optimal design of liability rules: how courts set damages (or should) paul m. goldbart and ian ayres...

22
Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres [email protected] w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department of Physics University of Illinois Yale Law School New Haven, CT To appear in Mich. Law Rev., vol. 100, p. 1 (Centenary Volume, 2001)

Upload: roland-heath

Post on 04-Jan-2016

214 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Optimal design of liability rules: How

courts set damages (or should)

Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres

[email protected]

w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart

Department of PhysicsUniversity of Illinois

Yale Law SchoolNew Haven, CT

To appear in Mich. Law Rev., vol. 100, p. 1 (Centenary Volume, 2001)

Page 2: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Outline

Property rules and liability rules Concerns of judges Central aims Nuisance disputes Options view of liability rules Analyzing liability rules Practical advice for courts

decoupling allocational & distributional concerns

choosing among liability rules

Page 3: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Property rules & liability rules

Property rules: protect by deterrence

Liability rules: protect by

compensation

Example: Abbott breaks Costello’s

armIntentionally

focus on taker’s welfare (a criminal offence) traditionally protect via a property rule

Through negligencefocus on takee’s welfare (compensatory

damages) traditionally protect via a liability rule

Page 4: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Property rules & liability rules

Property rules are not efficient

Example: Laurel steals Hardy’s hat Property rule: Hardy can sue to recover hat

(replevin) Liability rule: can also sue for value of hat

(trover) Advantage if hat is worth $10 to Laurel, $5 to

Hardy

Example: Barney holds over in Fred’s apartment Fred can sue to for trespass or to force Fred to rent for another year

Goal of liability rules: Add efficiency by compensating initial entitlement

holderfor transfer of entitlement (goes beyond mere deterrence)

Page 5: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Concerns of judges re liability rules

Traditional view: identity of the initial entitlement holder

compensation as deterrence

Modern view: identity of the more efficient chooser

decouple allocative and distributional concerns

liability rules: a means by which an imperfectlyinformed court can delegate choice to private litigants thus harnessing their superior information

Page 6: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Central aims

Expand and simplify classes of liability

rules that courts have at their disposal

Provide guidance in selecting… class maximizing ex post allocational

efficiency

member of class with best distributional

attributes

(equity, ex ante investment incentives)

Focus on nuisance dispute settings

Page 7: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

A/c noise reduced value of adjacent residence Estancias Dallas Corp. v. Shultz (Tex. App. 1973)

Hotel addition obstructed view of adjacent hotel Fontainbleu Hotel v. Twenty-Five Twenty-Five

Inc. (Fl. 1959)

Dog-track lights interfered w/ drive-in movie theater Amphitheaters, Inc. v. Portland Meadows (Or.

1948)

Pollution from Con Ed plant disrupted new carpreparation business Copart Indus. v. Con. Ed. Co. (N.Y. 1977)

Examples of nuisance disputes

Page 8: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Property rules & liability rules

What courts might do in nuisance disputes E.g. Boomer v. Atlantic Cement (N.Y. 1970)

Resident/Plaintiff (Boomer): discomforted by pollution

Polluter/Defendant (Atl. Cem.): factory operator

Prior to Calabresi & Melamed (’72): Rule 1: nuisance / injunction on Pol (stop!)

Property rule

Rule 2: nuisance / Pol pays damages to continue Liability rule

Rule 3: not a nuisance / Pol continues Property rule

Page 9: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Property rules & liability rules

After Calabresi & Melamed (’72): Rule 1: nuisance / injunction on Polluter (stop!)

Property rule

Rule 2: nuisance / Pol pays Res dam’s & continues

Liability rule

Rule 3: not a nuisance / Polluter continues Property rule

Rule 4: nuisance? / Res pays Pol dam’s to stop Pol

Liability rule

Page 10: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Call option choice of whether or not to pay a non-

negotiatedamount to purchase the entitlement

choice of forcing seller to sell (be paid)

Options: Call flavour

Page 11: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

After Morris (’93): Rule 1: nuisance / injunction on Polluter

(stop!) Property rule: entitlement to Resident

Rule 2: nuisance / Pol can pay dam’s & continue Liability rule: (initial) entitlement to Res; call

option to Pol

Rule 3: not a nuisance / Polluter continues Property rule: entitlement to Polluter

Rule 4: nuisance? / Res can pay dam’s to stop Pol Liability rule: (initial) entitlement to Pol; call

option to Res

Liability rules as call options

Rules 2 vs. 4: Who chooses (to pay)?

Page 12: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Options: Calls and Puts

Call option choice of whether or not to pay a non-

negotiated amount to purchase entitlement

choice of forcing seller to sell (be paid)

Put option choice of whether or not to be paid a non-

negotiated amount to sell entitlement

choice of forcing buyer to buy (pay)

Page 13: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Rule 2: nuisance / Pol can pay damages to continue

Liability rule: initial entitlement to Res; call option to Pol

Rule 4: nuisance / Res can pay damages to stop Pol

Liability rule: initial entitlement to Pol; call option to Res

Rule 5: nuisance / Pol can require damages & stop

Liability rule: initial entitlement to Pol; put option to Pol

Rule 6: nuisance / Res can require dam’s & allow Pol

Liability rule: initial entitlement to Res; put option to Res

Liability rules as call or put options

Put: force to buy Call: force to sell

Rules 2 & 6 v. 4 & 5: Who pays?

Page 14: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Rule 2: Entitlement to Resident; call to

Polluter

Boomer v. Atlantic Cement (N.Y. 1970)

Rule 4: Entitlement to Polluter; call to

Resident

Spur Indus., Inc. v. Del E. Webb Dev. Co. (Ariz.

1972)

Rule 6: Entitlement to Resident; put to

Resident

Thelma builds an encroaching wall on Louise’s

land;

Louise can sue Thelma to remove the wall or

to force

Thelma to buy the encroached land

permanently

Realizations

Page 15: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Imperfectly informed court Explore classes of rules Ex post efficiency as

criterion forwhich rule to adopt? several continuous families of

rules

beyond single-chooser rules dual-chooser rules and veto

power

higher-order rules

Emerging guidelines for courts

Basic ingredients for analyzing

liability rules

Page 16: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

E.g. Rule 2: initial ent to Res; call option to Pol Value of asset to Resident: (known only to

Res) Value of asset to Polluter: (known only to

Pol) Imperfectly informed court: (jpd

known to all)

Analyzing liability rules

RV

PV),( PR VVP

RV

PV

Qpivot

),( DVD P

)0,( RV

profit, (Resprofit) Pol

damages

which at of value PVexercised is option

)( PR VQV

)( QVV PP

meanTotal:profit

Page 17: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Rule 2: initial ent to Res;

call option to Pol

value to Res, Pol ,jpd pivot , damages

Analyzing liability rules

RV PV),( PR VVP

RV

PV

Q

),( DVD P )0,( RV

Q D

)(

)(

DV

DVVD

P

PR

Strategy: 1) choose pivot to

max total mean profit

2) choose damages to elicit this pivot

DQ

i.e. damages =nonchooser’s mean

Page 18: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

E.g. Rule 6: initial ent to Res; put option to Res Value to Resident: Value to Polluter: jpd (known to all):

Analyzing liability rules

RV PV),( PR VVP

RV

PV

Q

),( DVD P

)0,( RV

profit) Pol profit, (Res)( RP VQV

:profit meanTotal

)(

)(

DV

DVVD

R

RP

DQ

i.e. damages = nonchooser’s mean

)( QVV RR

Page 19: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

E.g. Joint veto: initial entitlement to Res; transfer only if Res &

Pol agree value to Res: ; value to Pol: ; jpd:

Dual-chooser rules

RV PV ),( PR VVP

PV

RV

Q

),( DVD P

)0,( RV

)~

()( RPRPR VQQVVVV

:profit meanTotal

)()( DVDVDV RPP

DQQ ~

i.e. implicit eq. for damages

Q~

)()( DVVDVD PRR

Page 20: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

E.g. second order: initial ent to Res call option to Pol call back option to

Res

Higher-order liability rules

RV

PV),( PR VVP

PV

RV

1Q

),( 11 DVD P

)0,( RV

profit) Pol profit, (Res

),( 22 DDVR

2Q

value to Resident: value to Polluter: jpd (known to all):

As usual, choose… pivots to max mean profit damages to elicit pivots

(damages are no longer pivot values: strategic takings)

Page 21: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Explore classes of liability rules single-chooser, dual-chooser, higher-order decouple allocational and distributional

concerns(via continuous families of extensions)

Property rules give entitlement to (estimated) higher

valuer suggested as a general practice, but…

Liability rules do better by harnessing private

information SCR: select more volatile valuer as

chooser DCR: select lower (mean) valuer as vetoee SCR v. DCR: select SCR if diff. in var’s

exceedsdiff. in means

Emerging guidelines

Page 22: Optimal design of liability rules: How courts set damages (or should) Paul M. Goldbart and Ian Ayres goldbart@uiuc.edu w3.physics.uiuc.edu/~goldbart Department

Correlated distributions(e.g. visual nuisances)

Higher-order rules(increased transaction costs)

Numerosity effects

Opportunities for elaboration