safe and accessible: bringing poor savers into the … · safe and accessible: bringing poor savers...

16
FocusNote NO. 37 SEPTEMBER 2006 Building financial systems for the poor Despite significant evidence to the contrary, many financial institution managers and policy makers do not believe poor people save money. They tend to assume that poor people are “too poor to save,” that they prefer to consume rather than save excess income, or that when they do save it is only to access a loan. 1 The numbers, however, paint a different picture. Research has repeatedly demon- strated that saving is central to poor people’s economic management strategies. Projects such as the Financial Diaries initiatives in India, Bangladesh, and South Africa; MicroSave in eastern and western Africa; and studies by the International Food Policy Research Institute, for example, have documented savings practices among the poor. 2 What is unclear is how well formal financial institutions satisfy poor savers’ needs. Although over 90 percent of adults in industrialized economies typically have accounts in financial institutions, market studies in some areas of the developing world indicate pen- etration rates as low as 6 percent. Access to savings services for the poor thus varies widely. Understanding this variation and its root causes is the primary goal of CGAP’s Country-Level Savings Assessments (see Box 1). The assessments explore opportuni- ties and constraints encountered by formal institutions in meeting demand for deposit services among the poor. 3 This Focus Note summarizes the findings from Country- Level Savings Assessments in Benin, Bosnia, Mexico, the Philippines, and Uganda, which suggest five strategies for improving poor people’s access to savings services. Although these five countries were chosen for the assessments, in part, because of their diversity, the findings of the assessments are strikingly similar in many ways. All five assess- ments found high demand for savings services but low usage of formal financial institu- tions, which lag behind informal savings mechanisms in fulfilling key client preferences. Institutional capacity and incentives are the primary factors behind the inability of for- mal financial institutions to compete with informal savings approaches. However, sup- portive industry infrastructure and policy frameworks also play important roles. SAFE AND ACCESSIBLE: BRINGING POOR SAVERS INTO THE FORMAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM The author of this Focus Note is Rani Deshpande, a mico- finance specialist at CGAP. The author thanks Brigit Helms for her guidance in writing this note; Rich Rosenberg, Ousa Sananikone, Jeanette Thomas, and Elizabeth Littlefield for their comments; and Mark Pickens and Jasmina Glisovic-Mezieres for their editorial and research assistance. © 2006, Consultative Group to Assist the Poor The Consultative Group to Assist the Poor (CGAP) is a consortium of 33 development agencies that support microfi- nance. More information is available on the CGAP Web site (www.cgap.org). 1 Interviews conducted as part of CGAP’s five Country-Level Savings Assessments, where review teams met with over 300 individuals knowledgeable about the financial system, indicate that these beliefs are widespread. 2 For more information on these findings see Rutherford 2003, Ruthven and Kumar 2002, the Financial Diaries Web site (www.financialdiaries.com), and Zeller and Sharma 2000. 3 Formal institutions are defined as those registered with the government. Generally, these include banks of all kinds; nonbank financial intermediaries, including microfinance institutions; and cooperatives licensed to take deposits. When not regulated or supervised, the latter are sometimes referred to as semi-formal.

Upload: dinhtram

Post on 14-Jul-2018

223 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

FocusNoteNO. 37 SEPTEMBER 2006

Building financial systems for the poor

Despite significant evidence to the contrary, many financial institution managers andpolicy makers do not believe poor people save money. They tend to assume that poorpeople are “too poor to save,” that they prefer to consume rather than save excessincome, or that when they do save it is only to access a loan.1

The numbers, however, paint a different picture. Research has repeatedly demon-strated that saving is central to poor people’s economic management strategies.Projects such as the Financial Diaries initiatives in India, Bangladesh, and South Africa;MicroSave in eastern and western Africa; and studies by the International Food PolicyResearch Institute, for example, have documented savings practices among the poor.2

What is unclear is how well formal financial institutions satisfy poor savers’ needs.Although over 90 percent of adults in industrialized economies typically have accounts infinancial institutions, market studies in some areas of the developing world indicate pen-etration rates as low as 6 percent. Access to savings services for the poor thus varies widely.

Understanding this variation and its root causes is the primary goal of CGAP’sCountry-Level Savings Assessments (see Box 1). The assessments explore opportuni-ties and constraints encountered by formal institutions in meeting demand for depositservices among the poor.3 This Focus Note summarizes the findings from Country-Level Savings Assessments in Benin, Bosnia, Mexico, the Philippines, and Uganda,which suggest five strategies for improving poor people’s access to savings services.

Although these five countries were chosen for the assessments, in part, because of theirdiversity, the findings of the assessments are strikingly similar in many ways. All five assess-ments found high demand for savings services but low usage of formal financial institu-tions, which lag behind informal savings mechanisms in fulfilling key client preferences.

Institutional capacity and incentives are the primary factors behind the inability of for-mal financial institutions to compete with informal savings approaches. However, sup-portive industry infrastructure and policy frameworks also play important roles.

SAFE AND ACCESSIBLE:

BRINGING POOR SAVERS INTO THE FORMAL FINANCIAL SYSTEM

The author of this Focus Note

is Rani Deshpande, a mico-

finance specialist at CGAP.

The author thanks Brigit Helms

for her guidance in writing this

note; Rich Rosenberg, Ousa

Sananikone, Jeanette

Thomas, and Elizabeth

Littlefield for their comments;

and Mark Pickens and

Jasmina Glisovic-Mezieres for

their editorial and research

assistance.

© 2006, Consultative Group to

Assist the Poor

The Consultative Group to

Assist the Poor (CGAP) is a

consortium of 33 development

agencies that support microfi-

nance. More information is

available on the CGAP Web

site (www.cgap.org).

1 Interviews conducted as part of CGAP’s five Country-Level Savings Assessments, where review teams met with over

300 individuals knowledgeable about the financial system, indicate that these beliefs are widespread.2 For more information on these findings see Rutherford 2003, Ruthven and Kumar 2002, the Financial Diaries Web site

(www.financialdiaries.com), and Zeller and Sharma 2000.3 Formal institutions are defined as those registered with the government. Generally, these include banks of all kinds;

nonbank financial intermediaries, including microfinance institutions; and cooperatives licensed to take deposits. When

not regulated or supervised, the latter are sometimes referred to as semi-formal.

2

Improving small deposit services, therefore, requireswork at all levels of the financial system.

Low Usage Does Not Mean Low Demand

The prevailing perception that poor people do notsave may stem from the low penetration of formalsavings mechanisms, the most common of whichare accounts in financial institutions. In Mexico,recent studies estimate that less than 25 percent ofthe urban population, and as little as 6 percent ofthe rural population, has any kind of account in afinancial institution (World Bank 2005 and WorldBank 2001). In the Philippines, only 12 percent ofsurvey respondents in small cities kept money in abank (Micro-Enterprise Bank and Karlan, Ashraf,and Wesley 2004). And in Uganda, only 10 per-cent of rural residents report using a financial insti-tution (Wright and Rippey 2003 and Pelrin andKabatalya 2005). Thus, low penetration rates offinancial institutions are evident regardless ofurban or rural distinctions.

Evidence suggests an enormous market fordeposit services among poor clients. In a few mar-kets, surveys have documented this demand. InBosnia, for example, Gallup International (2003)found that almost 40 percent of survey respondentsindicated that they wanted, but did not have, a bankaccount (see Figure 1). In a survey of Mexico Cityresidents, demand for interest-bearing accounts wasalmost unanimous among the unbanked (WorldBank 2003).

Because such market data are rare in low-incomecountries, demand often must be inferred in otherways. One indication of demand is the rapidgrowth in deposits among institutions that have

consciously targeted small deposits, a phenomenonobserved in market after market. In Benin, themicrofinance institution PAPME introduced volun-tary savings products in 2000 and saw depositsincrease over 20 times in five years even without anactive marketing campaign. In Mindanao, the poor-est region of Philippines, One Network Bankacquired 23,150 new depositors in three months byactively promoting an image of stability and goodmanagement to rural clients. And in Bosnia,ProCredit Bank doubled deposits in one year simplyby improving staff knowledge of available savingsproducts.

Another indicator of demand for deposit servicesis the extent of informal savings. A survey of ruralUgandans indicates that 89 percent save in cash, inkind, or in informal savings groups (as opposed toonly 12 percent who save in formal or semi-formalfinancial institutions) (Pelrine and Kabatalya 2005).Even employees of financial institutions are reported

Figure 1 Demand for bank accounts among Bosnian survey respondents

38%36%

26%

Have an account

Do not have account, do not want account

Do not have account, want account

CGAP’s Country-Level Savings Assessment methodology examines the obstacles and opportunities for improving smalldeposit mobilization in a particular market, and helps identify strategies to address them. Savings Assessments can beused as an input into design of particular programs or policies, or commissioned by groups of stakeholders to build industry-wide dialogue on the subject. For more information on the assessments, go to www.cgap.org/savings.

Box 1 Country-Level Savings Assessments: Purpose and Method

3

to operate their own rotating savings and credit asso-ciations among staff.

In the Philippines, one study suggests that two-thirds of people in smaller urban cities keep theirsavings at home (Karlan, Ashraf, and Wesley 2004).Informal savings are also widespread in Mexico,where another survey shows that 50 percent ofrural residents keep money at home. Respondentsalso reported keeping over 90 percent of their sav-ings in cash or in kind and less than 10 percent ondeposit in a financial institution (World Bank2001). In Mexico City, 28 percent of the unbankedand 40 percent of the banked hold some financialsavings outside of financial institutions (WorldBank 2003). Nationwide in Mexico, the level ofusage of informal instruments increases as educa-tion and income levels decrease (see Table 1).

Perhaps the most compelling evidence of demandfor deposit services comes from West Africa, whereclients routinely pay roving deposit collectors to holdtheir money. Just as the existence of moneylendersindicates a demand for credit among the poor, thewidespread use of informal savings mechanisms may

signal demand for formal deposit services. But to tapthat demand, formal services must offer clients amore attractive value proposition than what theyalready can access informally. Whether or not they cando so—at least with current service delivery models—is an open question.

How do formal savings services competewith the informal sector?

To compete with informal savings mechanisms,formal services must be appropriate for poor savers,satisfing key client preferences. Although these pref-erences vary from market to market, worldwide,low-income savers tend to care most about accessi-bility and security. Accessibility can be seen as physicalaccessibility (proximity) and financial accessibility(affordability). Accessibility also can be defined asliquidity, although studies indicate that poor clientshave both liquidity and illiquidity preferences (seeBox 2).

When formal and informal savings mechanisms arecompared on the key criteria of security, proximity,

Formal financial Informal financial Physical assets(represented by (Represented by (Grains, animals,

banks) tandas) construction materials)

TOTAL 27 20 29Income levelVery Low 10 11 42Low 22 19 32Medium 29 30 23Medium-high 53 23 24High 67 22 17

Table 1 Use of formal and informal savings mechanisms in Mexico(Percentage of respondents using respective mechanisms)

Source: Bolaño, Pilar Campos. 2005. El Ahorro Popular en México: Acumulando Activos para Superar la Pobreza. CIDAC and Miguel Angel Por-

Liquidity is often considered another key facet of accessibility and a priority for poor savers. Although this may be true for acertain set of clients—or a certain portion of most clients’ overall economic portfolios—market studies demonstrate demandfor a range of maturities.

For example, a study in Mexico found that a wide range of maturities is among the top three product features demanded byrural savers (World Bank 2001). A nationwide survey in Uganda found clients prefer making withdrawals monthly or quar-terly, but they want to make deposits more frequently, suggesting a preference for illiquidity (Pelrine and Kabatalya 2005).This may be related to the reasons for which clients saved, which were skewed heavily in favor of school fees and medicalexpenses. These were also the top two savings goals in a study of urban low-income Filipinos.

Box 2 Don’t poor people want liquidity?

4

and affordability, the reasons behind low usage of

formal services are clear.

Proximity

Informal mechanisms out compete formal financial

institutions when it comes to both dimensions of

accessibility. In terms of proximity, it is hard to beat

saving at home: cash stuffed into a mattress (or a

bamboo post in one’s house, as is done in the

Philippines) is always accessible and carries no extra

costs to the saver in terms of time or travel.

By contrast, formal deposit-taking institutions

can be very far away indeed. Because precise aver-

age distances are difficult to calculate, the Savings

Assessments used comparisons of branches, popu-

lation, and surface area as rough proxies. Figures

2a, 2b, and 2c illustrate the average number

of branches per population and square kilometer,

Benin Bosnia Mexico Philippines Uganda

0.005

0.016

0.005

0.026

0.005

-

0.005

0.010

0.015

0.020

0.025

0.030

Figure 2b Branches per square kilometer (regulated deposit-taking institutions)

Benin Bosnia Mexico Philippines Uganda

758

3,785

49303 191

-500

1,0001,5002,0002,5003,0003,5004,000

Figure 2c Branches/population/square kilometer (regulated deposit-taking institutions)

84

194

94

138

3850

100

150

200

250

Benin Bosnia Mexico Philippines Uganda

-

Figure 2a Branches per million inhabitants (regulated deposit-taking institutions)

5

separately and combined, across the countriesstudied. The tremendous variation in these num-bers shows little correlation to income level, withboth Mexico (annual per capita GNI of almost$7000) and Benin (annual per capita GNI under$300) scoring similarly.

Within countries, however, CGAP found a muchstronger relationship between income level and thedistribution of deposit-taking institutions. In thePhilippines, the correlation between the number ofsubsistence poor and the number of people perbranch of deposit-taking institutions in differentregions was 0.68. In Mexico, the correlationbetween the number of people per branch and thelevel of marginalization in different states was 0.62.4

Figures 3a and 3b illustrate this disparity ingreater detail. (See pages 6 and 7.) In parts ofMexico City, for example, population per branch isless than 3,000. However, in certain districts ofChiapas (Mexico’s poorest state), this ratio exceeds100,000. Several districts have no branches ofdeposit-taking institutions at all. Similar situationswere observed in Benin, Bosnia, the Philippines, andUganda; maps showing the distribution of branchesfor deposit-taking institutions in these countries areavailable in the Country-Level Savings Assessment

section of the Savings Information Resource Center(www.cgap.org/savings).

Affordability

Informal savings also tend to trump formal institu-tions in terms of price—even when they carry anexplicit cost, as in the case of deposit collectors inWest Africa. Typically, deposit collectors visit eachclient daily and collect a fixed amount, deductingone day’s deposit at the end of the month as theirservice fee. On an average-balance basis, thisamounts to a negative interest rate of 7 percent.

Although this fee seems steep, for most clients, itis still a better deal than using either local coopera-tives or banks. The travel cost to use either formalinstitution generally outweighs the interest rateadvantage, even without factoring in the value of theclient’s time. Figure 4 illustrates that a typical small-town resident of Benin would have to save morethan 10,000 FCFA (USD 20) per month beforeusing a cooperative made more financial sense thanusing a deposit collector. To make saving in a bankworthwhile, the client would have to save approxi-mately 100,000 FCFA (USD 200) per month.

4 Marginalization was measured according to a composite indicator es-

tablished by the government.

10%

0%

-10%

-20%

-30%

-40%

2,50

0

5,00

0

10,0

00

25,0

00

50,0

00

100,

000

250,

000

500,

000

1,00

0,00

0

1,50

0,00

0

2,00

0,00

0

2,50

0,00

0

5,00

0,00

0Figure 4 Net return on savings by mechanism (Benin)

Note: Calculations are based on costs faced by resident of typical small town in Benin. Assumptions: (1) Banquier ambulant (deposit collec-tor) collects 30 deposits per month for a fee equal to 1 daily deposit; (2) client makes weekly trips to local cooperative at a per trip cost of 150FCFA, cooperative pays no interest; (3) client makes monthly trips to the bank at a per trip cost of 5000 FCFA, bank pays 3.5% annual inter-est. See Helms, et al. 2005.

Banquier ambulant Cooperative Bank

Net

Ret

urn

Monthly Savings

Figure 3a Mexico penetration map

6

11

09

07

03

15

01

04

14

16

05

06

13

02

12

10

08

MEXICO

MEXICO

MORELOS

CAMPECHECAMPECHE

CHIAPASCHIAPAS

TABASCOTABASCO

OAXACAOAXACA

GUERREROGUERRERO

COLIMACOLIMA

JALISCOJALISCO

NAYARITNAYARIT

ZACATECASZACATECAS

TAMAULIPASTAMAULIPAS

NUEVONUEVOLEONLEON

C O A H U I L AC O A H U I L A

C H I H U A H U AC H I H U A H U ASONORASONORA

D U R A N G OD U R A N G O

SAN LUISSAN LUISPOTOSIPOTOSI

MICHOACANMICHOACAN PUEBLAPUEBLA

VERACRUZVERACRUZ YUCATANYUCATAN

QUINTANAQUINTANAROOROO

SIN

AL

OA

SI N

AL

OA

MazatlMazatláánn

TorreTorreóónnMatamorosMatamoros

LaredoLaredo

OjinagaOjinaga

Los MochisLos Mochis

NavojoaNavojoa

NogalesNogalesSanSan

FelipeFelipe

LoretoLoreto

SonoitaSonoita

AguaAguaPrietaPrieta

GuaymasGuaymas

TehuantepecTehuantepec

FronteraFrontera

VillahermosaVillahermosa

TuxtlaTuxtlaGutierrezGutierrez

OaxacaOaxaca

ChilpancingoChilpancingo

ColimaColima

GuadalajaraGuadalajara

TepicTepic

DurangoDurango

SaltSaltííllollo

ChihuahuaChihuahua

CuliacCuliacáánn

HermosilloHermosillo

MexicaliMexicali

GuanajuatoGuanajuato

PachucaPachuca

AguascalientesAguascalientes

QuerQueréétarotaro

MoreliaMorelia

TolucaToluca

CuernavacaCuernavaca PueblaPuebla

TlaxcalaTlaxcala

JalapaJalapa

San LuisSan LuisPotosPotosíí

CiudadCiudadVictVictóóriaria

ZacatecasZacatecas

MonterreyMonterrey

MEXICOMEXICOCITYCITY

YYaaqquu ii

RRiiooBBrraavvoo

FFuueerrttee

SSaallaaddoo

LLeerrmm

aa

BBaall ssaass

UUssuummaacciinnttaa

CCoonncchhooss

BAJABAJACALIFORNIACALIFORNIA

BAJABAJACALIFORNIACALIFORNIA

SURSUR

MEXICOMEXICO

MORELOSMORELOS

DISTRITO FEDERALDISTRITO FEDERAL

HIDALGOHIDALGOGUANAJUATOGUANAJUATO

AGUASCALIENTESAGUASCALIENTES

TLAXCALATLAXCALA

QUERQUERÉÉTAROTARO

RioGrande

GUAGUATEMALATEMALA

CAMPECHE

CHIAPAS

TABASCO

OAXACA

GUERRERO

COLIMA

JALISCO

NAYARIT

ZACATECAS

TAMAULIPAS

NUEVOLEON

C O A H U I L A

C H I H U A H U A

BAJACALIFORNIA

BAJACALIFORNIA

SUR

SONORA

D U R A N G O

SAN LUISPOTOSI

MICHOACAN

MEXICO

MORELOS

DISTRITO FEDERAL

PUEBLA

HIDALGOVERACRUZ

GUANAJUATO

AGUASCALIENTES

TLAXCALA

YUCATAN

QUINTANAROO

SIN

AL

OA

QUERÉTARO

Tapachula

PuertoEscondido

Acapulco

PuertoVallerta

Mazatlán

TorreónMatamoros

Laredo

Ojinaga

Los Mochis

Navojoa

Nogales

Ensanada

Tijuana

SanFelipe

SantaRosalia

Loreto

Cabo San Lucas

Sonoita

AguaPrieta

Ciudad Juárez

Guaymas

Veracruz

Tampico

Tehuantepec

Cozumel

Cancun

Frontera

Chetumal

Merida

Villahermosa

Campeche

TuxtlaGutierrez

Oaxaca

Chilpancingo

Colima

Guadalajara

Tepic

Durango

Saltíllo

Chihuahua

Culiacán

Hermosillo

Mexicali

La Paz

Guanajuato

Pachuca

Aguascalientes

Querétaro

Morelia

Toluca

Cuernavaca Puebla

Tlaxcala

Jalapa

San LuisPotosí

CiudadVictória

Zacatecas

Monterrey

MEXICOCITY

UNITED STATES OF AMERICA

GUATEMALA

BELIZE

HONDURAS

ELSALVADOR

Yaqui

RioGrande

RioBravo

Fuerte

Salado

Lerm

a

Bal sas

Usumacinta

Conchos

PACIFICOCEAN

Gulf of Mexico

Bay of Campeche

Gulf ofTehuantepec

Gulf of

Honduras

Gu

l fo

fC

al i f o

r ni a

115°W

30°N30°N

25°N

15°N

25°N

20°N

15°N

110°W

110°W

105° 001W ° 59W ° 09W °W

105° 001W ° 59W °W

85°W

115°W

Area of map

DELEGATIONS:01020304050607080910111213141516

This map was produced by the Map Design Unit of The World Bank.The boundaries, colors, denominations and any other informationshown on this map do not imply, on the part of The World BankGroup, any judgment on the legal status of any territory, or anyendorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

> 15.001

12.001 - 15.000

9.001 - 12.000

6.001 - 9.000

3.001 - 6.000

0 - 3.000

POPULATION PER FINANCIALINSTITUTION BRANCH*:

STATE BOUNDARY

DELEGATION BOUNDARY

Alvaro ObregónAzcapotzalcoBenito JuárezCoyoacánCuajimalpa de MorelosCuauhtémocGustavo A. MaderoIztacalcoIztapalapaLa Magdalena ContrerasMiguel HidalgoMilpa AltaTláhuacTlalpanXochimilcoVenustiano Carranza

Sources: INEGI, Bansefi, FONAES, ABM, Caja Libertad, Caja Popular Mexicana,Compartamos and FinComun.

Notes: Number of financial institution branches as of 2004 and population data from2000 National Census.

* The best information available from the sources cited was used tocreate the maps, some unregulated small local institutions may not beincluded.

MEXICOFEDERAL DISTRICT

POPULATION PER FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONALBRANCH

7

TU

XT

LA G

UT

IER

RE

Z

Tap

ach

ula

Co

mit

an

de

Do

min

gu

ez

Sa

n C

rist

ob

al

de

las

Ca

sas

Cin

talp

a d

eF

igu

ero

a

Vill

a F

lore

s

Ton

ala

02

03

09

10

15

16

23

28

30

31

34

36

37

38

41

46

48

49

5556

57

65

67

69

7376 77

78

80

82

84

90

95

96

98

100

103

105

108

109

113

114

115

116

117

5351

111 12

26

6033

07

1150

112

6261

110

89

01

92

66

106

2487

118

441954

2263 10

240

72

2005

86

7418

3247

79 75 9425

101

70

3597

214345 93

06

4239

8110

410

7

52

17 27

91

148568

99

71

29

02

03

09

10

15

16

23

28

30

31

34

36

37

38

41

46

48

49

5556

57

65

67

69

7376 77

78

80

82

84

90

95

96

98

100

103

105

108

109

113

114

115

116

117

5351

111 12

26

6033

07

1150

112

6261

110

89

01

92

66

106

2487

118

441954

2263 10

240

72

2005

86

7418

3247

79 75 9425

101

70

3597

214345 93

06

4239

8110

410

7

52

17 27

91

148568

99

71

29

TA

BA

SC

O

VE

RA

CR

UZ

OA

XA

CA

GUATEMALA

ALA

META

UG

PA

CIF

IC

OC

EA

N

CA

MP

EC

HE

CA

MP

EC

HE

TA

BA

SC

OT

AB

AS

CO

OA

XA

CA

OA

XA

CA

GU

ER

RE

RO

GU

ER

RE

RO

CO

LIM

AC

OLI

MA

JALI

SC

OJA

LIS

CO

NA

YA

RIT

NA

YA

RIT

ZA

CA

TE

CA

SZ

AC

AT

EC

AS

TA

MA

ULI

PA

ST

AM

AU

LIP

AS

NU

EV

ON

UE

VO

LEO

NLE

ON

CO

AH

UIL

AC

OA

HU

ILA

CH

IHU

AH

UA

CH

IHU

AH

UA

SO

NO

RA

SO

NO

RA

DU

RA

NG

OD

UR

AN

GO

SA

N L

UIS

SA

N L

UIS

PO

TO

SI

PO

TO

SI

MIC

HO

AC

AN

MIC

HO

AC

AN

PU

EB

LAP

UE

BLA

VE

RA

CR

UZ

VE

RA

CR

UZ

YU

CA

TA

NY

UC

AT

AN

QU

INT

AN

AQ

UIN

TA

NA

RO

OR

OO

S I NA L O

A

S I NA L O

A

Ma

zatl

Ma

zatláá

nn

To

rre

To

rreóó

nnM

ata

mo

ros

Ma

tam

oro

s

La

red

oL

are

do

Ojin

ag

aO

jina

ga

Lo

s M

och

isL

os

Mo

chis

Na

vojo

aN

avo

joa

No

ga

les

No

ga

les

Sa

nS

an

Fe

lipe

Fe

lipe

Lo

reto

Lo

reto

So

no

ita

So

no

ita

Ag

ua

Ag

ua

Pri

eta

Pri

eta

Gu

aym

as

Gu

aym

as

Te

hu

an

tep

ec

Te

hu

an

tep

ec

Fro

nte

raF

ron

tera

Vill

ah

erm

osa

Vill

ah

erm

osa

Tu

xtla

Tu

xtla

Gu

tie

rre

zG

uti

err

ez

Oa

xaca

Oa

xaca

Ch

ilpa

nci

ng

oC

hilp

an

cin

go

Co

lima

Co

lima

Gu

ad

ala

jara

Gu

ad

ala

jara

Te

pic

Te

pic

Du

ran

go

Du

ran

go

Sa

ltS

altíí

llollo

Ch

ihu

ah

ua

Ch

ihu

ah

ua

Cu

liac

Cu

liacáá

nn

He

rmo

sillo

He

rmo

sillo

Me

xica

liM

exi

cali

Gu

an

aju

ato

Gu

an

aju

ato

Pa

chu

caP

ach

uca

Ag

ua

sca

lien

tes

Ag

ua

sca

lien

tes

Qu

er

Qu

eréé

taro

taro

Mo

relia

Mo

relia

To

luca

To

luca

Cu

ern

ava

caC

ue

rna

vaca

Pu

eb

laP

ue

bla

Tla

xca

laT

laxc

alaJa

lap

aJa

lap

a

Sa

n L

uis

Sa

n L

uis

Po

tos

Po

tosíí

Ciu

da

dC

iud

ad

Vic

tV

ictóó

ria

ria

Za

cate

cas

Za

cate

cas

Mo

nte

rre

yM

on

terr

ey

ME

XIC

OM

EX

ICO

CIT

YC

ITY

YYaaqquuii

RRii

oo BBrraavvoo

FFuueerr

tt ee

SSaallaa

ddoo

LLeerrmmaa

BBaallss

aass

UUssuu

mmaacc

iinnttaa

CCoonncc

hhooss

BA

JAB

AJA

CA

LIF

OR

NIA

CA

LIF

OR

NIA

BA

JAB

AJA

CA

LIF

OR

NIA

CA

LIF

OR

NIA

SU

RS

UR

ME

XIC

OM

EX

ICO

MO

RE

LOS

MO

RE

LOS

DIS

TR

ITO

FE

DE

RA

LD

IST

RIT

O F

ED

ER

AL

HID

ALG

OH

IDA

LGO

GU

AN

AJU

AT

OG

UA

NA

JUA

TO

AG

UA

SC

ALI

EN

TE

SA

GU

AS

CA

LIE

NT

ES

TLA

XC

ALA

TLA

XC

ALA

QU

ER

QU

ERÉÉ

TA

RO

TA

RO

Rio Gra

nde

GU

AG

UAT

EM

ALA

TE

MA

LA

CA

MP

EC

HE

TA

BA

SC

O

OA

XA

CA

GU

ER

RE

RO

CO

LIM

A

JALI

SC

O

NA

YA

RIT

ZA

CA

TE

CA

S

TA

MA

ULI

PA

S

NU

EV

OLE

ON

CO

AH

UIL

A

CH

IHU

AH

UA

BA

JAC

ALI

FO

RN

IA

BA

JAC

ALI

FO

RN

IAS

UR

SO

NO

RA

DU

RA

NG

O

SA

N L

UIS

PO

TO

SI

MIC

HO

AC

AN

ME

XIC

O

MO

RE

LOS

DIS

TR

ITO

FE

DE

RA

L

PU

EB

LA

HID

ALG

OV

ER

AC

RU

ZG

UA

NA

JUA

TO

AG

UA

SC

ALI

EN

TE

S

TLA

XC

ALA

YU

CA

TA

N

QU

INT

AN

AR

OO

S I NA L O

A

QU

ER

ÉT

AR

O

Ta

pa

chu

la

Pu

ert

oE

sco

nd

ido

Aca

pu

lco

Pu

ert

oV

alle

rta

Ma

zatl

án

To

rre

ón

Ma

tam

oro

s

La

red

o

Ojin

ag

a

Lo

s M

och

is

Na

vojo

a

No

ga

les

En

san

ad

a

Tiju

an

a

Sa

nF

elip

e

Sa

nta

Ro

salia Lo

reto

Ca

bo

Sa

n L

uca

s

So

no

ita

Ag

ua

Pri

eta

Ciu

da

d J

rez

Gu

aym

as

Ve

racr

uz

Ta

mp

ico

Te

hu

an

tep

ec

Co

zum

el

Ca

ncu

n

Fro

nte

ra

Ch

etu

ma

l

Me

rid

a

Vill

ah

erm

osa

Ca

mp

ech

e

Tu

xtla

Gu

tie

rre

z

Oa

xaca

Ch

ilpa

nci

ng

o

Co

lima

Gu

ad

ala

jara

Te

pic

Du

ran

go

Sa

ltíl

lo

Ch

ihu

ah

ua

Cu

liacá

n

He

rmo

sillo

Me

xica

li

La

Pa

z

Gu

an

aju

ato

Pa

chu

ca

Ag

ua

sca

lien

tes

Qu

eré

taro

Mo

relia

To

luca

Cu

ern

ava

caP

ue

bla

Tla

xca

laJala

pa

Sa

n L

uis

Po

tosí

Ciu

da

dV

ictó

ria

Za

cate

cas

Mo

nte

rre

y

ME

XIC

OC

ITY

UN

ITE

D S

TA

TE

S O

F A

ME

RIC

A

GU

AT

EM

ALA

BE

LIZ

E

HO

ND

UR

AS

EL

SA

LVA

DO

R

Yaqui

Rio Gra

nde

Ri

o Bravo

Fuer

t e

Sala

do

Lerma

Bals

as

Usu

mac

inta

Conc

hos

PA

CIF

IC

OC

EA

N

Gu

lf o

f M

ex

ico

Bay

of C

ampe

che

Gul

f of

Tehu

ante

pec

Gul

f of

Hon

dura

s

G u l f o fC

a l if o r n i a

115

°W

30°N

30°N

25°N

15°N

25°N

20°N

15°N

110

°W

110

° W

105

°0

01W

°5 9

0 9W

° W

105

°0

01W

°5

9W

°W

85°W

115

°W

CH

IAP

AS

The

bou

ndar

ies,

col

ors,

den

omin

atio

ns a

nd a

ny o

ther

info

rmat

ion

show

n on

this

map

do

not i

mpl

y, o

n th

e pa

rt o

f The

Wor

ld B

ank

Gro

up, a

ny ju

dgm

ent o

n th

e le

gal s

tatu

s of

any

terr

itory

, or

any

endo

rsem

ent o

r ac

cept

ance

of s

uch

boun

darie

s.

PO

PU

LA

TIO

N P

ER

FIN

AN

CIA

LIN

ST

ITU

TIO

N B

RA

NC

H*:

N

O F

INA

NC

IAL

IN

ST

ITU

TIO

N B

RA

NC

HE

S

>

10

0.0

01

5

0.0

01

- 1

00

.00

0

2

0.0

01

- 5

0.0

00

1

- 2

0.0

00

020

4060

KIL

OM

ET

ER

S

ME

XIC

O

STA

TE

OF

CH

IAP

AS

PO

PU

LA

TIO

N P

ER

FIN

AN

CIA

L I

NS

TIT

UT

ION

AL

BR

AN

CH

ST

AT

E C

AP

ITA

L

SE

LE

CT

ED

CIT

IES

MU

NIC

IPA

L B

OU

ND

AR

IES

ST

AT

E B

OU

ND

AR

IES

INT

ER

NA

TIO

NA

L B

OU

ND

AR

IES

01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22

Sou

rces

: IN

EG

I, B

anse

fi, F

ON

AE

S, A

BM

, Caj

a Li

bert

ad, C

aja

Pop

ular

Mex

ican

a, C

ompa

rtam

os a

nd F

inC

omun

.

Not

es: N

umbe

r of

fina

ncia

l ins

titut

ion

bran

ches

as

of 2

004

and

popu

latio

n da

ta fr

om 2

000

Nat

iona

l Cen

sus.

* T

he b

est i

nfor

mat

ion

avai

labl

e fr

om th

e so

urce

s ci

ted

was

use

d to

crea

te th

e m

aps,

som

e un

regu

late

d sm

all l

ocal

inst

itutio

ns m

ay n

ot b

ein

clud

ed.

MU

NIC

IPA

LIT

IES

:

66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77 78 79 80 81 82 83 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 100

101

102

103

104

105

106

107

108

109

110

111

112

113

114

115

116

117

118

23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44

45 46 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65

Aca

coya

gua

Aca

laA

cape

tahu

aA

ldam

aA

ltam

irano

Am

atán

Am

aten

ango

de

la F

ront

era

Am

aten

ango

del

Val

leA

ngel

Alb

ino

Cor

zoA

rria

gaB

ejuc

al d

e O

cam

poB

ella

Vis

taB

enem

érito

de

las

Am

éric

asB

errio

zába

lB

ochi

lC

acah

oatá

nC

ataz

ajá

Cha

lchi

huitá

nC

ham

ula

Cha

nal

Cha

pulte

nang

oC

hena

lhó

Chi

apa

de C

orzo

Chi

apill

aC

hico

asén

Chi

com

usel

oC

hiló

nC

inta

lapa

Coa

pilla

Com

itán

de D

omín

guez

Cop

aina

láE

l Bos

que

El P

orve

nir

Esc

uint

laF

ranc

isco

Leó

nF

ront

era

Com

alap

aF

ront

era

Hid

algo

Hue

huet

ánH

uitiu

pán

Hui

xtán

Hui

xtla

Ixhu

atán

Ixta

com

itán

Ixta

pa

Ixta

pang

ajoy

aJi

quip

ilas

Jito

tol

Juár

ezLa

Con

cord

iaLa

Gra

ndez

aLa

Inde

pend

enci

aLa

Lib

erta

dLa

Trin

itaria

Larr

áinz

arLa

s M

arga

ritas

Las

Ros

asM

apas

tepe

cM

arav

illa

Ten

ejap

aM

arqu

és d

e C

omill

asM

azap

a de

Mad

ero

Maz

atán

Met

apa

Mito

ntic

Mon

tecr

isto

de

Gue

rrer

oM

otoz

intla

Nic

olás

Ruí

zO

cosi

ngo

Oco

tepe

cO

cozo

coau

tla d

e E

spin

osa

Ost

uacá

nO

sum

acin

taO

xchu

cP

alen

que

Pan

telh

óP

ante

pec

Pic

huca

lco

Piji

jiapa

nP

uabl

o N

uevo

Sol

ista

huac

ánR

ayón

Ref

orm

aS

aban

illa

Sal

to d

e A

gua

San

And

rés

Dur

azna

lS

an C

ristó

bal d

e la

s C

asas

San

Fer

nand

oS

an J

uan

Can

cuc

San

Luc

asS

antia

go e

l Pin

alS

iltep

ecS

imoj

ovel

Sita

láS

ocol

tena

ngo

Sol

osuc

hiap

aS

oyal

óS

uchi

apa

Suc

hiat

eS

unua

paT

apac

hula

Tap

alap

aT

apilu

laT

ecpa

tán

Ten

ejap

aT

eopi

sca

Tila

Ton

alá

Tot

olap

aT

umba

láT

uxtla

Chi

coT

uxtla

Gut

iérr

ezT

uzan

tán

Tzi

mol

Uni

ón J

uáre

zV

enus

tiano

Car

ranz

aV

illa

Com

altit

lán

Vill

a C

orzo

Vill

aflo

res

Yaj

alón

Zin

acan

tán

Figure 3b Mexico penetration map

8

These minimum amounts are equivalent to 12 daysand 120 days, respectively, of minimum wage inBenin. Given that many people in Benin earn farless than the minimum wage, formal savings serv-ices are beyond the reach of many poor people.

Formal financial institutions tended to pricethemselves out of the market for poor people’s sav-ings across the markets studied by CGAP. The“threshold costs” of basic deposit products—i.e.,the amount of money needed for opening fees,minimum balances, and shares, in the case of coop-eratives—were often many times what poor peoplecould afford. This was especially true in safer, regu-lated institutions, such as banks.

In CGAP’s analysis, “basic deposit products”were defined as the lowest-cost savings or transactionaccount in a given institution. Because of minimumbalance requirements for other products, thesedemand deposit or current accounts are often thefirst or only type of account poor clients can afford.

CGAP’s research found that threshold costs tendto decrease as branch density (the number ofbranches per population) increases. Across thecountries studied, the correlation between thresh-old costs (measured as a multiple of minimumwage) and population per branch was -0.78 for alldeposit-taking institutions. The correlation wasstronger (-0.83) when only bank branches wereconsidered (see Appendix 2). Although based on alimited sample of countries, the results support theexpectation that competition brings down price.

Security

Although informal options have advantages overfinancial institutions based on proximity and afford-ability, comparisons between informal and formaloptions based on security are less conclusive. Depositcollectors are rarely subject to regulation or supervi-sion, and reports of them absconding with client sav-ings are common. Saving at home carries its ownrisks, such as theft or loss from fire or flood. Butbanks also fail. In fact, every one of the markets stud-ied by CGAP had suffered a banking system crisis inthe past 10–20 years—well within the memory of the

current generation of savers, with the expectedimpact on client confidence. Still, the most thoroughstudy of security in informal savings to date indicatesthat informal mechanisms are far riskier than evenunsupervised deposit-taking institutions (Wright andMutesasira 2002).

Ironically, security often emerges as savers’ top pri-ority in surveys of low-income clients. Why, then, dopoor clients seem to prefer informal to formal sav-ings? Behavioral finance suggests that familiar risks orthose perceived to be under an individual’s controltend to be underestimated compared with risks thatare unfamiliar or perceived to be not within a per-son’s control (Hertwig et al. 2004). The risk inher-ent in saving at home, with a trusted depositcollector, or in livestock that one has been tendingsince childhood, may thus be underestimated com-pared with the risk of saving in an unfamiliar institu-tion with opaque management. Because importantmeasures of security in a formal institution—such asloan losses—are not directly observable, it is easy forclients to misjudge the relative security of informalversus formal savings options. Given the widespreadabsence of systems to signal institutional soundness,comparing the security of different formal institu-tions is also a challenge for customers.

Trade-offs between security and accessibility

Often, financial institutions that are most accessibleto poor clients—especially in rural areas—are lesssecure (in terms of financial soundness and there-fore risk to savings) than institutions that targetwealthier clientele. In the Philippines, for example,rural banks have higher nonperforming loan ratiosthan either thrift or commercial banks. In Uganda,the average reported portfolio at risk (PAR) greaterthan 30 days in savings and credit cooperatives(SACCOs) reach as high as 42 percent, comparedwith single digits for regulated institutions.5

However, these regulated institutions are seldomlocated outside primary and secondary cities.

5 PAR 30 equals the outstanding balance of loans with any payment more

than 30 days late, divided by the outstanding balance of all loans.

9

Reliable data are seldom available for institu-tions serving the poor. In Uganda, PAR data areavailable for only 147 SACCOs out of an estimatedtotal of 750–900 currently active in the country. Inthe Philippines, even the total number of financialcooperatives in operation is unknown. The onlyperformance data available come from a smallnumber of co-ops selected for a donor-fundedtechnical assistance project because of their prom-ise for improvement. At the time of entry into thisproject in 1997, their collective PAR 30 was 54.6percent (although by 2005 this had declined to8.76 percent).

No single type of deposit-taking institution gen-erally offers low-income clients security, proximity,and affordability. Therefore, clients tend to usesavings instruments whose advantages they can seeand that they can access. Proximity and affordabil-ity—features offered par excellence by informalmechanisms—are clearly visible to clients. Lack ofsecurity is not. Poor savers may thus be sacrificingwhat they most value in a deposit service—secu-rity—by using informal mechanisms that provideclear evidence of proximity and affordability but donot necessarily provide security. Conversely, formalinstitutions that offer secure savings opportunitieshave difficulty penetrating the savings market forpoor clients because they tend to be inaccessible topoor clients.

Why Can’t Formal InstitutionsCompete?

Why do so few formal financial institutions offerboth security and access to poor savers? CGAP’sSavings Assessments have identified a constellationof causes at three levels of the financial system.

Inadequate management capacity and

high cost structure

The skills needed to manage savings programs aredifferent, and often more sophisticated, than thoseneeded to run credit programs. Capable manage-ment, staff, and systems are crucial for mobilizingsavings. But high-capacity management often car-

ries a high price tag, and institutions that operate inpoor and rural areas usually need to maintain a lowcost structure.

To be able to afford high-capacity management,institutions, such as cooperatives, need to achieveeconomies of scale. Some institutions achieveeconomies of scale by consolidating and becomingbranches of a single “mother cooperative.” Theconsolidation of 60 independent cooperatives tobecome Caja Popular Mexicana is an example of asuccessful transformation. Between 2001 and 2005,Caja Popular Mexicana saw capital adequacyincrease by three times, operating expenses halved,delinquency fall by two-thirds, and assets and mem-bership double. However, this transformation tooksome 15 years of work by the consolidating creditunions and $4 million in donor funds for skilled,credible technical assistance providers.

Institutions that already have the capacity tosafely manage deposits need to focus on loweringdelivery costs to be able to serve low-income mar-kets. Advancements in technology have made indus-try professionals enthusiastic about the potential ofdeveloping technology-enabled channels to lowercosts for delivering services, including deposits.Unfortunately, this type of cost-cutting itself mayrequire substantial up-front investment.

In Uganda, one micro-deposit-taking institutionestimates that it has invested $200,000 in develop-ing a system using smart cards and point-of-sale ter-minals (in addition to considerable investment bypublic and private donors). Despite this investment,the new system has yet to be rolled out at scale.

Another strategy increasingly used by banks tolower service delivery costs is to take advantage ofretail infrastructure that is already in place. InMexico, one bank established mini-branches insidea network of appliance stores and was able to open4 million savings accounts in two years—moreaccounts than the entire “popular finance” sector,with comparable average balances.6

6 The “popular finance” or finanzas populares sector in Mexico refers to

institutions, such as MFIs and cooperatives, that serve the traditionally

unbanked.

In the Philippines, Banco de Oro enablescashiers at a major retailer to act as service pointsfor the bank’s main mass-market product, a reload-able payroll and debit card. In two years, this prod-uct mobilized $5.6 million in balances on 700,000cards in force (in a country with a working popula-tion of about 50 million). In both the Mexican andFilipino cases, the bank and cooperating retailer areowned by the same parent company.

Few outlets for excess liquidity

Excess liquidity in financial institutions limits incen-tives to mobilize additional deposits—especially poorpeople’s deposits, which tend to be perceived apriori as short term, unstable, and costly. Unfortu-nately, regulated financial institutions in manymarkets already have more than enough depositsrelative to lending or investment opportunities,especially in the short term. At the time of thePhilippines CGAP assessment, for example, savingsin banks were 150 percent of bank loans to theprivate sector. In Benin, the proportion was roughlysimilar. In Bosnia, although the banking system wasslightly under-liquid overall, excess liquidity wasconcentrated in the short term (under one year),with 60 percent of deposits against only 25 percentof loans.7

At the institutional level, excess liquidity may becaused by a lack of suitable lending opportunities(real or perceived). Especially among banks, demandfor on-lending funds can be limited, particularly incountries where government debt is not an attrac-tive investment opportunity.

Although particular institutions may betemporarily under- or over-liquid, in developedcountries these imbalances are usually corrected byliquidity management mechanisms. However, manydeveloping-country markets lack these liquiditymanagement mechanisms. Even Bosnia, which is, bysome measures, the most advanced financial systemstudied by CGAP, lacks overnight markets, repur-chase agreements, and other tools commonly usedby banks to manage liquidity.8

Lack of liquidity management mechanisms wasespecially common among cooperatives, perhapsbecause of the fear of spreading risk from badlymanaged to well-managed co-ops. The disincentive tosavings mobilization posed by excess liquidity in coop-eratives can be especially damaging for poor clients,because co-ops tend to be more accessible than othertypes of institutions. Better liquidity managementtools would make deposits more attractive.

In Uganda, stakeholders are considering ways toplace excess co-op liquidity in regulated institutionsthat offer safe, remunerative investments—or directlyinto Ugandan government bonds, which offer attrac-tive rates. Either option is less risky than encouragingthese cooperatives to ramp up lending (especiallyuncollateralized lending like microcredit) in light oftheir high loan delinquency rates.

Unfair competition from “cheap and easy”

wholesale funds

Unfortunately, deposit mobilization often is discour-aged by wholesale financing from apexes (usuallygovernment owned). In countries as diverse asUganda and the Philippines, donors and govern-ments provide millions of dollars in wholesalefinancing to deposit-taking institutions that areamong the most accessible to poor clients (SACCOsin Uganda and rural banks in the Philippines).

Second-tier financing in both Uganda and thePhilippines is at near-market rates, so the funds arenot as cheap as they could be. Still, relatively easyaccess to wholesale funds has served as a disincentivefor financial institutions to pursue additional depositsto finance portfolio growth. If these funds werecrowding out deposits in shaky institutions, thismight be considered a benefit to savers. However,

10

7 Nor were excess funds being soaked up by treasury bonds. In the

Philippines, these were returning around the same rate as inflation; in

Benin, government bond issues were extremely uncommon; and in

Bosnia, the government is currently prohibited from issuing sovereign

debt.8 Foreign-owned banks in Bosnia can alleviate excess short-term liquid-

ity by sending short-term deposits abroad to their parent banks in re-

turn for longer-term lines of credit. But most financial institutions do

not have this option.

11

ally, access to the payment system is restricted tomore highly regulated institutions and often requiresa hefty security deposit with the payments clearing-house. Payment systems are, in fact, often owned bylarge banks. These attributes tend to put access topayments systems beyond the reach of small financialinstitutions that cater to the poor. The inability ofthese institutions to make clients’ savings accessiblein multiple locations or to provide payments servicesmakes depositing with them less attractive.

However, a new breed of payments providerpromises to make payment services more widelyavailable. Some of these providers use mobile phoneslinked to bank accounts for domestic and interna-tional money transfers, purchases, loan repayments,and cash withdrawals. Often these transactionsinvolve a debit card and a network of point-of-saledevices located in financial institutions and retailestablishments (see Box 3) (Ivatury 2006).

the logic of wholesale funders leads them to channelfunds to the strongest, not the weakest, institutions.Incentives are therefore dampened for the very insti-tutions best able to safeguard client deposits.

A common rationale for second-tier credit lines isthe mismatch that sometimes exists between financialinstitution over-liquidity in the short term and under-liquidity in the longer term. But often, short-termfunds are much more stable than commonly thoughtand could be used for longer-term lending. Occasion-ally, regulation also can underestimate the stability ofshort-term deposits: in Bosnia, 95 percent of depositsunder 30 days must be lent out for the same term—a very limited market in a country with no overnightinterbank lending.

Incomplete payment systems

Access to the payment system can greatly affect aninstitution’s ability to capture deposits. Tradition-

Banks are increasingly teaming up with retailers and mobile phone providers to offer financial services, including paymentsand deposits, to poor customers. In Brazil, six banks have built a network of over 26,000 banking correspondents: mer-chants equipped with card-reading devices that customers can use to open accounts and make transactions.

To make a deposit, customers identify themselves by swiping their card and giving cash to the retailer. The bank transfersthe corresponding amount from the retailer’s account to the customer’s account. The clerk keeps the cash received in thetill and issues a receipt to the customer (see diagram below). Largely because of the increase in banking correspondents,by the end of 2003, banking services were available in all of Brazil’s more than 5,600 municipalities.

Similar services are being introduced elsewhere. In the Philippines, Globe Telecom offers G-Cash, a service that lets sub-scribers load cash onto their mobile phones via affiliated merchants or Globe outlets, and then use it to make internationalor domestic money transfers, pay bills, or make purchases. The service is usually operated like a “virtual wallet,” with nobank involved. However, Globe is partnering with a growing number of rural banks to enable clients to receive and repayloans via G-Cash. Mobile phone banking also is making inroads in South Africa, where a joint venture between StandardBank and mobile phone provider MTN has acquired more than 100,000 customers since 2004.

Box 3 Bypassing the payments system

Customer Retailer

Customer swipes card and gives cash to retailer

Retailer issues receipt to customer

xxxxx

XXXXXxxxxxxx

Bank

Bank transfer fundsto customer’s

account

Bank transfersfunds from

retailer’s account

Uneven regulation and supervision

Regulation and supervision, which can be highlyrestrictive for some types of institutions and looseor nonexistent for others, can perpetuate a situationwhere safe institutions have few incentives to pur-sue poor depositors, and accessible institutions can-not guarantee the safety of deposits.

Postal banks are a case in point. In many markets,they maintain some of the most extensive networksof service points for deposit taking, and they offerpayment services. However, many postal banks arenot subject to banking regulation. Because they areconsidered part of the postal service, their assets areat risk of leakage into loss-making postal systems.This is the case with Caisse Nationale d’Epargne, thepostal savings bank in Benin that is in the process ofseparating from the postal service.

Policy frameworks are often inappropriate forfinancial cooperatives as well. In Uganda, for exam-ple, SACCOs are not governed by dedicated legisla-tion. They operate under a variety of legal regimes,including the Cooperatives, Companies, and NGOActs. In many countries, they are not monitored byappropriate financial regulators, but rather by agen-cies in charge of all cooperatives. In Uganda, this isthe Ministry of Tourism, Trade, and Industry, whichis widely acknowledged to lack the capacity to super-vise the 1400 SACCOs currently registered.

Where a dedicated agency for cooperatives doesexist, as in the Philippines, that agency typically ischarged with promoting cooperatives as well asmonitoring them, resulting in a conflict of interestthat can weaken the supervisory function.Delegating supervision to membership-based feder-ations also can produce a conflict of interest, becausemember institutions may seek to leave the federationto avoid strict supervision. In Mexico, where multi-ple federations have been set up to supervise coop-eratives, institutions have reportedly switched theirmemberships to avoid possible sanctions.

For other types of institutions, regulation and su-pervision can be so strict that it ensures the securityof deposits, but limits outreach. In Mexico, bankingregulations that mandate expensive infrastructure re-

12

quirements discourage rural branches. A similar phe-nomenon is at work in Uganda, where investmentsrequired by the new Micro-Deposit Taking Institu-tions (MDI) Act have at least temporarily slowedbranch expansion among newly regulated MDIs.9 Bydriving up costs, these regulations can limit safer in-stitutions to wealthier areas. Worldwide efforts tocombat money laundering and the financing of ter-rorism are also threatening to make small transac-tions unviable for financial institutions.10

In addition, partnerships that could help safeinstitutions extend their outreach are often discour-aged by financial regulators in the name of safety. InBosnia and Uganda, for example, regulators recov-ering from recent systemic crises have prohibitedagency relationships that would allow unregulatedinstitutions to handle transactions on behalf of reg-ulated ones.

It would be irresponsible to suggest that regula-tions like these be loosened without careful analysisof the implications of such a change. Strict regula-tion and supervision is, after all, part of the reasonthat safe institutions are safe. Nor is strict regulationand supervision the primary bottleneck to extend-ing quality deposit services to the poor. Evidencefor this can be found in countries like Uganda,where significant donor and government invest-ments in creating a separate regulatory category forMDIs has not yet led to significant increases in out-reach.

Furthermore, there is a legitimate place for unsu-pervised deposit-taking institutions in the financialsystem, specifically for those that take only depositsfrom members and are too small to supervise costefficiently (where supervision costs are measuredagainst the institution’s assets). Research in Ugandashows that even unsupervised institutions tend tobe safer than informal savings options (Wright andMutasesira 2002).

9 The 2004 MDI Act allows a limited number of MFIs that meet high

performance thresholds to transform into regulated financial intermedi-

aries supervised by the Bank of Uganda.10 For more information, see Isern et al. 2005.

Strategies for Supporting Small-BalanceSavings Mobilization

What can be done to help financial institutions pro-vide both safe and accessible deposit services?CGAP’s Country-Level Savings Assessments iden-tifies five strategies that could alleviate key demand-and supply-side constraints. Although the impor-tance of specific constraints varies from country tocountry, the strategies developed are relevant toalmost all of the five markets studied.

Document the market. Generating solid dataon the size of the low-income market and clientpreferences for deposit services provides institu-tions with a sound basis for business planning andproduct development. Making these data widelyavailable and visible could contribute to a change inmind set that might encourage previously inacces-sible institutions to reach out to poor savers withdeposit services. Donor-subsidized market studiescan increase awareness and contribute to this attitu-dinal shift. The one market—Uganda—in whichCGAP found ready acceptance of the propositionthat the poor do save was also the market whereclient preferences were the best documented.

Help clients make smart savings choices.Many clients find it difficult to accurately assess therisks of different savings instruments, both formaland informal. Consumer education and financialliteracy training can help poor clients judge the rel-ative risks of available savings options and use themto manage household finances more effectively.

Client education on how to assess a financial insti-tution’s safety is especially valuable. Client knowl-edge of the indicators of institutional soundness mayhelp alleviate some of their uncertainty aboutentrusting their savings to formal financial institu-tions. Such mechanisms could build on the ratingsystems often used by apexes, federations, and tech-nical assistance projects and can be promoted toclients through public education campaigns.

Increase capacity in accessible institutionsand lower costs in safe institutions. To competemore effectively with informal savings mechanisms,

13

financial intermediaries must offer products thatcombine the security of well-run institutions withthe proximity and affordability of informal instru-ments. For regulated institutions, such as banks, thekey is developing less costly delivery mechanismswhile maintaining high levels of depositor protec-tion. Technologies such as mobile phones andpoint-of-sale networks hold promise, but oftenrequire substantial up-front investment. In the shortterm, offering incentives for regulated institutionsto reach out to unserved markets may be an effec-tive use of subsidies. For institutions that buildpoints of service in poor areas, incentives couldinclude a share of the government’s payments busi-ness, temporary exclusivity rights in certain areas, ortax breaks.

For less tightly regulated institutions, such ascooperatives, strengthening management is oftenmore important. Both types of institutions shoulduse data on client preferences to design productsthat respond to specific client needs. Donors, train-ing and technical assistance providers, policy mak-ers, regulators, and supervisors all have roles to playin helping institutions make these upgrades.

Align liquidity-related incentives. Finding out-lets for excess liquidity in strong institutions mayheighten their incentive to offer deposit services topoor clients. Helping institutions take and manageintelligent lending risks, for example in the micro-credit market, could drive deposit collection.Improved liquidity management mechanisms thatenable institutions to place excess funds into safe,remunerative investments also could increase theirappetite for deposits.

At the very least, donors and governments shouldthink twice about pumping more liquidity intoalready over-liquid systems through cheap, easilyaccessible credit lines. There may be alternatives thatbetter preserve incentives for deposit collection. Forexample, an emergency liquidity fund that “guaran-tees” short-term deposits could help financialinstitutions transform them into longer-term assets.In countries with very strict asset-liability regulation,increasing the proportion of short-term deposits that

can be transformed into longer-term loans could beanother potential solution. A study of the truestability of short-term deposits in a given institu-tional or country context should underpin boththese strategies.

Establish balanced regulatory and supervi-sory frameworks. Regulatory and supervisoryframeworks exert a strong influence over financialinstitutions’ ability and incentives to provide securedeposit services to low-income savers. In light ofpast crises, they often exhibit a bias toward ensur-ing systemic stability. But the restrictions entailedby this approach can inhibit outreach to poorclients. Often, this pressures regulated institutionsto innovate outside the law. For such institutions,permitting limited piloting of new products anddelivery methods may be a constructive alternativeto closing off all avenues for experimentation.

Stronger monitoring is often needed for moreaccessible institutions, especially for postal banksand large cooperatives that approach the definitionof institutions that take deposits from the public.Financial authorities often are reluctant to regulatea plethora of small institutions because of the costsinvolved. As a compromise, some countries have orare considering delegating supervision to member-ship-based federations of institutions. These effortshave been largely unsuccessful, and internationalexperiences may hold useful lessons.

For smaller institutions that cannot be cost-effectively supervised, nonprudential systems thatinvolve collecting and posting performance data—as well as communicating clearly to members that

14

these institutions are not supervised—may be apractical alternative. The emphasis on performancedata also could help build institutional capacity—anecessary counterpart to improved policy and effi-cient industry infrastructure.

Conclusion

Poor people worldwide want safe, accessible savingsmechanisms. Formal financial institutions cannotfulfill this demand until they can offer services thatare secure, affordable, and located where poorclients live and work. In the meantime, poor peoplewill continue to hide money at home, lock up assetsin animals, or entrust cash to informal providers—with all the risks those mechanisms entail. Funders,policy makers, and financial institutions themselvesmust work at all levels of the financial system toalign incentives and create the capacity for formalinstitutions to tap the demand for savings services.

These efforts translate into different activities,depending on the local context. While offeringincentives to banks to downscale in deposit mobi-lization may be the most promising strategy in onecountry, staunching the flow of subsidized on-lend-ing funds to cooperatives or strengthening postalbank management may be more important inanother. Regardless of the specific action, safety andaccessibility are the goals. If financial institutionscan offer these, they will not only increase access tosavings services for poor people, but also createaccess to a fortune of deposits for themselves.

Appendix: Data on Average Product Costs and

Branch Density

In the markets studied, average threshold coststracked closely to branch density. “Basic depositproducts” were defined as the lowest cost savingsor transaction account in a given institution.“Threshold” costs are the direct financial costs toopen such accounts, comprised of minimum open-ing balances, fees, and any shares that must be pur-chased in the case of cooperatives.

Table A-1 gives the range and averages of thresh-old costs in institutions sampled by country. Theinstitutions represent a cross-section of deposit-taking institutions catering to low-income people—usually mass-market-oriented banks, postal/savingsbanks, deposit-taking microfinance institutions,and financial cooperatives. For each country, dailyminimum wage is also given.

To study the relationship between thresholdcosts and population per branch, average thresholdcosts for a range of institutions were converted intoa multiple of the local daily minimum wage. (SeeTable A-2.)

Figure A-1 illustrates high, low, and averagethreshold costs and compares them against dailyminimum wages by country.

When these multiples were compared to averagenationwide population per branch, the correlationwas -0.78 for all deposit-taking institutions, meaning

that, as the number of branches per populationincreased, the average costs to open an accountdecreased. The correlation was even stronger (-0.83)when only bank branches were considered. Althoughbased on a limited sample of countries, the resultssupport the expectation that competition betweeninstitutions brings down price.

15

■ ■ ■

$160.00

$140.00

$120.00

$100.00

$80.00

$60.00

$40.00

$20.00

$-

554x

251x253x

2x1x

6x9x

0x

22x

0x

0x

1x

92x

5x88x

Figure A-1 Threshold costs for deposit products

Benin Bosnia Mexico Philippines Uganda

High LowUnweighted avgMin daily wageXx multiple of min daily wage

Table A-1 Threshold costs for basic deposit prod-ucts in institutions sampled, by country

All figures in USD High Low Average Minimum daily wage

Benin 946.97 9.09 157.43 1.71

Bosnia 6.33 0 0.79 6.55

Mexico 88.50 0.88 34.73 4.04

Philippines 35.66 8.91 14.49 6.15

Uganda 28.29 5.66 9.86 0.11

Table A-2 Threshold costs as multiples of dailyminimum wage

High Low Average

Benin 554 5 92

Bosnia 1 0 0

Mexico 22 0 9

Philippines 6 1 2

Uganda 253 51 88

Table A-3: Correlations between measures ofbranch density and threshold costs

High Low AverageBank branches/million people 0.73 0.56 0.83Deposit-taking institution 0.57 0.72 0.78branches/million people

Please share this

Focus Note with your

colleagues or request extra

copies of this paper or others

in this series.

CGAP welcomes

your comments on this paper.

All CGAP publications are

available on the CGAP Web site

at www.cgap.org.

CGAP

1818 H Street, NW

MSN P3 - 300

Washington, DC 20433 USA

Tel: 202-473-9594

Fax: 202-522-3744

Email:

[email protected]

FocusNote

No. 37

References

Bolaño, Pilar Campos. 2005. El Ahorro Popular en México: Acumulando Activos para Superar la Pobreza. Mex-ico City, Mexico: CIDAC and Miguel Angel Porrúa.

Financial Diaries Web site. www.financialdiaries.com.

Hertwig, Ralph, Greg Barron, Elke Webber, and Ido Erev. 2004. “Decisions from Experience and the Effectof Rare Events in Risky Choice.” Psychological Science 15 (8): 534–9.

Helms, Brigit, Rani Deshpande, Mark Pickens, and Nazaire Sado. 2005. Benin Country-Level Savings As-sessment. Washington, D.C.: CGAP, August.

Isern, Jennifer, David Porteous, Raul Hernandez-Coss, and Chinyere Egwuagu. 2005. “AML/CFT Regu-lation: Implications for Financial Service Providers That Serve Low-Income People.” CGAP Fo-cus Note 29. Washington, D.C.: CGAP, July.

Ivatury, Gautam. 2006. “Using Technology to Build Inclusive Financial Systems.” CGAP Focus Note 32.Washington, D.C.: CGAP, January.

Karlan, D. S., N. Ashraf, and Y. Wesley. 2004. Market Survey Report. Universities of Princeton and Harvard.Mimeo.

Mareco Index Bosnia Gallup International. 2003. Omnibus Survey. Mareco Index Bosnia Gallup Interna-tional, June.

Micro-Enterprise Bank. Market research. Manila, Philippines: Micro-Enterprise Bank.

Pelrine, Richard, and Olive Kabatalya. 2005. “Savings Habits, Needs and Priorities in Rural Uganda.” Kam-pala: USAID/Rural SPEED, September.

Rutherford, Stuart. 2003. “Money Talks: Conversations with Poor People in Bangladesh about ManagingMoney.” Journal of Microfinance 5(2).

Ruthven, O., and S. Kumar. 2002. “Fine-Grain Finance: Financial Choice & Strategy Among the Poor inRural North India.” Finance & Development Working Paper 57, IDPM, University of Manches-ter.

World Bank. 2001. “Mexico Rural Finance: Savings Mobilization Potential and Deposit Instruments in Mar-ginal Areas.” Report No. 21286-ME. Washington, D.C.: World Bank, June 4.

———. 2005. “Broadening Access to Financial Services among the Urban Population: Mexico City’s Un-banked.” Washington, D.C.: World Bank.

Wright, Graham, and Leonard Mutesasira. 2002. “The Relative Risks to the Savings of Poor People.” Nairobi:MicroSave.

Wright, Graham, and Paul Rippey. 2003. “The Competitive Environment in Uganda: Implications for Mi-crofinance Institutions and their Clients.” Kampala: MicroSave/FSDU/Imp-Act, September.

Zeller, Manfred, and Manohar Sharma. 2000. “Many Borrow, More Save, and All Insure: Implications forFood and Micro-finance Policy.” Food Policy 25(2): 143–67.

■ ■ ■