september 24th 2011 a game of catch-up - the...

20
SPECIAL REPORT THE WORLD ECONOMY September 24th 2011 A game of catch-up

Upload: dolien

Post on 09-Mar-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


1 download

TRANSCRIPT

S p e c i a l r e p o r t

T h e w o r l d e c o n o m ySeptember 24th 2011

A game of catch-up

SRWorldeconomy.indd 1 09/09/2011 16:20

CODE: CAP-11-64 PUB/POST: NACD Directorship; Send PRODUCTION: D. Hanson LIVE: 8.5” x 10.375”

DESCRIPTION: United Globally Around One Goal (Worldscape) WORKORDER #: 002928 TRIM: 9” x 10.875”

Delivery Support: 212.237.7000 FILE: 01A-002926-01A-CAP-11-64-NACD.indd SAP #: BAR.BARCAP.11048.K.011 BLEED: 9.25” x 11.125”

Art: BarCapital_Logo_Band_COL_20mm.eps (Up to Date), BAR-Euromoney 2011 AFE wTag Wht-4C.ai (Up to Date), 4002_Barclays_Cap_RT9a-Mag_v1.tif (CMYK; 826 ppi; Up to Date)

barcap.com

Earn Success Every Day

Issued by Barclays Bank PLC, authorized and regulated by the Financial Services Authority and a member of the London Stock Exchange, Barclays Capital is the investment banking division of Barclays Bank PLC, which undertakes US securities business in the name of its wholly-owned subsidiary Barclays Capital Inc., an SIPC and FINRA member. ©2011 Barclays Bank PLC. All rights reserved. Barclays Capital is a trademark of Barclays Bank PLC. All other trademarks, servicemarks or registered trademarks are the property, and used with the permission, of their respective owners.

UNITED GLOBALLY AROUND ONE GOAL: YOUR SUCCESS.

Day after day, our award-winning teams come together to set industry benchmarks

and deliver the services you need to ensure your financing and risk management

decisions result in success. It’s an approach that is not only highly successful for our

clients but has been recognized in our latest accolades, including ‘Best Global

Investment Bank’ in Euromoney’s Awards for Excellence 2011.

A game of catch­up

QUARRY BANK MILL is a handsome �ve­storey brick building set in thevalley of the river Bollin at Styal, a small English village a few miles southof Manchester. It was built in 1784 by Samuel Greg, a merchant, whofound pro�t in supplying cotton thread to Lancashire’s weavers. The rawcotton shipped from America’s slave plantations was processed on thelatest machinery, Richard Arkwright’s water frame. Later Greg extendedthe factory and installed coal­�red steam engines to add to the waterpower from the Bollin. All this gave a huge boost to productivity. In 1700 aspinster with a pedal­driven spinning wheel might take 200 hours to pro­duce a pound of yarn. By the 1820s it would take her around an hour.

Greg’s mill was part of a revolution in industry that would pro­foundly alter the world’s pecking order. The new technologies�labour­saving inventions, factory production, engines powered by fossil fuels�spread to other parts of western Europe and later to America. The earlyindustrialisers (along with a few late developers, such as Japan) wereable to lock in and build on their lead in technology and living standards.

The �great divergence� between the West and the rest lasted for twocenturies. The mill at Styal, once one of the world’s largest, has become amuseum. A few looms, powered by the mill’s water wheel, still producetea towels for the gift shop, but cotton production has long since movedabroad in search of low wages. Now another historic change is shakingup the global hierarchy. A �great convergence� in living standards is un­der way as poorer countries speedily adopt the technology, know­howand policies that made the West rich. China and India are the biggest andfastest­growing of the catch­up countries, but the emerging­marketboom has spread to embrace Latin America and Africa, too.

And the pace of convergence is increasing. Debt­ridden rich coun­tries such as America have seen scant growth since the �nancial crisis.The emerging economies, having escaped the carnage with only a fewcuts and grazes, have spent much of the past year trying to check theireconomic booms. The IMF forecasts that emerging economies as a wholewill grow by around four percentage points more than the rich world

The shift in economic power from West to East is accelerating, says

John O’Sullivan. The rich world will lose some of its privileges

The Economist September 24th 2011 1

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

1

A C K N O W L E D G M E N T S

C O N T E N T S

In addition to those named inthe text, the author wouldlike to thank the following fortheir generous help: MarceloCarvalho, Robert Ellison,Stephen King, Guilherme daNóbrega, Eswar Prasad,Kenneth Rogo�, Mary Roseand Alan Taylor.

A list of sources is at

Economist.com/specialreports

An audio interview with

the author is at

Economist.com/audiovideo/specialreports

3 Becoming number oneWhen will China’seconomy overtakeAmerica’s?

5 Converging economiesOne­track bind

8 Reserve currenciesGreenback mountain

12 CommoditiesCrowded out

13 Exporting jobsGurgaon grief

15 South­north FDIRole reversal

16 Beefed upBrazil’s meat giant

17 The path aheadCottoning on

0 20 40 60 80 100

Official foreign-exchange reserves, Q2 2011

Rich world$3.2trn

Emerging world

$6.5trn

Breakdown by currency Allocated reserves, Q2 2011, %

$ ¥¤ £ Other

1.8

1.1

1.32.0

10.68.0

4.9

5.8

4.3

6.8

4.6

3.9

3.1

5.5

2.2

4.7

0.6

Population2010, bn

Canada0.03

United States0.31

Mexico0.11

Brazil0.20

Britain0.06

Japan0.13

India1.23

China1.34

Russia0.14

Sub-SaharanAfrica0.80

CIS*0.14

Central &E. Europe0.18

Euro area0.33

Indonesia0.24

Australia0.02

Middle East& N. Africa0.42

Latin America& Caribbean0.28

GDP growth, 2001-11, %2011 forecast

0

1

5

10

GDP per person, 2010, PPP $'000

RICH WORLDEMERGING WORLD

>4035-4010-165-10<5 30-35

*Commonwealth of Independent States

Sources: IMF; UN; The Economist

both this year and next. If the fund is proved right, by 2013 emerg­ing markets (on the IMF’s de�nition) will produce more than halfof global output, measured at purchasing­power parity (PPP).

One sign of a shift in economic power is that investors ex­pect trouble in rich countries but seem con�dent that crises inemerging markets will not recur. Many see the rich world as old,debt­ridden and out of ideas compared with the young, zestfuland high­saving emerging markets. The truth is more complex.One reason why emerging­market companies are keen for a toe­hold in rich countries is that the business climate there is farfriendlier than at home. But the recent succession of �nancialblow­ups in the rich world makes it seem more crisis­prone.

The American subprime mess that turned into a �nancialdisaster had the hallmarks of a developing­world crisis: largecapital in�ows channelled by poorly regulated banks to margin­al borrowers to �nance a property boom. The speed at whichbond investors turned on Greece, Ireland and then Portugal wasreminiscent of a run on an overborrowed emerging economy.

Because there is as yet no reliable and liquid bond marketin the emerging world to �ee to, scared investors put their moneyinto US Treasury bonds and a few other rich­country havens in­stead. So few are the options that even a ratings downgrade ofAmerican government debt in August spurred buying of the de­rided Treasuries. Indeed the thirst in emerging markets for suchsafe and liquid securities is one of the deeper causes of the series

of crises that has a�icted the rich world. Developing countriesbought rich­world government bonds (stored as currency re­serves) as insurance against future crises. Those purchasespushed down long­term interest rates, helping to stoke a boomin private and public credit.

Today’s faltering GDP growth is a hangover from that boomand adds to the sense of malaise in the rich world. Many house­holds in America, Britain and elsewhere have taken to savinghard to reduce their debts. Those with spare cash, including com­panies, are clinging on to it as a hedge against an uncertain fu­ture. A new breed of emerging­market multinational �rms, usedto a tough business climate at home, seem keener to invest in therich world than most Western �rms, which have lost their mojo.

Grandeur and decline

People who grew up in America and western Europe havebecome used to the idea that the West dominates the worldeconomy. In fact it is anomalous that a group of 30­odd countrieswith a small fraction of the world’s population should be callingthe shots. For most of human history economic power has beendetermined by demography. In 1700 the world’s biggest econ­omy (and leading cotton producer) was India, with a populationof 165m, followed by China, with 138m. Britain’s 8.6m peopleproduced less than 3% of the world’s output. Even in 1820, as theindustrial revolution in Britain was gathering pace, the two

2 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

2

1

The Economist September 24th 2011 3

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

Asian giants still accounted for half theworld’s GDP.

The spread of purpose­built manu­factories like Quarry Bank Mill separatedeconomic power and population, increas­ingly so as the West got richer. Being ableto make a lot more stu� with fewer work­ers meant that even a small country couldbe a giant economic power. By 1870 the av­erage income in Britain was six times larg­er than in India or China. But by the eve ofthe �rst world war Britain’s income perhead had been overtaken by that ofAmerica, the 20th century’s great power.

America remains the world’s biggesteconomy, but that status is under threatfrom a resurgent China. With hindsight, itschange in fortune can be traced to 1976, theyear of America’s bicentennial and thedeath of Mao Zedong. By then income perperson in China had shrunk to just 5% ofthat in America, in part because of Mao’sextreme industrial and social policies.

The average Indian was scarcelyricher than the average Chinese. Both Chi­na and India had turned inward, cuttingthemselves o� from the �ow of ideas andgoods that had made Japan and other lesspopulous Asian economies richer. India’seconomy, like China’s, was largely closed.Huge swathes of industry were protectedfrom foreign competition by high importtari�s, leaving them moribund.

China was �rst to reverse course. In1978 Deng Xiaoping won approval for aset of economic reforms that opened Chi­na to foreign trade, technology and invest­ment. India’s big liberalisation came a lit­tle later, in 1991. The GDP of China andIndia is many times bigger now than itwas in the mid­1970s. In both economiesannual growth of 8% or more is consid­ered normal. Average living standards inChina are still only a sixth and in India afourteenth of those in America at PPP ex­change rates, but the gap is already muchsmaller than it was and is closing fast.

Moreover, the great convergence hasspread beyond India and China. Three­quarters of biggish non­oil­producing poor countries enjoyedfaster growth in income per person than America in 2000­07,says Arvind Subramanian, of the Peterson Institute for Interna­tional Economics, in his new book, �Eclipse: Living in the Shad­ow of China’s Economic Dominance�. This compares with 29%of such countries in 1960­2000. And those economies are catch­ing up at a faster rate: average growth in GDP per person was 3.3percentage points faster than America’s growth rate in 2000­07,more than twice the di�erence in the previous four decades.

If emerging markets keep on growing three percentagepoints a year faster than America (a conservative estimate), theywill account for two­thirds of the world’s output by 2030, reck­ons Mr Subramanian. Today’s four most populous emergingmarkets�China, India, Indonesia and Brazil�will make up two­�fths of global GDP, measured at PPP. The combined weight inthe world economy of America and the European Union will

shrink from more than a third to less than a quarter. Economic catch­up is accelerating. Britain’s economy dou­

bled in size in the 32 years from 1830 to 1862 as increased produc­tivity spread from cotton to other industries. America’s GDP

doubled in only 17 years as it overtook Britain in the 1870s. Theeconomies of China and India have doubled within a decade.

This is cause for optimism. An Indian with a basic collegeeducation has access to world­class goods that his parents (whomight have saved for decades for a sputtering scooter) could onlyhave dreamed of buying. The recent leap in incomes is visible inChinese cities, where the cars are new but the bicycles look an­cient, and in the futuristic skyline of Shanghai’s �nancial district.

China is still a fairly poor country but, by dint of its largepopulation, it is already the world’s second­largest economymeasured in current dollars. It may overtake America as theworld’s leading economy within a decade (see box), a prospect

IN 2010 CHINA shot past Japan to becomethe world’s second­largest economy (basedon current market prices). But when mightit supplant America at number one? Theanswer depends on how the exchange ratesare calculated. The IMF’s forecasts and thelong­run tables of GDP compiled by the lateAngus Maddison, an economic historian,are based on purchasing­power parity(PPP), which makes allowances for the lowerprices of non­traded services in poorercountries. On that basis, the size of China’seconomy is already close to America’s and islikely to overtake it by 2016.

China is further behind when itseconomy is measured in current dollars(and much further in terms of GDP perperson). America’s GDP in 2010 was $14.5trillion at current market prices; China’swas $5.9 trillion. How quickly the gap isclosed depends on three things: the relativespeed of real GDP growth in China and Amer­ica respectively; the in�ation gap betweenthe two economies; and the rate at whichthe yuan rises or falls against the dollar.

The Economist has crunched thenumbers and found that, based on reason­able assumptions about these three vari­ables, China could overtake America in thenext decade. Its economy has grown by anaverage of more than 10% a year over thepast ten years. As the country gets richerand its working­age population starts toshrink, that growth rate is likely to tail o�to perhaps 8% soon. For the Americaneconomy the calculation assumed an aver­age annual growth rate of 2.5%.

In�ation tends to be higher in fast­growing emerging economies than inslow­growing rich ones. This is because of

Becoming number one

China’s economy could overtake America’s within a decade

the Balassa­Samuelson e�ect, named forthe two economists who �rst explained it.Fast productivity growth in export in­dustries raises average wage costs acrossthe economy, including in non­tradedservices where productivity is sluggish. Thatin turn pushes up average in�ation. Ourprojection assumes a 4% in�ation rate inChina compared with 2% in America.

The third factor is the exchange rate.To sustain its catch­up with America, Chinaneeds to rebalance its economy away fromexports towards consumer spending, whichwill require a rise in its real exchange rate.Some of this will come from having a higherin�ation rate than its trading partners. ButChina’s large current­account surplus andAmerica’s big de�cit also suggest that theyuan will have to become much strongerand the dollar much weaker. We have al­lowed for an extra 3% annual rise in theyuan against the dollar on top of the in­�ation gap of two percentage points.That implies a slight slowdown inthe yuan’s recent appreciation.

If all this comes to pass,China’s economy will bebigger than America’s by2020. On a di�erent set ofassumptions�a Chinesegrowth rate of 6%, an Americanone of 3% and an appreciation ofthe yuan of 2% a year�the dateslips to 2024. Or you can makeyour own predictions, using theinteractive chart on The Econo­

mist’s website, by going tohttp://www.economist.com/blogs/dailychart/2010/12/save_date.

2

1

4 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

2 that has given rise to many concerns in that country. More gener­ally, there are worries about what the ascendancy of emergingmarkets would mean for jobs, pay and borrowing costs in therich world.

The �rst worry is about direct competition for things thatare in more or less �xed supply: geopolitical supremacy, theworld’s oil and raw materials, the status and perks that comewith being the issuer of a trusted international currency. Formost people, most of the time, their country’s ranking in terms ofmilitary power is not a big issue. The emerging world’s hungerfor natural resources, on the other hand, has made rich­worldconsumers palpably worse o� by pushing up the prices of oiland other commodities. The yuan’s increased use beyond Chi­na’s borders is a (still distant) threat to the dollar’s central role intrade and international �nance, but if the dollar were eventuallyshoved aside, it would make Americans poorer and raise the costof their borrowing.

A second set of anxieties relates to job security and pay.Ever stronger trade links between rich and would­be rich coun­tries will mean a reshu�e in the division of labour around theworld, creating new jobs and destroying or displacing existingones. Low­skilled manufacturing and middle­skilled servicejobs that can be delivered electronically have been outsourced tocheaper suppliers in China, India and elsewhere (indeed, Chinais now rich enough to be vulnerable to losing jobs to Vietnamand Indonesia). The threat of outsourcing puts downward pres­sure on pay, though most American studies suggest that trade ac­counts for only a small part of the increase in wage inequality.

A third concern, which is at odds with the �rst two, is thatthe emerging markets are prone to crises that can cause a still­fragile world economy to stumble. Sluggish GDP growth in therich world means developing countries have to fall back on inter­nal spending, which in the past they have not managed well. Itraises the risks of the overspending, excessive credit and in�ationthat have spurred past emerging­market crises. Even if crises areavoided, emerging markets are prone to sudden slowdowns asthey become richer and the trick of shifting underemployed ru­ral migrants to urban jobs becomes harder to repeat. The rapidgrowth rates of the recent past are unlikely to be sustained.

Status anxiety

Few forecasters expect America to be a poorer place in tenor 20 years’ time than it is now. The present may be grim, buteventually the hangover from the �nancial crisis will fade andunemployment will fall. What rich Western countries face is arelative economic decline, not an absolute fall in average livingstandards (though a few of their citizens may become worse o�).That matters politically, because most people measure their well­being by how they are doing in relation to others rather than bytheir absolute level of income.

The e�ect of the loss of top­dog status on the well­being ofthe average American is unlikely to be trivial. Britain felt similarangst at the beginning of the 20th century, noting the rise of Ger­many, a military rival. It seemed stuck with old industries, suchas textiles and iron, whereas Germany had advanced into �eldssuch as electricals and chemicals. That Britain was still well o� inabsolute terms was scant consolation. The national mood con­trasted starkly with the triumphalism of the mid­19th century,says Nicholas Crafts of Warwick University. A wave of protec­tionist sentiment challenged the free­trade consensus that hadprevailed since 1846. It was seen o�, but not before it had split theTory party, which lost the 1906 election to the Liberals.

No country, or group of countries, stays on top forever. His­tory and economic theory suggest that sooner or later others willcatch up. But this special report will caution against relying on

linear extrapolation from recent growth rates. Instead, it will sug­gest that the transfer of economic power from rich countries toemerging markets is likely to take longer than generally expect­ed. Rich countries will be cursed indeed if they cannot put on anoccasional growth spurt. China, for its part, will be lucky toavoid a bad stumble in the next decade or two. Emerging­marketcrises have been too quickly forgotten, which only makes themmore likely to recur.

Education and social security will have to adapt to a worldin which jobs continue to be created and displaced at a rapidrate. The cost of oil and other commodities will continue to risefaster than prices in general, shifting the terms of trade in favourof resource­rich countries and away from big consumers such asAmerica. The yuan will eventually become an international cur­rency and rival to the dollar. The longer that takes, the less pres­sure America will feel to control its public �nances and the likeli­er it is that the dollar’s eclipse will be abrupt and messy.

The force of economic convergence depends on the in­come gap between developing and developed countries. Goingfrom poor to less poor is the easy part. The trickier bit is makingthe jump from middle­income to reasonably rich. Can Chinaand others manage it? 7

1

WITH A MAXIMUM speed of 430kph (267mph), theShanghai magnetic­levitation (or maglev) train is as much

fairground ride as vital cog in the city’s transport system. Astretch of the 30km track from Longyang Road to Pudong Inter­national Airport runs alongside a motorway. The speeding carsleft behind are a guide to how fast the train is moving. For pas­sengers who like to quantify their thrills, a digital speedometerin each carriage counts up the train’s acceleration to its top speedbefore the numbers tumble again as the train slows towards theairport terminal.

The Shanghai maglev is a powerful symbol of China’s mo­dernity�even if the technology was developed in the 1960s inslowcoach Britain and the kit was made by Siemens, a Germanengineering �rm. But the venture is not a money­spinner. On amidsummer afternoon, the train is half­empty and many of itsoccupants are tourists travelling just for fun. That is because, forall its impressive speed, the maglev is not a great way to get to orfrom the airport. Tickets are too pricey for all but rich businessfolk and foreign tourists, and those customers �nd the line incon­venient. Once they alight at Longyang Road they are still someway from the �nancial district and the best hotels.

Sceptics about China’s economic miracle see the Shanghaishuttle as an example of how badly state­directed banks allocatecapital. China invests some 50% of its GDP, more than double theaverage in rich countries. The big capital projects of state­ownedenterprises, such as railways, receive funding on easy terms, butinterest rates paid on bank deposits are capped. A system that fa­vours certain borrowers over ordinary savers or bank share­holders is bound to back ill­judged projects and run up baddebts, argue the bears. A collision between two high­speedtrains in China on July 23rd, which killed 40 and left 191 injured,seemed only to con�rm those suspicions.

Let’s leapfrog

But there is a kinder interpretation of China’s appetite forprestige projects such as high­speed rail. Its leaders must knowthat as an economy develops it cannot rely inde�nitely on copy­ing the machinery and know­how of richer countries. The bet­ter­o� a country becomes, the closer its technology is to bestpractice and the fewer of its workers are left in low­productivityjobs such as farming. The easy catch­up gains are exhausted andthe economy slows or gets stuck. One way out of this �middle­in­come trap� is by trying to leapfrog the technology leaders.

China’s recent growth has been so impressive that it seemschurlish to question whether it can continue. Yet the country will�nd it more di�cult to grow quickly as it becomes richer, as willIndia and Brazil. All three big emerging markets need to �ndways to avoid the in�ation that has bedevilled developing coun­tries in the past, and to strike a good balance between consump­tion and investment, foreign and domestic demand.

China’s reliance on exports and on investment that sup­ports export industries has reached its limits. The country nowneeds to shift the balance towards domestic demand, which re­quires capital to be redirected toward the smaller enterprisesthat serve consumers. Brazil is almost the mirror image of China.

It has a thriving consumer economy which it is �nding hard tokeep in check. Its high interest rates discourage the investmentspending it needs to improve its poor productivity record. And itneeds to make sure that the strong currency that comes with abooming commodity sector does not leave it with too narrow anindustrial base. India, like Brazil, is prone to overheating and hasa current­account de�cit, though thanks to its high investmentrate its productivity record is closer to China’s.

The problems of middle­aged development will soon af­�ict China and others, according to research by Barry Eichen­green of the University of California, Berkeley, Donghyun Parkof the Asian Development Bank and Kwanho Shin of Korea Uni­versity. They examined middle­income countries (with earningsper person of at least $10,000 in 2005 prices) which in the pasthalf­century had enjoyed average GDP growth of at least 3.5% forseveral years but whose growth rate had subsequently fallen byat least two percentage points. The research con�rmed theirhunch that the loss of momentum is mostly due to economicmaturity rather than a shortage of workers or a slackening in in­vestment. The workforce grew at the same rate after the slow­down as before it, and its quality kept improving: indeed the av­erage worker acquired skills at a slightly faster rate after theeconomy had slowed. The increase in physical capital (factories,o�ces, roads, machines and so on) tailed o�, but this accounted

for only a small fraction of thedrop in GDP growth.

Instead, most of that dropwas caused by a slump in �totalfactor productivity��the e�­ciency with which workers andcapital are used. �Growth slow­downs, in a nutshell, are pro­ductivity­growth slowdowns,�write Mr Eichengreen and hiscolleagues. A decline in totalfactor productivity is what youwould expect when the �easy�phase of economic develop­ment comes to a close. Movingunderemployed villagers intourban jobs in factories and of­�ces with imported equipment

Converging economies

One­track bind

To become rich, the emerging markets must spring

the middle­income trap

Great fall of China

Source: CEIC

Chinese householdconsumption as % of GDP

0

20

40

60

80

1952 70 80 90 2000 10

1

The Economist September 24th 2011 5

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

2

1

raises productivity. But as rural slack is used up there are no moresuch gains to be had.

According to the three economists, this sort of slowdown ismost likely to happen when average income reaches around$16,000 in 2005 prices; when income per person rises to 58% ofthat in the world’s leading economy; or when the share of em­ployment in manufacturing gets to 23%. Those three thresh­olds�of which the absolute level of income is the most impor­tant�will not necessarily all be reached at the same time. Chinamay already have hit the manufacturing target, and if its econ­omy sustains a growth rate of around 9%, the average incomethreshold will soon be breached. But the relative income thresh­old remains far o�. In 2010 China’s income per person was 16% ofAmerica’s, according to the IMF.

The research shows that economies such as China’s, withan undervalued currency and a low rate of consumer spending,are more likely to su�er such a growth slowdown. These mile­stones are based on averages of many countries that livedthrough sudden slowdowns, and their experiences varied wide­ly, cautions Mr Eichengreen. These are not iron laws. Even so, itseems certain that a slowdown will follow once the easier partof the catching up has been done. The question is whether Chinacan mitigate this by changing its growth model.

Last year’s model

That model has proved successful in other parts of Asia. It isexport­led, so demand has been mainly from abroad. To meet it,China has mobilised its vast reserves of cheap labour, to which ithas added a fast­growing stock of physical capital, much of it im­ported but �nanced from the country’s own savings. Because ofChina’s capital­intensive growth model, consumer spending hasan unusually small share of GDP: in 2010 it fell to only 34% (seechart 1, previous page). This only adds to the reliance on exports.

China’s �nancial set­up reinforces this model. The �ow ofcapital across its borders is heavily policed. China has curbed therise in its currency, and kept its exports competitive, by buyinghuge quantities of dollars and other foreign currencies, amass­ing $3.2 trillion of foreign­exchange reserves, worth 54% of Chi­na’s 2010 GDP.

The banking system is closely managed by the state. For­eign banks account for barely 2% of total bank assets. The cashcreated to keep the yuan down is mopped up by forcing China’sbanks to buy low­yielding �sterilisation� bonds or to hold morecash in reserve. Interest rates are set in favour of state­ownedcompanies (often monopoly suppliers to exporters) but o�er lit­tle reward for householders. Credit for consumers is still scarce.

China’s growing weight in the world economy means itcannot rely inde�nitely on other countries’ spending. The debtoverhang in parts of the rich world means that China’s foreigncustomers are hard­pressed. And the country is a drain on de­mand from the rest of the world: its current­account surplus (ameasure of its excess saving) rose above 10% of GDP in 2007,though it has since halved. This is a source of tension: the Ameri­cans complain that China’s exchange­rate policy provides its ex­porters with an unfair subsidy at the expense of their own work­ers. The export­led strategy is also beginning to lose its potency.Each rural migrant set to work on machinery to serve China’s for­eign customers is harder to �nd than the last.

If China is to avoid the middle­income trap, it needs to de­velop its domestic market. It must switch from indiscriminatelyamassing factories, ports and other �xed assets to a more �nelygraded allocation of capital and workers that allows small ser­vice �rms to �ourish. That transition will be helped along by twofactors. As the working population starts to shrink around 2015,the household saving rate should fall because countries with

fewer earners and a larger proportion of dependents tend tospend more. And China already devotes a bigger share of its GDP

to research and development than do other countries with simi­lar income levels. That gives it a better chance of sustaining pro­ductivity growth when the gains from adopting existing technol­ogies run out. But other facets of China’s economy militateagainst change. For example, the World Bank ranks China 65thout of 183 countries for giving companies access to credit, behindIndia (in 32nd place).

The obstacles are formidable. Shifting to an economy thatconcentrates on consumers will mean dislocating entire indus­tries. Higher wages in China, which are needed for this sort of re­balancing, are already driving some textile jobs to Vietnam andCambodia. Removing implicit subsidies to rents and interestrates would cut many �rms’ pro�ts and stir opposition. Banksused to dishing out capital at the government’s say­so wouldneed to make �ner judgments, withholding money from indus­tries with low returns and moving it to promising new ventures.But will they be able to tell the di�erence between the two?

Brazil is the textbook example of a fast­growing countrythat hit a wall (though it is not covered in the study by Mr Eichen­green and his colleagues). Its economy grew by an average of al­most 7% a year between 1945 and 1980. GDP per person rose fromjust 12% of America’s to 28%, according to the Maddison statistics.

But then convergence went into reverse.The debts accumulated to pay for import­ed machinery became crippling as inter­est rates shot up. Industries that hadserved a protected home market were re­vealed as ine�cient. A weak currencyand wage indexation fed �rst in�ationand then hyperin�ation.

A series of monetary and �scal re­forms in the 1990s tamed in�ation and ar­rested the decline in relative income. Bra­zil’s income per person is now above 20%of America’s level. But the economy suf­fers from frailties that are the mirror­im­age of China’s. Investment is 19% of GDP,well below China’s and quite low evenby rich­world standards. That is one rea­son why productivity is feeble, thoughBrazil’s woeful education system and de­crepit infrastructure are also to blame.The economy tends to grow at around 4%a year, faster than most rich countries butmore slowly than Brazil’s emerging­mar­ket peers.

Weak investment re�ects low do­mestic saving. Brazil still habitually runs acurrent­account de�cit. This reliance onforeign capital has left it vulnerable to per­iodic balance­of­payments crises, thoughit has piled up $344 billion of foreign­cur­rency reserves to fend them o� in future.Brazil’s net foreign liabilities (private andpublic) amount to $700 billion, comparedwith China’s net assets of £1.8 trillion.

The �ip side of Brazil’s low saving isstrong consumer spending, at 61% of GDP

last year. The business of providing loansto householders is booming. This is inpart because BNDES, the state­owned de­velopment bank, provides subsidisedloans to Brazil’s big state­directed compa­

China’sgrowingweight inthe worldeconomymeans itcannot relyinde�nitelyon othercountries’spending

6 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

The Economist September 24th 2011 7

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

nies and to some other �rms. That limits opportunities for busi­ness lending, so private banks must look elsewhere.

Brazil’s economy has two great strengths. Its population ofworking age is growing quickly, and it is rich in natural resourcesat a time when emerging markets are industrialising at an un­precedented rate. Brazil vies with Australia as the world’s largestexporter of iron ore, much of it to China.Its plentiful arable land is astonishingly fe­cund (in some places three harvests a yearare possible), thanks to an ample supplyof sun and fresh water. The �sub­salt� res­ervoirs o� Brazil’s south­eastern shorecontain at least 13 billion barrels of oil.

The commodities boom and the oil�nds have freed Brazil from its traditionalbalance­of­payments constraints. Foreign money is �ooding in,lured by Brazil’s high interest rates and the expected earningsonce the oil starts to �ow. But that creates a new problem: astrong currency that hurts the country’s exporters outside the re­source industries.

The textbook remedy for this sort of �Dutch disease� is toraise productivity or lower costs in tradable industries that donot bene�t from the resource boom. In August the governmentsaid it would abolish payroll taxes in four labour­intensive in­dustries: footwear, clothing, furniture and software. There is am­ple scope to further lower the �Brazil cost��local shorthand for arange of handicaps including ramshackle roads, high interestrates, jobs levies, taxes and bureaucracy.

Brazil is one of the most onerous countries to do businessin, coming 127th out of 183 in the World Bank’s ranking. Hiringand �ring is costly and closing a business can take years. The taxsystem is complex and bedevilled by rules that often con�ict. �Ifyou’re honest and want to comply with the tax code, you needan accountant and a tax lawyer for life,� laments one São Paulo­based economist.

Real interest rates in Brazil are among the highest in theworld. The central bank’s benchmark rate is 12% and may need torise again to tame in�ation, which is well above the target of4.5%. High rates are in part a legacy of past in�ation that pun­ished saving and rewarded borrowing. A culture of saving hasyet to take �rm root, so demand for credit outstrips supply. Fiscallaxity has also played a part. The economy is running at or be­yond full capacity. The jobless rate is 6%; it has rarely been lower.Brazil’s budget ought to be in surplus. Government debt is rolledover every three years and crowds out other borrowing. But amarket for longer­term debt would require a commitment tokeeping public­sector payrolls and state pensions in check.

Brazil hopes that the oil discoveries will be exploited in away that helps other industries rather than harming them. Thegovernment has insisted that Petrobras, the state­controlled oilgiant with sole operating rights in the sub­salt �eld, must buymost of its supplies in Brazil.

Eike Batista, a colourful magnate with interests in mining,oil exploration and logistics, is building a port complete withshipyard (in tandem with Hyundai, a South Korean �rm) to com­ply with the local­content rules. �The demand from Petrobrascould �ll two shipyards,� he says. A modern port will encourageforeign manufacturers to build factories along Brazil’s coast andserve the domestic market. �Brazil will not be trapped in com­modities,� he insists. But others worry that Brazil is �irting with astate­in�uenced and inward­facing model of industrialisationthat has failed before.

Brazil and China need to make di�erent sorts of transitionsif they are to sustain their development. Brazil has to save and in­vest more; China needs to consume more. Brazil is rich in re­

There is ample scope tolower the �Brazilcost��local shorthand fora range of handicaps

1

2

8 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

sources; China is hungry for them. Brazil is short of good roadsand railways; some of China’s will attract too little tra�c. Brazil isyoung; China is ageing. �Perhaps they should merge,� is the wrysuggestion of Arminio Fraga, a former central­bank governor ofBrazil who now runs Gávea Investments in Rio de Janeiro.

India’s bumpy road

India’s main challenges are a mix of those facing Brazil andChina. Like China, India has enjoyed a recent growth rate abovethe emerging­market norm, at around 8% a year. It ought to be do­ing better still: after all, it is poorer than China, so the scope forcatching up is greater. Investment is a healthy 38% of GDP. Muchof India’s investment is �nanced out of companies’ own pockets,a symptom of an immature �nancial system. Most �rms cannotrely on external funding, though giant Indian conglomerates,such as Tata, are able to tap into international capital markets.

Like Brazil, India is in desperate need of better roads to linkits far­�ung internal markets. It is a young country, with its work­ing­age population set to grow at 1.7% a year until 2015, a fasterrate even than Brazil’s. But too many of its people are educatedbadly, if at all. As in Brazil, companies often have to provide re­medial education to bring recruits up to scratch. Arcane lawsstand in the way of a well­functioning jobs market. Corruption isa blight on infrastructure projects. The economy is prone to over­heating and has a current­account de�cit.

This speaks of a deeper weakness in emerging markets. Inthe past they have not been good at managing internal demand.Relying on exports allowed them to grow and save at the sametime. Now that the rich world’s economies are struggling, thathas become harder, raising the prospect of the sort of ills that ledto emerging­market crises in the past: excess government spend­ing, rapid credit growth and in�ation. The transition from mid­dle­income to rich economy relies on sound monetary, �scal andregulatory policies, says Raghuram Rajan, a former IMF chiefeconomist now at Chicago’s Booth School of Business.

The fear of renewed trouble in the debt­laden rich­worldeconomies has meant that Brazil and India have been slow tostop local in�ationary pressures from building. China passed its�rst big test �lling in for rich­world demand when it increasedbank credit by an astonishing one­third during 2009. It was awelcome stimulus to the local and global economy, but there aregrowing doubts about the wisdom of many of those loans. Thedebts run up by local authorities to �nance infrastructure are ofparticular concern.

China bulls argue that the expenditure was essential to thecountry’s rebalancing. Better transport links between the richcoastal cities and poorer western regions were needed to devel­op China’s internal market. Sceptics see roads with no cars,trains with few passengers and empty buildings. Some reportssay 2 trillion yuan of local­authority loans have gone sour. Wor­ryingly, some of the foreign investors who had rushed to takestakes in Chinese banks are slinking away. Bank of America,which has problems in its home market, has sold half its stake inChina Construction Bank.

Even so, stabilising aggregate demand may prove easierthan settling the social con�icts or tackling the industrial stasisthat entrap middle­income countries. This depends not only ona well­tuned economic engine; it also relies on how fairly thepain of adjustment is shared, says Harvard University’s Dani Ro­drik. Societies torn by class or other rivalries are often set back byeconomic change. Democracies with rules and procedures forsettling disputes and compensating losers tend to do better.

Mr Rodrik contrasts South Korea’s bounce­back from theEast Asian crisis in 1998 (as well as from earlier troubles) with theslump endured by Brazil and other Latin American countries in

the 1980s. South Korean industry had been tested in export mar­kets so it could build a recovery on its industrial strength. Brazilhad lacked that strength. But South Korea was also able to recov­er more quickly because each interest group agreed to absorbsome of the pain from the downturn. The government said itwould do its best to help the country get over the crisis but �rmsshould do their bit by avoiding lay­o�s and unions should mod­erate their wage demands. In Brazil, by contrast, everyone triedto shift the pain of lower living standards onto others. In�ationtook o� and Brazil’s GDP per person stagnated for 15 years.

China may have the stronger economy, says Mr Rodrik, butBrazil and India are likely to be better at handling the social mo­bility that comes with being a middle­income country. All threeof these emerging­market giants will have to work hard to avoidthe middle­income trap. Their recent economic performance isgood but experience suggests that there will be setbacks. Yet asthe rich world stumbles from crisis to crisis, the prosperity gap isclosing fast. America’s claim to economic leadership looks in­creasingly threadbare, and one of its long­held privileges�hav­ing the world’s main reserve currency�is under threat. 7

AT THE FLAGSHIP store of Yue Hwa Chinese Products inHong Kong customers can �nd exotic and everyday items

from mainland China without having to cross the border. The of­ferings include silk brocades, sandalwood carvings, Sichuanpeppers and traditional Chinese remedies such as ribbed ante­lope horns. Horn shavings, boiled in water, are said to quietenthe liver and quell fevers.

Feverish visitors from the mainland can even pay for theirshavings in their own currency, the yuan. The store charges2,660 yuan ($416) for a whole horn, at an exchange rate of 1.1Hong Kong dollar per yuan. Nearby money­changers o�er a bet­ter rate, but some Chinese visitors prefer the convenience of us­ing their own money. That way they can still get a late­nightsnack at the 7­Eleven after the money­changers have closed.

That is how, not long ago, the yuan set out on its career as aninternational currency. It crept into Hong Kong in the wallets ofmainland visitors. The trickle across China’s borders quickenedlast year when the government allowed a broader range of Chi­nese �rms to settle imports and exports in yuan. In the same yearit set these o�shore yuan free. Outside the mainland, the yuancould be transferred between banks, borrowed, lent and invest­ed, just like any other currency.

This o�shore experiment is, for many forecasters, a �rst ten­tative step towards making the yuan a fully �edged reserve cur­rency to rival the dollar and the euro. But China’s policymakersare in two minds, as they tend to be when it comes to freeing �­nance. Restricting the �ow of money into and out of China pro­tects the country’s immature banking system. When Japan sanc­tioned the international use of the yen in the 1980s it set the stagefor a damaging property bubble.

On the other hand China hates having to rely on the dollar.O�cials are troubled by the Federal Reserve’s notably loose

Reserve currencies

Climbing greenbackmountain

The yuan is still a long way from being a reserve

currency, but its rise is overdue

2

1

The Economist September 24th 2011 9

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

2

1

monetary policy and by America’s rapidly rising public debt.They fear that stimulus measures put in place to revive America’s�agging economy will sooner or later generate a burst of high in­�ation and weaken the dollar. That would hurt holders of US

government bonds, including China. Around $2 trillion of itscurrency reserves of $3.2 trillion are in dollars, mostly in bonds.On August 5th America lost its triple­A credit rating from Stan­dard & Poor’s because it had failed to come up with a credibleplan to cap its public debt. China’s o�cial news agency, Xinhua,immediately called for a new reserve currency.

Such calls have been made before, during bouts of dollarweakness in the late 1970s and mid­1990s, but the dollar stillholds the privileged position in the world’s monetary system ithas occupied since the second world war. It faces no immediatechallenge to its status, notwithstanding the debt downgrade, be­cause there are few good alternatives. Despite a long and steadydecline in its value against other currencies, it still accounts for60.7% of the world’s $9.7 trillion of currency reserves. That isaround three times America’s weight in the world economy asmeasured by GDP. The dollar’s closest rival, the euro, accountsfor 26.6% of the world’s reserves.

How does one currency maintain such dominance? Text­book economics says domestic money has three uses: as a unitof account against which the value of goods is measured; as amedium of exchange; and as a store of value used to conservespending power for a rainy day.

The won ful�ls these roles in South Korea; the yuan doesthe job in China; and the dollar provides these services in inter­national markets as well as in America. It is the unit of accountfor commodities such as crude oil that are traded globally. Mosttrade that is invoiced in a currency other than those of the trad­ing partners is quoted in dollars. And be­cause the dollar is the benchmark forworld prices and is used to settle cross­border trades, it makes sense for countriesto keep stores of dollar reserves, both as a�oat and to bolster con�dence in theirown currencies.

The demand for reserve currenciesis a boon to their issuers. Around $500 bil­lion of America’s currency is used outsidethe country’s borders. Some of this cash isused to lubricate dollar­based interna­tional trade. But much of it greases thewheels of cross­border crime such asdrug tra�cking: crooks need a unit of ac­count, a medium of exchange and a storeof value just like legitimate businesspeople.

Indeed, a reserve currency might almost be de�ned by itsappeal to criminals. Of the ¤900 billion­worth of euro notes incirculation, a third by value comes in the form of the pink andpurple ¤500 note. Cynics say it was issued to capture a share ofthe international black market from the dollar, for which the larg­est denomination is $100. An illegal stash of ¤500 bills would belighter, easier to conceal and easier to count. The ¤500 note waswithdrawn by banks in Britain after police said its main use wasin organised crime. That is a compliment of sorts to the euro.When Somali pirates or Russian gangsters demand payment inyuan, it will be the surest sign that economic power has shiftedto China.

The cost of printing $500 billion­worth of notes is negligi­ble compared with the value of the goods and services they cancommand. In order for those notes to circulate outside America,they must �rst have been exchanged for $500 billion­worth ofgoods and services. They represent a cost in real resources. The

gap between the printing cost of banknotes and their face valueis called seigniorage. Governments that print reserve currenciesbene�t from extending seigniorage beyond their own borders.

Issuers of international currencies also enjoy protectionfrom currency volatility. A Vietnamese exporter selling to Chinais exposed to exchange­rate risk: he pays his workforce in dong,the local currency, but receives payment in dollars. If the dollarfalls, so do his earnings, but his labour costs are unchanged.American exporters do not have to worry about currency mis­match because both their domestic costs and their export earn­ings are in dollars.

Nor has America had much need to acquire costly reservesof its own. Under the Bretton Woods system of �xed exchangerates that governed rich­country trade until 1971, members wereconstantly at risk of running short of dollars if their exports be­came uncompetitive, whereas America could always print moredollars. This was an �exorbitant privilege�, grumbled France’s �­nance minister at the time, Valéry Giscard d’Estaing.

Exorbitant privilege v original sin

The privileges of reserve­currency status were not con�nedto the dollar, though it enjoyed the lion’s share. They include be­ing able to borrow cheaply. The dollars and euros (and, to a lesserextent, the pounds, Swiss francs and yen) that other centralbanks keep in reserve are mostly in the form of governmentbonds. The extra demand weighs on bond yields and sets a low­er threshold for the cost of credit for businesses and consumers.

This part of the exorbitant privilege contrasts with theemerging world’s �original sin�, a term coined by Barry Eichen­green of the University of California, Berkeley, and RicardoHausmann of Harvard University for some countries’ inabilityto borrow in their own currencies. Borrowing in foreign curren­cies (as Brazil and other Latin American countries had done be­fore the 1980s debt crisis) leaves original sinners at risk of defaultif their currency loses value. Trouble­prone countries have oftenhad to keep interest rates high, even in a recession, to supporttheir currencies and stave o� default on foreign­currency debts.Hungary is a recent example of a country in this sort of trap. TheFederal Reserve has never had to worry about such things.

The divide between the exorbitantly privileged and the

original sinners was especially deep after the East Asian crisis of1997­98. The lesson from that crisis was never to be short of re­serves. The investment rate in emerging Asia fell, the saving ratestayed high and the excess saving was sent abroad. It marked thestart of an unprecedented build­up of foreign exchange to insureagainst future balance­of­payments problems. The world’s cur­rency reserves increased from $1.9 trillion in 2000 to $9.3 trillionin 2010. Much of the increase was in China.

The surge in demand for safe and liquid assets in dollars,euros and pounds pushed down long­term borrowing costs. Thesavings of the emerging world allowed the rich world to spendtoo freely, one of the deeper causes of the wave of crises that hasa�icted the rich world since 2007. America’s �nancial marketsmet the global demand for �safe� dollar assets by repackagingthe mortgages of marginal borrowers as bonds, which turnedsour. But the resulting �nancial crisis hit mainly the rich worldrather than the emerging markets.

Rich­world banks and investors seeking higher returns

China hates having to rely on the dollar. O� icials aretroubled by the Federal Reserve’s loose monetary policyand by America’s rapidly rising public debt

10 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

2

1

when interest rates were low had bought a lot of the ropy mort­gage securities. That made room for reserve managers in emerg­ing markets to buy more bonds backed by governments or is­sued directly by them. Investors were so anxious for yield thatthey barely distinguished between good and bad credits. Coun­tries with large public debts, such as Greece and Italy, could bor­row as cheaply as countries with sound public �nances such asGermany. Windfall tax revenue from housing booms fuelled bycheap foreign credit made the public �nances of Ireland andSpain look sound until recession (and, in Ireland’s case, the terri­fying cost of bank bail­outs) caused public debt to explode.

Some believe the exorbitant privilege is really a curse thatlures the reserve­currency country into too much borrowing orprinting too much money. Over time this saps the economic andpolitical strength that was the source of the privilege. This para­dox was �rst noted in 1947 in a Federal Reserve paper written byRobert Tri�n, a Belgian­born economist.

Under the Bretton Woods arrangement currencies werepegged to the dollar at �xed exchange rates. The dollar in turnwas tied to gold at a �xed price. Tri�n spotted a dilemma. A ris­ing stock of dollars was needed to �nance world trade. The moredollars were supplied, the more the currency’s link to goldwould be questioned since America’s gold stocks would supportan ever­larger pile of banknotes. This came to a head in August1971 when heavy selling forced President Nixon to suspend the

conversion of dollars into gold. The Tri�n dilemma is echoed in contemporary worries

about the rich world’s public debts and its currencies. Easy accessto credit lured the euro zone’s periphery into overborrowing.Greece is insolvent, Ireland and Portugal are not far o�. For re­serve currencies, what is safe is in con�ict with what is conve­nient, argues Stephen Jen of SLJ Macro Partners, a hedge fund,adding that �the euro is e�cient but it’s not safe.� Reliable and liq­uid repositories for rainy­day saving are scarce, which is why re­serve managers and bond investors continue to push money intothe Treasury market. But this tempts America to overextend itself,amassing debts it may one day struggle to service.

As America’s weight in the global economy drops, supply­ing the world with most of its reserve currency needs may be­come too big a job for the country. In his recent book, �ExorbitantPrivilege�, Mr Eichengreen argues that a reserve­currency systemwill emerge in which the dollar, the euro and the yuan share theprivileges and the responsibilities. That would make the world asafer place, he reckons, because each issuer would nudge the oth­ers towards �nancial and �scal discipline.

It is not obvious that one currency needs to play a pre­emi­nent part. In its heyday, sterling was rarely as dominant as the dol­lar has been since it took over. On the eve of the �rst world warthe pound accounted for only around half of all reserves: most ofthe rest was in French francs and German marks. By 1924 more re­

The Economist September 24th 2011 11

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

serves were held in dollars than in sterling.The dollar is �awed, but so are the candidates to displace it.

The euro has no single �scal authority standing behind it. Nor isthere a single issuer of sovereign debt to match the size and li­quidity of the market for US Treasuries�although the bonds is­sued by the European Financial Stability Facility (EFSF), the euroarea’s emergency bail­out fund, may foreshadow a single eurobond backed by all its members. For all its shortcomings, theeuro still accounts for a quarter of the world’s reserves. Even asthe region’s sovereign­debt crisis has deepened over the pastyear, its currency has gained groundagainst the greenback.

The speed at which the dollar rose toprominence suggests that the yuan mightbe an international currency as soon as2020, says Mr Eichengreen. The greenbackovertook sterling in reserves barely a de­cade after the founding of the Federal Reserve in 1913 as the back­stop of dollar liquidity. The Fed pushed the dollar by fostering aliquid market for trade acceptances, the credit notes used to fundshipments. By the mid­1920s more trade was carried out in dol­lars than pounds and more international bonds were issued inNew York than in London.

However, the obstacles to the yuan becoming a reserve cur­rency are bigger than those faced by the dollar in 1913. At that timeAmerica was already a trusted storehouse for capital, a democra­cy where the rule of law was �rmly established. China’s recenthistory is less reassuring, so it will take a while before foreignersfeel secure keeping their savings in yuan. The currency wouldhave to be fully convertible so that investors could park theiryuan reserves in assets of their choosing and redeem themwhen needed.

This in turn would require China to allow capital to movefreely across its borders, which it has been reluctant to do. In re­cent years it has eased restrictions on residents taking capital outof the country; for example, more foreign takeovers by big Chi­nese �rms have been allowed to go ahead. But foreigners faceformidable barriers to bringing money into China because thegovernment is reluctant to cede control of the yuan’s value or ofdomestic bond yields to the ebb and �ow of foreign capital.

China has taken some baby steps toward setting the yuanfree. It has allowed trade in goods to be invoiced and paid inyuan. The proceeds can be put to work in a �edgling o�shoreyuan market in Hong Kong with restricted links to the mainland.Trade settlement in yuan has grown rapidly, reaching 600 billionin the second quarter of 2011 (around 10% of total trade), accord­ing to the People’s Bank of China.

So far such trade settlement has been a rather one­sided af­fair: most has been for imports (ie, Chinese �rms paying foreign­ers in yuan for supplies). Few of China’s exporters are willing orable to demand yuan from foreign customers, though those cus­tomers should not �nd it hard to get hold of the currency. China’scentral bank has set up swap agreements with the central banksof many of its emerging­market trading partners, ranging fromSingapore to Kazakhstan, allowing foreign banks to supply yuanto their customers.

By the end of July yuan deposits in Hong Kong had swollento 572 billion. The IMF said in July that 155 billion of yuan­de­nominated bonds (so­called �dim sum� bonds) had been issuedin Hong Kong since the market was set up, many by branches ofmainland banks. Issues by non­�nancial foreign companies areless common, in part because �rms still need permission to bringthe cash raised into China. There have been some high­pro�ledeals, though the bonds have short duration. McDonald’s sold athree­year bond last year. Caterpillar, an American maker of

earthmoving equipment, has issued a couple of two­year bondsso far. A recent sale in Hong Kong of 20 billion yuan of govern­ment debt was heavily oversubscribed.

The o�shore yuan market has quickly come up from no­where and China’s central bank has continued to strike bilateralswap deals to keep it growing. But it is a big leap from being a cur­rency in which a chunk of your own trade is settled to being afully �edged international currency, and a further jump to re­serve­currency status. Only a small fraction of the world’s $4 tril­lion in foreign­exchange deals each day are for trade settlement.

The bulk of currency dealing is for hedging or related to tradingin stocks, bonds and other assets. The dollar is one side of 85% ofall currency trades, according to the Bank for International Settle­ments (see chart 2). The yuan accounts for just 0.3% of turnover.

Yet the exorbitant curse will catch up with the dollar oneday and the yuan is its most likely replacement. China’s econ­omy is second only to America’s in size and is likely to overtake itsoon. It is already the world’s largest exporter. And it has net for­eign assets of $1.8 trillion, whereas America owes a net $2.5 tril­lion to foreigners. Only Japan is in a stronger position.

A global yuan?

Reserve­currency status depends on these three gauges ofeconomic dominance�size of economy, exports and net foreignassets�says the Peterson Institute’s Arvind Subramanian. By 1918America had the world’s biggest economy and would soon be itslargest creditor and exporter; within a few years the dollar alsohad the lion’s share of the world’s foreign­exchange reserves. Ifthat precedent is anything to go by, the yuan should soon be­come the main global reserve currency, and not merely a junioralternative to the dollar or the euro.

The rewards to China of opening up fully to foreign capitaltrump the risks, reckons Mr Subramanian. Turning the yuan intoa reserve currency o�ers China a way out of its mercantilistgrowth model, which has run its course. Demand for yuan re­serves would push up the exchange rate, discourage exports andgive China’s consumers greater purchasing power. A push for re­

serve status for the yuanwould go hand in hand withthe development of China’s �­nancial system�a necessarystep to support the small­ andmedium­size businesses itneeds to serve its domesticmarket, and for many otherreasons. For China to escapethe middle­income trap, it willhave to let go of the yuan.

The rich world’s monop­oly on reserve­currency privi­leges has given it �rst call onthe world’s precautionarysavings. For now, it is clingingon to its privileges. But rivalryfrom developing countries inthe markets for oil and com­modities is already exacting aprice from the West. 7

It is a big leap from being a currency in which your owntrade is settled to being a fully �edged internationalcurrency, and a further jump to reserve­currency status

Passing the buck

Source: Bankfor InternationalSettlements

Currency share of average dailyforeign-exchange turnoverApril 2011, %

2

0 20 40 60 80 100

$

¤

¥

£

E-w* other

R-w† other

A$

Swiss franc

C$

Yuan

*Emerging-world†Rich-world

2

12 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

1

LOOK OUT ON any day from Pier Two at the Tubarão Portcomplex in Brazil and you will see at least half a dozen

ships on the horizon. The queue of waiting vessels allows theport’s loading manager, Leonardo Barone, to keep its three piersin constant use. Tubarão is owned by Vale, the world’s largestiron­ore company. A record 104m tonnes of ore was shippedfrom here last year.

Back from the water’s edge a phalanx of huge dumpers un­load iron ore from the trains arriving from Vale’s mines in MinasGerais. The 905km railroad carries 40% of Brazil’s rail freight onjust 3% of its track. A standard freight train on this line has 252 car­riages and three locomotives. Around 4,000 carriages are emp­tied in Tubarão each day.

The unloaded ore is blended and stockpiled in a vast yardenclosed by �ne­mesh screens to stop the dust from blowing to­wards the nearby city of Vitória. Then it is scooped by giant rotat­ing buckets onto a moving belt and conveyed to a long chute atthe pier where it is poured into the hold of a waiting vessel.

The port’s construction in the mid­1960s was sponsored bysteelmakers from Japan. Today Brazil’s main customer is China,which takes 15% of its exports (mostly iron ore, soyabeans andoil), up from almost nothing ten years ago. The cargo that theships are queuing up for at Tubarão has become far more valu­able. Iron ore now fetches $178 a tonne, compared with $13 atonne in 2001.

Broader measures of raw­material costs have jumped aswell. The Economist’s index of non­oil commodity prices has tre­bled in the past decade. The recent surge has reversed a down­ward trend that had lasted a century. Industrial raw­materialprices fell by around 80% in real terms between 1845, when The

Economist began collecting data, and their low point in 2002 (seechart 3). But much of the ground lost over 150 years has been re­covered in the space of just a decade.

This has raised the incomes of commodity­rich countriessuch as Brazil and Australia as well as parts of Africa. It has alsocaused even sober analysts to speak of a �new paradigm� in

commodity markets. Even though GDP has slowed to a near­standstill in many parts of the rich world, the price of crude oil isclose to $100 a barrel�as high in real terms as after the oil shocksof the 1970s (see chart 4 on next page).

What accounts for this turnaround? The price spikes overthe past century were linked to interruptions in supply, notablyduring the �rst world war. But recent price rises have been toobroad­based and long­lasting to be adequately explained byfrost or bad harvests. Nor is it obvious that producers are hoard­ing supplies. At Tubarão everybody is straining to get the oreonto the ships more quickly. Valuable time is lost in docking andin starting the loading.

There is a more straightforward explanation for the scarci­ty: the surge in commodity prices is simply the result of explod­ing demand and sluggish supply. The demand side has beenboosted by industrial development unprecedented in its size,speed and breadth, led by China but not con�ned to it. Growth in

emerging markets is both rapid and re­source­intensive. The IMF estimates thatin a middle­income country a 1% rise inGDP increases demand for energy by thesame percentage. Rich economies are farless energy­hungry: the oil intensity ofOECD countries has steadily fallen in re­cent years.

China’s appetite for raw materials isparticularly voracious because of thecountry’s size and its high investmentrate. Though it accounts for only aboutone­eighth of global output, China usesup between a third and half of theworld’s annual production of iron ore,aluminium, lead and other non­preciousmetals (see chart 5 on page 16). Most of theenergy for Chinese industry comes fromcoal�a dirty fuel that contributes to Chi­na’s poor air quality. Its consumption ofoil roughly tallies with the economy’s sizebut is likely to grow faster than GDP as

China gets richer and buys more cars. Supply has struggled to keep pace with this burgeoning de­

mand. The world’s iron­ore production has doubled over thepast decade but prices have risen 13­fold. The metal content ofcopper ore has been falling since the mid­1990s as existing minesare depleted. This mismatch between demand and supply is anage­old problem in commodity markets. It takes years to �nd anddevelop new mines and oil reservoirs and to build the infrastruc­

Commodities

Crowded out

Chinese demand had ended a century of steadily

falling raw­material costs for rich­world consumers

Metal detector

Sources: The Economist; Thomson Reuters *Adjusted by US GDP deflator

The Economist industrial commodity-price index, real* $ terms, 1845-50=100

0

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

1845-50

1860 1870 1880 1890 1900 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2011

3

Optimistsbet onhumaningenuity tospring theMalthusiantrap, as ithas done sooften before

The Economist September 24th 2011 13

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

2 ture (rigs, pipelines, railways, ports) to bring the commodities tomarket. Supply responds slowly to price increases and delay of­ten leads to excessive investment which then depresses prices.

The extractive industries had only just recovered from sucha binge when prices began to rise again. By the start of the millen­nium a long bear market in commodities had purged the ex­cesses of the 1970s, says Dylan Grice at Société Générale. The sec­tor was poised for contraction but instead faced the biggest andfastest industrialisation in history.

The supply of commodities is again slowly catching up.The big reserves are mainly in remote and sparsely populated ar­eas. That is in part why the economies of Australia, Canada, Bra­zil and sub­Saharan Africa have been growing quickly. Brazil isblessed with timber, exceptionally fertile land, metal ores andnow oil reserves�though the biggest of these are in hard­to­reach places, far o� the coast and in deep water beneath a layerof salt. There is now a shortage of geologists who can help withthe search for oil. OGX, an oil �rm founded by Eike Batista, a Bra­zilian magnate, has tempted some retired ones back to work.

Brazil’s o�shore oil will be expensive and di�cult to recov­er. If this is what the world is relying on, say the pessimists, theshortage of oil is truly critical. They argue that the resource limitsto growth �rst noted by Thomas Malthus in the late 18th centurystill apply. Optimists bet on human ingenuity to spring the Mal­thusian trap, as it has done so often before.

Why it matters

The imbalance in commodity markets is likely to persist atleast until resource­hungry countries become richer and newsupplies come on stream. In the meantime the surge in emerg­ing­market demand will continue to hurt the advanced econo­mies. The rise in oil and commodity prices has pushed up in�a­tion in rich countries and acted like a tax on consumers.

The IMF reckons that a 10% rise in oil prices knocks 0.2­0.3%o� global GDP growth in the �rst year, but the impact on a big oilconsumer like America is twice as large. The sluggish growth inAmerica’s economy in the �rst half of this year was due in part tohigher oil prices, which in turn were caused partly by strong GDP

growth in China (though supply disruptions also played a role). The commodities boom has also made monetary policy

more complicated. In�ation targets allowed governments andcentral banks to argue that price stability and full employmentwere complementary goals. If too many workers were idle, thatwould bear down on prices and allow central banks to keep in­terest rates low to boost spending and jobs and to guard againstde�ation. For a decade after 1997 China’s e�ect on world priceshad made life easier for the rich world’s central banks. Imports of

cheap goods from China brought down prices in America andelsewhere, keeping in�ation low. But now that Chinese wagesare rising, the e�ect of the country’s rapid industrialisation onworld commodity prices is pushing up rich­world in�ation.

Because of the persistent rise in commodity prices, in�a­tion has not come down even though there is lots of slack in mostadvanced economies. The textbook response to commodity­ledin�ation is to regard it as temporary and ignore it. But that be­comes harder if it persists and raises expectations of future in�a­tion. In Britain, for instance, in�ation has been above the Bank ofEngland’s 2% target for most of the past four years, yet interestrates have been close to zero. Some complain that the in�ationtarget has simply been abandoned.

Commodity prices are acting as regulators of globalgrowth. The emerging markets are �rst in the queue for suppliesbecause they are often able to use each extra barrel of oil or ship­load of ore more gainfully. Their demand raises prices and low­ers real incomes in the rich world, which gets crowded out. Richcountries had become used to unlimited access to cheap raw ma­terials: prices had been falling for a century or more. Now there iscompetition for primary resources. Producers are bene�ting andrich­world consumers are su�ering, at precisely the time whenthey are also increasingly anxious about job security as Chinaand India rise and rise. 7

Crude awakening

Sources: The Economist; Thomson Reuters *West Texas Intermediate

Oil price*, $ per barrel at 2011 prices

1970 80 90 2000 110

20

40

60

80

100

120

140

4

AS THE DELHI metro snakes its way out of the crowdedsouth of the city the scene turns more rural, with the occa­

sional water bu�alo, schoolgirls playing hopscotch outside a vil­lage school and crudely built brick houses. But by the time thetrain draws up to the suburb of Gurgaon, the cacophony of ur­ban India is heard once again.

Twenty years ago Gurgaon was farmland. Now it is a sea ofvillas, shopping malls, o�ce blocks and apartment buildingswith names like Beverly Park and Oakwood Estate. The metrohoardings advertise the best places to buy o�cewear or theLovely Professional University’s record for getting people intojobs. On a busy Friday the roads are crammed with honking TataSumos, the local sports­utility vehicle. Many drivers are on theirway home after a night working the American shift.

Gurgaon is a global centre for outsourcing back­o�ce ser­vices. Here and in other such hubs around India, routine o�cework and data analysis are carried out for a variety of corporatecustomers, many from rich countries (so their tasks have beeno�shored as well as outsourced). The work can be sophisticated:crunching the pro�t­and­loss numbers of listed companies forWall Street analysts, or teasing spending patterns from the datagathered by supermarket tills.

Wages in Gurgaon are a small fraction of those of a back­of­�ce clerk in Newcastle or New York. That lowers costs for con­sumers. But it also raises anxiety among workers about low payand a drain of jobs to cheaper locations. The range of tasks thatcan be outsourced and o�shored is constantly expanding.

The notion that trade kills jobs is based on the false premisethat there is a �xed amount of work to do. The world’s leading

Exporting jobs

Gurgaon grief

Now for the next shake­up in the global labour market

1

14 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

2

1

larger than in the past. A quarter of American jobs in 1970 were inmanufacturing and hence potentially o�shorable. Many didmove o�shore but were replaced by jobs in service industries.

A lot also depends on what happens in emerging markets.If China can successfully switch from export­led growth to do­mestic sources of demand it will create more opportunities forAmerican exports. As China and India become better o� thewage gap with the rich world will narrow and the pace of o�­shoring will slow. And as technology opens up more sorts ofwork to cross­border trade it will create openings for rich­worldeconomies whose comparative advantage is in services.

If services become more tradable that will be good forAmerica’s workers. But it might also exacerbate the growingwage divide within its own labour market. Economic theory sug­gests that trade with emerging markets creates a wage premiumfor the skilled workers in rich countries. The world’s division oflabour is determined by the relative abundance of skilled andunskilled workers. Rich countries have more of the former, sospecialise in traded goods with a high skill content. Poor coun­tries have more of the latter, so concentrate on low­skilled work.Skilled workers in rich countries bene�t from trade, but thewages of the less skilled su�er from foreign competition.

Most studies so far have found that trade explains only asmall part of the increase in income inequality in America sincethe 1980s. The decline of trade­union power and below­in�ationincreases in the minimum wage also played a role. But most ofthe growing inequality is probably due to technological changewhich makes a college education more valuable�in much thesame way that trade does, in fact. It is possible that the e�ect oftrade on wages is more signi�cant than those studies have found.Much of the stu� that China makes is no longer produced in therich world, so it is di�cult to establish a direct link.

That may also be because the data are not detailed enoughto capture the e�ects on relative wages within industries, saysJosh Bivens of the Economic Policy Institute, a think­tank inWashington, DC. Only those with a four­year college degree(perhaps a quarter of America’s workforce) are clear winners

economies have been ceding jobs to low­income rivals since theindustrial revolution. The cotton industry in Britain was in thevanguard of that transformation but soon faced competition��rst from New England, then from America’s South. The millshave largely disappeared and the spinning and weaving jobs re­placed by better­paid ones. As the division of global labour be­comes ever more �ne­grained, small tasks rather than whole in­dustries move abroad. Trading partners share the e�ciencygains. The world is better o�, even if some individuals lose out.

Many more to go

This sort of gradual restructuring is not new, and neither isthe job insecurity that stems from it. But anxiety about o�shor­ing has risen, for three reasons. First, jobs are already scarce be­cause the hangover from recessions caused by �nancial criseslasts longer than that from other sorts of downturns. Second,China and India between them have around 2.5 billion people,so the potential for further o�shoring from the rich world is im­mense. Third, advances in computing and communications al­low for a wider range of jobs to be shifted across borders.

These last two factors mean that o�shoring will be a hugelydisruptive force, says Alan Blinder, a professor at Princeton Uni­versity. A recent study carried out in America with a Princetoncolleague, Alan Krueger, found that a quarter of the workers in­terviewed considered their work potentially �o�shorable�.This �gure includes all manufacturing jobs, as goods are readilytraded across borders. But it also covers many occupations thatused to be thought safe from foreign competition.

Any service job that can be delivered down a wire withoutany diminution in quality is o�shorable, reasons Mr Blinder.That means high­paying jobs in accountancy, �nancial analysisor computer programming are at risk. Jobs that involve face­to­face contact or require the worker to be present are safer: think oftaxi drivers, plumbers, police o�cers or janitors. Mr Blindermakes a distinction between personal and impersonal services.Only the latter are o�shorable. A contract lawyer or radiologist isvulnerable to o�shoring; a divorce lawyer or family doctor isn’t.

Yet not all the jobs that can be o�shored will be. Even inmanufacturing the savings on labour from o�shoring are oftenoutweighed by other cost considerations. Low­value bulkygoods, such as bricks or bottles, tend to be made close to wherethey are consumed because transporting them is expensive. Carsare also mostly made in the countries where they are sold.

High­tech manufacturing relies on a skilled labour forceworking closely with designteams. There is little cost ad­vantage to o�shoring for smallbatches of goods or where fastdelivery to local customers isimportant. Economies of scalemean industries are �sticky�:Britain’s cotton industry, for in­stance, did not go into seriousdecline until the 1960s eventhough wages were high.

The alarm over the threatto jobs from India and Chinaechoes the anxiety about Ja­pan’s rise in the 1970s and1980s. America’s economy hassurvived the shake­up of itssteel, electronics and car indus­tries, as have other rich coun­tries. The scale of the challengeis large but may not be so much

Wok, stock and barrel

Sources: BP StatisticalReview; IMF; ThomsonReuters; World Bureauof Metal Statistics

*Purchasing-power parity

China’s share of worldcommodity consumption2010, %

0 20 40 60

Iron ore

Coal

Lead

Zinc

Aluminium

Copper

Nickel

GDP at PPP*

Oil

5

2 from growing trade, reckons Mr Bivens.The most striking feature of rising wage dispersion is not

the wider gap between the skilled and unskilled but the biggerslice that goes to a tiny elite. The share of income claimed by thetop 0.1% of earners increased from 2% in 1970 to 8% by 2007, ac­cording to research by Emmanuel Saez of the University of Cali­fornia, Berkeley, and Thomas Piketty of the Paris School of Eco­nomics. Much of this trend, says Harvard University’s RichardFreeman, is explained by stock options, which are counted aspart of pay. �This goes back to something we have thought of asold­fashioned: capital versus labour,� says Mr Freeman.

Waiting for intelligent robots

There are dangers in extrapolation. The recent rapid growthrates in emerging markets are unlikely to be sustained. And per­haps the wage premium paid to workers with a college degreewill shrink again, for reasons unrelated to trade. Scarce and ex­pensive skilled labour is often a spur to invention. Before the in­dustrial revolution the hand­spinning of raw cotton into threadwas the main bottleneck in the production of cloth. It took sixspinsters to feed each handloom used to weave thread into cloth.The introduction of mechanised spinning (of the sort carried outat Quarry Bank Mill) changed that, creating a dearth of hand­weavers. Then power looms destroyed the wage premium forhand­weaving, so the Luddites destroyed some of the looms inresponse. It is conceivable that advances in arti�cial intelligencemight spell the end of the wage premium for skilled workers, too.

But for the immediate future skilled workers in the richworld still seem to have the best prospects. College­educatedworkers are more likely to be able to switch jobs in response tooutsourcing than those with little education. And the rewardsfor those with jobs that compete in the global market for tradableservices are likely to be higher than for those in low­skill perso­nal services�though the risks of losing their jobs are also greater.

The anxiety about o�shoring has obscured another changein the economic landscape that will bring jobs to rich countries:the rise of the emerging­market multinational. 7

THE HALEWOOD CAR plant near Liverpool was once no­torious for strife. In the 1970s its bolshie workforce fre­

quently clashed with tetchy managers. In the peaceful interludesthe plant turned out �eets of Ford Escorts, a popular family car.

The plant is now part of Jaguar Land Rover (JLR), owned byTata Motors, the car division of an Indian conglomerate. Thesedays it is a cheerful and contented place. At one end of the plantworkers examine the body parts shaped by one of ten giant met­al presses. At the other end, in the paint shop, a sprayer dressed ina protective suit squirts a mist of colour inside the back door of acar shell. Fork­lift buggies, owned by DHL, a logistics �rm withan on­site operation, distribute parts from outside suppliersaround the factory.

The reason for the activity and the good humour is that pro­duction has recently started on the new Land Rover Evoque, amini sports­utility vehicle. Before the car had appeared in theshowrooms, JLR had taken 18,000 orders for it and it was alreadyfor sale on eBay. Thanks to the contract for the Evoque, Hale­wood’s workforce has doubled to 3,000 in the past year. Local

suppliers will also bene�t. Two centuries ago the rise

of the cotton trade in the millsaround Manchester and theport of Liverpool spelled doomfor India’s textile industry. To­day Indian �rms own largechunks of Britain’s old industri­al north­west. The Stanlow oilre�nery close to Halewoodwas bought earlier this year byEssar, an Indian conglomerate.Brunner Mond, a chemicals�rm started in 1873 just a fewmiles from Quarry Bank Mill,was bought by Tata Chemicalsin 2006. Blackburn Rovers, afounder member of England’sprofessional football league in1888, is owned by VH Group, anIndian poultry �rm.

These Indian outposts arepart of a broader shoppingspree by emerging­market�rms. Their share of cross­bor­der mergers and acquisitions(M&A) rose to 17% in the sevenyears to 2010, up from just 4% inthe previous seven years, ac­cording to a recent report by theWorld Bank. They are thesource of more than a third offoreign direct investment (FDI)in other emerging markets.Typically this sort of FDI is �or­

South­north FDI

Role reversal

Emerging­market �rms are increasingly buying up

rich­world ones

Uphill rushCross-border M&A deals fromemerging world to rich world 2000-10

Source:World Bank

*Middle East & North Africaexcluding United Arab

Emirates (UAE)

By source

By destination

6

0 50 100 150

China

ME & NA*

UAE

Singapore

Brazil

India

Russia

Other Asia

Mexico

Sub-SaharanAfrica

Other

0 40 80 120 160 200

UnitedStatesOther

Britain

Canada

Australia

Italy

Germany

1

The Economist September 24th 2011 15

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

ganic�, which involves setting up a localfactory or branch o�ce. By contrast, directinvestment by emerging­market �rms inrich countries (so­called south­north FDI)tends to be �acquisitive�, which meansone company buying another.

The bulk of the emerging­markets’M&A in rich countries comes from �vecountries, led by China but also includingIndia. America is the rich world’s main re­cipient, with Britain not far behind, eventhough its economy is only around one­sixth America’s size. Other big targets arecommodity­rich Canada and Australia(see chart 6 on previous page).

Firms from America and Europe arefalling over themselves to invest in fast­growing emerging markets like China andIndia to escape sluggish economies athome. But why are emerging­market�rms rushing in the other direction? Themain reason is that, like rich­world multi­nationals, they seek access to new cus­tomers. �As a company you don’t want tobe con�ned to local growth,� says Man­soor Dailami, one of the authors of theWorld Bank report. �You want to have theglobal economy as your market.�

An acquisition is often the quickest(and sometimes the only) way to gain afoothold in a country. JBS Friboi, a bigmeat company based in Brazil, had nopresence in the American market until itbought Swift, a struggling American rival,in 2007 (see box). Tata’s purchase in 2000of Tetley, a British tea �rm, gave it instantaccess to consumers in North America, aswell as in Britain.

Slow but steady

Emerging­market �rms may alsowant to limit their exposure to their livelybut often brittle home market. Growth inthe rich world may be slow but the invest­ment climate is often warmer. There arebetter regulations; the tax laws are easierto live with; the courts are less capricious.

Brands are a consideration too. Ra­tan Tata, the chairman of the Tata group,said the chance to own the Jaguar brandwas �irresistible�. Building a brand cantake years and pots of money; buying anestablished one is often cheaper. Acquir­ing a rich­world company can also be aquick way to get hold of technology aswell as the tacit know­how that comes with operating a �rm inmature markets.

Moreover, a corporate presence in the rich world o�ers ac­cess to cheaper and more reliable �nancing. The World Bankstudy found that around two­thirds of emerging­market �rmswhich were active in cross­border M&A had used some form ofinternational �nancing to do so�a bank syndicate, a bond issuein foreign currency or a stockmarket listing in a rich country. Cor­porate bond markets in places like China and India are still un­derdeveloped, so a big, globally �nanced M&A deal paves the

way for future capital­raising. A deeper macroeconomic force behind south­north FDI is

the need to put emerging­market savings to work. The three larg­est emerging­market buyers of rich­world �rms, China, the Un­ited Arab Emirates and Singapore, all run large current­accountsurpluses and so acquire claims on foreigners. (Acquisitions by�rms in Brazil and India are part of a more even two­way �ow ofcapital with the rich world.) By contrast, America funds its cur­rent­account de�cit by selling assets to foreigners. Much of theimbalance in savings between the rich world and the emerging

purchased Pilgrim’s Pride, a Texan chickenproducer. The deals were in part opportu­nistic: both companies were in �nancialtrouble and JBS was able to raise moneyquickly, some of it in Brazil’s equity market.But they also gave JBS a presence in andaccess to the American market. That in turnallowed it to export to Japan and otherAsian markets from which it had previouslybeen shut out.

Like other emerging­market �rms,JBS found it cheaper to buy brands than tobuild them. A �eet of small vans sportingthe Swift logo sells fresh meat in the areaaround the Lins factory. The �rm is alsolaunching a branded range of high­qualitysteaks. JBS already sells fresh beef fromBrazil to the European Union under theHilton quota scheme, which cuts importtari�s on meat produced to a high stan­dard. JBS buys 2,500 Hilton­grade cattleeach year from Edson Crochiquia’s SantaIzabel farm, an hour or so from Lins. It is hisonly customer and sends inspectors to thefarm four times a year to monitor the cat­tle’s food and board.

Because freshness is vital to high­quality food, jobs at food­processing �rmscannot easily be shifted to wherever labourcosts are lowest. �You have to be where thecows are,� says Wesley Batista, one of thefounder’s sons, who runs the �rm. As ithappens, the cost advantage is shiftingtowards the �rm’s rich­world operations.The strong real makes it more expensive toexport from Brazil and the weak dollar is aboon to the American arm. America hasother advantages, too. Taxes are simplerand the jobs market is much slacker than inBrazil. �There are more people availablewho have the right skills and are well­educated,� says Mr Batista. Moreover, it isnow easier to persuade senior sta� to movefrom Colorado to Brazil than the other wayaround�another sign of a world turnedupside down.

Beefed upThe world’s largest meat company is Brazilian, but mostly operates abroad

16 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

2

1

JBS STARTED IN 1953 as a butchers found­ed by José Batista Sobrinho in Anápolis, acity in Brazil’s central state of Goiás. The�rm expanded initially thanks to a fast­growing Brazilian economy and morerecently by acquiring other companies. Itis now the world’s largest meat producer.In 2010 it had revenues of 55 billion reais($31 billion), only a third of which werefrom its operation in Brazil.

The JBS plant at Lins, 450km fromSão Paulo, is one of the �rm’s largest andemploys 5,000 people, working two eight­hour shifts. Inside teams of butchers �lletand trim the carcasses that arrive on aconveyor belt, tossing the cut meat intoplastic­lined trolleys. Much of the raw beefis cooked and canned at the plant. It is�rst ground into mince and then steamedand rotated in an oven angled like a ce­ment mixer so that the juices run o�. Fat,salt, sugar and colouring are added to thehalf­cooked mix before it is canned. Thecooking is completed at high temperaturesin the cans which are then dried andlabelled. The market for this sort of pro­cessed meat is global: the plant suppliescanned meat for Princes, a British �rm, aswell as beef toppings for pizza parlours in

Belgium and Holland. Fresh meat is a

di�erent matter. Bra­zilian companies like

JBS are bannedfrom exporting itto America forfear of foot­and­mouth disease.

This is one reasonwhy in 2007 JBS

bought Swift,then America’sbiggest beef pro­cessor, based inColorado. Twoyears later it

markets is made up by the sale of government bonds. But emerg­ing markets such as China already have their �ll of low­yieldingTreasuries and want to acquire assets with better prospective re­turns, including rich­world companies.

The pattern of developed­country de�cits and emerging­market surpluses is likely to continue. Except for China, the de­veloping world is mostly young, which means that its savingstend to be higher than those of the ageing rich world. If the com­modities boom continues, it will leave the oil­rich Middle Eastwith bulging trade surpluses. The up­and­coming economiesmay seek to emulate China’s model, which relies on others to dothe spending. The resulting balance of global saving will meanthat emerging­market �rms will spread themselves around therich world and employ a growing share of its workforce.

Emerging­market buyers usually o�er cash and tend tooverpay. A study by Ole­Kristian Hope and DushyantkumarVyas, of the University of Toronto, and Wayne Thomas, of theUniversity of Oklahoma, found that �rms from developingcountries generally bid higher than rich­world rivals to buy com­panies in developed markets, often for patriotic, social or politi­cal reasons. Tata’s 2007 acquisition of Corus, an Anglo­Dutchsteel �rm, is a case in point. Yet although Tata may have paid overthe odds, it got a big con�dence boost out of it, as did India as awhole. �The psychological and cultural dimensions of the dealwere enormous,� says Shamik Dhar, who covers Asian econo­mies for Aviva Investors, a London­based fund manager.

Apart from a good price, the targets of such acquisitionsalso get a welcome infusion of animal spirits and an appetite forinvestment that are frequently missing from rich­world board­rooms. Developing­country bidders have created a more vibrantmarket for the control of rich­world companies that keeps man­agers on their toes.

They often gain speedier access to emerging markets too.China is JLR’s fastest­growing market and might soon be its big­gest one. A few of the cars made at Halewood are shipped in kitform to India for assembly. That makes the cars cheaper for Indi­an consumers, as there is less import duty to pay. Carworkers atHalewood seem happy to be working for an emerging­marketmultinational. Above all, they are happy to be working. 7

The Economist September 24th 2011 17

SPECIAL REPORTTHE WORLD ECONOMY

2

1

IT IS A crisp Friday morning in Santa Isabel, a small Brazil­ian town 60km north­east of São Paulo. Gabriel de Matos,

technology director at Paramount Textiles, is taking delivery ofthe latest machine for dyeing the wool yarn that is made here. Itwon’t look out of place: most of the equipment is less than tenyears old. The machines for spinning yarn are 40% faster thanthe ones they replaced. The new kit has allowed Paramount tosupply �ner­grade wools for the men’s suits its customers make.

The factory re�t and the move upmarket was a response tocompetitive pressures that have driven many local rivals out ofbusiness. The global market for woollens has halved since themid­1990s. Consumers these days prefer casual clothes, but Bra­zil is now too rich to compete with cotton producers in Vietnamor Indonesia. �We need a premium product like wool to coverour costs,� says Mr de Matos. China also produces wool and itsland, labour and capital are often cheaper. �Thank goodness weare so far away,� he says. �Time is money and that gives us somebreathing space.�

Paramount is copying the tricks long used by rich­worldbusinesses to fend o� low­cost rivals from emerging markets:better designs, newer machinery, shorter production runs (togive rarity value to each line) and faster delivery to local markets.

Britain bounded ahead in textile production two centuriesago, and established �rms have been looking over their shoulderever since. An early challenge came from the textile industry inNew England, where countless townships called Manchesterwere founded (of which one survives). That cluster soon facedcompetition from factories in the low­wage American South.

The cotton industry has carried on travelling: its technol­ogy moves easily to wherever labour costs are low. The patternhas been repeated for other sorts of ventures. More complextechnologies are harder to copy, so their di�usion has been slow­er. But technology eventually spreads. It is what drives economicconvergence, making large parts of the developing world bettero� year by year.

Demography is destiny again

For much of the past two centuries the know­how that de­termines productivity and living standards has been concentrat­ed in the West. That is true of hard engineering technology aswell as the tacit knowledge of how best to organise production,support markets and manage aggregate demand. Because largeproductivity gains were con�ned to the West, the populous partsof the world stayed poor.

That was anomalous. Population has determined eco­nomic power for most of human history. Now demography andproductivity are pushing in the same direction. America and Eu­rope are demographic minnows compared with the developingworld’s two giants, China and India. And the rich world’s �nan­cial crisis and its aftermath is accelerating the shift of economicpower eastwards. Just as the catch­up in emerging markets isspeeding up and broadening out, the rich world’s economiesseem to be grinding to a halt. If China can avoid a blow­up in thenext decade, it is likely to become the world’s biggest economy�

The path ahead

Cottoning on

The West’s relative decline is inevitable but the East’s

rise will still be troublesome

18 The Economist September 24th 2011

THE WORLD ECONOMY

SPECIAL REPORT

18 The Economist September 24th 2011

though its citizens would still be poor by American standards.The big question for the global economy is whether the rap­

id growth in emerging markets can continue. The broad eco­nomic logic suggests more of the world economy’s gains shouldcome from convergence by emerging markets than from the richworld pushing ahead. Each innovation adds less to rich­worldprosperity than the adoption of an established technology doesto a poor country. At the start of the industrial revolution the cot­ton industry alone could make Britain’s productivity jump. Butnow that the frontier is wider, there is less scope for leading econ­omies to surge ahead. More of the world’s growth ought to comefrom catching up.

But contrary to some excited forecasts, the growth ofemerging economies is unlikely to continue at the same pace, orin a straight line. Economic convergence is a powerful force butcannot knock over every obstacle. And the barriers to growth be­come bigger as economies enter the di�cult middle­incomephase of development.

Moving capital and workers from dying to rising ventures istrickier than transplanting poor rural migrants to cities in the ear­ly phase of catch­up. As economies become richer they can relyless and less on the brute force of additional machine power todrive their prosperity. They have greater need of a skilled work­force and a �nancial system that is attuned to where the best re­turns are likely to be made. Countries thathave relied on exports to fuel their growthneed to shift to internal sources of spend­ing, with all the associated headaches formonetary and �scal policy. In the pastmany middle­income economies haverun aground because they have failed tomeet such challenges.

Careful what you wish for

The biggest emerging markets, withtheir huge foreign­exchange reserves, ap­pear to be almost crisis­proof (at least out­side eastern Europe) in contrast to theseemingly crisis­prone rich world. But set­backs in making the shift from poor to richare inevitable. Indeed a lesson of recenteconomic history is that countries and re­gions that ride out a crisis well are all themore vulnerable to the next one. Hubrisleads to policy mistakes, as the developedworld has proved so devastatingly. Sothick is the gloom pervading the richworld that the once­regular emerging­market crises have almost been forgotten.But this makes it even likelier that theywill one day return.

Those anxious that the rich world’s economic power isebbing might welcome a few emerging­market slip­ups. A lessfrantic rate of growth in the developing world would also slowthe relative decline of the West and allow it to cling on to some ofits privileges for longer. The dollar and the euro could maintain areserve­currency duopoly for longer; commodity­price pres­sures on businesses and consumers would ease; and the impactof developing economies on relative wages and jobs turnovermight be less jarring.

Yet the emerging markets are the best hope for globalgrowth�for the next few years at least. Japan’s economy is in afunk; the euro zone is in danger of imploding; and much of therest of the rich world is hung­over from a giant credit boom.America, Britain and others took on debts that now look steep

compared with incomes andthe value of the homes againstwhich much of the money wasborrowed. They are saving hardto �ll the gap. Those with cash(including a chunk of the cor­porate world and not a fewhouseholds that gained fromthe housing boom) are clingingon to it because of uncertaintyabout future demand, job pros­pects, taxes, the supply of creditand much else.

That is the main reasonwhy a fast rate of catch­up bythe emerging markets would bebetter for the West than a falter­ing one. A richer and more con­sumer­led China would be like­lier to buy more of the servicesin which developed countrieshave a comparative advantage.

It would be healthy, too, ifthe developing world couldbreak the rich world’s monopo­ly on international �nance. Theemerging markets account foralmost half of global GDP buthave no reserve currency oftheir own. For now there seemslittle alternative to the dollar asa �nancial lodestar and the main storehouse for the world’s pre­cautionary saving. The yuan is the likeliest candidate to sup­plant it but has so far taken only baby steps to becoming interna­tional. The longer it takes for the yuan to emerge, the more riskythe global �nancial set­up will become. The worry is that strongdemand for Treasuries as reserves might tempt America to over­stretch itself. The wreckage from the rich world’s housing bustshows the dangers of money that is too cheap.

In other ways, too, it might be better for the rich world ifChina and others caught up with it sooner rather than later. Fast­er catch­up would narrow the wage gap between emerging andrich countries and help to relieve the downward pressure on un­

skilled wages. A mature Chinese economy would waste fewernatural resources on hard­to­justify investments. Many in therich world fear the loss of economic dominance that will be theeventual outcome of convergence. But perhaps losing it is worsethan having lost it.

And perhaps the pessimism about America and Europe isas overdone as the optimism about emerging markets. The richworld is an enticing place when viewed from the developingworld. For all its troubles, America’s economy is a source of envy.Europe’s high­end industries and luxury goods are not easilymimicked. Emerging­market �rms �nd it easier to do business, toraise �nance and to �nd skilled workers in the rich world. Suchattributes are hard to replicate. If it were easy, the emerging econ­omies would already be rich. 7

The growth of emerging economies will not continue at thesame pace, or in a straight line. Setbacks in making theshift from poor to rich are inevitable

2 O�er to readers

Reprints of this special report are available. A minimum order of �ve copies is required.Please contact: Jill Kaletha at Foster PrintingTel +00(1) 219 879 9144e­mail: [email protected]

Corporate o�er

Corporate orders of 100 copies or more areavailable. We also o�er a customisationservice. Please contact us to discuss yourrequirements.Tel +44 (0)20 7576 8148e­mail: [email protected]

For more information on how to order specialreports, reprints or any copyright queriesyou may have, please contact:

The Rights and Syndication Department26 Red Lion SquareLondon WC1R 4HQ

Tel +44 (0)20 7576 8148Fax +44 (0)20 7576 8492e­mail: [email protected]/rights

Future special reports

International banking May 14thAustralia May 28thItaly June 11thChina June 25th

Previous special reports and a list offorthcoming ones can be found online:economist.com/specialreports