research article basel iii and asset securitizationthe transaction costs related to low-quality...

20
Hindawi Publishing Corporation Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society Volume 2013, Article ID 439305, 19 pages http://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/439305 Research Article Basel III and Asset Securitization M. Mpundu, M. A. Petersen, J. Mukuddem-Petersen, and F. Gideon Faculty of Commerce & Administration, North-West University (Ma๏ฌkeng Campus), Private Bag x2046, Mmabatho 2735, South Africa Correspondence should be addressed to M. A. Petersen; [email protected] Received 14 June 2013; Revised 28 September 2013; Accepted 30 September 2013 Academic Editor: Oswaldo Luiz do Valle Costa Copyright ยฉ 2013 M. Mpundu et al. is is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License, which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited. Asset securitization via special purpose entities involves the process of transforming assets into securities that are issued to investors. ese investors hold the rights to payments supported by the cash ๏ฌ‚ows from an asset pool held by the said entity. In this paper, we discuss the mechanism by which low- and high-quality entities securitize low- and high-quality assets, respectively, into collateralized debt obligations. During the 2007โ€“2009 ๏ฌnancial crisis, asset securitization was seriously inhibited. In response to this, for instance, new Basel III capital and liquidity regulations were introduced. Here, we ๏ฌnd that we can explicitly determine the transaction costs related to low-quality asset securitization. Also, in the case of dynamic and static multipliers, the e๏ฌ€ects of unexpected negative shocks such as rating downgrades on asset price and input, debt obligation price and output, and pro๏ฌt will be quanti๏ฌed. In this case, we note that Basel III has been designed to provide countercyclical capital bu๏ฌ€ers to negate procyclicality. Moreover, we will develop an illustrative example of low-quality asset securitization for subprime mortgages. Furthermore, numerical examples to illustrate the key results will be provided. In addition, connections between Basel III and asset securitization will be highlighted. 1. Introduction Asset securitization involves the process by which securities are created by a special purpose entity (SPE)โ€”herea๏ฌ…er, simply known as an entityโ€”and then issued to investors with a right to payments supported by the cash ๏ฌ‚ows from a pool of ๏ฌnancial assets held by the entity. ere is broad-based usage of entities by ๏ฌnancial institutions of many types, in various jurisdictions, and for many purposes (see, e.g., [1]). Securitization has been popular as an alternative funding source for consumer and asset lending in market economies. Its main objective is to improve credit availability by con- verting hard-to-trade and nontradable assets into securities that can be traded on capital markets. e categorization of the payment rights into โ€œtranchesโ€ paid in a speci๏ฌc order and supported by credit enhancement mechanisms provides investors with diversi๏ฌed credit risk exposure to particular investor risk appetites (see, e.g., [2, 3]). Immediately prior to the securitization market collapse in 2007-2008, structured asset products (SAPs) such as asset-backed securities (ABSs) and collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) as well as covered bonds provided between 25 and 65% of the funding for new residential assets originated in the US and Western Europe (see, e.g., [4]). In most developed economies, SAP growth peaked by 2007 before declining rapidly due to a lack of liquidity in secondary markets and decreases in primary issuance (see [5] for more details). For example, SAP issuance in the US decreased from about US $2 trillion in 2007 to around US $400 billion in 2008. e impact of the ๏ฌnancial crisis on securitization in emerging markets was more modest as initial growth had been more subdued. e contribution of securitization to the ๏ฌnancial crisis necessitated changes to banking regulation. In this regard, the introduction of Basel III capital and liquidity regulation includes elements that will potentially a๏ฌ€ect the incentives for banks to securitize assets (see, e.g., the Basel documents [2, 5โ€“7]). ere are several Basel III provisions that address areas of concern that were highlighted during the ๏ฌnancial crisis and which supervisors determined as not adequately addressed under the previous framework (see, e.g., [6]). More speci๏ฌcally, in July 2009, the Basel Committee for Banking Supervision (BCBS) published enhancements to the Basel II framework that were intended to strengthen the framework and respond to lessons learned from the ๏ฌnancial crisis (see [8] for more details). For instance, because of the higher degree of inherent risk in resecuritization exposures,

Upload: others

Post on 28-Jan-2021

6 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Hindawi Publishing CorporationDiscrete Dynamics in Nature and SocietyVolume 2013, Article ID 439305, 19 pageshttp://dx.doi.org/10.1155/2013/439305

    Research ArticleBasel III and Asset Securitization

    M. Mpundu, M. A. Petersen, J. Mukuddem-Petersen, and F. Gideon

    Faculty of Commerce&Administration, North-West University (Mafikeng Campus), Private Bag x2046,Mmabatho 2735, South Africa

    Correspondence should be addressed to M. A. Petersen; [email protected]

    Received 14 June 2013; Revised 28 September 2013; Accepted 30 September 2013

    Academic Editor: Oswaldo Luiz do Valle Costa

    Copyright ยฉ 2013 M. Mpundu et al. This is an open access article distributed under the Creative Commons Attribution License,which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

    Asset securitization via special purpose entities involves the process of transforming assets into securities that are issued to investors.These investors hold the rights to payments supported by the cash flows from an asset pool held by the said entity. In thispaper, we discuss the mechanism by which low- and high-quality entities securitize low- and high-quality assets, respectively,into collateralized debt obligations. During the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis, asset securitization was seriously inhibited. In responseto this, for instance, new Basel III capital and liquidity regulations were introduced. Here, we find that we can explicitly determinethe transaction costs related to low-quality asset securitization. Also, in the case of dynamic and static multipliers, the effects ofunexpected negative shocks such as rating downgrades on asset price and input, debt obligation price and output, and profit will bequantified. In this case, we note that Basel III has been designed to provide countercyclical capital buffers to negate procyclicality.Moreover, we will develop an illustrative example of low-quality asset securitization for subprime mortgages. Furthermore,numerical examples to illustrate the key results will be provided. In addition, connections between Basel III and asset securitizationwill be highlighted.

    1. Introduction

    Asset securitization involves the process by which securitiesare created by a special purpose entity (SPE)โ€”hereafter,simply known as an entityโ€”and then issued to investors witha right to payments supported by the cash flows from a poolof financial assets held by the entity. There is broad-basedusage of entities by financial institutions of many types, invarious jurisdictions, and for many purposes (see, e.g., [1]).Securitization has been popular as an alternative fundingsource for consumer and asset lending in market economies.Its main objective is to improve credit availability by con-verting hard-to-trade and nontradable assets into securitiesthat can be traded on capital markets. The categorization ofthe payment rights into โ€œtranchesโ€ paid in a specific orderand supported by credit enhancement mechanisms providesinvestors with diversified credit risk exposure to particularinvestor risk appetites (see, e.g., [2, 3]). Immediately prior tothe securitization market collapse in 2007-2008, structuredasset products (SAPs) such as asset-backed securities (ABSs)and collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) as well as coveredbonds provided between 25 and 65% of the funding for newresidential assets originated in the US and Western Europe

    (see, e.g., [4]). In most developed economies, SAP growthpeaked by 2007 before declining rapidly due to a lack ofliquidity in secondary markets and decreases in primaryissuance (see [5] formore details). For example, SAP issuancein the US decreased from about US $2 trillion in 2007 toaround US $400 billion in 2008. The impact of the financialcrisis on securitization in emergingmarketswasmoremodestas initial growth had been more subdued.

    The contribution of securitization to the financial crisisnecessitated changes to banking regulation. In this regard,the introduction of Basel III capital and liquidity regulationincludes elements that will potentially affect the incentivesfor banks to securitize assets (see, e.g., the Basel documents[2, 5โ€“7]). There are several Basel III provisions that addressareas of concern that were highlighted during the financialcrisis and which supervisors determined as not adequatelyaddressed under the previous framework (see, e.g., [6]).More specifically, in July 2009, the Basel Committee forBanking Supervision (BCBS) published enhancements to theBasel II framework that were intended to strengthen theframework and respond to lessons learned from the financialcrisis (see [8] for more details). For instance, because of thehigher degree of inherent risk in resecuritization exposures,

  • 2 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    the BCBS significantly increased the risk weights applicableto such exposures under both the standardized (SA) andinternal ratings based (IRB) approaches relative to the riskweights for other securitization exposures (see, e.g., [3, 9,10]). As a result, the capital requirements for resecuritizationhave risen dramatically. In addition, to address the lack ofappropriate due diligence on the part of investing institutionsand deter them from relying solely on external credit ratings,the Basel framework now requires banks to meet specificoperational criteria in order to use the risk weights specifiedin the Basel II securitization framework. During the financialcrisis, credit rating agencies (CRAs) downgraded the ratingsof many securitization tranches, including senior trances,highlighting deficiencies in credit rating agency modelsoriginally used to determine the ratings. Capital requirementsassigned to highly rated (e.g., AAA) senior and mezzaninesecuritization exposures were too low and this was illustratedby the poor performance of these securities (see, e.g., [9, 10]).As CRAs downgraded highly rated securitization exposuresbelow investment grade, regulatory capital requirementsincreased rapidly and significantly due to the presence ofcliff effects within the securitization framework (in thiscontext, cliff effects refer to significant increases in capitalrequirements resulting from a change to a factor used toassign regulatory capital) (see, e.g., [9, 10]). The BCBS alsorevised the market risk rules to increase the level of capitalthatmust bemaintained against securitization exposures heldin the trading book. In addition, the BCBS is reviewingwhether the risk weights for all securitization exposuresshould be recalibrated, which could lead to higher capitalrequirements (see, for instance, the Basel papers [9, 10]).

    The main motivation for this paper is that securitizationhas to be reestablished on a sound basis in order to supportcredit provision to the real economy and enhance banksโ€™access to funding globally (see, e.g., [4]). Basel III would liketo ensure an appropriate risk-sensitive and prudent capital-ization of risks arising from securitization exposures whilereducing cliff effects and mitigating mechanistic reliance onexternal credit ratings (see [3, 9]). The interplay betweenBasel III and asset securitization will be the central themeof this paper. As far as the contribution of this paper isconcerned, we investigate the securitization of low- and high-quality assets (denoted by LQAs andHQAs, resp.) into CDOsvia low-quality entities (LQEs) and high-quality entities(HQEs), respectively, (see, e.g., the BCBSpublications [9, 10]).

    1.1. Literature Review about Asset Securitization and Basel III.In this subsection, we provide literature reviews about assetsecuritization and Basel III capital and liquidity regulation(see [5] for more details).

    1.1.1. Literature Review about Asset Securitization. Motivatedby the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis, there is an ever-growingbody of literature on LQA-related issues such as shocks toLQEs, investors, and CDOs via, for instance, rating changes.The contribution [11] studies the pricing of LQAs and relatedSAPs on the basis of data for the ABX.HE family of indices(see [12] for further details). This, of course, is a recurringtheme in our contribution where we consider asset and CDO

    pricing during the financial crisis. Moreover, [4] addressesthe impact of speculative asset funding on the pricing ofLQAs (measured by risk premia) and securities backed bythese assets (measured by ABX.HE indices). In addition, thepaper [13] extends a Kiyotaki-Moore-type model that showshow relatively small shocks might suffice to explain businesscycle fluctuations, if credit markets are imperfect (see [14] formore details). Our work has a connection with this paper viathe consideration of the effect of shocks on asset parametersalthough we do not emphasize the imperfection of creditmarkets (see [15] for additional analysis). The paper [16]studies the impact of penalties on LQ-loans (see, also, [17]).Here, asset prices and penalties are chosen simultaneouslywith the latter being associated with lower asset prices (see[15] for more details). The paper also contains discussionson prices and penalties and their relationship with loan-to-value ratios (see, also, [18] for more on house equity). In ourcontribution, we will use the framework introduced in [16] toshow how a change in profit subsequent to a negative shockis influenced by subprime mortgage features (see, also, [19]).

    1.1.2. Literature Review about Basel III. In July 2009, the BCBSintroduced enhancements to the Basel II framework via [8].This was done in order to address deficiencies identifiedduring the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis. These measures pri-marily addressed immediate concerns over resecuritizationand was part of reforms known as โ€œBasel 2.5โ€ (see the Baseldocuments [8, 9] for more details about securitization). TheBCBS subsequently agreed to conduct a more fundamentalreview of the securitization framework, including its relianceon external ratings (see, e.g., [20]). The performance of androle played by securitization exposures during the financialcrisis were a key motivation for studying this category of thecapital framework. Subsequently, in [2], the BCBS noted thatit was โ€œconducting amore fundamental review of the securiti-zation framework, including its reliance on external ratings.โ€The BCBS has now performed a broader review of thesecuritization framework for regulatory capital requirementswith objectivesmotivated by events during the financial crisis(see, also, [7]). Furthermore, the consultative document [6]reflects the BCBSโ€™s proposal to revise the Basel frameworkโ€™streatment of securitization exposures. In developing thisproposal, the BCBS seeks to make capital requirements moreprudent and risk sensitive,mitigate reliance on external creditratings, and reduce cliff effects (see, e.g., [3, 6]). In particular,our paper adds to the debate about rating downgrades andshocks associated with them. The policy directions set outin [6] form part of the BCBSโ€™s broader agenda of reformingbank regulatory capital standards to address the lessons ofthe crisis. These proposals build on a series of reforms thatthe BCBS has delivered through Basel III and explain theapproaches under consideration by the BCBS to revise thesecuritization framework (see [6, 21] for further discussion).As in our paper, the features of SPEs are discussed in somedetail in [1].

    1.2. Preliminaries about Asset Securitization. In this subsec-tion, we provide preliminaries about low- and high-quality

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 3

    Table 1: Defining features of LQAs and HQAs; source: [5].

    Feature LQAs HQAsExternal information

    External ratings Low HighMarket data Poor RichAnalystsโ€™ reports Negative Positive

    Internal informationCredit risk High LowLiquidity risk High LowSecuritization exposure Not understood UnderstoodFinancial obligations Not easily met Easily met

    classification as well as LQA and HQA securitization (seeTable 1 for more information).

    1.2.1. Preliminaries about Low- and High-Quality Classifi-cation. As indicated in the BCBS documents [2, 7], thecharacterization of โ€œhigh qualityโ€ is based both, on availableexternal information, such as external ratings, market data,and analystโ€™s reports, and the entityโ€™s own assessment of creditand liquidity risk, whereby the entity should demonstrate itsunderstanding of the terms of the securitization exposure andthe risks of the underlying collateral (see, e.g., [1, 5]). Theentity would be required to demonstrate that the creditquality of the position is strong, with very low default risk,and is invulnerable to foreseeable events, implying thatfinancial commitmentswould bemet in a timelymannerwitha very high probability (see [6, 21] for further discussion).Where this determination could not be made, the positionwould be assumed to be โ€œlow quality.โ€ In particular, in theBasel III document [1], the Joint Forum Working Groupon Risk Assessment and Capital (JFWGRAC) consisting ofthe BCBS, International Organization of Securities Commis-sions (IOSC), and the International Association of InsuranceSupervisors (IAIS) under the support of the Bank for Interna-tional Settlements (BIS), make recommendations about suchentities.

    1.2.2. Preliminaries about LQA and HQA Securitization. Inthis paper, we have that the reference asset portfolios are botha means of generating CDOs and collateral for interentitysponsoring (see, e.g., [1]). Our paper quantifies the effects ofunexpected negative shocks such as rating downgrades onasset price and input, CDO price and output, and profit ina Basel III context (see, also, [19]). For instance, the afore-mentioned result demonstrates how the proportional changein profit subsequent to a rating downgrade is influenced byLQA features such as asset rates. Finally, we present examplesthat illustrate that asset price is most significantly affectedby unexpected negative shocks from asset rates, while, forCDO price, shocks to speculative asset funding, investorrisk characteristics, and prepayment rate elicit statisticallysignificant responses (compare with [3]).

    LQAswere financed by securitizing these assets into SAPssuch as ABSs and CDOs. The lower-rated tranches of low-quality ABSs formed 50 to 60% of the collateral for CDOs

    during 2007.These were extremely sensitive to a deteriorationin asset credit quality. Housing went through a classic inven-tory cycle with a worsening of the inventory-to-sales cyclebeing evident in the midst of the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis.When this inventory situation worsened, the risk that pricewould fallmore rapidly deepened.Themore substantial fall inprices accelerated the delinquency and foreclosure rater andspelt doom for the CDOmarket which was further revised inBasel III (see, e.g., the BCBS paper [3, 9]). We briefly describethe aforementioned SAPs in turn.

    LQ-ABSs are quite different from other securitizationsbecause of the unique features that differentiate low-qualityassets from other assets. Like other securitizations, LQ-ABSsof a given transaction differ by seniority. But unlike othersecuritizations, the amount of credit enhancement for and thesize of each tranche depend on the cash flow coming into thedeal in a very significant way. The cash flow comes largelyfrom prepayment of the reference asset portfolios throughrefinancing. What happens to the cash coming into the dealdepends on triggerswhichmeasure (prepayment and default)performance of the reference asset portfolios.The triggers canpotentially divert cash flows within the structure. In somecase, this can lead to a leakage of protection for higher-rated tranches. Time tranching in low-quality transactions iscontingent on these triggers. The structure makes the degreeof credit enhancement dynamic and dependent on the cashflows coming into the deal.

    In our case, a CDO issues debt and equity and uses theincome to invest in financial assets such as assets and ABSs.It distributes the cash flow from its asset portfolio to holdersof various liabilitiesโ€”usually a capital structure consistingof equity or preferred shares, subordinated debt, mezza-nine debt and AAA-rated senior debt, and borrowingsโ€”inset ways taking into account the relative seniority of theaforementioned liabilities. A key feature of such CDOs isthat they are mainly constituted by ABS portfolios that arerated according to their prevailing credit risk and put intotranches (compare with [3]). CDO tranches include LQ-and Alt-A deals and consist of three categories, namely,senior, mezzanine, and equity or low tranches according toincreasing credit risk. This risk is spread to investors whoinvest in these risky CDO tranches. It is difficult for investorsto locate the risk exposure of these CDOs because of theircomplex design structure.Despite this, CDOshave additionalstructural credit protection which can be characterized aseither cash flow or market value protection. Finally, all CDOsare created to fulfill a given purpose that can be classified asarbitrage, balance sheet, or origination.

    1.3. Main Contributions and Outline. Themain contributionsabout Basel III regulation and asset securitization in thispaper are constituted by the answers to the questions listedbelow.

    Question 1 (LQA securitization). How can we characterizethe securitization of LQAs into CDOs by the LQE? Forinstance, canwe determine the LQE cash flow constraint? (seeLemma 3 in Section 2.1).

  • 4 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    Question 2 (HQA securitization). How can we character-ize the securitization of HQAs into CDOs by HQEs? Forinstance, can we determine the HQEsโ€™ cash flow constraint?(see Lemma 5 in Section 2.2).

    Question 3 (LQE at steady state). How can we characterizethe behavior of an LQE at steady state? (see Theorem 7 inSection 2.3).

    Question 4 (dynamic multiplier: negative shocks to assetsecuritization). For a dynamic multiplier, how do negativeshocks affect asset price and input, CDO price and output,and profit? (see Theorem 8 in Section 3.1).

    Question 5 (static multiplier: temporary shocks to asset secu-ritization). For a static multiplier, how do negative shocksaffect asset price and input? (see Corollary 9 in Section 3.2).

    Question 6 (example of subprime mortgage securitization).How canwe provide an example to illustrate themain featuresof LQA securitization specifically for subprime mortgages?(see Corollary 10 in Section 4.1).

    Question 7 (numerical examples of asset securitization). Howcan we provide numerical examples to illustrate the mainresults obtained in this paper? (see Section 4.2).

    Question 8 (Basel III and asset securitization in general). Ingeneral, how does Basel III capital and liquidity regulationassist in eliminating flaws in existing asset securitizationpractice in banking? (see Sections 2, 3, and 4 formore details).

    This paper is arranged as follows. Section 2 describesHQA and LQA securitization. Also, Section 3 sheds lighton the effect of negative shocks like rating downgrades onthe asset securitization process in a Basel III context whileSection 4 provides numerical examples of the aforemen-tioned. Finally, Section 5 provides some concluding remarksand possible topics for future research.

    2. Low- and High-Quality Entities

    In this section, we consider LQEs and HQEs and theirequilibrium features. We study an economy consisting ofLQAs with a fixed total supply of ๐ด and CDOs that cannotbe retained by the entity. In the sequel, for the sake of argu-ment, we assume that the CDOs correspond to senior CDOtranches. In this model, CDOs are taken as the numeraire.There is a continuum of infinitely lived LQEs andHQEs, withpopulation sizes 1 and ๐‘›, respectively. Both these entities takeone period to securitize assets into CDOsโ€”the LQEs andHQEs produce CDOs from HQAs and LQAs, respectivelyโ€”but they differ in their securitization technologies (refer toTable 1). At each date, ๐‘ก, there is a competitive spot marketin which assets for CDOs are purchased by entities at a priceof ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก. The only other market is a one-period credit market

    in which one CDO unit at date ๐‘ก is exchanged for a claimto 1 + ๐‘ŸB

    ๐‘กunits of CDOs at date ๐‘ก + 1. These markets are

    opaque and are dominated by a handful of interests. During

    Risk profile

    GoodBad xLow

    High

    y

    High-gradeLQ ABS

    LQ ABSbonds

    Low-

    assetsMezzanineABS CDO

    Senior

    Mezzanine

    Equity

    Senior

    Mezzanine

    Equity

    Senior

    Mezzanine

    Equity

    quality

    x-axis: Investor credity-axis: Investor down payment

    Figure 1: Chain of LQAs and their SAPs; source: [4].

    the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis, because CDOs were lightlyregulated their details often went undisclosed. This createdmajor problems in the monitoring of these credit derivativesand the new regulatory framework in Basel III focuses oncorrecting such problems (see [9] for further explanation).

    2.1. The LQE. Figure 1 illustrates the securitization of assetsinto ABSs and ABS CDOs by the LQE.

    We notice from Figure 1 that LQAs are securitized intoABSs that, in turn, get securitized into ABS CDOs. As faras the latter is concerned, it is clearly shown that seniorABS bonds rated AAA, AA, and A constitute the high-gradeABS CDO portfolio. On the other hand, the mezzanine-ratedABS bonds are securitized into mezzanine ABS CDOs, sinceits portfolio is based on BBB-rated ABSs and their trancheswhich expose the portfolio to an increase in credit risk (see,e.g., [3]). From Figure 1, it is clear that the LQEs (and anyother entities), rather than banks, hold assets and ABSs. As aresult, there are reductions in the incentives of banks to playtheir traditional monitoring function. The fundamental roleof banks in financial intermediation according to Basel IIIin the document [22] (see, also, [21]) makes them inherentlyvulnerable to liquidity risk, of both an institution-specific andmarket nature (see [5] for more details). Financial marketdevelopments have increased the complexity of liquidity riskand its management. During the early โ€œliquidity phaseโ€ ofthe financial crisis that began in 2007, many banksโ€”despiteadequate capital levelsโ€”still experienced difficulties becausethey did not manage their liquidity in a prudent manner(see [5] for further discussion). The difficulties experiencedby some banks, which, in some cases, created significantcontagion effects on the broader financial system, were dueto lapses in basic principles of liquidity risk measurementand management (see, e.g., [5] for more details). During the2007โ€“2009 financial crisis, systemic risk from CDOs wasproblematic. In this case, the default of one or more collateral

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 5

    assets or bond classes generated a ripple effect on CDOdefaults. Figure 1 suggest how this may have happened. TheLQE is risk neutral, with its expected utilities being

    E๐‘ก(

    โˆž

    โˆ‘

    ๐‘ =0

    ๐›ฝ๐‘ ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก+๐‘ ) , E

    ๐‘ก(

    โˆž

    โˆ‘

    ๐‘ก=0

    ๐›ฝ๐‘ก๐‘ฅ๐‘ก) , (1)

    where๐‘ฅ๐‘ก+๐‘ 

    and๐‘ฅ๐‘กare their respective LQECDOconsumption

    at dates ๐‘ก + ๐‘  and ๐‘ก, with E๐‘กdenoting the expectation

    formed at date ๐‘ก.These entities have constant returns on scalesecuritization function of

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    = ๐‘† (๐ด๐‘ก) โ‰ก (๐œ‡ + ]) ๐ด

    ๐‘ก, ] = ๐‘ + ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“,

    (๐œ‡

    ๐œ‡ + ]) < ๐›ฝ,

    (2)

    where ๐ด๐‘กare the input assets securitized at date ๐‘ก and ๐ถ

    ๐‘ก+1is

    the CDO output at date ๐‘ก + 1. Also, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“ is the fraction of assetsthat have refinanced and ๐‘ the fraction of CDOs consumed.However, only ๐œ‡๐ด

    ๐‘กof the CDO output is marketable. Here,

    ]๐ด๐‘กis nonmarketable and can be consumed by the LQE. We

    introduce ]๐ด๐‘กin order to avoid the situation in which the

    LQE continually postpones consumption.The ratio ๐œ‡(๐œ‡+])โˆ’1may be thought of as a technological upper bound on theLQEโ€™s retention rate. Since ๐›ฝ is near 1, the inequality in (2)amounts to a weak assumption. We shall see later that thisinequality ensures that in equilibrium the LQE will not wantto consumemore than illiquid CDOs as observed in Basel III(see, e.g., [21]). The overall return from investment, ๐œ‡ + ], ishigh enough that all its marketable CDO outputs are used forinvestment. There is a further critical assumption we makeabout investing.

    Assumption 1 (LQE CDO technology and labor). We assumethat each LQEโ€™s CDO technology is distinct in the sense that,once securitization has started at date ๐‘ก with assets, ๐ด

    ๐‘ก, only

    the LQE has the skill necessary for securitizing assets intoCDOs at date ๐‘ก + 1, subject to the availability of appropriatetechnology and labor. Secondly, we assume that an LQEalways has the option to withdraw its labor.

    In other words, if the LQE were to withdraw its laborbetween dates ๐‘ก and ๐‘ก + 1, there would be no CDO outputat ๐‘ก+1. Assumption 1 leads to the fact that if an LQE is highlyleveraged, it may find it advantageous to threaten the HQEsby withdrawing its labor and repudiating its debt contract.HQEs as interentity lenders protect themselves from thethreat of repudiation by collateralizing the LQAs. However,because assets yield no SAPs without the LQEโ€™s labor, theasset liquidation value (outside value) are less than whatthe assets would earn under its control (inside value). Thus,following a repudiation, it is efficient for the LQE to persuadethe sponsoring HQE into letting it keep the assets. In effect,the LQE can renegotiate a smaller loan. HQEs know of thispossibility in advance, and so take care never to allow thesize of the debt (gross of interest) to exceed the value of thecollateral as in the following assumption.

    Assumption 2 (credit limit). If at date ๐‘ก, the LQE possessesthe assets, ๐ด

    ๐‘ก, then it can borrow B

    ๐‘กin total, as long as the

    repayment does not exceed the market value of assets at date๐‘ก + 1 given by

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB) B๐‘กโ‰ค ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1๐ด๐‘ก, (3)

    where ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก+1

    represents the asset price in period ๐‘ก + 1 while ๐ด๐‘ก

    represents the LQEโ€™s asset holdings in period ๐‘ก. In this case,given rational expectations, agents have perfect foresight offuture asset prices.

    As noted in the Basel III document [21], the objectiveof the LCR is to promote the short-term resilience of theliquidity risk profile of banks (see [5] for additional). Itdoes this by ensuring that banks have an adequate stock ofunencumbered high-quality liquid assets (HQLA) that can beconverted easily and immediately in privatemarkets into cashto meet their liquidity needs for a 30-calendar-day liquiditystress scenario. Of course, during the 2007โ€“2009 financialcrisis, when monitoring incentives was reduced, it is unlikelythat the HQE monitored the LQE closely. The LQEโ€™s balancesheet consists of assets and marketable securities (assets)as well as borrowings and capital (liabilities). Therefore, anLQEโ€™s balance sheet constraint can be represented at time ๐‘ก as

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐ต๐‘ก= B๐‘ก+ ๐พ๐‘ก, (4)

    where ๐‘๐ด, ๐ด, ๐ต, B, and ๐พ represent the LQEโ€™s asset price,asset holdings,marketable securities, borrowings, and capital,respectively. As we have mentioned before, the entitiesโ€™capital structure consisting of equity or preferred shares,subordinated debt, and mezzanine debt LQE enforces a pricecap (PC), with the weighted average PC being denoted by ๐‘(see, e.g., [4] for more details). In this case, we have that theCDO price is given by

    ๐‘๐ถ

    ๐‘ก= min [๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก, ๐‘๐‘ก] , (5)

    where ๐ถ๐‘กโˆ’1

    denotes the quantity of CDOs in period ๐‘ก โˆ’ 1.Hedge funds and other sophisticated investors have incen-tives to manipulate the pricing and structuring of CDOs.Some studies suggest that CDO managers manipulate col-lateral in order to shift risks among various tranches. Thepotential for this can be clearly seen in (5) where the PCoffers ameans of changing collateral features that is importantin determining the CDO price, ๐‘๐ถ

    ๐‘ก. During the 2007โ€“2009

    financial crisis, collateral according to Basel III was alsomanipulated via the violation of restrictions on asset portfoliocomposition, rating category, weighted average life, weightedaverage weighting factor, correlation factors, and the numberof obligors (see [2]). Nevertheless, in our case, the value ofassets in period ๐‘ก can be represented as

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    = B๐‘ก+ ๐พ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ต๐‘ก. (6)

    In general, the asset rate, ๐‘Ÿ๐ด, for profit maximizing entities(see, also, [19]), may be represented as

    ๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘Ÿ๐ฟ

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘ก, (7)

  • 6 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    where ๐‘Ÿ๐ฟ is, for instance, the 6-month LIBOR rate and is therisk premium, that is indicative of asset price (see, e.g., [3]).Next, the LQEโ€™s profit may be expressed as

    ฮ ๐‘ก= (๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘กโˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB๐‘ก, (8)

    where ๐‘Ÿ๐ด, ๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘…, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†, ๐‘Ÿ๐ต, and ๐‘ŸB represent the assetrate, prepayment costs, fraction of assets that refinance,recovery rate, default rate, returns on marketable securities,and borrowing rate in period ๐‘ก, respectively. In this case, assetvalue can be represented by

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    =ฮ ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘ก+ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB๐‘ก

    ๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘กโˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก

    . (9)

    From (9), it is clear that, as recognized by Basel III regulation,even a relatively small default rate can trigger a crisis. Theunwinding of contracts involving the securitization of suchassetsโ€”such as CDO contractsโ€”created serious liquidityproblems during the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis as detailedin Basel III (see [5, 21, 22]). Since the CDO market wasquite large, the crisis caused convulsions throughout globalfinancial markets. By considering the above, we can deducean appropriate LQE cash flow constraint in the followingresult.

    Lemma 3 (LQE cash flow constraint). Suppose that the creditconstraint (3) as well as (6) to (9) holds. In this case, the LQEโ€™scash flow is subject to the constraint

    ฮ ๐‘กโ‰ฅ (๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘กโˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘ก

    โˆ’ ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1๐ด๐‘ก+ B๐‘ก.

    (10)

    Proof. The proof follows from taking constraint (3) fromAssumption 2 and (10) into consideration.

    The LQE can expand its scale of securitization by invest-ing in more assets. Consider an LQE that holds ๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1assets

    at the end of date ๐‘ก โˆ’ 1 and incurs a total debt of B๐‘กโˆ’1

    . Atdate ๐‘ก, the LQE harvests ๐œ‡๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1marketable CDOs, which,

    together with a new loan B๐‘ก, is available to cover the cost

    of purchasing new assets, to repay the accumulated debt(1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B)B๐‘กโˆ’1

    (which includes interest), and to meet any addi-tional consumption ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ]๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    that exceeds the normal con-sumption of non-marketable output ]๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1. The LQEโ€™s flow-

    of-funds constraint is thus

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก(๐ด๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1) + (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) B๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘ฅ๐‘กโˆ’ ]๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    = ๐œ‡๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ B๐‘ก.

    (11)

    2.2. HQEs. For HQEs, Figure 2 shows the chain formed byHQAs, ABSs, and ABS CDOs.

    As we proceed from left to right in Figure 2, HQAs aresecuritized into ABSs that, in turn, get securitized into ABSCDOs. Only the higher-grade ABS bonds rated AAA, AA,andA are securitized thatmake out the high-gradeABSCDOportfolio. Figure 2 also suggests that HQE ABSs and CDOsare not as risky as those of the LQE since the reference asset

    Risk profile

    GoodBad

    Low

    High

    y

    High-gradeABS CDO

    High-qualityABS

    bondsHigh-

    assetsSenior

    Mezzanine

    Equity

    Senior

    Mezzanine

    Equity

    quality

    x

    x-axis: Investor credity-axis: Investor down payment

    Figure 2: Chain of HQAs and their SAPs; source: [4].

    portfolios have higher credit quality. HQE capital levels willalso be greater than those of the LQE, in the sense that theLQE used its capital to provision for low-quality default. Inthis regard, we have the secondary effect of securitizationwhere credit risk is transferred to investors. Basel III identifiesa number of shortcomings within the current securitizationframework some of which were categorised broadly as toolow-riskweights for highly rated securitizations and too high-riskweights for low-rated senior securitization exposures (see[9] for detailed explanation). Furthermore, we assume thatHQEs are risk neutral, with expected utilities:

    E๐‘ก(

    โˆž

    โˆ‘

    ๐‘ =0

    ๐›ฝ๐‘ ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก+๐‘ ) , E

    ๐‘ก(

    โˆž

    โˆ‘

    ๐‘ก=0

    ๐›ฝ๐‘ก๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก) , (12)

    where ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก+๐‘ 

    and ๐‘ฅ๐‘กare their respective consumptions of CDOs

    at dates ๐‘ก + ๐‘  and ๐‘ก. For the discount factors ๐›ฝ๐‘  and ๐›ฝ๐‘ ,we have that 0 < ๐›ฝ๐‘ , ๐›ฝ๐‘  < 1 and suppose that ๐›ฝ <๐›ฝ. This inequality ensures that, in equilibrium, the LQEs

    will not want to postpone securitization because they arerelatively impatient (compare with [13] and the referencescontained therein). The following assumption is made forease of computation.

    Assumption 4 (HQE price, asset, default and borrowing rate).For HQEs, suppose that ๐‘๐ด

    , ๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    , and ๐‘ŸB

    are the asset price,asset rate, and borrowing rate, respectively. For all ๐‘ก, weassume that

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก, ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐ด

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก, ๐‘Ÿ

    B

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘Ÿ

    B๐‘ก, (13)

    where ๐‘๐ด, ๐‘Ÿ๐ด, and ๐‘ŸB are as before for HQEs. Also, we assumethat the assets held by HQEs do not default or refinance.

    In reality, this assumptionmay be violated since LQAs aremore expensive thanHQAs. However, this adjustment can becatered for in the sequel. We shall see that in equilibrium theLQE borrows from HQEs and that the rate of interest alwaysequals the HQEsโ€™ constant rate of time preference so that

    ๐‘ŸB= ๐‘Ÿ

    B๐‘กโ‰ก1

    ๐›ฝโˆ’ 1. (14)

    All HQEs have an identical securitization function thatexhibits decreasing returns to scale. In a Basel III context, the

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 7

    additional quantitative information that HQEs may considerdisclosing could include customised measurement tools ormetrics that assess the structure of HQEsโ€™ balance sheets, aswell as metrics that project cash flows and future liquiditypositions, taking into account off-balance sheet risks, whichare specific to that HQE (see the BCBS publications [5, 21,22]). In this case, per unit of population, an asset input of ๐ด

    ๐‘ก

    at date ๐‘ก yields an output of ๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    marketable CDOs at date๐‘ก + 1, according to

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    = ๐‘ƒ (๐ด

    ๐‘ก) , where ๐‘ƒ > 0,

    ๐‘ƒ< 0, ๐‘ƒ

    (๐ด

    ๐‘›) < ๐œ‡ (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) < ๐‘ƒ(0) .

    (15)

    The last two inequalities in (15) are included to ensure thatboth the LQE and HQEs are producing in the neighborhoodof the steady-state equilibrium. HQEs securitization doesnot require any specific skill nor do they produce any non-marketable CDOs. As a result, no HQE is credit constrainedas noted in Basel III (see [9]). At date ๐‘ก, such entitiesโ€™ budgetconstraint can be expressed as

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก(๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1) + (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) B

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘ƒ(๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1)๐‘กโˆ’1+ B

    ๐‘ก,

    (16)

    where ๐‘ฅ๐‘กis secondary securitization at date ๐‘ก, (1 + ๐‘ŸB)B

    ๐‘กโˆ’1

    is debt repayment, and B๐‘กis new interbank sponsoring. The

    HQEsโ€™ balance sheet constraint

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐ต

    ๐‘ก= B

    ๐‘ก+ ๐พ

    ๐‘ก, (17)

    is the same as in the case for an LQE, but the ratios of thesevariables will differ from those of the LQEs with much lowerrisk (compare with (4)). In this regard, assets held by HQEsare less risky, long-term loans with fixed rates (compare with[3]). Next, the HQEsโ€™ profit may be expressed as

    ฮ 

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB

    ๐‘ก, (18)

    where ๐‘Ÿ๐ด, ๐‘Ÿ๐ต, and ๐‘ŸB represent the asset rate, returns onmarketable securities, and borrowing rate in period ๐‘ก, respec-tively. Notice that the prepayment cost is zero in the case forHQEs (see (10)). Thus, the value of HQAs is represented by

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1=ฮ 

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB๐‘ก

    ๐‘Ÿ๐ด. (19)

    We provide an appropriate HQE cash flow constraint inthe following result.

    Lemma 5 (HQE cash flow constraint). Suppose that the creditconstraint (3) as well as (16) to (19) holds. In this case, theHQEsโ€™ cash flow constraint is given by

    ฮ 

    ๐‘กโ‰ฅ ๐‘Ÿ๐ด๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ B

    ๐‘ก. (20)

    2.3. Market Equilibrium. In equilibrium, B๐‘กโˆ’1

    and B๐‘กare

    negative, reflecting the fact that HQEs lend the LQE. For ourpurposes, market equilibrium is defined as follows.

    Definition 6 (market equilibrium). Market equilibrium is asequence of asset prices and allocations, debt, and securitiza-tion by the LQE and HQEs, given by

    {๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก, ๐ด๐‘ก, ๐ด

    ๐‘ก, B๐‘ก, B

    ๐‘ก, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก, ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก} , (21)

    such that each LQE chooses (๐ด๐‘ก, B๐‘ก, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก) to maximize the

    expected discounted utilities of the LQE andHQEs subject tothe securitization function, sponsoring constraint and flow-of-funds constraint given by (2), (3), and (11), respectively. Onthe other hand, each HQE chooses (๐ด

    ๐‘ก, B๐‘ก, ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก) to maximize

    the above expected discounted utilities subject to the securi-tization function (15) and budget constraint (16). Also, in thecase of the HQE, we have that the markets for assets, CDOs,and debt clear.

    2.3.1. LQE at Equilibrium. In the sequel, we assume that theasset price bubble does not burst during securitization. Inthis case, it turns out that there is a locally unique perfect-foresight equilibrium path starting from initial values ๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1

    and B๐‘กโˆ’1

    in the neighborhood of the steady state. In thisstate, the LQEโ€™s marketable output, ๐œ‡๐ดโˆ—, is just enoughto cover the interest on their debt, ๐‘ŸBBโˆ—. Equivalently, therequired screening costs per asset unit, ๐‘ขโˆ—, equal the LQEโ€™ssecuritization of marketable output, ๐œ‡. As a result, entitiesneither expand nor shrink. To further characterize entityequilibrium, we provide the following Kiyotaki-Moore-typeresult (see [14] for further discussion).

    Theorem 7 (LQE behavior at steady state). Assume that theasset bubble does not burst during the securitization process. Inthe neighborhood of the steady state, the LQE prefers to borrowup to the maximum and invest in assets, consuming no morethan its current output of non-marketable CDOs. In this case,there is a unique steady-state (๐‘๐ดโˆ—, ๐ดโˆ—, Bโˆ—), with the associatedtransaction cost, ๐‘ขโˆ—, being given by

    ๐‘ขโˆ—=

    ๐‘ŸB

    1 + ๐‘ŸB๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    =1

    1 + ๐‘ŸB๐‘ƒ[1

    ๐‘›(๐ด โˆ’ ๐ด

    โˆ—)] = ๐œ‡, (22)

    Bโˆ—=๐œ‡

    ๐‘ŸB๐ดโˆ—. (23)

    Proof. The result follows by considering the LQEโ€™s marginalunit of marketable CDOs at date ๐‘ก. This entity can invest in1/๐‘ข๐‘กassets, which yields ๐‘/๐‘ข

    ๐‘กnon-marketable CDOs and ๐‘Ž/๐‘ข

    ๐‘ก

    marketable CDOs at date ๐‘ก + 1. The former are consumedwhile the latter are reinvested. This, in turn, yields

    ๐‘Ž

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก

    ๐‘

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก+1

    (24)

    non-marketable CDOs and๐‘Ž

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก

    ๐‘Ž

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก+1

    (25)

    marketable CDOs at date ๐‘ก + 2 and so on.

  • 8 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    Next, we appeal to the principle of unimprovability, whichstates that we need to only consider single deviations at date ๐‘กto show that this investment strategy is optimal.There are twoalternatives open to the LQE at date ๐‘ก. Either it can save themarginal unitโ€”equivalently, reduce its current borrowingby oneโ€”and use the return ๐‘… to commence a strategy ofmaximum levered investment from date ๐‘ก + 1 onward orthe LQE can simply consume the marginal unit. Its choiceis equivalent to choosing one of the following consumptionpaths:

    Invest : 0, ๐‘๐‘ข๐‘ก

    ,๐‘Ž

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก

    ๐‘

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก+1

    ,๐‘Ž

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก

    ๐‘Ž

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก+1

    ๐‘

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก+2

    , . . . (26)

    Save : 0, 0, ๐‘ŸB ๐‘๐‘ข๐‘ก

    , ๐‘ŸB ๐‘Ž

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก

    ๐‘

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก+2

    , . . . (27)

    Consumption : 1, 0, 0, 0, . . . (28)

    at dates ๐‘ก, ๐‘ก + 1, ๐‘ก + 2, ๐‘ก + 3, . . ., respectively.To complete the proof of the result, we need to confirm

    that, given the LQEโ€™s discount factor, ๐›ฝ, consumption path(26) offers a strictly higher utility than (27) or (28), in theneighborhood of the steady-state. We shall be in a positionto show this once we have found the steady-state value of ๐‘ข

    ๐‘ก

    in (34) below.Since the optimal ๐‘Ž

    ๐‘กand ๐‘๐‘กare linear in ๐‘Ž

    ๐‘กโˆ’1and ๐‘๐‘กโˆ’1

    , wecan aggregate across entities to find the equations of motionof the aggregate asset holding and borrowing, ๐ด

    ๐‘กand B

    ๐‘ก,

    respectively, of entities may be given by

    ๐ด๐‘ก=1

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก

    [(๐œ‡ + ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก)๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) B๐‘กโˆ’1] , (29)

    B๐‘ก=

    1

    1 + ๐‘ŸB๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1๐ด๐‘ก. (30)

    Next, we consider market clearing. Since all HQEshave identical securitization functions, their aggregate assetdemand equals ๐ด

    ๐‘กtimes their population ๐‘›. The sum of the

    aggregate demand for assets by the LQE and HQEs is equalto the total supply given by

    ๐ด = ๐ด๐‘ก+ ๐‘›๐ด

    ๐‘ก. (31)

    In this case, from (35), we obtain the asset market (clearing)equilibrium condition

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก= ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1

    1 + ๐‘ŸB= ๐‘ข (๐ด

    ๐‘ก) ,

    where ๐‘ข (๐ด) โ‰ก 11 + ๐‘ŸB

    ๐‘ƒ[1

    ๐‘›(๐ด โˆ’ ๐ด)] .

    (32)

    Next, it is useful to look at the steady-state equilibrium.From (29), (30), and (32), it is easily shown that there is aunique steady-state (๐‘โˆ—, ๐ดโˆ—, Bโˆ—), with associated steady-statetransaction cost ๐‘ขโˆ—, where (22) and (23) hold.

    Theorem 7 postulates that at each date ๐‘ก, the LQEโ€™soptimal choice of (๐ด

    ๐‘ก, B๐‘ก, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก) satisfies ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก= ]๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    in (11), andthe borrowing constraint (3) is binding so that

    B๐‘ก=

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1

    1 + ๐‘ŸB๐ด๐‘ก,

    ๐ด๐‘ก=

    1

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’ 1/ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐‘

    ๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1

    [(๐œ‡ + ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก)๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) B๐‘กโˆ’1] .

    (33)

    Here, the term (๐œ‡ + ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก)๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘ŸB)B๐‘กโˆ’1

    is the LQEโ€™s nettworth at the beginning of date ๐‘ก.This corresponds to the valueof its marketable CDOs and assets held from the previousperiod nett of debt repayment. In effect, (33) says that the LQEuses all its nett worth to finance the difference between theasset price, ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก, and the amount the entity can borrow against

    each asset unit, ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก+1/1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B. This difference is given by

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก= ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1

    1 + ๐‘ŸB(34)

    and can be thought of as the screening costs required topurchase an asset unit. The equations of motion of the aggre-gate asset holding and borrowing, ๐ด

    ๐‘กand B

    ๐‘ก, respectively, of

    entities may be given by (29) and (30). Notice from (29) thatif, for example, present and future asset prices, ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กand ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1,

    were to rise, then the LQEโ€™s asset demand at date ๐‘กwould alsoriseโ€”provided that leverage is sufficient that debt repayments(1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B)B๐‘กโˆ’1

    exceed current output ๐œ‡๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    , which holds inequilibrium. The usual notion that a higher asset price ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก

    reduces the LQEโ€™s demand is more than offset by the factsthat they can borrow more when ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1is higher and their

    nett worth increases as ๐‘๐ด๐‘กrises. Even though the required

    screening costs, ๐‘ข๐‘ก, per asset unit rises proportionately with

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กand ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1, the LQEโ€™s nett worth is increasing more than

    proportionately with ๐‘๐ด๐‘กbecause of the leverage effect of the

    outstanding debt.

    2.3.2. HQEs at Equilibrium. Next, we examine the HQEsโ€™behavior at equilibrium. Such entities are not credit con-strained, and so their asset demand is determined at the pointat which the present value of the marginal product of assetsis equal to the transaction fee associated with assets (refer toBasel III in [1]). In this case, we have that

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก= ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1

    1 + ๐‘ŸB=

    1

    1 + ๐‘ŸB๐‘ƒ(๐ด

    ๐‘ก) . (35)

    In themodel,๐‘ข๐‘กis both theHQEsโ€™ opportunity cost of holding

    an asset unit and the required screening costs per unit ofassets held by the LQE.

    2.3.3. LQE and HQE Market Clearing. In this subsection, weconsider market clearing that refers to either a simplifyingassumption made that markets always go to where the assetssupplied equal the assets demanded or the process of gettingthere via price adjustment. Amarket clearing price is the price

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 9

    of goods or a service at which assets supplied are equal toassets demanded, also called the equilibrium price. Anothermarket clearing price may be a price below equilibrium priceto stimulate demand.

    Since all HQEs have identical securitization functions(see Basel III and revision to securitization in [9]), theiraggregate asset demand equals ๐ด

    ๐‘กtimes their population ๐‘›.

    The sum of the aggregate demand for assets by the LQE andHQEs is equal to the total supply given by (31). In this case,from (35), we obtain the asset market (clearing) equilibriumcondition (32). The function ๐‘ข(โ‹…) is increasing. This arisesfrom the fact that if the LQEโ€™s asset demand,๐ด

    ๐‘ก, goes up, then

    in order for the asset market to clear, the HQEsโ€™ demand hasto be stymied by a rise in the transaction fee, ๐‘ข

    ๐‘ก. Given that the

    HQEs have linear preferences and are not credit constrained,in equilibrium they must be indifferent about any path ofconsumption and debt (or credit). In this case, the interestrate equals their rate of time preference so that

    ๐‘ŸB=1

    ๐›ฝโˆ’ 1. (36)

    Moreover, given (32), the CDO markets and credit are inequilibrium.

    We restrict attention to perfect-foresight equilibria inwhich, without unanticipated shocks, the expectations offuture variables realize themselves. For a given level of theLQEโ€™s asset holding and debt at the previous date, ๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1and

    B๐‘กโˆ’1

    , an equilibrium from date ๐‘ก onward is characterized bythe path of asset price, LQE asset holding, and interbank bor-rowings given by

    {(๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+๐‘ , ๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ , B๐‘ก+๐‘ ) ๐‘  โ‰ฅ 0} , (37)

    satisfying (29), (30), and (32) at dates ๐‘ก, ๐‘ก + 1, ๐‘ก + 2, . . ..

    2.4. LQE and HQE Equilibrium Summary. Figure 3 displaysthe main features of market equilibrium for the LQE andHQEs.

    The horizontal axis represents LQA and HQA demandfrom the left-hand side and right-hand-side, respectively. Wenote that the total asset supply is denoted by ๐ด. The verticalaxis represents the marginal products of assets for LQE andHQEs given by ๐œ‡ + ] and ๐‘ƒ(๐ด/๐‘›), respectively. The HQEsโ€™marginal product decreases with asset use. If there are nocredit limits, then ๐ธ0 would be the best allocation for wherethe LQE and HQEmarginal products are in equilibrium.Theasset price would then be ๐‘0 = (๐œ‡ + ])(๐‘ŸB)โˆ’1. On the otherhand, when credit limits exist, then the equilibrium is at point๐ธโˆ—, where the marginal product of the LQE is greater than

    that of the HQE. In this case, we have

    ๐œ‡ + ] > ๐‘ƒ [(๐ด โˆ’ ๐ด

    โˆ—)

    ๐‘›] = ๐œ‡ (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) . (38)

    This means that the LQEโ€™s asset use is not enough.The outputof CDOs per period in equilibrium is represented by thelight gray area under the thick line, whereas the gray trianglerepresents the CDO loss per period. In this case, CDO outputincreases relative to LQA holdings. If ๐ด

    ๐‘กincreases, then the

    CDO output will also increase in period ๐‘ก + 1.

    LQE HQEs0 Aโˆ— At A0 A

    Eโˆ—Et

    E0

    A A

    P(A/n)

    ๐œ‡ + ๏ฟฝ

    ๐œ‡(1 + rB)

    Figure 3: LQE and HQE market equilibrium.

    3. Asset Securitization Shocks

    In this section, we describe the effect of unexpected negativeshocks on LQA price and input, CDO price in a Basel IIIcontext and output, and profit (see, e.g., [19]). In this regard,two kinds of multiplier processes are considered. The firstis the within-period or static multiplier process. Here, theshock such as a ratings downgrade reduces the nett worthof the constrained LQE and compels it to reduce its assetdemand. In this case, by keeping the future constant, thetransaction fees decrease to clear the market and the assetprice drops by the same amount. In turn, this lowers the valueof the LQEโ€™s existing assets and reduces their nett worth evenmore. Since the future is not constant, this multiplier missesthe intuition offered by the more realistic intertemporal ordynamic multiplier. In this case, the decrease in asset pricesresults from the cumulative decrease in present and futureopportunity costs, stemming from the persistent reductionsin the constrained LQEโ€™s nett worth and asset demand, whichare in turn exacerbated by a decrease in asset price and nettworth in period ๐‘ก.

    3.1. Dynamic Multiplier: Response to Temporary Shock. Inorder to understand the effect of unexpected inter-temporalshocks on the economy, suppose at date ๐‘กโˆ’1 that it is in steadystate with

    ๐ดโˆ—= ๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1, B

    โˆ—= B๐‘กโˆ’1. (39)

    3.1.1. Dynamic Multiplier: Shock Equilibrium Path. We intro-duce an unexpected inter-temporal shock where the CDOoutput of the LQE and HQEs at date ๐‘ก are 1 โˆ’ ฮฃ timestheir expected levels. In order for our model to resonatewith the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis, we take ฮฃ to be positive.Eventually, the LQE and HQEsโ€™ securitization technologiesbetween dates ๐‘ก and ๐‘ก+1 (and thereafter) return to (2) and (15),

  • 10 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    respectively. Combining the market-clearing condition (32)with LQA demand under a temporary shock and borrowingconstraint given by (29) and (30), respectively, we obtain

    ๐‘ข (๐ด๐‘ก) ๐ด๐‘ก= (๐œ‡ โˆ’ ๐œ‡ฮฃ + ๐‘

    ๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    )๐ดโˆ—, (date ๐‘ก) , (40)

    ๐‘ข (๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ ) ๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ = ๐œ‡๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    , (dates ๐‘ก + 1, ๐‘ก + 2, . . .) . (41)

    The formulae (40) and (41) imply that at each date the LQEcan hold assets up to the level ๐ด at which the required costof funds, ๐‘ข(๐ด)๐ด, is covered by its nett worth. Notice that in(41), at each date ๐‘ก + ๐‘ , ๐‘  โ‰ฅ 1, the LQEโ€™s nett worth is just itsambient output of marketable CDOs, ๐œ‡๐ด

    ๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1. In this case,

    from the borrowing constraint at date ๐‘ก + ๐‘  โˆ’ 1, the value ofthe LQEโ€™s assets at date ๐‘ก + ๐‘  is exactly offset by the amountof debt outstanding. From (40), subsequent to the shock, wesee that the LQEโ€™s nett worth at date ๐‘ก is more than only theircurrent output given by

    (1 โˆ’ ฮฃ) ๐œ‡๐ดโˆ— (42)

    because ๐‘๐ด๐‘กchanges in response to the shock and unexpected

    capital gains of

    (๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    )๐ดโˆ— (43)

    result in their asset holdings. In this case, the asset value heldfrom date ๐‘ก โˆ’ 1 is now ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ดโˆ—, while the debt repayment is

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB) Bโˆ—= ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ดโˆ—. (44)

    To find closed-form expressions for the new equilibriumpath, we take ฮฃ to be small and linearized around the steadystate. In the sequel, we let the proportional changes in๐ด

    ๐‘ก, ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก,

    and ฮ ๐‘กrelative to their steady-state values ๐ดโˆ—, ๐‘๐ดโˆ—, and ฮ โˆ—,

    respectively, be given by

    ๐ด๐‘ก=๐ด๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ดโˆ—, ๐‘

    ๐ด

    ๐‘ก=๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    , ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก=ฮ ๐‘กโˆ’ ฮ โˆ—

    ฮ โˆ—,

    (45)

    respectively. For our purpose, assume that steady-state profit,ฮ โˆ—

    ๐‘ก, represents profit when the asset value and borrowings are

    in steady state (compare with [19]). Thus, steady-state profitfor the LQE and HQEs are represented by

    ฮ โˆ—

    ๐‘ก= (๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘กโˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘ก๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BBโˆ—

    ๐‘ก,

    ฮ โˆ—

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘Ÿ๐ด๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘ก๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB

    ๐‘ก

    โˆ—

    ,

    (46)

    respectively. Then, by using the steady state, transaction fee,and (22), we have from (40) and (41) that

    (1 +1

    ๐œ‚)๐ด๐‘ก=1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B

    ๐‘ŸB๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ฮฃ, (date ๐‘ก) , (47)

    (1 +1

    ๐œ‚)๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ = ๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    ,

    for ๐‘  โ‰ฅ 1, (dates ๐‘ก + 1, ๐‘ก + 2, . . .) ,(48)

    where ๐œ‚ > 0 denotes the elasticity of the residual asset supplyto the LQE with respect to the transaction fee at the steadystate. Here, we have

    1

    ๐œ‚=๐‘‘ log ๐‘ข (๐ด)๐‘‘ log๐ด

    ๐ด= ๐ดโˆ—

    = โˆ’๐‘‘ log๐‘ƒ(๐ด)๐‘‘ log๐ด

    ๐ด= 1/๐‘›(๐ดโˆ’๐ดโˆ—)

    ร—๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ด โˆ’ ๐ดโˆ—.

    (49)

    The right-hand side of (47) divides the change in the LQEโ€™snett worth at date ๐‘ก into two components: the direct effectof the securitization shock, ฮฃ, and the indirect effect of thecapital gain arising from the unexpected rise in price, ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก. In

    order to compute (47), from (22), (40), and (45), we have thatthe RHS of (47) is given by

    1 + ๐‘ŸB

    ๐‘ŸB๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ฮฃ =

    ๐‘ข (๐ด๐‘ก) ๐ด๐‘ก

    ๐œ‡๐ดโˆ—โˆ’ 1. (50)

    Also, from (22), (40), and (45), we have that the LHS of (47)is given by

    (1 +1

    ๐œ‚)๐ด๐‘ก

    = (๐ด๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ดโˆ—) + (โˆ’

    ๐‘‘ log๐‘ƒ (๐ด)๐‘‘ log๐ด

    ๐ด=1/๐‘›(๐ดโˆ’๐ดโˆ—)

    ร—๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ด โˆ’ ๐ดโˆ—)(

    ๐ด๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ดโˆ—) .

    (51)

    Crucially, the impact of ๐‘๐ด๐‘กis scaled up by the factor (1 +

    ๐‘ŸB)/(๐‘Ÿ

    B) because of leverage. Furthermore, the factor 1 + 1/๐œ‚

    on the left-hand sides of (47) and (48) reflects the fact thatas LQA demand rises, the transaction fee must rise for themarket to clear and, this in turn, partially chokes off theincrease in the LQEโ€™s demand.Thekey point to note from (48)is that, except for the limit case of a perfectly inelastic supply๐œ‚ = 0, the effect of a shock persists into the future.The reasonis that the LQEโ€™s ability to invest at each date ๐‘ก+๐‘  is determinedby how much screening costs they can afford from their nettworth at that date, which in turn is historically determined bytheir level of securitization at the previous date ๐‘ก + ๐‘  โˆ’ 1.

    3.1.2. Dynamic Multiplier: Asset Price and Input, CDO Priceand Output, and Profit. We will determine the size of theinitial change in the LQEโ€™s asset holdings, ๐ด

    ๐‘ก, which, from

    (47), can be jointly determined with the change in assetprice, ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก. Also, we would like to compute the proportional

    change in CDO output and profit denoted by ๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    and ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก,

    respectively (see, e.g., [19]).

    Theorem 8 (dynamic multiplier: shocks to asset price andinput, CDO price and output, and profit). Assume that theasset bubble does not burst during the securitization processand that ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโ‰ค ๐‘๐‘ก, for all ๐‘ก in (5). In this case, one has that the

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 11

    proportional change in asset price and input, CDO price andoutput, and profit subject to a negative shock is given by

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก= โˆ’

    1

    ๐œ‚ฮฃ, (52)

    ๐ด๐‘ก= โˆ’

    1

    1 + 1/๐œ‚(1 +

    1 + ๐‘ŸB

    ๐œ‚๐‘ŸB)ฮฃ, (53)

    ๐‘๐ถ

    ๐‘ก= โˆ’

    1

    ๐œ‚ฮฃ (54)

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    =

    ๐œ‡ + ] โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡

    ๐œ‡ + ]

    (๐œ‡ + ]) ๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ถโˆ—๐ด๐‘ก, (55)

    ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก=

    (๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘กโˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB๐‘ก

    (๐‘Ÿ๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘กโˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘ก๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘ŸBBโˆ—๐‘ก

    โˆ’ 1,

    (56)

    respectively.

    Proof. Since there are no bursting bubbles, (32) intimatesthat the asset price, ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก, is the discounted sum of future

    opportunity costs given by

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก+๐‘ = ๐‘ข (๐ด

    ๐‘ก+๐‘ ) , ๐‘  โ‰ฅ 0. (57)

    Linearizing around the steady state and then substitutingfrom (48) given by

    (1 +1

    ๐œ‚)๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ = ๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    , for ๐‘  โ‰ฅ 1,

    (dates ๐‘ก + 1, ๐‘ก + 2, . . .) ,(58)

    we obtain

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก=1

    ๐œ‚

    ๐‘ŸB

    1 + ๐‘ŸB

    โˆž

    โˆ‘

    ๐‘ =0

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB)โˆ’๐‘ 

    ๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ 

    =1

    ๐œ‚

    ๐‘ŸB

    1 + ๐‘ŸB

    1

    1 โˆ’ ๐œ‚/ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) (1 + ๐œ‚)๐ด๐‘ก.

    (59)

    We have to verify that

    โˆž

    โˆ‘

    ๐‘ =0

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB)โˆ’๐‘ 

    ๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ =

    1

    1 โˆ’ ๐œ‚/ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) (1 + ๐œ‚)๐ด๐‘ก

    =

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB) (1 + ๐œ‚)

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB) (1 + ๐œ‚) โˆ’ ๐œ‚๐ด๐‘ก

    (60)

    is standard for infinite series. The dynamic multiplier

    [1 โˆ’๐œ‚

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB) (1 + ๐œ‚)]

    โˆ’1

    =

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB) (1 + ๐œ‚)

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB) (1 + ๐œ‚) โˆ’ ๐œ‚

    (61)

    in (59) captures the effects of persistence in entitiesโ€™ referenceasset portfolio holdings and has a dramatic effect on the sizesof๐‘๐ด๐‘กand๐ด

    ๐‘ก. In order to find๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กand๐ด

    ๐‘กin terms of the size of

    the shock ฮฃ, we utilize (47) and (59). The calculations aboveverify that (52) and (53) as well as (54) hold.

    Next, we prove that (55) holds. As we saw in Figure 3,aggregate CDO outputโ€”the combined harvest of the LQEand HQEsโ€”is positively correlated to the LQA holdings,since such entitiesโ€™marginal product is higher than theHQEsโ€™.Suppose that the proportional change in aggregate output,๐ถ๐‘ก+๐‘ , is given (compare with ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กand ๐ด

    ๐‘กabove) by

    ๐ถ๐‘ก=๐ถ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ถโˆ—

    ๐ถโˆ—, ๐ถ

    ๐‘ก= (๐ถ๐‘ก+ 1)๐ถ

    โˆ—, ๐ถ

    โˆ—=

    ๐ถ๐‘ก

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+ 1

    .

    (62)

    In this case, we can verify that at each date ๐‘ก + ๐‘  the propor-tional change in aggregate output, ๐ถ

    ๐‘ก+๐‘ , is given by

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+๐‘ =

    ๐œ‡ + ] โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡

    ๐œ‡ + ]

    (๐œ‡ + ]) ๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ถโˆ—๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    , for ๐‘  โ‰ฅ 1.

    (63)

    The RHS of (63) yields

    ๐œ‡ + ] โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡

    ๐œ‡ + ]

    (๐œ‡ + ]) ๐ดโˆ—

    ๐ถโˆ—๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    =

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’ [(1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) ๐œ‡๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    + (๐œ‡ + ] โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡)๐ดโˆ—]

    ๐ถโˆ—.

    (64)

    In order to verify (63), we have to show that

    ๐ถโˆ—= (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) ๐œ‡๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    + (๐œ‡ + ] โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡)๐ดโˆ—

    = [(1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    + ๐œ‡ + ]] ๐ดโˆ—.(65)

    This, of course, is true since

    ๐ถโˆ—= (๐œ‡ + ]) ๐ดโˆ—, (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡๐ด

    ๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1= (1 + ๐‘Ÿ

    B) ๐œ‡๐ดโˆ—

    or ๐ด๐‘ก+๐‘ โˆ’1

    = ๐ดโˆ—.

    (66)

    Theproportional change in profit, ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก, given by (56), is a direct

    consequence of its definition.

    The proportional changes in CDO output, ๐ถ, and profit,ฮ ฬ‚, given by (55) and (56), respectively, have importantconnections with the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis and Basel III.For mortgage loans, this relationship stems from the termsinvolving the asset and prepayment rates, refinancing, andhouse equity.

    At date ๐‘ก, (52) tells us that, in percentage terms, the effecton the asset price is of the same order of magnitude as thetemporary securitization shock. As a result, the effect of theshock on the LQA holdings at date ๐‘ก is large. In this case, themultiplier in (53) exceeds unity, and can do so by a sizeablemargin, thanks to the factor (1 + ๐‘ŸB)(๐‘ŸB)โˆ’1. In terms of (47),the indirect effect of ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก, scaled up by the leverage factor (1 +

    ๐‘ŸB)(๐‘Ÿ

    B)โˆ’1, is easily enough to ensure that the overall effect on

    ๐ด๐‘ก, is more than one-for-one.

  • 12 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    3.2. Static Multiplier: Response to Temporary Shocks. At thebeginning of this section, we made a distinction betweenstatic and dynamic multipliers. Imagine, hypothetically, thatthere was no dynamic multiplier. In this case, suppose ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1

    were artificially pegged at the steady-state level๐‘๐ดโˆ—. Equation(47) would remain unchanged. However, the right-hand sideof (59) would contain only the first term of the summationโ€”the term relating to the change in transaction fee at date ๐‘กโ€”so that the multiplier (61) would disappear. Combining themodified equation, we have

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก= [

    ๐‘ŸB

    ๐œ‚ (1 + ๐‘ŸB)]๐ด๐‘ก. (67)

    The following result follows from the above.

    Corollary 9 (static multiplier: shocks to asset price andinput). For the static multiplier, suppose that the hypothesis ofTheorem 8 holds. Then, one has that

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก

    ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก+1=๐‘๐ดโˆ— = โˆ’

    ๐‘ŸB

    ๐œ‚ (1 + ๐‘ŸB)ฮฃ, (68)

    ๐ด๐‘ก|๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1=๐‘๐ดโˆ— = โˆ’ฮฃ. (69)

    Proof. Weprove the result by considering (47) and (59) wherethe changes in the asset price and the LQA holdings can besolely traced to the static multiplier.

    Subtracting (68) from (52), we find that the additionalmovement in asset price attributable to the dynamic mul-tiplier is (1 + ๐‘ŸB)โˆ’1 times the movement due to the staticmultiplier. And a comparison of (53) with (69) shows that thedynamic multiplier has a similarly large proportional effecton LQA holdings. The term

    ๐œ‡ + ] โˆ’ (1 + ๐‘ŸB) ๐œ‡

    ๐œ‡ + ](70)

    reflects the difference between LQA (equal to ๐œ‡ + ]) andHQA securitization (equal to (1 + ๐‘ŸB)๐œ‡ in the steady state).The ratio (๐œ‡ + ])๐ดโˆ—๐ถโˆ—โˆ’1 is the share of the LQEโ€™s output. Ifaggregate securitization was measured by ๐ถ

    ๐‘ก+๐‘ ๐ดโˆ’1, it would

    be persistently above its steady-state level, even thoughthere are no positive securitization shocks after date ๐‘ก. Theexplanation lies in a composition effect. In this regard, thereis a persistent change in asset usage between the LQE andHQEs, which is reflected in increased aggregate output.

    4. Illustrative Examples of Asset Securitization

    In this section, we present examples of asset securitization.Firstly, we consider a LQA securitization example involvingsubprime mortgages. Next, we illustrate LQE and HQEequilibrium from Section 2 as well as the effects of shocks toasset and CDO prices as discussed in Section 3.

    4.1. Example of Subprime Mortgage Securitization. In thissubsection, we provide a specific example of LQA securi-tization involving subprime mortgages (see, e.g., [4, 15]).For such securitization, we bring into play the main resultscontained in [16]. Subprime mortgages are usually adjustableratemortgages (ARMs), where high step-up rates are chargedin period ๐‘ก+1 after low teaser rates apply in period ๐‘ก. Secondly,this higher step-up rate causes an incentive to refinance inperiod ๐‘ก+1. Refinancing is subject to the fluctuation in houseprices. When house prices rise, the entity is more likely torefinance. This means that investors could receive furtherassets with lower interest rates as house prices increase.Thirdly, a high prepayment penalty is charged to dissuadeinvestors from refinancing (see [4] for more details).

    In subprime mortgage context, the paper [16] providesa relationship between the mortgage rate, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€, loan-to-valueratio (LTVR), ๐ฟ, and prepayment cost, ๐‘๐‘, by means of thesimultaneous equations model

    ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€

    ๐‘ก= ๐›ผ0๐ฟ๐‘ก+ ๐›ผ1๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก+ ๐›ผ2๐‘‹๐‘ก+ ๐›ผ3๐‘๐‘Ÿ๐‘€

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘ข๐‘ก,

    ๐ฟ๐‘ก= ๐œ“1๐‘Ÿ๐‘€

    ๐‘ก+ ๐œ“2๐‘‹๐‘ก+ ๐œ“3๐‘๐ฟ

    ๐‘ก+ V๐‘ก,

    ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก= ๐›พ1๐‘Ÿ๐‘€

    ๐‘ก+ ๐›พ2๐‘‹๐‘ก+ ๐›พ3๐‘๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘ค๐‘ก.

    (71)

    Investors typically have a choice of ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€ and ๐ฟ, while thechoice of ๐‘๐‘ triggers an adjustment to the mortgage rate,๐‘Ÿ๐‘€. Thus, ๐ฟ and ๐‘๐‘ are endogenous variables in the ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€-equation. There is no reason to believe that ๐ฟ and ๐‘๐‘ aresimultaneously determined. Therefore, ๐‘๐‘ does not appear inthe ๐ฟ-equation and ๐ฟ does not make an appearance in the ๐‘๐‘-equation. From [16],๐‘‹ comprises explanatory variables suchas asset characteristics (owner occupation, asset purpose,and documentation requirements); investor characteristics(income and Fair Isaac Corporation (FICO) score); anddistribution channel (broker origination). The last term ineach equation ๐‘๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘€

    , ๐‘๐ฟ, or ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘

    comprises the instrumentsexcluded from either of the other equations. Reference [16]points out that the model is a simplification with otherterms such as type of interest rate, the term to maturity, anddistribution channel possibly also being endogenous.

    Corollary 10 (dynamic multiplier: shocks to profit for sub-prime mortgages). Suppose that the hypothesis of Theorem 8holds. Then, the relative change in profit may be expressed interms of ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€, ๐‘๐‘, and ๐ฟ as

    ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก(๐‘Ÿ๐‘€) =

    ๐น๐‘ก๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB๐‘ก

    ๐น๐‘ก๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘ก๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘ŸBBโˆ—๐‘ก

    โˆ’ 1, (72)

    ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก(๐‘๐‘) =

    ๐บ๐‘ก๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB๐‘ก

    ๐บ๐‘ก๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘ก๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘ŸBBโˆ—๐‘ก

    โˆ’ 1, (73)

    ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก (๐ฟ) =

    ๐ป๐‘ก๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    BB๐‘ก

    ๐ป๐‘ก๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘ก๐ดโˆ—

    ๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘ŸBBโˆ—๐‘ก

    โˆ’ 1, (74)

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 13

    respectively. Here, one has in (72), (73), and (74) that

    ๐น๐‘ก= ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€

    ๐‘ก(1 + ๐›พ

    1๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘ก) + (๐›พ

    2๐‘‹๐‘ก+ ๐›พ3๐‘๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘ค๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘ก

    โˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก,

    ๐บ๐‘ก= ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก(1

    ๐›พ1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘ก) โˆ’

    1

    ๐›พ1(๐›พ2๐‘‹๐‘ก+ ๐›พ3๐‘๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘ค๐‘ก)

    โˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก,

    ๐ป๐‘ก= [๐›พ1{1

    ๐œ“1๐ฟ๐‘กโˆ’๐œ“2

    ๐œ“1๐‘‹๐‘กโˆ’๐œ“3

    ๐œ“1๐‘๐ฟ

    ๐‘กโˆ’1

    ๐œ“1V๐‘ก} + ๐›พ2๐‘‹๐‘ก+ ๐›พ3๐‘๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก

    +๐‘ค๐‘ก] [๐›พ1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘ก] + ๐›ผ0๐ฟ๐‘ก+ ๐›ผ2๐‘‹๐‘ก+ ๐›ผ3๐‘๐‘Ÿ๐‘€

    ๐‘ก

    + ๐‘ข๐‘กโˆ’ (1 โˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ

    ๐‘…

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘Ÿ๐‘†

    ๐‘ก,

    (75)

    respectively.

    The most important contribution of the aforementionedresult is that it demonstrates how the proportional changein profit subsequent to a negative shock is influenced byquintessential low-quality asset features such as asset andprepayment rates, refinancing, and house equity given by ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€,๐‘๐‘, ๐‘Ÿ๐‘“, and ๐ฟ, respectively, The default rate is also implicitlyembedded in formulas (72) to (74) in Corollary 10. In thisregard, by consideration of simultaneity in the choice of ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€and ๐‘๐‘, it is possible to address the issue of possible bias inestimates of the effect of ๐‘๐‘ on ๐‘Ÿ๐‘€.

    4.2. Numerical Examples of Asset Securitization. In this sub-section, we provide numerical examples to illustrate LQEand HQE equlibrium as described in Section 2 as well as theeffects of shocks on asset and CDO prices as in Section 3.Initial asset securitization parameter choices are given inTable 2.

    The financial crisis has exposed the limits of liabilitymanagement and the proposed regulation will make theretreat from liability management permanent. To a muchgreater extent than at any time since the 1970s, banks willbe forced back towards โ€œasset management,โ€ in other wordstowards a business model in which balance sheet size isdetermined from the liabilities side of the balance sheet, bythe amount of funding which the bank can raise, and inwhich asset totals have to be adjusted to meet the availableliabilities. This amounts to a โ€œmacroprudentialโ€ policyโ€”thatis, a policy designed to prevent credit creation from spirallingout of control as it did in the run-up to the recent crisis asexpressed in Basel III on the the macroprudential overlay(see, e.g., [21, 22]).

    4.2.1. Numerical Example: LQE and HQE Equilibrium. Sup-pose that the LQEโ€™s and HQEsโ€™ deposits, borrowings, mar-ketable securities and capital are equal. In this case, noticethat the LQEโ€™s and HQEsโ€™ asset holdings, A and ๐ด, are a

    Table 2: Asset securitization parameter choices.

    Parameter Value๐œ‡ 0.002๐‘๐‘ก+1

    0.113๐ด๐‘ก

    720 000๐‘Ÿ๐‘… 0.5B๐‘กโˆ’1

    $2 600๐‘Ÿ๐ต 0.205ฮฃ 0.002] 0.2๐‘๐‘ 0.03๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    460 000๐‘Ÿ๐‘† 0.15๐‘ŸB 0.2๐พ๐‘ก

    $3 000๐ถโˆ— 240 000

    ๐›ผ 0.3๐‘Ÿ๐‘“ 0.2๐‘Ÿ๐ด 0.061B๐‘ก

    $4 800๐ต๐‘ก

    $5 000๐‘› 1๐‘ƒ(๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1) 240 000

    proportion,๐›ผ and 1โˆ’๐›ผ, of the aggregate assets,๐ด, respectively.Thus, we have that

    ๐ด = ๐›ผ๐ด = 0.3 ร— 720000 = 216000;

    ๐ด= (1 โˆ’ ๐›ผ)๐ด = (1 โˆ’ 0.3) 720000

    = 504000.

    (76)

    We compute the LQEโ€™s debt obligation output in period t + 1by considering the securitization function (2). Therefore, theCDO output can be computed by

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    = (๐œ‡ + ]) ๐ด๐‘ก= (๐œ‡ + ]) ๐›ผ๐ด

    ๐‘ก

    = (0.002 + 0.2) ร— 0.3 ร— 720000 = 43632.

    (77)

    Next, the upper bound of the LQEโ€™s retention rate should beless that the discount factor ๐›ฝ; thus,

    ๐›ฝ(0.002

    0.002 + 0.2) = 0.0099099. (78)

    The value of LQAs in period t is computed by using (6).Thus,we have

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    = ๐ท๐‘ก+ ๐ต๐‘ก+ ๐พ๐‘กโˆ’ ๐ต๐‘ก= 1200 + 4800 + 3000 โˆ’ 5000

    = 4000.

    (79)

    The asset price in period t is therefore

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก=4000

    ๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    =4000

    ๐›ผ๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    =4000

    (0.3 ร— 460000)

    = 0.0289855072.

    (80)

  • 14 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    The LQEโ€™s profit is computed by considering the cash flowconstraint (10):

    ฮ ๐‘ก= (๐‘Ÿ๐ด+ ๐‘๐‘

    ๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘“

    ๐‘ก) ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1+ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ๐ท๐ท๐‘กโˆ’ ๐‘Ÿ๐ต๐ต๐‘ก

    ฮ ๐‘ก= (0.061 + 0.03 ร— 0.2) ร— 4000 + 0.205 ร— 5000 โˆ’ 0.205

    ร— 1200 โˆ’ 0.2 ร— 4800 = 87.

    (81)

    Furthermore, the LQEโ€™s profit is subject to the constraint (15);thus,

    ฮ ๐‘ก= (0.061 + 0.03 ร— 0.2) 4000 + 0.205 ร— 5000 โˆ’ 0.205

    ร— 1200 โˆ’ 0.113 ร— 0.3 ร— 720000 + 4800 = โˆ’18561.

    (82)

    We compute the LQEโ€™s additional consumption, ๐‘ฅ๐‘กโˆ’]๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    byconsidering the flow of funds constraint given by

    0.002 ร— 0.3 ร— 460000 + 8000 โˆ’ (1 + 0.2) ร— 2600

    โˆ’ 0.011904761 (0.3 ร— 720000 โˆ’ 0.3 ร— 460000)

    = 4227.4286.

    (83)

    Next, we concentrate onHQE constraints. In this case, HQEsโ€™secondary securitization at date ๐‘ก is computed by using thebudget constraint (16); thus,

    ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก= 280000 + 4800 โˆ’ 0.011904761 (1 โˆ’ 0.3) 720000

    โˆ’ (1 โˆ’ 0.3) ร— 460000 โˆ’ (1 + 0.2) ร— 2600

    = โˆ’46319.99954.

    (84)

    Thus, ๐‘ฅ๐‘ก= 54103.64210. Next, we consider the HQEโ€™s profit

    (18) at face value to compute profit at date ๐‘ก; thus,

    ฮ 

    ๐‘ก= 0.061 ร— 4000 + 0.205 ร— 5000 โˆ’ 0.205 ร— 1500

    โˆ’ 0.2 ร— 4800 = 123.5.

    (85)

    In this regard, the value of assets can be computed as

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1=123.5 โˆ’ 0.205 ร— 5000 + 0.205 ร— 1200 + 0.2 ร— 4800

    0.061

    =4991.8.

    (86)

    The HQEsโ€™ cash flow constraint (20) is given by

    ฮ 

    ๐‘กโ‰ฅ 0.061 ร— 4000 + 0.205 ร— 5000 โˆ’ 0.205 ร— 1200 โˆ’ 0.113

    ร— (1 โˆ’ 0.3) ร— 720000 + 4800 = โˆ’51007.

    (87)

    The screening cost an LQE has to pay to purchase an assetunit is financed by the HQEโ€™s nett worth. This screening costis represented by

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก= ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1

    1 + ๐‘Ÿ๐ต= 0.011904761 โˆ’

    0.113

    1 + 0.2

    = โˆ’0.082261905.

    (88)

    Themotion of the aggregate asset holding and borrowing,๐ด๐‘ก

    and ๐ต๐‘ก, of the entity may be computed as

    ๐ด๐‘ก=

    1

    0.082261905[(0.002 + 0.011904761) ร— 0.3 ร— 460000

    โˆ’ (1 + 0.2) ร— 2600 = 14601.44865] ,

    ๐ต๐‘ก=

    1

    1 + 0.20.113 ร— 0.3 ร— 720000 = 20340.

    (89)

    The sum of the aggregate asset demand from asset originatorsby the LQE and HQEsโ€™ is computed by

    ๐ด=๐ด๐‘ก+ ๐‘›๐ด

    ๐‘ก=0.3 ร— 720000 + 1 (1 โˆ’ 0.3) 720000=720000.

    (90)

    The steady-state asset price and borrowings for the LQE are

    ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    =0.0021 + 0.2

    0.2=0.012, ๐ต

    โˆ—=0.002

    0.2260000=2600.

    (91)

    Notice that the required screening costs per asset unit equalsthe LQEโ€™s securitization of marketable output, ๐‘ขโˆ— = ๐œ‡ =0.001. Also, we have ๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1= ๐ดโˆ— and ๐ต

    ๐‘กโˆ’1= ๐ตโˆ—.

    4.2.2. Numerical Example: Negative Shocks to LQAs andTheirCDOs. LQA demand and borrowings under a temporaryshock at date ๐‘ก are computed by

    ๐ด๐‘ก=

    1

    โˆ’0.082261905[(0.002 โˆ’ 0.002 ร— 0.002 + 0.011904761)

    ร—0.3 ร— 460000 โˆ’ (1 + 0.2) ร— 2600]

    = 14608.15893,

    ๐ต๐‘ก=

    1

    1 + 0.20.113 ร— 0.3 ร— 720000 = 20340,

    (92)

    respectively. In this regard, we compute the cost of funds inperiod ๐‘ก as

    ๐‘ข (๐ด๐‘ก) ๐ด๐‘ก= (0.002 โˆ’ 0.002 ร— 0.002 + 0.011904761 โˆ’ 0.022)

    ร— 0.3 ร— 460000 = โˆ’1117.69.

    (93)

    Also, we see that the LQEโ€™s nett worth at date ๐‘ก is more thantheir current output just after the shock; thus,

    (1 โˆ’ ฮฃ) ๐‘ข๐ดโˆ—= (1 โˆ’ 0.002) 0.002 ร— 0.3 ร— 460000 = 275.448.

    (94)

    With unexpected capital gains,

    (๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐ดโˆ—)๐ดโˆ—= (0.011904761 + 0.022) ร— 0.3 ร— 460000

    = 4679.

    (95)

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 15

    While the debt repayment is given by

    (1 + ๐‘Ÿ๐ต) ๐ตโˆ—= ๐‘๐ดโˆ—๐ดโˆ—= (1 + 0.2) 2600 = 3120. (96)

    Proportional change in ๐ด๐‘กand ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กcan be computed as

    ๐ด๐‘ก=0.3 (720000 โˆ’ 460000)

    0.3 ร— 460000= 0.565217391,

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก=0.011904761 โˆ’ 0.022

    0.022= โˆ’0.4588745.

    (97)

    The steady-state profit for LQE is

    ฮ โˆ—

    ๐‘ก= (0.061 + 0.03 ร— 0.2) 0.022 ร— 0.3 ร— 460000 + 0.205

    ร— 5000 โˆ’ 0.205 ร— 1200 โˆ’ 0.2 ร— 2600 = 462.412.

    (98)

    and steady-state profit for HQEs is

    ฮ โˆ—

    ๐‘ก= 0.061 ร— 0.022 ร— (1 โˆ’ 0.3) ร— 460000 + 0.205 ร— 5000

    โˆ’ 0.205 ร— 1200 โˆ’ 0.2 ร— 2600 = 691.124.

    (99)

    Thus, the proportional changes in ฮ ๐‘กand ฮ 

    ๐‘กare

    ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก=87 โˆ’ 462.412

    462.412= โˆ’0.81186,

    ฮ ฬ‚

    ๐‘ก=123.5 โˆ’ 691.124

    691.124= โˆ’0.82131.

    (100)

    Elasticity of the residual asset supply to the LQE with respectto the monitoring cost at the steady-state at date ๐‘ก is

    ๐œ‚ = [((2 + 0.2) /0.2) 0.4588745 โˆ’ 0.002

    0.565217391โˆ’ 1]

    โˆ’1

    = 0.126718931.

    (101)

    The proportional changes for ๐‘๐ด๐‘กand ๐ด

    ๐‘กin terms of the size

    of the shock ฮฃ are computed by

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก= โˆ’

    1

    0.1267189310.002 = โˆ’0.015782961,

    ๐ด๐‘ก= โˆ’

    1

    1 + 1/0.126718931(1 +

    1 + 0.2

    0.126718931 ร— 0.2) 0.002

    = โˆ’0.010875327,

    (102)

    respectively. By considering (47), we see from (63) and (71)that ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กand ๐ด

    ๐‘กbecome

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก

    ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก+1=๐‘๐ดโˆ—= โˆ’

    0.2

    0.126718931 (2 + 0.2)0.002

    = โˆ’0.001434814,

    ๐ด๐‘ก

    ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก+1=๐‘

    ๐ดโˆ—= โˆ’0.002,

    (103)

    Table 3: Computed asset securitization parameters.

    Parameter Value๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    43 632๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    $4 000ฮ ๐‘กโ‰ฅ $โˆ’18 561

    ๐‘ฅ

    ๐‘ก$โˆ’46 319.9995

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก๐ด

    ๐‘กโˆ’1$4 991.8

    ๐‘ข๐‘ก

    โˆ’0.082261905Aggregate B

    ๐‘ก$20 340

    ๐‘๐ดโˆ— 0.012๐ด๐‘กunder shock $14 608.15893

    ๐‘ข(๐ด๐‘ก)๐ด๐‘ก

    โˆ’1 117.69(๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+ ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    )๐ดโˆ— $4 679

    ๐ด๐‘ก

    0.565217391ฮ โˆ—

    ๐‘ก$462.412

    ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก

    $โˆ’2.1118๐œ‚ 0.126718931๐ด๐‘กin terms of shock 0.01

    ๐ด๐‘กwhere ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1= ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    โˆ’0.002๐›ฝ > 0.0099099ฮ ๐‘ก

    $87๐‘ฅ๐‘ก

    $54 103.6421ฮ 

    ๐‘ก$123.5

    ฮ 

    ๐‘กโ‰ฅ $โˆ’51 007

    Aggregate ๐ด๐‘ก

    14 601.44865๐ด 720 000Bโˆ— $2 600B๐‘กunder shock $20 340

    (1 โˆ’ ฮฃ)๐œ‡๐ดโˆ— 275.448

    (1 + ๐‘ŸB)Bโˆ— $3 120

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก= ๐‘๐ถ

    ๐‘กโˆ’0.4588745

    ฮ โˆ— $275.31

    ฮ ฬ‚

    ๐‘ก$691.124

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กin terms of shock โˆ’0.015782961

    ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘กwhere ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก+1= ๐‘๐ดโˆ—

    โˆ’0.001434814๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    0.064869

    respectively. The proportional change in aggregate output,๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    , represented by (54) is given by

    ๐ถ๐‘ก+1

    =0.002 + 0.2 โˆ’ (1 + 0.2) 0.002

    0.002 + 0.2

    ร—(0.002 + 0.2) 0.3 ร— 460000

    2400000.565217391

    = 0.064869.

    (104)

    We provide a summary of computed asset securitizationparameters in Table 3.

    An analysis of the computed shock parameters in Table 3shows that the aggregate output, ๐ถ

    ๐‘ก+1, increases to $43632.

    The value of LQAs, ๐‘๐ด๐‘ก๐ด๐‘กโˆ’1

    , increases to $5 000. LQAdemand,๐ด

    ๐‘ก, has declined to $14 608.15893 while the borrow-

    ings ๐ต๐‘กhave increased to $20 340. This implies that HQAs

  • 16 Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society

    were more sensitive to changes in market conditions andthat asset transformation may have been a greater priority.The proportional negative change in profit for the LQEsubsequent to a temporary shock is higher than that of theHQEs. In addition, the steady-state asset price ๐‘๐ด

    โˆ—

    and theborrowings ๐ตโˆ— for the LQE increased to $0.012 and $2 600,respectively. In summary, this example shows that whenparameter choices are altered and the size of shock increased,the LQE suffers bigger losses on their asset holdings and therate of borrowing to refinance increases. This explains whymost people could not pay back their loans during the 2007โ€“2009 financial crisis.

    4.2.3. Numerical Example: Financial Intuition. A finan-cial motivation for the numerical example discussed inSection 4.2.1 is outlined in the current paragraph. Accordingto Basel III capital and liquidity regulation, LQEs and HQEshave a couple of obligations in terms of transaction costs(refer to (22)).The first is towards the originator for acquiringthe assets while the second is for using the assets forsecuritization into CDOs, a type of user cost. In Section 4.2.1,we compute LQE and HQE equilibrium variables to addcredence to the aforementioned statements.

    The financial intuition behind the numerical examplediscussed in Section 4.2.2 is given below. Investors soughtSAPs because they met certain prudential standards such asrestrictions to purchase only investment grade debt (see theBasel documents [8, 9] for more details about securitization).Investors could meet relative โ€œsafety requirementsโ€ sincesecuritization is essentially a form of bankruptcy-remotesecured lending (as assets are legally isolated in a SPE) withcredit enhancement (or government guarantees for RABSin some jurisdictions) that often resulted in the securitiesbeing highly rated (e.g., AAA, AA, or A). However, as notedbefore, the reliance on credit ratings sowed the seeds of laterdifficulties, as many investors relied too heavily on creditratings and effectively โ€œoutsourcedโ€ their due diligence to thecredit rating agencies (see the BCBS papers [8, 9] for furtherdiscussion). It is also worth noting that investor requirementsfor HQLAs created liquidity concerns during the crisis whenpolicies or requirements forced investors to sell assets afterratings downgrades (see [5] for more details). This tested theliquidity assumptions about securitized products whenmanyinvestors were simultaneously forced to sell, driving pricesever lower in a down market (see, e.g., [5, 21, 22]). Investorscould avoid exceeding concentration limits, both regulatoryrestrictions and internal limits on exposures to a single name,by purchasing SAPs. Further, investors could manage riskin the entire portfolio by holding securitized assets that hada low correlation with other components of the investorsโ€™portfolios, such as equities and corporate bonds (see [3]for further discussion). Also, investors could meet theirinternal portfolio diversification requirements by increasingthe types of assets as well as the geographical location ofthe assetsโ€™ origination. Synthetic securitizations also allowedinvestors to increase the variety and volume of instrumentsthey could acquire without funding the credit exposure (see[8, 9] for further discussion on asset securitization). However,

    as the crisis unfolded, investors learned that their expecteddiversification benefits were partially false and that in somecases the underlying assets were highly correlated. SAPshelped investors achieve higher yield thresholds since therisk-adjusted return on ABS was typically higher relative toa similarly rated nonsecuritization investment. In the periodbefore the crisis, investors were seeking higher yields at thesame time spreads in the broader fixed income markets werenarrowing (see the Basel documents [8, 9]).

    5. Conclusions about Basel III andAsset Securitization

    The main conclusions about LQA and HQA securitization,an LQE at equilibrium, negative shocks to asset securitizationfor dynamic and static multipliers, and illustrative examplesinvolving asset securitization are summarized in this section.

    5.1. Conclusions about LQA Securitization. We answeredQuestion 1 in Section 2.1 by characterizing the securitizationof LQAs by an LQE. In this case, the cash flow constraintis given by (10). The discussion on LQE cash flow hasconnections with Basel III capital and liquidity regulation(see [5] for further discussion). In this regard, it is clear thatinvestors may be motivated to purchase securities issued byLQEs to avert Basel III regulatory limits, such as those relatingto LQAs. In the case of synthetic transactions, investors mayfind it beneficial that they would not have to fund creditexposures at the outset (see, e.g., the Joint Forum paper [1]).In cases where parties to entities possessed a comprehensiveunderstanding of the associated risks and possible structuralbehaviors of these LQEs under various scenarios, they haveeffectively engaged in and reaped benefits from their LQEactivities (see [1, 3, 6] for more details). However, it isunclear that LQAs sold into the LQE can be attributed to theexistence of these structures, that were simply the legal forminwhich such assets were held to issue bonds backed by them.Nonetheless, it is important for Basel III to address why someof the recent failures of LQE usage occurred (see, e.g., theBasel publications [1, 6]).

    5.2. Conclusions about HQA Securitization. Next, we an-sweredQuestion 2 in Section 2.2 by describing the securitiza-tion of HQAs by HQEs. In this case, the HQE cash flow con-straint is expressed as in (20). In Section 2.2, the discussionon HQEs has relationships with Basel III capital and liquidityregulation (see [5] for more details). For example, a bankmight view the Basel III risk-based capital charge appliedto HQAs as being excessive and therefore might engage insecuritization activities of these receivables to benefit from aslightly lower capital charge resulting from other aspects ofthe risk-based capital rules (see, e.g., [1]). In the bankโ€™s view,this slightly lower Basel III charge might be more rationalin terms of the true risks and capital needed for corporatelending activities (see, e.g., the Basel documents [1, 6]).5.3. Conclusions about an LQE at Steady State. Theorem 7in Section 2.3 provides the answer to Question 3. Here, acharacterization of the behaviour of an LQE in equilibrium

  • Discrete Dynamics in Nature and Society 17

    is given. According to the Basel III securitization framework,LQEs and HQEs have at least two obligations in terms oftransaction costs (refer to (22)). The first is towards theoriginator for acquiring the assets while the second is forusing the assets for securitization into CDOs, a type ofuser cost. The latter fee involves, for instance, an externalcredit rating agency (see Section 2.4 for more details). Also,because of information asymmetry and regulatory dysfunc-tion, CDOs open up opportunities for arbitrage, a point thathas been considered in Basel III for balanced informationdistribution (see, e.g., [9]). In this regard, sophisticated CDOentities, often circumvent regulatory constraints.This type ofarbitrage is accompanied by high costs with originators andother financial intermediaries earning huge transaction feesand eroding value for entities and investors (see, e.g., the Baselpapers [9, 10]).

    5.4. Conclusions about Negative Shocks to Asset Securitization(Dynamic Multiplier). In the presence of a dynamic multi-plier, in Theorem 8 from Section 3.1, we quantify changes toasset price and holdings, CDO output, and profit subsequentto negative shocks. Also, we quantify changes to profitin terms of asset and prepayment rates as well as equitysubsequent to negative shocks (refer to Question 4). Weconclude that the proportional change in asset price, ๐‘๐ด

    ๐‘ก,

    and input, ๐ด๐‘ก, as well as CDO price, ๐‘๐ถ

    ๐‘ก, is negative in

    response to a negative shock like a ratings downgrade. BaselIII endeavours to make provision for these negative changesin a countercyclical way (see, e.g., [1, 6, 23]). The sameobservation can bemade about CDO output,๐ถ

    ๐‘ก+1, and profit,

    ฮ ฬ‚๐‘ก, where a ratings downgrade has a negative impact (see, e.g.,

    Basel IIIโ€™s (see, e.g., the BCBS documents [1, 6]).

    5.5. Conclusions about Temporary Shocks to Asset Se