Determinants”. Asia Pacific Journal of Economics and Business Vol.6, No.1.

Bengos, M. and Sanchez-Robles, B. (2003) “Foreign Direct Investment, Economic Freedom and

Growth: New Evidence from Latin America”. European Journal of Political Economy,

Vol.19, No.3.

Betts, A., et al (2006) ‘Editorial Introduction: ‘The International Politics of Oil,’’ Stair 2, No. 1

Page 154: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

140

Blömstrom, M. (1986) Foreign Investment and Productive Efficiency: The Case of Mexico.

Journal of Industrial Economics Vol.15.

Blömstrom, M. and Kokko, A. (1998) Multinational Corporations and Spillovers. Journal of

Economics Surveys Vol.12, No.3.

Blomstrom, M. and Sjoholm, F. (1999) “Technological Transfer and Spillover: Does Local

Participation with Multinationals Matter?” European Economic Review, 43.

Borensztein, E., et al (1998) “How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?”.

Journal of Economics Vol.45.

Broad, R. (1995) ‘The Political Economy of Natural Resources: Cases of the Indonesian and

Philippine Forest Sectors’, Journal of Developing Areas 29.3.

Bruno, M. and Sachs, J. (1982) ‘Energy and Resource Allocation: A Dynamic Model of the

“Dutch Disease”’, Review of Economic Studies XLIX.

Cairncross, A.K. (1961) “International Trade and Economic Development”, Economica, Vol.28,

No.109.

Chaudhry, K. (1994) ‘Economic Liberalisation and the Lineages of the Rentier State’,

Comparative Politics 27 (October).

Cohen, A. and Alasa, R.(2007) “Africa’s Oil and Gas Sector: Implications for US Policy,”

Backgrounder No. 2052. Washington, DC: The Heritage Foundation, July.

Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (2005) ‘Resource Rents, Governance, and Conflict’, Journal of

Conflict Resolution Vol. 49 No 4.

Collier, P., et al. (2004) ‘On the Duration of Civil War’, Journal of Peace Research Vol.41 No 3

Corden, W. and Neary, J. (1982), ‘Booming Sector and De-Industrialisation in a Small Open

Economy’, The Economic Journal 92 (December).

Davis, G.A. (1995) ‘Learning to Love the Dutch Disease: Evidence from Mineral Economies’,

World Development 23.10.

De Soysa, I. (2002) ‘Paradise is a Bazaar? Greed, Creed, and Governance in Civil War, 1989–

99’, Journal of Peace Research 39.4.

Dees, S. (1998) “Foreign Direct Investment in China: Determinants and Effects”. Economics of

Planning,Vol.31.

Doyle, M. and Sambanis, N. (2000) ‘International Peace Building: A Theoretical and

Quantitative Analysis’, American Political Science Review 94.4.

Driffield, N. (2001) “The Impact of Domestic Productivity of Inward Investment in the UK”. The

Manchester School, Vol.69.

Page 155: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

141

Durham, J.B. (2004) “Absorptive Capacity and the Effects of Foreign Direct Investment and

Equity Foreign Portfolio Investment on Economic Growth”. European Economic Review,

Vol.48, No.2.

Economies,” Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 27, No. 1

Ekpo, A.H. (1995) “Foreign Direct Investment in Nigeria: Evidence From Time Series Data”.

CBN Economic and Financial Review, Vol.35, No.1.

Ezirim, G. E. (2010) “The Political Economy of the Resource Curse and Development in the Gulf

of Guinea: Nigeria in Perspective”, International Journal of Modern Political Economy,

Vol.1, No.1, September.

Fearon, J. (2004) ‘Why Do Some Civil Wars Last So Much Longer Than Others’, Journal of

Peace Research Vol.41 No.3.

Fearon, J. (2005) ‘Primary Commodity Exports and Civil War’, Journal of Conflict Resolution

Vol.49 No.4.

Fearon, J. and Laitin, D. (2003) ‘Ethnicity, Insurgency and Civil War’, American Political

Science Review Vol.97 No.1.

Findlay, R. (1978) “Relative Backwardness, Direct Foreign Investment and the Transfer of

Technology: A Simple Dynamic Model”. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 92

Fradinamesh, M. (1991). “Dutch Disease Economies and the Oil Syndrome: An Empirical

Study”. World Development, Vol. 19, No. 6.

Fritsch, P. (2008) “Africa’s Potential to Sate World’s oil Demand Dims,” Wall Street Journal.

Furtado, C. (1976) “Economic Development in Latin America”, New Left Review, 74.

Gao, Z (1994) International Petroleum Exploration and Exploitation Agreement: Comprehensive

Environmental Appraisal, in Thomas W. Walde and George K. N. (Eds) International Oil

and Gas Investment, Moving Eastward?.

Glass, A. J. and Saggi, K. (1998) “FDI Policies under Shared Markets”. Journal of International

Economics, 49.

Gylfason, T. (2001) “Natural Resources, Education, and Economic Development”. European

Economic Review, 45.

Gylfason, T., et al. (1999). “A Mixed Blessing: Natural Resources and Economic Growth”,

Macroeconomic Dynamics, Vol. 3.

Humphreys, M. (2005), ‘Natural Resources, Conflict, and Conflict Resolution: Uncovering the

Mechanisms’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 49.4.

Huntington, S. (1965) “Political Development and Political Decay”, World Politics, Vol.17, No.

2.

Page 156: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

142

Jedrzej G. F. and Manuel P. (2006) “A New Scramble for African oil?, Historical Political and

Business Perspectives”, African Affairs, Series, 106/423.

Jensen, N. and Wantchekon, L. (2004) ‘Resource Wealth and Political Regimes in Africa’,

Comparative Political Studies 37.7.

Jones Luong, P. and Weinthal, E. (2001) ‘Prelude to the Resource Curse: Explaining Oil and Gas

Development Strategies in the Soviet Successor States and Beyond’, Comparative

Political Studies 34.4.

Kalyuzhnova, Y. (2006 Overcoming the Curse of Hydrocarbon: Goals and Governance in the Oil

Funds of Kazakhstan and Azerbaijan. Comparative Economic Studies, Vol.48.

Keen, D. (1998) ‘The Economic Functions of Violence in Civil Wars’, Adelphi Paper 32,

London: International Institute for Strategic Studies.

Kokko, A. (1994) “Technology, Market Characteristics and Spillovers”. Journal of Development

Economics, 43.

Krueger, A. (1980) ‘Trade Policy as an Input to Development’, American Economic Review, 70.2

Krugman, P. (1987) “The Narrow Moving band, the Dutch Disease and the Competitive

Consequences of Mrs. Thatcher: Notes on Trade in the Presence of Dynamic Scale

Economics”, Journal of Development Economics, Vol 27, No.1.

Le Billon, P. (2001) ‘The Political Ecology of War: Natural Resources and Armed Conflicts’,

Political Geography 20

Lucas, R. E. J. (1988) “On the Mechanics of Economic Development”. Journal of Monetary

Economics, 22.

Luong, P.J. and Weinthal, E. (2006) “Rethinking the Resource Curse: Ownership Structure,

Institutional Capacity, and Domestic Constraints”. Annual Review of Political Science,

Vol. 9, June.

Mabro, R. and Monroe, E. (1974). Arab Wealth from Oil: Problems of its Investment.

International Affairs, January.

Mahon Jr., J. (1992) ‘Was Latin America Too Rich to Prosper?’ Journal of Development Studies

28.2 (January)

Markussen, J.R. and Vernable, A.J. (1998) “Multinational Firms and the New Trade Theory”.

Journal of International Economics, 46.

Mehlum , H. et al. (2006) “Institutions and the Resource Curse”, The Economic Journal, 116

(January),

Mikesell, R. (1997). “Explaining the Resource Curse, with Special Reference to Mineral-

Exporting Countries”. Resources Policy, Vol. 23, No. 4.

Mody, A. and K. Srinivasan. (1998) “Japanese and United States firms as foreign investors: Do

they march to the same tune?” Canadian Journal of Economics, 31(4).

Page 157: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

143

Moore M. (2000) ‘Political Underdevelopment: What Causes Bad Governance?’, Public

Management Review 3.3.

Moore, M. (2004) “Revenues, State Formation, and the Quality of Governance in Developing

Countries” International Political Science Review, Vol.25, No 3.

Morisset, J. (2000) “Foreign Direct Investment in Africa: Policies Matter”. Transnational

Corporations, 9(2).

Neumayer, E. (2004). ‘Does the “Resource Curse” Hold for Growth in Genuine Income as

Well?’, World Development 32.,10.

Ngowi, H. P. (2001) “Can Africa Increase its Global Share of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI)”.

West African Review, 2(2).

Nurske, R. (1958) ‘Trade Fluctuations and Buffer Policies of Low-Income Countries’, Kyklos

11.2: 141 Obwona, M. B. (2001) “Determinants of FDI and their Impacts on Economic Growth in

Uganda”. African Development Review, 13: (1). Blackwell Publishers, Oxford UK

Okruhlik, G. (1999) ‘Rentier Wealth, Unruly Law, and the Rise of Opposition: The Political

Economy of Oil States’, Comparative Politics 31.3.

Olofsdotter, K. (1998) “Foreign Direct Investment, Country Capabilities and Economic Growth”.

Weltwitschaftliches Arckive, 134 (3).

Pearce, J. (2005) “Policy Failure and Petroleum Predation: The Economics of Civil War Debate

Viewed “From the War Zone”, Government and Opposition 40.2.

Perelman, M. (2003), ‘Myths of the Market’, Organization and Environment 16.2 (June).

Reynal-Querol, M. (2002) ‘Ethnicity, Political Systems, and Civil Wars’, Journal of Conflict

Resolution 46.

Robinson, J., Torvik, R. and Verdier, T. (2002) Political Foundations of the Resource Curse,

Centre For Economic Policy Research, Discussion Paper Series No 3422.

Robinson, J.A., Torvik, R. and Verdier, T. (2006) “Political Foundations of the Resource Curse”.

Journal of Development Economics, 79.

Rodrik, D. (1999) ‘Where Did All The Growth Go? External Shocks, Social Conflict and

Growth Collapses’, Journal of Economic Growth 4 (December).

Romer, P. (1986) “Increasing returns and long run growth”. Journal of Political Economy, 94.

Romer, P. (1990) “Endogenous Technological Change”. Journal of Political Economy, 98.

Ross, M (1999) ‘The Political Economy of the Resource Curse’, World Politics Vol. 51 No2

Ross, M (2001a) ‘Does Oil Hinder Democracy?’, World Politics 53

Page 158: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

144

Ross, M. (2004a) ‘What Do We Know About Natural Resources and Civil War?’, Journal of

Peace Research Vol.41.No.3

Ross, M. (2004b) ‘How Do Natural Resources Influence Civil War? Evidence from 13 Cases’,

International Organisation 58. No1.

Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. (1998). “The big Push, Natural Resource Booms and Growth”,

Mimeo, January.

Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. (1999). “The Big Push, Natural Resource Booms and Growth”,

Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 59.

Schneider, F. and Frey, B.S. (1985) “Economic and Political Determinants of Foreign Direct

Investment”. World Development, Vol.13, No.2.

Seers, D. (1964) “The Mechanism of an Open Petroleum Economy”, Social Economic Studies,

13.

Seers, D. (1969) “The Meaning of Development”, International Development Review, No.4,

December.

Seers, D. (1977) “The Meaning of Development”, International Development Review, No.3

December.

Shaxson, N. (2005) ‘New Approaches to Volatility Dealing With the “Resource Curse” in Sub-

Saharan Africa’, International Affairs 81.2.

Sherman, J. (2000) ‘Profits vs. Peace: The Clandestine Diamond Economy of Angola’, Journal of

International Affairs 53.2: 699–719

Shihata, I. (1992) “The World Bank and the Environment: A Legal Perspective”, 16 Maryland

Journal of International Law and Trade, Vol. 1.

Silberfein, M. (2004) ‘The Geopolitics of Conflict and Diamonds in Sierra Leone’, Geopolitics

9.1.

Singer, H. (1950), The Distribution of Gains Between Investing and Borrowing Countries, The

American Economic Review 40.2 (May), Papers and Proceedings of the Sixty-Second

Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association.

Sjoholm, F. 1999. “Technology Gap, Competition and Spillovers From Direct Foreign

Investment: Evidence from Establishment Data”. Journal of Development Studies,

Vol.36, No.1.

Smarzynska, B. K. (2002) “Does Foreign Direct Investment Increase the Productivity of

Domestic Firms? In Search of Spillovers through Backward Linkages”. Policy Research

Working Paper No. 29. The World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Smith, B. (2004) ‘Oil Wealth and Regime Survival in the Developing World: 1960–1999’,

American Journal of Political Science 28.2.

Page 159: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

145

Snyder, R. and Bhavnani (2005) ‘Diamonds, Blood and Taxes: A Revenue-Centred Framework

for Explaining Political Order’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 49.

Sørli, M., Gleditsch, N. and Strand, H. (2005) ‘Why is There So Much Conflict in the Middle

East?’, Journal of Conflict Resolution 49.1.

Stevens, P. (1986). The Impact of Oil on the Role of the State in Economic Development: A Case

Study of the Arab World. Arab Affairs Vol. 1 No. 1.

Torvik, R. (2002) ‘Natural Resources, Rent Seeking and Welfare’, Journal of Development

Economics 67.

Tsai, P. L. (1994) “Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment and its Impact on Economic

growth”. Journal of Economic Development, 19.

Useem, J. (2003) ‘The Devil’s Excrement’, Fortune, 147

Usui, N. (1997) ‘Dutch Disease and Policy Adjustments to the Oil Boom: A Comparative Study

of Indonesia and Mexico’, Resources Policy 23.4.

Van Wijinbergen, S.J. (1984) “The Dutch Disease: A Disease after All?”, Economic Journal

Vol.94.

Watkins, M. (1963) ‘A Staple Theory of Economic Growth’. Canadian Journal of Economics

and Political Science 32.

Watts, M. (2006) “Empire of Oil Capitalist Dispossession and the Scramble for Africa”, Monthly

Review, Sept. 2006.

Weinthal, E. and Jones L. P. (2001) ‘Energy Wealth and Tax Reform in Russia and Kazakhstan’,

Resources Policy 27.

Wheeler, D. (1984) ‘Sources of Stagnation in Sub-Saharan Africa’, World Development 12.1.

Wheeler, D. and Mody, A. (1992) “International investment location decisions: The Case of U.S.

Firms”. Journal of International Economics, 33.

Wood, A. and Berge, K. (1997) ‘Exporting Manufactures: Human Resources, Natural Resources,

and Trade Policy’, Journal of Development Studies 34.

Zhang, K. H. (2001) “Does Foreign Direct Investment Promote Economic Growth? Evidence

from East Asia and Latin America”. Contemporary Economic Policy, 19(2, April).

Unpublished Works

Ross, M (2003a) ‘How Does Mineral Wealth Affect the Poor?’, Unpublished Paper

Ross, M (2002) ‘Resources and Rebellion in Indonesia’, Unpublished Manuscript

Dah, K. F. and Khadijah, M. S. (2010) “The Contribution of Oil to the Economic Development of

Ghana: The Role of Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) and Government Policies”,

Page 160: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

146

Unpublished Masters Thesis, Department of Economics and Informatics, University

West.

Kapela, J. M. (2009) “Ghana’s New Oil: Cause For Jubilation Or Prelude To The Resource

Curse” Unpublished Masters Project Submitted to the Nicholas School of the

Environment of Duke University.

Official Publications

“GNPC says Jubilee Development on Schedule,” Middle East and Africa Oil and Gas Insights,

Dec. 1, 2008.

“Oil and Gas Find In Ghana,” (2008) Ghana Catholic Bishops’ Conference, Dialogue and

Advocacy for Good Governance Office, Accra, Ghana, December.

African Development Bank, (2007) “Africa’s Natural Resources: The Paradox of Plenty” in

“African Development Report 2007”. New York: Oxford University Press.

Akanni, P. (2007) Oil Wealth and Economic Growth in Oil Exporting African Countries. AERC

Research Paper 170, African Economic Research Consortium, Nairobi.

Alaska Permanent Fund (2009). www.pfd.state.ak.us

Alfaro, L, et al (2001) “FDI and Economic Growth: The Role of Financial Markets”. Working

Paper 01-083. Harvard Business School.

Al-Kasim, F., et al (2010) “Shrinking Oil: Does Weak Governance and Corruption Reduce

Volumes of Oil Produced?” CHR Michelsen Institute, U4 Issues N0.3.

Allen, R. and Bougha-Hagbe, J. (2008) “Ghana aims for Firmer Fiscal Discipline Before Oil

Flows,” IMF Survey Magazine, July 31.

Anokye, M. A. and Tweneboah, G. (2008) Foreign Direct Investment and Stock Market

Development: Ghana’s Evidence. MPRA Paper No. 11985.

Arab Monetary Fund, AMF (2005) Arab Financial Institutions and Development Financing and

Investment in the Arab Countries (in Arabic). Abu Dhabi.

Arbenser, L. (n.d.) “A General Equilibrium Analysis of the Impact of Inward FDI on Ghana: The

Role of Complementary Policies”, International Agricultural Trade Development.

Auty, R. (1994) “Industrial Policy Reform in Six Large Newly Industrializing Countries: The

Resource Curse Thesis”. World Development, 22.

Aydin, B., (2010), “Ghana: Will it be Gifted or Will it be Cursed?” IMF Manuscript.

Bank of Ghana, “Statistics: Inflation,” www.bog.gov.gh/index1.php?linkid=174.

Bank of Ghana, Policy Brief (2007) “A Framework for the Management of Oil Resources in

Ghana”. Dec. 12.

Page 161: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

147

Basu, A. and Srinivasan, K. 2002. “Foreign direct investment in Africa – Some Case Studies”.

IMF Working Paper WP/02/61. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Bellamy, et al. (2004) ‘Ecological Imperialism: The Curse of Capitalism’, Socialist Register 2004

Blomström, (1994) “Home country determinants of foreign direct investment: Evidence from

Sweden”. CEPR Discussion Paper No. 931, Centre for Economic Policy Research,

London.

Borensztein, et al. (1995) “How Does Foreign Direct Investment Affect Economic Growth?”

NBER Working Paper No. 5057. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,

Massachusetts.

Breisinger, C., et al (2009) “Managing Future Oil Revenue in Ghana: An Assessment of

Alternative Allocation Options”, Working Papers, No 1519, Institute for the World

Economy.

Calvo, G., et al (1993) “Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in Latin America:

The Role of External Factors”. IMF Staff Papers, Vol.40.

Campos N.F. and Kinoshita, Y. (2003) “Why Does FDI go Where it Goes? New Evidence from

the Transition Economies”. IMF Working Paper WP/03/228. International Monetary

Fund, Washington, D.C.

Cavnar, A. (2008) “Case Studies of Oil Governance: What Ghana can Learn about Oil Revenue

Management from the Rest of the World”. Ghana Centre for Democratic Development,

CDD-Ghana, Critical Perspectives No. 23.

Cavnar, A. (2008) “Averting the Resource Curse in Ghana: The Need for Accountability”

Briefing Paper, Ghana Centre for Democracy Development (CDD-Ghana), October.

Chenery, H.B., et al. (1986) Industrialization and Growth: A Comparative Study. Washington,

D.C.: The World Bank.

Civil Society Communiqué, “Ghana’s 2008 Oil for Development Forum,” Mankessim, Feb. 22–

23.

Cobham, A. (2001) “Capital Account Liberalisation and Impact on the Poor”. Paper Produced

for Oxfam and Bretton Woods project.

Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A (1998) ‘On Economic Causes of Civil War’, Oxford Economic Papers

No 50.

Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A (2002) The Political Economy of Secession, Washington, DC:

Development Research Group, World Bank.

Constitution of the Republic of Ghana.

Cotton, L. and Ramachandran, V. (2001) Foreign Direct Investment in Emerging Economies:

Lessons from Sub Saharan Africa. WIDER Paper No? World Institute for Development

Economics Research, Helsinki.

Page 162: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

148

Dagher, J., et al. (2010) Oil Windfalls in Ghana: A DSGE Approach. IMF Working Paper

WP/10/116.

Davis, J., et al. (2001) Stabilization and Savings Funds for Nonrenewable Resources: Experience

and Fiscal Policy Implications. IMF Occasional Paper No. 205.

De Gregorio, J. (2003) “The Role of Foreign Direct Investment and Natural Resources in

Economic Development”. Working Paper No 196. Central Bank of Chile, Santiago.

De Melo, M., C., et al (1997) “Circumstance and Choice: The Role of Initial Conditions Policies

in Transition Economies”. Policy Research Working Paper No. 1866, The World Bank,

Washington, D.C.

Diao, X. and Breisinger, C. (2010) “Managing Oil Revenue in Ghana - Controlling Spending is

the Key”, Policy Note 2, International Food Policy Research Institute.

Draft Oil and Gas Policy for Ghana, 2008.

Dunning, J., (1981) International Production and the Multinational Enterprise, Allen & Unwin,

London.

Edwards, S. 1990. “Capital flows, Foreign Direct Investment and Debt – Equity Swaps in

Developing Countries”. NBER Working Paper No. 3497.

Eifert, B., et al. (2003) ‘The Political Economy of Fiscal Policy and Economic Management in

Oil Exporting Countries’ in J.M. Davis, R. Ossowski and A. Fedelino (eds), Fiscal Policy

Formulation and Implementation in Oil-Producing Countries, Washington, DC:

International Monetary Fund.

EIR (2003) ‘Extractive Industries Review Report, Annex 5 – Government’s View’ Washington

DC: World Bank; Oil, Gas, Mining and Chemicals Group

EITI (2008) EITI Press Release, 22nd February, Accra, Ghana

Gary, I. (n.d.) “Oil and Gas Revenues, Funds and State Budgets: Minimising Leakages and

Maximizing Transparency and Accountability in the Hydrocarbon Value Chain”. UNDP

Discussion Paper No 6.

Ghana Petroleum Regulatory Authority Bill, 2011.

Ghana’s Petroleum Sector: Preliminary Macroeconomic Impact,” in “Ghana: 2008 Article IV

Consultation. IMF, Staff Report”. October.

GIC (1991) Investment Code (Areas of Special Priority) Instrument. Accra: Ghana Investment

Centre.

Goldsmith, S. (n.d.) "The Alaska Permanent Fund Dividend: An Experiment in Wealth

Distribution." Geneva

Goldwyn, D. L. (2008) Drilling Down the Civil Society Guide to Extractive Industry Revenues

and the EITI. The Revenue Watch Institute.

Page 163: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

149

Government of Ghana (2010) “Medium-Term National Development Policy Framework: Ghana

Shared Growth and Development Agenda (GSGDA), 2010-2013”, Policy Framework,

Vol.1. National Development Planning Commission (NDPC).

Hanson, G.H. (2001) “Should Countries Promote Foreign Direct Investment?”, G-24 Discussion

Paper No. 9. UNCTAD Geneva.

IMF (2005) ‘Revised Good on Good Practice on Fiscal Transparency’, Washington DC:

International Monetary Fund

IMF, (1993), Balance of Payment Manual, 5th Edition, Washington DC.

IMF, (2004) Lifting the Oil Curse: Improving Petroleum Revenue Management in Sub-Saharan

Africa.

IMF, (2007) Guide on Resource Revenue Transparency.

International Finance Corporation, (2008) “Environmental and Social Review Summary,

Kosmos Energy,” Project Number 27550, December 22.

ISSER, (2004) The State of the Ghanaian Economy in 2003. Accra: Institute of Statistical, Social

and Economic Research, University of Ghana.

Karl, T. L. (2005) Understanding Resource Curse” in Covering Oil: a Reporter’s Guide to

Energy and Development, New York: Open Society Institute.

Kwabena, M. (2002), Communities, Civil Society Organisations and the Management of Mineral

Wealth. Mining, Minerals and Sustainable Development No.16, International Institute for

Environment and Development (IIED).

Lehmann, A. (1999) “Country Risks and the Investment Activity of U.S. Multinationals in

Developing Countries”. IMF Working Paper No. 133. International Monetary Fund,

Washington.

Leite, C. and Weidmann, J. (1999) Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption,

and, Economic Growth, IMF Working Paper WP/99/85, Washington, DC: International

Monetary Fund

Lim, E. (2001) “Determinants of, and the Relationship Between Foreign Direct Investment and

Growth: A Summary of Recent Literature”. IMF Working Paper No. WP/01/175.

International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Mähler, A. (2010) “Nigeria: A Prime Example of the Resource Curse? Revisiting the Oil-

Violence Link in the Niger Delta”. GIGA Working Papers, No.120.

Majid, A. (2006) “The Contribution of Oil Sector to Arab Economic Development”, OFID

Pamphlet Series 34.

Maloney, W. (2002) ‘Missed Opportunities: Innovation and Resource-Based Growth in Latin

America’ Unpublished paper, Washington: World Bank.

Page 164: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

150

McMahon, G. (1997). “The Natural Resource Curse: Myth or Reality?” Mimeo, World Bank

Institute.

Mensah, K. (2008) “The Discovery of Oil in Ghana – Time for a Reality Check”, Briefing Paper

Vol.9, No.1 Ghana Centre for Democratic Development (CDD-Ghana).

Mody, A and Murshid, A.P. (2002) “Growing up with Capital Flows”. IMF Working Paper

WP/02/75. International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.

Morisset, J. (2000) “Foreign Direct Investment in Africa”, Policy Research Working Paper, 2481.

Moss, T. and Young, L. (2009) Saving Ghana From Its Oil: The Case for Direct Cash

Distribution, Working Paper 186, Centre for Global Development.

Norway, Act Relating to the Government Petroleum Fund, art 1-2, 1990

Norwegian Ministry of Finance

Nankani, G. (1979), Development Problems of Mineral Exporting Countries, Staff Working

Paper 354 (August), Washington, DC: World Bank

Official Gazette, (1983) Ghana National Petroleum Corporation Law, 1983, (PNDC Law 64).

Osei, R. D. and Domfe, G. (2008) Oil Production in Ghana: Implications for Economic

Development (ARI). Institute of Statistical Social and Economic Research (ISSER), University of Ghana

Oxfam (2002), Oxfam Briefing Paper 19: Africa at the Crossroads, Oxford: Oxfam

Oxfam America/ISODEC (2009) “New Producers and the Challenges of Transparency: The Case

of Ghana”. African Studies Program, March.

Pigato, M. A. (2001) “The foreign direct investment environment in Africa”. Africa Region

Working Paper Series No. 15. The World Bank, Washington, D.C

Prasad, E., et al. (2003) Effects of Financial Globalization on Developing Countries: Some

Empirical Evidence. IMF Occasional Paper 220. Washington, DC: International

Monetary Fund.

Rosser, A. (2004) Why Did Indonesia Overcome the Resource Curse?, IDS Working Paper 222,

Brighton: IDS

Rosser, A. (2006) “The Political Economy of the Resource Curse: A Literature Survey”. Institute

of Development Studies, Working Paper No 268.

Sachs, J. and Sievers, S. (1998) “FDI in Africa”. In Africa Competitive Report, 1998. Geneva:

World Economic Forum.

Sachs, J.D. and Warner A.M. (1997) ‘Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth’

Development Discussion Paper No. 51

Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. (1995). “Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth”,

NBER Working Paper, No. 5398.

Page 165: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

151

Sala-i-Martin, X. and Subramanian, A. (2003) “Addressing the Natural Resource Curse: An

Illustration from Nigeria”, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

Skancke, M. (2003) ‘Fiscal Policy and Petroleum Fund Management in Norway’ in J. Davis, R.

Ossowski and A. Fedelino (ed.), Fiscal Policy Formulation and Implementation in Oil-

Producing Countries, Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund.

Skocpol, T. (1982) ‘Rentier State and Shi’a Islam in the Iranian Revolution’, Theory and Society

II.

Snyder, R. (2003) Does Lootable Wealth Breed Disorder? A Political Economy of Extraction

Framework, Notre Dame, Kellogg Institute: 31

Stauffer, T. R. (1984) Accounting for “Wasting Assets”: Income Measurement for Oil and

Mineral-Exporting Rentier States. Vienna: OPEC Fund for International Development.

Stevens, P. (2003) ‘Resource Impact: A Curse or a Blessing’, Draft Working Paper, Centre for

Energy, Petroleum and Mineral Law and Policy, University of Dundee

Stiglitz, J.E. (2005) “Making Natural Resources into Blessing Rather than a Curse”, in Covering

Oil: A Reporter’s Guide to Energy and Development, New York: Open Society Institute.

The Norwegian Ministry of Finance, (2009) “The Norwegian Petroleum Sector”.

The Norwegian Ministry of Finance, 2010, The Government Pension Fund-Global, Asset

Management Department.

The Norwegian Ministry of Petroleum and Energy (2009) Facts 2009: The Norwegian Petroleum

Sector.

The World Bank, (2009) “Economy-Wide Impact of Oil Discovery in Ghana”, Africa Region

Report, No. 47321-GH.

Truman, E. M. (2008) “A Blueprint for Sovereign Wealth Fund Best Practices”, Peterson

Institute for International Economics.

Tsikata, G.K., et al (2000) Determinants of Foreign Direct Investment in Ghana. London:

Overseas Development Institute/University of Ghana.

UNCTAD (1999) Foreign Direct Investment in Africa: Performance and Potential. United

Nations Publications UNCTAD/ITE/IIT/Misc.15. New York and Geneva: United

Nations.

UNCTAD, (2002) Foreign Direct Investment Statistics.

UNCTAD (2000) Capital Flows and Growth in Africa. New York: United Nations.

World Bank (1996). Annual Report on Development, World Bank Group, Washington DC

World Bank (2005) Economic Development and Prospects: Oil Booms and Revenue

Management, Washington, D.C.

Page 166: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

152

World Bank (2007) “Country Experience with EITI Part 1: World Bank Cambodia, Oil and Gas

Special Supplement”, Petroleum Sector Briefing Note (5), July.

Yate, D. (2009) “Enhancing the Governance of Africa’s Oil Sector” South African Institute of

International Affairs (SAIIA) Occasional Paper, No.51.

Conference Papers

Ake, C. (1972) “Development for What and By Whom”, A Paper Presented at a Conference on

Development Strategies Organised by the Dag Hammerskjoild in Arusha, Tanzania.

Akyeampong, J. (2008) “Petroleum Licensing and Control” Presentation at Workshop on Oil and

Gas Sector Development in Ghana, Ghana Institute of Management and Public

Administration [GIMPA], Accra, Ghana, Feb. 27.

Auty, R. (2001) “Why Resource Endowments can Undermine Economic Development: Concepts

and Case Studies”. Paper Prepared for the BP-Amoco Seminar, Lincoln College, Oxford.

28–29 November.

Bryan C. L and, World Bank (2008) “Key Roles in Resource Management: Who will Play

Them?”, Presentation to Workshop on Oil and Gas Sector Development in Ghana,

GIMPA, Accra, Ghana, Feb. 27, 2008.

Huno, F. and Konda, K. (2010) “Issues on Oil and National Development in Ghana, 2007 –

2010”, Ghana’s National Forum on Oil and Gas Development GIMPA, Accra, Ghana

25-26 February 2008.

MacIntyre, A. (2003) Institutions and the Political Economy of Corruption in Developing

Countries, Discussion Paper, Workshop on Corruption, Stanford University, 31st

January–1st February.

Manu, T. (2008) “Government Take”. Presentation at Workshop on Oil and Gas Sector

Development in Ghana, GIMPA, Accra, Ghana, Feb. 27.

Mateaw, S. (n.d.) “Oil’s Challenge to Ghana’s Democratic Development” Paper Presented at

DANNIDA Development Day Event at Copenhagen.

Nweke, G. A. (1984) “Nigeria and the World Economy”, Proceeding of the Twelfth Annual

Conference of the Nigerian Society of International Affairs, Held at University of Illorin,

5th -8th November.

Obwona, M. B. (2004) “Foreign Direct Investment in Africa”. In Financing Pro-Poor Growth:

AERC Senior Policy Seminar VI, Kampala, Uganda, 2–4 March 2004 – Seminar Papers.

Nairobi: African Economic Research Consortium.

Olsen, W.H. (2002) ‘Petroleum Revenue Management – An Industry Perspective’. Workshop on

Petroleum Revenue Management, Oil, Gas, Mining and Chemicals Department of the

WGB and ESMAP, Washington DC.

Page 167: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

153

Stevens, P. (2005) Promoting Economic Development through the Oil and Gas Sector, Paper

Presented to The Royal Institute for International Affairs, London

Newspapers and Magazines

“Ghana’s Jubilee Moves Ahead,” International Oil Daily, October 10, 2008.

“Kosmos Seeks More Credit for Jubilee,” African Energy, Oct. 17, 2008.

“The Upstream Petroleum Industry in Ghana,” GNPC Supplement. The Ghanaian Times, July

11, 2008.

Agence France Presse, “Ghana to Fly with New-Found Oil or Flounder?” December 5, 2008.

BBC Worldwide Monitoring, (2008) “Ghana: Opposition Hopeful to Ensure Development in Oil

Find Area if Elected,” Dec. 22.

Daily Graphic, (2008) Status Report on the Jubilee Field Oil and Gas Development, by

Management of Ghana National Petroleum Corporation. July, 16th.

Daily Graphic (2008) The Upstream Petroleum Industry in Ghana—Oil and Gas Exploration,

Development and Production, by the Management of Ghana National Petroleum

Corporation (GNPC), July 10th.

Esau, I (2008) “Jubilee Celebration: Ghana Oil Field likely to Require Second FPSO [Floating

Production, Storage, and Offloading Vessel] as well Boosts Play,” Upstream, Dec. 19,

2008.

Ghana News Agency, (2008) “Norway to Sensitize Ghana in Management of Petroleum

Revenue,” July 17, 2008.

Green, M. (2008) “Crude Realities: Can Ghana Escape Africa’s Oil Curse?” Financial Times,

Aug. 27.

Kemp, P. (2009) “Ghana: Ready to Gush,” Energy Compass, January 23.

News Service, “Ghana: Government Prepares to Battle the ‘Oil Curse,’” 22 April, 2008.

Internet Materials

Addotey, A. (2010) Oil Receipts and National Development.

http://www.danquahinstitute.org/news/1222-oil-receipts-and-national-development.html

Agyemang, F. (2010) Stepping on the Oil to Accelerate Industrial Growth.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=178900

Ahovi, K (2011) Findings and Observations in Ghana’s Oil and Gas Exploration.

http://zotomelo.blogspot.com/2011/05/findings-and-observations-in-ghanas-oil.html. Retrieved on May 28th 2011.

Alexeev, M. and Conrad, R. (2008) The Elusive Curse of Oil. http://www.mypage.iu.edu/-

malexeev/alexeev_conrad_result_feb_08.pdf Retrieved on 12th December, 2010.

Page 168: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

154

Amin, A. M. (2010) Ghana: Country's Oil Revenue Management - Transparency or Prudence?

http://www.africancrisis.co.za/Article.php?ID=67614&. Retrieved on August 30th, 2010.

Amin, A. M. (2011) Ghana’s Petroleum Revenue Management Bill Promises Greater

Transparency and Accountability

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=204394

Amin, A. M. (2011) Slippery Steps in Oil Revenue Management,

http://news.peacefmonline.com/features/201107/58684.php Retrieved on 29th July, 2011.

Amin, A.M. (2010) Collateralization Of Ghana’s Future Oil Revenues.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=197594

Ampong, C. H. (2010) Why Ghana Could be the Right Place for Foreign Investors? (Part

1)http://ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/features/artikel.php?ID=175369

Anny, A (2009) Ghana’s Oil Boom Raises Questions Of Transparency

http://adinkravibes.blogspot.com/2009/02/ghanas-oil-boom-raises-questions-of.html

Asenso-Okyere, (2010)Open Special Oil Account In Ghana,

http://www.modernghana.com/news/161171/1/open-special-oil-account-in-ghana-prof-

asenso-okye.html

At a Glance: Ghana. http://www.unicef.org/infobycountry/ghana_statistics.html

Avoiding the Oil Curse; Ghana Repeating Nigeria’s Mistakes

http://news.myjoyonline.com/business/201006/47983.asp

Boadi, B. (2008) Guarding Against The Stealing Of Ghana's Oil

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=151781

Boateng, J. Y. Enhancing Business—Community Relations, Ghana Mining Industry, Case Study,

at www.new-academy.ac.uk

Broad, M. (2009) Ghana's Oil Boom: Blessing Or Curse?

http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/8081717.stm

Civil Society, http://eiti.org/supporters/civilsociety

Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (2000) Greed and Grievance in Civil War. Washington, DC: World

Bank, http://worldbank.org/research/conflict/papers/greedhtm

Commentary On The Environmental Impact Of Ghana’s Emerging Oil Industry On The

Livelihood Of Inhabitants In The Catchment Areas.

http://www.gbcghana.com/index.php?id=1.182992

Cudjoe, F. (2010) Effective Utilization of Oil Revenue, Transparency and Accountability...and

Local Content Issues, http://www.afrik-news.com/article18540.html. Retrieved on

December 11th, 2010.

Page 169: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

155

Dake, M. (2010) Ghana's 2010 Oil 'Boom': Ensuring Public Interest Over Private Gain.

http://pambazuka.org/en/category/features/62534

Democracy Drives Oil Debates in Ghana,

http://www.africanexecutive.com/modules/magazine/articles.php?article=5593

Di John, J. (2010) The ‘Resource Curee’: Theory and Evidence (ARI)

http://www.realinstitutioelcano.org/wps/portal.rielcano_eng/Content?WCM_GLOBAL_C

ONTENT=/elcano/elcano_in/zonas_in/ari172-2010.

Dogbevi E. K. and Seidu, D. (2011) Tight Monetary, Fiscal Discipline Trigger Increase in FDI to

Ghana – IMF, http://www.ghanabusinessnews.com/wp-

content/uploads/2009/01/investments.jpj

Egu, F. K. (n.d.) Managing Ghana’s Oil Revenue: GNPC is Capable.

http://www.ghanaoilandgasonline.com/index_046.htm

Exploration and Production in the Marine Environment, by the Australian Institute of Petroleum

http://www.aip.com.an/industry/fact_exploration_marine.htm.

Extractive Industries Transparency Initiative, see - http://www.eitransparency.org/

Ezeala, P. (2011) Oxfam and Partners hail Ghana for Enacting Law on Petroleum Revenue

http://www.oxfamamerica.org/articles/oxfam-and-partners-hail-ghana-for-enacting-law-on-petroleum-revenue

FDI to Africa Continues to Fall, UNCTAD Survey Reveal,

http://daressalaam.unic.org/2011/07/26/fdi-to-africa-continues-to-fall-unctad-survey-

reveal/ Fighting the Resource Curse through Cash Transfers,

http://www.cgodev.org/section/initiatives/active/revenues_distribution

Five Indicators of Development/. http://www.idrc.ca/its/ev-28769-201-1-DO_TOPIC.html

Foreign Direct Investment ... Ghana in April 2010!

http://communityanalyticsca.blogspot.com/2010/05/foreign-direct-investment-ghana-

in.html

Foreign Direct Investment: A Lead Driver for Sustainable Development?

http://www.stakeholderforum.org/policy/economic/fdi.pdf

Gabriel, J (2010) Ghana Turns the Taps as Oil Producer.

http://www.businessdayonline.com/NG/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&i

d=16750:ghana-turns-the-taps-as-oil-producer&catid=172:world&Itemid=618

Gary and Karl, T. L. (2003) “Bottom of the Barrel: Africa’s Oil Boom and the Poor” Baltimore,

MD: Catholic Relief Services. www.crs.org/publications/showpdf.cfm?pdf_id=183

Gary, I. (2011) Oil Boom Transparency Moves Made by Ghana,

http://www.resourceinvestor.com/News/2011/5/Pages/-Oil-Boom-Transparency-Moves-

Made-by-Ghana.aspx

Page 170: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

156

Gast, B. (2008) Ghana: Optimistic About Oil. http://www.globalenvision.org/2008/02/27/ghana-

optimistic-about-oil

Generally Accepted Principles and Practices (GAPP)—Santiago Principles. International

Working Group of Sovereign Wealth Funds, http://www.iwg-swf.org/pubs/gapplist.htm.

Ghana as a Case Study for Contract Disclosures

http://wbi.worldbank.org/wbi/news/2011/07/18/ghana-case-study-contract-disclosures

Ghana - Foreign investment, http://www.nationsencyclopedia.com/Africa/Ghana-FOREIGN-

INVESTMENT.html

Ghana Oil and Gas NEWS (2010) Extent Of Oil And Gas Deposits In Ghana And Environmental

And Strategic Concerns. http://www.ghanaoilandgasonline.com/index_051.htm

Ghana Oil Law aims to Keep the People Happy. (2011) http://dailytimes.com.ng/article/ghana-

oil-law-aims-keep-people-happy. Retrieved on 30th May 2011.

Ghana Receives $2.5b, Becomes 7th Largest Recipient of FDIs in Africa, as Oil Attracts

Investors http://www.ghanabusinessnews.com/2011/07/27/ghana-receives-2-5b-becomes-

7th-largest-recipient-of-fdis-in-africa-as-oil-attracts-investors/

Ghana, http://www.business-anti-corruption.com/country-profiles/sub-saharan-

africa/ghana/background-information/

Ghana: Country Brief,

http://web.worldbank.org/wbsite/external/countries/africaext/ghanaextn/0,,menupk:35196

2~pagepk:141132~pipk:141107~thesitepk:351952,00.html

Ghana: E-Governance Could Make Oil Business Transparent,

http://ghanaoilonline.org/2010/06/ghana-e-governance-could-make-oil-business-transparent/ Retrieved on 30th July, 2010.

Ghana: Government Prepares to Battle the “Oil Curse” http://www.irinnews.org/report.aspx?reportid=77851

Ghana: Slow Progress on Oil Policy http://www.irinnews.org/report.aspx?ReportID=88001

Ghana’s Oil Boom - Will it Fuel Conflict?

http://inec.org/blog/2011/feb/21/ghana%E2%80%99s-oil-boom-%E2%93-will-it-fuel-

conflict Retrieved on December 2nd 2010.

Ghana’s Oil Find... Tall Dreams and Risk of Conflict (2010) http://treasureafrik.com/ghana-

oil.php

Ghana Oil Law Aims at Stability, Transparency in Hiring

http://main.omanobserver.om/node/51675 Retrieved on April 2nd, 2011.

Page 171: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

157

Ghana’s Oil Wealth has often Fueled Conflict rather than Development

http://michigancitizen.com/ghanas-oil-wealth-has-often-fueled-conflict-rather-than-

development-p9341-78.htm Retrieved on Sat, 08 Jan, 2011

Ghana’s Per Capital Income nearing US$ 1000 by 2010? www.ghanaconscious.ghanathink.org

Ghana: What Lack of Transparency Can Do to Oil-Producing States - Beware Ghana!

http://allafrica.com/stories/201011261165.html Retrieved on November 28th, 2010.

Ghanadot E. A. (n.d) Who Wants a Financial Stake in an Oil Conflict Zone?,

http://www.ghanadot.com/commentary.ablorh.oilconflict.031110.html

Global Witness. (2005) Extracting Transparency: The Need for an International Financial

Reporting Standard for the Extractive Industries. London: Global Witness.

http://www.globalwitness.org/cgibin/parser.pl/0104/www.globalwitness.org/media_librar

y_get.php/245/1235870468/IFRS

GNPC, www.gnpcghana.com/aboutus/newseventsdetails.asp?nwsiD=21

Gobah, T. (2011) Ghana Will Follow Best Examples of Oil Management.

http://www.graphic.com.gh/news/page.php?news=12465. Retrieved on 13th April 2011

Herb, M. (2003) ‘No Representation without Taxation? Rents, Development and Democracy’,

Unpublished Worldwide Web document, available at URL:www.gsu.edu/~polmfh/herb_r

entier_state.pdf

Heuty, A. and Aristi, J. (2010) “Fool’s Gold: Assessing the Performance of Alternative Fiscal

Instruments during the Commodities Boom and the Global Crisis”. Revenue Watch

Institute. http://expatriatepay.blogspot.com/2010/03/ghana-accra-cost-of-living-january-

2010.html

Hufstader, C. (2008) The Coming Oil Boom in Ghana.

http://www.publishwhatyoupay.org/resources/coming-oil-boom-ghana

IMF Survey: Oil Offers Hope of Middle-Income Status for Ghana.

www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/survey/so/.../int021710a.htm

Indicators Of Sustainable Development: Guidelines And Methodologies

http://www.un.org/esa/sustdev/natlinfo/indicators/isdms2001/isd-ms2001isd.htm#Poverty

Is this a Convenient Step Towards the ‘Curse’ of Oil? http://ghanaian-chronicle.com/features/is-

this-a-convenient-step-towards-the-%E2%80%98curse%E2%80%99-of-oil/

Isham, J., et al (2002) ‘The Varieties of Rentier Experience: How Natural Resource Export

Structures Affect the Political Economy of Economic Growth’, Worldwide Web

document, available at www.middlebury.edu/NR/rdonlyres/23035072-BFD1-43A1-

923C-99CF11831F32/0/0308.pdf

ISODEC/Oxfam (2009) Ghana’s Oil ‘Hot Spot’ Must Proceed With Caution

http://www.oilandgaspress.com/wp/2009/02/20/ghana%E2%80%99s-oil-

%E2%80%98hot-spot%E2%80%99-must-proceed-with-caution-isodec-oxfam/

Page 172: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

158

Jaques, S. (2011) Ghana: The New Land Of Opportunity For Oil & Gas Investment,

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=213079. Retrieved on 10th July, 2011.

Kale, (2010) How Does Ghana Avoid the Oil Curse?

http://povertynewsblog.blogspot.com/2010/12/how-does-ghana-avoid-oil-curse.html

Kalenga, M. (2011) A Place at the Table: Civil Society Participation in the EITI,

http://eiti.org/blog/place-table-civil-society-participation-eiti. Retrieved August 11th,

2011.

Kingson, K. W. (2010) Concerns Over Ghana’s Petroleum Exploration Bill

Kobbie, A. J. (2010) Why Our Oil Will Be A Blessing.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=180632

Kokutse, F. and Pitman, T. (2010) Ghana to Begin Pumping Oil for First Time

http://www.wtop.com/?sid=2200390&nid=111 Retrieved on Saturday, Jan 8, 2011

Kosmos Energy, www.kosmosenergy.com/ghana.html

Kpando Konda, F. H. (2010) Opinion: Ghana’s Oil-Find and Her Development.

http://news.myjoyonline.com/features/201011/55056.asp

Kwaben Okyere, K. (2009) Ghana’s Oil and Gas: The Peoples’ Connection.

http://www.theghanaianjournal.com/2009/10/02/ghana%E2%80%99s-oil-and-gas-the-

peoples%E2%80%99-connection/

Lam R. and Wantchekon L. (2003) Political Dutch Disease, NYU Working Paper, Web

Document, http://www.nyu.edu/gsas/dept/politics/faculty/wantcheko/research/lr-04-

10.pdf

Lamptey, A. (2010) Developmental Benefits of Ghana’s Oil Find.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=198338

Marbell, E. and Tsiboe-Darko, A. (2001) The Flow of FDI to Ghana.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/features/artikel.php?ID=18988

McConnell, T. (2008) Ghana Votes for a Share of the Oil.

http://www.newstatesman.com/africa/2008/12/ghana-oil-democracy-president. Retrieved on October, 2nd 2010.

Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning, 2008 Budget Statement, “Managing Future Oil

Revenues,” 420–421, www.mofep.gov.gh/documents/SECTION%20EIGHT.pdf.

Ministry of Finance and Economic Planning, Republic of Ghana, “Ghana’s budget statement for

2008,” www.mofep.gov.gh/budget2008.cfm.

Mulligan, C. B. (2011) How Oil Wealth Undercuts Democracy in Libya.

http://globaloileconomy.blogspot.com/2011/04/how-oil-wealth-undercuts-democracy-

in.html. Retrieved on May, 3rd 2011.

Page 173: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

159

Myers K. (2010) What Difference Will Oil Make? An Energy Analyst Considers Ghana's Oil

Boom http://www.revenuewatch.org/news/news-article/ghana/what-difference-will-oil-

make-energy-analyst-considers-ghanas-oil-boom

Nana, A. (2010) Ghana Oil II - Transforming the Ghanaian Economy

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=176359

Nana, A. (2010) The Economic Prospects of the Oil Discovery to the Nation

http://www.thestatesmanonline.com/pages/news_detail.php?newsid=9824&section=1.

Retrieved on November, 12th, 2010.

Nana, A. H. (2009) Creating a Framework for Ghanaians to Benefit from Oil Rich Ghana

http://www.modernghana.com/newsp/220829/1/pagenum3/creating-a-framework-for-

ghanaians-to-benefit-from.html#continue. Retrieved on 19th October, 2010.

Nana, A. H. (2010) Can Oil Succeed Where Gold Failed Ghanaians?

Nevin, T. (2011) We Will Avoid the Oil Curse Ghana.

http://findarticles.com/p/articles/mi_qa5327/is_373/ai_n57181670/ Retrieved on April

2nd, 2011.

Neubauer, C. (2010) Ghana Oil Revenues To Gush Without Spending Plan. The Washington

Times Thursday, July 8, 2010 http://www.washingtontimes.com/news/2010/jul/8/oil-

revenues-to-gush-in-ghana-but-no-spending-plan/

New Oil—and a Huge Challenge—for Ghana

http://news.nationalgeographic.com/news/energy/2010/12/1012115-oil-ghana-

environment-jubilee/

Nguyen-Thanh, D., Good Financial Governance (GFG) http://www.gtz.de/en/aktuell/15228.htm

Oil Boom Transparency Moves Made by Ghana (2011)

http://www.resourceinvestor.com/News/2011/5/Pages/-Oil-Boom-Transparency-Moves-Made-by-Ghana.aspx. Retrieved May 20th 2011.

Oil Boom: Will Ghana Learn From the Mistakes of Others? (2010)

http://ghanaoilwatch.org/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=624:oil-

boom-will-ghana-learn-from-the-mistakes-of-others&catid=6:ghana-oil-a-gas-

news&Itemid=27

Oil Contributes Over $550m of $1.3b FDI in Ghana (2010)

http://www.ghanabusinessnews.com/2010/12/14/oil-contributes-over-550m-of-1-3b-fdi-

in-ghana/

Oil Find To Propel Ghana into a Middle Income Status (2010)

http://www.ghana.gov.gh/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=3976:oil-

find-to-propel-ghana-into-a-middle-income-status-prof-&catid=28:general-

news&Itemid=162

Oil gives Ghana Hope (2010)http://news.myjoyonline.com/features/201010/53631.asp

Page 174: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

160

Olters, J. (2007) “Old Curses, New Approaches? Fiscal Benchmarks for Oil-Producing Countries

in Sub-Saharan Africa,” IMF Working Paper, WP/07/107. Washington, DC: IMF, May.

www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2007/wp07107.pdf.

Osabutey, P. D. (2010) Ghana's Oil can Breed Violence If… - Ghanaian Chronicle

http://www.modernghana.com/news/287322/1/ghanas-oil-can-breed-violence-if.html

Otabil , A (2010) Need For National Development Strategy To Govern Oil Revenue.

http://ghana.gov.gh/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=2595:need-for-

national-development-strategy-to-govern-oil-revenue&catid=28:general-

news&Itemid=162

Oxford Analytica, (2009) Oil Revenue Challenges Ghana: Can the Country Avoid the Pitfalls

Other African Nations have Faced? http://www.forbes.com/2009/11/18/ghana-oil-angola-

nigeria-business-africa-oxford.html

Pakistan Today, (2010) Ghana Enters New Oil Era with Jubilee Launch

http://pakistantoday.com.pk/pakistan-news/Foreign/16-Dec-2010/Ghana-enters-new-oil-

era-with-Jubilee-launch Retrieved 17th December, 2010

Peak Oil and Economic Growth: Where Do We Go From Here? (2008)

http://www.theoildrum.com/node/3759

Political Economy of Oil, http://globaloileconomy.blogspot.com/2011/04/how-oil-wealth-

undercuts-democracy-in.html. Retrieved on April 29th, 2011.

Public Agenda/Ghana (2009) Gov’t Changes Plans For Ghana’s Oil

http://business.peacefmonline.com/news/200912/35068.php

Publish What You Pay, www.publishwhatyoupay.org.

PWYP (2005) ‘Submission to IMF on Draft Guide on Resource Revenue Transparency’

http://pwyp.gn.apc.org/english/pdf/statements/pwyp_imf_180205.pdf

Quandzie, E. (2010) FDIs into Africa Rise $32b on Oil, Metals Exports – World Bank

http://ghanaoilonline.org/2011/04/fdis-into-africa-rise-32b-on-oil-metals-exports-

%E2%80%93-world-bank/ Retrieved on 10th April, 2011.

Quandzie, E. (2011) Ghana Receives $2.5b, becomes 7th Largest Recipient of FDIs in Africa, as

Oil Attracts Investors. http://www.ghanabusinessnews.com/2011/07/27/ghana-receives-2-

5b-becomes-7th-largest-recipient-of-fdis-in-africa-as-oil-attracts-investors/

Quartey, L (2011) Ghana’s FDI Inflow Registers 70 Percent Increase

http://www.theafricareport.com/archives2/business/5141660-ghanas-fdi-inflow-registers-

70-percent-increase.html Retrieved on 17th June, 201.

Resource Curse or Blessing? Africa’s Management of its Extractive Industries: Hearing before

the Committee on Foreign Relations,” 110th Cong., 2d sess., 2008,

www.foreign.senate.gov/hearings/2008/hrg080924a.html.

Resource Curse, http://www.wikipedia.org/wiki/Resource_Curse.html

Page 175: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

161

Revenue Watch Institute, “Helping Ghana Manage its Oil Wealth Wisely”,

http://www.revenuewatch.org/parliaments

Ross, C. (2010) Potential Implications of Oil in Ghana

http://www.yourvox.org/news/ViewArticle.php?id=29

Ross, M. (2001). Extractive Sectors and the Poor. Oxfam America.

www.oxfarmaerica.org/eirexport/index.html.

Sambah, T. A. (n.d.) Ghana – A Shining Example of Democratic Governance Courting the

World.

http://ghana.gov.gh/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=154:ghana-a-

shining-example-of-democratic-governance-courting-the-world-&-

catid=24:features&Itemid=167 Retrieved on December 2nd 2010.

Sapa-AFP: (n.p.) Ghana Becomes An Oil Nation.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=199503

Sarpong, F. (2011) FDI into Ghana up by 92.95% in first qtr 2011.

http://zotomelo.blogspot.com/2011/05/fdi-into-ghana-up-by-9295-in-first.html. Retrieved

on 22nd May, 2011.

Smith, J. (2010) New Oil and a Huge Challenge for Ghana,

http://news.nationalgeographic.com/news/energy/2010/12/1012115-oil-ghana-

environment-jubilee/

The Commission on Growth and Development, (2009) The Growth Report: Strategies for

Sustained Growth and Inclusive Development. www.growthcommission.org

The Ghana Oil Watchdog (2009) Ghana’s Oil Find – What is our Real Stake?

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/features/artikel.php?ID=171858

The Petroleum Sector in Ghana,

http://ghanaoilwatch.org/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=1463:the-

petroleum-sector-in-ghana&catid=6:ghana-oil-a-gas-news&Itemid=27 Retrieved on May

16th, 2011.

The Resource Curse,

http://www.globalization101.org/index.php?file=issue&pass1=subs&id=355

The World Bank (2006) “From Curse to Blessing: Natural Resources and Institutional Quality”.

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTENMAT/641999551162240805462/21125342/9fR

OMCurse.pdf Retrieved on November 20th, 2010.

Two-day Development Forum Opens in Western Region

(2010)http://www.ghanabusinessnews.com/2010/09/26/two-day-development-forum-

opens-in-western-region/

Twum, C. and Ovie, M. (2010) Ghana: Infrastructure, a Must to Empower National Development

http://allafrica.com/stories/201003251032.html

Twumasi, P. (2010) Conflict to Thrive With Black Gold in Ghana.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=180289

Page 176: OIL AND NATIONAL DEVELOPMENT IN GHANA

162

UK’s Tullow Uncovers Oil in Ghana,” BBC News, June 18, 2008.

http://news.bbc.co.uk/go/pr/fr/-/2/hi/business/6764549.stm.

UNCTAD (2002) Investment Policy of Ghana, http://www.unctad.org

UNCTAD, 2007 World Investment Report, Part II, Transnational Corporations, Extractive

Industries and Development

http://www.unctad.org/Template/WebFlyer.asp?int/temID=4361&lang=II

UNCTAD. 2009. "Foreign Direct Investment Database." http://www.unctad.org/.

US Agency for International Development (2010) Ghana: Governing Justly and Democratically.

http://www.usaid.gov. Retrieved on 12th January, 2011.

Veep (2010) Oil Alone Can't Make Ghana Middle Income Nation.

http://www.ghananewsagency.org/s_economics/r_20884/

Walters, D. (2010) Ghana and the Discovery of Oil: Will Ghana Escape the Black Gold Curse?

http://www.consultancyafrica.com/index.php?option=com_content&view=article&id=62

4:ghana-and-the-discovery-of-oil-will-ghana-escape-the-black-gold-

curse&catid=82:african-industry-a-business&Itemid=266

When Ghana Oil Start to Flow. http://www.ghananewsagency.org/s_economics/r_21787/

Will Ghana’s Oil Lubricate Her Hopes and Aspirations?

http://www.ghananewsagency.org/details/Features/WILL-GHANA-S-OIL-LUBRICATE-

HER-HOPES-AND-ASPIRATIONS/?ci=10&ai=30249

Wolfensohn, (2010) Ghana Must Consolidate Economy with Oil Wealth.

http://www.ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=198693

World Bank, “IDA at Work—Ghana: Accelerating Growth to Halve Poverty,” Briefing Paper,

August 2008, http://siteresources.worldbank.org/IDA/Resources/IDA-Ghana.pdf

Yeboah, I. (2008) “Ghana’s Oil: Chief Hopes Opposition and Government are not in Bed,” Joy

FM Website, June 29. http://news.myjoyonline.com/news/200806/17706.asp.

Yeboah, S. (2010) Regulating Ghana's Oil and Gas Sector: What should be the Parameters?

http://www.modernghana.com/news/259623/1/regulating-ghanas-oil-and-gas-sector-

what-should-b.html. Retrieved on December, 15th 2010.

Yeboah, S. (2011) Ghana’s Oil Wealth: Delusion of Grandeur?

http://ghanaweb.com/GhanaHomePage/NewsArchive/artikel.php?ID=202818

2010 Bid for Ghana Oil Field Rebuffed: Kosmos Energy of U.S. Rejects $5 Billion Offer From

CNOOC and GNPC.

http://online.wsj.com/article/SB10001424052748704141104575588111375730330.html