on the nobel prize in economics and mises

3

Click here to load reader

Upload: mises-fan

Post on 14-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: On the Nobel Prize in Economics and Mises

7/27/2019 On the Nobel Prize in Economics and Mises

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/on-the-nobel-prize-in-economics-and-mises 1/3

40 Years Later: Mises’s Lasting Legacy 

Mises Daily: Thursday, October 10, 2013 by Jörg Guido Hülsmann (http://mises.org/daily/author/231/Jorg-Guido-

Hulsmann)

Tweet 20 2 14

Editor’s note: October 10, 2013 is the 40th anniversary 

of the death of Ludwig von Mises.

Each year in early October, the world looks to Sweden

and Norway, where the annual Nobel Prize winners are

announced in the fields of literature, medicine-

physiology, physics, chemistry, and peace-making.

The great Swedish entrepreneur, Alfred Nobel did not

sponsor a prize in economics, and the committees sponsored out of his estate did not grant any

such prize until the present day. But there is a “Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred

Nobel” which is sponsored by the central bank of Sweden. Since 1969, that prize has been granted

every year in early October, too.

The timing and the labeling of the prize, as well as the fact that its laureates are selected by the

Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences, which also picks the other laureates (except for the peace

prize), have misled people all over the world into thinking it is the real thing. Like counterfeit

banknotes, the economics prize has been circulating among the unsuspecting public.

Alfred Nobel did not intend to sponsor a prize in economics. Apparently, neither did the Swedish

central bank. Its prize has usually been awarded to scholars specializing in applied mathematics, or

applied psychology, or in the art of playing with statistical data that goes under the name of 

econometrics. Very rarely is it awarded to scholars who actually spend most of their time thinking

about real-world economic problems, and almost never to anybody who has anything new and

important and true to say about the real economy. It is true that many laureates were very well

versed in economics, but even they did not, as a rule, obtain the prize for any contribution to that

discipline.

The problem with the “dismal science” of economics is well known. It mercilessly exposes and

dispels the myths that have been invented to justify central planning and government

interventionism. This flies in the face of the very institutions that finance and award the Prize in

memory of Alfred Nobel. The Swedish central bank is institutionally committed to central planning

in money. It can hardly be expected to print and spend millions of kronas on research that is

useless — and potentially nefarious — from its very own point of view. Moreover, Sweden has beenruled by socialists for most of the post-war period. The venerable Royal Swedish Academy of 

Sciences was not immune from this tendency.

Unsurprisingly, the economics prize has always been heavily biased against economists who oppose

the fiat-money foundation of the welfare state and of the warfare state. The facts speak for

themselves. With the notable exception of F.A. Hayek (laureate in 1974), none of the prize winners

is on record as an outspoken critic of central banking and monetary interventionism. And even

Hayek came out of the closet only after winning the prize, publishing Choice in Currency (1976)

and Denationalisation of Money  (1977).

Unsurprisingly, two giants of economic thought, Ludwig von Mises (1881-1973) and Murray Rothbard

(1926-1995) did not obtain the economics prize in memory of Alfred Nobel. Mises, who was arguably

the greatest economist ever, died at the very moment when that prize was awarded for the fifth

time. On the occasion of the 40th anniversary of his passing, it is appropriate to commemorate his

achievements and to highlight his lasting legacy.

Recommend Send 54 people recommend this. Be the first of your friends.

Like 54

Page 2: On the Nobel Prize in Economics and Mises

7/27/2019 On the Nobel Prize in Economics and Mises

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/on-the-nobel-prize-in-economics-and-mises 2/3

Ludwig von Mises is well known as a fountainhead of the revival of classical liberalism and

libertarianism after WWII. But his influence on contemporary political thought was based entirely

on his groundbreaking contributions to social analysis, and to monetary economics in particular. At

the very moment when inflationist ideas had made their intrusion into the academic world and

were about to supersede classical economics, Mises revolutionized the theory of money. He was the

first economist to develop a full-fledged explanation of money prices, and he was also the first to

develop a comprehensive analysis of the causes and consequences of money production. His work

renewed and greatly reinforced the case against monetary interventionism, which had been at the

heart of classical economics.

Before Adam Smith, public opinion was infused with the notion that the volume of spending (in

today’s Keynesian jargon known as “aggregate demand”) drives the economy. Politicians and

businessmen therefore strove to increase the national money supply in order to promote production

and growth. Smith argued that this was all wrong. The true causes of aggregate wealth were to be

seen in the division of labor and in a frugal lifestyle. Policies designed to increase the national

money supply by encouraging exports and hampering imports were ineffective. They impoverished

the nation rather than to promote its growth.

This thesis inspired the intellectual movement known as classical economics. It has also inspired the

economists of the Austrian School. When Carl Menger developed his price theory based on the rock-

solid foundation of subjective value, he did not seek to overthrow classical economics root and

branch. What he did was to repair one fundamental shortcoming of classical price theory, and in so

doing he solidified the overall edifice. Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk reinforced the classical teachings

on savings and capital by analyzing the role of time in the production process. At the beginning of 

the 20th century, then, Ludwig von Mises completed the Austrian revision and reconstruction of 

classical economics with his theory of money.

Adam Smith had neglected money because neither the demand for money, nor the supply thereof 

were to be counted among the causes of the wealth of nations. Many of his disciples — especially

the great David Ricardo — delved into the matter in more detail. But their writings suffered from

the Achilles’ heel of Smith’s theory: his cost-of-production theory of prices. They could therefore

not quite come to grips with the economics of banking, and the practical consequence was a never-

ending sequence of booms and busts. This practical failure in the field of money and bankingeventually discredited the entire edifice of classical economics. Inflationist doctrines made a

comeback, first creeping (second half of the 19th century), then galloping (around WWI), and

eventually triumphing in the 1930s.

Mises did not develop his theory of money in order to come up with classical-liberal practical

conclusions. Quite to the contrary, it took him a while to understand the political implications of 

what he had found. The first edition of this monetary treatise (1912) is actually quite tame in that

respect. It is only in the second edition (1924) that Mises starts to hammer the anti-interventionist

implications of his work in monetary economics. At about the same time, he had begun to delve

into other areas of research, most notably into the analysis of socialist and interventionist systems

of government. These works brought him great fame, and they were instrumental in converting anentire generation of young intellectuals — such as Hayek, Haberler, Machlup, Morgenstern, and

Robbins — to classical liberal ideas. But his monetary thought would always remain the backbone of 

his thinking. Eventually he would present it fully developed within a general theory of human

action (Nationalökonomie, Human Action).

It was Mises’s personal misfortune that, during all of his life, his economic and political ideas were

thoroughly out of fashion. But, precisely for this very reason, his legacy is lasting and strong. Today

the ideas that Mises had painstakingly refuted have run their course. Inflationism, socialism, and

statism have spelled misery, corruption, and chaos. Reading Mises enables us to understand this

world, and it helps us to see the road that leads out of these quagmires.

Note: The views expressed in Daily Articles on Mises.org are not necessarily those of the Mises

Institute.

Comment on this article.

Page 3: On the Nobel Prize in Economics and Mises

7/27/2019 On the Nobel Prize in Economics and Mises

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/on-the-nobel-prize-in-economics-and-mises 3/3

Jörg Guido Hülsmann is senior fellow of the Mises Institute and author of Mises: The Last Knight of 

Liberalism (http://mises.org/store/Mises-The-Last-Knight-of-Liberalism-P433C0.aspx) and The Ethics of Money Production

(http://mises.org/store/Ethics-of-Money-Production-P536.aspx) . He teaches in France, at Université d'Angers. See Jörg

Guido Hülsmann's article archives (http://mises.org/daily/author/231/Jorg-Guido-Hulsmann) .

You can subscribe to future articles by Jörg Guido Hülsmann via this RSS feed

(http://mises.org/Feeds/articles.ashx?AuthorId=231) .

(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0/)