ottoman state finance and fiscal institution

Upload: phonkrit

Post on 03-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    1/40

    Ottoman State Finances and Fiscal Institutions

    in European Perspective, 1500-1914

    paper presented at the Workshop onStates and Long-Term Economic Growth

    London School of Economics and Political Science

    October 2, 2008

    by Kivan Karaman * and evket Pamuk **

    * Department of Economics

    Bogazii (Bosphorus) University, Istanbul

    ** European Institute

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    2/40

    1

    I- Introduction

    The early modern era witnessed the emergence of more centralized and bigger states across

    Europe. One of the most important changes involved large increases in the capacity of states to

    command resources. This was achieved primarily through increases in tax collection. These

    higher revenues were obtained not through plunder of other countries, not so much because of a

    rise in per capita incomes but mostly through the taxation of a higher percentage of the existing

    per capita income or GDP. As a result, most states were much larger at the end of the eighteenth

    century in comparison to the beginning of the sixteenth century. At the same time, however,

    there emerged glaring differences between states that were able to raise more revenue and those

    that could not.

    In the long run, there existed a positive relationship between fiscal resources and a capacity

    for sustained and effective action in the international as well as the domestic arena. States

    survived only if they possessed sufficient command over the financial means necessary to defend

    their territories and citizens against external aggression and to meet internal challenges.Throughout the early modern era, by far the largest share of resources commanded by the

    European states went into military expenditures. Military expenditures dominated state budgets

    in peace time but they usually overwhelmed state finances during the frequent wars. Wars thus

    posed the greatest challenge to early modern states. In fact, the survival of states depended

    closely on their ability raise revenue to finance these wars.1

    Wars damaged the economy not only because of the physical destruction but also because of

    the excessive taxation, outright expropriation of resources and other extraordinary measures they

    led to. Large budget deficits, borrowing and the accumulation of large volumes of debt by the

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    3/40

    2

    In other words, there existed in early modern Europe a close relationship between fiscal

    policies, institutional change and economic growth. How states taxed their citizens and how they

    financed the wars prepared had far reaching consequences for the development of economic

    institutions. States and their fiscal policies played a critical role in the development of economic

    as well as political institutions, most notably of property rights.

    Those states which were able to establish and implement an efficient system of taxation and

    revenue generation to command larger volume of resource not only had greater capacity to dealwith domestic challenges, they also enjoyed greater military success to survive in the

    international arena of competing states. Moreover, these early modern states were also able to

    shield their economies better from the very large fiscal shocks created by the wars and bring

    about economic development in the longer term.

    These considerations suggest that the connections between fiscal regime and economic

    institutions as well as economic growth were not simple. Highest rates of economic growth did

    not necessarily take place in countries with low tax rates and small states. It made a big

    difference how tax states raised and commanded more revenues. Those states that were able to

    collect more taxes and finance the wars with less damage to the economy were able to create

    more favorable conditions for long term economic development.

    Tax collection was certainly not easy. One can think of a variety of factors that had an

    impact on the ability of central governments to collect taxes. Size and geography of the country

    certainly played an important role. It was much more difficult to collect taxes in a large country

    with difficult terrain. By the same token, it was a lot easier to collect taxes in a smaller or medium sized country with a relatively homogeneous terrain. In addition, the capacity to collect

    taxes increased in proportion to the degree of urbanization and the size of the urban economy.

    Similarly, the degree of monetization and market orientation had a significant impact on the

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    4/40

    3

    process. All European monarchs had to confront powerful obstacles to their will. None was able

    to raise revenue without negotiation, consultation and sometimes bribery. This was true for the

    so-called absolutist states. In countries with absolutist regimes, large segments of the economy

    remained under the control of elites which were able to evade taxes, at least partially. In contrast,

    parliamentary or representative regimes may have been able to apply taxes to broader sections of

    the economy and collect more taxes because the representative bodies helped negotiate and

    sanction fiscal demands in return for limits on the power of the monarch, especially during

    periods of fiscal crises.2

    Similar considerations applied to state borrowing which was the basic instrument used by

    early modern states to finance the fiscal shocks created by the wars. Those states which were able

    to establish and implement an efficient system of taxation and revenue generation could also

    better manage their long term debt and did not have to resort to more dramatic measures such as

    debasements. Fiscally more successful states were able to reduce their debt during periods of

    peace and establish a permanent system of public debt. In contrast, states which were not able

    collect significant amounts of resources through taxation, were forced to borrow larger amounts

    during periods of war. They also experienced frequent defaults during the early modern era.

    Debasements were also used for generating revenue during periods of war in these states.3

    2 Philip T. Hoffman and Kathyrn Norberg,Conclusion, in Hoffman and Norberg (eds.), Fiscal

    Crises, Liberty and Representative Government, 1450-1789, Stanford University Press, StanfordCalif., 1994, pp. 299-310; Philip T. Hoffman and Jean-Laurent Rosenthal, The PoliticalEconomy of Warfare and Taxation in Early Modern Europe: Historical Lessons for EconomicDevelopment, in John N. Drobak and John V. C. Nye (eds.), The Frontiers of the NewInstitutional Economics, San Diego, Calif., 1997, pp. 31-56; and Patrick K. OBrien and PhilipHunt, England, 1485-1815, in Richard Bonney (ed.) The Rise of the Fiscal State in Europe, c.

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    5/40

    4

    For six centuries until World War I, the Ottoman Empire stood at the crossroads of

    intercontinental trade, stretching from the Balkans and the Black Sea region through

    Anatolia, Syria, Mesopotamia and the Gulf to Egypt and most of the North African

    coast. During the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, its population exceeded 30

    million (of which the European provinces accounted for half or more; Anatolia and

    Istanbul for 7 to 8 million, other Asian and North African provinces for another 7 to 8

    million) but it declined thereafter due to territorial losses.

    For most of its six-century existence, the Ottoman Empire is best characterized as a

    bureaucratic, agrarian empire. The economic institutions and policies of this entity were

    shaped to a large degree by the priorities and interests of a central bureaucracy. Until

    recently, Ottoman historiography had depicted an empire in decline after the sixteenth century. In

    contrast, we will argue that the Ottoman state and society were able to adapt to changing

    circumstances in the early modern era, well before the nineteenth century reforms known as

    Tanzimat or re-ordering. The central bureaucracy managed to contain the many

    challenges it faced with its pragmatism, flexibility and a readiness to negotiate in order

    to co-opt and incorporate into the state the social groups that rebelled against it. The

    Ottoman state also showed considerable flexibility to adapt not only its military

    technology but also its fiscal, financial and monetary institutions in response to the

    changing circumstances.

    The Ottomans were familiar with pragmatism and flexibility from the earliest period.

    Emerging in a highly heterogeneous region populated by Christians and Muslims, Turks and

    Greeks, the Ottomans success in western Anatolia and later in the Balkans during the fourteenth

    and fifteenth centuries owed much to their willingness and ability to adapt to changing

    conditions, to utilize talent and accept allegiance from many peoples, and to make many-sided

    appeals for support. They were thus able attract many followers not only as warriors fighting

    i h Ch i i b l M li d Ch i i fi h i f h i h b i d h

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    6/40

    5

    and borrowing institutions from others. In short, the early Ottoman enterprise was not a religious

    state in the making, but rather a pragmatic one.

    Ultimately, however, pragmatism and flexibility were utilized by the central bureaucracy for

    the defense of the existing order and for its own purposes. Institutional change did not apply

    equally to all areas of Ottoman economic life. Because the central bureaucracy retained its

    leading position in Ottoman society and politics, the influence of various social groups, not only

    of landowners but also of merchants, manufacturers and financiers, over economic matters, andmore generally over the policies of the central government remained limited until the end of the

    empire. Many of the key institutions of the Ottoman order such as state ownership of land, urban

    guilds and restrictions on private capital accumulation remained intact until well into the

    nineteenth century.

    In this study we will review the evolution of Ottoman fiscal institutions and, for the first time,

    analyze the long term trends in the revenues of the Ottoman central government during the early

    modern era, from the early part of the sixteenth century until the end of the eighteenth century.

    We will also compare the long term trends in Ottoman revenues with those of the leading

    European states during the same period. For this pupose, we will use detailed revenue series for the leading European states that we have developed for a related study. To gain further insights

    into the evolution of the ability of the central government to collect taxes, we will also extend

    Ottoman tax revenue series into the period of centralizing reforms of the nineteenth century, from

    the 1840s up to World War I.

    For the purposes of our intertemporal and international comparisons, we will firstconvert all monetary magnitudes in current akes into tons of silver by multiplying the

    magnitudes in current akes with the silver content of the ake for that year. We will

    also take into account inflation by deflating all monetary magnitudes by a consumer

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    7/40

    6

    We expect our study to shed s good deal of light into the long-term changes in

    Ottoman history, especially into the relative power of the central government and the

    tensions between the center and the elites in the provinces which have long been major

    themes in Ottoman historiography. The sixteenth century is generally regarded as a

    period when the power of the central government was at its peak. In contrast, the

    seventeenth and eighteenth centuries are considered a period of de-centralization when

    the rising urban notables in the provinces began to challenge the central government.

    Sharing of locally collected tax revenues is regarded as the critical mechanism that

    helped the ascent of the urban notables during this period. In contrast, the historiography

    has characterized the nineteenth century as a period of centralizing reforms when the

    central government began to undermine the power of local groups. It would be important

    to learn to what extent these generalizations are reflected in the tax revenues of the

    central government by undertaking the inter-temporal analysis suggested by some of the

    indicators above.

    The international comparisons we will develop with the leading European states,

    England, France, Holland and the Dutch Republic, Spain, Venice, Austria-Hungary and

    Russia will help us in at least two respects. By establishing the prevailing trends

    regarding the tax collection capacity of the European states during the early modern era,

    we expect to learn about the extent to which the Ottomans were part of or diverged from

    these trends. Secondly, our comparisons of state revenues should provide important

    insights into Ottoman military power both in absolute and relative terms. We also hope

    to be able to establish the timing and extent to which the decline in Ottoman military

    power was related to trends in Ottoman tax revenues, again in both absolute and relative

    terms.

    We begin below with an overview of the long-term changes in the Ottoman fiscal

    i i i f h i h il 1850 W ill l i h i

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    8/40

    7

    II- Evolution of Ottoman Fiscal Institutions in the Early Modern Erai- Rise of a Centralized State, 1450-1580

    During his two reigns totaling thirty years, Mehmed II (1444 and 1451 to 1481)

    successfully built up an emerging state dependent upon the goodwill and manpower of

    the rural aristocracy into an expanding empire with a large army and bureaucracy. As a

    result, the central government began to control a larger share of the resources andrevenues at the expense of the provinces. A number of harsh measures were used during

    this process. In addition to higher taxes, state monopolies were established in such basic

    commodities as salt, soap and candle wax and their sale to private merchants. Land and

    other properties in the hands of private owners or pious foundations were confiscated.

    Policies of forced colonization and tax concessions were used to bring skilled artisansand other immigrants from Anatolia and the Balkans to reconstuct and repopulate the

    capital city of Istanbul. Finally, very detailed laws were issued to control and regulate

    the economic life in the leading cities of the empire, Bursa, Edirne and Istanbul. The

    degree of interventionism exhibited by the central government in fiscal, economic and

    monetary affairs during this period was unmatched in later periods.

    Revenues increased considerably as a result of these measures. The treasury also

    benefited from the territorial conquests of the period and the extraction of one-time or

    annual tributes from vassal states, often paid in gold ducats. Not all of the new revenues

    were spent immediately, however. Mehmed II believed that a strong treasury brought

    power and independence to the ruler. The central government thus followed a policy of accumulating large reserves in its treasury. Budget surpluses and accumulation of

    reserves contributed further to the fiscal strains and shortages of specie experienced by

    the economy and society at large.4

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    9/40

    8

    The reign of Mehmed II was also unique in Ottoman history as a period of frequent

    currency debasements. The silver content of the ake had changed very little from the

    1320s until the 1440s. During the next four decades, however, debasements were used as

    regular policy to finance costly military campaigns and expand the role of the central

    government. Between 1444 and 1481, the silver content of the Ottoman currency was

    reduced by a total of 30 percent through debasements undertaken roughly every ten

    years to raise funds for the central treasury. Debasements thus complimented increased

    taxation and other fiscal measures adopted by Mehmed II to concentrate a greater share

    of imperial resources at the center, to support the growing needs of an expanding

    bureaucracy and a central army as well as to finance the mil itary campaigns.5

    Mehmed's harsh fiscal measures and strong doses of interventionism encountered

    strong discontent if not opposition, particularly from the ulema who lost control of

    larges sources of revenue from the pious foundations. Owners of the privately held lands

    (mlk) which were expropriated by the state joined the opposition. The nomads, warriors

    and aristocrats of the frontier areas who had participated in the military campaigns and

    contributed to their success also opposed to increased centralization and taxation.

    Nonetheless, Mehmed II continued with these policies until the end of his reign through

    a combination of increased power at the center and the success of his military campaigns

    which resulted in considerable territoral expansion and booty for many of the groups

    involved. Over the long term, the opposition of the janissaries and other groups to

    periodic debasements contributed to the stability of the ake. After the death of Mehmed

    II, his son Bayezid II was forced to seek reconciliation with those groups that his father

    alienated during his long and forceful reign. He returned the assets of some of the pious

    foundations and lands expropriated by his father. In addition, he promised to end the

    policy of debasements. During the following century, ake returned to the stability it had

    enjoyed before the reign of Mehmed II with little change in its weight and silver content

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    10/40

    9

    ii- Institutions of Tax Collection and Internal Borrowing during Decentralization,

    1580-1780

    The evolution of Ottoman fiscal institutions during the seventeenth and eighteenth

    centuries provides a good example of the ability of the Ottoman state to contain the

    challenges it faced with pragmatism, flexibility and negotiation in order to co-opt and

    incorporate into compliance the social groups that challenged its authority. At the same

    time, however, the rise of provincial groups severely curtailed the ability of the Ottoman

    government to collect taxes was. Administrative and military weakness went hand in

    hand with fiscal weakness.

    While loans to kings, princes and governments were part of the regular business of

    European banking houses in the late medieval and early modern periods, in the Islamic

    world advances of cash to the rulers and the public treasury were handled differently.They took the form of tax-farming arrangements in which individuals possessing liquid

    capital assets advanced cash to the government in return for the right to farm the taxes

    of a given region or fiscal unit for a fixed period. Tax-farming thus dominated the

    Islamic world from the Mediterranean to the Indian Ocean, from the earliest days

    through the early modern period.From the very beginning the Ottomans relied on tax-farming for the collection of

    urban taxes. Until late in the sixteenth century, however, the agricultural taxes which

    constituted the largest part of the tax revenues were collected locally and mostly in kind

    within the timar system. Sipahis, state employees who resided in the rural areas were

    expected to spend these revenues to equip and prepare a given number of soldiers for military campaigns. Until the second half of the sixteenth century state finances were

    relatively strong thanks to the revenues obtained through the rapid territorial expansion

    of the empire and the state did not come under pressure to increase the revenues

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    11/40

    10

    the sixteenth century. These services earned the financiers, mostly Jews and Greeks, the

    inside track for the most lucrative tax-farming contracts.6

    With the changes in military technology during the sixteenth century and the need to

    maintain larger and permanent armies at the centre, however, pressures increased to

    collect a larger share of the rural surplus at the centre. As a result, the timar system

    began to be abandoned in favor of tax-farming and the tax-farms were auctioned off at

    Istanbul.7 The shift away from the timar system had been designed to increase the cash

    receipts at the center, but the decline of the state power vis--vis the provinces reduced

    the benefits expected from this change. During the seventeenth century, bureaucrats in

    the capital and provincial groups began to share tax farming revenues with the central

    government.

    In the longer term, further deterioration of the state finances increased thedependence of the central government on the tax-farming system for the purposes of

    domestic borrowing. The central government began to increase the length of the tax-

    farming contracts from one to three years to three to five years and even longer. It also

    demanded an increasingly higher fraction of the auction price of the contract in advance.

    Tax-farming was thus converted to a form of domestic borrowing with the actual taxrevenues being used as collateral by the central government.

    In 1695 further steps were taken in the same direction with the introduction of the

    malikane system in which the revenue source began to be farmed out on a life-time basis

    in return for a large initial payment to be followed by specified flows of annual

    payments.8

    One rationale often offered for this system was that by extending terms of contracts, the state hoped that tax contractors might take better care of the tax source,

    6 H. Inalcik, and D. Quataert (eds.), An Economic and Social History, pp. 212-14.

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    12/40

    11

    most importantly the peasant producers, and try to achieve long term increases in

    production. In fact, the malikane allowed the state to use tax revenues as collateral and

    borrow on a longer term basis. In comparison to the straightforward tax-farming system,

    it represented an important shift towards longer term borrowing by the state. The timing

    of this shift is interesting as it came at a time when the central government was in the

    midst of an extended period of wars against an alliance of European powers, the

    Habsburg, Poles and Russians in the west following the unsuccessful siege of Vienna in

    1683.

    With the extension of terms and the introduction of larger advance payments, long

    term financing of these contracts assumed an even greater importance. Private financiers

    thus began to play an increasingly important role in the tax collection process. Behind

    the individual that bid in the tax-farming auctions, there often existed a partnership

    including financiers as well as the agents organizing the tax collection process itself

    often by dividing the initial contract into smaller pieces and finding sub-contractors.

    Non-Muslims were prohibited from holding most malikane contracts but Greeks,

    Armenians and Jews were very much part of this elite as financiers, brokers and

    accountants. These arrangements mostly took the form of Islamic business partnership

    involving both Muslims and non-Muslims.9 Over the course of the eighteenth century,

    some 1,000 to 2,000 Istanbul based individuals, together with some 5,000 to 10,000

    individuals based in the provinces, as well as innumerable contractors, agents,

    financiers, accountants and managers came to control an important share of the states

    revenues. These coalitions of Istanbul based elites and the rising elites in the provinces

    constituted a semi-privatized but interdependent component of the regime.10 Many

    provincials were able to acquire and pass from one generation to next small and medium

    sized malikane shares on villages as long as they retained favour with local

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    13/40

    12

    administrators or their Istanbul sponsors. For both the well-connected individuals in the

    capital city and those in the provinces, getting a piece of government tax revenues

    became an activity more lucrative than investing in agriculture, trade or manufacturing.

    These changes in the tax collection and revenue sharing system did not, however,

    alter the legal basis of land ownership until the nineteenth century. Despite the rise of

    provincial elites, most agricultural lands remained miri or state land with the peasant

    households holding the usufruct while the sipahis gave way to tax farmers who were

    later replaced by malikane owners. State ownership of land combined with usufruct by

    the peasant household, a key institution of the classical Ottoman order thus remained

    intact until the modern era.

    In the longer term, however, the malikane system did not fulfill the expectations of

    the central government. It actually led to a decline in state revenues because of theinability of the state to regain control of its revenue sources after the death of the

    individuals who had purchased them.11 The central government thus began to experiment

    with other methods for tax collection and domestic borrowing as state finances came

    under increasing pressure from the 1770s onwards. After the end of the war of 1768-

    1774, which had dramatically exposed the military as well as financial weaknesses of

    the Ottoman system, the financial bureaucracy instituted a new and related system of

    long-term domestic borrowing called esham. In this system, the annual net revenues of

    from tax source were specified in nominal terms. This amount was divided into a large

    number of shares which were then sold to the public for the lifetime of the buyers. The

    annual revenues of the source continued to be collected by the tax farmers. The esham

    generally sold for six to seven times the annual net payments which remained fixed.12 As

    the linkage between the annual government payments to esham holders and the

    underlying revenues of the tax source weakened, the esham increasingly resembled a life

    i i l i E i f h i d

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    14/40

    13

    One motivation for the new system was to broaden the base of state borrowing and

    reach beyond the limited numbers of large financiers who tended to dominate the

    malikane auctions towards a larger pool of small and medium sized lenders. However,

    the inability of the state to control or limit the sales of the esham between individuals

    and the difficulties in preventing the heirs of the deceased f rom continuing to receive

    payments seriously limited the fiscal benefits of this system. During the next half

    century, the state vacillated between abolishing the esham during periods of fiscal

    stability and expanding it when fiscal pressures mounted and additional funds had to be

    secured with little regard for their long-term cost.13

    iii- Linkages with western European capital markets?

    Recent research suggests that western European capital markets experienced a substantialdegree of integration during the early modern era. Most international capital flows during this

    period took the form of lending to private and public borrowers in other countries, not direct

    investment. These international flows were facilitated by the political and institutional changes

    taking place in western European countries. As a result of institutional changes and greater

    integration of capital markets, there occurred from the late medieval to the eighteenth centurysubstantial decreases in and a large degree of convergence of interest rates paid by the western

    European governments. These nominal rates of interest declined from a range of 10 to 20 percent

    per annum in the fourteenth century to a range of 5-10 percent in the seventeenth and to less than

    5 percent in the eighteenth century.14

    The Ottoman Empire remained outside the European capital markets network until the secondhalf of the nineteenth century. While the Ottoman government did not consider external

    borrowing until late in the eighteenth century, it is not clear how much interest there would have

    been in the western European capital markets to lend to the Ottoman government. In part because

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    15/40

    14

    Ottoman Empire remained significantly higher than those prevailing in western Europe during

    the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. Since the Ottoman government used the tax collection

    process for most of its borrowing as discussed above, it is not easy to identify the rate of interest

    paid by the state. Nonetheless, one may calculate the implicit rate of interest on the basis of some

    of the esham auctions in the second half of the eighteenth century. Such calculations suggest that,

    until the middle of the nineteenth century, interest rates at which the state could borrow remained

    in the 12 to 15 percent range and rose to the 15 to 20 percent range and even higher during

    periods of distress such as wars or monetary instability.15 It appears that the Ottoman

    governments inability or unwillingness to commit credibly to repayment put limits to the

    amounts they could borrow in the domestic markets. While the successful European pattern of

    public borrowing during wartime was followed by budget surpluses and paying back in

    peacetime, the Ottomans resorted to debasements whenever borrowing could not meet the states

    financial needs.

    The evolution of Ottoman tax collection institutions during the seventeenth and

    eighteenth centuries illustrates the state's ability and willingness to reorganize as a way

    of adapting to changing circumstances, albeit slowly and often with considerable time

    lags. This pragmatism and flexibility also provides important clues for understanding the

    longevity of the empire as well as the key position of the central bureaucracy until the

    end. In order to remain at the top, the central bureaucracy was thus willing to share the

    tax revenues with the provincial groups during the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries

    until it was able to re-assert itself in the nineteenth century.

    It also appears that the Ottomans were willing to borrow or adapt European fiscal

    institutions well before the nineteenth century. Despite recent research on the evolution

    of the Ottoman forms, the causal connections between the evolution of the Ottoman

    institutions of public finance as outlined here and the evolution of the European

    i i i f bli fi d i h h d i h h i h

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    16/40

    15

    century brought about rapid changes not only in the institutions of private finance but

    also in those of public finance.16

    III- Evidence from Ottoman Budgets, 1523-1788

    The Ottoman state prepared many ex-post budgets in the early modern era. These

    documents itemized and recorded the cash receipts of the central treasury as well as itsexpenditures. A recent project has brought together all of the more than 40 such

    documents that have been located to date in the Ottoman archives. These budgets cover

    the years 1523 to 1788 and constitute an important primary source for analyzing the

    Ottoman finances during the early modern era.17

    In this section we present the basic results of our analysis of the long term trends in therevenue side of these budgets. Graph 1 summarizes the long term trends in the tax revenues of the

    Ottoman central government during the early modern era. The series given in tons of silver are

    obtained by multiplying the nominal revenues in current akes by the silver content of the ake.18 We present two revenue series in this and the following graphs. The first series named

    Ottoman I refers to the cash receipts of the central government in Istanbul or the central treasury.The second series named Ottoman II includes, in addition the direct cash receipts, the indirect

    receipts of the central government. A large part of the tax revenues of the Ottoman state

    were collected in the provinces, in fact, in the villages, by cavalrymen (sipahis) who

    16 G. Parker, The emergence of modern finance in Europe, 1500-1730, C. Cipolla (ed.), TheFontana Economic History of Europe, 2 (1974), 560-82; For the case of France, the country mostlikely to have influenced the changes in Ottoman institutions of public finance, see D. R. Weir,Tontines, public finance and revolution in France and England, 1688-1789, The Journal of Economic History 49 (1989), 95-124; and F. R. Velde and D. R. Weir, The financial market and

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    17/40

    16

    were appointed by the state under the prebendal timar system. The sipahi converted

    these revenues to cash in order to equip and train soldiers a specified number of soldiers.

    He then joined the military campaigns together with the soldiers as requested by the

    Ottoman government. It is estimated that the cash equivalent of the tax revenues

    collected by the cavalrymen exceeded the cash receipts of the central treasury during the

    sixteenth century. After the timar system began to be replaced by the central government

    in the seventeenth century in favor of a larger central army permanently stationed in the

    capital and other urban areas, these indirect revenues began to decline. We estimate that

    the share of these and other indirect revenues declined to 40 percent of total revenues of

    the central government by the end of the eighteenth century.

    It would be more meaningful to calculate tax revenues of the Ottoman central government on

    a per capita basis, by dividing the total revenues in tons of silver by the population of the empire

    and also in inflation adjusted terms. We recognize that it is not easy to come up with precise

    population estimates for the Ottoman Empire for the early modern centuries. However, if we

    accept to work with a certain margin of error, say 10 to 15 percent, in our population estimates, it

    is possible to derive the per capita revenue series which should provide us with important

    insights into the revenue collection capacity of the Ottoman central government. For the purposes

    of this study, however, we have decided to exclude all the autonomous or semi-autonomous

    territories such as Crimea, Hungary, Wallachia and Moldavia, the Maghreb, that is, present day

    Libya, Tunis and Algeria and those regions of the Arabian Peninsula at least nominally controlled

    by the Ottoman government. These territories did not send any tax revenues to the central

    Treasury. This leaves us primarily with the present day Balkans, Anatolia, greater Syria and

    present day Iraq and Egypt. Since total population of these latter areas fluctuated narrowly between 17 and 23 million for most of the early modern era, the long term trends in per capita

    revenues of the central government are very similar to those in tons of silver terms.

    I G h 2 h i i i i fl i dj d b d fl i h

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    18/40

    17

    inflation in nominal prices or nominal akes was quite significant, inflation in silver terms was

    rather limited in the Ottoman Empire during the early modern centuries.19

    The long term trends in tax revenues expressed in both tons of silver and also in inflation

    adjusted per capita terms suggest that cash receipts of the Ottoman central government fluctuated

    within a relatively narrow range during the early modern era. The basic trend in both of these

    series was horizontal, neither decline nor increase. In addition to this broad trend, a number of

    secondary trends were at work. Total revenues both in tons of silver and in inflation adjusted

    terms increased until the third quarter of the sixteenth century. This may be called the peak of

    Ottoman power in the sixteenth century. The basic trend was for revenues of the central

    government to decline from the fourth quarter of the sixteenth century until the end of the

    seventeenth century. This was basically due to decentralization and the sharing of the revenues of

    the central government by various provincial groups. In response, the Ottoman government

    undertook major fiscal reforms at the end of the seventeenth century and these efforts succeeded

    in raising significantly. The trend then was one of increase during the first half of the eighteenth

    century. The second half of the eighteenth century witnessed and steady decline in the revenues

    of the central government until the 1780s for which we have budget documents. We should

    reiterate, however, all of these medium term fluctuations took around the basic horizontal trend

    for the early modern centuries as a whole.

    Another indicator that would enable us to gain insights into the revenue collection capacity of

    the central govenment would be to compare revenues collected per capita with some indicator of

    incomes, preferably average incomes. For the early modern era, our estimates of per capita

    incomes are available only for a few benchmark years and even those are subject to some not

    insignificant margin of error. In contrast, data for the the daily wages of construction workers in

    the urban centers, especialyy in the leading urban centers is much more abundant and a lot more

    reliable. For this reason, we prefer to follow the lead of other economic historians in recent years

    d b i i h i f h i i h h d il f kill d

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    19/40

    18

    data for the daily wages of unskilled as well as skilled construction workers in Istanbul for many

    if not most years of the early modern era. Daily wage data is also available for other urban

    centers such as Edirne, Bursa, Belgrade, Salonica, Jerusalem and others but not to the same

    extent. 20

    By dividing the per capita capita revenues of the central government by the daily wage of

    unskilled workers, we obtain a reasonably good measure of the tax collection capacity of the

    central government. (Graph 3) We recognize that even if daily wages in Istanbul were quite

    comparable to those in other Ottoman cities such as Edirne, Bursa or Belgrade in the sixteenth

    and even in the seventeenth centuries. However, there began to emerge a gap between the daily

    wages in Istanbul and other cities possibly in the eighteenth century and certainly in the

    nineteenth century. This may create some problems especially in the sake of international

    comparisons we will develop in the next section but we are willing to work with that limited

    margin of error.

    IV- Comparisons with Other European States in the Early Modern Era

    This section presents the summary results of the comparisons we have undertaken between

    Ottoman central government revenues in the early modern era with those of the leading

    European states, England, France, Holland and the Dutch Republic, Spain, Venice,

    Austria-Hungary and Russia. We have taken care to apply similar definitions of revenue

    to all the states to ensure that we are comparing similar magnitudes.

    Graphs 4, 4B and 5 present the long term trends in total and per capita revenues of theOttoman state and leading European states during the early modern era. Some very basic patterns

    emerge from these comparisons. Tax revenues of the Ottoman central government in both total

    and per capita terms were comparable to those of large European states during the sixteenth

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    20/40

    19

    century. In fact, Ottoman total revenues were greater than all European states except France and

    Spain during the sixteenth century. This pattern is consistent with Ottoman military power vis-a-

    vis the leading European states during that era. The Ottomans did quite well militarily during the

    sixteenth century. In per capita terms, tax revenues of the Ottoman central government were also

    comparable with those of larger European states but was already below those of European city

    states like Venice and Holland. It should also be noted that a large part of the revenues of Spain

    were due to inflows of silver from the Americas.

    Our series make clear that that revenues and tax collection capacity of most European states

    tended to increase during the seventeenth and especially the eighteenth centuries. Most striking

    in this respect were England and Holland but others including, most importantly for the Ottomans

    Austria and Russia also experienced significant increases in tax revenues. At a time when the

    Ottoman central government was struggling with the adverse effects of decentralization, these

    trends led to the emergence of large gaps in state revenues between the Ottomans and most

    European states. These differences reached their peak during the second half of the eighteenth

    century when the revenues not only of the more successful and more powerful states in western

    Europe but also those in central and eastern Europe such as Austria and Russia with which the

    Ottomans engaged militarily increased sharply. The picture we present here is strikingly

    consistent with what happened in the battlefield during this period.

    The Ottomans were defeated at the gates of Vienna at the end of the seventeenth century only

    against a large coalition of central and eastern European states. Due, in part, to fiscal reforms that

    show up very clearly in our fiscal series, the Ottomans were able to increase their revenues and

    militarily hold their own against Austria, Venice and Russia during the first half of the eighteenth

    century. As the fiscal gap widened further during the second half of the eighteenth century,

    however, Ottoman military performance began to lag clearly behind these states and they were

    defeated in most of the wars that took place in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries

    i A i d R i 21

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    21/40

    20

    It would be useful to briefly analyze the causes of the emerging differences in tax revenues

    between the Ottoman Empire on the one hand and the European states, on the other. As Identities

    1, 2 and 3 below make clear, there were four basic causes of the emerging differences in tax

    revenues measured in tons of silver between the Ottoman Empire and other European states. One

    source of the growing differences in tax revenues in tons of silver was growing the differences in

    GDP per capita. Per capita GDP and incomes were rising rapidly in England and the Netherlands

    during the early modern centuries. By the second half of the eighteenth century, per capita GDP

    and incomes in these countries were approximately double those in the Ottoman Empire. Incontrast, however, per capita GDP in the rest of the continent did not show any strong trend,

    rising to some extent in western Europe but declining in southern Europe, especially in Italy.

    Identity 1:Tax Revenues in Tons of Silver = Nominal GDP in Tons of Silver * Tax Revenues aspercent of GDP

    Identity 2:

    Nominal GDP in Tons of Silver = Population * Real GDP per capita (index, Britain,

    1820=100) * Price Level in grams silver

    Identity 3:

    Tax Revenues as percent of GDP = Revenues in Tons of Silver / Nominal GDP in Tons of Silver

    Another cause of the emerging differences in tax revenues measured in tons of silver was the

    changing price levels. In the late fifteenth and early sixteenth centuries, before the impact of the

    so-called Price Revolution began to be felt in Europe and the Near East, price levels in southern

    E d th Ott E i high th th i th t f ti t l E D i g

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    22/40

    21

    Ottoman Empire and in Italy by the second half of the eigteenth century. With a higher price

    level in silver terms, states tended to collect more taxes measured in tons of silver. Higher price

    levels also meant, however, that it would cost more in northwestern and more generally in

    western Europe to buy the same basket of military goods including soldiers and equipment. In

    other words, this component of the growing difference in tax revenues did not translate into

    differences in military power.22 (Graph 6)

    The third cause of the growing gap in tax revenues was the differences in population trends.

    The population of the Ottoman Empire changed very little from the middle of the sixteenth

    century until the end of the eighteenth century. This is the case even if we exclude those areas

    that seceeded from the Ottoman Empire and limit our intertemporal comparison to areas within

    the same borders. In contrast, population in most Euroepan countries that are included in our

    comparisons increased sharply during the early modern centuries, doubling or more than

    doubling in many cases.

    Table 1 here. Population in 1500 and in 1780 for all countries.

    These three causes of the emerging differences, population, GDP per capita and the price level

    were all components of total GDP. In fact, when we multiply these three components, we reach

    total GDP. In other words, one important reason for the emreging differences in total revenues

    between the Ottomans, on the one hand, and the most of the continental European countries, on

    the other, was the large growing differences in total GDP. Ottoman GDP changed little during the

    early modern era while GDP of most European countries increased substantially during the early

    modern centuries for the reasons we have discussed.

    The final cause of the emerging differences in revenues was the rapidly growing differences

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    23/40

    22

    income per capita in western Europe undoubtedly made it easier for states to collect more taxes,

    and even raise the ratio of taxes as a percent of GDP but our comparisons suggest that rising

    GDP can not be the only explanation for the growing differences in state revenues.

    One simple way to measure the differences in the capacity of states to collect tax revenues or

    the tax burden of the population is to compare the tax revenues of the states per capita with the

    daily wages of unskilled workers. We have detailed and quite reliable wage data for this purpose.

    Graph 3 made very clear that ratio of per capita tax revenues of the Ottoman central government

    to daily wages of unskilled construction workers did not exhibit a siginificant trend during the

    early modern centuries. In other words, the capacity of the Ottoman state to collect taxes was not

    any higher at the end of the early modern era. In sharp contrast, Graph 7 makes clear that the

    same ratio rose sharply in most European countries during the early modern era. European states

    were able to collect significantly more taxes even after holding constant for incomes, the most

    readily avaialable measure of which was daily wages of construction workers in the early modern

    era. As a result, the differences in this ratio between the Ottomans and leading European states

    widened substantially during the eighteenth century.

    These very basic international comparisons make clear that while the Ottomans experimented

    with and were willing to adopt a variety of different fiscal institutions for the purposes of tax

    collection and domestic borrowing during the early modern era, unlike most other Eurpean states,

    they were unable to increase their revenues. By sharing the revenues with the provincial groups,

    most importantly the urban notables, they may have been able to obtain the commitment of these

    groups to the unity of the empire and they were able to to hold the empire together. Our

    comparisons also make clear, however, that in terms of the ability of states to command resources

    and translate that into military power by the second half of the eighteenth century, the differences

    between the Ottomans and most European states was becoming increasingly stark.

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    24/40

    23

    It would be important to explore the reasons why the central government and the ayan were

    not able to reach an agreement that might have allowed the central government a higher share of

    the tax revenues in return for greater recognition of the powers of the ayan and more explicit

    limits on the powers of the central government. For such an agreement, the ayan needed to act

    collectively and effectively, but they suffered from coordination problems. As a result, despite

    substantially lower tax revenues and reduced military and administrative powers, the central

    government was able to benefit from the local and regional rivalries amongst the ayan families

    and play one against the other. Without collective action, most ayan refrained from individualinitiatives that would place them directly in conflict against the central government. All the ayan

    needed the legitimation Istanbul provided them by recognizing them as tax collectors for the

    central government.

    It would also be worth exploring the impact of lower central government revenues on the

    economy and on economic institutions. Fiscally successful European states did not allocate large

    resources towards economic development, through infrastructure investment, for example, during

    the early modern era. However, they did create an macroeconomic and institutional environment

    favorable to economic development, at least not unfavorable to economic development.

    On the other hand, states which were not able to manage their finances well created

    unfavorable consequences for the economy and economic institutions.

    Large public debt, frequent defaults and frequent debasements led to an macroeconomic

    environment unfavorable for long term economic development.

    Moreover, the fiscal difficulties of the Ottoman state forced it to employ practices such as :

    - extraordinary taxes- exporopriations of the wealth of former state officials but not of merchants- fiscally motivated monopolies in international trade

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    25/40

    24

    V- Epilogue: Modern Reforms and Fiscal Centralization, 1780-1914

    The reign of sultan Mahmud II (1808-1839) was a particularly difficult period for the

    empire and the central government. During these three decades the government was

    forced to deal with a series of uprisings, nationalist revolutions and wars abroad. While

    it was able to suppress the various uprisings of notables in both the Balkans and

    Anatolia, the Serbian and Greek revolutions led to the secessions of these territories

    from the empire. Much more costly to the state finances than any of these was a series of

    wars against Russia (1806-1812 and 1828-29), Iran (1820-28) and Egypt (1831-33 and

    1838-39).

    This was also a critical period for Western style, centralizing reforms. Attempts at

    military reform had begun earlier, during the reign of Selim III (1789-1807), but progress had been limited due to the opposition of the janissaries. These efforts gained

    momentum after the abolition of the janissaries in 1826. As the size of the new army

    (Nizam-i Cedid) rose from a mere 2,000 around the turn of the century to 120,000 in the

    late 1830s, pressures on state finances increased.23 Roughly speaking, about half of the

    budget expenditures were allocated for mil itary spending from the late eighteenth until

    the 1840s; this share was considerably higher during periods of war.24

    Another important and difficult task was the reorganization and modernization of the

    bureaucracy. The strategy of the reformist and centralizing sultan Mahmud II (1808-

    1839) was to eliminate the intermediate authorities both in the capital and the provinces.

    As the reform movement began to spread beyond the military arena in the 1820s, toadministration, justice, and education, however, the demands for resources increased as

    well. Precise budget figures do not exist, but recent estimates suggest that after

    adjusting for inflation, the expenditures of the central government increased by 250 to

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    26/40

    25

    300 percent, from about 18 million current kurush or 2 million ducats at the end of the

    eighteenth century to about 400 million current kurush or 7 million ducats at the end of

    the 1830s. To deal with changes of such magnitudes constituted a financial task of

    enormous proportions for the central government. As a result, one of the key goals of the

    reform process was the re-organization of state finances and greater centralization of the

    revenues. As part of these efforts the multi-treasuries and budgets of the earlier era were

    gradually dissolved for the single budget system.25

    These increases in revenue were not sufficient to meet the rising expenditures,

    however. From the 1770s until the 1840s the Ottoman state finances frequently

    experienced large budget deficits. These deficits reached their peak during the 1820s and

    1830s. In response, the state attempted to increase control over revenue sources, made

    use of various forms of internal borrowing, and when the short term fiscal pressures

    mounted, resorted to debasements. The highest rates of debasement in Ottoman history

    took place during the reign of the centralizing and reformist sultan Mahmud II. The

    silver content of the Ottoman kurush or piaster declined by more than 80 percent from

    1808 to 1844. Closely paralelling the debasement of the currency was the sharp fall in

    its exchange rate and the rapid rise in the general price level. The exchange rate of the

    kurush against the British pound sterling declined from 18 kurush per pound in 1808 to110 kurush per pound in 1844. Indices constructed from the account books of the

    imperial kitchen and the account books of the pious foundations at Istanbul show that

    food prices increased more than 5 fold during the same period.

    In the longer term, centralization helped the government raise its revenues at the

    expense of the previously powerful groups in the provinces. Beginning in the 1820s, the

    central government began to undermine the powerful alliance between the high level

    bureaucrats and financiers in the capital and the notables in the provinces. As a result, it

    bl l h ll i d i h

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    27/40

    26

    interpreted as the modernization of Ottoman state finances. Nonetheless, due to the

    costs military and administrative reform, the expenditures continued to rise at a faster

    pace. For this reason, the government was forced to devote a large part of its energies,

    from the late eighteenth century until the 1840s, towards developing new methods of

    long-term internal borrowing.

    Around mid-century, the financing of the budget deficits reached a new phase. Under

    the fiscal pressures created by the Crimean War, the Ottoman government began to

    borrow in the European financial markets in 1854. After two decades of rapid borrowing

    the proceeds of which were used mostly for military expenditures, the government was

    forced to declare a moratorium in debt payments in 1876. After a prolonged period of

    negotiations and in return for a 50 percent reduction on the outstanding nominal debt,

    the government agreed in 1881 to cede large segments of its revenue sources to the

    Ottoman Public Debt Administration to be developed for the purposes of future debt

    payments. The Ottoman Public Debt Administration remained in place until World War

    I.

    VI- Evidence from Ottoman Budgets, 1840 to 1914

    Ottoman budget documents do not exist for the period from the end of the 1780s to the end of

    the 1830s. This is not surprising because, as we discussed above, this was a period of great

    institutional changes for Ottoman state finances and budgets as well. One of the key goals of

    the reform process was the re-organization of state finances and greater centralization of

    the revenues. As part of these efforts the multi-treasuries and budgets of the earlier erawere gradually dissolved for the single budget system. Since the centralization of the state

    finances and budgets literally took decades, revenues of the central governments rose as many of

    the revenue sources were being incorporated to the budgets of the central government during this

    27

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    28/40

    27

    of silver. Graph 8 presents revenues of the Ottoman central government during the

    nineteenth century in tons of silver and Graph 9 presents per capita revenues as a

    multiple of the daily wage of unskilled construction workers in the capital city. These

    series make strikingly clear that the nineteenth century was a very different era as far as

    Ottoman state finances and Ottoman capacity for revenue collection was concerned.

    After all of the adjustments are made regarding changes in prices, population and

    growing per capita income, they show unequivocally that the centralizing reforms that

    began at the end of the eighteenth century and continued throughout the nineteenthcentury until World War I, led to large increases in the revenues of the Ottoman central

    government. If there was any doubt that the reforms of the nineteenth century led to

    significant rise in the power of the central government, these series make very clear that

    they did.

    This very sharp rise in central government revenues during the nineteenth century in many

    ways reflected an attempt at catching up for the Ottomans. Since most European states had

    experienced a significant rise in their revenues during the early modern era, especially during the

    eighteenth century when the Ottoman revenues were in fact declining, the trends summarized in

    graphs xx and xx reflect the fiscal results of the delayed centralization for the Ottomans. This

    sharp rise in revenues undoubtedly helped the Ottoman government to improve its militarycapabilities and keep the empire together during the nineteenth century. This did not mean that

    the Ottomans were able to catch up to any significant extent with the European countries

    countries. The tax collection capacity of most European states also continued to rise during the

    nineteenth century as a result of both the rise in GDP and the rise of tax revenues tax collection

    capacity of the states as measured by the total revenues / GDP ratio. Moreover, wars becameeven more expensive and military expenditures kept on rising during the nineteenth century.

    Ottoman efforts to finance these expenditures led to large amounts of foreign borrowing and the

    accumulation of a large debt despite the substantial rise in tax revenues

    28

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    29/40

    28

    given the right to develop these revenue sources. The OPDA was able to make regular large

    annual payments on the Ottoman debt to the creditors until World War I. We estimate that the

    annual revenues of the OPDA from these sources amounted to an additional 1 to 2 percent of theOttoman GDP during the decades before World War I.

    VII- Conclusion

    For most of its 600-year existence, the Ottoman Empire is best characterized as a bureaucratic,agrarian empire. The economic institutions and policies of this large entity were shaped to a large

    degree by the priorities and interests of its central bureaucracy. The influence of various social

    groups, not only of landowners but also of merchants and moneychangers, over the policies of

    the central government remained limited. Key economic institutions of the Ottoman order such as

    state ownership of land, guilds, urban provisioning and selective interventionism remainedmostly intact during this period. Pragmatism, flexibility, willingness to negotiate, ability to adapt

    their institutions to changing circumstances were traits that enabled the Ottomans to keep the

    empire together until the nineteenth century. Ultimately, however, pragmatism and flexibility was

    utilized by the central bureaucracy for the defense of the existing order and of its own position.

    This paper examined the long term changes in the Ottoman fiscal institutions in the earlymodern era from this perspective of pragmatism, flexibility and selective institutional change. It

    focused on the changing Ottoman strategies and institutions in dealing with tax collection,

    debasements and internal borrowing. Ottoman institutions of private and public finance retained

    their Islamic lineage and remained little influenced by the developments in Europe until the end

    of the seventeenth century. The Ottoman government continued to rely on tax-farming for bothtax collection and short term borrowing purposes during this period. As fiscal pressures mounted

    in the eighteenth century, the Ottomans began to experiment more forcefully with new

    institutions of tax collection and domestic borrowing.

    29

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    30/40

    29

    during periods of war. There was also a significant difference between the Ottoman state finances

    and those of the leading European countries, however. In early modern Europe successful states

    were able to mobilize the reseources required for effective action in international relations as wellas the force needed to meet domestic challenges to its authority. While revenues of most

    European states rose significantly during the early modern era, especially during the eighteenth

    century, revenues of the Ottoman state did not. Our comparison of the tax revenues indicate that

    one important difference between the Ottomans and the western European states was the political

    and administrative power of the central government. In the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries,the Ottoman state was not strong but weak; it was forced to share its tax revenues with various

    intermediaries, both in the capital and the provinces. As a result, state finances came under a

    good deal of pressure, especially during periods of war. Fiscally motivated debasements were

    used frequently during this period and created a good deal of macroeconomic instability

    especially in the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries.

    States which were not able to manage their finances well created unfavorable consequences

    not only for the economy but also for economic institutions. The fiscal difficulties of the Ottoman

    state forced it to employ practices such as extraordinary taxes, exporopriations of the wealth of

    former government officials and fiscally motivated monopolies on international trade. Most

    important, perhaps, was the decline in internal security as well as external security due to thefiscal difficulties of the government. These developments led to a marked deterioration in the

    economic institutional environment during the second half of the eighteenth century and the early

    decades of the nineteenth century.

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    31/40

    Graph 1: Annual Revenues of the Ottoman Statein tons of si lver

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    1523 1546 1567 1590 1653 1669 1693 1698 1702 1710 1747 1785

    Ottoman II

    Ottoman I

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    32/40

    Graph 2: Inflation adjusted Revenues per capita,1566-67=100

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    500

    600

    1523 1546 1567 1590 1653 1669 1693 1698 1702 1710 1747 1785

    Ottoman II

    Ottoman I

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    33/40

    Graph 3: Revenues per capita / daily wage in Istanbul

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    1523 1546 1567 1590 1653 1669 1693 1698 1702 1710 1747 1785

    Ottoman II

    Ottoman I

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    34/40

    Graph 4: Annual Revenues of European States, 1500-1789in tons of silver

    0

    500

    1000

    1500

    2000

    2500

    1500-09 1550-59 1600-09 1650-59 1700-09 1750-59

    France England

    Spain Austria

    Russia Holland

    Dutch Rp Ottoman II

    Ottoman Venice

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    35/40

    Graph 4B: Revenues o f the European States

    in tons of silver

    10

    100

    1000

    10000

    1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800

    England France

    Spain Ottoman

    Ottoman 2 Venice

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    36/40

    Graph 5: Per Capita Tax Revenues of European Statesin grams of silver

    0

    50

    100

    150

    200

    250

    300

    350

    1500-09 1550-59 1600-09 1650-59 1700-09 1750-59 1780-89

    France Ottoman

    Ottom II England

    Spain Austria

    Russia Holland

    Dutch Rp Venice

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    37/40

    Graph 6: Consumer Price Index in Leading Cities

    0,0

    0,5

    1,0

    1,5

    2,0

    2,5

    3,0

    1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800

    London Paris Valencia Istanbul

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    38/40

    Graph 7: Per Capita Tax Revenues of European Statesin daily wages of unskilled construction workers in the capital city

    0

    5

    10

    15

    20

    25

    30

    35

    1500-09 1550-59 1600-09 1650-59 1700-09 1750-59 1780-89

    France Ottoman

    Ottom II England

    Spain Austria

    Russia Holland

    Dutch Rp Venice

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    39/40

    Graph 8: Revenues of the Ottoman Government

    in tons of si lver

    0

    500

    1000

    1500

    2000

    2500

    3000

    3500

    1523 1566 1608 1669 1696 1704 1747 1852 1872 1892 1910

    Ottoman II

    Ottoman I

    19th century

  • 7/28/2019 Ottoman State Finance and Fiscal Institution

    40/40

    Graph 9: Revenues per capita / daily wage in Istanbul

    0

    2

    4

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    16

    1523 1547 1582 1653 1691 1696 1702 1734 1784 1852 1868 1884 1900 1912