risk to control riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 introduction fighting fire with fire, a...

63
Risk to Control Risk ú Fernando Mendo Princeton University This version: November 19, 2018 Download latest version here Abstract Can low risk be risky? In this continuous-time macroeconomic model, low mea- sured volatility may disguise the buildup of hidden systemic run risk. Runs trigger large drops in asset prices and real production and propel the economy into a highly unstable crisis regime. Agents take on too much leverage in the hidden risk regime because they disregard their contribution to the economy’s exposure to systemic runs. Surprisingly, a leverage cap can increase hidden run risk by deepening crises that follow runs. Economies exposed to less volatile fluctuations due to real shocks are more prone to systemic runs: stability breeds instability. This trade-osug- gests that full stabilization of business cycles is not necessarily optimal once runs are taken into account. Instead, policymakers may consider allowing risk to control risk. JEL classification: E13, E32, E44, G01, G12, G21, G33. ú I am deeply indebted to Markus Brunnermeier for his invaluable guidance and support, as well as to Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and Mark Aguiar for many helpful conversations and advice. I thank Joseph Abadi for detailed comments and corrections on preliminary versions of the manuscript. I also thank Oleg Itskhoki, Moritz Lenel, Chris Sims, Césaire Meh, Sebastien Merkel, Motohiro Yogo, Paul Ho, Julius Vutz, Nick Huang, Yann Koby, Ezra Oberfield, Simon Schmickler, and seminar participants at Princeton University and at the 2018 Macro Financial Modeling Summer Meeting for their comments and suggestions. Financial support of the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation and the Macro Financial Modeling (MFM) project is gratefully acknowledged. Email: [email protected].

Upload: others

Post on 18-Jun-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Risk to Control Risk

ú

Fernando Mendo

Princeton University

This version: November 19, 2018

Download latest version here

Abstract

Can low risk be risky? In this continuous-time macroeconomic model, low mea-sured volatility may disguise the buildup of hidden systemic run risk. Runs triggerlarge drops in asset prices and real production and propel the economy into a highlyunstable crisis regime. Agents take on too much leverage in the hidden risk regimebecause they disregard their contribution to the economy’s exposure to systemicruns. Surprisingly, a leverage cap can increase hidden run risk by deepening crisesthat follow runs. Economies exposed to less volatile fluctuations due to real shocksare more prone to systemic runs: stability breeds instability. This trade-o� sug-gests that full stabilization of business cycles is not necessarily optimal once runsare taken into account. Instead, policymakers may consider allowing risk to controlrisk.

JEL classification: E13, E32, E44, G01, G12, G21, G33.

úI am deeply indebted to Markus Brunnermeier for his invaluable guidance and support, as well asto Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and Mark Aguiar for many helpful conversations and advice. I thank JosephAbadi for detailed comments and corrections on preliminary versions of the manuscript. I also thankOleg Itskhoki, Moritz Lenel, Chris Sims, Césaire Meh, Sebastien Merkel, Motohiro Yogo, Paul Ho,Julius Vutz, Nick Huang, Yann Koby, Ezra Oberfield, Simon Schmickler, and seminar participants atPrinceton University and at the 2018 Macro Financial Modeling Summer Meeting for their commentsand suggestions. Financial support of the Alfred P. Sloan Foundation and the Macro Financial Modeling(MFM) project is gratefully acknowledged.

†Email: [email protected].

Page 2: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

1 Introduction

Fighting fire with fire, a principle e�ectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac-cines) or firefighting (controlled burns), can be the key to controlling risk in economics.The hypothesis that prolonged periods of stability incite the buildup of hidden risksis a first-order concern among policymakers and academics, yet there is no frameworkthat illustrates the internal consistency of this concern or the mechanism underlyingit. Such a framework is necessary to incorporate its e�ects into risk measurement andpolicy design.

The seemingly paradoxical idea that stability breeds instability is widespread in policyand academic discussions. However, we have limited knowledge about the interactionsbetween the di�erent forms of risk. Several questions regarding these interactions re-main unresolved. Do prolonged periods of macroeconomic stability (e.g. the GreatModeration) disguise the risk of sudden collapses such as the last financial crisis? If so,how can we identify this vulnerability in seemingly safe low-volatility environments? Isthere a trade-o� between business cycle stabilization and financial stability, i.e., do lessvolatile real fluctuations foster financial fragility? How e�ective are macroprudentialpolicies to simultaneously control di�erent forms of risk?

To study these questions, I set up a continuous-time macro model with risk-averse banksand households. Banks obtain higher returns from managing capital than householdsand these returns are subject to small exogenous shocks to capital quality which are theonly real shocks in the economy. There are no equity markets, so banks finance capitalholdings beyond their net worth by issuing short-term non-contingent debt (deposits)to households. Households occasionally consider whether or not to roll over deposits(according to a sunspot that follows a Poisson process). If banks are unable to meet theirdeposit obligations by liquidating capital, households refuse to roll over their deposits,triggering a systemic run. Bank runs wipe out large parts of the banking system andtrigger large collapses in asset prices and output.

The economy exhibits two endogenous instabilities: 1) amplification of real shocks onoutput and asset prices, and 2) exposure to systemic runs. The main contribution of thispaper is to include both instabilities in a tractable framework in order to characterizetheir joint dynamics and study how they respond to changes in the underlying volatilityof real shocks.

The presence and intensity of the endogenous instabilities vary according to the keyendogenous state variable: the ratio of the banking sector’s wealth to the aggregatevalue of capital (or banks’ wealth share). In particular, the joint dynamics unveilthree di�erent risk regimes: 1) a highly unstable crisis regime characterized by theamplification of real shocks and occasional runs, 2) a safe regime with no endogenous

1

Page 3: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

risks, and 3) a hidden risk regime in which real shocks are not amplified but systemicruns can occur.

The crisis regime corresponds to situations in which the wealth share of the bankingsector is low enough to prevent banks from holding all capital in the economy. Thismisallocation depresses output and asset prices. Managing the entire stock of capitalwould require such high leverage and risk exposure that banks refrain from doing sodespite their productivity advantage. Then, banks’ capital demand depends on theirrisk-bearing capacity, which in turn depends on their wealth. Real shocks are amplifiedin this regime precisely because of their impact on banks’ risk-bearing capacity, whichtranslates into changes in allocative e�ciency.

Within the crisis regime, the economy is exposed to systemic runs only if the bankingsector’s wealth share is su�ciently large. For runs to be possible, the di�erence betweencontemporaneous asset prices and their liquidation value (i.e. their price just after arun when households manage almost all capital) needs to be large enough to implybankruptcy. When banks’ wealth share is exceptionally low, this di�erence is minuscule,and the economy is shielded from systemic runs. This region with amplification risk butno run risk is the exact opposite of the hidden risk regime in terms of the endogenousinstabilities present.

The safe regime is associated with situations in which the banking sector’s wealth shareis su�ciently large to allow banks to absorb all capital in the economy and yet maintainlow leverage. The absence of misallocation implies no amplification. The soundness ofbanks’ balance sheets prevents exposure to systemic runs in spite of the large di�erencebetween contemporaneous high asset prices and their liquidation value.

The hidden risk regime corresponds to an intermediate range of the banking sector’swealth share. It is high enough to allow banks to hold the entire capital stock butlow enough to require them to choose weak balance sheets, i.e., high leverage, in orderto do so. The latter combined with the high asset prices implied by the absence ofmisallocation exposes the economy to systemic runs, which immediately propel thesystem into the unstable crisis regime.

Importantly, prior to the realization of a run, the hidden risk regime is observationallyequivalent to the safe regime in terms of the volatility of real and financial variables. Inthis sense, run risk is hidden.1 This illustrates the potential fragility of low-volatilityenvironments and highlights the necessity of a risk topography to identify risks. Inparticular, the model suggests the following warning signals of run risk when measuredvolatility is low: the joint presence of high asset prices and a highly (or, at least,

1Run risk is not hidden for agents in the economy.

2

Page 4: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

moderately) levered banking sector, high excess returns per unit of measured volatility,and a low risk-free rate.

Systemic instabilities are an ergodic phenomenon in this economy. That is, the riskregimes associated with amplification and systemic runs are frequently visited by thesystem. In fact, the two peaks of the bimodal stationary distribution of banks’ wealthshare may lie within these risky regimes. The highest peak corresponds to the stochasticsteady state, i.e., the balance point to which the system tends to return, and it canbe located within the hidden risk regime. The economy spends prolonged periods inthis regime because, in contrast to amplification risk, run risk has a limited impacton excess returns on capital over the deposit rate. Then, wealth accumulation bylevered banks is not particularly accelerated in the hidden risk regime. The secondpeak corresponds to the situation that follows a systemic run, which is characterizedby a severely undercapitalized banking sector, i.e., it lies within the crisis regime. Thispeak reflects that the initial phase of the recovery after a run is slow.

A comparison across economies with di�erent levels of exogenous risk (fundamentalvolatility of real shocks) unveils the key insight of the model: stability breeds instabil-ity or its contrapositive, risk controls risk. Economies with the lowest exogenous riskhave the most severe endogenous instabilities. Lower fundamental risk prompts banksto issue more debt in order to expand capital holdings. This translates into a moree�cient allocation of resources and therefore into higher asset prices. In other words,lower exogenous risk fuels high leverage and asset prices, which lead to both greateramplification risk and greater run risk.

Crucially, the increase in amplification risk is not enough to overcome the initial re-duction of exogenous risk, so total volatility due to real shocks decreases alongsideexogenous risk. Then, the main risk for economies with low fundamental volatility ofreal shocks is an elevated exposure to systemic runs. On the other end of the spectrum,economies exhibiting su�ciently high exogenous risk are completely shielded from runrisk, i.e., risk controls risk. The weak reaction of amplification risk follows from thepresence of an automatic stabilization mechanism, which is absent in the case of runrisk. An increase in amplification risk feeds back into more prudent equilibrium portfo-lios for banks, while larger exposure to systemic runs has no e�ect on banks’ equilibriumleverage. This is ultimately related to the fact that banks disregard their contributionto run risk when making portfolio decisions (run externality).

An important insight is that the welfare ranking with respect to exogenous risk isnon-monotonic. The key e�ect driving the result is that lower exogenous risk induceshigher bank leverage (capital holdings). This has two opposing e�ects on welfare: 1)reduced misallocation, and 2) increased exposure to endogenous instabilities. Banks failto adequately internalize these forces, so laissez-faire leverage can be excessive or overly

3

Page 5: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

restrained with respect to its e�cient level. The total e�ect on welfare depends on therelative strengths of externalities a�ecting banks’ portfolio decisions.

If the externality associated with misallocation is stronger than those related to instabil-ities, then banks’ capital holdings are ine�ciently restrained, and a marginal reductionof exogenous risk helps minimize this ine�ciency. Otherwise, a marginal reduction ofexogenous risk aggravates the economy’s ine�ciencies. Numerical results suggest thatthe run externality is the decisive factor in this comparison between externalities. Thisis the key behind the non-monotonicity since run risk is present only in economies whereexogenous risk is su�ciently low.

Regarding policy interventions, the model reveals that a constant leverage constraintmay fail to control endogenous instabilities. A leverage cap depresses the liquidationprice of capital by deepening the recession that follows a run. This fuels run risk andis particularly detrimental for the economy since leverage is limited when it is neededthe most. This force dampens the reduction of run vulnerability due to lower leveragein the crisis regime and, most importantly, it leads to greater exposure to runs in thehidden risk regime (unless the constraint is tight enough to completely rule out runs).A constant leverage constraint also increases amplification risk in situations where it isnot binding and households still hold some capital. Despite these shortcomings, welfareanalysis suggests that a constant leverage cap can benefit both agents as long as itreduces the economy’s overall exposure to runs.

The optimal state-contingent leverage cap overcomes the mentioned drawbacks by re-stricting banks’ portfolio decisions only when the economy would be exposed to runs,i.e., in an intermediate range of banks’ wealth share. Interestingly, a binding optimalleverage cap in the hidden risk regime can limit run risk but introduces amplificationrisk. This emphasizes the relative importance of the run externality.

I also explore a di�erent approach to control run risk. In particular, I study how a benev-olent policymaker would adjust the complete markets prescription of full stabilizationwhen considering exposure to runs. The exercise ignores any cost of stabilization byassuming the policymaker can directly adjust fundamental volatility conditional on thestrength of banks’ balance sheets. This allows me to focus on the optimal adjustmentgiven the presence of run risk. Results suggest that it is optimal to allow risk asso-ciated with real shocks if the economy is exposed to runs and to implement completestabilization if it is not. The exercise illustrates the direction in which the possibility ofruns should a�ect stabilization policy; however, it is not a direct policy recommendationsince the model does not capture known benefits of stabilizing the economy.

Literature. The idea that stability breeds instability has been discussed at least sinceMinsky [1986]. He argues that instability is a normal result of modern financial capital-

4

Page 6: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

ism and casts doubts on the “fine-tuning” approach to policy. Minsky conjectures thateven if policy does manage to achieve transitory stability, this stability would renderfinancial markets complacent and susceptible to the reemergence of instability. Thispaper formalizes one such mechanism: a larger exposure to systemic runs.

The literature has extensively explored, separately, the two endogenous risks studied inthis paper. In the case of amplification risk, the financial accelerator mechanism behindit was first discussed by Kiyotaki and Moore [1997] (henceforth KM), and Bernanke et al.[1999] (henceforth BGG). Later work by Brunnermeier and Sannikov [2014] (henceforthBruSan) identifies that the intensity of this risk varies in a highly nonlinear fashion alongthe business cycle. In the case of run risk, there is an ample literature studying bankruns following the seminal contribution of Diamond and Dybvig [1983]. This literatureworks with partial equilibrium or short-horizon macroeconomic frameworks, which arenot suitable for studying endogenous risk dynamics.

Only after both risks arguably played an important role during the last financial crisisdid economists start to explore them together within macroeconomic models. Prominentexamples are Gertler and Kiyotaki [2015] (henceforth GK) and Gertler et al. [2017]. Themain interest in these papers is to compare the propagation mechanisms of real shockswith and without bank runs. In contrast, this paper focuses on the interactions betweenthese risks and their implications for macroeconomic stability. Moreover, while theliterature concentrates on the economy’s response to shocks in some specific situations,this paper provides a full characterization of the endogenous risks necessary to uncoverthe di�erent risk regimes.

The “volatility paradox” result in BruSan shares with this paper the general idea thatlow exogenous volatility of real shocks can fuel endogenous risks. However, their resultsdi�er from mine along several dimensions. First, their model predicts that every timethe economy is subject to risks associated with the financial sector, the risks trans-late into observable volatility of financial and macroeconomic variables. That is, theirmodel is unable to identify the buildup of hidden risks. Second, this paper raises muchstronger concerns about low exogenous volatility. In BruSan, endogenous amplificationpersists as exogenous volatility vanishes, but this e�ect is not enough to increase overallvolatility, so welfare improves with lower exogenous volatility. This paper shows thatthe welfare ranking reverses once run risk is considered since this risk is magnified asexogenous fluctuations are reduced.

The modeling approach of this paper builds on BruSan and GK. The continuous-timetechniques used to characterize the dynamics of risks expand work by BruSan, whilethe approach to include systemic runs in an infinite-horizon economy follows GK. Inan international context, Brunnermeier and Sannikov [2015] study amplification risktogether with a di�erent class of discrete collapses: sudden stops of international capital

5

Page 7: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

flows. Their work is technically the closest to this paper since they also consider acontinuous-time framework with self-fulfilling runs; yet they only study unanticipatedruns, i.e., their analysis disregards any feedback e�ects from run risk to agents’ decisionsor equilibrium dynamics. These feedback e�ects are key in this paper.

From a technical point of view, this paper expands the literature on continuous-timemacro-finance models, e.g., BruSan and Hansen et al. [2018], by considering (antic-ipated) aggregate jump risk. This is necessary to include systemic runs, and it istechnically challenging because aggregate jump risk breaks the key feature that makescontinuous-time models tractable: their focus on local perturbations.

2 Model

2.1 Environment

Let (�, F ,P) be a probability space that satisfies the usual conditions, and assumeall stochastic processes are adapted. The economy evolves in continuous time witht œ [0, Œ) and is populated by a continuum of banks and households as well as agovernment. There are two goods: the final consumption good and physical capital.

A. Technology

The production technology is linear and reflects that bankers are more e�cient thanhouseholds at managing capital. In particular, capital held by bankers produces

yt = akt

while households’ production function is yt = akt with a > a. In general, I use theunderbar notation for parameters and variables associated with the household sector.

Physical capital evolves according to2

dkt = (�(ÿt) ≠ ”) ktdt + ‡ktdZt , (1)

where ÿt is the investment per unit of capital, ” is the depreciation rate, ‡ > 0 is theexogenous volatility of capital growth, and Zt is a Brownian motion associated withcapital quality shocks. The investment technology allows for transforming ÿtkt units offinal goods into �(ÿt)kt units of capital. Function � represents technological illiquidityor adjustment costs and satisfies �(0) = 0, �Õ(0) = 1, �Õ(·) > 0, and �ÕÕ(·) < 0. The

2As is standard in the literature, this law of motion does not include capital purchases.

6

Page 8: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Brownian shock is the only source of exogenous aggregate uncertainty in the model. Ita�ects capital quantity but not its productivity, which can be motivated by stochasticdepreciation or news about capital quality. Further discussion follows in subsection 2.4.

B. Preferences

Preferences are symmetric for both types of agent. In particular, the utility that agentsobtain from a stochastic consumption path {ct}tØ0

is

E0

5⁄ Œ

0

e

≠flt log(ct)dt

6,

where fl is the preference discount rate.

C. Switching identities

Agents experience idiosyncratic Poisson shocks that switch their types, i.e., turn bankersinto households and viceversa. Let ⁄ be the intensity of the shock that turns bankersinto households and ⁄ be the intensity of the inverse process. These dynamics preventeither sector from taking over the entire wealth of the economy indefinitely and thereforeensure the existence of a non-degenerate stationary distribution.

D. Markets and financial friction

There are markets for physical capital and final goods. Deposit contracts are the onlyfinancial assets in this economy. A deposit contract ensures the repayment of principaland interest as long as the borrower remains solvent, and it transforms into a claimon borrowers’ assets in the case of default. Note that deposits held at di�erent banksare distinct assets because banks’ exposures to default and recovery values may di�er.The absence of equity markets represents a financial friction that can be motivated bya “skin in the game” constraint.

Also, I assume that banks that underperform with respect to their peers incur in aprohibitively high cost „ (measured in final goods). This allows me to focus on sym-metric equilibriums among banks. Further discussion of these assumptions is presentedin subsection 2.4.

E. Bank runs

Households are occasionally concerned about the soundness of banks. In particular,they “wake up” to consider whether or not to roll over their deposits according to aPoisson process Jt with arrival rate pt. The timing of events within the “dt period” isas follows.

7

Page 9: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

1. Households decide whether or not to roll over their deposits. Banks sell theirassets to repay deposits not rolled over. The liquidation price of capital is the oneat which capital can be sold at the end of the dt period.

2. Banks that are not able to fully repay deposits go into bankruptcy. Failed banks’assets are liquidated and the resources are used to pay depositors. Depositors whodecided not to roll over deposits are served first.3

3. Failed banks receive a small transfer, which is financed by taxes on the householdsector. This transfer allows them to resume operations.

4. Agents optimally rebalance their portfolios.

Whenever a bank run equilibrium is feasible, there is equilibrium multiplicity since theno-run equilibrium is always a possibility. I assume depositors coordinate on a bank runusing a sunspot Êt œ {0, 1}. If Êt = 1, then the run equilibrium is realized. This canbe interpreted as a panic among households. Since the no-run equilibrium is equivalentto households not evaluating the soundness of banks, the only relevant wake-up callsare the ones linked to panics, i.e., to a run equilibrium. I define the Poisson process Jt

associated with wake-up calls linked to panics as

dJt = {Êt=1}dJt

with arrival rate pt = Pr(Êt = 1)pt. In general, the probability of coordinating on arun equilibrium Pr(Êt = 1) can be a function of endogenous variables. From now on,I work with Poisson process Jt and later I discuss the equilibrium selection mechanismdirectly in terms of pt.

F. Transfer policy

Let TtKt be the total transfer from the household sector to banks that go bankrupt dueto a systemic run, where Kt is the aggregate capital in the economy and Tt is chosenby the government. The transfer is financed via taxes levied on households, and thegovernment runs a balanced budget at each point in time.

Taxes and transfers are proportional to the net worth agents had before the systemicrun in order to preserve tractability. Denote ·t as the transfer per unit of net worth to

3If depositors recover the same value independently of their rollover decision, they are always indif-ferent as to whether banks fail (no loss on deposits’ value) or not (recovery rate depends on liquidationvalue). There are several (o�-equilibrium) assumptions that break the indi�erence if the bank will fail.I assume sequential services in two stages: depositors who do not roll over deposits are paid before therest. Alternatively, I could assume that banks can divert a fraction of deposits that are rolled over justbefore collapse.

8

Page 10: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

banks and · t the tax per unit of net worth levied on households. The transfer can beinterpreted as a direct bailout of the banking sector or as recognition that banks areable to rescue some value after a collapse.

2.2 Agents’ problems

A. Debt rollover decision and run vulnerability

Liquidation value. The liquidation value of capital corresponds to the price of capitalafter a systemic run, i.e., the price when almost all capital is managed by unproductivehouseholds (except for the capital banks can acquire using the small transfer). I denotethe liquidation value of capital in terms of the numeraire (final goods) as qt≠.

I use notation zt≠ © lims¬t zs to refer to the value of variables just before a jump.4

The liquidation price is known before the uncertainty regarding the Poisson shock isunveiled. The liquidation price is equal to the capital price qt if the systemic run isrealized, i.e., qt≠ = qt if dJt = 1 and the economy is vulnerable to runs (see conditionbelow).

Debt rollover decision. If a bank is not able to meet its deposit obligations at theliquidation price for its assets, i.e.,

qt≠kt≠ < bt≠,

where bt≠ is the value of deposits at the bank and kt≠ are the banks’ capital hold-ings, then households decide not to roll over their deposits at this bank. In this case,households recover qt≠kt≠/bt≠ per deposit. If households had rolled over deposits, theywouldn’t have been able to recover any value from their deposits since there are no re-sources left after serving depositors who decided not to roll over deposits. Importantly,households are only willing to pay the liquidation value qt≠ to banks selling capital tomeet their deposit obligations. If this run condition is not met, then households rollover their deposits in this bank after the wake-up call.

The run condition can also be written in terms of the percentage loss on deposits incase of a run, i.e.,

¸

dt≠(kt≠, bt≠) ©

51 ≠ qt≠kt≠

bt≠

6+

> 0, (2)

where [·]+ © max {·, 0}. I use ¸

dt≠ to denote the loss on deposits evaluated at banks’

equilibrium portfolio (kt, bt). For convenience, also define the capital price drop following4This means zt≠ is measurable with respect to the filtration associated with {Zs, Js : s œ [0, t)}.

9

Page 11: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

a systemic run as¸

qt≠ © 1 ≠ qt≠

qt≠,

where qt is the contemporaneous capital price.

Run vulnerability. The liquidation price qt at which banks’ solvency is evaluatedassumes that the entire banking sector fails (and resumes operation only with the networth provided by the transfer). Therefore, consistency requires that this is indeed thecase, i.e., that all banks collapse in case of a run. This condition can be characterizedin terms of the aggregate percentage loss on deposits after a systemic run5

Ldt≠ ©

C

1 ≠ qt≠K

bt≠

Bt≠

D+

> 0,

where Bt is the aggregate value of deposits at the banking sector and K

bt represents

banks’ aggregate capital holdings.6 Systemic runs occur if and only if there is a wake-up call linked to a panic (dJt = 1) and the banking sector is su�ciently vulnerable(Ld

t≠ > 0).

Equilibrium selection mechanism. I assume

pt≠ = �(Ldt≠), (3)

where �(.) is continuous and satisfies �(0) = 0 and �Õ(·) Ø 0, i.e., households aremore likely to coordinate on the bank run equilibrium if potential losses for them arehigher. Note that Ld

t≠ is an aggregate variable, which cannot be influenced by anyindividual agent alone. The equilibrium selection mechanism chosen has a key role forwelfare analysis and numerical exercises, but qualitative features about joint dynamicsof instabilities will be independent from it. Further discussion about this assumption ispresented in subsection 2.4.

B. Households

Households choose their consumption rate ct, investment rate ÿt, capital holdings kt, anddeposits bt. Let nt denote a household’s net worth, which is the only individual statevariable for this problem.7 Also, let T be the stochastic arrival time of the idiosyncraticshock that turns a household into a bank. For a given ns, a household solves

5Given that in equilibrium all banks will choose the same portfolio, the average loss will be equal tothe individual loss of each agent.

6The formal definition of aggregate variables is provided in subsection 2.3.7The shock structure (capital quality shocks instead of productivity shocks) and the linear production

technology allow for reducing individual states from capital and deposits to only net worth.

10

Page 12: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

V s (ns) © max{ct,ÿtØ0,ktØ0,bt}T

s

Es

C⁄ T

se

≠fl(t≠s) log(ct)dt + VT (nT )D

(4)

s.t.

dnt = [(a ≠ ÿt) kt + rtbt ≠ ct] dt + d(qtkt)--d ˇJt=0

≠ {Ldt≠>0}

˸

dt≠bt≠ + ¸

qt≠qt≠kt≠ + · t≠nt≠

ÈdJt ’t Æ T

nt = qtkt + bt,

where Vt (.) is banks’ value function, defined below. The last term of the dynamic bud-get constraint represents the cost households bear in case of a systemic run: losseson deposits ¸

dt≠bt≠, on capital value ¸

qt≠qt≠kt≠, and taxes levied to bail out banks

· t≠nt≠. The other terms are standard and correspond to production net of invest-ment (a ≠ ÿt) kt, return on deposits rtbt, consumption expenditure ct and capital gainsabsent runs d(qtkt)

--dJt=0

.

For simplicity, this formulation assumes that all banks choose the same portfolio andtherefore there is a unique deposit contract available for households with return rt

conditional on no default. In general, deposits at banks with di�erent portfolios renderdi�erent returns, i.e., they are di�erent assets, because the portfolio determines therecovery rate of deposits in case of a run.

C. Banks

Banks choose their consumption rate ct, investment rate ÿt, capital holdings kt, and debtbt (deposits). Let nt denote the household’s net worth, which is the only individual statevariable for this problem. Also, let T be the stochastic arrival time of the shock thatturns the bank into a household. Given ns, a bank solves

Vs (ns) © max{ct,ÿtØ0,ktØ0,bt}T

s

Es

C⁄ T

se

≠fl(t≠s) log(ct)dt + V T (nT )D

(5)

s.t.

dnt = [(a ≠ ÿt) kt ≠ rt(kt, bt)bt ≠ ct] dt + d(qtkt)--d ˇJt=0

≠ {Ldt≠>0}

Ë{¸d

t≠(kt≠,bt≠)>0} (1 ≠ ·t≠) nt≠dJt + {¸dt≠(kt≠,bt≠)Æ0}„dt

È’t Æ T

nt = qtkt ≠ bt

The last term of the dynamic budget constraint is the one associated with runs, and itis relevant only if the economy is vulnerable to runs, i.e., Ld

t > 0. In these situations,

11

Page 13: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

the bank can choose a portfolio (kt, bt) that implies bankruptcy and losses for depositorsafter a systemic run, i.e., ¸

dt (kt, bt) > 0. In this case, a run wipes out the bank’s net worth

nt≠ but allows it to receive a transfer ·t≠nt≠. Alternatively, the bank can choose a safeportfolio that allows it to avoid bankruptcy in case the run is realized (¸d

t (kt, bt) Æ 0)and pay the underperforming cost „. A safe portfolio implies underperforming withrespect to banks choosing a risky portfolio and exposing the economy to a systemic run.

The other terms in the constraint are standard and analogous to that described for thehousehold. The only di�erence is that the banks’ portfolio decision a�ects the rate paidon deposits rt(kt, bt) because it influences the depositors’ loss rate in case of a run. Thisfunction needs to be consistent with households’ asset-pricing conditions.

2.3 Equilibrium

Notation. Denote the set of banks by the interval It = [0, ‹t] and index individualbanks by i œ It. Similarly, let the set of households be the interval Jt = (‹t, 2] and indexindividual households by j œ Jt. Let I be the interval including the index of all agentswho are banks at some point and J be the corresponding interval for households.8

The following notation is necessary because agents alternate types. Let T

un be the n

th

point in time in which agent u œ [0, 2] experiences an idiosyncratic shock that changeshis type. Define Bu © {[T u

n≠1

, T

un ] : u is a banker} as the set of all intervals in which

agent u is a banker, and denote an element of this set as Bum. Similarly, define set Hu

with elements Hum to be the set of time intervals in which the agent is a household. I

abuse notation and also use Bu = fimBum and Hu = fimHu

m.

Equilibrium definition.

9 Fix a transfer policy {Tt}. For any initial endowment ofcapital {k

i0

, k

j0

: i œ I0

, j œ J0

} such that⁄

I0k

itdi +

J0k

j0

dj = K

0

an equilibrium is a set of stochastic functions10 on the filtered probability space defined8The threshold ‹t captures the transition between types and satisfies d‹t = (⁄(1 ≠ ‹t) ≠ ⁄‹t) dt with

‹0 = 1. This representation assumes agents don’t know their own index so they cannot anticipatetheir switching time. It also assumes only net flows between agents type take place. Alternativerepresentations are possible, but imply reassigning indexes to keep intervals connected.

9The definition includes the symmetry assumptions embedded in agents’ problems. In particular,when defining the asset prices available to an agent type, it assumes a symmetric portfolio decision ofthe other one. This simplifies considerable notation and exposition.

10Stochastic functions on a probability space (�, F ,P) are mappings X : S ◊ � æ R such that X(s, .)is random variable ’s œ S. Stochastic processes are the special case where S = R+, which is usuallyinterpreted as time. In this definition,

)qt, qt, pt, ¸

dt

*are stochastic processes, but other objects are

associated with di�erent definitions of S: {Vt(·), V t(·)} with S = R2,{rt(·)} with S = R3, {c

it, ÿ

it, x

it≠}

with S = Bi, and {c

jt , ÿ

jt , x

jt≠} with S = Hj .

12

Page 14: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

by aggregate shocks {Zt, Jt : t Ø 0}: capital price {qt} and liquidation value {qt}, depositrate function {rt(·)}, losses function {¸

dt }, arrival intensity {pt}, transfers and taxes

{·t, · t}, households’ decisions {c

jt , ÿ

jt , k

jt , b

jt}tœHj and value function {V

jt (·)} for j œ J,

and banks’ decisions {c

it, ÿ

it, k

jt , b

jt }tœBi and value function {V

it (·)} for i œ I such that

1. Initial net worths satisfy n

i0

= q

0

k

i0

and n

j0

= q

0

k

0

for all i œ I0

and j œ J0

.

2. Agents optimize

(a) Households: Given stochastic functionsÓ

qt, qt, rt, ¸

dt , pt, V

it (·)

Ô, decisions {c

jt , ÿ

jt , k

jt , b

jt}

tœHjm

solve households’ problem for all j œ J, Hjm œ Hj .

(b) Banks: Given stochastic functions {qt, qt, rt(·), pt, V

jt (·)}, decisions {c

it, ÿ

it, k

jt , b

jt }tœBi

m

solve banks’ problem for all i œ I, Bim œ Bj .

3. Markets clear

(a) Goods⁄

It

c

itdi+

Jt

c

jtdj +„ {Ld

t >0}⁄

It¸d

t (kjt ,bj

t )<0

di =⁄

It

(a≠ÿ

it)ki

tdi+⁄

Jt

(a≠ÿ

jt )kj

t dj

(b) Capital ⁄

It

k

itdi

¸ ˚˙ ˝©Kb

t

+⁄

Jt

k

jtdj

¸ ˚˙ ˝©Kt

= Kt

(c) Deposits ⁄

It

b

itdi =

Jt

b

jtn

jtdj

4. The law of motion of aggregate capital is

dKt =3⁄

It

�(ÿit)ki

tdi +⁄

Jt

�(ÿjt )kj

tdi ≠ ”Kt

4dt + ‡KtdZt

5. Consistency conditions:

• Value functions {V

it (·), V

jt (·)} are consistent with agents’ optimal decisions,

i.e., they satisfy (4) and (5).

• Deposit rate function rt(kt, bt) is consistent with asset-pricing conditions ofhouseholds.

• Arrival intensity of Poisson process {pt} is consistent with the selection mech-anism chosen.

• Liquidation value {qt} is consistent with the capital price process {qt}, i.e.qt≠ = qt if {Ld

t≠>0}dJt = 1.

13

Page 15: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

6. Total transfers are consistent with the government’s policy and its budget is bal-anced

TtKt = ·t

It

n

itdi = · t

Jt

n

jtdj

2.4 Discussion of assumptions

Productivity di�erence. Banks’ higher productivity captures the advantage that thebanking sector has in allocating resources to productive agents. It summarizes the realcontribution of the financial sector to the economy. Ideally, the banking sector wouldintermediate all resources to achieve the most e�cient allocation.

Capital quality shocks. The model features shocks to the quantity of capital instead ofthe more standard productivity shocks. This assumption is made for tractability andis typical in the macro-finance literature. This formulation together with the linearityof the production function allows the economy to scale with the capital stock; i.e., itreduces the state space by eliminating the aggregate capital stock as a state variable.An interpretation is that capital is measured in e�ciency units and the shocks are newsabout its quality. A positive capital quality shock behaves similarly to a very persistentpositive productivity shock that induces a higher utilization rate.

Financial friction. The financial friction is that agents cannot issue equity to raisefunds. This can be thought of as a limited case of a “skin in the game” constraint,which can be microfounded by an agency problem in which banks are able to divert afraction of asset returns at the expense of households (see, for example, BruSan). Dueto this constraint, markets are incomplete, so agents cannot write contracts conditionalon the aggregate capital quality shock. Market incompleteness links the allocation ofproductive resources to the allocation of risk since agents need to bear the risk associatedwith capital in order to use it for production.

Cost of underperforming the market. If the economy is exposed to systemic runs, banks’portfolio choices will have two local maxima: 1) one that exploits excess returns butexposes them to bankruptcy in case the run is realized, and 2) one that allows them tosurvive a run but forgo high contemporaneous excess returns. Given that systemic runsare rare events, consistently choosing the second investment strategy implies under-performing the market for a prolonged period, e.g., 40 years with baseline parameters.The cost of underperformance captures the fact that no asset manager can stay in hisjob long following such a strategy. Recent history is replete with examples of financialinstitutions that have chosen to underperform the market while waiting for a large col-lapse but were not able to sustain the strategy long enough, such as Tiger Managementfunds11 during the dot-com bubble.

11In March 2000, Tiger Management LLC closed its six hedge funds after poor return performances

14

Page 16: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

The underperformance cost does not force the economy to be exposed to systemic runs.It simply allows me to focus on symmetric equilibria among banks. Absent this cost,the economy would be exposed to runs in the same situations, but only a fraction ofthe banking sector would fail after a run.

Transfer policy. The transfer policy ensures that, after a bankruptcy, banks are ableto recover some value at the expense of their creditors. This policy allows banks to beincluded in the welfare analysis since the obvious alternative is that, after a systemic run,some banks’ wealth drops to zero, leading to a minus infinity value for utility. A commonsolution is to assign an arbitrary utility value in these situations, e.g., assuming thatbankers die and their continuation payo� is zero. This is not suitable with an endogenousarrival intensity of the death event, since the arbitrary value influences the preferenceranking between situations with di�erent exposures to such a event. Alternatively, onecan focus on households for welfare analysis and disregard the transfer policy, i.e., setT = 0.12

Equilibrium selection mechanism. The dependence of the selection mechanism on theaggregate average loss of deposits relates the fundamental that determines the existenceof a run equilibrium to the likelihood such an equilibrium would be realized. This followsthe spirit of global games which application would deliver the probability of a run as afunction of the relevant fundamental without the necessity of a sunspot.13 Importantly,for a systemic run to be self-fulfilling, it needs to generate a drop in asset prices, whichcannot be influenced by individual decisions. This implies that the relevant fundamentalneeds to be an aggregate variable. The approach follows work by GK. Welfare resultsdepend on this assumption, but qualitative results about joint dynamics of risk do not.

3 Recursive equilibrium solution

A. Aggregate state

As mentioned before, the shock structure and the linear production function eliminatecapital k as a state variable (scale invariant) for each individual household and bank.Therefore, the only individual state variable of an agent’s problem is his net worth. So,in general, the aggregate state of this economy will be the distribution of net worth.Fortunately, the state space of this economy can be simplified to a single aggregate statevariable. First, all agents’ decisions will be linear in their net worth, which makes thethat followed from staying out of Internet and technology stocks. Julian H. Robertson, manager andco-founder, correctly anticipated the collapse to come but could not stay in business long enough toprofit from his prediction.

12In this case, the o�-equilibrium cost of underperforming would need to diverge toward infinity.13A direct application of global games in this model is not pursued due to technical complications.

15

Page 17: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

net worth heterogeneity within sectors irrelevant. In other words, it reduces the set ofaggregate states to banks’ aggregate net worth Nt and households’ aggregate net worthN t. Second, I can instead use total capital in the economy Kt and the net worth shareof banks

÷t © Nt

N t + Nt

as states of the economy. The reason is that capital is the only asset in positive netsupply, and therefore aggregate net worth is equal to the total value of the capitalstock. Third, I can dispense with Kt as an aggregate state because allocations (scaledby capital) do not depend on the level of the capital stock. This result follows from thelinear production technology and the linearity of decisions in net worth. To summarize,the only aggregate state is the banking sector’s wealth share ÷t.

From now on, I switch to recursive notation, i.e., time subindexes are suppressed. Allequilibrium objects are functions of the aggregate state of the economy ÷, but thisdependence is left implicit. Also, I denote by z the value that variable z would take ifthe sunspot were realized when the aggregate state is ÷, i.e., z = z(÷(÷)), where ÷(÷) isbanks’ wealth share just after a systemic run is realized.

B. Risks

The economy is subject to two di�erent types of aggregate risk. The first one correspondsto the exogenous real shock and its propagation mechanism. In this case, the riskmeasure associated with a variable of interest is its sensitivity to that shock, which Irefer to as total di�usion risk or di�usion volatility. This risk can be decomposedinto an exogenous component and an endogenous one. The former represents the directe�ect of the shock absent any change in the behavior of agents, while the latter isthe additional sensitivity generated by agents’ endogenous responses, which generatesamplification. For concreteness, I refer to these components as exogenous risk andamplification risk, respectively. Note that these risks are defined with respect to avariable of interest, e.g., returns on capital or output growth.

The second type of aggregate risk corresponds to vulnerabilities that arise due to thesystem’s internal dynamics without any real exogenous impulse, e.g., systemic runs.This type of risk can materialize whenever the economy is su�ciently fragile. In thecase of runs, this fragility is captured by the losses depositors would experience in casea run is realized, and it manifests through the arrival rate of runs.14 I refer to the latteras run risk, and it constitutes a risk measure not associated with a particular variable

14In fact, losses for depositors and the arrival rate of runs are positively related through the equi-librium selection mechanism chosen. As discussed before, this assumption is natural since it links thevulnerability’s determinant with the likelihood of the risk being realized.

16

Page 18: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

of interest. Of course, the sensitivity of a variable with respect to the realization of therun is also informative about the risk a run represents, but I focus the discussion on thethe arrival rate of runs.

Importantly, the two types of risks are qualitatively di�erent. While exogenous realshocks are small and frequent, systemic runs are rare events that occur suddenly andhave a discrete impact on real and financial variables. Continuous time allows the modelto sharply distinguish between these two types of risk by associating real shocks to adi�usion process and systemic runs to a jump process.

C. Capital price and returns

Poisson process. To alleviate notation, from now on I work with Poisson process Jt thatcaptures the realization of systemic runs. Runs require a panic wake-up call dJt = 1and a vulnerable economy Ld

> 0, i.e. dJt = {Ld>0}dJt. The associated arrival rate isp = {Ld>0}p. Note that the selection mechanism considered implies pt = pt = �(Ld)because �(0) = 0.

Physical capital. Return on capital managed by banks is

dr

k © (a ≠ ÿ) k

qk¸ ˚˙ ˝dividend

dt + d(qk)qk¸ ˚˙ ˝

capital gains

, (6)

where the first term represents capital’s dividend yield net of investment and the secondterm is the capital gains rate, which includes price and capital quantity fluctuations.Returns on capital managed by households, dr

k, are defined analogously using theirlower productivity a and corresponding investment rate ÿ.

Given the uncertainty driving the economy, I conjecture the following dynamics for thecapital price process

dq

q

= µ

qdt + ‡

qdZt ≠ ¸

qdJt, (7)

where µ

qt is the capital price growth conditional on no aggregate shocks, ‡

q is thesensitivity of the capital price growth to the aggregate capital quality shock dZt, and¸

q is the percentage loss on capital value when a bank run is realized. {µ

q, ‡

q, ¸

q} areendogenous objects, i.e., functions of the aggregate state. Liquidation value correspondsto q = q(÷) = q(÷) (1 ≠ ¸

q(÷)).

Then, using capital evolution (1), capital return for banks can be written as

dr

k = µ

Rdt + ( ‡¸˚˙˝

exogenous

+ ‡

q¸˚˙˝

amplification¸ ˚˙ ˝difussion risk

) dZt¸˚˙˝real shock

≠ ¸

q¸˚˙˝loss

dJt¸˚˙˝runs

(8)

17

Page 19: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

whereµ

R © a ≠ ÿ

q

+ �(ÿ) ≠ ” + µ

q + ‡‡

q,

The expected return conditional on no aggregate shocks, µ

R, includes a dividend com-ponent (first term) and deterministic capital gains. The latter are associated withdeterministic quantity gains �(ÿ) ≠ ”, deterministic price gains µ

q, and the interactionbetween unexpected quantity and price gains (Ito’s term, related to the nonlinearity ofvalue = price ◊ quantity).

The dynamics of capital return show the di�erent risks discussed above. In this economy,the exogenous aggregate shocks are the capital quality shocks, dZt, and the endogenousaggregate shocks are the bank runs coordinated by Poisson shocks dJt. Total di�usionrisk of capital returns, |‡ + ‡

q|, includes exogenous risk, ‡, and amplification risk,‡

q. The former represents the sensitivity of capital quantity to the shock, while thelatter represents the sensitivity of capital price. Given that ‡ > 0, the price responseamplifies the e�ect of the initial shock on returns whenever a price increase follows apositive quality shock, i.e., ‡

q> 0.15 If the economy experiences a systemic run, i.e.

dJt = 1, total capital value decreases proportionally to the percentage price drop ¸

q

because there is no e�ect on quantity (no direct real e�ect).

The capital returns (in the absence of shocks) obtained by households are identicalto those obtained by banks in terms of capital gains, but the dividend component isdi�erent due to a lower productivity and a potentially di�erent investment rate, i.e.,

µ

R © a ≠ ÿ

q

+ �(ÿ) ≠ ” + µ

q + ‡‡

q.

D. Consumption and real investment

Consumption. Optimal consumption for both agents is proportional to their wealth,i.e.,

c

n

= c

n

= fl. (9)

Logarithmic preferences imply that consumption decisions are independent of assetreturns.

Investment. The return on capital for both agents is maximized by choosing the invest-ment rate that solves

maxÿ

q�(ÿ) ≠ ÿ.

15The literature focuses on the equilibrium that exhibits amplification, i.e., ‡

q> 0, but there is

another one where capital price movements hedge real shocks, i.e., ‡

q< 0. Mendo [2018] discusses

hedging equilibrium in financial frictions models.

18

Page 20: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

The first-order condition q�Õ(ÿ) = 1 (marginal Tobin’s Q) equates the marginal benefitof investment (extra capital �Õ(ÿ) times its price q) with its marginal cost (a unit of finalgoods). The concavity of adjustment cost �(·) implies that investment is an increasingfunction of the price of capital (if ÿ > 0), which can be written as

ÿ = ÿ =5�Õ≠1

31q

46+

¸ ˚˙ ˝©ÿ(q)

. (10)

The investment decision is a completely static problem (it only depends on the currentcapital price) because the investment process has no delays.

D. Households’ portfolio decision

Capital portfolio share. The portfolio decisions, i.e., capital holdings kt and deposits bt,can be summarized by the capital portfolio share x © qk

n . Given x and individual staten, capital holdings are k = xn/q and deposits b = (1 ≠ x)n. Also, note that ¸

d(k, b)presented in equation (2) can be written in terms of x alone as

¸

d(x) =51 ≠ q(÷)

q

3x

x ≠ 1

46+

. (11)

The optimal portfolio share of capital for households x satisfies

µ

R ≠ r Æ x (‡ + ‡q)2

¸ ˚˙ ˝di�usion risk compensation

+ p

��

q ≠ ¸

d2

¸ ˚˙ ˝run risk compensation

, (12)

where � © c

≠1 = fln

≠1 denotes household’s stochastic discount factor. The LHS is themarket excess return (conditional on no aggregate shocks) of capital over deposits andthe RHS is the compensation for risk required by the households to hold capital. Ifx > 0, the condition holds with equality and the excess return needs to compensate fordi�usion risk and run risk.

Both compensations can be expressed as risk price times risk quantity. The prices of allrisks are associated with the agent’s stochastic discount factor. In the case of di�usionrisk, the price is measured by the sensitivity of the agent’s net worth to this risk, i.e.x(‡ + ‡

q), while its quantity is the sensitivity of the asset return to di�usion risk, i.e.,‡ + ‡

q. In the case of run risk, the price is the arrival rate of the run p times a measureof the drop in net worth when a run is realized, i.e.,

�� = n

n

=11 ≠ ¸

d ≠ x(¸q ≠ ¸

d) ≠ ·

2≠1

19

Page 21: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

while the quantity of risk is the excess loss of capital over deposits, i.e., ¸

q ≠ ¸

d. Thefollowing lemma provides a formal characterization of households’ portfolio decision.

Lemma 1. Household’s optimal capital portfolio share is

x = 12

51x

nr + x

th2

≠Ò

(xth ≠ x

nr)2 + 4p(‡ + ‡

q)≠2

6+

, (13)

where x

nr = µR≠r

(‡+‡q)

2 is the optimal portfolio decision absent runs, i.e. p = 0, and x

th =1≠¸d≠·¸q≠¸d is the threshold capital share above which the household’s net worth collapses

to zero in case of a systemic run. Moreover, x Æ min{x

nr, x

th}. Households’ capitaldemand is decreasing in the run intensity p, di�usion volatility |‡ +‡

q|, and capital loss¸

q.

Pricing of deposits. Recall that the recovery value of a bank’s deposits depends on thecomposition of its portfolio. In equilibrium, households have access to a unique typeof deposit because all banks choose the same portfolio; however, banks need to knowhow households would price deposits if they were to choose a di�erent portfolio. Theasset-pricing condition for a bank’s portfolio with capital share x can be written as

r(x) ≠ r

f = p

��¸

d(x), (14)

where r

f © ≠EË

d�

Èis the return households require for a risk-free asset. The spread of

deposits over the risk-free rate needs to compensate households for the run risk and isincreasing in the likelihood of the run p, the net worth drop �/�, and the loss rate ondeposits ¸

d(x). An intuitive derivation of this condition follows from including a risk-free asset with return r

f and a deposit with return r(x) and loss ¸

d(x) in households’problem.

E. Banks’ portfolio decision

Capital portfolio share for banks is x © qkn . Given x and the individual state n, capital

holdings are given by k = xn/q and debt (deposits) by b = (x ≠ 1)n. The optimalportfolio share for banks satisfies

µ

R ≠ r (x) = x (‡ + ‡q)2

¸ ˚˙ ˝di�usion risk compensation

+ (x ≠ 1)rÕ (x)¸ ˚˙ ˝

increase in deposits’ cost

. (15)

The LHS is the market excess return (conditional on no aggregate shocks) of capitalover deposits and the RHS is the excess return required by households in order to holdcapital. The logic behind the compensation for di�usion risk is analogous to that in

20

Page 22: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

the case of households. Recall that banks’ portfolio decisions influence the deposit ratethey need to pay households due to their e�ect on potential losses for depositors. Thecompensation for the increase in the cost of deposits is the marginal increase in thedeposit rate, r

Õ (x) > 0, times the portfolio share of deposits, (x ≠ 1).

The first-order condition presented assumes that the cost of underperforming „ is largeenough, i.e., it satisfies condition (32) in Appendix A. When the economy is exposedto runs, the optimization with respect to capital’s portfolio share features two localmaxima: a safe one that implies no failure after a systemic run, and a risky one thattriggers bankruptcy if the systemic run is realized. In the absence of a cost „ > 0 ofunderperforming the market, this feature can imply an asymmetric equilibrium amongbanks, i.e., one in which a fraction of banks choose the optimal risky portfolio and therest choose the optimal safe one. Choosing the optimal safe portfolio implies underper-forming the market and assuming the corresponding cost. The assumption regardingthe cost „ rules out the safe portfolio choice. The following lemma characterizes theoptimal portfolio decision.

Lemma 2. For a su�ciently large underperforming cost „, banks’ optimal portfolioweight on capital x satisfies

x = 1(‡ + ‡

q)2

C

µ

R ≠ r

f ≠ p

��¸

q

D

. (16)

banks’ capital demand is decreasing in the run intensity p, capital loss ¸

q, and di�usionvolatility |‡ + ‡

q|. A su�ciently large underperforming cost is defined by equation (32)in Appendix A.

F. Wealth dynamics

Evolution of aggregate state. Agents’ decisions, i.e., on capital, investment, andconsumption, are linear in their net worth. Therefore, aggregation is immediate. Thedynamics of household and banking sector net worths are

dN

N

= dn

n

≠ ⁄ + N

N

and

dN

N

= dn

n

≠ ⁄ + N

N

⁄,

respectively. The only di�erence between the evolution of a sector’s net worth andthat of an individual agent within that sector comes from the Poisson type-switching

21

Page 23: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

processes. The following lemma characterizes the evolution of the aggregate state inthe economy.

Lemma 3. The banking sector’s wealth share dynamics are

÷

= µ÷dt + ‡÷dZt ≠ ¸÷dJt,

where

÷µ÷ = ÷(1 ≠ ÷)Ëx

R ≠ r

2≠ x

R ≠ r

2È≠ ÷‡÷(‡ + ‡q) + ⁄(1 ≠ ÷) ≠ ⁄÷ (17)

÷‡÷ = ÷(1 ≠ ÷)(x ≠ x)(‡ + ‡q) (18)

÷¸÷ = 1 ≠ ÷ (19)

and ÷(÷) represents the wealth share of banks after a systemic run and satisfies

÷q(÷) = T (20)

whenever p > 0.

These dynamics determine the ergodic distribution of the share of wealth held by banks.Importantly, the dynamics are mainly driven by the portfolio decisions x and x. Absentthe realization of any shocks, i.e. considering just the drift of ÷, the wealth share ofbanks moves according to 1) the di�erence in portfolio expected returns, i.e., sharetimes market excess return x

R ≠ r

2, 2) an adjustment term due to the nonlinearity

of wealth share as a function of the wealth levels of each sector, ÷‡÷(‡ + ‡q), and 3) thetype-switching processes.

The wealth share of banks is exposed to capital quality shocks as long as agents choosedi�erent portfolio shares. In particular, if banks choose a larger capital portfolio sharethan households, a positive capital quality shock increases their wealth share. Theimpact depends on the sensitivity of returns: it includes the direct quantity e�ect andthe amplification e�ect on the price of capital. The condition that determines the wealthshare after a systemic run (20) establishes that banks’ new wealth share ÷ is equal tothe banking sector’s new wealth T K divided by the new value of total wealth q(÷)K.

G. Markov Equilibrium

Market clearing. For convenience, define  © x÷ as the capital share managed bybanks. Also, since capital is the only asset in positive net supply in this economy, totalwealth in the economy is qK = N + N .

22

Page 24: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Market clearing for goods (scaled by total capital) can be written as16

flq + ÿ(q) = Âa + (1 ≠ Â)a, (21)

where the LHS represents aggregate demand, and the RHS is aggregate supply. Thefirst term on the left is aggregate consumption, which is a constant fraction fl timestotal wealth qK, and the second term represents aggregate investment ÿ(q)K. Totalproduction per unit of capital is equal to agents’ productivities weighted by the shareof capital that they manage.

Market clearing for capital (scaled by total wealth) is

x÷ + x(1 ≠ ÷) = 1, (22)

where xN = x÷qK is total wealth invested in capital by banks, and xN = x(1 ≠ ÷)qK

is the corresponding quantity for households.

Consistency. Capital price dynamics need to be consistent with the dynamics of theaggregate state, i.e.

qµq = q÷µ÷ + 12q÷÷ (‡÷÷)2 (23)

q‡q = q÷‡÷÷ (24)

¸

q = 1 ≠ q(÷)q

(25)

These conditions follow from applying Ito’s lemma to function q(÷). Also, the equi-librium loss on deposits in case of a run needs to be consistent with banks’ portfoliodecision x and capital price dynamics, i.e., equation (11) has to hold. Finally, run in-tensity needs to be consistent with depositors’ average losses in case of a systemic run,i.e., equation (3) evaluated at Ld = ¸

d or

p = �(¸d). (26)

Markov equilibrium. Given an exogenous transfer policy T (÷), an equilibrium is aset of functions of banks’ share of net worth ÷ for prices {q, µq, ‡q, ¸

q, r, ¸

d}, allocations{c/n, (c/n), ÿ, ÿ}, portfolio decisions {x, x}, run intensity {p}, and the dynamics of banks’wealth share {µ÷, ‡÷, ¸÷, ÷} such that

• Agents optimize. Given prices, allocations and portfolio decisions solve the agents’problem: (9), (10), (12), and (16).

16The market clearing conditions for goods assumes that no bank pays the underperforming cost inequilibrium.

23

Page 25: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

• Markets clear: (21) and (22).

• The dynamics of the aggregate state are consistent with optimal decisions: (17) ≠(20).

• Capital price dynamics are consistent with the dynamics of the aggregate state:(23) ≠ (25).

• Depositors’ losses are consistent with banks’ portfolio choices and capital pricedynamics: (11).

• Run intensity is consistent with depositors’ losses: (26).

Value functions. The Markov equilibrium definition does not include agents’ valuefunctions but they are necessary for welfare analysis. The following lemma characterizesthem.

Lemma 4. The value function for a bank with individual net worth n can be written as

V (n; ÷) = v(÷) + 1fl

log(K) + 1fl

log3

n

N

4(27)

while the corresponding value for a household with individual net worth n is

V (n; ÷) = v(÷) + 1fl

log(K) + 1fl

log3

n

N

4, (28)

where v(÷) and v(÷) satisfy functional equations (35) and (34) in Appendix A, respec-tively.

The first term in (27) is the indirect utility (scaled by total capital) of a banker thatowns the entire sector’s net worth, i.e., n = N , and it is the relevant welfare measurediscussed below. The second term is the adjustment for aggregate capital level andcaptures the non-stationary component of the value function since the economy is con-stantly growing. The third term represents a simple adjustment to consider the wealthshare of the agent within the sector. If there were no switching identity shocks, i.e.,⁄ = ⁄ = 0, the latter would be a constant. In general, it is time-varying but its dynam-ics are taken into account by v(÷). The description of the value function for householdsis completely analogous.

H. Numerical approach

The Markov equilibrium defines a functional equation for q(÷). Given the presence ofjumps, this functional equation is not an ODE, as is the case in basically all continuous-time macroeconomic models in the literature. Besides {q(÷), q

Õ(÷), q

ÕÕ(÷)}, the functional

24

Page 26: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

equation also includes q(÷(÷)), the capital price if a systemic run were to arrive at state÷. Importantly, the post-run banks’ wealth share ÷(÷) is endogenous to the system.There is no general approach to solving this class of functional equations.

The key to the two-step numerical approach I implement is that a subset of equilibriumconditions defines a standard ODE for capital price. In particular, it is possible find amap from {÷, q(÷)} to q

Õ(÷) that is independent from non-local changes {÷(÷), q(÷(÷))}.The first step is to solve this ODE. Given function q(÷), the second step is to solve for÷(÷). Finally, all other equilibrium objects are recovered from these two functions. Dueto logarithmic preferences, the equilibrium definition does not include value functions, sothe numerical procedure does not require iterations. Given the solution for the Markovequilibrium, I use an iterative approach to solve for the value functions. I also develop anumerical strategy to solve for the stationary distribution of the state variable withoutresorting to simulations. The details of the numerical implementation are discussed inAppendix B.

Importantly, the numerical procedures to solve for the Markov equilibrium, the valuefunctions, and the stationary distribution of the state variable are su�ciently fast tobe embedded into an optimization procedure. This makes it possible to implement adirect numerical approach to welfare analysis.

I. Baseline Parameters

The exposition of results combines theoretical insights and numerical illustrations, so Ibriefly discuss the baseline parametrization summarized in Table 1. I use a logarithmicadjustment cost function, �(ÿ) = log(Ÿÿ + 1)/Ÿ , and a linear function for the sunspotarrival rate, �(¸d) = “

¸¸

d. Time is measured in years. I use a standard value forthe discount rate fl (2 percent) and a slightly low value for the depreciation rate ” (3percent) given that capital quality shocks are similar to persistent productivity shockswith endogenous capital utilization, i.e., depreciation increases during booms since themodel measures capital in e�ciency units. The Poisson arrival rate for the transitionfrom households to banks ⁄ could be set to zero, but I choose a positive small number(1 percent) to prevent the economy from becoming trapped near ÷ = 0 due to lowvolatility. The choice of a nonzero value for ⁄ can be viewed as conservative in that itreduces the importance of bank runs for welfare. I also set the total transfer T to asmall number (0.1 percent of total capital).

For the set of parameters {a, a, ‡, Ÿ}, I match the set of moments presented in Table 1at the stochastic steady state, i.e., at the point in the state space at which the economyconverges absent any shocks. The moments in the data are calculated using U.S. datafor the post-World War II period, except for the largest drop in asset prices, which I

25

Page 27: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

set to 30 percent. The last two parameters require information about the dynamics invulnerable regions and are therefore matched using the entire stationary distribution.The rate ⁄ at which banks become households targets a conservative leverage estimateof 5. Larger values of leverage translate into a larger fraction of time spent in vulnerableregions. Finally, the sensitivity of the arrival rate of runs to potential losses in depositvalue “

¸ is set so that runs happen on average once every 40 years. This paper focuseson mechanisms, so I provide robustness exercises for numerical illustrations but leavemore ambitious quantitative exercises to less stylized models.

Table 1: Baseline parameters

Parameter Value Moment Target Model

Depreciation rate ” 0.03 – – –Discount rate fl 0.02 – – –

Transition hh æ banks ⁄ 0.01 – – –Transfer after run T 0.001 – – –

Stochastic steady state

Productivity banks a 0.125 Investment/Capital 8.8% 8.8%Productivity hh a 0.058 Max. price drop 30% 29%

Exogenous volatility ‡ 0.023 GDP growth volatility 2.31% 2.31%Inv. adjustment costs Ÿ 10.19 GDP growth 3.24% 3.24%

Including vulnerable regions

Transition banks æ hh ⁄ 0.047 Financial sector leverage 5 5Eq. selectionmechanism “

¸ 0.742 Run probability 2.5% 2.5%

4 Instabilities

The full dynamic solution allows me to address the following economic questions aboutthe di�erent forms of risk: 1) when is the economy more vulnerable to real shocks? 2)is this vulnerability a�ected by the possibility or realization of rare collapses such assystemic runs? 3) can the economy be exposed to systemic runs when real shocks arenot amplified and volatility is limited? (iv) if so, how do we identify this hidden risk?and 5) is the economy prone to spending large periods of time exposed to systemic runsand/or amplification of real shocks?

The economy is faced with two endogenous instabilities. First, the response to realshocks is larger than the exogenous fundamental impulse due to the presence of en-dogenous amplification risk. Second, the economy is exposed to systemic runs, which

26

Page 28: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

trigger collapses in output and asset prices and propel the economy to an unstableregime characterized by large amplification risk and occasional runs.

These two risks vary in distinct ways according to the key endogenous state variable:the wealth share of the banking sector. Amplification risk, which operates throughchanges in misallocation, is present when this share is su�ciently low to prevent banksfrom holding all capital in the economy due to the large risk exposure it would involve.In contrast, run risk manifests in the intermediate region of banks’ wealth share anddepends on potential losses for depositors. The economy is shielded from runs if banks’wealth share is too high because their balance sheets are sound in these situations. Runrisk is also absent for exceptionally low levels of the state variable because of low assetprices, i.e., small potential price drops.

The distinct dynamics of the two instabilities unveil a hidden risk regime in whichvolatility of macroeconomic and financial variables is low due to the absence of ampli-fication, yet the economy is exposed to sudden collapses because of runs. In order todistinguish this regime from a truly safe low-volatility environment, it is necessary toconsider a set of indicators that can flag the economy’s vulnerabilities, i.e., a risk to-pography. The model suggests the following as indicators of run risk: the joint presenceof high asset prices and a highly (or, at least, moderately) levered banking sector, highexcess returns per unit of measured volatility, and a low risk-free rate.

There is a sharp contrast between the feedback among the two forms of endogenousrisk. The presence of amplification risk ‡

q induces banks to lower their leverage inequilibrium, which lowers the economy’s exposure to systemic runs. In contrast, thearrival rate of systemic runs p or the losses they generate, ¸

q, have no influence on banks’equilibrium risk taking.

The system frequently visits the crisis and hidden risk regimes. In fact, absent ag-gregate shocks, the economy gravitates toward the hidden risk regime for the baselineparameter configuration. Furthermore, the economy passes through the crisis regimewhile recovering from systemic runs.

A. Financial and macroeconomic amplification risk

The exposition focuses on the e�ect of amplification risk on capital returns due tofluctuations in asset prices as presented in equation (8). In this model, the volatility ofasset prices translates into volatility of output due to the financial accelerator mechanismdiscussed below. Therefore, the amplification ‡

q that a�ects asset returns is also amacroeconomic risk, not just a financial one. In order to emphasize this point, I alsodiscuss results in terms of output growth.

27

Page 29: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Let Y © yK © (Â(a ≠ a) + a) K represent total output in the economy. Then itsdynamics can be written as

dY

Y≠© µ

Ydt + ( ‡¸˚˙˝

exogenous

+ ‡

y¸˚˙˝

amplification¸ ˚˙ ˝di�usive volatility

) dZt¸˚˙˝real shock

≠ ¸

Y¸˚˙˝loss

dJt¸˚˙˝runs

,

where ‡

y is the amplification associated with changes in allocative e�ciency. Changesin the fraction of capital allocated to banks  are directly related to the price of capitalin equilibrium through (21). The following lemma characterizes the equilibrium relationbetween the amplification risk a�ecting capital returns and output growth.

Lemma 5. Amplification risk of output growth ‡

y can be written as ‡

y = Áy,q‡

q, whereÁy,q > 0 represents the elasticity of aggregate demand (per unit of capital), i.e., y

d ©flq + ÿ(q), with respect to capital price.

B. Amplification risk

Amplification risk for capital return dr

k corresponds to fluctuations in capital price ‡

q

generated by the real shock driving the economy. Given that shocks in this economyare to the quantity of capital and not to its productivity, a unit of capital always hasthe same productive capacity. Then, an e�cient allocation would imply a constantcapital price, i.e., any fluctuation in capital price in response to the real shock operatesthrough the internal dynamics of the system. In particular, these changes follow fromportfolio adjustments due to precautionary motives, which vary with the state of thesystem. This translates into state-dependent amplification risk despite a constant levelof exogenous risk ‡.

The financial accelerator mechanism behind amplification was initially identified in KMand BGG, and the dynamics of this endogenous risk are discussed in BruSan using asimilar model but without considering systemic runs. My main interest lies in the e�ectof run risk on the financial accelerator mechanism and amplification dynamics.

(i) Invariance to run risk

The following proposition shows that run risk has no e�ect on amplification risk in thiseconomy.

Proposition 1. Amplification risk ‡

q is independent of the presence of run risk. Thatis, it is independent of the feasibility of a run equilibrium, the sunspot arrival ratefunction �(·), and the potential losses associated with its realization ¸

q. Moreover, theequilibrium capital allocation  and capital price q are also independent of run risk.

28

Page 30: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

The amplification mechanism crucially depends on banks’ leverage x (assets to networth). Given that capital is the asset with the largest value drop in a systemic run, itshould be expected that agents’ capital demand decreases when the economy is exposedto runs. Lemmas 1 and 2 show that this is indeed the case. However, the key determi-nant of amplification risk is the change in banks’ capital demand relative to households’,which turns out to be invariant with respect to run risk. Simple manipulation of optimalportfolio conditions (12), (15), and (14) delivers an illustration of the independence ofcapital allocation with respect to runs, i.e.,

x ≠ x Æ3

a ≠ a

q

4 1(‡ + ‡

q)2

with equality for x > 0. The excess capital demand of banks x ≠ x depends on theirexcess return due to the productivity advantage (a ≠ a)/q, and the risk associated withreal shocks ‡ + ‡

q, but not on run risk. Recall both agents require excess compensationdue to run risk: households because capital losses exceed those on deposits, and banksdue to the increase in the cost of deposits. The last equation implies that these excesscompensations are the same.

There are two reasons to expect that banks’ capital demand decreases more than house-holds due to run risk. First, runs a�ect banks more than households since they prac-tically wipe out all their net worth and therefore they should be less willing to exposethemselves. Second, it is precisely banks’ leverage decision that exposes the economyto systemic runs. However, neither line of reasoning is correct. Regarding the former,banks do not bear losses beyond bankruptcy due to limited liability, meaning marginalchanges in banks’ portfolio choices do not a�ect their net worth after a run. Regardingthe latter, systemic runs depend on aggregate leverage of the banking sector, so no agentinternalizes this e�ect. In other words, there is a run externality: individual banks maketheir portfolio decisions disregarding the fact that, as a sector, they influence run risk.Externalities associated with banks’ leverage decision are discussed in section 5B.

(ii) Mechanism and dynamics

The irrelevance of runs for amplification risk implies that the mechanisms behind am-plification risk and its dynamics will be similar to those in previous work.17 However, itis necessary to understand and characterize both in order to study the joint dynamics ofthe di�erent forms of risk and the potential influence of amplification risk on run risk.

Endogenous amplification risk depends on 1) bank leverage x and 2) the sensitivityof the capital price to changes in banks’ wealth share q

Õ(÷). The latter captures the17The description of the spiral behind amplification risk closely follows BruSan.

29

Page 31: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

sensitivity of banks’ capital demand to net worth, which in equilibrium is reflected byÂ

Õ(÷). Recall banks’ capital share  and the capital price q move together to preserveequilibrium in the goods market.

In equilibrium, banks finance capital holdings beyond their net worth by issuing short-term debt to households, i.e., x > 1, in order to exploit their higher e�ciency in al-locating resources. Then, a negative aggregate capital quality shock dZt < 0 directlyreduces wealth share of banks ÷. If banks’ capital demand is not linked to their networth, i.e., if they just hold the entire capital stock, then there is no amplification. Onthe contrary, if banks’ capital demand is limited by their net worth, initial losses triggera downward spiral. The reduction of relative capital demand by banks implies a dropin its price since households are less e�cient at managing capital. The drop in assetprices generates a further reduction in ÷ due to leverage, which translates again intolower capital demand by banks. Figure 1(a) illustrates the spiral.

Figure 1: Amplification risk

(a) Amplification spiral (b) Amplification risk ‡

q

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

Am

pli-ca

tion

risk<

q

The continuous-time framework allows a simple characterization of the spiral. Consideran exogenous shock that reduces capital quantity by 1 percent; the direct e�ect oncapital price then is a

’ © q

Õ(÷)÷q(÷)

¸ ˚˙ ˝©Áq,÷

(x ≠ 1)¸ ˚˙ ˝

direct drop in ÷

percent drop. The shock directly reduces the value of capital holdings by 1 percent,which translates in a reduction of (x ≠ 1) percent of banks’ wealth share ÷. The changein the state implies a price change governed by the elasticity of capital price with respectto the banks’ wealth share, Áq,÷. The direct e�ect on the price of capital feeds back into÷ and its e�ect is identical to the e�ect of the initial quantity shock because price andquantity have the same impact on total value. Then, the second-round e�ect on capital

30

Page 32: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

price is ’

2, and the total e�ect can be found by summing the corresponding geometricseries. Therefore, the total e�ect of a unit shock to capital quantity on capital price,i.e., amplification risk, can be written as

q = ’

1 ≠ ’¸ ˚˙ ˝spiral e�ect

‡¸˚˙˝exogenous risk

.

The e�ect of the initial impulse, dZt, on capital quantity depends on exogenous risk ‡,and the change in capital quantity triggers the spiral described above.

There are two di�erent regimes relevant for amplification risk that are characterizedby the strength of the banking sector. In normal times, banks are well-capitalized andare willing to absorb the risk of managing all capital in the economy, so  = 1 andq

Õ(÷) = 0. There is no amplification spiral, i.e., ‡

q = ’ = 0, since the equilibriumdemand of banks does not depend on their net worth. However, when banks becomepoorly capitalized, the risk of managing all capital stock is too great and it is optimalto sell some to households despite their lower productivity, so in this regime  < 1and q

Õ(÷) > 0. In these situations, banks’ capital demand depends on their net worthbecause, with larger net worth, their risk-bearing capacity increases, and therefore thespiral described is triggered after negative capital shocks. These dynamics are formalizedby the following proposition and illustrated in Figure 1(b).

Proposition 2. There exists a threshold ÷

 œ (0, 1] such that amplification risk ispresent, i.e., ‡

q> 0, if and only if banks’ wealth share is below this threshold, i.e.,

÷ < ÷

 (otherwise, ‡

q = 0). Moreover, the positive amplification region is precisely themisallocation region, i.e. the region where  < 1.

The independence result implies that run risk can a�ect the manifestation of amplifica-tion risk only through its influence on the shape of the stationary distribution.18 Thereare two competing forces at play: 1) when the economy is exposed to run risk, runscause banks’ wealth share to be almost completely erased, sending the economy intothe amplification region, and 2) run risk increases the risk premium on capital, allowinglevered banks to increase their wealth share faster. Under the baseline parameter spec-ification, the former e�ect dominates, and the economy spends more time in the crisisregime when I allow for the possibility of bank runs.

C. Run risk

Systemic runs represent a di�erent class of risk faced by the economy. Runs are notdriven by a real exogenous impulse; rather, they are the outcome of agents’ behavior and

18The independence result shows that amplification risk function ‡

q(÷) does not depend on run risk.Nevertheless, run risk will a�ect the time the economy spends at di�erent ÷ values.

31

Page 33: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

can arrive whenever the financial system is su�ciently fragile. The impetus for a runis a coordinating signal that arrives at a rate determined by the equilibrium selectionmechanism. Hence, the possibility of a run is driven purely by the system’s internaldynamics and coordination among agents.

There are three relevant measures of the risk that systemic runs pose: 1) the region inthe state space in which a run is possible, 2) the losses they impose in terms of variablesof interest such as asset values or output, and 3) the frequency of runs. The followingproposition shows that, out of these three measures, only the frequency of runs dependson the equilibrium selection device.

Proposition 3. Let S = {÷ œ [0, 1] : ¸

d> 0} be the set of aggregate states in which a

run equilibrium is feasible, i.e., the run vulnerability region. Then, S is independent ofthe equilibrium selection device �(·). Moreover, the capital value losses ¸

q and outputgrowth drop ¸

y that a systemic run generates are independent of �(·) as well.

A run may occur whenever the economy is fragile enough that a run on the bankingsystem would imply losses for depositors. Under these circumstances, households’ de-cision not to roll over deposits yields a self-fulfilling equilibrium. Potential losses fordepositors are determined by two factors: 1) bank leverage x and 2) the drop in assetprices ¸

q conditional on a run, as evidenced by the equation

¸

d =51 ≠ (1 ≠ ¸

q)3

x

x ≠ 1

46+

,

where [·]+ © max {·, 0}. Importantly, the preceding proposition demonstrates that theregion in the state space in which ¸

d> 0 is independent of the coordination device

chosen. The intuition underlying this result is that, as argued earlier, relative capitaldemand is independent of the equilibrium selection mechanism because households andbanks require equal compensation to bear run risk. Therefore, bank leverage x is inde-pendent of the possibility of a run, so the price function q(÷) (and hence the potentialloss in the event of a run) is independent of the equilibrium selection mechanism as well.

The run vulnerability region corresponds to intermediate levels of banks’ wealth share.At one extreme, when banks hold a large share of total wealth, the leverage requiredto hold the entire capital stock is low. Even though the potential fall in asset pricesis large, bank equity is su�cient to absorb any losses in the event of a run. On theother hand, when banks hold a very small share of wealth, misallocation is severe andasset prices are depressed. Despite the fact that bank leverage is high, the economyis shielded from runs because the potential drop in asset prices is not large enough towipe out bank equity. The next corollary formalizes this intuition.

32

Page 34: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Corollary 1. There exist wealth share levels for banks {÷

L, ÷

H} œ (0, 1) with ÷

L Æ ÷

L

such that the economy is not vulnerable to runs if banks’ wealth share is lower than ÷

L

or larger than ÷

H , i.e., ÷ /œ S if ÷ < ÷

L or ÷ > ÷

H .

Figure 2 illustrates the state-dependence of depositors’ losses ¸

d as well as its determi-nants: the potential drop ¸

q in the price of capital and bank leverage x. In the regionwhere the economy is exposed to amplification risk, ¸

q increases in ÷ as asset pricesincrease, but leverage declines in ÷ as banks’ balance sheets become stronger. The in-crease in ¸

q dominates in all numerical exercises, so in this region the potential lossesfaced by depositors are increasing in ÷. In the region where the economy is exposed onlyto run risk, ¸

d is decreasing as a function of ÷ as asset prices are constant but leveragedeclines.

Within the region where runs are possible, the frequency of runs depends on the sunspotintensity function �(·). In the baseline specification, �(·) is a linear function of deposi-tors’ losses, so the state-dependence of run frequency coincides with that of depositors’potential losses.

The intuition behind capital price losses increasing in banks’ wealth share is the fol-lowing. When a run occurs, banks’ wealth share jumps to ÷ ¥ 0, so households areforced to operate essentially the entire capital stock, and the price of capital falls toits minimum value. The drop in the price of capital is larger when the initial capitalprice is higher, i.e., when ÷ is higher and misallocation is lower. Allocative e�ciencyalso jumps to a minimum after a run, so the potential drop in output is increasing in÷ as well. This implies runs are more costly in the region where the economy is onlyexposed to runs. This logic is formalized below.

Corollary 2. For a non-contingent transfer policy, i.e., T (÷) = T , potential losses interms of output ¸

Y and capital value ¸

q are weakly increasing in ÷ within the regionvulnerable to runs.

The economy is not necessarily exposed to run risk in any region of the state space.Whether run risk emerges depends on the losses to which depositors are exposed, whichin turn are a function of bank leverage and the potential fall in asset prices. Wheneither the exposure of asset prices to runs or leverage is su�ciently low, depositorsnever rationally decide to run because the levered losses incurred by banks are toosmall to wipe out their equity. For instance, if banks’ productivity approaches that ofhouseholds (a æ a), the potential drop in prices goes to zero, which itself is enough torule out runs. More importantly, as will be shown below, large values of exogenous risk‡ will endogenously restrain bank leverage to the point that households never have tofear a loss on their deposits. This result stands in stark contrast to Proposition 2, whichestablishes that amplification risk is always present in some region of the state space.

33

Page 35: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Figure 2: Run risk

(a) Determinants of run risk (b) Depositors’ loss ¸

d

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4Bankers' wealth share 2

0.6

0.8

1

Ban

ks'

deb

t/ass

etsra

tio

(x!

1)=

x

0

0.1

0.2

Pot

ential

capitalprice

dro

p`q

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

Dep

osito

rs'lo

ss`d

D. Joint dynamics and the “hidden risk” regime

The economy’s state space is comprised of three distinct risk regimes: 1) a highly unsta-ble crisis regime, 2) an apparently stable hidden risk regime, and 3) a truly stable saferegime. The regimes are characterized by the economy’s exposure to endogenous risks(amplification risk and run risk) and correspond to distinct regions of the state space.As a consequence, the qualitative features of the economy’s dynamics and the distri-bution of variables of interest, e.g. capital returns or output growth, vary dramaticallyacross these three regions.

Figure 3(a) presents the distributions of output growth conditional on the state ÷,and Figure 3(b) presents one example of a distribution per risk regime. These graphsillustrate how the di�erent endogenous risks translate into outcomes for variables ofinterest. Amplification risk implies large variability, but it cannot generate a distributionof output growth with asymmetries or fat tails given the normality of real shocks. Incontrast, run risk generates an output growth distribution with negative skewness andfat tails. Systemic runs are responsible for the second mode at large negative growthrates, so this mass in the left tail appears only when the economy is vulnerable to runs,i.e., at intermediate values of ÷. Figure 3(c) presents the stationary density for banks’wealth share ÷ and distinguishes the three risk regimes.

The safe region, amplification risk and systemic runs are absent. In this region, banks’share of wealth is large and they hold the entire capital stock without exposing depos-itors to losses in the event of a run. There is no misallocation, so the price of capitalis constant. Banks’ wealth share is exposed only to the direct e�ect of real shocks, i.e.,the change in the quantity of capital. Output growth inherits the distribution of thegrowth of the capital stock, which is normal with volatility ‡.

34

Page 36: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

In the hidden risk region, the economy is exposed to systemic runs, yet insulated fromamplification risk. Banks’ wealth share must lie in an intermediate range: it must besmall enough for depositors to rationally fear losses in the event of a run, but largeenough that banks do not wish to fire-sell assets to households. Apart from the econ-omy’s response to the realization of systemic runs, the dynamics in this region areidentical to those in the safe regime. In particular, in the absence of runs, the dynamicsof output and asset prices are observationally equivalent in the two regimes. Banks holdthe entire capital stock, so capital price is constant and banks’ portfolios are exposedonly to exogenous risk and systemic runs. The distribution of output growth is similarto that in the safe regime, except for a second mode at large negative growth ratesresulting from the economy’s exposure to runs.

In the crisis region, banks’ share of aggregate wealth is low enough that the economy

Figure 3: Risk regimes

(a) Conditional distributions of output growth (b) Distributions by risk regime (examples)

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6

Growth rate

0

0.5

1

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4

Den

sity

Crisis regime 2 = 0:15Hidden risk regime 2 = 0:22Safe regime 2 = 0:30

(c) Stationary distribution of ÷ (d) Decomposition of conditional variance

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4Bankers' wealth share 2

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

Den

sity

Safe regimeHidden risk regimeCrisis regime

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4

Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.005

0.01

0.015

0.02

0.025

0.03

0.035

0.04

Conditio

nalva

riance

ofoutp

utgro

wth

Run riskAmpli-cation riskFundamental risk

35

Page 37: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

is exposed to amplification risk. Negative real shocks force banks to sell assets, whichincreases misallocation, lowers asset prices, and sets o� a loss spiral. As a result, thevolatility of macroeconomic and financial variables is high in this region. Systemic runsmay also be possible in this region due to the weakness of bank balance sheets, buttheir incidence is not guaranteed because asset prices in this region may be so lowthat the potential loss during a mass liquidation is insu�cient to wipe out bank equity.The distributions of output growth and returns on capital have high variance and arebimodal when runs are possible.

Relative to earlier work such as BruSan, the main qualitative di�erence brought aboutby the introduction of systemic runs lies in the dynamics of the hidden risk regime.Unlike the safe region and the crisis region, the hidden risk region may not alwaysexist. Indeed, as argued earlier, there are some parameter combinations for which theeconomy is never exposed to runs. Therefore, the relevant question is whether a hiddenrisk regime is always present, conditional on the economy being exposed to systemicruns, i.e., S ”= ÿ. The following corollary describes a necessary and su�cient conditionfor the existence of the hidden risk regime: positive losses for depositors (conditionalon a run) when the state is at the boundary ÷

 of the crisis regime.

Corollary 3. Given a constant transfer policy T , there exists a hidden risk regime ifand only if a run equilibrium is feasible at the threshold banks’ wealth share level ÷

Â,i.e., ¸

d1÷

Â2

> 0.

The condition mentioned in corollary 3 is satisfied for all parameter combinations forwhich the economy is exposed to run risk. Moreover, in each such numerical exercise,depositors’ losses ¸

d reach a maximum at ÷

Â. Absent a formal proof, this illustratesthat the hidden risk regime is a robust feature of the model.

Continuous-time methods allow me to analytically characterize the stochastic evolutionof the variables of interest at any point in the state space and, therefore, to calculate anyrelevant conditional moment. In order to illustrate the relative contributions of eachrisk to variability, Figure 3(d) presents the decomposition of the variance of outputgrowth19 into components associated with exogenous risk, amplification risk, and runrisk.

For baseline parameters, the contribution of exogenous risk to the conditional varianceof output is dwarfed by the contributions of endogenous risks. The variability associatedwith run risk is at least as important as that due to amplification risk in the crisis regime.Furthermore, it is clearly the dominant source of risk in the hidden risk regime, wherethe potential drops in output and asset prices are largest.

19See Appendix C for details about the decomposition.

36

Page 38: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

E. Ergodic instabilities

The stationary distribution of the state of the economy has several interesting prop-erties. To begin with, the economy is highly prone to instability under the baselineparametrization, as evidenced by the stationary distribution in Figure 3(c). In fact, theeconomy spends more time in the hidden risk region than it does in the safe region.More subtly, the stationary distribution exhibits a counterintuitive feature: despite thefact that, more often than not, the state of the economy is in a region where endogenousrisks are present, it is also true that most of the time there is no observable amplifica-tion. This can be seen in Figure 3(c) by noting that the economy spends a considerablylarger span of time in the hidden risk region than in the crisis region.

Another striking property of the stationary distribution is that there is a significantamount of mass in the extreme left tail near ÷ = 0. The following lemma shows thatthis mass is entirely due to runs.

Lemma 6. Consider the model without runs, i.e., �(·) © 0. If there is a positive flow ofagents from the household to the banking sector ⁄ > 0, then the stationary distributionhas density zero at ÷ = 0.

This lemma shows that exogenous risk and amplification risk together do not generateenough volatility to keep banks’ wealth near zero when there is a stabilizing force ontheir wealth. The implication is that systemic runs on the financial system are whollyresponsible for the most severe crises. Further, the size of the mass near ÷ = 0 in thestationary distribution indicates that runs are not only severe but subject to a slowrecovery.

There is a sharp contrast between the shape of the ergodic distribution in the crisisregime and outside it. The reason is that, in the crisis regime, excess returns on cap-ital include compensation for amplification risk, which favors wealth accumulation inthe banking sector. Therefore, the endogenous dynamics imply a relatively fast thoughhighly volatile transition out of the crisis regime. This explains the relatively low massin this region. Once amplification disappears, banks’ accumulation of wealth is signifi-cantly slower, as reflected by the large increase in the density at threshold banks’ wealthshare ÷

Â.

The shape of the ÷-density within the crisis regime follows from the dynamics of endoge-nous risks: when risks are small or absent, excess returns on capital are also limited andbanks accumulate wealth slowly relative to households. Therefore, recovery is slowestimmediately after a systemic run, i.e., close to ÷ = 0, since there is no run risk and am-plification risk is small (because for low levels of ÷, even a large percentage movementimplies a small absolute change, which determines the extent of the loss spiral). As ÷

37

Page 39: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

increases in the crisis regime, amplification and run risk increase, so the transition outof this highly unstable regime speeds up as long as no run is realized. The downwardslope of the density in the crisis regime follows from this logic.

F. Risk topography

The hidden risk regime and the safe regime are observationally equivalent in severalrespects. For one, the level of asset prices, output per unit of capital, and real investmentper unit of capital are all identical across the two regimes. Moreover, in each of the tworegimes the volatility of output is equal to the exogenous volatility of the quantity ofcapital, and the volatility of asset prices is equal to zero.

In order to distinguish between these two regimes, it is necessary to develop a risktopography to describe the joint behavior of macroeconomic variables, financial indica-tors, asset prices, and returns. In this environment, three important quantities suggestpresence of hidden run risk. First, the simultaneous incidence of high asset prices andhigh bank leverage directly implies that depositors will take large losses in case of a run,since these are precisely what drive depositors’ potential losses ¸

d. Second, high excessreturns on capital per unit of observed volatility can be indicative of run risk as well.Even though run risk does not a�ect relative capital demand, it does a�ect the riskpremium required by both types of agents. Hence, risk premia relative to asset pricevolatility will be high in the hidden risk regime because observable volatility in thatregime is low. Third, a low risk-free rate indicates the possibility of a run. Althoughthere is no risk-free asset in the model, an asset-pricing exercise shows that the risk-freerate tends to be low in the hidden risk regime. This is because the possibility of acollapse due to a run drags down agents’ expected consumption growth.

5 Risk to control risk

The following examines how the model’s endogenous instabilities change as the amountof exogenous risk ‡ varies. The interactions between the di�erent types of risks arekey to understanding the main insight of the model: stability breeds instability and itscontrapositive, risk controls risk. Economies with the lowest level of exogenous risk willbe most exposed to systemic runs in the sense that the region in which they can occuris largest for low ‡. Importantly, this result will hold independently of the equilibriumselection device. On the other hand, total volatility ‡ + ‡

q will decrease alongsideexogenous risk.

These results lead to a non-monotonic welfare ranking with respect to exogenous risk.For high levels of exogenous risk, the economy is shielded from runs and agents dislike

38

Page 40: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Figure 4: Exogenous risk e�ect over endogenous instabilities

increases in exogenous risk since they translate into a larger probability of entering thecrisis regime and worse crises, i.e., higher misallocation and amplification. However,for low levels of exogenous volatility, the economy is exposed to runs and agents favorincreases in exogenous volatility because they restrain risk-taking by banks and preventruns. The welfare analysis assumes the equilibrium selection mechanism is independentof exogenous volatility.

A. Stability breeds instability

A brief examination of the mechanisms at play illustrates why low exogenous volatilityleads to lower total volatility but greater run risk. When exogenous volatility is low, thecapital demand of both types of agents increases, but banks’ demand increases relativeto households’ because of their greater exposure to the exogenous risk. Therefore,banks’ equilibrium leverage increases. The increase in leverage is dampened (but notcompletely reversed) by the corresponding increase in amplification risk. Higher leveragereduces misallocation and increases asset prices. However, higher leverage and assetprices also increase the economy’s exposure to a run. Unlike the increase in amplificationrisk, the increase in run risk does not feed back into banks’ equilibrium leverage becauseof 1) limited liability, which makes the banks’ fate after a run – bankruptcy – insensitiveto their risk-taking at the margin, and 2) banks’ failure to internalize their contributionto aggregate run risk. Figure 4 illustrates this logic.

Next I describe in detail how each type of endogenous vulnerability responds to lowerexogenous risk and provide formal results.

Amplification risk. Lower exogenous risk has two opposing e�ects on the loss spiralthat generates amplification risk. First, it decreases the impact of a given exogenousimpulse on the quantity of capital. Second, it increases the sensitivity of banks’ relativecapital demand to changes in net worth, i.e., Â

Õ(÷) and q

Õ(÷) are higher in the crisis

39

Page 41: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Figure 5: Endogenous instabilities and exogenous risk

(a) Amplification risk ‡

q (b) Total di�usion risk ‡ + ‡

q (c) Arrival rate of runs p

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

Am

pli-cation

risk<

q

< ! 0< = 0:02< = 0:04

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

0.09

0.1

Tota

ldi,

usion

risk<

+<

q

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.02

0.04

0.06

0.08

0.1

0.12

Run

risk

p

regime. As a result, the crisis regime shrinks, but amplification risk is higher in thenew crisis regime. Nevertheless, the increase in amplification is never enough to undothe initial reduction in exogenous volatility, so total risk associated with real shocks de-creases. Panels (a) and (b) in Figure 5 illustrate this e�ect and the following propositionformalizes it.

Proposition 4. Total di�usion risk ‡ + ‡

q is weakly increasing in exogenous risk ‡

for every ÷ œ [0, 1]. Also, capital price q and banks’ capital share  (or leverage x) areweakly decreasing in ‡ for every ÷ œ [0, 1].

Run risk. When exogenous risk is reduced, total risk associated with real shocks de-creases as well. Banks then increase their leverage, resulting in less misallocation andhigher capital prices. The greater fragility of bank balance sheets and higher capitalprices both contribute to a larger potential loss for depositors and hence a greater expo-sure to systemic runs (holding the liquidation price fixed). The reduction in exogenousvolatility does not have a large e�ect on the liquidation price because the transfer toreboot the banking sector is small enough that the liquidation price is close to q(0),which is independent of exogenous volatility. Nevertheless, in general the small increasein the liquidation price due to lower exogenous risk dampens the increase in run risk.This e�ect is illustrated in Figure 5(c) and made precise by the following proposition.

Proposition 5. For a constant liquidation price, the size of the run vulnerability re-gion, i.e., the Lebesgue measure of S, is weakly decreasing in ‡. A constant liquidationcorresponds, for example, to the case where there are no transfers to banks after theircollapse, i.e., T æ 0.

In this model, both endogenous risks remain as exogenous volatility vanishes. For am-plification risk this e�ect is simply the “volatility paradox” of BruSan: as the exogenous

40

Page 42: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

impulse vanishes (‡ æ 0), the spiral e�ect grows unboundedly (’/(1 ≠ ’) æ Œ) in away that endogenous amplification risk persists (‡q æ ‡

q œ R). The persistence ofrun risk as exogenous risk vanishes in this model is actually more powerful than thevolatility paradox. First, given the previous result, when exogenous risk vanishes runrisk is actually maximized. Second, if exogenous risk is initially high enough that theeconomy is not exposed to runs, a reduction of exogenous risk may actually introducethe possibility of runs to the economy. This intuition is partially formalized below.

Corollary 4. Amplification risk does not vanish as exogenous risk disappears, i.e.,threshold level for banks’ wealth share ÷

 æ ÷

+

> 0 as ‡ æ 0.

B. Externalities and welfare measures

In order to understand how exogenous risk a�ects welfare in this economy, it is firstnecessary to examine the externalities arising from banks’ portfolio decisions and discussthe relevant welfare measures.

Externalities. Absent runs, there are two pecuniary externalities related to banks’portfolio decisions (or capital demand). First, there is a static pecuniary externalityassociated with the level of capital price. Banks do not take into account that a decreasein their leverage has a negative impact on the price of capital, which reduces the risk-bearing capacity (or net worth) of other banks, forcing them to decrease their capitalpositions and increase misallocation. In this sense, banks’ leverage is ine�ciently low.Second, there is a dynamic pecuniary externality associated with the volatility of capitalprice. Banks disregard that, by increasing their leverage, they increase the amplificationof future real shocks in the economy. In this other sense, banks’ leverage is ine�cientlyhigh. Therefore, these externalities bias leverage in di�erent directions.

Bank runs introduce two additional externalities in banks’ portfolio decisions. First,banks do not internalize that their choice of leverage a�ects the economy’s exposureto systemic runs. Larger leverage increases potential losses for depositors directly andthrough asset prices: higher leverage increases the price of capital and therefore thesize of the drop to its liquidation price. Agents fail to internalize this e�ect becauseindividual decisions have zero impact on aggregate variables and run risk depends onaggregate losses of depositors if the bank run is realized. Second, banks disregard thecost of transfers after their collapse. These run externalities lead to excessive leverage.Importantly, even though their presence does not depend on the equilibrium selectionmechanism (as long as the economy is exposed to runs), their magnitude does.

Welfare measures. The solution to the model provides a detailed characterization ofagents’ well-being. In particular, it delivers a solution for the value function (scaled

41

Page 43: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

by total capital) conditional on each aggregate state, i.e., v(÷) for banks and v(÷) forhouseholds, and also describes the frequency with which the economy visits each of thesestates, i.e., the stationary distribution. Then, a welfare comparison across economiesneeds to select a relevant summary statistic. For a given agent, the most intuitivestatistic is the expected indirect utility where the expectation is taken with respect tothe stationary distribution, i.e., E [v(÷)] and E [v(÷)]. For the entire economy, a Pareto-weighted average of these statistics is a natural measure. The non-monotonic welfareranking with respect to exogenous risk (emphasized later in this section) will hold notonly for any Pareto weights but will be robust to alternative welfare measures such asthe indirect utility conditional on a particular value of ÷.

C. Exogenous risk and welfare

The welfare consequences of changing the level of exogenous risk in the economy canbe conceptually decomposed into three components: 1) a fundamental e�ect, 2) a re-distributive e�ect, and 3) the impact on externalities.

Fundamental e�ect. The fundamental e�ect of exogenous risk on welfare is the impactit would have in a frictionless economy. In this model, the frictionless benchmarkcorresponds to a version that allows for equity issuance. In this case, the model collapsesto a growth model with a representative agent that has access to the most productivetechnology. All financing happens through equity contracts, so there is no short-termdebt and no runs. Larger exogenous risk decreases the utility of the representative agentdue to risk aversion. The following lemma formalizes this intuition.

Lemma 7. With complete markets, i.e., allowing for equity issuances, the indirectutility function of the representative agent is decreasing in exogenous volatility ‡.

Redistributive e�ect. The redistributive e�ect corresponds to shifts in the wealth distri-bution. Without externalities, any wealth redistribution has a positive welfare impactfor the agent whose net worth increases and a negative one for the agent whose wealthdecreases. In comparisons across economies, this e�ect is related to shifts of stationarydistribution. For example, a switch toward a stationary distribution that spends moretime at states where banks own a small fraction of wealth would represent a redistri-bution toward households. This is precisely the case when considering a reduction ofexogenous risk.

Lower ‡ increases the exposure to systemic runs – see Proposition 5 – so the economy ismore frequently propel to situations where households own a large fraction of wealth. Italso decreases excess capital returns in the safe regime, making the economy less likelyto visit this region of low wealth share for households. Therefore, if reducing exogenous

42

Page 44: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

risk has a negative welfare e�ect for households, it will be in spite of the redistributiveimpact.

Impact on externalities. A reduction of exogenous risk increases banks’ leverage –see Proposition 4 below – so the impact of ‡ on externalities in this model depends onwhether banks’ leverage is ine�ciently high or ine�ciently low. If leverage is ine�cientlylow, the main e�ect of a marginal reduction of ‡ is to increase allocative e�ciency (re-duce the static pecuniary externality), and therefore it benefits both agents. If leverageis ine�ciently high, the principal e�ect of a marginal decrease of ‡ is the increase ofendogenous instabilities (larger dynamic pecuniary externality and run externalities),so it is detrimental for both agents.

Whether leverage is ine�ciently low or high depends on the relative strengths of exter-nalities (and potentially on the welfare measure adopted). When exogenous risk is highenough to shield the economy against runs, leverage tends to be too low, so reducingexogenous volatility reduces ine�ciencies in the economy. Moreover, as discussed be-fore, the larger endogenous amplification risk does not overcome the fundamental e�ectof lower ‡, so total risk associated with real shocks decreases.

In contrast, when exogenous volatility is low enough to expose the economy to systemicruns, equilibrium leverage tends to be too high and a marginal decrease in ‡ is costlyfor agents. Intuitively, the ine�ciencies caused by systemic runs tend to be strongerbecause there is no feedback from larger run risk to portfolio decisions (as is the casewhen considering risk associated with real shocks).

Non-monotonic welfare ranking and run risk. The overall e�ect of exogenous risk ‡ oneach agents’ welfare is illustrated in Figure 6(a). It shows the expected indirect utility ofagents, i.e., E [v(÷)] and E [v(÷)], and the annual probability of systemic runs E [p(÷)] foreconomies with di�erent levels of exogenous risk. The non-monotonicity of the welfaremeasure for both agents is evident. Moreover, the change in the relationship betweenthe welfare measures and exogenous risk coincides with the presence of systemic runs.This feature is robust to alternative parameter configurations (see Appendix D). It isimportant to mention that results presented in this section assume that the equilibriumselection mechanism �(·) is invariant to exogenous volatility ‡.

The reversal of the relationship between welfare and exogenous risk in the presence ofsystemic runs indicates that the main driving force is the e�ect of ‡ on externalities. Thedirections of the other two e�ects discussed do not depend on the presence of run risk:lower ‡ implies a positive fundamental e�ect and a redistribution toward households.In contrast, leverage switches from being ine�ciently low to ine�ciently high in thepresence of run risk, which implies that lower ‡ exacerbates externalities.

The non-monotonicity result and its dependence on the presence of runs not only hold

43

Page 45: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Figure 6: Welfare e�ect of exogenous risk

(a) Welfare e�ect of ‡ (b) Pareto frontier (no run risk) (c) Pareto frontier (run risk)

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2Exogenous volatility <

-300

-250

-200

-150

-100

Expec

ted

valu

efo

ragen

ts

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

Run

pro

bability

E[v(2)] value bankersE[v(2)] value householdsE[p(2)] run intensity (right axis)

-350 -300 -250 -200 -150 -100Value bankers v(2)

-210

-200

-190

-180

-170

-160

-150

-140

-130

Valu

ehouse

hold

sv(2

)

< = 0:06< = 0:08< = 0:10

-600 -500 -400 -300 -200 -100Value bankers v(2)

-150

-145

-140

-135

-130

-125

Valu

ehouse

hold

sv(2

)

< ! 0< = 0:02< = 0:04

on average, i.e., considering the expectation operator over the stationary distribution,but also hold conditioning on any particular wealth distribution, i.e., taking ÷ as given.Figure 6(b) shows the expansion of the Pareto frontier of the economy as ‡ decreaseswhen the economy is not exposed to runs (high exogenous risk), while Figure 6(c)illustrates the exact opposite e�ect when the economy is exposed to runs (low exogenousrisk). The frontier represents combinations (v(÷), v(÷)) for each ÷ œ [0, 1].20 To furtherillustrate the dependence on run risk, Appendix D shows the welfare ranking assumingaway run risk, i.e., �(·) © 0, and verifies that welfare is monotonic for households.21

6 Policy

Given the financial friction, i.e., the restriction not to issue equity, short-term debtfulfills the key role of allowing banks to finance larger capital holdings in order to im-prove productive e�ciency in the economy. However, this comes at the cost of systemicinstability due to amplification and run risk. As discussed before, banks do not appro-priately internalize all the costs or benefits of their portfolio decisions, which opens thepossibility for a welfare-improving policy intervention.

First, I consider a simple and intuitive macroprudential policy: a constant leveragecap L Ø 1. The analysis unveils important shortcomings of this policy as a tool tolimit endogenous risks. Surprisingly, a leverage constraint increases amplification riskwhenever it is not binding and exacerbates exposure to systemic runs within the hiddenrisk regime. Despite these limitations, a leverage cap can improve welfare by reducing

20The expansion (contraction) of the frontier does not necessarily imply that both agents are better(worse) o� at each aggregate state ÷ but that is indeed the case for Pareto frontiers shifts discussed (fordetails and robustness exercises, see Appendix D).

21Absent runs, the welfare ranking might be non-monotonic in exogenous risk for banks because anincrease of ‡ redistributes wealth toward them.

44

Page 46: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

overall run risk.

Second, I study a leverage cap contingent on the wealth share of the banking sector:L(÷) Ø 1. The optimal state-contingent leverage cap restrains banks’ risk-taking whenthe economy would be exposed to runs, i.e., in the intermediate range of banks’ wealthshare, but allows for large leverage when banks’ wealth share is particularly low, i.e.,during downturns.

Third, I study economies in which exogenous risk varies along with the wealth share ofthe banking sector and explore which of these relations, ‡(÷), benefits agents the most.Results indicate that agents would prefer to live in an economy in which exogenous riskincreases in regions of ÷ where the economy would be exposed to systemic runs. Beyondthe model, this suggest that exposure to systemic runs can be an unintended e�ect ofpolicies that stabilize real fluctuations.

6.1 Constant leverage constraint

The aim of implementing a leverage cap, despite the increase in misallocation it implies,is to limit the endogenous risks that leverage fosters, i.e., amplification and run risk.However, there are important shortcomings in using a constant leverage cap as a policytool to control risk.

A. Misallocation and risk control

Misallocation. The main cost of implementing a leverage constraint is to decrease alloca-tive e�ciency, i.e., to reduce the capital share of banks. This drop is the largest duringdownturns when banks are poorly capitalized and prices signal they should use sub-stantial leverage. The drop in equilibrium leverage is not limited to situations in whichthe constraint is binding (the low ÷ region) but extends to other regions of the statespace because banks reduce their capital demand in anticipation of a deeper recession.Since capital price is directly related with allocative e�ciency, the leverage constraintalso reduces it. The following proposition formalizes the increase in misallocation.

Proposition 6. The share of capital  held by banks weakly decreases with the imple-mentation of a leverage cap, i.e.,  (÷) Ø Â

1÷; L

2for ÷ œ [0, 1]. The same applies to

the capital price function q.

Amplification risk. The leverage cap controls amplification risk whenever it is binding.This is the case during downturns, i.e., the region where banks’ wealth share is low.However, this leverage constraint actually increases amplification risk whenever both:1) the economy exhibits misallocation and 2) the constraint is not binding. This increase

45

Page 47: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

in amplification risk is necessary to ensure both agents still want to hold capital. Theintuition is the following. A lower capital price implies a larger gap between marketreturns for banks and households (a≠a)/q while a lower capital share for banks impliestheir relative capital demand (x ≠ x) is lower, so the only way that both agents couldstill be willing to hold capital is if total di�usion risk ‡ + ‡

q increases. This logic isillustrated by

(x ≠ x)¸ ˚˙ ˝

¿(‡ + ‡

q)2

¸ ˚˙ ˝øø

= a ≠ a

q¸ ˚˙ ˝ø

.

An alternative interpretation is that the only way banks will reduce their relative capitaldemand (with respect to households’) given the increase in the return gap is if di�usionrisk increases. Moreover, the leverage constraint also enlarges the region of positiveamplification risk. The following proposition formalizes the limitations of a constantleverage cap to contain amplification risk, and Figure 7(a) shows how amplification riskvaries with the inclusion of a leverage cap.

Proposition 7. Amplification risk weakly increases when including a leverage cap, i.e.,‡

q(÷) Æ ‡

q1÷; L

2, for the ÷-region in which there is misallocation in both environments

and the leverage cap is not binding, i.e.,Ó

Â

1÷; L

2, Â (÷)

Ԝ [0, 1) and x

1÷; L

2< L.

Moreover, the region with positive amplification risk weakly increases, i.e., ÷

Â Æ ÷

Â1L

2.

Run risk. The leverage cap achieves lower equilibrium leverage, which dampens run risk.However, the inclusion of such a constraint decreases the liquidation price of capital,increasing potential drops in asset prices and the economy’s exposure to systemic runs.The leverage e�ect usually dominates when both forces are present, i.e., in the crisisregime, but only the second force is present in the hidden risk regime (where there is nomisallocation, so leverage is the same with and without the constraint). Therefore, aleverage cap increases run risk in this regime. The following proposition formalizes thedimension in which a leverage cap increases run risk in the economy, and Figure 7(b)illustrates how this risk changes with the inclusion of a leverage cap.

Proposition 8. (a) The liquidation price weakly decreases with the inclusion of a lever-age cap, i.e., q(÷(÷)) Ø q(÷(÷; L); L).

(b) For the ÷-region that belongs to the hidden risk regime in both solutions, i.e. Â (÷) =Â

1÷; L

2= 1 and

Óp(÷), p(÷; L)

Ԝ R

++

, the solution with the leverage constraint isweakly more prone to runs, i.e., p(÷) Æ p(÷; L).

Resilience of endogenous risks to leverage caps. While the only way to eliminate allamplification risk using a leverage cap is to ban any debt issuance, i.e., L = 1, it ispossible that the economy is completely shielded from systemic runs with L > 1.

46

Page 48: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Figure 7: Leverage constraint

(a) L e�ect over amplification risk (b) L e�ect over run risk

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

Am

pli-ca

tion

risk<

q

No leverage cap7L = 5

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

0.07

0.08

Run

risk

p

No leverage cap7L = 5

(c) L and welfare (d) State-contingent leverage cap L(÷)

2 4 6 8 10 12 14Leverage cap 7L

-300

-200

-100

Expecte

dvalu

efo

ragents

0

0.02

0.04

Run

pro

bability

E[v(2)] value bankersE[v(2)] value householdsE[p(2)] run intensity (right axis)

0 0.05 0.1 0.15 0.2 0.25 0.3 0.35 0.4 0.45 0.5Bankers' wealth share 2

0

5

10

Ban

ks'

leve

rage

0

0.02

0.04

Run

risk

Leverage x, no capRun risk p, no cap [right axis]Leverage x, optimal capRun risk p, optimal cap [right axis]

0

0.05

0.1

B. Leverage constraint and welfare

Despite the shortcomings of a constant leverage constraint in controlling endogenousrisks, it can still improve agents’ welfare by reducing the economy’s exposure to runs.Figure 7(c) summarizes the comparison between economies with di�erent leverage capsin terms of welfare and exposure to systemic runs. It shows that, as long the leveragecap helps reduce run risk (L > 3.4 for baseline parameters), both agents prefer atighter leverage constraint. However, once the leverage cap is tight enough to shield theeconomy completely from runs, there is a disagreement among agents about reducingL any further. Banks would prefer an even tighter leverage constraint while householdsprefer L to be just small enough to avoid runs.

A leverage cap poses a trade-o� between misallocation and endogenous instabilities: atighter leverage cap increases misallocation but potentially reduces endogenous insta-

47

Page 49: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

bilities. Results suggest it is worthwhile to impose the larger misallocation when thereduction of endogenous risk includes shielding the economy with respect to runs. Forleverage caps low enough to prevent any chance of systemic runs, a tighter leverage con-straint might benefit banks because of the redistributive e�ect: economies with lower L

spend more time in regions where banks own a larger fraction of wealth. The reason isthat risk-adjusted capital excess return increases for the region where the constraint isbinding (lowest ÷ region). The leverage cap limits competition among banks, allowinglarger risk-adjusted returns that translate into faster recoveries.

The same exercise assuming away run risk (not shown), i.e., �(·) © 0, further illustratesits role. Absent runs, households prefer not to have any leverage constraint (banks stilllike it due to the redistributive e�ect). This means that the misallocation cost tendsto be stronger than the imperfect reduction in amplification risk, at least for the agentrelatively less exposed to capital.

Given that welfare results weight opposing forces, they depend on the magnitude andsensitivity of the arrival rate of runs, i.e., they are sensitive to the equilibrium selectionmechanism. Appendix D shows that the qualitative features are robust to alterna-tive parameters. Also, an implicit assumption in this exercise is that the equilibriumselection mechanism is invariant to the leverage cap and exogenous risk.

6.2 State-contingent leverage cap

A state-contingent leverage cap L(÷) can overcome some of the shortcomings highlightedin the case of the constant leverage constraint. In particular, it allows for controllingbanks’ risk-taking when the economy would be exposed to runs, i.e., the middle region ofthe banking sector’s wealth share, without limiting leverage during downturns, i.e., whenthe aggregate state variable is particularly low. The latter avoids deepening recessionsthat follow a run, i.e., it prevents fostering run risk by depressing the liquidation priceof assets. This intuition is illustrated by the following numerical exercise.

I search for the state-contingent leverage constraint that maximizes an equally Pareto-weighted average of expected indirect utilities.22 Figure 7(d) shows banks’ leverage, x,and the arrival rate of runs, p, for the laissez-faire equilibrium and the one with theoptimal leverage constraint. The di�erence between leverage levels corresponds to theregion where the optimal leverage constraint is binding. This optimal state-contingentleverage constraint unequivocally reduces run vulnerability, i.e., the p decreases for

22In particular, I consider the family of functions described by L(÷) =q5

i=≠1 cixi and use as a welfare

measure 0.5E(v(÷)) + 0.5E(v(÷)), where the expectation is with respect to the stationary distributionof the state variable.

48

Page 50: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

every value of the aggregate state variable because it reduces leverage and capital pricewithout having an e�ect over its liquidation value.

Interestingly, the optimal leverage constraint reintroduces amplification risk in the hid-den risk regime of the laissez-faire equilibrium in order to limit risk-taking by banksand shield the economy from run risk. This highlights the larger detrimental e�ectsof systemic runs, especially the ones that occur when the economy is seemingly stablesince these generate the largest collapses. This point is also illustrated by the fact thatthe optimal state-contingent leverage constraint allows for run risk only for relativelylow levels of banks’ wealth share, i.e., it eliminates completely run risk for levels ofthe aggregate state variable associated with the hidden risk regime in the laissez-faireequilibrium.

A parallel exercise in an environment without runs (not shown), i.e., �(·) © 0, showsthat the optimal state-contingent leverage constraint only slightly limits risk-takingaround the banks’ wealth share level that divides the crisis regime and the safe one,÷

Â, around which amplification risk is the highest. This indicates that only for extremeamplification risk it is worthwhile to increase misallocation by using a leverage constraintto control this instability.

6.3 Stabilization of real shocks

Previous results showed that stability can breed instability, and they illustrated that,given this trade-o�, agents prefer an economy with strictly positive exogenous risk. Thissuggested that a full stabilization of real shocks has a cost in terms of financial fragilityand might not be an appropriate policy objective. In order to further illustrate thispoint, I assume a benevolent policymakers are able to influence fluctuations due to realshocks directly and at no cost, and evaluate how they would stabilize real fluctuationsdepending on the aggregate state variable of the economy: the wealth share of thebanking sector.

The exercise searches for the exogenous risk function23

‡(÷) that maximizes an equallyPareto-weighted average of expected indirect utilities. Results reinforce the messagethat full stabilization is not optimal in the presence of run risk: it is optimal to allowrelatively large fluctuations due to real shocks whenever the economy is exposed to runs,i.e., in the crisis and hidden risk regimes for baseline parameters, to control exposureto runs. Nevertheless, it is optimal to stabilize, i.e., insure against real fluctuations inthe economy, when there is no exposure to runs, such as in the safe regime. Figure8(a) illustrates this exercise (the colors indicate the regimes in the economy without thepolicy) and Appendix D shows robustness to alternative parameter configurations.

23The optimization is performed over fifth-degree polynomial functions.

49

Page 51: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Figure 8: Stabilization policy

(a) Baseline model (run risk) (b) Model without runs, �(·) © 0.

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06Exog

enousrisk<(2

)

OptimalBaseline

0 0.1 0.2 0.3Bankers' wealth share 2

0

0.01

0.02

0.03

0.04

0.05

0.06

Exog

enousrisk<(2

)

OptimalBaseline

A similar exercise conducted in the version of the economy without runs delivers theresult that a low non-contingent level of exogenous risk is optimal, as shown in Figure8(b).24 This is aligned with the common stabilization prescription and indicates thatthe misallocation cost and the negative fundamental e�ect of larger real fluctuationsare stronger than the benefit of reducing amplification risk alone. However, the trade-o� changes once real fluctuations also reduce the likelihood of large collapses. It isimportant to mention that, absent financial frictions, full stabilization is always theoptimal policy prescription with respect to real fluctuations.

7 Conclusions

This paper presents a tractable macroeconomic framework that includes two di�erentendogenous risks related to the financial sector: amplification of real shocks and systemicruns. The model demonstrates that economies with smaller exposure to real shocks aremore prone to systemic runs, i.e., stability breeds instability. This interaction can beexploited by using risk to control risk, i.e., by eschewing the full stabilization prescriptionand permitting small disruptions in order to prevent excessive risk-taking. Welfareanalysis suggests that such an approach can benefit all agents in the economy.

The analysis also illustrates important challenges in the identification of systemic risks.In particular, the threat of large collapses due to systemic runs can be present evenwhen volatility of real and financial variables is low. In other words, systemic risk maybe hidden. The model provides guidance on how to di�erentiate such a regime fromsafe, low-volatility environments.

24It is not optimal to set ‡ æ 0 because I include banks in the welfare measure and such a policyredistributes wealth toward households. If Pareto-weight on banks is zero, then it is indeed optimal tofully stabilize the economy, i.e., set ‡ æ 0.

50

Page 52: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Finally, the study of a simple and intuitive macro-prudential policy such as a leveragecap exemplifies the di�culties in controlling two di�erent dimensions of risk at the sametime, even in an economy in which the financial sector invests in a single asset. Thissuggests that policies that discourage agents’ risk-taking by influencing (the appropriatetype of) risk in the economy rather than controlling portfolio decisions may be moresuccessful at promoting systemic stability.

51

Page 53: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

References

Ben Bernanke, Mark Gertler, and Simon Gilchrist. the Financial Accelerator in aQuantitative Business Cycle Framework. 1, 1999.

Markus K. Brunnermeier and Yuliy Sannikov. A Macroeconomic Model with a FinancialSector. American Economic Review, 104(2):379–421, 2014. doi: 10.1257/aer.104.2.379. URL http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.104.2.379.

Markus K. Brunnermeier and Yuliy Sannikov. International credit flows, pecuniaryexternalities, and capital controls. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics,7(1):297–338, 2015. URL http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/workshops/macro/

past/pdf/BrunnermeierSannikovInternational.pdf.

Douglas W. Diamond and Philip H. Dybvig. Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liq-uidity. Journal of Political Economy, 91(3):401–419, 1983. ISSN 0022-3808. doi:10.1086/261155. URL http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/doi/10.1086/261155.

Mark Gertler and Nobuhiro Kiyotaki. Banking, Liquidity and Bank Runs in an InfiniteHorizon Economy. American Economic Review, 2015.

Mark Gertler, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, and Andrea Prestipino. A Macroeconomic Modelwith Financial Panics. 2017.

Lars Hansen, Paymon Khorrami, and Fabrice Tourre. Comparative Valuation Dynamicsin Models with Financing Restrictions. 2018.

Nobuhiro Kiyotaki and John Moore. Credit Cycles. Journal of Political Economy, 105(2):211–248, 1997.

Fernando Mendo. Financial Frictions: Amplification or Hedging Real Shocks? pages1–6, 2018.

Hyman Minsky. Stabilizing An Unstable Economy. 1986. ISBN 9780071592994.

52

Page 54: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Appendix A: Analytical results.

Proof Lemma 1. Households’ problem. The HJB equation for households’ problem is

flV (n, ÷) = maxc,ÿØ0,xØ0

log(c) + E5

dV (n, ÷)dt

6+ ⁄ (V (n, ÷) ≠ V (n, ÷))

s.t.dn

n

= xdr

k + (1 ≠ x)r ≠ c

n

dt ≠Ë(x ≠ 1)¸d + ·

ÈdJt ,

where the last term in the HJB equation is associated with idiosyncratic Poisson shock that turnsthe household into a bank and V represents the value function of banks. The dynamics of aggregatestate ÷ are taken as given by the household.

Solution. Take as given V (n, ÷) = fl

≠1 log(n) + ›(÷), which is proved below. Conjecture V (n, ÷) =fl

≠1 log(n) + ›(÷) with d› = µ

››dt + ‡

››dZt +

1›(÷) ≠ ›

2dJt. These dynamics will need to satisfy

consistency conditions with the aggregate state’s law of motion, detailed below. Given the conjectureand using Ito’s lemma, the evolution of V can be written as

dV = V n

nndt + ‡

nndZt

2+ V ›

››dt + ‡

››dZt

2+ 1

2V nn (‡nn)2

dt + 12V ››

1‡

››

22

dt...

... + V ›n‡

n‡

›n›dt + [V (n, ÷) ≠ V (n, ÷)] dJt

Then, the HJB reduces to

log(n) + fl›(÷) = maxc,ÿØ0,xØ0

log(c) + 1fl

µ

n≠ 1

2fl

2

n + p

51fl

log3

n

n

46

¸ ˚˙ ˝only these terms depend on decisions

...

... + p

1›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)

2+ ⁄

Ë›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)

È+ µ

››

where the tilde notation refers to the value of a variable just after a systemic run. Note that decisionsonly a�ect the first four terms on the RHS so, if the conjecture is correct, the maximization isequivalent to optimize over these terms. First-order conditions deliver c = fln, ÿ = [�Õ(1/q)]+, and

µ

R ≠ r Æ x (‡ + ‡q)2 + p

q ≠ ¸

d2

1 ≠ ¸

d ≠ x(¸q ≠ ¸

d) ≠ ·

, (29)

which holds with equality for x > 0. Solving the latter for x delivers two roots but only the smallerone, explicitly displayed in equation (13) in the main text, is a solution to the maximization problem(the other violates n Ø 0 after a run). Second-order conditions are satisfied and ensure a uniqueglobal maximum.

53

Page 55: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Replacing these optimal decision on the HJB equation,

fl› = log(fl) + 1fl

Ëx

R ≠ r

2+ r ≠ fl

È≠ 1

2fl

x

2 (‡ + ‡

q)2

...

... + p

51fl

log11 ≠ ¸

d ≠ x(¸q ≠ ¸

d) ≠ ·

2+ ›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)

6+ ⁄

Ë›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)

È+ µ

›› , (30)

where x is given by equation (13) and µ

›satisfies

µ

›› = ›

÷(µ÷

÷) + 12›

÷÷(‡÷

÷)2

which follows from Ito’s lemma. Since equation (30) does not depend on individual state n, function›(÷) can be chosen to ensure it is always satisfied. This verifies the conjecture.

I have characterized the solution of the HJB equation but I still need to verify that process

Gt ©⁄ t

0

e

≠fls log(cs)ds + e

≠fltV (nt, ÷t)

is martingale under the optimal policy and a supermartingale under any other admissible policy. Iomit this technical discussion.

The relation of x with respect to arrival rate of a run p and total di�usion volatility ‡ + ‡

q followfrom (29). Note that the RHS is strictly increasing in x (for solutions that imply positive net worthafter the run n), run intensity p, di�usion volatility |‡ + ‡

q|, and capital loss ¸

q. So x is decreasingin the mentioned variables.

Proof Lemma 2. Banks’ problem. The HJB equation for the banks’ problem is

flV (n, ÷) = maxc,ÿØ0,xØ0

log(c) + E5

dV (n, ÷)dt

6+ ⁄ (V (n, ÷) ≠ V (n, ÷))

s.t.

dn

n

= xdr

k ≠ (x ≠ 1) r (x) dt ≠ c

n

dt + {¸d(x)>0} (x¸

q ≠ 1 + ·) dJt ≠ {Ld>0 · ¸d(x)<0}„dt

where the last term in the HJB equation is associated with idiosyncratic Poisson shock that turnsthe bank into a household and V represents the value function of households. The law of motion ofaggregate state ÷ is taken as given by the banker.

Solution. Take as given V (n, ÷) = fl

≠1 log(n) + ›(÷). Conjecture V (n, ÷) = fl

≠1 log(n) + ›(÷) withd› = µ

››dt + ‡

››dZt + (›(÷) ≠ ›) dJt. These dynamics will need to satisfy consistency conditions

with the aggregate state’s law of motion, detailed below. Given the conjecture and using Ito’s

54

Page 56: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

lemma, the evolution of V can be written as

dV = Vn (µnndt + ‡

nndZt) + V›

››dt + ‡

››dZt

2+ 1

2Vnn (‡nn)2

dt + 12V››

1‡

››

22

dt...

... + V›n‡

n‡

›n›dt + [V (n, ÷) ≠ V (n, ÷)] dJt

Then, the HJB reduces to

log(n) + fl›(÷) = maxc,ÿØ0,xØ0

log(c) + 1fl

µn ≠ 12fl

2

n + p

51fl

log3

n

n

46

¸ ˚˙ ˝only these terms depend on decisions

+ p [›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)] + ⁄

Ë›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)

È+ µ››

Note that decisions only a�ect the first four terms on the RHS. So, if the conjecture is correct, themaximization is equivalent to optimize over these terms. First-order conditions for consumptionand investment are symmetric to households’, i.e., c = fln, and ÿ = [�Õ(1/q)]+. There are twolocal maxima with respect to x, one safe that satisfies x

s Æ (¸q)≠1 and another risky that satisfiesx

r> (¸q)≠1. The optimal condition for x

s is

µ

R ≠ r(xs) Æ x

s (‡ + ‡q)2 + p

¸

q

1 ≠ x

q,

which holds with equality for x

s> 0. The optimal condition for x

r is

µ

R ≠ r (xr) Æ x

r (‡ + ‡q)2 + (xr ≠ 1)rÕ (xr) , (31)

which holds with equality for x

r> (¸q)≠1. The risky solution is optimal if

(xr≠x

s)(µR≠r

f )≠(xr≠1)(r(xr)≠r

f )+„ Ø 12

1(xr)2 ≠ (xs)2

2(‡+‡

q)2+p (log (1 ≠ x

q) ≠ log(·)) .

(32)The assumption is that the cost of underperforming „ is su�ciently large for this condition to besatisfied and therefore ensure that equilibrium is symmetric (avoid that a fraction of banks choosethe safe leverage while the others choose the risky one). The optimal risky leverage condition canbe rearranged to render equation (16) using the pricing condition for deposits (14).

Replacing these optimal decisions on the HJB equation,

fl› = log(fl) + 1fl

Ëx

R ≠ r

2+ r ≠ fl

È≠ 1

2fl

x

2 (‡ + ‡

q)2 + p

51fl

log (·) + ›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)6

...

... + ⁄

Ë›(÷) ≠ ›(÷)

È+ µ›› , (33)

55

Page 57: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

where x is given by equation (16) and µ

›satisfies

µ›› = ›÷ (µ÷÷) + 1

2›÷÷ (‡÷÷)2

,

which follows from Ito’s lemma. Since equation (33) does not depend on individual state n, function›(÷) can be chosen to ensure it is always satisfied. This verifies the conjecture. I omit the technicaldiscussion about the verification argument.

Proof Lemma 3. Aggregate state dynamics. The proof follows directly from applying Ito’s formulafor processes with jumps to ÷ (N, N) = N/ (N + N) and the law of motions of N and N .

Proof Lemma 4. Scaled value functions. Households. The value function of a households withnet worth n can be written as

V (n, ÷) = fl

≠1 log(n) + ›(÷)

= fl

≠1 log3

n

N

(1 ≠ ÷)qK

4+ ›(÷)

= fl

≠1

5log

3n

N

4+ log(K)

6+ fl

≠1 log ((1 ≠ ÷)q) + ›(÷)¸ ˚˙ ˝

©v(÷)

where the first line follows from Lemma 1, the second from N = (1 ≠ ÷)qK, and the third justillustrates how v(÷) is defined in terms of equilibrium objects already derived. Using this definitionto replace ›(÷) with v(÷) and market clearing conditions, equation (30) becomes

flv(÷) = log(fl(1 ≠ ÷)q) + 1fl

5�(ÿ) ≠ ” ≠ 1

2‡

2 + ⁄ ≠ ⁄

1 ≠ ÷

46+ vµ

v...

... + p(÷) [v(÷) ≠ v(÷)] + ⁄

51fl

log3

÷

1 ≠ ÷

4+ v(÷) ≠ v(÷)

6(34)

whereµ

vv = v÷ (µ÷

÷) + 12v÷÷ (‡÷

÷)2

Alternatively, this expression can be derived directly by conjecturing directly (28) and replacingthis together with optimal decisions in the HJB equation. In this approach, it is necessary to takeinto account that the share of individual wealth to sector’s wealth has non-trivial dynamics due tothe idiosyncratic shocks that switch agents’ type. I verified my results using both procedures.

Banks. Derivation is symmetric using value function in Lemma 2 and N = ÷qK. In this case,v(÷) © fl

≠1 log (÷q) + ›(÷). Using this definition to replace ›(÷) with v(÷) and market clearing

56

Page 58: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

conditions, equation (33) becomes

flv(÷) = log(fl÷q) + 1fl

5�(ÿ) ≠ ” ≠ 1

2‡

2 + ⁄ ≠ ⁄

31 ≠ ÷

÷

46+ vµv... (35)

... + p(÷) [v(÷) ≠ v(÷)] + ⁄

51fl

log3

÷

1 ≠ ÷

4+ v(÷) ≠ v(÷)

6

whereµvv = v÷ (µ÷

÷) + 12v÷÷ (‡÷

÷)2

The alternative procedure described for value function of households also applies for banks.

Proof Lemma 5. Output growth and capital returns. Aggregate demand per unit of capital is

y

d(q) = C + C + ÿK

b + ÿK

K

= flq + ÿ(q)

where the second line follows from optimal consumption and investment decisions. Then, the resultfollows directly from applying Ito’s lemma to function y

d(q).

Proof Proposition 1. Invariance to run risk. I characterize functions {q(÷), Â(÷), ‡

q(÷)} inde-pendently from selection mechanism �(·).First, consider the case in which households hold some capital, Â < 1. In this case, expression(12) holds with equality. Subtract the latter from (15) and use equation (14) to find the explicitexpression for r

Õ(x). This yields

(x ≠ x) (‡ + ‡

q)2 = a ≠ a

q

. (36)

Equations (24) and (18) render

‡ + ‡

q = ‡

1 ≠ q÷

q ÷(1 ≠ ÷)(x ≠ x) . (37)

Replacing x = Â/÷, and x = (1 ≠ Â)/(1 ≠ ÷) into these two conditions and using goods marketclearing (21), I find an ODE for q(÷), i.e.,

Â(q) ≠ ÷

÷(1 ≠ ÷)

A‡

1 ≠ q÷

q (Â(q) ≠ ÷)

B2

= a ≠ a

q

(38)

where Â(q) © [q (ÿ(q) + fl) ≠ a] /(a ≠ a). The boundary condition for this first-order ODE followsfrom goods market clearing condition evaluated at ÷ = 0, i.e.,

q(0) [ÿ(q(0)) + fl] = a .

57

Page 59: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

The latter equation has a unique solution due to the concavity of �(·). This ODE describes thesolution for q(÷) as long as respects the non-negativity constraint for households’ capital holdings,i.e., x Ø 0.

Second, consider the case in which households hold no capital, i.e., Â = 1. In this case, goodsmarket clearing condition implies q(÷) = q which is defined by

q [ÿ(q) + fl] = a .

Then, q÷ = 0 and equation (37) implies ‡

q = 0. This is a solution as long as households do notdesire to hold any capital, i.e.,

x‡

2

<

a ≠ a

q

.

Note that in both cases the equations that characterize q(÷) are independent from selection mecha-nism �(·). The same applies for {Â, ‡

q} which are related to q through static conditions presentedabove. Also, the following endogenous objects do not appear on the ODE or boundary condition:arrival rate of runs, p, losses conditional on runs, ¸

q and ¸

d, and the state of the economy after therun ÷.

Proof Proposition 2. Amplification region. The first step of the proof is to show that q(÷) is aweakly increasing function. The ODE (38) can be written as

q÷ = q

Â(q) ≠ ÷

A

1 ± ‡

Û(Â(q) ≠ ÷) q

÷(1 ≠ ÷)(a ≠ a)

B

(39)

Equation (36) implies that  > ÷. If both agents are holding capital, they price it the same. Forthis to be possible banks who earn a larger return on capital need to have a larger exposure. Then,if we consider the solution with the plus sign, which is associated with ‡ + ‡

q< 0, we have that

q÷ > 0 immediately. However, this paper (and the literature) does not focus on this solution. Fora discussion about the type of equilibria that includes this solution, see Mendo [2018].

For the solution with the minus sign, which is characterized by ‡ + ‡

q> 0, a su�cient condition

for q÷ > 0 is the presence of amplification, i.e. ‡

q> 0. This is evident from writing the ODE as

q÷ = q

Â(q) ≠ ÷

31 ≠ ‡

‡ + ‡

q

4

Since, in this paper, I only consider solutions with ‡

q Ø 0, we have that q÷ Ø 0. In fact, theinequality must be strict, i.e. ‡

q> 0, because the original ODE (38) is not satisfied by a constant

q.

Then, I have proved that q÷ > 0 if  < 1 (for the equilibria of interest). For the region in which = 1, we know that q = q and q÷ =0. See proof of proposition 1.

The second step is to show that ÷÷

 œ (0, 1] s.t.  < 1 if and only if ÷ < ÷

Â. In equilibrium,

58

Page 60: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Â

Õ(÷) has the same sign as q

Õ(÷) so Â÷ Ø 0. This follows from goods market clearing. We alsoknow that Â Æ 1 because no agent can short capital. Therefore, if Â(÷a) = 1, then Â(÷) = 1 for all÷ > ÷a. I define the minimum ÷ such that banks manage all capital as ÷

Â, i.e., ÷

 = inf÷œ�

÷ where� = {÷ œ [0, 1] s.t. Â(÷) = 1}. If ÷ < ÷

 , then the ODE above holds and q÷ > 0. Note that ÷

Â> 0

since without net worth banks cannot hold any capital Â(0) = 0. The proof is completed by notingthe following. First, q÷ = 0 implies ‡

q = 0. Second, q÷ > 0 implies ‡

q> 0.

Proof Proposition 3. Run vulnerability region. Proposition 1 establishes that {q(÷), Â(÷)} areindependent from selection mechanism �(·). Losses for depositors ¸

d depend on banks’ leveragex = Â/÷, capital price q(÷), and liquidation value q(÷). Then, it is only left to show that liquidationvalue does not depend on �(·). This follows directly from equation (20), which determines ÷ givenq(÷) and transfer policy T . Note that {¸

q, ¸

y} only depend on {q(÷), Â(÷), q(÷)} so they are alsoindependent from selection mechanism.

Proof Corollary 1. Propositions 1 shows that {q, Â} are continuous functions of state ÷. Then,equation (20) implies function ÷ is also a continuous function if policy T (÷) is continuous. Considerthe uncapped potential losses ˆd = 1 ≠ q(÷)

q

1x

x≠1

2which are equivalent to ¸

d(÷) except they can benegative. It follows that ˆd(÷) is a continuous function.

Note that lim־0

ˆd(÷) < 0 because there are no potential losses since q (÷) Ø q(0) and lim÷æ1

ˆd(÷) <

0 because banks don’t use leverage anymore as ÷ æ 1. Then, the result follows directly from thecontinuity of ˆd(÷).

Proof Corollary 2. Given equation (20), a constant T implies a constant liquidation valueq(÷). Then, results follow from the fact that q(÷) and Â(÷) are weakly increasing in ÷ as shown inproposition 2.

Proof Corollary 3. Note that for ÷ > ÷

Â, the expression for depositors’ losses is

¸

d =51 ≠ q(÷)

q

3 11 ≠ ÷

46+

which is strictly decreasing in ÷ for a constant q(÷). Therefore, if ¸

d1÷

Â2

= 0, then ¸

d = 0 for all÷ > ÷

 and there is no hidden risk region. Conversely, if ¸

d1÷

Â2

> 0, by the continuity of ¸

d, thereexists a da > 0 s.t. ¸

d(÷) > 0 for all |÷ ≠ ÷

Â| < da.

Proof Lemma 6. Consider the following geometric process (with constant coe�cients)

dwt

wt= µwdt + ‡wdZt

If the associated stationary distribution is not degenerate, it satisfies satisfies g(w) = cww

2

1µw‡2

w≠1

2

where cw is a scaling constant. This follows directly from the Kolmogorov Forward Equation (KFE).For details, see for example BruSan.

59

Page 61: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

I show that the dynamics of the aggregate state ÷ converge to a geometric process as ÷ æ 0 andthat the associated drift and volatility satisfy lim÷æ0

µ÷ > lim÷æ0

‡÷ . This implies that stationary

distribution g(÷) = c÷÷

2

1µ÷

‡2÷

≠1

2

has mass zero at ÷ = 0 since exponent is positive. I consider themodel l without runs, i.e. �(·) © 0. The existence of a non degenerate stationary distributionfollows from the idiosyncratic Poisson shocks that switch agents’ type.

Using lemma 3, market clearing and first order conditions, the geometric drift and di�usion of ÷

can be written as

µ÷ = ‡

2

÷ + (1 ≠ Â)3

a ≠ a

q

4+ ⁄(1/÷ ≠ 1) ≠ ⁄

‡÷ =3

Â

÷

≠ 14

(‡ + ‡q)

I now work on the limits as ÷ æ 0 of the necessary expressions. First, note that equation (37) andthe fact that lim÷æ0

ʾ 0 implies that lim־0

q æ 0. From goods market clearing, we have thatlim÷æ0

q = q whereq

1ÿ(q) + fl

2= a

It is left to define the limit of Â/÷. Equation (36) can be written as

a ≠ a

q

=3

Â

÷

≠ 14

(‡ + ‡

q)2

so taking the limit as ÷ æ 0, we have that

lim־0

Â

÷

= a ≠ a

q‡

2

+ 1

Therefore,

lim־0

‡÷ =A

a ≠ a

q‡

B

lim־0

µ÷ =A

a ≠ a

q‡

B2

+3

a ≠ a

q

4+ ⁄

5lim־0

≠ 16

≠ ⁄

Clearly, if ⁄ > 0, we have that lim÷æ0

µ÷ > lim÷æ0

‡÷ and the stationary distribution has mass zeroat ÷ = 0.

Proof Proposition 4. Exogenous risk and total di�usion risk. First, I show that q(÷; ‡) is weaklydecreasing in ‡ for ÷ œ [0, 1]. I only consider the solution with ‡ + ‡

q> 0, i.e. the one associated

with the minus sign for ODE (39). Consider ‡

H> ‡

L. Since for ÷ = 0, the price of capital doesnot depend on ‡, we have q(0; ‡

L) = q(0; ‡

H). I prove that q(÷; ‡

L) Ø q(÷; ‡

H) by contradiction.Assume q(÷; ‡

L) < q(÷; ‡

H) for some ÷. Since both functions are continuous in ÷, this means that

60

Page 62: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

÷÷ œ (0, ÷) such that q(÷; ‡

L) = q(÷; ‡

H) and q÷(÷; ‡

L) < q÷(÷; ‡

H). This is a contradiction since q÷

is decreasing in ‡ (and all other values are the same). Since Â(÷) is directly related to q(÷) throughmarket clearing condition, it is also weakly decreasing in ‡.

To prove that ‡ + ‡

q is weakly increasing in ‡ for every ÷, note that equation (36) can be writtenas

(‡ + ‡

q)2 = ÷

 ≠ ÷

3a ≠ a

q

4.

Then, the result follows from q and  being weakly decreasing in ‡. Note this implies that the RHSof the latter equation weakly increasing in ‡.

Proof Proposition 5. Exogenous risk and run risk. It is su�cient to prove that depositors lossesare weakly decreasing in ‡ for a given liquidation price, which I call q

liq. Then, losses can be writtenas

¸

d =C

1 ≠ q

liq

q

3 11 ≠ ÷/Â

4D+

.

The result follows from q and  being weakly decreasing in ‡, which is proved in proposition 4.Lower capital price and lower leverage shield the economy from runs.

Proof Corollary 4. The follows from noting that the ODE for q(÷), i.e., equation (39), convergesto

q÷ = q

Â(q) ≠ ÷

when ‡ æ 0. The relevant boundary conditions q(0) is the same as before. The solution to thisdi�erential equation reaches  = 1 at ÷

+

> 0 because q(0) < q where q is the capital pricesassociated with  = 1.

Proof Lemma 7. The equilibrium with complete markets is standard. I provide a brief overviewof the equilibrium and focus on the welfare result. The economy collapses to a representative singleagent model with production technology yt = akt, i.e. all capital is managed by banks and riskis perfectly shared among agents. Since all agents have the same preferences, perfect risk sharingimplies symmetric positions (no deposits). Capital price q solves q(ÿ(q) + fl) = a.

The single agent problem can be written as

flV (k) = log(c) + E [dV (k)]

s.t. (1). It is straightforward to guess and verify that the value function can be written as

V (k) = fl

≠1 log(qk) + v

wherev = fl

3log(fl) + �(ÿ(q) ≠ ” ≠ 1

2‡

2

4

61

Page 63: Risk to Control Riskú - scholar.princeton.edu · 1 Introduction Fighting fire with fire, a principle eectively exploited in fields such as medicine (vac- cines) or firefighting

Note that value for agents is decreasing in exogenous risk ‡.

Proof Proposition 6. When the leverage constraint is not binding the ODE that characterizesthe equilibrium is still (38) for  < 1. If the leverage constraint is binding, then  = L÷, and capitalprice q(÷) can be solved from goods market clearing condition,

q(ÿ(q) + fl) = L÷(a ≠ a) + a ,

which delivers a strictly increasing function of ÷. Then, amplification risk ‡

q solves (37).

I proceed to prove the result by contradiction. Consider ÷

1

as the minimum ÷ such that Â(÷; L) >

Â(÷). Given that Â(0; L) = Â(0) = 0, by continuity, ÷÷

2

œ [0, ÷

1

) such that Â(÷2

; L) = Â(÷2

) andlim÷¿÷2 Â÷(÷; L) > lim÷¿÷2 Â÷(÷). Since the laissez-faire leverage x = Â/÷ is a decreasing function of÷, we know it is a feasible allocation for ÷ > ÷

2

. Therefore, the characterization of both solutionsin this region is given by ODE (38) with boundary condition q(÷

2

). This implies lim÷¿÷2 Â÷(÷; L) =lim÷¿÷2 Â÷(÷) which is a contradiction. Therefore, Â(÷; L) Æ Â(÷) for all ÷.

Given the direct relation between capital price q and allocation Â, it follows that q(÷; L) Æ q(÷).

Proof Proposition 7. Consider the ÷-region in which there is misallocation in both environmentsand the leverage cap is not binding, i.e.,

ÓÂ

1÷; L

2, Â (÷)

Ԝ [0, 1) and x

1÷; L

2< L. Then, both

solutions need to satisfy(‡ + ‡

q)2 =3

a ≠ a

q

4÷(1 ≠ ÷)

 ≠ ÷

Then, the result follows from  and q weekly decreasing when a leverage cap in introduced, seeproposition 6.

Proof Proposition 8. (a) Given that q(÷) weakly decreases with the introduction of a leveragecap, the ÷ that solves T (÷) = q(÷)÷ increases. Given that T (÷) is not a�ected by the inclusion ofthe leverage cap, the new liquidation price needs to be weakly lower, i.e. q(÷(÷; L); L) Æ q(÷(÷)).

(b) The result follows from the fact that q(÷) weakly decreases with the introduction of a leveragecap.

Appendix B: Numerical strategy.

• For an updated version of the appendix, please click here.

62