outline

39
Outline 1. Locating a shopping mall 2. A model of the firm 3. Profit maximization 4. Marginal analysis 5. Sensitivity analysis

Upload: nuwa

Post on 05-Jan-2016

48 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Outline. Optimal Decisions using Marginal Analysis. Locating a shopping mall A model of the firm Profit maximization Marginal analysis Sensitivity analysis. Locating a shopping mall in a coastal area. Villages are located East to West along the coast (Ocean to the North) - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Outline

Outline

1. Locating a shopping mall

2. A model of the firm

3. Profit maximization

4. Marginal analysis

5. Sensitivity analysis

Page 2: Outline

Locating a shopping mall in a coastal area

West East15 15

Number of Customers per Week (Thousands)

Distance between Towns (Miles)

AH

B C D E F G

10 1010 10205

x

3.0 3.5 2.5 4.5 4.52.0 2.0

•Villages are located East to West along the coast (Ocean to the North)

•Problem for the developer is to locate the mall at a place which minimizes total travel miles (TTM).

Page 3: Outline

Minimizing TTM by enumeration

•The developer selects one site at a time, computes the TTM, and selects the site with the lowest TTM.

•The TTM is found by multiplying the distance to the mall by the number of trips for each town (beginning with town A and ending with town H).

•For example, the TTM for site X (a mile west of town C) is calculated as follow:

(5.5)(15) + (2.5)(10) + (1.0)(10) + (3.0)(10) + (5.5)(5) +

(10.0)(20) + (12.0)(10) + (16.5)(15) = 742.5

Page 4: Outline

Marginal analysis is more effective

Enumeration takes lots of computation. We can find the optimal location for the mall

easier using marginal analysis—that is, by assessing whether

small changes at the margin will improve the objective (reduce

TTM, in other words).

Page 5: Outline

Illustrating the power of marginal analysis

1. Let’s arbitrarily select a location—say, point X. We know that TTM at point X is equal to 742.5—but we don’t need to compute TTM first.

2. Now let’s move in one direction or another (We will move East, but you could move West).

3. Let’s move from location X to town C. The key question: what is the change in TTM as the result of the move?

4. Notice that the move reduces travel by one mile for everyone living in town C or further east.

5. Notice also that the move increases travel by one mile for everyone living at or to the west of point X..

Page 6: Outline

Computing the change in TTM

To compute the change in total travel miles (TTM) by moving from point X to C:

TTM = (-1)(70) + (1)(25) = - 45

Reduction in TTM for those residing in and to the East of town C

Increase in TTM for those residing at or to the west of point X.

Conclusion: The move to town C unambiguously decreases TTM—so keep moving East so long as TTM is decreasing.

Page 7: Outline

Rule of Thumb

Make a “small” move to a nearby alternative if, and only if, the move will improve one’s objective (minimization of TTM, in this case). Keep moving, always in the direction of an improved objective, and stop when no further move will help.

• Check to see if moving from town C to town D will improve the objective.

• Check to see if moving from town E to town F will improve the objective.

Page 8: Outline

Model of the firm

Assumptions:

1. A firm produces a single good or service for a single market with the objective of maximizing profit.

2. The task for the firm is to establish price and output at levels which achieve the objective.

3. Firms can predict the revenue and cost consequences of its price and output decisions with certainty.

Page 9: Outline

A microchip manufacturer

A microchip is a piece of semiconducting material that contains a large number of integrated circuits.

• The problem for the microchip manufacturer is to determine the quantity of chips to manufacture, as well as their price.

• The objective of management is to maximize profits—the difference between revenue and cost.

• In algebraic terms, we have:

= R – C

where is profit; R is revenue, and C is cost.

Page 10: Outline

Definitions

•Demand: The quantities of a good or service (or factor of production) buyers are willing and able to buy at various prices, other things being equal.

•Quantity demanded: The quantities of a good or service (or factor of production) buyers are willing and able to buy at a specific price, other things being equal.

•Law of demand: Other things being equal, price and quantity demanded of a good or service (or factor of production) are inversely related.

Page 11: Outline

The demand for microchips

2 4 6 8 100

50

100

150

200

A

B

C

Price (Thousands of Dollars)

Quantity (Lots)

The firm uses the demand curve to

predict the revenue consequences of

alternative pricing and output policies

Page 12: Outline

Algebraic representation of demand

•The demand curve for microchips is given by:

Q = 8.5 - .05P, [2.1]

Where Q is the quantity of lots demanded per week, and P denotes the price per lot (in thousands of dollars).

•We see, for example, that if the P = 50, then according to [2.1] Q = 6. This corresponds to point C on our demand curve.

Page 13: Outline

Inverse demand and the revenue function (R)

By rearranging equation [2.1], we obtain the following inverse demand equation for microchips:

P = 170 – 20Q [2.2]

Note that revenue from the sale of microchips (R) is given by price (P) times quantity sold (Q) or:

R = P Q

Substituting [2.2] into this equation yields the revenue function (R);

R = P Q = (170 – 20Q)Q = 170Q – 20Q2 [2.3]

Page 14: Outline

The revenue function (R)

2 4 6 8 100

100

200

300

400

Quantity (Lots)

Total Revenue (Thousands of Dollars)Quantity Price Revenue

(Lots) ($000s) ($000s)0.0 170 01.0 150 1502.0 130 2603.0 110 3304.0 90 3605.0 70 3506.0 50 3007.0 30 2108.0 10 808.5 0 0

Page 15: Outline

Check Station 1

The inverse demand function is given by:

P = 340 - .8Q

Find the revenue function:

Thus the revenue function is given by:

R = P Q = (340 - .8Q)Q = 340Q - .8Q2

Page 16: Outline

The cost function (C)

To produce microchips, the firm must have a plant, equipment, and labor.

•The firm estimates that for each chip produced, the cost of labor, materials, power, and other inputs is $38. This converts to a variable cost of $38,000 per lot.

•In addition, there are $100,000 in cost the firm could not avoid even if it shut down—that is, fixed cost = $100,000.

•Thus, the cost function is given by:

C = 100 + 38Q [2.4]

Page 17: Outline

C = 100 + 38Q

450

400

350

300

250

200

150

500 2 4 6 8 10

Total cost

100

Quantity (Lots)

Total Cost (Thousands of Dollars)

Quantity Cost(Lots) (000s)

0.0 1001.0 1382.0 1763.0 2144.0 2525.0 2906.0 3287.0 366

Page 18: Outline

The profit function ()

Given a revenue function (R) and a cost function (C), we can derive a profit function ():

= R – C [2.5]

= (170Q – 20Q2) – (100 + 38Q)

= -100 + 132Q – 20Q2

Page 19: Outline

Profit from microchips

150

100

50

0

-50

-100

-1500 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

Total Prof it (Thousands of Dollars)

Total prof it

Quantity Profit Revenue Cost(Lots) ($000s) ($000s) (000s)

0.0 -100 0 1001.0 12 150 1382.0 84 260 1763.0 116 330 2144.0 108 360 2525.0 60 350 2906.0 -28 300 3287.0 -156 210 366

Page 20: Outline

Check Station 2Suppose the demand function is

P = 340 - .8Q

And the cost function is:

C = 120 + 100Q

Write the profit() function:

28.240120 QQ

Page 21: Outline

Marginal Analysis--Again

OK, we have a profit equation. Now we want to find the profit maximizing quantity (Q). One

method is enumeration—that is, we substitute different values

for Q into [2.5] until we find the Q that gives the highest profit

(). But this is too cumbersome. Marginal analysis is better.

Page 22: Outline

The marginal profit (M) function

Marginal profit (M) is the change in profit resulting from a small change in a managerial decision variable, such as output (Q).

The algebraic expression for marginal profit is

Change in profit

Change in outputMarginal profit =

01

01

QQQ

where the term “” stands for “change in,” Q0 is the initial level of output (0 is the corresponding level of profit) and Q1 is the new level of output.

Page 23: Outline

Marginal profit

Quantity Profit Marginal Profit(Lots) (dollars) Per Lot

2.5 1050002.6 108000 300002.7 110600 260002.8 112800 220002.9 114600 180003.0 116000 140003.1 117000 100003.2 117600 60003.3 117800 20003.4 117600 -20003.5 117000 -60003.6 116000 -100003.7 114600 -14000

To compute M when Q increases from 2.5 to 2.6 lots:

000,30$1.

3000$

Q

M

Page 24: Outline

Marginal profit (M) is equal to the slope of a line tangent to the profit function

119

118

117

116

Prof it (Thousands of Dollars)

3.0 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5Quantity (Lots)

B

•Slope at point A = M = 8,000

•Slope at point B = M = 0

Notice that profit () is maximized when the slope of the function is equal to zero

A

Page 25: Outline

Maximum profit is attained at the output level at which marginal profit is zero.

Again our profit function is given by

= -100 + 132Q – 20Q2 [2.6]

Marginal profit (the slope of the profit function) can be found by taking the first derivative of the profit function with respect to output:

QdQ

dM 40132

[2.7]

Page 26: Outline

Set M = 0 and solve for Q

M = 132 – 40Q = 0

Solving for Q yields:

Q = 132/40 = 3.3 lots

We know that profit is maximized when the slope of the profit function is equal to

zero. So set the first derivative of the function equal to zero to

find the optimal output

Page 27: Outline

Check Station 4

Suppose the demand function is

P = 340 - .8Q

And the cost function is:

C = 120 + 100Q

Write the marginal profit (M) function. Set M = 0 to find the optimal output:

QdQ

dM 6.1240

1506.1/24006.1240 QQ

Page 28: Outline

Marginal revenue

•Marginal revenue is the additional revenue that comes from a unit change in output and sales. The marginal revenue (MR) of an increase in sales from Q0 to Q1 is given by:

Change in revenue

Change in outputMarginal revenue =

01

01

QQ

RR

Q

R

Page 29: Outline

Marginal cost

•Marginal cost is the additional cost of producing an extra unit of output. The marginal revenue (MC) of an increase in output from Q0 to Q1 is given by:

Change in cost

Change in outputMarginal cost =

01

01

QQ

CC

Q

C

Page 30: Outline

Profit maximization revisited

We know that = R – C. It follows that:

M = MR – MC [2.9]

We also know that profit is maximized when M = 0. Another way is say this is that profit is maximized when MR – MC = 0. This leads to profit maximizing rule of thumb:

The firm’s profit-maximizing level of output occurs when the additional revenue from selling an extra unit just equals the extra cost of producing it, that is, when MR = MC

Page 31: Outline

400

300

200

100

0

–1000 2 4 6 8

Total Revenue, Cost, and Profit (Thousands of Dollars)

Total cost

Revenue

Profit

(a)

Equating MR and MC

•MR is given by the slope of a line tangent to the revenue function

•MC is given by the slope of a line tangent to the cost function.

•Profit is maximized when the slopes of the revenue and cost functions are equal

Page 32: Outline

Microchip example--again

We know that MR = 170 – 40Q. We know also that MC = 38. To solve for the profit maximizing output set MR = MC and solve for Q:

170 – 40Q = 38

Thus:

40Q = 132, therefore Q = 3.3 lots

Page 33: Outline

Check station 5

Suppose the inverse demand and cost functions are given by:

P = 340 - .8QC = 120 + 100Q

Solve for the profit maximizing level of output using the MR = MC approach.

Step 1 is to obtain the revenue function (R):

R = P · Q = (340 - .8Q)Q = 340Q - .8Q2

Now find MR by taking the first derivative of R with respect to Q:

MR = dR/dQ = 340 - 1.6Q

Now find MC by taking the first derivative of C with respect to Q:

MC = dC/dQ = 100

Now set MR = MC and solve for Q:

340 – 1.6Q = 100

1.6Q = 240. Thus Q = 240/1.6 = 150

Page 34: Outline

Sensitivity analysis

For any change in economic conditions, we can trace the impact (if any) on the firm’s marginal revenue or marginal cost. Once we have identified this impact, we can appeal to the MR = MC rule to determine the new, optimal decision.

In light of changes in the economic facts of a given problem, how should the

decision maker alter his or her course of action? Marginal

analysis is a big help.

Page 35: Outline

Changing economic facts

Using sensitivity analysis, we can determine the change in the optimal output resulting from the following:

•A change in overhead (fixed) costs;

•A change in materials (variable) cost; and

•A change in demand

Page 36: Outline

150

100

50

(a) Marginal Revenue and Cost (Thousands of Dollars)

3.3Quantity (Lots)

MR = 170 - 40Q

MC = 38

MR = MC when Q = 3.3 lots

Initial optimum output of microchips

Page 37: Outline

150

100

50

(a) Marginal Revenue and Cost (Thousands of Dollars)

3.3Quantity (Lots)

MR = 170 - 40Q

MC = 38

MR = MC when Q = 3.3 lots

Overhead increases by $12,000

Notice that the optimal output does not change, since MC is unaffected by a change in overhead cost. Profit, however, decreases by $12,000—whatever the level of output

Page 38: Outline

150

100

50

(b) Marginal Revenue and Cost (Thousands of Dollars)

3.3Quantity (Lots)

MR = 170 - 40Q

MC = 38

MC = 46

3.1

Silicon prices rise from $38,000to $46,000 per lot

Note this will shift the MC function up the vertical axis

Setting MR = MC we obtain:

170 – 40Q = 46

Q = 124/40 = 3.1 lots

Page 39: Outline

150

100

50

(c) Marginal Revenue and Cost (Thousands of Dollars)

3.3Quantity (Lots)

MR = 190 - 40Q

MC = 38

3.8

Note the increase in demand is manifest in a shift to the right of the MR function

Setting MR = MC, we obtain:

190 – 40Q = 38

Q = 152/40 = 3.8 lots

Increased demand for microchips