section 1 macroeconomics 2.1a the circular flow

150
Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow In the resource (or factor) market, businesses are buyers who compete for the factors of production to produce their goods and services. This generates demand for labor, capital, land and entrepreneurial ability. For these resources, they will pay wages, interest, rent and profits (WiRP).

Upload: emma-chambers

Post on 15-Mar-2016

50 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow. In the resource (or factor) market , businesses are buyers who compete for the factors of production to produce their goods and services. This generates demand for labor, capital, land and entrepreneurial ability. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Section 1 Macroeconomics2.1a The circular flow

• In the resource (or factor) market, businesses are buyers who compete for the factors of production to produce their goods and services.

• This generates demand for labor, capital, land and entrepreneurial ability.

• For these resources, they will pay wages, interest, rent and profits (WiRP).

Page 2: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Each payment correlates to a factor of production:

Factor of production

Payment

Labor WagesCapital InterestLand Rent

Entrepreneurial ability

Profits

Page 3: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Sellers of resources (households) will try to maximize their income by selling their factors to the highest bidder.

• For example, a worker with scarce skills will be

able to sell their labor for a higher wage than a less qualified competitor.

• With their incomes, the sellers of resources will turn to the product market to spend their earnings on goods and services.

Page 4: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

The circular flow

Page 5: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Circular Flow Diagrams are the simplest models for understanding how a macro-economy works. This relatively simple example shows how aggregate income levels are exchanged for resources—including labor—that are bought from households.

• Income, in turn, gets spent on goods and services, repaying firms for the money spent on resources.

Page 6: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Sophisticated circular flow models include leakages and injections into the macroeconomy. The relative size of each leakage or injection can have a large impact upon the economy’s final output.

• Leakages and injections must equal each other and therefore can be presented as follows:

Page 7: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Leakages Injections

Taxes Government spending

Imports Exports

Savings Investment

Page 8: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• One implication of the model is that the values of each flow are equal.

• Since resource expenditure is funded by

consumer spending, they must be equal, and the total value of production must be the same as well.

Page 9: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.1b Measuring national income

• There are two distinct methods of measuring the total output of an economy.

• Gross Domestic Product (GDP)

• Gross National Product (GNP)

Page 10: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• GDP is the total money value of all goods and services produced in an economy over a certain time, usually one year. GDP includes the output of foreign firms in a country, but does not include the output of domestic firms overseas. This figure is based on geographic boundaries.

Page 11: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• GNP is the total money value of all goods and services produced by the citizens or firms of a particular country, no matter where they are based, but does not include the production of foreign firms within the country. This figure is based on nationality/citizenship of the owner of the property or labor.

Page 12: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Net Domestic Product (NDP) is Gross Domestic Product less depreciation, and depreciation is the value of capital that is used-up in production and must be replaced.

• GDP = NDP + depreciation

Page 13: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Another important distinction is that of Nominal GDP vs. REAL GDP.

• Nominal GDP can exaggerate the true value of production because it measures output at current prices. If there is significant inflation, any change in GDP will be greater than the real change in output.

Page 14: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• REAL GDP measures output with a single year’s prices, what is called a base year.

• GDP is useful in discerning a broad picture of the relative size of economies and making general comparisons between countries.

Page 15: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Another valuable measure is called Per Capita GDP, which is a better measure of, on average, how wealthy people are in different countries.

• Per Capita GDP = GDP ÷ population

Page 16: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• GDP as a measurement has several shortcomings, one of which was just noted (income distribution).

A. GDP also does not take into account qualitative changes in the output of goods and services. We know that electronics that have been developed recently have many more features than those just 5 years old. GDP does not take into consideration this advance in technology.

Page 17: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

B. GDP does not take into account informal or black market activities. Consequently, the babysitting that you provided to your neighbor last weekend is not counted in the GDP. Nor are illegal activities such as selling stolen goods counted.

C. Do it yourself activities are not counted in the GDP. The work of stay at home parents around their house nor is the shed built by your dad last summer included in GDP.

Page 18: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

D. Used or second hand goods are not counted as they were already calculated in the GDP the year they were originally manufactured.

E. Purely financial transactions such as stock market transactions or transfer payments between the government and citizens or family gifting of cash (such as at holiday or graduation time).

Page 19: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

F. In developing countries, most citizens are engaged in informal subsistence economic activities, which are not in the formal economy and therefore not counted in the GDP figures.

Page 20: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Finally, GDP does not take into account negative externalities that are produced as a result of economic activity.

• The green GDP, which has been attempted by several countries, is meant to measure the output of goods and services while subtracting the “bads” of environmental destruction.

Page 21: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• There two primary methods of calculating GDP:

Income method = adding up all of the money incomes generated by the owners of the factors of production (or WiRP) of a given economy for a given accounting period.

Expenditure method = compiling all of the

expenditures on final goods and services within an economy for a given accounting period.

Page 22: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The income approach to GDP accounting is demonstrated from the data for the U.S. economy in the first quarter of 2012 shown below:

Page 23: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Category Gross value (billions USD)

Compensation of employees (wages)

8,451.5

Rents 445.5Interest 709.6Proprietor’s profits 1,130.8Corporate profits 1,604.5

Taxes on production and imports

1,113

Adjustments to misc. income

52.6

National Income 13,507.5

Consumption of Fixed Capital

2,004.1

GDP 15,511.6

Page 24: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Note several interesting elements of the methodology:

• Taxes on Production and Imports: This is basically an adjustment to take into account indirect taxes (i.e. business property, sales and excise taxes) that find their way into transactions but are not really counted in the WiRP figure.

Page 25: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Consumption of Fixed Capital: Essentially this is value of depreciated capital that has been replaced as a cost of production, which is not counted as income. As the money is not available for other uses, it does not show up in anybody’s income. This category is an accounting method to balance the GDP in the income method with the expenditure method.

Page 26: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The most common method of GDP accounting though is the expenditure method. It is broken down as follows:

• Consumption (C): Personal household

expenditures on goods and services. This includes everything from food to utilities to rent to clothing to cars to school supplies. Services are things like hair styling, doctors, auto repair and banking.

Page 27: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Investment (I): Gross private investment in physical plant, machinery, construction and inventories. This includes replacement investment of worn out machinery or buildings. This figure does not include paper assets (stocks and bonds) as these are mere changes in ownership rather than the creation of new productive capacity.

Page 28: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Government expenditures (G): Government purchases includes expenditures on goods and services used in providing public services as well as spending on schools and highways which might not be used up in a year.

Page 29: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Net exports (X-M): Exports are goods and services, which are developed within an economy and sold abroad to consumer from other countries. In the expenditure method these are an injection, yet imports (our country’s purchases of foreign made goods and services) are a leakage. Therefore, we take the net effect of these transactions and include that figure in the final GDP figure.

Page 30: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• All of this can be put together as a simple equation:

C + I + G +(X – M) = GDP

• This equation also happens to be the equation for Aggregate Demand (AD) which will become a useful tool for you in future sections when discussing how different policies impact economic output.

Page 31: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Here is an example from the first quarter of 2012 in the U.S. economy.

Category Value (billions USD)

Personal Consumption (C) 11,009.5

Gross private investment (I) 2,046.5

Government expenditures (G) 3,108.2

Net exports (X-M) - 620.1

GDP 15,454.0

Page 32: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.1c The business cycle

• Most economies experience a long run upward trend in economic growth partially due to the increase in population and improvements in productivity.

Page 33: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Potential output is represented as a trend line of growth. Potential output is the output of the economy if all factors of production are fully employed in their highest and best use.

• However, the actual growth of the economy is not always a straight line and there are often periods of instability or recession.

Page 34: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• There are four phases most commonly referred to in business cycle theory.

• Peak – When an economy has reached its maximum output with the performance being at or near full employment or the economy’s capacity. This is characterized by a shortage of skilled labor and materials, which puts upward pressure on prices. Companies are making solid profits and optimism is high.

Page 35: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Recession – Indicates a period of decreasing total output and other measurements. A recession can be a point at which consumers and firms have exhausted their consumption or investment budgets. This usually lasts at least 6 months and is associated with contractions in employment and business activity. Unemployment rates usually rise during these periods

Page 36: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Trough – The bottom of a recession. This is associated with high rates of unemployed labor and productive capacity. Corporate profits are low and pessimism is high.

Page 37: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Recovery – Sometimes called an expansion. Economies cannot stay in a trough forever as machinery wears out and firms have to start to replace capital. Price levels may have fallen low enough to induce new investment in inventories or new consumption as consumers may be tired of not buying. GDP growth and employment increase off the bottom of the trough as the economy expands.

Page 38: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Some of these periods are also associated with what are called output gaps.

 • If the gap is negative (Y < Yfe), then it is

referred to as a recessionary gap • If the gap is positive (Y>Yfe), then it is

referred to as an inflationary gap as we have gone beyond full employment.

 • Let’s look at a diagram.

Page 39: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 40: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• As the diagram makes clear, the inflationary gaps occur when the economy is peaking or growing faster than the trend line of growth.

 • The recessionary gaps are apparent when

economic growth dips below the trend line or potential output of the economy.

Page 41: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.2a Aggregate Demand

• Aggregate demand (AD) is comprised of all the spending that comes to a domestic market. Aggregate demand, is a schedule, which shows the amounts of real GDP that buyers will collectively buy at given average price levels in the economy.

Page 42: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Therefore we categorize the different types of demand like this:

• Consumer spending (C)• Investment (I)• Government spending (G)• Net Exports (X – M)

Page 43: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The aggregate demand curve has a negative slope. Essentially the AD curve is the visual representation of the expenditure method of GDP accounting.

• The price level is measured as the average price level of final goods and services (product) in the economy and is considered a measurement of inflation.

Page 44: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Why is the AD curve negatively sloped? • The first reason is called the real balances

effect. As the price level rises, the purchasing power of the public’s income or savings decreases so they can buy less as the price level rises. This factor is most closely associated with consumption (C).

Page 45: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Secondly, the interest rate effect influences the slope. As prices rise, there is an increase in demand for money and the cost of borrowing money (the interest rate) will rise as well. Lenders will charge a higher rate of interest for the public to borrow money to finance household consumption or for firms to invest in productive capacity. This effect is usually most visible in investment (I).

Page 46: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Finally there is the foreign purchases effect. When the price level rises, it makes the country’s exports more expensive to foreign buyers. This leads to a decrease in foreign purchases of the country’s exports. Moreover, rising domestic prices may make imported goods cheaper and result in citizens substituting imports for exports at higher price levels. This is effect is seen in net exports (X – M).

Page 47: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 48: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• In the diagram above, the economy is producing output Y at the price level P.

• Shifts in the AD curve are the result of changes in the components of AD or changes in the factors of the following equation:

C + I +G + (X – M) = AD

Page 49: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Consumption – The elements that affect consumer spending would be changes in the following:

Consumer wealth – While changes in income will clearly change consumption, so will the wealth of households. If there is a change in the value of physical (real estate) or paper (stocks and bonds) assets, then consumers will feel more or less wealthy and adjust their spending accordingly.

Page 50: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Consumer expectations – If consumers believe that their real income will change in the future, they will increase or reduce expenditures based upon their expectations.

• Personal income taxes – A direct tax will affect disposable income which will have an impact upon households ability to consume.

Page 51: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Household indebtedness – When households borrow to consume (or invest), the purchases bought with borrowed money will increase AD. However, when consumers pay back that debt, they will have to reduce current expenditures to pay back for previous consumption which will decrease AD.

Page 52: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Interest rates – The cost of borrowing money will impact the purchase of “big ticket” items or consumer durable goods. These are goods that last longer than a year and are difficult for households to buy without borrowing moneyIf interest rates are low, then households would be willing to borrow money to buy the goods they desire, thereby increasing AD as noted above.

Page 53: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Investment spending – Investment is the most volatile variable in AD because it relies upon future expectations of businesses and individuals of economic activity. The elements that affect business investment would be changes in the following:

Page 54: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Real interest rates – Again, the cost of borrowing money can induce businesses to take or put off investing. If the real interest rate increases, then businesses will hold off borrowing to buy new plant and equipment. If real interest rates decrease, then firms would increase investment with a corresponding increase in AD.

Page 55: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Expected returns – If companies believe that they will be able to make a good return on investment, then they will increase their purchases and shift the AD curve to the right. If businesses believe that business conditions will improve, then they will invest in new projects.

Page 56: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Business taxes – Taxes will have a direct effect upon the profits that a firm expects to make from an investment. Consequently, a reduction in business taxes will increase investment and AD. An increase in such taxes will have the opposite effect.

Page 57: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Technology – Improvements in technology, which bring with them a corresponding increase in productivity, will increase returns to an investment. Technological change incentivizes firms to increase their investment, which then leads to an increase in AD.

Page 58: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Government spending – The elements that affect government spending would be changes in the following:

Changes in political priorities – If a government decides to change spending due to a perceived threat or crisis then the G variable will impact AD. An example might be a change in defense expenditures.

Page 59: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Changes in economic priorities – In the case of a recessionary environment, the government may increase expenditures to make up for the loss of AD or employment that occurs in a downturn. An example of this might be increasing expenditures on infrastructure such as roads.

Page 60: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Net Export spending would be affected by the following:

National income abroad – When trade partners incomes rise, they have a tendency to buy more imports, which could mean an increase in purchases of our exports. The opposite is true if their incomes decrease.

Page 61: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Exchange rates – When our country’s currency depreciates, it makes our exports cheaper to foreign buyers as it takes fewer units of their currency to pay for the goods or services we sell them. This will increase AD. Conversely, we may see the opposite effect if our currency appreciates against that of our trade partners.

Page 62: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Levels of protectionism – If there is increased protectionism (import tariffs or quotas) practiced by trade partners, this can reduce exports and thereby AD.

Page 63: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.2b Aggregate supply

• Aggregate supply (AS) is a schedule of real domestic output that is produced at each possible price level.

• Unlike aggregate demand, aggregate supply is more complex in its measurement. This is due to the fact that producers cannot adjust quickly to changes in the average price level.

Page 64: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The short run is defined as the timeframe in which wages and input prices cannot adjust to changes in the average price level.

• The long run is considered to be the time in which wages and input prices can adjust to changes in the average price level.

Page 65: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Movements along the SRAS curve –

• Due to what we call a recognition lag, wages and factor input costs do not respond immediately to changes in the price level so it takes time for these prices to adjust.

• While an increase in the price level might allow a firm to increase its product prices, the factor input costs will respond much more slowly.

Page 66: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Remember that the largest cost for most firms is labor and so the nominal wage rate plays a dominant role in firms’ operations.

• Wage rate changes often lag changes in the price level in an economy as it takes time for workers to realize that their purchasing power has declined.

• When the price level rises, firms are able to increase their final goods prices and make larger profits as their wage bill remains unchanged.

Page 67: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Subsequently, a firm will increase its output when the price level is rising to capture more profits.

• Consequently, the firms increase output and can push the economy beyond full employment as they hire unemployed workers and encourage employees to work overtime or to move to full time work.

Page 68: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The situation is illustrated in the diagram below at point b in which the Y’ level of RGDP at the P’ price level demonstrates a rise up along the SRAS curve.

Page 69: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Firms respond to falls in the price level by lowering their final goods prices as they attempt to clear inventory.

• This reduction in sales revenues will reduce profits and put firms in a position to decrease production or even lay off workers. The increase in unemployment will correspond to a decrease in SRAS.

• This condition corresponds to the Y” level of RGDP at the P” price level or at point c on the diagram below.

Page 70: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The movements along the SRAS curve described above originate at point a.

Page 71: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Production costs are the primary factor in changes in AS. However, there are several determinants of AS:

Page 72: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Resource costs – All factor input prices will play a role in the final product price, consequently any change in resource costs will shift the curve. If for example, there is a decrease in the price of oil, then the AS curve will shift out to the right as we can produce more output with the same expenditure as before the price change. Conversely, a rise in wages will push the curve up and to the left.

Page 73: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Resource costs are not just domestic in nature. While labor is a domestic expense, some raw materials are imported. As a result, exchange rates and control over the supply of the needed resource can complicate prices firms.

Page 74: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• If one particular trade partner has inordinate market power over a commodity, then it can increase the price and thereby impact our AS due to our use of the input in our production. Furthermore, if our exchange rate depreciates, we will have to pay more for imports of a critical factor input.

Page 75: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Productivity – Improvements in productivity will increase output at all price levels and push the AS out and to the right.

• By improving the quality of factor inputs, either in the case of new machines or increasing the skill level of workers, we can produce more output at current prices and shift out the AS curve.

Page 76: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Business Environment – This addresses many variables such as:

• Business taxes – Higher direct and indirect taxes increase costs in the short run and can lead to a reduction in output at every price level with a corresponding leftward shift in the AS curve.

Page 77: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Subsidies – Payments by the government to firms to encourage the production of specific goods can lower production costs and encourage companies to expand their output.

• Regulation - The costs associated with complying with government regulations can divert funds from production and decrease output for firms. An increase in government regulation may shift the AS curve to the left.

Page 78: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.2c Controversy over aggregate supply

Aggregate supply is a source of debate among different schools of economic thought. Most economists agree that the long run AS (LRAS) curve is vertical and that it represents the full employment/potential level of output.

Page 79: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Neo- Classical economists (Friedrich Hayek and Milton Friedman) argue that production levels are determined through the efficient operation of markets. Therefore, there is no SRAS as the economy is always just at full employment operating on or near the LRAS curve.

Page 80: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• If there is a temporary downturn, then laid off workers will quickly adjust their wage demands or change their location and be reemployed very soon. There is no need for the government to intervene

• Neo-classical economists believe that any policy to address instability in the economy will interfere with the self-correcting mechanism of markets and result in price distortions (inflation).

Page 81: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• In essence, the neo-classical perspective believes that AS in the long run is independent of prices as markets will act to push the economy back towards equilibrium.

Page 82: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The neo-classical school is often associated with non-interventionist and market based policies. By reducing the role of government in the economy and regulating the rate of growth in the money supply (more on this later), markets will self-correct and the economy will grow more effectively.

Page 83: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Consequently, neo-classical economists focus on the long run and as a result they will push for supply-side policies which reduce impediments to competition as well as reduce government intervention in the economy.

Page 84: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Neo-classical attitudes are connected to mostly right leaning political parties. Policies promoted in Ireland in the period after the 2009 financial crisis which reduced government spending and encouraged austerity in general, could be considered to be neo-classical in nature.

Page 85: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• However, Keynesian economists believe that markets are imperfect and that macroeconomic instability is the result of different forms of market failure.

• Consequently, the Keynesians believe in the AS curve which has three regions.

Page 86: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• They believe that output can fall at such as rate that it falls into the horizontal range of the AS curve. This means that there could be a decrease in output with no change in the price level.

• This is due to the belief that resource costs and final product prices are “sticky downwards”. This perspective is rooted in the belief that workers do not adjust their wage demands as rapidly as they will attempt to find employment at their previous income.

Page 87: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Moreover, from this perspective, producers do not adjust their product prices until absolutely necessary to clear inventory.

• When both of these scenarios are in play, there is plenty of spare capacity for the economy to put back to work without putting upward pressure on the price level.

Page 88: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Horizontal range – this is substantially below full employment implies that the economy is in recession or worse, a depression. There are plenty of unemployed resources and there is upward pressure on prices. This is characterized by a flat portion of the AS curve.

Page 89: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Intermediate range – as the economy starts to grow, there is increased demand for labor and other resources. This results in upward pressure on factor input prices and requires firms to increase their product prices to maintain profitability. There will begin to be shortages of resources, which will further drive up prices. This region is where most of the short run analysis is done and is upward sloping.

Page 90: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Vertical range – when the economy reaches its potential output or full employment, the curve becomes vertical. This is because the economy is at full capacity. Any efforts by firms to increase output will only bid resources away from other firms and drive up prices in the process. This is due to the finite resources in the economy.

Page 91: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 92: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Keynesian economists believe that markets are imperfect and that macroeconomic instability is the result of different forms of market failure.

• They believe that output can fall at such as rate that it falls into the horizontal range of the AS curve. This means that there could be a decrease in output with no change in the price level.

Page 93: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• This is due to the belief that resource costs and final product prices are “sticky downwards”. This perspective is rooted in the belief that workers do not adjust their wage demands as rapidly as they will attempt to find employment at their previous income.

Page 94: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Moreover, producers do not adjust their product prices until absolutely necessary to clear inventory.

• When both of these scenarios are in play, there is plenty of spare capacity for the economy to put back to work without putting upward pressure on the price level.

Page 95: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Keynesian policies to address economic instability are often a mix of fiscal (government driven) and monetary (central bank directed) policies. These policies often affect the economy through the demand or AD side.

• These tactics can be interventionist as in increasing government spending to make up for a decrease in AD or cutting taxes to increase investment. Or the central bank could increase the money supply to lower interest rates to promote investment.

Page 96: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Unfortunately, both of these policies often result in inflation, which we will discuss in more detail in the future.

• An example of such Keynesian government driven policies was the $819 billion stimulus package of increased spending and continuation of tax cuts passed by Congress in the U.S. in 2009.

Page 97: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.2d Long run aggregate supply

• Despite their differences, both Keynesians and neo-classical economists agree on the LRAS being vertical at the potential output of the economy and the goal of shifting the LRAS to the right.

• The LRAS corresponds to the full-employment output (Yfe) of the economy. This is basically when the economy is operating at its potential.

Page 98: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Another way of saying this is that the economy is operating at the natural rate of unemployment (NRU). This point occurs when the number of job applicants is equal to the number of vacancies.

• The economy can operate below the NRU or at time beyond the NRU. How the economy adjusts to these two conditions is the subject of much controversy and we will discuss this dispute in more detail in section 2.3.

Page 99: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Shifting the LRAS is another way of demonstrating economic growth through expanding the potential or full employment output of the economy.

• In this case it is very similar to the how the PPC operates.

Page 100: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Notice how the PPC is pushed out demonstrating economic growth and how this matches the increase from Yfe to Yfe’ in the LRAS on the AD/AS model on the right.

Page 101: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Two sources of expansion of the LRAS are increasing the quantity and quality of factor inputs.

• If there is an increase in the factors of production we can shift the potential of full employment output.

Page 102: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• For example, we can add more to our labor force via population growth or increase labor force participation. By having formerly unemployed workers or more women enter the labor force, we have increased our potential output.

Page 103: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• If we increase our stock of physical capital through investment, we have pushed out our potential. When firms put in place more machinery, it will increase the productivity of labor and consequently potential output.

Page 104: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• A new natural resources discovery will push the LRAS to the right reflecting an increase in land as a factor of production. An example of this might be Brazil’s oil discovery in 2006, which added to its potential GDP.

Page 105: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• By improving the quality of inputs, we can push the LRAS outward as well. This is usually associated with improvements in training and education for labor to increase productivity. Highly trained labor can be more capable of suggesting cost saving ideas to increase output.

Page 106: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Technological advances associated with capital equipment will make labor more productive and thereby push the LRAS out as well. For example, new machines in a metal fabrication plant, which use raw materials more efficiently, will increase potential output.

Page 107: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Finally, we can improve our allocative efficiency by more effectively organizing our productive resources. Companies endeavor to do this by continually examining production processes to decrease wasted movements or procedures.

Page 108: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.2e SRAS/AD equilibrium

• Similar to equilibrium in microeconomics, macroeconomic equilibrium occurs when AD and the SRAS behave in a manner to move towards equilibrium in which:

P level = AD = SRAS

Page 109: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

Real Output Demanded (AD)

Price level (Index Number)

Real Output Supplied (AS)

440 110 453

443 105 450

447 100 447

450 95 444

453 90 441

The table makes evident that macroeconomic equilibrium will occur at a price level of 100 with a real output of $447 billion. Let’s look at a diagram.

Page 110: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

As the diagram makes clear, the equilibrium level of output is at $447 billion at the price index of 100.

Page 111: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Arriving at a new equilibrium in the short run can be achieved through the demand side or the supply side. Let’s examine the demand side first.

• Whenever one of the determinants of aggregate demand (C+I+G+(X-M)) changes, the result will be a shift in the AD curve.

Page 112: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 113: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The increase in investment described above will lead to an increase in aggregate demand from AD to AD’. This results in a new equilibrium level of output Y’ at a higher price level of P’.

• While the economy experiences higher output, the challenge here is that there is a rise in the price level, which is associated with demand pull inflation.

Page 114: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Suffice it to say, if we see a decline in any of the AD variables, the new equilibrium would be at a lower output and a lower price level (all things being equal).

• Drops in various components of AD may be the result of higher interest rates resulting in businesses reducing Investment or Consumers income stagnating so they buy fewer goods and services.

Page 115: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• One final note here is that a natural or man-made event can reduce Consumption (as well as Investment) due to the disruption in people’s lives. An example of this might be the terrorist attacks in Spain in 2004 and in England in 2005 leading to less train travel by citizens or a decline in consumption due to the earthquake in Haiti in 2010.

• Do you think that you can draw the correct diagram for a decline in AD?

Page 116: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Decreases in SRAS are usually associated with supply shocks. These events are often the result of the disruption of a segment in the supply chain due to a natural or man-made disaster.

• The 2011 earthquake and tsunami in Japan lead to a decrease in the SRAS in Japan as well as impacting the supply chain of firms in other countries.

Page 117: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The classic explanation of a supply shock is an increase in oil prices that is so dramatic as to make every unit of output that much more expensive to produce that the economy creates less output at a higher price.

• In the 1970’s when oil prices tripled in a very short period of time, the U.S. economy in particular, production costs soared and the result was what is called cost push inflation.

Page 118: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

The lower output was at a higher price and the diagram below illustrates the conundrum.

Page 119: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• With an increase in factor input costs (such as oil in this case), producers can make fewer goods and services for a given budget.

• The scenario leads to a shift in the SRAS curve to SRAS’.

• This results in a decrease in output form Y to Y’, yet with prices increasing from P to P’ accounting for the corresponding increase of resource costs.

Page 120: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• There are occasions when the both AD increases and the SRAS curve shifts out as well. This results in low inflation and strong economic growth.

• Unfortunately, this sort of benign environment is not always seen in the real economy…the U.S. experienced this scenario between 1996 and 2000.

• The diagram below will illustrate this favorable environment.

Page 121: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 122: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• As the diagram makes evident, the growing economy shows a shift in the AD curve from AD to AD’. The new equilibrium shows a corresponding output of Y’ at the price level P’.

• However, as a result of increased worker productivity, the SRAS curve shifts out to SRAS’. The shift in the SRAS curve increases output even further to Y” at a lower price level of P”.

Page 123: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.2f LRAS-SRAS-AD equilibrium

• Short run and long run equilibrium can come together at full employment.

• Remember that the full employment level of output corresponds to the LRAS. This is because nominal wages adjust in response to changes in the price level over time.

Page 124: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• In the long run, the SRAS goes through a series of adjustments to changes in the price level.

• As we will see shortly, these adjustments can lead to a recessionary or inflationary gap in the short run.

• Corrections can result in AD-SRAS-LRAS equilibrium, as demonstrated by the diagram below.

Page 125: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 126: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• In the scenario above, the economy starts in a recessionary environment at Y output at the P price level. Now suppose that prices have fallen far enough to induce firms to invest in new machinery and hire workers to operate the machinery.

• The increase in I, leads to a shift in the AD curve to AD’ at the P’ price level and Yfe level of output. This happened to be in long run equilibrium for the economy.

Page 127: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The neo-classical school believes that the economy always self-corrects, so therefore we only need to worry about policies that push out the LRAS.

• The neo-classical analysis shown below starts at full employment output (Yfe) at the price level Y or point a.

Page 128: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• If there is an unanticipated increase in aggregate demand shown by the shift in the AD curve from AD to AD’, then this will push equilibrium beyond the full employment level of output corresponding to Y’ at point b.

Page 129: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• However, owners of resources/factor inputs are quick to realize that the price level has increased and they will demand higher prices or wages to restore lost purchasing power.

Page 130: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• As per unit production costs increase, aggregate supply will decrease leading to a shift in the curve from AS to AS’. Hence the economy self-corrects to point c back at the full employment output (Yfe) but at a higher price level (P”).

Page 131: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 132: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Neo-classical economists believe that people behave rationally and therefore take action rapidly to protect their self-interest.

• Even though the economy will slip out of long run equilibrium, individuals and firms interacting in the market place will automatically push it back to Yfe.

• For these reasons, there is no need for the government to invoke any changes in fiscal policy or for the central bank to take monetary action…let the markets work.

Page 133: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Keynesian economists have a different perspective on how an economy falls into, and for how long the economy can be in, disequilibrium.

• The basic belief here is that the economy is in equilibrium wherever AS = AD…whether at full employment or not.

Page 134: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The Keynesian school of thought focuses on the role that aggregate demand plays in economic instability.

• Rapid changes in any of the variables of AD will lead to the economy reaching a new equilibrium often above or below full employment.

Page 135: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Remember that another key to the Keynes perspective is that individuals and firms take a longer time to recognize and adjust their wage and price demands.

• For example, a dramatic drop in Consumption in an economy where consumption plays a large role can push the economy into recession.

Page 136: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• However, the most destabilizing variable is wide swings in Investment.

• Due to investment relying upon real interest rates and expected rates of return, optimism (or pessimism) can lead to big booms (or busts) in investment.

Page 137: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

2.2g Keynesian perspective on equilibrium.

• A recessionary gap is defined as a level of macroeconomic equilibrium below the full employment level of output as show in the diagram of the Malaysian economy below.

• This gap corresponds to the point when actual economic growth falls below potential economic growth in the business cycle.

Page 138: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• The result of this decline is unemployed resources whether it be labor or capital in the form of plant and machinery being idle.

• In the Keynesian system, the economy can experience long periods of recession due to the downward rigidity in wages and prices. In this view, individuals do not adjust their wage demands as rapidly as they will attempt to find employment at their previous income.

Page 139: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• As noted earlier, from this perspective, producers do not adjust their product prices until absolutely necessary to clear inventory.

• An equation for this might be:

AD = AS < LRAS/Yfe

Page 140: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 141: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• This diagram of the Malaysian economy shows a recessionary gap where equilibrium is reached at a price level of 100 equaling a RGDP of $447 billion.

• However, this point is below the full employment level of potential output at $450 billion.

Page 142: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• This model also allows for an inflationary gap to occur in which the economy reaches equilibrium beyond full employment.

• In this case, we might be able to write this

as an equation:AD = SRAS > LRAS/Yfe

Page 143: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• If an economy starts to grow rapidly and overheat, there can be a reduction in spare manufacturing capacity and very tight labor markets.

• Wage rates will be bid up as firms try to secure scarce labor to meet the growing demand for their output.

Page 144: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Natural resource and other factor input prices will increase as firms continue to compete for scarce resources as most producers of natural resources cannot quickly increase supply to meet growing demand.

• These input price increases will lead to higher final goods and services prices as shown below.

Page 145: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 146: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• In this scenario it is evident that the Malaysian economy is overheating reaching equilibrium at a price level of 105 with RGDP beyond full employment at $453 billion.

Page 147: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Finally, unlike neo-classical economists, Keynes did not believe that increases in AD had to be inflationary.

• It is a core belief of the Keynesians that the economy can operate for long periods of time in the horizontal range of the Keynesian AS curve.

Page 148: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• Because of the large amount of unused resources (labor, capital or natural resources), there are plenty of factor inputs available for production.

• These unemployed resources can be engaged without worry for bottlenecks or shortages leading to wage and price increases.

• Therefore, increases in AD can result in growth and output can be increased with little or no upward pressure on the overall price level.

Page 149: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow
Page 150: Section 1 Macroeconomics 2.1a The circular flow

• In the economy above, equilibrium is deep in the horizontal zone of the AS curve and there is enough excess capacity and surplus labor that AD can increase to AD’ with no impact upon the overall price level as RGDP moves from Y to Y’.