research paper 55 | 2017repec.graduateinstitute.ch/pdfs/ciesrp/cies_rp_55.pdf · filipe silva,...

43
Research Paper 55 | 2017 DO FIRMS INNOVATE IF THEY CAN RELOCATE? EVIDENCE FROM THE STEEL INDUSTRY François COHEN, Giulia VALACCHI

Upload: trinhtuyen

Post on 15-Feb-2019

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Research Paper 55 | 2017

DO FIRMS INNOVATE IF THEY CAN RELOCATE? EVIDENCE FROM THE STEEL INDUSTRY François COHEN, Giulia VALACCHI

DO FIRMS INNOVATE IF THEY CAN RELOCATE?

EVIDENCE FROM THE STEEL INDUSTRY

Francois Cohen and Giulia Valacchi

Centre for International Environmental Studies

Graduate Institute of International and Development Studies

Geneva, Switzerland

September 15th, 2017

Abstract:

We estimate the effect of coal prices on steel plant location worldwide and production

preferences for BOF, a polluting technology, and EAF, a greener one. A 1% increase in national

coal prices could reduce the share of BOF and EAF units of that country over total active steel-

making units present in the world by around 0.61% and 0.43% respectively. We simulate the

implementation of a stringent European carbon market and find a non-negligible shift in steel

production outside Europe, with limited impact on the technologies employed to produce steel. If

applied worldwide, the same policy would strongly affect production in Asia, which relies on

BOF and currently benefits from lower coal prices.

Keywords: Steel industry; firm relocation; technological change; energy prices.

JEL Classification: O14, O33, Q41, Q42

Acknowledgements: This research was funded by the Swiss National Science Foundation under

the Sinergia programme, Project "Innovation, Diffusion and Green Growth" No CRSII1_147612.

For useful comments, we would like to thank Tim Swanson, Joëlle Noailly, Anthony Decarvalho,

Filipe Silva, Florian Egli, Yuan Zi, Banban Wang, Suchita Srinivasan and Marco Pistis. We

thank Xiaojing Zhou, Misato Sato, Tania Theodoluz and Beni Suryadi for precious data

contribution and Helena Ting for her work as research assistant on this project.

1

1. Introduction

The Paris Agreement (2015) has set the ambitious objective of limiting global warming below

2°C. However, while economists have long argued that the most effective policy to achieve this

would be either a global price of carbon or a global carbon market (e.g. Stoft et al., 2013;

Weitzman, 2014), extensive international discussions have so far not been successful in

delivering it.1 To date, only a small number of independent carbon schemes are operative (e.g. the

EU, Japan, China and California). In all these schemes, the price of carbon is far below its social

cost as estimated by integrated impact assessment models.2 One of the main reasons why carbon

prices are low on these markets comes from the risk that regulated industries lose

competitiveness. For sectors that are both energy intensive and largely exposed to international

competition, unilaterally implementing a carbon tax or trading scheme may push industries to

relocate.

In this paper, we estimate the effect of changes in coal prices on steel plant location worldwide.

We simultaneously observe changes in production choices. More precisely, we can track whether

steel plants start relying or not on recycling processes which are known to be far less energy

intensive. Looking jointly at the effect of energy price shocks on plant location and production

preferences constitutes the main contribution of this paper.

A large body of economic literature has looked at the effect of energy prices or environmental

regulation on firm performance and location. Earlier studies attempting to measure the effect of

environmental regulation on net exports, overall trade flows, job creation or plant-location

decisions produced estimates that were either small or statistically insignificant (Jeppesen et al.,

2002; Morgenstern et al., 2002; Jaffe et al., 1995). Ever since, studies focusing on US-based

pollution-intensive industries have shown that environmental regulation tended to decrease

1 Leading emitters (e.g., US, China, India) diverge on the concept of “differentiated responsibilities” as proposed

initially in the Berlin Mandate of 1995. While the developing countries argue that severe emission caps may hinder

the economic growth trajectory of such countries, developed nations, mainly the United States, argue that having

differentiated targets defeats the purpose of a common market, as global pollution levels would continue to grow as

usual through the pathway of leakage.(Bosetti et al., 2014). 2 Nordhaus (2017) estimates that the social cost of carbon is around $31/tCO2

eq. for the current period. Yet, in

2015, the traded price of carbon ranged from $1 to $13/tCO2 eq. worldwide, and 90% of carbon permits were

traded at less than $10/tCO2 eq. (WBG and ECOFYS, 2015). In the EU, the carbon price oscillated between $3 and

$10/tCO2 eq. between 2013 and 2015 (Marcu, 2016).

2

output and profits (Aldy and Pizer, 2015b; Ho et al., 2008; List et al., 2003; Greenstone, 2002).

Regulated and polluting industries would also experience a reduction in exports and an increase

in imports, in particular if they are geographically mobile (Aldy and Pizer, 2015a; Levinson and

Taylor, 2008; Ederington et al., 2005). Therefore, the location of plants seems impacted by

environmental regulation and/or energy prices. Using longitudinal data on outward FDI flow of

German manufacturing industries, Wagner and Timmins (2009) find evidence of a pollution

haven effect in the chemical industry. For the US, Kellenberg (2009) finds that US

multinationals’ subsidiaries in foreign countries exploit less stringent environmental regulation. It

attributes 8.6% of the growth of these subsidiaries to the falling levels of environmental

regulation in destination countries. Kahn and Mansur (2013) use county-level US data and

observe that energy-intensive industries concentrate in low electricity price counties, while labor-

intensive industries avoid pro-union counties. They also find mixed evidence that pollution-

intensive industries may locate in counties featuring relatively lax Clean Air Act regulation. In

parallel, the existence of locational effects may encourage neighboring States or countries to

adapt their regulations to the ones of their neighbors (Fredriksson and Millimet, 2002). Some

recent papers study the impact of the EU-ETS on firm relocation (Dechezlepretre et al., 2014,

Borghesi et al., 2016, Koch and Basse Mama, 2016). Both Borghesi et al. (2016) and Koch and

Basse Mama (2016) find evidences of relocation caused by the EU-ETS particularly for these

sector exposed to international competition. On the other hand, Dechezlepretre et al. (2014) find

no evidence of carbon leakages triggered by the introduction of the carbon scheme. A limitation

of their study is that they focus only on the initial period of activity of the EU-ETS, up to 2009,

and they do not rule out the possibility of finding different results in case of an increase of the

policy stringency by the EU policy makers. The studies focusing on the impact of environmental

regulation (or energy taxation) on firm performance and location paid little attention to the

concomitant effect of environmental stringency on technology development and diffusion.

Evidence that energy prices foster the adoption of cleaner technologies has been found in very

diverse industry contexts (e.g. Cohen et al., forthcoming; Aghion et al., 2016; Dechezlepretre et

al., 2011; Popp, 2006; Brunnermeier and Cohen, 2003; Popp, 2002; Newell et al., 1999; Jaffe and

Palmer, 1997; Lanjouw and Mody, 1996). Yet, none of the above-mentioned studies considered

plant location and technological choice as simultaneous decisions. The two are likely to interact.

3

Even though changes of location may be encouraged by the availability low environmental

standards in some countries, the choice to relocation will be ultimately dependent on the cost of

compliance, which depends on the availability of low-pollution technologies or the potential for

their development.

This paper dives into this topic while focusing on the steel industry. This sector is particularly

relevant to assess the role of energy taxation in climate change mitigation. Steel is one of the

most energy intensive industries and a very large emitter of greenhouse gases: it represents 27%

of all greenhouse gas emissions (GHG) from industry worldwide (IEA, 2017).3

We directly estimate the impact of an increase in coal price expectations on the share of steel

producing units located in a country relative to all active steel-making units in the world in that

year, separately evaluating this figure according to the technology they use to produce steel.4 We

use steel plant data (1960-2014) collected by the OECD and covering 132 countries. The dataset

records the opening, operating and closing times of steel plants, along with the main technology

that they employ to produce steel. Currently, two major steel-making technologies are available.

The Basic Oxygen Furnace (BOF) is highly energy intensive and polluting whereas the Electric

Arc Furnace (EAF) is a recycling technology able to cut up to a quarter of the emissions from the

production process. The OECD data displays if a plant resorts to BOF and/or EAF, allowing us to

3 In 1990, steel industry’s global energy consumption was estimated to be 18 to 19 Ej, accounting for 10 to 15% of

the annual global industrial energy consumption. By 1995, its CO2-emissions were estimated at 1442 Mt, or about

7% of global anthropogenic CO2-emissions (IEA, 2016). In more recent years, as a consequence of the rapid growth

in the Asia Pacific region, steel production has shifted: Asia now produces over 60% of global output (in particular,

China accounts for almost 50% of crude steel production in 2015); in contrast, the EU-28 and NAFTA regions share

of global production has decreased from 28% in 2005 to 17% in 2015 (WSA, 2016). Additionally, there has been a

steady increase of BOF production in emerging economies (above all China, but also India and Brazil), where raw

materials are cheap and steel scrap is not yet adequately available; while north-western countries, which are overall

more concerned about environmental preservation, closed up their BOF plants much faster than their EAF ones. 4 In the steel sector, a few studies have looked at the impact of energy prices on firm production choices. However,

they do not properly address the endogeneity caused by the simultaneous determination of production choices and

input prices. Reppelin-Hill (1999) finds no response of the share of EAF over total steel production to change in

input prices: namely coal, iron ore, scrap and electricity. She looks at 30 steel producing countries for the period

(1970-1994). Other more recent and more geographically restricted studies find significant negative elasticities

between the price of coal and dirty steel production. Schleich (2007) show that, for the case of German steel-makers,

an increase in 10% in the relative price of coal to steel reduces fuel consumption in BOF by 0.1%, by increasing the

use of EAF for overall production of steel. Flues et al. (2015) consider in the analysis Germany, Italy, Spain, France

and the UK; they find that an increase by 1% in the price of coal leads to a decrease of 0.12%-0.14% in energy

consumption for steel production. Mathiesen and Maestad (2004) aims to jointly account for the locational and

technological choices of manufacturers in a static numerical partial equilibrium model of the world steel industry.

These authors however rely on expert opinion to assess the magnitude of the elasticities relevant to their modelling

exercise, in particular the elasticity of steel production technologies to changes in energy prices.

4

produce country aggregates by technology. We match the OECD data on steel plants with coal

price statistics from the International Energy Agency and, for China, information from the

Chinese Ministry of Coal and the Bohai-Rim Price Index. The coal data covers 22 countries for

the period 1978-2014. Hence, our final dataset comprises 22 countries for which we could match

coal prices with steel plant data over 37 years. These 22 countries encompass around 82% of the

steel produced worldwide.5

We find that an increase in coal prices at national level have a negative effect on the size of steel

manufacturing in a country. In our preferred specification, a 1% increase in coal prices reduces

the share of BOF units in that country, compared to the rest of the world, by around 0.61% and

the share of EAF units by around 0.43%. This consistently suggests that the most energy-

intensive types of units are more affected by increases in coal prices.

To assess the impact of coal prices on relocation, we simulate the impact of the implementation

of a global carbon market on the location of steel plants for the 22 countries that we cover. In the

carbon market, we set the price of GHG emissions at $31/tCO2 eq. This is the estimate of the

current social cost of carbon in Nordhaus (2017). We assess the impact of two different

scenarios and compare them to a business-as-usual scenario: a) all countries join a global

carbon market; b) European countries only increase the stringency of the EU ETS, increasing the

price of GHG emissions by $31/tCO2 eq. for the steel industry. Our econometric estimates allow

us to determine the share of BOF and EAF plants remaining in each country depending on the

geographical amplitude of the carbon market. In these two scenarios, we find that the increase in

the price of coal has a positive impact on the final share of active EAF units over the share of total

active units in a region. In the scenario in which only European countries implement the carbon

scheme, we observe a non-negligible shift in production (1.65 percentage points) from the

countries that are part of the carbon market to the non-participating countries. An important

finding is that we also observe a shift in production in the case where a carbon market is

applied worldwide, this time from Asian countries to other regions of the world. This shift of 9.74

percentage points is much larger than for the unilateral carbon scheme in Europe. Historically,

Asian firms have benefitted from lower coal prices and currently rely more on BOF technologies

5 This figure is obtained from the estimates given by the World Steel Association for the year 2014.

5

(as reported in the data section, cf. Figure 1 and Table 1). Therefore, when the global carbon tax

is implemented, Asian firms are more affected than European and North American ones.

These effects, found in the case of steel manufacturing, may apply to other highly energy

intensive industries that are also strongly exposed to international competition, such as the

cement industry or the chemical industry. They have strong policy relevance. They may largely

explain the reticence of EU countries to increase the stringency of the EU ETS, or to allow for

exemptions in the steel sector due to the risk of carbon leakage. National industrial interests are one

of the main reasons why multinational carbon markets are not being put forward. Since countries

will be asymmetrically affected by it, systems with quota allocations that take into account the

current distribution of firms across countries may be necessary if a multilateral agreement on a

common carbon market is to be found.

All these results have been obtained from an econometric setting that circumvents several

difficulties. First, our econometric strategy accounts for the fact that building and operating a

steel plant requires making long-term investments. It follows that investors should be forward

looking and care more about the expected price of coal in the coming years than about its current

market price. We compute national average coal price expectations with autoregressive integrated

moving average models (ARIMA) to produce expectations about future coal prices that take into

account basic knowledge (by manufacturers) of previous energy price trends. Second, the steel

industry is the largest buyer of coal. Therefore, the price of coal is endogenous since it depends

on the size of the steel sector. We circumvent this problem while relying on the lags of coal

prices as instruments in a setting that tolerates the use of pre-determined variables as instruments.

More precisely, we use the pre-sample mean estimator exposed in Blundell et al. (2002). The

general idea is to inject additional information into the econometric model in cases where pre-

sample data is available for the dependent variable. In this case, we use the pre-sample data for

1960-1981 on the average amount of steel-producing units in country i. Blundell et al. (2002)

prove that this strategy is both more efficient and less biased than traditionally used first

differenced estimators, even for a small amount of observations and pre-sample periods.

Furthermore, the estimator by Blundell et al. (2002) is a non-linear count model that restricts

predicted outcomes to be strictly positive or equal to zero. This type of models offers a much

6

better account that any linear model of the situations where we observe no steel plant of

technology s in country i operating at time t. Our results are furthermore robust to several

changes in the base specification, in particular regarding the calibration of the estimation method

and the computation of expected coal prices.

The rest of the paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the data while providing a brief

overview of the steel industry. Section 3 presents our estimation technique. Section 4 comments

on the results and the main robustness checks performed. Section 5 presents our simulation

exercise and section 6 concludes.

2. Data

This piece of research relies on OECD data on steel plant location and data on coal prices at

national level. We briefly describe both data sources hereafter.

2.1 OECD data on the steel industry

The steel plant data has been assembled by the OECD and provides information on the location

of steel plants in 132 countries. For some countries, data is available since the beginning of the

20th

century whereas it starts by around 1960 for most of them. The most disaggregated layer of

observation in the database is the production unit: a steel plant is composed of several units,

which may become operative or close down at different moments in time, even if they are on the

same site. The data records the opening and closing year of these different units. Finally, units

may also use different production technologies. The dataset records whether a unit is EAF or

BOF.

A limitation of this study is that we don’t have information on the intensive margin, i.e.

production capacity, of the steel plants under analysis. It is likely that many of these plants would

stay open for a long time, but they will operate at reduced capacity in times of high coal prices.

All throughout the analysis, we assume that production capacity remains stable across the years.

In addition, EAF units are on average smaller than BOF ones. This does not jeopardize our

results, but it actually reinforces them. The emissions decrease, entailed by a reduction in BOF

units and an increase in EAF ones, will be even bigger than what anticipated in this paper where

EAF and BOF are assumed to have the same production capacity.

7

BOF is a technology that came into wide adoption in the 1960s.6 It takes, as inputs, iron ore and

coking coal, and produces steel in two integrated steps. In the first step, coal is heated up to

2400 degree Fahrenheit, and transformed into coke. Coke is then combined with iron ore to

produce molten iron. In the second step, molten iron and some scrap are transformed into steel

in the basic oxygen furnace. CO2 is emitted through both the raw material and the combustion

process. Furthermore, CO2 can be emitted indirectly through the use of electricity, usually

generated with on-side coal-fired power generators. For BOF, the blast furnace and other

combustion processes contribute 88% of CO2 emission, while indirect electricity consumption

contributes 12% (EPA, 2012; OECD, 2013; IEA, 2012).7

EAF is a different steel-making process which uses ferrous scrap as main input instead of raw

materials (Giarratani et al., 2013). Additionally, it makes use of electricity to convert scrap into

new steel. The electricity produced to run EAF units is usually generated on site using steam coal.

The first EAF plant was established in the US in 1907 but, initially, the quality of the steel

produced was lower than the one obtained through BOF and not enough scrap was around to make

it cheaper to produce only through recycling.8 At the beginning of the 20th century, it was difficult

to control the quality of the scrap, therefore, EAF steel was considered a byproduct. With

technology advancement there has been improvements in the quality of steel produced via EAF

and in the second half of the 20th century it started to spread as an almost-perfect substitute to

BOF. The main source of emissions in the EAF process is through electricity usage, which

accounts for about 50% of emissions (EPA, 2012). As EAF uses recycled ferrous scrap, and

bypasses the coke production process, it is considered a more advanced technology with less

energy burden. However, the fact that EAF resorts to scrap implies that EAF could not possibly

6 In the 19th century and early 20

th century, the steel-making process widely used was Open Heart Furnace (OHF). It

employs as main inputs raw materials such as iron ore, natural gas, oil or coal. It is a slow and inefficient procedure

which, from the 1960s, has been completely replaced by the more efficient Blast Oxygen Furnace (BOF), which uses

the same inputs, but exhibits big improvements in efficiency: approximately 1 BOF is required to replace 6 OHFs.

Given this phase-out we exclude OHF from the analysis. 7 BOF can use scrap to produce steel, but up to a maximum of 25% of the amount of total inputs.

8 Steel scrap can have different sources: “home scrap” generated within the plant (nowadays it is not sufficient any

more to produce steel due to the requirement of very high volumes of materials, therefore it needs to be integrated with

the one purchased outside the firm); “new/prompt scrap” which is produced within the industrial activity of other firms

(it is the same as home scrap, but it is not produced within the firm); “post-consumer scrap” which returns in the

market after it ends its useful life (it could be very quick, as for cans, but it could take up to some years, as in the case

of cars) (Yellishetty et al., 2011).

8

fully substitute to BOF. The diffusion of these two steel-making technologies crucially depends

on the availability of input materials. In general, EAF is more frequent in (developed) countries

where scrap is sufficiently available to sustain the production.

Table 1 below provides information on the number of steel units recorded in the data for three

periods (1982-1990, 1991-2000, 2001-2014)9, with a breakdown by technology and geographical

location. It only displays the data used in the econometric estimation, i.e. the one that could be

matched with coal price data and covers 22 countries. More complete descriptive statistics for

unmatched countries and data for before 1982 are available in Appendix A.

Also, please note that EAF plants have typically a smaller capacity than BOF. On average, one

BOF unit produces the same amount of steel as almost 3 EAF units (OECD, 2015). Unfortunately,

our data does not feature the production capacity of each unit or plant.

Table 1: Descriptive statistics of OECD data on steel plant location and main technology

used in production (1982-2014)

Period 1982-1990 1991-2000 2001-2014

Technology BOF EAF BOF EAF BOF EAF

North America 70.3 234.8 64.8 210.0 54.3 183.3

Europe 113.3 180.9 100.6 161.6 84.3 166.7

Asia 222.1 217.9 255.4 285.7 339.7 345.9

Other 9.0 5.4 8.8 7.0 7.0 7.0

Total 414.8 639.0 429.6 664.3 485.3 702.86 Notes: The table reports the average number of active units of steel-making production in each region of the world

over three different time periods. Note that we only report figures for the restricted list of 22 countries used in the

regressions hereafter. North America includes Canada and the US; Europe includes Germany, Turkey, Spain, Italy,

France, Poland, Belgium, Czech Republic, Sweden, Finland, the Netherlands, Portugal, Switzerland and Norway;

Asia includes China, Japan, Russia and India; Other includes Australia and Chile.

In terms of GHG emissions, EAF units emit, for the same amount of steel produced, 4 times less

than their BOF counterparts (OECD, 2013 IEA, 2012). This is why, in the remaining of the

analysis, EAF is considered as a greener alternative to BOF. However, switching from BOF to

EAF is not the only choice available to manufacturers if they want to reduce GHG emissions.

Worrel et. Al. (1999) discusses in details many alternative measures to improve the energy

efficiency of steel manufacturing (e.g. preventative maintenance, cogeneration, heat recovery,

9 Coal prices are available starting from 1978, but, since in the final estimation we will use the expected prices of

coal instead of the actual ones and given that we need at least 4 years to estimate the forecast, our analysis will cover

the interval (1982-2014).

9

etc). Nevertheless, technology switching remains the one of greater impact on the emissions

performance of a plant. In this study, we have no data on the efficiency of active EAF and BOF

units and, therefore, cannot evaluate the extent to which an increase in coal prices may lead to

changes in the efficiency of installed EAF and BOF units.

2.2 Coal price data

We use the industrial coal price10

data from the International Energy Agency (IEA), converted to

constant 2010 USD,11

except for China, for which we use the data from the Chinese Ministry of

Coal, integrated with the Bohai-Rim Price Index. These sources report both coking coal and

steam coal prices starting from 1978.

Steam coal, or thermal coal, is used primarily in electricity generation, while coking coal, or

metallurgical coal, is used in steel-making. In BOF processes, coking coal is converted to coke by

eliminating virtually all impurities and leaving close to pure carbon. This process involves

heating coking coal in coke ovens to around 1000 to 1100 degrees Celsius in the absence of

oxygen. The coking process takes 12 to 36 hours in the coke oven, and the finished coke is

cooled before transferring to blast furnaces and combined with iron ore to make molten iron.

Around 600kg of coke produces 1000kg of steel, which mean around 770kg of coking coal is

used to produce 1000kg of steel (WCA, 2017) The EAF processes do not involve mixing coke

with iron-one. However, they are reliant on electricity generated by coal-fired power plants. With

EAF, around 150kg of steam coal is used to produce 1000kg of steel (WCA, 2017).

Coking coal and steam coal prices strongly correlate (Pearson correlation coefficient is 0.58).

Even though EAF uses steam coal and BOF coking coal, we only include coking coal prices as an

independent variable in our preferred model. This allows reducing losses of precision due to

multicollinearity. Nonetheless, this choice implies that the price of coal is measured with error for

EAF units. We solve this problem econometrically since we will be instrumenting for coal prices.

10

We collected the total price charged to the industrial sector. 11

Coal prices are initially extracted in national currency/tonne. To convert them in constant 2010 USD/tonne, we

apply the formula: 𝑃𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠2010 =𝑃𝑡

𝐿𝐶

𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑡𝐺𝐷𝑃

𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟2010𝐺𝐷𝑃

𝑟2010𝑥 , where 𝑃𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠2010 is the price of coal expressed in constant

2010 USD/tonne, 𝑃𝑡𝐿𝐶 is the price of coal expressed in local currency/tonne at time t, 𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟𝑡

𝐺𝐷𝑃 is the GDP

deflator for that country at time t, 𝑑𝑒𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑜𝑟2010𝐺𝐷𝑃 is the GDP deflator of that country in 2010, and 𝑟2010

𝑥 is the

exchange rate between the local currency and USD in 2010.

10

Furthermore, in Appendix C4, we use steam coal prices and not coking coal in alternative

regressions, and both steam and coking coal prices in appendix C5. Results with these alternative

specifications are consistent with the ones obtained in our preferred specification.

Figure 1 presents the evolution of average coking coal prices in North America, Europe, Asia and

the other regions of the world for 1978-2014. Coking coal prices observed a strong decline in all

regions in 1988 because of the concomitant oil price collapse (King and Tang, 1988). After 2000,

they then abruptly increased because of the so-called commodities super-cycle, mainly due to the

rising demand from emerging markets such as the BRIC countries (Schwartz and Creswell,

2015). On the other side, coking coal prices have been consistently lower in Asia compared to

Europe or North America.

Figure 1: Evolution of coking coal prices in major geographical areas (1978-2014)

Notes: North America includes Canada and the US; Europe includes Germany, Turkey, Spain, Italy, France, Poland,

Belgium, Czech Republic, Sweden, Finland, the Netherlands, Portugal, Switzerland and Norway; Asia includes

China, Japan, Russia and India; Other includes Australia and Chile. Average prices are unweighted (i.e. they do not

take into account the relative size of each country).

3. Empirical method

11

We develop an empirical strategy that allows estimating the impact of expected coal prices on the

size of steel manufacturing in a country. Our general approach consists in applying a count model

with the share N of steel units using technology 𝑠 ∈ {𝐵𝑂𝐹; 𝐸𝐴𝐹} in country i during year t over

the total number of active units in the world in that year as the main dependent variable. In this

national-level count model, we have separated the counts of BOF and EAF units since this

provides us with the right level of aggregation to simultaneously look at cross-country relocation

and technological choice.12

The expected price of coal, denoted 𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ , constitutes the independent variable of interest of our

model. We aim to estimate a model such that:

𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 = 𝑓(𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ )

To estimate such a model, we are confronted with two difficulties. The first difficulty is that we

do not observe the expected price of coal in country i at time t, but its actual realization, which

we denote 𝑝𝑖,𝑡. However, the right variable of interest is the expected price of coal because

manufacturing companies are likely not to base their production decision on current inputs’ prices.

They will rather take in consideration their expected value in the future. This is particularly true

for a sector like the steel one because investments are costly and have a long lifetime.

The second difficulty is that expected coal prices constitute an endogenous variable. The total

demand for coal in country i and at time t depends on the demand for coal from the steel industry.

Since the price of coal in country i and at time t depends on the demand for coal in this same

country, it mechanically depends on the demand for coal from the steel industry. Therefore, the

total number of steel plants using technology s in country i and at time t is a determinant of the

price of coal in country i at time t. Since 𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 has an impact on 𝑝𝑖,𝑡 while it also depends on 𝑝𝑖,𝑡,

these two factors are simultaneously determined. On the other hand, expectations about future

coal prices necessarily depend on the current price of coal. It follows that 𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 and 𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ are also

simultaneously determined.

We resolve these two problems as follows.

12

Under specific conditions, count models applied on aggregate data are furthermore equivalent to binary choice

models applied at more disaggregate levels (Guimaraes et al., 2003).

12

3.1 Computing expected coal prices

To compute expected coal prices, we consider that a perfectly rational agent forecasts future

prices based on the information that s/he has. We assume that past prices constitute all the

information easily available to economic agents, such that their expectations about future prices

are a function of past prices. In this framework, expectations can be recovered with a time-series

model that produces a forecast of the coal price at time t+1, t+2, t+3, etc. with the coal price at

time t, t-1, t-2, etc. In practice, we recursively apply autoregressive integrated moving-average

models (ARIMA) on national annual time-series of real coal prices. The ARIMA model that we

use to make the predictions is a first-order autoregressive model. This is because this model

proved to be the best fit to the data:

𝑝𝑖,𝑡 = 𝜇𝑖 + 𝛾𝑖𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1 + 휀𝑖,𝑡

In this model, the price of coal in each country i is regressed on its first lag. 휀𝑖,𝑡 is a term of error

and 𝜇𝑖 and 𝛾𝑖 are parameters to be estimated. For each period t and country i, the ARIMA model

is estimated with data from the previous 10 years. When we lack information on the previous 10

years, we estimate the model with all available years, provided that we have data for the previous

4 years at least. In each case, we then take the 10-year average of forecasted prices (for time t+1,

t+2, t+3, etc.) as our value for the expected coal price, 𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ . Therefore, the ARIMA model is re-

estimated for each time period t present in the sample, except for the first four years of our data

(1978-1981), for which we did not have enough data to run the ARIMA model, i.e. (𝑡 ∈

[1982; 2014]). We then make out of sample predictions and, year after year, we allow steel

companies to update their beliefs about future prices as soon as new information is available.

Detailed statistics on the output of the ARIMA model and the predictions obtained are reported in

Appendix B.

Furthermore, we performed several robustness checks to make sure that our final results are not

dependent on the choices made to compute energy price expectations. All robustness checks

relative to the choice of the coal price variable are reported in Appendix C. They are also briefly

discussed in the results section.

3.2 Endogeneity of expected coal prices

13

Our econometric strategy needs to deal with the endogeneity of the expected price of coal. In the

literature, the most frequently suggested technique consists in using cost shifters as instruments,

i.e. factors that are correlated with the cost of producing coal, and not with the demand for coal

(e.g. Berry, 1994). However, the context of coal and steel production makes it hard to find strictly

exogenous instruments: the two sectors are closely related. For example, steel production uses

another output of the mining industry as an input, namely iron ore. Therefore, supply shocks on

the extraction of coal may also affect the extraction of iron. If cost shifters cannot be used as

instruments, an alternative would consist in using shocks on the demand for coal that are not

correlated with the demand from the steel industry as instruments. This approach is the one of

Hausman et al. (1994), who instruments the price of a product in a given market j, with the price

of this same product on other markets. Provided that demand shocks are not correlated across

markets, this instrumentation strategy is valid. Yet, the steel industry is the main demander for

coal and markets are integrated across regions. When not used to make steel, coal is used to

produce electricity. The assumption that shocks on the electric market are not correlated with the

steel market is not serious. For example, steel is used in construction, and shocks on the

construction sector should translate into a simultaneous increase in energy demand and the

demand for steel.

We adopt a conservative approach and consider that most of the (demand and supply) shocks on

coal prices are likely to be correlated with contemporaneous shocks on the steel industry. As a

consequence, we abstain from using fixed effect models since they rely on the assumption of

strict exogeneity of the instruments. To relax the assumption of strict exogeneity of the

instruments, applied economists have usually relied on models in first differences (Roodman,

2008). These models present the advantage of allowing for pre-determined variables to serve as

instruments, for example the lags of both the exogenous and endogenous variables. However,

these models lack efficiency, in particular when time-persistent processes are studied. Models in

first differences are also subject to small sample bias. With a total sample of around 900

observations and an industry that relies on long-term investments, first difference models are

likely to provide inefficient estimates, if not inconsistent, in the present case.

In such an econometric context, Blundell, Griffith and Windmeijer (2002) recommend using pre-

14

sample mean estimators. A specific interval of time {𝑡1; 𝑡𝑓} is set to be the time of the analysis.

In this interval, the set of information about dependent and independent variables is complete.

There is, additionally, a pre-sample interval {𝑡𝑖; 𝑡0} where only information on the dependent

variable is available. A mean of the dependent variable is estimated over {𝑡𝑖; 𝑡0} and included as

a control variable in the estimation. With small samples, Blundell, Griffith and Windmeijer

(2002) show that pre-sample mean estimators are more efficient and significantly less biased than

first difference estimators, even when time persistence is not extreme and for a small number of

pre-sample observations. The intuition why pre-sample mean estimators are superior to first

difference estimators is quite simple: they incorporate additional information into the model,

namely the pre-sample mean of the dependent variable. The main limitation explaining why these

estimates are barely used is that they can only be applied if pre-sample information on the

dependent variable is available to the econometrician.

In the present case, we have data on 𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 since the 1960s, while our data on 𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ starts in 1982.

We have 22 years of pre-sample information on 𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 which can be used to run pre-sample mean

estimators in the fashion of Blundell, Griffith and Windmeijer (2002).13

We estimate the

following count model:

𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 = 𝑒𝑥𝑝(𝛼 + 𝛽 ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ ) + 𝜎 ln(�̅�𝑠,𝑖,𝑡𝑖

) + 𝜃𝑡) + 𝑒𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 (1)

Where �̅�𝑠,𝑖,𝑡𝑖 is the pre-sample mean of 𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 over {1960; 1981} and 𝑒𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 is the error term. 𝛼, 𝛽,

𝜎 and 𝜃 are parameters to be estimated. The expression 𝜃𝑡 captures the effect of time on 𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡.14

This expression can be estimated using GMM. To instrument for ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ ), the lags of ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡

∗ ) are

valid instruments provided that contemporaneous shocks on 𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ are not correlated with previous

shocks. The latter means that shifts in expectation between time t and t-1 arise from the inclusion

of new information about 𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ . This is the case if expectations are rationally formed, or if they

follow a random walk.

In our base specification, we simply use ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1∗ ) to instrument for ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡

∗ ). In an alternative

13

In Appendix D.1, we modify the pre-sample period used for estimation to 1970-1981instead of 1960-1981. Results

are similar to our preferred specifications. 14

Specifications with time-fixed effects where not converging in the non-linear case. We, however, use time fixed

effects in a linear version of this specification in Appendix D.2.

15

specification, we expand the number of lags used as instruments, and run the model with the first

five lags of ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ ) as instruments. This allows us to run an over-identification test and make

sure that all lags provide the same results when used as instruments. This test corroborates our

assumption that there is no correlation between 𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1∗ and 𝑝𝑖,𝑡

∗ creating endogeneity. This

specification is described in the results section. Finally, we report the results obtained with a

fixed effect model with no treatment of endogeneity in Appendix D.3 and the results obtained

with a first difference estimator in Appendix D.4. Unsurprisingly, the results of the fixed effect

model are inconsistent. The results with the first difference estimator are inefficient. They should

also suffer from a small sample bias (Staiger and Stock, 1997; and Blundell and Bond, 1998).

The bias of the first difference estimator leads the estimates to be similar to the ones provided by

a first differenced model where the expected price of coal would be treated as be exogenous. We

also provide the results of such a model in Appendix D.4.

4. Results

Table 2 presents the results of the estimation of equation 1. Column 1 reports the results for the full

sample, column 2 for BOF units only and column 3 for EAF units only. For each of these

specifications, the pre-sample period used for the estimation is 1960-1981. It is the largest pre-

sample interval available to us for all 22 countries. The logarithm of expected coal prices is

instrumented with its one-year lag.

Overall, we find that a 1% increase in the expected price of coal in country i would cause a

decrease in the share of active units in this country, compared to the rest of the world, by around

0.51%. If we look at EAF and BOF separately, the impact of an increase in coal prices appears to

be 45% larger for BOF units. It corresponds to a 0.61% reduction for a 1% coal price increase,

versus a 0.43% reduction for EAF units. Nonetheless, we cannot conclude that these effects are

statistically different from each other.

16

Table 2: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units using

the pre-sample mean estimator (Blundell, Griffith and Windmeijer, 2002)

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.507***

(0.121)

-0.607***

(0.128)

-0.433***

(0.125)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.710***

(0.039)

0.734***

(0.072)

0.672***

(0.043)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 723 364 359

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of the logarithm of expected coal price is used as instrument.

The models include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are included in

logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and ***

respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

The results displayed in Table 2 rely on the validity of our instrumentation strategy. In particular,

we assume that past shocks on expected coal prices do not correlate with the error term (𝑒𝑠,𝑖,𝑡),

and only determine the value of expected coal prices at time t. In mathematical terms, our

instrument is valid if ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ ) = 𝛿 ln(𝑝𝑖,𝑡−1

∗ ) + 𝑣𝑖,𝑡, with 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟(𝑣𝑖,𝑡, 𝑣𝑖,𝑡−1) = 0. The pre-sample

mean estimator tolerates that 𝑣𝑖,𝑡 is correlated with 𝑒𝑖,𝑡−𝑥 with 𝑥 ≥ 1, whereas a fixed effect

model would require 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟(𝑣𝑖,𝑡, 𝑒𝑖,𝑡−𝑧) = 0 with 𝑧 ≥ 0.

We corroborate that this is the case in the present situation. We jointly use the first five lags of

𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ as instruments in Table 3. The general idea of this process is that deeper lags are even less

likely to be correlated with 𝑒𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 than the first lag. If the first lag is not an exogenous instrument,

then it should be providing different estimates than the ones obtained with deeper lags. Using up

to 5 lags, we can apply this same logic to the 2nd

lag, the 3rd

lag and so on, assuming that, at least,

shocks on the 5th

lag of expected coal prices should not be correlated with 𝑒𝑠,𝑖,𝑡. The sufficient

condition for the 5th

lag to be a valid instrument is that 𝑐𝑜𝑟𝑟(𝑣𝑖,𝑡, 𝑣𝑖,𝑡−5) = 0. All in all, results in

Table 3 are very close to the ones obtained with only one lag. Furthermore, we can run an over-

identification test since we have more instruments than variable. We reject the hypothesis that at

least one instrument would give results different than the other instruments.

The results of Tables 2 and 3 are robust to many specification changes. In particular, results are

17

not altered when we directly use expected coal prices instead of their logarithm in the model

(see Appendix C.1). Furthermore, we used a specific technique to produce coal price

expectations. However, our general results do not rely on the way expectations were computed.

We obtain similar results when we use contemporaneous prices (𝑝𝑖,𝑡) instead of expected prices

(𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ ) as the main independent variable (see Appendix C.2). To allow for more flexibility, we

also try using distributed lags for coal prices as independent variables in an alternative

specification (see Appendix C.3). Results lose precision but point estimates remain stable.

Table 3: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.643***

(0.113)

-0.744***

(0.112)

-0.579***

(0.126)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.681***

(0.044)

0.658***

(0.061)

0.662***

(0.040)

year trend yes yes Yes

Overidentification test

Hansen’s J chi2 7.146 6.804 7.498

p-value 0.128 0.147 0.112

Observations 555 280 275

Countries 19 19 19 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first 5 lags of the logarithm of expected coal price are used as

instrument. The models include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are

included in logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, **

and *** respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

In our preferred specifications, we also chose to exclusively rely on coking coal prices.

Estimates with steam coal prices are provided in Appendix C.4. They are almost identical for

EAF. In the case of BOF, the point estimate is close but the model loses precision, which is not

surprising considering that BOF units mostly rely on coking coal. Likewise, using both steam

and coking coal prices at the same time does not change our overall findings, even though

results lose precision due to the high correlation between steam and coking coal prices (see

Appendix C.5).

The choice of the pre-sample period has also little influence on our findings: modifying the pre-

sample period from 1960-1981 to 1970-1981 does not significantly alter our results (see

18

Appendix D.1). Likewise, switching to a fully linear model instead of using a non-linear count

model does not alter our findings (see Appendix D.2).

5. Simulation of multilateral carbon markets

We now run a simulation where we quantify the effect of the introduction of a multinational

carbon market on the location of steel plants and the share of EAF units in a given country at time

t. We assume that the policy, if implemented in country i at time t, raises the price of carbon by

an additional $ 31 per ton of CO2 equivalent. This figure corresponds to the current social cost of

carbon as estimated in Nordhaus (2017). For simplicity, we assume that this increase in the price

of carbon would be additional to any existing policies. We convert the carbon tax of $

31/tCO2eq. into a coal price increase by assuming that a ton of coal emits 2.457/tCO2eq. (Trust,

2008). We therefore raise the expected price of coal in regulated countries by about $ 76 per ton.

We define one business-as-usual scenario and two policy scenarios. In the business as usual

scenario, the policy is implemented nowhere. The first policy scenario is a scenario in which all

countries agree on entering the multilateral carbon market. Therefore, we apply the coal price

increase of $ 76 per ton to the 22 countries of our sample. We furthermore develop one additional

policy scenario in which the carbon market is applied only in European countries. This scenario

corresponds to the one where the steel industry would be strictly regulated under the EU

Emissions Trading Scheme (ETS), with a much higher carbon price (of $ 31/tCO2eq.) than the

one that can be observed today in the EU ETS.

The simulation uses the specifications displayed in columns 2 and 3 of Table 2: we assume that

the impact of increasing coking coal prices is different for BOF and EAF units. Using these

specifications, we compute the share of BOF and EAF units that would have operated in country i

over the sample period (1982-2014) under the two policy scenarios, and compare this share to the

one recorded in our data (which corresponds to the business-as-usual scenario). Demand for steel

is assumed to be fixed in spite of the changing coal prices. Results are reported in Table 4.

In the business as usual scenario, 24.04% of plants are in North America, 23.87% are in Europe,

50.79% are in Asia, and 1.31% in other regions of the world. EAF plants represent 76.83% of

North American plants, 63.36% of European plants, 50.96% of Asian plants, and 45.90% of other

regions’ plants.

19

In the scenario where the coal price increase only affects European countries, the share of steel

units present in Europe goes down to 22.2%. This is a 1.7% reduction in market share. The share

of EAF units would increase by 0.17% (from 63.36% to 63.53%) in Europe. The reduction in

market share appears to be disproportionately high compared to the gains obtained in greening

the domestic production of steel in Europe.

In the “all countries” scenario, Asian countries significantly lose market share (minus 9.7

percentage points), mostly in favor of European countries (plus 7.9 percentage points). Higher

coal prices also lead to a shift towards greener production processes everywhere, in Asia

particularly where the share of EAF plants would increase by 4.8 percentage points. The two

phenomena are linked. The main reason why Asian countries would lose market share is because

Asian firms are more coal intensive (they rely more on the BOF technology) and have built their

steel industry on relatively cheaper energy. European firms are relatively less affected by the coal

price increase because energy prices are already high in Europe.

Table 4: Simulation results on the location and technology of steel units under the

implementation of carbon markets, pricing GHG emissions at $ 31/tCO2eq.

Indicator Share of units over the total amount of

units operative in the world

Percentage of units that are EAF

Scenario BAU Europe

only is

regulated

All regions

are

regulated

BAU Europe

only is

regulated

All regions

are

regulated

North

America 24.0% 24.6% 26.2% 76.83% 76.83% 78.8%

Europe 23.9% 22.2% 31.8% 63.4% 63.5% 63.5%

Asia 50.8% 51.9% 41.1% 51.0% 51.0% 55.8%

Other 1.3% 1.3% 1.0% 45.9% 45.9% 44.3% Notes: The simulations are run for the case of the implementation of a carbon scheme with an optimal price of

carbon of $31=tCO2. Share of active units is calculated as the number of active steel-making units in a region over

the total number of active units in the rest of the world. The share of EAF is calculated as the proportion of EAF

units over the total number of steel-making units in a region. North America includes Canada and the US; Europe

includes Germany, Turkey, Spain, Italy, France, Poland, Belgium, Czech Republic, Sweden, Finland, the

Netherlands, Portugal, Switzerland and Norway; Asia includes China, Japan, Russia and India; Other regions include

Australia and Chile.

These simulations are informative about the upcoming difficulties in finding common agreements

on carbon markets across the globe. Our figures suggest that some European firms would relocate

if the European steel industry was to comply with a more stringent carbon price, e.g. in the

20

framework of the EU ETS. However, we also find that Asian countries have benefited from a

competitive advantage because of relatively cheap energy, allowing them to rely on polluting

technologies to produce steel. They would lose part of this advantage if emissions were uniformly

priced worldwide as they specialized more in BOF technologies. Finally, cross-country relocation

effects appear stronger than within-country changes in steel-making technologies.

6. Conclusion

The Paris Agreement, in 2015, has shown the ambition of countries to undertake a global action

against climate change. The steel sector is particularly sensible to this topic as it is a major emitter

of GHG emissions in the atmosphere. Given the availability of two substitutable steel-making

technologies, the interest lies on the possibility, through environmental policies, to shift steel

production from BOF to EAF, making it less carbon intensive.

This study aims at shedding light on the impact of an increase in coal prices on the location of

steel plants and the technologies that the firms would choose to produce steel. We find that, on

average, an increase of 1% in the expected price of coal reduces the share of steel-making units

active in one country, compared to the rest of the world, by 0.51%. This effect seems to differ

across types of production technologies: BOF units are more sensitive (minus 0.61%) than EAF

ones (minus 0.43%). When we simulate the effect of regional increases in coal prices, we find

that European firms would lose competitiveness if they were to unilaterally set a binding carbon

price on their firms. Therefore, the risk of relocation is real for EU firms if steel making

processes were more heavily taxed. Another important finding is that a uniform increase of coal

prices across the globe would also have an impact on the location of steel plants. Asian firms

would be more severely touched because they are the ones that rely on BOF technologies the

most.

Therefore, the simulation on the European market shows that unilateral agreements may prove

detrimental to national industries in industrialized countries, making the search for a

multilateral agreement all the more necessary. Yet, a multilateral agreement could also have

strong redistributive consequences for the steel sector. Our results suggest a multilateral

agreement on taxing energy use in the steel sector could only be reached if measures were

taken to guarantee that reducing GHG emissions in the industry would not strongly modify the

21

location of production worldwide. Whereas these results mostly apply to the steel sector, they

are likely to be valid for other energy-intensive sectors open to international competition, such

as the cement industry.

22

REFERENCES

Aghion, P., Dechezlepretre, A., Hemous, D., Martin, R. and VanReenen, J. (2016). Carbon taxes, path

dependency, and directed technical change: evidence from the auto industry. Journal of Political

Economy. 124(1), 1–51.

Aldy, J. E., & Pizer, W. A. (2015a). The competitiveness impacts of climate change mitigation policies.

Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists, 2(4), 565-595.

Aldy, Joseph E., and William A. Pizer. (2015b). The impacts of power sector carbon regulations on U.S.

manufacturing employment. Harvard Kennedy School Working paper

Berry, S. T. (1994). Estimating Discrete-Choice Models of Product Differentiation. RAND Journal of

Economics. 25(2), 242–262.

Blundell, R., Bond, S., 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models.

Journal of Econometrics 87, 115-144.

Blundell, R., Griffith, R. andWindmeijer, F. (2002). Individual effects and dynamics in count data models.

Journal of Econometrics. 108(1), 113–131.

Bosetti, V., Carraro, C., Duval, R., De Cian, E., Massetti, E. and Tavoni, M. (2014). The incentives to

participate in and the stability of international climate coalitions: a game theoretic approach using the

witch model. OECD Economics Department Working Papers (1177) .

Borghesi, S., Franco, C., and Marin, G., (2014). Outward foreign direct investments: pattern of Italian

firms in the EU-ETS. SEEDS Working Paper (01/2016) .

Brunnermeier, S. and Cohen, M. (2003). Determinants of environmental innovation in us manufacturing

industries. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 45(2), 278–293.

Chamberlain, G., 1992. Sequential moment restrictions in panel data. Journal of Business & Economic

Statistics 10, 20-26.

Cohen, F., Glachant, M. and Soderberg, M. (2017). The impact of energy prices on product innovation:

evidence from the uk refrigerator market. Forthcoming.

Dechezlepretre, A., Glachant, M., Hascic, I., Johnstone, N. and Meniere, Y. (2011). Invention and transfer

of climate change-mitigation technologies: a global analysis. Review of Environmental Economics and

Policy. 5(1). 109–130.

Dechezlepretre, A., Gennaioli, C., Martin, R., and Muuls, M. (2014). Searching for carbon leaks in

multinational companies. Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment Working

Paper (165).

Ederington, J., A. Levinson, and J. Minier. 2005. Footloose and pollution-free. Review of Economics and

Statistics 87 (1): 92 – 99.

EPA (2012). Available and emerging technologies for reducing greenhouse gas emissions from the iron

and steel industry. Environmental Protection Agency .

Flues, F., Rubbelke, D. and Vogele, S. (2015). An analysis of the economic determinants of energy

efficiency in the european iron and steel industry. Journal of Cleaner Production. 104, 250–263.

Fredriksson, P. G., & Millimet, D. L. (2002). Strategic interaction and the determination of environmental

policy across US states. Journal of Urban Economics, 51(1), 101-122.

23

Giarratani, F., Hewings, G. J. and McCann, P. (2013), Handbook of Industry Studies and Economic

Geography. Edward Elgar Publishing.

Greenstone, Michael. 2002. The impacts of environmental regulations on industrial activity: Evidence

from the 1970 and 1977 Clean Air Act Amendments and the Census of Manufactures. Journal of Political

Economy. 110 (6): 1175-1219.

Guimaraes, P., Figueiredo, O. and Woodward, D. (2003). A tractable approach to the firm location

decision problem. The Review of Economics and Statistics. 85(2), 201–204.

Hausman, J., Leonard, G. and Zona, J. D. (1994). Competitive Analysis with Differentiated Products.

Annals of Economics and Statistics. (34), 143–157.

Ho, M. S., Morgenstern, R. D., & Shih, J. S. (2008). Impact of carbon price policies on US industry.

Resources for the Future Discussion Paper No. 08-37.

IEA (2012). Profiles- co2 abatement in the iron and steel industry. International Energy Agency.

IEA (2016). Energy technology perspective 2016: Towards sustainable urban energy systems.

International Energy Agency.

IEA (2017). Tracking clean energy progress 2017. International Energy Agency.

Jaffe, Adam B., Steven R. Peterson, Paul R. Portney, and Robert N. Stavins. 1995. Environmental

regulation and the competitiveness of U.S. manufacturing: What does the evidence tell us? Journal of

Economic Literature. 33 (1): 32–63.

Jaffe, A. and Palmer, K. (1997). Environmental regulation and innovation: a panel data study. The Review

of Economics and Statistics. 79(4), 610–619.

Jeppesen, Tim, John A. List, and Henk Folmer. 2002. Environmental regulations and new plant location

decisions: evidence from a meta-analysis. Journal of Regional Science. 42 (1): 19–49.

Kahn, Matthew E., and Erin T. Mansur. 2013. Do local energy prices and regulation affect the geographic

concentration of employment?. Journal of Public Economics. 101:105–14.

Kellenberg, D. K. (2009). An empirical investigation of the pollution haven effect with strategic

environment and trade policy. Journal of international economics, 78(2), 242-255.

King, R.E., Tang, H. (1988). International Macroeconomic Adjustment, 1987-1992 : a World Model

Approach (The World Bank).

Koch, N. and Basse Mama, H. (2016). European climate policy and industrial relocation: evidence from

German multinational firms. Available at

SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2868283 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2868283

Lanjouw, J. and Mody, A. (1996). Innovation and the international diffusion of environmentally

responsive technology. Research Policy. 25(4), 549–571.

Levinson, Arik, and M. Scott Taylor. (2008). Unmasking the pollution haven effect. International

Economic Review. 49 (1): 223-54.

List, J. A., Millimet, D. L., Fredriksson, P. G., & McHone, W. W. (2003). Effects of environmental

regulations on manufacturing plant births: evidence from a propensity score matching estimator. The

Review of Economics and Statistics, 85(4), 944-952.

Marcu, A. (2016). Carbon market provisions in the Paris agreement (article 6). CEPS Special Report,

Centre for European Policy Studies 128.

24

Mathiesen, L. and Maestad, O. (2004). Climate Policy and the Steel Industry: Achieving Global Emission

Reductions by an Incomplete Climate Agreement. The Energy Journal. (4), 91–114.

Morgenstern, R. D., Pizer, W. A., & Shih, J. S. (2002). Jobs versus the environment: an industry-level

perspective. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43(3), 412-436.

Newell, R., Jaffe, A. and Stavins, R. (1999). The induced innovation hypothesis and energy-saving

technical change. Quarterly Journal of Economics. 114(3), 941–975.

Nordhaus, W. (2017). Evolution of modeling of the economics of global warming: changes in the dice

model, 1992-2017. Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 2084.

OECD (2013). Impacts of energy market developments on the steel industry.

OECD (2015). Steelmaking capacity. URL: http://www.oecd.org/sti/ind/steelcapacity.htm

Popp, D. (2002). Induced innovation and energy prices. The American Economic Review. 92(1), 160–180.

Popp, D. (2006). International innovation and diffusion of air pollution control technologies: the effects of

nox and so2 regulations in the US, Japan and Germany. Journal of Environmental Economics and

Management. 51(1), 46–71.

Reppelin-Hill, V. (1999). Trade and Environment: An Empirical Analysis of the Technology Effect in the

Steel Industry. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management. 38(3), 283–301.

Roodman, D. (2008). Through the looking glass, and what ols found there: on growth, foreign aid, and

reverse causality. Center for Global Development, Working Paper No. 137.

Schleich, J. (2007). Determinants of structural change and innovation in the German steel industry: an

empirical investigation. International Journal of Public Policy. 2(1/2), 109–123.

Schwartz, N. D., Creswell, J. (23 October 2015). A Global Chill in Commodity Demand Hits America’s

Heartland. The New York Times.

Staiger, D., Stock, J. H., 1997. Instrumental variables regression with weak instruments. Econometrica 65,

557-586.

Stoft, S., Ockenfels, A. and Cramton, P. (2013). How to negotiate ambitious global emissions abatement.

Working Paper .

Trust, C. (2008). URL: https://www.carbontrust.com/

UNCOMTRADE (2017). United nations commodity trade statistics database. United Nations Commodity

Trade Statistics Database.

USDOC (2016). Global steel report. Department of commerce .

Wagner, U. J., & Timmins, C. D. (2009). Agglomeration effects in foreign direct investment and the

pollution haven hypothesis. Environmental and Resource Economics, 43(2), 231-256.

WBG and ECOFYS (2015). State and trends of carbon pricing, 2015. World Bank Group .

WCA (2017). How is steel produced?. World Coal Association . https://www.worldcoal.org/coal/uses-

coal/how-steel-produced.

Weitzman, M. L. (2014). Can negotiating a uniform carbon price help to internalize the global warming

externality?. Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists. 1, 29–49.

Wirtschaftsvereinigung Stahl, 2012. Statistisches Jahrbuch der Stahlindustrie 2012/ 2013. Stahleisen-

Verlag, Düsseldorf.

25

Worrell Ernst, Martin Nathan, and Price Lynn (1999). Energy Efficiency and Carbon Dioxide Emissions

Reduction Opportunities in the U.S. Iron and Steel Sector.

Wooldridge, J. M., 1997. Multiplicative panel data models without the strict exogeneity assumption.

Econometric Theory 13, 667-678.

WSA (2016). Steel statistical yearbook. World Steel Association.

Yellishetty, M., Mudd, G. M., Ranjith, P. and Tharumarajah, A. (2011). Environmental life-cycle

comparisons of steel production and recycling: sustanaibility issues, problems and prospects.

Environmental Science & Policy. 4, 650–663.

26

APPENDICES

A. Descriptive statistics of full dataset and pre-sample data

Table A1 provides information on the number of steel units recorded in the data for the pre-

sample period (1960-1981) for the countries included in the final analysis.

Table A1: Descriptive statistics of OECD data on steel plant location and main technology

used in production (1960-1981)

Period 1960-1981

Technology BOF EAF

North America 48.8 143.7

Europe 56.4 83.5

Asia 105.4 76.4

Other 5.1 2.5

Total 215.7 306.0

Notes: The table reports the average number of active units of steel-making production in each region of the world.

North America includes Canada and the US; Europe includes Germany, Turkey, Spain, Italy, France, Poland,

Belgium, Czech Republic, Sweden, Finland, the Netherlands, Portugal, Switzerland and Norway; Asia includes

China, Japan, Russia and India; Other includes Australia and Chile.

27

Table A2 provides information on the number of steel units recorded in the data for the full

period available in the OECD data. Also countries which we couldn’t match with coal prices are

included here. In addition to lower data quality, the fact that BOF seems remarkably scarce in the

period before 1960 could be explained by the large presence, in that time frame, of OHF which is

not reported in the table. Starting from the 1960s, OHF has been almost completely phased out by

BOF processes.

Table A2: Descriptive statistics of OECD data on steel plant location and main technology

used in production (1900 – 2014)

Period Before 1960 1960-1981 1982-1990 1991-2000 2001-2014

Technology BOF EAF BOF EAF BOF EAF BOF EAF BOF EAF

North America 0.2 9.4 48.8 143.7 70.3 234.8 64.8 210.0 54.3 183.3

Europe 0.6 0.4 96.0 109.0 188.7 253.3 168.9 230.7 137.6 236.9

Asia 0.1 1.8 112.8 99.5 246.3 305.8 287.2 445.0 373.0 567.4

Other 0.1 0.2 18.9 34.3 52.0 94.1 53.6 109.8 51.7 111.9

Total 1.0 11.8 276.4 386.6 557.3 888.0 574.5 995.5 616.7 1099.5

Notes: The table reports the average number of active units of steel-making production in each region of the world.

North America includes Canada and the US; Europe includes Albania, Austria, Belgium, Bosnia, Bulgaria, Croatia,

Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Israel, Italy, Latvia, Luxembourg,

Macedonia, Moldova, Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Serbia, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden,

Switzerland, Turkey, Ukraine, United Kingdom; Asia includes Armenia, Azerbaijan, Bangladesh, Belarus, China,

Hong Kong, India, Indonesia, Iran, Iraq, Japan, Kazakhstan, North Korea, South Korea, Lebanon, Malaysia,

Mongolia, Oman, Pakistan, Philippines, Qatar, Russia, Saudi Arabia, Singapore, Sri Lanka, Taiwan, Thailand,

Tunisia, United Arab Emirates, Uzbekistan and Vietnam; Other includes Argentina, Australia, Brazil, Chile,

Colombia, Cuba, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, New Zealand,

Paraguay, Peru, Uruguay and Venezuela.

28

B. Output of ARIMA model to produce coal price expectations

Figure B1 shows, for a selection of countries, the expectations on coking coal prices computed

with the ARIMA model presented in section 3. Predictions are only displayed for specific years

(1995, 2000, 2005, 2010 and 2015) even though they were computed for each year and country

used to run our econometric model.

Figure B1: Expected coking coal prices as predicted with the ARIMA model

29

C. Alternative specifications of coal prices

1. Using coal prices in levels and not in logarithm

Table C1 presents the estimation where the expected coal prices are included in normal values

instead of the logarithmic form. Instead of equation 1, we estimate:

𝑁𝑠,𝑖,𝑡 = 𝑒𝑥𝑝(𝛼 + 𝛽𝑝𝑖,𝑡∗ + 𝜎 ln(�̅�𝑠,𝑖,𝑡𝑖

) + 𝜃𝑡) + 𝑒𝑠,𝑖,𝑡

Logically, the magnitude of the estimated betas is around 100 times smaller, but the relative

effects remain stable.

Table C1: Estimation of the impact of coal prices on the share of steel units

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

expected coking coal price -0.0053**

(0.0026)

-0.0066**

(0.0029)

-0.0044*

(0.0023)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.686***

(0.042)

0.721***

(0.080)

0.650***

(0.044)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 723 364 359

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of the expected coal price is used as instrument. The models

include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Pre-Sample Mean is included in logarithmic form.

Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote

significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

30

2. Using the contemporaneous price of coal

Table C2 reports the estimation results obtained when using the current coal prices instead of the

expected ones. Results are similar.

Table C2: Estimation of the impact of contemporaneous coal prices on the share of steel

units

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. coking coal price -0.487*** -0.582*** -0.424***

(0.148) (0.168) (0.141)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.710***

(0.035)

0.724***

(0.070)

0.677***

(0.041)

year trend yes yes Yes

Observations 787 395 392

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of the logarithm of contemporaneous coal price is used as

instrument. The models include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are

included in logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, **

and *** respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

31

3. Using distributed lags for the price of coal

Table C3 provides the results of a distributed lag model in which we have included the first 2 lags

of the expected price of coal. We use the first to third lags of expected coal prices as instrument.

If we add up the effects of the current expected coal price with the ones of its lags, we obtain an

overall effect of -0.67% which is not far away from the effect found in the basic regression. This

formulation is therefore consistent with our baseline specification, even though it loses precision.

Table C3: Estimation of the impact of coal prices on the share of steel units using a

distributed lag model with 2 lags

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.076

(0.277)

-0.375

(0.374)

0.029

(0.304)

lag_1(log. expected coking

coal price)

-0.413

(0.462)

-0.356

(0.520)

-0.434

(0.516)

lag_2(log. expected coking

coal price)

-0.178

(0.187)

-0.106

(0.169)

-0.157

(0.200)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1971)

0.681***

(0.045)

0.688***

(0.077)

0.647***

(0.050)

year trend Yes Yes Yes

Observations 637 300 295

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of each independent variable is used as instrument. The

models include a time trend. The pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are included in

logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and ***

respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

32

4. Using steam coal prices instead of coking coal prices

In Table C4, we use expected steam coal prices instead of expected coking coal ones. As this type

of coal is only used in EAF processes, we find a significantly negative effect for the EAF

estimation. The model instruments for coal prices and, therefore, may correct for measurement

error in the case of BOF (who uses coking coal). The point estimate for BOF is negative and

larger than for EAF units, even though only statistically significant at 10%.

Table C4: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units using

the first lag of the logarithm of expected steam coal prices as instrument

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected steam coal price -0.511** -0.561* -0.470**

(0.257) (0.306) (0.221)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.654***

(0.056)

0.699***

(0.093)

0.629***

(0.057)

year trend yes yes Yes

Observations 675 327 348

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of the logarithm of expected coal price is used as instrument.

The models include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are included in

logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and ***

respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

33

5. Using both coking coal and steam coal prices

Table C5 presents the results of the estimation where both coking coal prices and steam coal

prices are used. The overall findings remain the same: increasing the price of coal may

discourage more BOF production rather than EAF. Nevertheless, except for the coefficient

associated to coking coal in the BOF estimation, all the coefficients are now insignificant. This

may be attributed to the loss of precision due to multicollinearity between coking and steam coal

prices.

Table C5: Estimation of the impact of both expected coking and steam coal prices on the

share of steel units

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.548

(0.370)

-0.866**

(0.384)

-0.377

(0.371)

log. expected steam coal price 0.033

(0.190)

0.252

(0.223)

-0.080

(0.216)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.691***

(0.046)

0.709***

(0.069)

0.649***

(0.055)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 583 294 289

Countries 19 19 19 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of each dependent variable is used as instrument. The models

include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are included in logarithmic form.

Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote

significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

34

6. Using coking coal price / electricity price ratio

The choice of the main independent variable – the price of coal – seems natural, but an

interesting extension could be to use the price ratio between expected coking coal price and

expected electricity price. Indeed, the decision of using BOF rather than EAF seemingly depends

on the difference between coal and electricity prices, since BOF uses coal, but EAF uses

electricity. Electricity used to operate EAF plants is usually produced on-site using coal, but this

could vary according to the energy mix of the country of operation. Including the price ratio

between the two should capture this possibility. Table C6 presents the results under this

specification. They appear even stronger than in the baseline scenario. An increase of 1% in the

ratio, which could be associated either with an increase in expected coking coal price or a

decrease in expected electricity price, reduces the share of BOF steel-making units active in a

country, compared to the rest of the world, by 3.2%, while it only reduces the share of EAF by

2.52%. Again, we find evidence of a directed technical change effect.

Table C6: Estimation of the impact of expected coking coal price / expected electricity

price ratio on the share of steel units

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. (expected coking coal

price/ expected electricity

price ratio)

-2.579***

(0.870)

-3.180**

(0.976)

-2.520***

(0.665)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.782***

(0.052)

0.723***

(0.104)

0.763***

(0.052)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 671 338 333

Countries 19 19 19 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of each dependent variable is used as instrument. The models

include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are included in logarithmic form.

Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote

significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

35

7. Adding more controls

Table C7a presents the results of the estimation where the logarithm of GDP is added, as an

additional control, to the baseline specification. The main findings remain the same. The GDP

coefficient is not significantly different from 0, indicating that the economic development of a

country does not give an a priori advantage in investing in one steel-making technology rather

than the other.

Table C7a: Estimation of the impact expected coking coal prices on the share of steel

units, adding GDP

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.439***

(0.132)

-0.494***

(0.120)

-0.406***

(0.142)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

log.GDP

0.816***

(0.060)

-0.121

(0.089)

0.899***

(0.105)

-0.150

(0.089)

0.722***

(0.047)

-0.059

(0.087)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 723 364 359

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of each dependent variable is used as instrument. The models

include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are included in logarithmic form.

Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote

significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

Table C6b tests for the presence of non-linear effects. The logarithm of the squared price of coal

is added to the baseline estimation. Results are even stronger in this scenario. An increase of 1%

in the expected price of coal reduces the share of BOF steel-making units active in a country,

compared to the rest of the world, by 2.3%, while it only reduces the share of EAF by 1.77%. The

positive second order coefficient indicates a convexity in the relation between the share of steel-

making units and the expected coking coal price. It means that the maximum decrease in share of

active units may be reached with a medium decrease in coal price. In this specification the two

coefficients appear significantly different from each other at 0.05 significance level.

36

Table C7b: Estimation of the impact expected coking coal prices on the share of steel

units, adding a non-linear effect

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-2.095***

(0.500)

-2.304***

(0.448)

-1.775***

(0.565)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

log. expected coking coal

price_sq

0.731***

(0.036)

0.195***

(0.070)

0.755***

(0.066)

0.210***

(0.065)

0.690***

(0.038)

0.164***

(0.076)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 723 364 359

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of each dependent variable is used as instrument. The models

include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981. Independent variables are included in logarithmic form.

Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote

significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

37

D. Choice of estimation method

1. Using a different pre-sample period

Using a shorter pre-sample period starting in 1970 has little influence on the results obtained (see

Table D1 below).

Table D1: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units, pre-

sample starting in 1970

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.418***

(0.089)

-0.486***

(0.073)

-0.399***

(0.122)

log. pre-sample mean (1970-

1981)

0.776***

(0.047)

0.756***

(0.056)

0.751***

(0.050)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 723 364 359

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The first lag of the logarithm of expected coal price is used as instrument. The models include a time

trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1970 to 1981. Independent variables are included in logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in

parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and ***__ respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

38

2. Linear version of the pre-sample mean estimator

The linear version of the pre-sample estimator, shown in Table D2, uses a 2SLS procedure.

Given that we are dealing with a count model, we lose efficiency when we switch from the non-

linear to the linear setting. Nevertheless, the 2SLS provides similar results and allows computing

a weak identification test to verify the strength of the instrument.

Table D2: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units, linear

model

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.034**

(0.015)

-0.034**

(0.016)

-0.033**

(0.014)

log. pre-sample mean (1960-

1981)

0.439***

(0.025)

0.459***

(0.094)

0.431***

(0.020)

year dummy yes Yes yes

Weak Identification Test

Kleibergen-Paap rk Wald F

statistic

2816.23 3056.82 2308.95

Stock-Yogo maximum bias <10% <10% <10%

Observations 555 280 275

Countries 19 19 19 Notes: The linear model uses IV 2SLS. The models include a time dummy. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981.

Independent variables are included in logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are

set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant

has not been reproduced.

39

3. Results with a fixed effect model

In Table D3, we present the results obtained when using a fixed-effect estimator. This model

assumes that expected coking coal prices are fully exogenous. Results are biased and the model is

inconsistent.

Table D3: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units, fixed-

effect model

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

0.223*

(0.132)

0.299**

(0.137)

0.163

(0.129)

year trend yes yes Yes

Observations 767 386 381

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The models include a time trend. Independent variable is included in

logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are set at country level. *, ** and ***

respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant has not been reproduced.

40

4. Results with a first difference estimator

Tables D4.a and D4.b feature first-difference estimators. Table D4.a uses a transformed model

based on Chamberlain (1992) and Wooldridge (1997). We use the second lagged difference of

the independent variable as an instrument. In this case, the estimated effect of coal price on steel

production is negative. We find a stronger effect for EAF than BOF. Nevertheless, all these

effects are not statistically different from 0. This is not surprising since we know that results from

the first-difference estimators are usually inefficient.

Table D4.a: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units,

model in first difference based on Chamberlain (1992) and Wooldridge (1997)

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

-0.007

(0.036)

-0.029

(0.077)

-0.070

(0.091)

year trend yes Yes Yes

Observations 637 321 316

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The models include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981.

Independent variables are included in logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are

set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant

has not been reproduced.

The results of table D4.a are also likely to be biased towards a first differenced model where we

would assume that the coal price is exogenous (as shown in Staiger and Stock, 1997; and Blundell

and Bond, 1998). Such a first differenced model is reported in Table D4.b. Results are

inconsistent due to the violation of the exogeneity assumption. Here, the coefficient for BOF is

positive and higher than for EAF, so the small sample bias is likely to explain why, in table D5.a,

we found that the negative coefficient for EAF was higher in magnitude than the one for BOF.

41

Table D4.b: Estimation of the impact of expected coal prices on the share of steel units,

model in first difference with assumption of exogenous coal prices

Dependent Variable (Share

Units of Steel Production)

Non-Linear Model

All

(1)

BOF

(2)

EAF

(3)

log. expected coking coal

price

0.043

(0.030)

0.081*

(0.044)

0.025

(0.032)

year trend yes yes yes

Observations 723 364 359

Countries 22 22 22 Notes: The non-linear model uses GMM. The models include a time trend. Pre-sample ranges from 1960 to 1981.

Independent variables are included in logarithmic form. Cluster-robust standard errors in parentheses. Clusters are

set at country level. *, ** and *** respectively denote significance at 10%, 5% and 1% levels. Coefficient of constant

has not been reproduced.