on detectable and non-detectable structural changedirectory.umm.ac.id/data...

21
Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45 – 65 On detectable and non-detectable structural change David F. Hendry * Nuffield College, New Road, Oxford OX11NF, UK Abstract A range of parameter changes in I(1) cointegrated time series are not reflected in econometric models thereof, in that many shifts are not easily detected by conventional tests. The breaks in question are changes that leave the unconditional expectations of the I(0) components unaltered. Thus, dynamics, adjustment speeds etc. may alter without detection. However, shifts in long-run means are generally noticeable. Using the VECM model class, the paper discusses such results, explains why they occur, and uses Monte Carlo experiments to illustrate the contrasting ease of detection of ‘deterministic’ and ‘stochastic’ shifts. © 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classification: C15; C53 Keywords: Cointegrated time series; Parameter changes; Forecast error www.elsevier.nl/locate/strueco 1. Introduction Structural change and dynamics are inherent facets of economic life, and over recorded history have revolutionized the human condition: statistical tests are not needed to discriminate between conditions in 1899 and 1999. Nevertheless, it transpires that a range of parameter changes in econometric models cannot be easily detected by conventional tests, whereas other changes are manifest and easy to detect. The former class includes changes that leave unaltered the unconditional expectations of non-integrated (denoted I(0)) components even if dynamics, adjust- ment speeds, and intercepts are radically altered. The later class comprises shifts in those unconditional expectations. Some related illustrations are provided in Hendry and Doornik (1997), Clements and Hendry (1998). * Corresponding author. Tel.: +44-1865-278554; fax: +44-1865-278557. 0954-349X/00/$ - see front matter © 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII:S0954-349X(00)00020-5

Upload: others

Post on 24-Oct-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    On detectable and non-detectable structuralchange

    David F. Hendry *Nuffield College, New Road, Oxford OX1 1NF, UK

    Abstract

    A range of parameter changes in I(1) cointegrated time series are not reflected ineconometric models thereof, in that many shifts are not easily detected by conventional tests.The breaks in question are changes that leave the unconditional expectations of the I(0)components unaltered. Thus, dynamics, adjustment speeds etc. may alter without detection.However, shifts in long-run means are generally noticeable. Using the VECM model class,the paper discusses such results, explains why they occur, and uses Monte Carlo experimentsto illustrate the contrasting ease of detection of ‘deterministic’ and ‘stochastic’ shifts. © 2000Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

    JEL classification: C15; C53

    Keywords: Cointegrated time series; Parameter changes; Forecast error

    www.elsevier.nl/locate/strueco

    1. Introduction

    Structural change and dynamics are inherent facets of economic life, and overrecorded history have revolutionized the human condition: statistical tests are notneeded to discriminate between conditions in 1899 and 1999. Nevertheless, ittranspires that a range of parameter changes in econometric models cannot beeasily detected by conventional tests, whereas other changes are manifest and easyto detect. The former class includes changes that leave unaltered the unconditionalexpectations of non-integrated (denoted I(0)) components even if dynamics, adjust-ment speeds, and intercepts are radically altered. The later class comprises shifts inthose unconditional expectations. Some related illustrations are provided in Hendryand Doornik (1997), Clements and Hendry (1998).

    * Corresponding author. Tel.: +44-1865-278554; fax: +44-1865-278557.

    0954-349X/00/$ - see front matter © 2000 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.PII: S0954 -349X(00 )00020 -5

  • 46 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    This paper extends those studies, using a co-integrated vector autoregression(CVAR) as the general model. The analytical framework is the taxonomy ofpossible sources of forecast error developed in Clements and Hendry (1994), whichhighlights the impact of various forms of structural break in closed dynamicsystems, and allows some surprising predictions about which parameters of a VARcan be altered without much impact on the properties of the resulting data. Inmatching Monte Carlo experiments, a bivariate system is subject to two structuralbreaks in its parameters, where the second re-instates the original parameter values,to show the contrast between the ‘detectable’ and (relatively) ‘non-detectable’changes.1 For example, even when the general data are integrated of order unity(I(1)), the intercepts and the dynamic coefficients of a CVAR can be changedconsiderably (i.e. by more than 50%), yet parameter-constancy tests do not detectsuch changes. Moreover, this is not due to model mis-specification: the in-samplemodel considered here coincides with the data generation process (DGP). Nor is ita matter of generically low-powered tests: the same tests have high power to detectother shifts in either intercepts or dynamic coefficients. The paper explains why thisoutcome occurs: for more general studies of the size and power properties ofparameter-constancy tests in both I(0) and I(1) systems, see Anderson et al. (1993),Hylleberg et al. (1993).

    To summarize why non-detectability occurs, let yt denote a vector I(0) time serieswith actual unconditional expectations and variances denoted by E[yt ] and V[yt ]respectively. Let the corresponding expectations, based on assuming the model isthe in-sample DGP, be denoted by E[yt ] and V[yt ] (an alternative notation mightbe EM[·]). Then so long as V[yt ] is not markedly different from V[yt ], detectabilitydepends strongly on the difference E[yt ]−E[yt ]. Consequently, parameter changesin the class that leave E[yt ]#E[yt ], suffer from a detectability problem unless theygenerate large variance increases. Since I(1) CVARs can be reparameterized bydifferencing and cointegration transformations as I(0) vector equilibrium-correctionmodels (VEqCMs), where all variables are expressed as deviations around their(pre-break) means, the same logic applies: only shifts in those means inducedepartures that are readily detectable. Indeed, it is easy to create major parametershifts that leave the first two moments virtually unchanged, and such breaks will bealmost impossible to detect using tests based on those moments. Although otheraspects of the model might reveal such shifts, including residual auto-correlationwhen dynamics alter, the correct interpretation would not be obvious, and indeedother tests could well be distorted by the mis-specification deriving from the break.Different tests might be developed to prise out the correct underlying state ofnature, but here we focus on the properties of recursively-computed F-tests ofparameter constancy, and the associated recursive parameter estimates.

    The structure of the paper is as follows. Section 2 describes the n-dimensional I(1)DGP that forms the class within which the analysis is undertaken. Section 3

    1 Of course, for a sufficiently large sample, both pre and post any change, and for a big enough break,all shifts are detectable on the tests used here. The practical issue, however, is their ease of detection forrealistic sample sizes and breaks of a plausible magnitude.

  • 47D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    formalizes the structural breaks to be studied, and Section 3.1 discusses whichchanges are and are not easily detected. This is followed by a Monte Carlo studyof a bivariate I(1) CVAR in Section 4, for three classes of structural break, and inSection 4.5 for shifts in the cointegration space. Section 5 offers potential explana-tions for the mixture of results obtained and Section 6 concludes.

    2. The data generation process

    Consider a first-order vector autoregression in n variables denoted xt :

    xt=t+Gxt−1+nt (1)

    where nt� INn(0, Vn) denotes an independent, normal error with expectationE[nt ]=0 and variance matrix V[nt ]=Vn. The data are assumed to be integrated oforder unity (I(1)), perhaps after suitable transformations (such as logs), representedby:

    G=In+ab % (2)

    where a and b are n×r matrices of rank r. All eigenvalues of G lie on or inside theunit circle, to exclude explosive processes, and to exclude I(2), rank (a %ÞGbÞ)= (n−r), where aÞ and bÞare n× (n−r) matrices of rank (n−r) and a %aÞ=b %bÞ=0(although the analysis could be generalized to accommodate I(2) data). Additionallags are easily added, but do not seem to materially affect the outcomes, althoughlinearity may do (primarily because most non-linear functions entail nonzeromeans, an issue of importance below). The parameters will be allowed to shift,which induces structural change in the system.

    In (1):

    t=g−am (3)

    where m is r×1, and to ensure the appropriate number of ‘free’ parameters,b %g=0. Substituting Eqns. (2) and (3) into (1) yields the vector equilibrium-correc-tion model (denoted VEqCM):

    Dxt−g=a(b %xt−1−m)+nt (4)

    where Dxt and bxt are I(0). From Eq. (4), E[Dxt ]=g (the unconditional growthrate) so E[b %xt ]=m defines the equilibrium means.

    2.1. Parameter-constancy tests

    The statistics reported below for testing parameter constancy are recursively-computed, system variants of Chow (1960) tests, as described in Doornik andHendry (1997), Ch. 14. In a univariate setting, the tests are calculated from theresidual sums of squares as the sample size is increased, and so are related to theCUSUMSQ statistic in Brown et al. (1975). The vector F-tests use the F-approxi-mation in Rao (1952), as described in Rao (1973), Section 8c.5) or Anderson (1984),Section 8.5.4): for other approaches, see (inter alia) Anderson and Mizon (1983).

  • 48 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    3. Structural change

    Under structural change, any or all of g, a, b, m or Vn, could alter (or indeed theforms of the relationships in the system, the distributional assumptions, and laglengths, but these are not considered here). Situations such as economic transitionundoubtedly involve changes to cointegration links and growth rates, as well as tospeeds of adjustment and equilibrium means. We will focus on the more ‘normal’setting where g, a, or m shift. However, changes that involve setting a=0, orchanging a=0 to a non-zero value, inherently involve changes in the cointegrationstructure, and these are investigated below. Changes to b could be studied, but poserather different problems, as discussed later. Finally, changes to Vn are predicted bythe following theory to have less of an impact, unless they are very large, so are notconsidered here.

    Individual realizations of integrated time series almost inherently have non-zerodata means, by force of their stochastic trends. Nevertheless, the I(0) componentscould have zero unconditional means, depending on the form of data transforma-tion and units of measurement. Thus, in order to clarify the impacts of parameterchanges, we also write the system Eq. (4) in I(0) space for the n variables yt, the firstr of which are the b %xt and the remaining n−r are the relevant elements of Dxt (e.g.Dxt which ensures a non-singular representation). Of course, this representation isinappropriate when b can alter. Thus:

    yt=f+Pyt−1+et with et� INn(0, Ve). (5)

    The unconditional expectation (or long-run mean) E[yt ] of yt over t=1,…, T is:

    E[yt ]= (I−P)−1f=8 (6)

    since the earlier assumptions ensure that P has all its eigenvalues less than unity inabsolute value, leading to the homogeneous specification:

    yt−8=P(yt−1−8)+ot. (7)

    Under the assumption of constant parameters, Eq. (7) would deliver the one-stepahead outcome (assuming known parameters):

    yT+1−8=P(yT−8)+oT+1. (8)

    At time period T, however, we let (f :P) change to (f*:P*), so from T+1 onwards,the data are generated by:

    yT+h=f*+P*yT+h−1+oT+h, h]1.

    We assume P* still has all its eigenvalues less than unity in absolute value, andthat the number and form of the cointegrating vectors remains the same. Let8*= (In−P*)−1f*, then:

    yT+h−8*=P*(yT+h−1−8*)+oT+h. (9)

    The thrust of Hendry and Doornik (1997), building on Clements and Hendry(1994), is that changes in 8 are easy to detect, whereas those in f and P are not

  • 49D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    when 8 is unchanged, so we consider that issue first. We refer to shifts in 8 as‘deterministic’ changes (since they change the long-run mean), whereas shifts in fand P that leave 8 unchanged are referred to as ‘stochastic’ or ‘non-deterministic’,even though they might involve a changed intercept.

    Let oT+1/T denote the difference between Eqs. (8) and (9) at one-step ahead:

    oT+1/T=8*+P*(yT−8*)+oT+1− (8+P(yT−8)+oT+1)=8*−8+P*(yT−8*)−P(yT−8)= (In−P*)(8*−8)+ (P*−P)(yT−8)

    (10)

    This would be the expected one-step ahead forecast error from using Eq. (8) asa model when Eq. (9) is the DGP, and all parameters are known. The first term onthe last line is the equilibrium-mean shift, and the second is the slope change, whichhas an unconditional expectation of zero. Indeed, if a slope change occurred whenthe economy was near equilibrium, so yT#8 and 8 did not alter, then oT+1/T#0.Of course, if the economy was in substantial disequilibrium, a larger effect wouldresult, but this seems to part of the explanation for the non-detectability of shiftsin f and P that leave 8 unchanged.

    3.1. Detectable shifts

    We now show that deterministic shifts, namely shifts from 8 to 8*, whetherinduced by changes in the intercept f, or indirectly by changes in dynamics (i.e. via(In−P*)−1f) are a detectable failure in linear dynamic econometric systems. Wethen demonstrate that even if every parameter alters, but this leaves the ‘long-runmeans’ 8 unchanged, so f*= (In−P*)8, structural change is not easily detected.Indeed, shifts in f, P with constant 8 transpire to be isomorphic to changes inmean-zero processes, where f=f*=0. Further, while breaks in P alone can causeforecast failures, their ease of detection depends on the magnitudes of the long-runmeans of the I(0) components relative to their error standard deviations. As Hendryand Doornik (1997) remark, when the long-run mean is non-zero, breaks shift thelocation of the data, inducing a short-run ‘trend’ to the new equilibrium mean,which is more easily detected than a one-off variance change around the origin. IfEq. (4) had additional dynamics, these could be expressed in growth-rate form, andhence re-written to have zero means around (the equivalent of) g, so the sameargument about detectability would apply to shifts in their parameters.

    Because the system is dynamic, the impact of any break takes time to have its fulleffect, and for the system to reach a new equilibrium, so the data expectations alterin every period, making the process highly non-stationary. To develop the primaryimplications, we just consider the first period following a change, denoted time T :later periods are amenable to analysis, as are successive changes, although thealgebra becomes increasingly complicated. Let denote an estimate, so the forecasterror at T+1, immediately after the break (or ex post residual using parameterestimates up to T), is ôT+1/T=yT+1− ŷT+1/T where:

  • 50 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    ôT+1/T=f*+P*yT+oT+1−f. −P. yT (11)

    We treat finite-sample biases in estimators as negligible (see Hendry, 1997, for anexplanation), so set E[P. ]=P and E[f. ]=f. Further, as almost all estimationmethods match data means in-sample, 8̂= (In−P. )−1f. . Let E denote the expectedvalue computed from the model, namely, the actual mean of the forecasts given thein-sample parameter values, when Eq. (5) is assumed to hold (i.e. in ignorance ofthe shift), then conditional on yT :

    E[ŷT+1/T �yT ]=f+PyT.This is to be contrasted with the actual data expectation at T+1:

    E[ŷT+1/T �yT ]=f*+P*yT.Then, detectability depends primarily on E[yT+1�yT ]−E[ŷT+1/T �yT ]. More preciselyfrom Eq. (11):

    E[ôT+1/T �yT ]=f*+P*yT+E[oT+1]−E[f. ]−E[P. ]yTE[ôT+1/T �yT ]=f*−f+ (P*−P)yTE[ôT+1/T �yT ]=E[yT+1/T �yT ]= −E[ŷT+1/T/yT ].

    (12)

    Moreover, taking the unconditional means of each term using Eq. (6):

    E[ŷT+1/T ]=f+PE[yT ]= (In−P)8+P8=8 (13)

    whereas:

    E[yT+1]=f*+P*8= (In−P*)8*+P*8*−P*(8*−8)=8*−P*(8*−8),

    so unconditionally:

    E[yT+1]−E[ŷT+1/T ]=E[ôT+1]= (In−P*)(8*−8). (14)

    This is simply the first term in the last line of Eq. (10)The key implication from Eq. (14) is that E[yT+1]=E[ŷT+1/T ] when 8*=8. This

    can occur despite changes in the dynamics, represented by shifts in P, or changesin f : for example, if {yt} is a mean-zero process; if 8 does not change; or if shiftsin f* offset those in P* to leave 8 constant, despite both dynamics and interceptsshifting. Further, for a given value of (8*−8), the ellect is larger or smaller as(In−P*) moves closer to (further from) zero.

    Of course, the detectability of any shifts depends on their magnitude relative tothe error standard deviations. Let Vo−1=K%K so that:

    Kyt=Kf+KPK−1Kyt−1+Kot,

    or letting yt+=Kyt :

    yt+=c+Cyt−1+ +ot+,

  • 51D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    where KfC, ot+=Kot� INn [0, In ] and C=KPK−1 (since C and P are related bya similarity transform, the ordering-dependence of the transformation by K doesnot matter here). Then, after the break:

    E[yT+1+ ]−E[ŷT+1/T+ ]=K(In−P*)(8*−8).

    This is the appropriate metric for judging the ‘magnitude’ of a break.We now illustrate the implications of this analysis for detecting structural change,

    using some numerical simulations of parameter-constancy tests. Although theabove analysis only applies to one-step ahead errors after a single break, the MonteCarlo will examine many forecast (break-test) horizons, and allows for two shifts.Nevertheless, the implications will be seen to hold more generally.

    4. An I(1) Monte Carlo

    The Monte Carlo simulation considers the following experiments, implemented inOx by PcNaive for Windows (see Doornik, 1996; Doornik and Hendry, 1998). Thedata are generated by a bivariate cointegrated I(1) VAR:

    Dx1, t=g1+a1(x1, t−1−x2, t−1−m1)+o1, tDx2, t=g2+a2(x1, t−1−x2, t−1−m1)+o2, t

    (15)

    where oi, t� IN[0, sii ], with E[o1, t o2, s ]=0 Öt, s, so in Eq. (15), K is diagonal withelements, sii. We consider four types of experiment:1. a constant DGP (to establish actual test size)2. breaks in the coefficients of the feedbacks (a1 and a2)3. breaks in the long-run mean (m1)4. breaks in the growth rates (g1 and g2).

    Four different full-sample sizes are considered T=24, 60, 100, and 200 (de-noted a, b, c, d on graphs), the last of which is relatively large for macro-eco-nomic models. Breaks occur at t=0.5T, and revert to the original parametervalues at t=0.75T to mimic a second break. Thus, the design seeks to isolatethe effects of more information at larger T with fixed relative break points: aswill be seen, ‘undetectable’ breaks remain hard to find even at the largest samplesize considered here. Since breaks are involved, these experiments could not havebeen conducted as one recursive experiment from T=10 to 200, except whenstudying null rejection frequencies. However, for graphical presentation, the indi-vidual graph lines between a, b, c, d are only distinguished by a different symbolwhere that clarifies an important feature, even when the recorded outcomesoverlap.

    The unrestricted VAR with intercept and one lag is estimated and tested.When breaks occur, modelling cointegrated processes is difficult, and as a VARis usually the first step, constancy tests should be implemented at that stage (i.e.prior to checking cointegration): detectability may increase if a VECM form is

  • 52 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    imposed, but doing so is unlikely to affect the rankings across the outcomes inour experiments 1–4. Throughout, 500 replications were used, and rejection fre-quencies at both 0.05 and 0.01 nominal test sizes were recorded (so have stan-dard errors of about 0.01 and 0.004, respectively).

    The experimental formulation is invariant to what induces changes in gi−ai m1, but large growth-rate changes seem unlikely in real economic variables. Itmay seem surprising that the ‘absolute’ size of m1, can matter, since even afterlog transforms, the measurement units affect m1: for example, a switch from aprice index normalized at unity to one normalized at 100 radically alters m1 in(say) a log-linear money-demand model without affecting either a or s. Never-theless, changes in m1 (relative to error standard deviations) also need to bejudged absolutely, not as percentages: thus, using 9 to denote parameterchanges, 9m1/s matters per se, and this cannot depend on the measurementsystem, only on agent’s behaviour. When m1/s is large (small), a given effect willbe a small (large) percent, but will have the same detectability for a given a. Forexample, for both broad and narrow money demand in the UK after financialinnovation in the mid 1980s (see Hendry and Ericsson, 1991; Ericsson et al.,1998), 9m1/s#25–30, in models that excluded appropriate modifiers. The rise inthe savings rate in the mid 1970s was of roughly the same absolute magnitude(see e.g. Hendry, 1994). For ‘standard’ values of a, (around 0.1–0.2) these num-bers translate into ‘permanent’ equilibrium shifts of 2.5s–6s. Such consider-ations determined the values of the parameters in the experimental design.

    Two baseline sets of dynamics are considered: a1= −0.1, and a2=0 (so x2, tis both weakly and strongly exogenous for the parameters of the first equation:see Engle et al., 1983); and a1= −0.1, and a2=0.1 (so x2, t is neither weaklynor strongly exogenous for the parameters of the first equation). For a1 thechange is −0.05. We investigate m1=1, changed by an amount of +0.3 for itsbreak (so 9a1m1=3sii). Also, using b %= (1:−1) enforces g1=g2 which was setto 0.01 (roughly 4% p.a. for quarterly data): the change considered is to doubleboth of these to 0.02 in (4), which would constitute a very dramatic increase inlong-term growth. Thus, two ratios of gi/sii are examined, namely unity and 2(see Hylleberg and Mizon, 1989), inducing the derived values of sii=0.01throughout (roughly 1% for the one-step ahead forecast standard error underconstant parameters). Notice that g and m correspond to elements of 8 ratherthan f. In total, there are eight baseline experiments, and the same number ofchanges to a, g, and m making 32 experiments in total. These are reportedgraphically, each panel showing all four sample size outcomes for both p values.The critical values for the constancy tests are those for a known break point,which delivers the highest possible power for the test used. The graphs serve toillustrate the outcomes visually, showing that rejection frequencies are everywherelow in some cases, confirming that the highest power is immediately before thefirst break, whereas the second break is often less detectable when the first hasnot been modelled, and sometimes showing that the tests are actually biasedafter the second break.

  • 53D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    4.1. Test size

    The relation of the actual to the nominal size for vector constancy tests has notbeen much investigated, so the experiments in (1) check their size in an I(1),cointegrated setting, with and without feedback in the second equation. As Fig. 1reveals, the results are reasonably reassuring when the EqCM enters both relations:with 500 replications, the approximate 95% confidence intervals are (0.03, 0.07) and(0.002, 0.018) for 5% and 1% nominal, and these are shown on the graphs as dottedand dashed lines respectively, revealing that few null rejection frequencies lieoutside those bounds once the sample size exceeds 60. At the smallest sample sizes,there is some over-rejection, though never above 9% for the 5% nominal or 3% forthe 1% nominal. When the EqCM enters the first relation only, there is asystematic, but small, excess rejection: around 6% instead of 5%, and 1.5% insteadof 1%. However, these outcomes are not sufficiently discrepant to markedly affectthe outcomes of the ‘power’ comparisons below.

    4.2. Dynamic shift

    Experiments in (2) demonstrate that a change in the strength of reaction to azero-mean disequilibrium is not readily detectable. This is despite the fact that theintercept also shifts in the VAR representation:

    Fig. 1. Constancy-test null rejection frequencies in a cointegrated process.

  • 54 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    Fig. 2. Constancy-test rejection frequencies for changes in a.

    xt=g−am+ab %xt−1+ot pre breakxs=g−a*m+a*b %xs−1+os post break.

    One might have anticipated detectablity from 9am"0, particularly since thatchange numerically exceeds the equivalent jump in (3) which we show below iseasily detected. Nevertheless, despite the induced intercept shift, changes in thedynamics alone are not easily detectable. Fig. 2 records the outcomes: the powersare so low, do not increase with sample size, and indeed barely reflect any breaks,that one might question whether the Monte Carlo was correctly implemented: beassured it was, but anyway, this effect is easy to replicate using PcNaive. Moreover,it was predicted by the analysis above, by that in Clements and Hendry (1994), andhas been found in a different setting by Hendry and Doornik (1997), so is not likelyto be spurious.Further, the presence of an additional EqCM feedback does notinfluence these results, even though one might expect an induced shift. Perhapsother tests could detect this type of change, but they will need some other principleof construction than that used here if power is to be noticeably increased. Althoughdirect testing of the parameters seems an obvious approach, as Fig. 3 shows, thereis no evidence in the recursive graphs of any marked change in estimates for theexperiments where T=60 (similar results held at other sample sizes).

    The remarkable feature of this set of experiments is that most of the parametersin the system have been changed, namely from:

    G=�0.9 0.1

    0.1 0.9�

    ; t=� 0.11

    −0.09�

    (16)

  • 55D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    G*=�0.85 0.15

    0.1 0.9�

    ; t*=� 0.16

    −0.09�

    , (17)

    yet the data hardly alter. Moreover, increasing the size of the shift in a1, and indeedmaking both as shift, does not improve the detectability: for example, usinga1*= −0.2, and a2*= −0.15 causes no perceptible increase in the rejection fre-quency, or movement in the recursive estimates, over those shown in Figs. 2 and 3.

    The detectability of a shift in dynamics is dependent on whether the as areincreased or decreased, for example, setting a1*=a2*=0, so that cointegrationvanishes and the DGP becomes a VAR in first differences, delivers the graphs inFig. 4. The powers are a little better but the highest power is still less than 30% eventhough in some sense, the vanishing of cointegration might be deemed a majorstructural change to an economy. The re-instatement of cointegration is somewhatmore detectable than its loss, despite the earlier break not being modelled: intu-itively, after a period without cointegration, the xs have drifted apart, so there-imposition has a marked deterministic effect, whereas when cointegration hasoperated for a time, the cointegration vector will be near its equilibrium mean, andhence switching it off will have only a small deterministic effect.

    4.3. Equilibrium-mean shift

    Experiments in (3) show the contrasting ease of detecting equilibrium-meanbreaks. Fig. 5 confirms the anticipated outcomes for the mean shifts: the break-point test rejection frequencies are close to their nominal size of 5% under the null;the break in the equilibrium mean is easily detected, even at quite small sample

    Fig. 3. Recursively computed parameter estimates with 92ŝ at T=60.

  • 56 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    Fig. 4. Constancy-test rejection frequencies for loss of cointegration.

    Fig. 5. Constancy-test rejection frequencies for changes in m.

  • 57D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    sizes, especially when the EqCM enters both relations, which also serves to sharpenthe location of the break. Because the relative positions of the breaks are held fixed,the power only increases slowly at p=0.05 as T grows, but has a more markedeffect on p=0.01: larger samples do not ensure higher power for detecting thebreaks.

    To emphasize the detectability issue, note that the corresponding VAR here hasthe same G as Eq. (16) throughout, and:

    t=� 0.11

    −0.09�

    changes to t*=� 0.14

    −0.12�

    . (18)

    Without the underlying theory to explain this outcome, it might seem astonishingthat Eq. (18) can cause massive forecast failure, yet a shift from Eq. (16) to:

    G*=�0.80 0.20

    0.15 0.85�

    ; t*=� 0.21

    −0.14�

    (19)

    is almost completely undetectable.

    4.4. Growth-rate shift

    Finally, experiments in (4) examine the ease of detecting the correspondingdoubling of the growth rate. This is a large change in real growth, but that isequivalent to a fraction of the change in (3), and at about 5% rejection, is againalmost undetectable on these tests at small T, but now does become increasinglyeasy to spot as the sample size grows. This is sensible, since the data exhibit abroken trend, but the model does not, so larger samples with the same relativebreak points induce effects of a larger magnitude. Thus, the type of structural breakto be detected affects whether larger samples will help.

    The model formulation also matters: if a VEqCM is used, the first growth breakshows up much more strongly, as Fig. 7 illustrates. The upper panel shows thebreak-point test rejection frequencies for the same experiment as Fig. 6; the lowerpanel records the recursively-computed growth coefficients in the first equation with92 SE. This increased initial detectability is because the VEqCM ‘isolates’ the shiftin g, whereas the VAR ‘bundles’ it with g−am, where the second component canbe relatively much larger, camouflaging the shift. Moreover, VAR estimates ofg−am generally have very large standard errors because of the I(1) representation,whereas estimates of g are usually quite precise. Even so, a large growth-ratechange has a surprisingly small effect at T=200 on the recursively-estimatedintercept.

    4.5. Cointegration changes

    The main difficulty in considering changes in b is to ensure that these actuallyoccur, and are not just linear recombinations, potentially offset by changes to a soG is unaltered. At the same time, one must isolate their impact from induced effects,

  • 58 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    including induced rank changes, and changes to m. The first problem is due totransformations from the class of non-singular matrices H such that a*(b*)%=aHH−1b %=ab % under which G is invariant. We have considered the second of

    Fig. 6. Constancy-test rejection frequencies for changes in g.

    Fig. 7. Constancy-test rejection frequencies in VEqCM and intercept estimates.

  • 59D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    these indirectly above when a changed from a non-zero value to zero, then back.The third requires that E[(b*)%xt ]=m* be known numerically in the Monte Carloso that the disequilibrium remains at mean zero. In practice, changes in cointegra-tion parameters almost certainly induce changes in equilibrium means, so will bedetectable via the latter at a minimum.

    The experiment to illustrate this case therefore set m=m*=0, with the otherdesign parameters as before, and changed b % from (1:−1) to (1:−0.9), alteringt=g to ensure b %g=0 both before and after the shift, and commencing thesimulation from y%0= (0:0), but discarding the first 20 generated observations. Sincethe process drifts, power should rise quickly as the sample size grows both becauseof increased evidence, and the increased data values. Moreover, the re-instatementshould be more detectable than the initial change, matching when cointegration isfirst lost then re-appears. Conversely, the induced change to G is not very largewhen a %= (−0.1:0):

    G=�0.9 0.1

    0.0 1.0�

    ; whereas G*=�0.9 0.09

    0.0 1.0�

    ,

    with appropriate changes to t. In one sense, the very small shift in G is remarkablydetectable, and reveals how important a role is played by shifts in off-diagonalelements in a VAR: we note with interest that the so-called ‘Minnesota’ priorshrinks precisely these terms towards zero (see Doan et al., 1984). Equally, aslightly bigger change results when a %= (−0.1:0.1), as:

    G=�0.9 0.1

    0.1 0.9�

    ; whereas G*=�0.9 0.09

    0.1 0.91�

    ,

    and correspondingly, the power is higher in larger samples: see Fig. 8.

    5. Potential explanations

    Based on the taxonomy of possible sources of forecast errors in Clements andHendry (1994), Hendry and Doornik (1997) and Clements and Hendry (1998) linkthe non-detectability to the mean-zero nature of the variables whose parameters arechanged. In their taxonomy, some forecasting mistakes derive from parameterchanges that multiply the values of the regressors at the forecast origin: when suchvalues are precisely zero, no errors can eventuate. Conversely, other changesmultiply the data means (for I(0) components at least) and these only vanish incertain combinations. This suggests that the former, and the appropriate annihilat-ing combinations of the latter, will be hard to detect, and that mean changes willbe easy. This matches our simulation results.

    Next, Hendry and Doornik (1997) prove that parameter-shift combinationswhich leave equilibrium means unaltered are isomorphic to mean-zero effects. Theyillustrate this result by an I(0) example akin to case (2) above, where the intercepts

  • 60 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    Fig. 8. Rejection frequencies for a change in the cointegration parameter.

    and dynamics are changed, but the equilibrium mean is constant, and show that thedetectability is low. Clements and Hendry (1998) also demonstrate nearly equaldetectability from inducing a shift of a given magnitude in the equilibrium mean byeither an intercept shift, or by changing the coefficient of a regressor with anon-zero mean, even though the latter involves two sources of change (mean andreaction coefficient) and the former only one. This confirms that changes toreaction coefficients are primarily detectable through the induced mean shift.

    Indeed, the data generated by the constant DGP, and that suffering the shiftsshown in Eq. (19), are almost the same, as Fig. 9 (panels a, c) shows, whereas thosefrom Eq. (16) or (4) are noticeably different (panels b, d respectively): both as arenon-zero in every panel. Such a feature is close to a lack of empirical identification,namely the evidence does not discriminate between two very different parameteriza-tions, subject to maintaining the same means, and in fact, similar variances.Changing a only induces variance shifts, and from the data graphs, these are seento be small relative to the background ‘noise’. Clements and Hendry (1999) derivethe variance impacts of changes to a which depend on 9aVb(9a)% where Vb is thevariance matrix of the cointegrating relations, (b %xt−1−m). When Vb is small, thedata resulting from the shift will be only slightly different from the constant DGP,as Fig. 9 shows, despite the substantive change in dynamics. Conversely, thedeterministic shift is all too obvious even in data differences (Fig. 10).

    Even bigger shifts in initially larger values of a are still not easily detected. Forthe case:

  • 61D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    Fig. 9. Data generated with and without structural breaks.

    Fig. 10. Differenced data generated with and without structural breaks.

  • 62 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    Fig. 11. Rejection frequency for a large a shift.

    Fig. 12. The differenced-data generated with a large dynamic break.

  • 63D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    G=�0.7 0.3

    0.3 0.7�

    to G*=� 0.8 0.2

    0.15 0.85�

    ,

    the rejection-frequency outcomes are shown in Fig. 11, with the corresponding datafor the four sample sizes shown in Fig. 12: the break points are far from obviousin the data, and the rejection frequencies remain low, and little improved by theincreased sample size.

    Finally, the algebra of the intercept in Eq. (3) also helps account for theoutcomes in (4). There are two components to t in a VAR, namely the uncondi-tional growth rate, g, and the equilibrium mean times the feedback, am. The formeris almost inevitably small, whereas the latter can be huge, simply depending on theunits of measurement, as discussed above. Often, therefore, t̂ is a large number,with a large standard error, suggesting its value is very uncertain, and hence — butbe careful — that it can be changed considerably without much impact ongoodness of fit. Certainly, small changes in G. can offset those in t̂ when estimatingthe VAR unrestrictedly, which is what the large standard errors reflect. However,consider estimating the VAR in Eq. (1) to ‘calibrate’ a Monte Carlo: given G. (tothree digits say), round t̂ to three digits as well when the numbers are of the orderof (say) 10.54 (SE=2.1), thereby using 10.5. The result will generate data whollyunlike those from which the VAR was estimated, because the implicit ĝ has beenaltered from (say) 0.01 to −0.03: instead of growing at about 4% p.a., the economyis vanishing at 12% p.a.2 Equally, orthogonalizing the equilibrium mean and thegrowth rate (a linear transform within the estimated model, to which it is invariant),can induce a dramatic change in the remaining intercept standard error, to (e.g.)0.01 (SE=0.004). This helps explain the difficulty of detecting (4), and suggests thatgrowth-rate changes will be far easier to detect in VEqCMs than VARs. Con-versely, the VAR is more robust to such shifts from the perspective of forecastfailure. Finally, we have already explained why relatively tiny VAR parameterchanges are readily detected when they correspond to shifts in cointegrating vectors.

    6. Conclusion

    With I(1) data generated from a cointegrated VAR, the detectability of a changeis not well reflected by the original VAR parameterization. Apparently large shiftsin both the VAR intercept and dynamic coefficient matrix need not be detectable,whereas seemingly tiny changes can have a substantial and easily detected effect.Viewing the issue through a vector equilibrium-correction parameterization helpsclarify this outcome. Moreover, it reveals that equilibrium mean shifts are readilydetectable, whereas mean-zero shifts are not. Thus, the implicit variation-freeassumptions about parameters are crucial in a world of structural shifts, withconsequential benefits of robustness in forecasting, versus drawbacks of non-detec-tion in modelling. Other tests, including monitoring and variance-change tests,

    2 This occurred in early versions of the Monte Carlo DGP used in Doornik et al. (1998).

  • 64 D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    merit consideration, but overall the results suggest a focus on mean shifts to detectchanges of concern to macro-economic forecasting.

    Acknowledgements

    Financial support from the UK Economic and Social Research Council undergrant R65237500 is gratefully acknowledged. I am pleased to acknowledge helpfulcomments from Mike Clements, Bronwyn Hall, Grayham Mizon, John Muellbauer,Bent Nielsen and Ken Wallis.

    References

    Anderson, T.W., 1984. An Introduction to Multivariate Statistical Analysis, 2nd. Wiley, New York.Anderson, G.J., Mizon, G.E. (1983). Parameter constancy tests: old and new. Discussion Paper in

    Economics and Econometrics, no. 8325, Economics Department, University of Southampton.Anderson, G.J., Mizon, G.E., O’Brien, R.J. (1993). Testing for parameter constancy in systems of I(0)

    variables. mimeo. European University Institute, Florence, Italy.Brown, R.L., Durbin, L., Evans, J.M., 1975. Techniques for testing the constancy of regression

    relationships over time. J. R. Stat. Soc. B 37, 149–192.Chow, G.C., 1960. Tests of equality between sets of coefficients in two linear regressions. Econometrica

    28, 591–605.Clements, M.P., Hendry, D.F., 1994. Towards a theory of economic forecasting. In: Hargreaves, C.

    (Ed.), Non-stationary Time-series Analysis and Cointegration. Oxford University, Oxford, pp. 9–52.Clements, M.P., Hendry, D.F. (1998). On winning forecasting competitions in economics. Mimeo,

    Institute of Economics and Statistics, University of Oxford.Clements, M.P., Hendry, D.F., 1999. Forecasting non-stationary economic time series. MIT Press,

    Cambridge, MA.Doan, T., Litterman, R., Sims, C.A., 1984. Forecasting and conditional projection using realistic prior

    distributions. Econom. Rev. 3, 1–100.Doornik, J.A. (1996). Object-Oriented Matrix Programming using Ox. International, Timberlake

    Consultants, London and http://www.nuf.ox.ac.uk/users/doornik, OxfordDoornik, J.A., Hendry, D.F., 1997. Modelling Dynamic Systems using PcFiml 9 for Windows.

    Timberlake Consultants, London.Doornik, J.A., Hendry, D.F., 1998. Monte Carlo simulation, using PcNaive for Windows. Unpublished

    typescript, Nuffield College, University of Oxford.Doornik, J.A., Hendry, D.F., Nielsen, B., 1998. Inference in cointegrated models: UK M1 revisited. J.

    Econ. Surv. 12, 533–572.Engle, R.E., Hendry, D.F., Richard, J.F., 1983. Exogeneity. Econometrica 51, 277–304. Reprinted in (a)

    Hendry, D.E., 1993. Econometrics. Alchemy or Science? Blackwell, Oxford. (b) Ericsson, N.R.,Irons, J.S. (Eds.), 1994. Testing Exogeneity. Oxford University, Oxford.

    Ericsson, N.R., Hendry, D.E, Prestwich, K.M., 1998. The demand for broad money in the UnitedKingdom, 1878–1993. Scand. J. Econ. 100, 289–324.

    Hendry, D.F., 1994. HUS revisited. Oxf. Rev. Econ. Policy 10, 86–106.Hendry, D.F., 1997. The econometrics of macro-economic forecasting. Econ. J. 107, 1330–1357.Hendry, D.F., Doornik, J.A., 1997. The implications for econometric modelling of forecast failure.

    Scott. J. Polit. Econ. 44, 437–461.Hendry, D.F., Ericsson, N.R., 1991. Modeling the demand for narrow money in the United Kingdom

    and the United States. Eur. Econ. Rev. 35, 833–886.

  • 65D.F. Hendry / Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 11 (2000) 45–65

    Hylleberg, S., Mizon, G.E., 1989. Cointegration and error correction mechanisms. Econ. J. 99, 113–125Supplement.

    Hylleberg, S., Mizon, G.E., O’Brien, 1993. Testing for parameter constancy in systems of cointegratedvariables. Mimeo, European University Institute, Florence.

    Rao, C.R., 1952. Advanced Statistical Methods in Biometric Research. Wiley, New York.Rao, C.R., 1973. Linear Statistical Interference and its Applications, 2nd. Wiley, New York.

    .