ssrn-id94034

32
Separation of Ownership and Control Eugene F. Fama University of Chicago [email protected] and Michael C. Jensen Harvard Business School [email protected] Abstract This paper analyzes the survival of organizations in which decision agents do not bear a major share of the wealth effects of their decisions. This is what the literature on large corporations calls separation of “ownership” and “control.” Such separation of decision and risk bearing functions is also common to organizations like large professional partnerships, financial mutuals and nonprofits. We contend that separation of decision and risk bearing functions survives in these organizations in part because of the benefits of specialization of management and risk bearing but also because of an effective common approach to controlling the implied agency problems. In particular, the contract structures of all these organizations separate the ratification and monitoring of decisions from the initiation and implementation of the decisions. © Copyright 1983. Eugene F. Fama and Michael C. Jensen. All rights reserved. Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. XXVI, June 1983. Also published in Foundations of Organizational Strategy, Michael C. Jensen, Harvard University Press, 1998. You may redistribute this document freely, but please do not post the electronic file on the web. I welcome web links to this document at http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=94034 . I revise my papers regularly, and providing a link to the original ensures that readers will receive the most recent version. Thank you, Michael C. Jensen

Upload: casefortrils

Post on 06-Nov-2015

217 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

academic research, finance

TRANSCRIPT

  • Separation of Ownership and Control

    Eugene F. Fama University of Chicago

    [email protected]

    and

    Michael C. Jensen Harvard Business School

    [email protected]

    Abstract

    This paper analyzes the survival of organizations in which decision agents do not bear a major share of the wealth effects of their decisions. This is what the literature on large corporations calls separation of ownership and control. Such separation of decision and risk bearing functions is also common to organizations like large professional partnerships, financial mutuals and nonprofits. We contend that separation of decision and risk bearing functions survives in these organizations in part because of the benefits of specialization of management and risk bearing but also because of an effective common approach to controlling the implied agency problems. In particular, the contract structures of all these organizations separate the ratification and monitoring of decisions from the initiation and implementation of the decisions.

    Copyright 1983. Eugene F. Fama and Michael C. Jensen. All rights reserved.

    Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. XXVI, June 1983.

    Also published in

    Foundations of Organizational Strategy, Michael C. Jensen, Harvard University Press, 1998.

    You may redistribute this document freely, but please do not post the electronic file on the web. I welcome

    web links to this document at http://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=94034. I revise my papers regularly, and providing a link to the original ensures that readers will receive the most recent version.

    Thank you, Michael C. Jensen

  • * This paper is a revision of parts of our earlier paper, The Survival of Organizations (September 1980). In the course of this work we have profited from the comments of R. Antle, R. Benne, F. Black, F. Easterbrook, A. Farber, W. Gavett, P. Hirsch, R. Hogarth, C. Holderness, R. Holthausen, C. Horne, J. Jeuck, R. Leftwich, S. McCormick, D. Mayers, P. Pashigian, M. Scholes, C. Smith, G. Stigler, R. Watts, T. Whisler, R. Yeaple, J. Zimmerman, and especially A. Alchian, W. Meckling, and C. Plosser. Financial support for Famas participation is from the National Science Foundation. Jensen is supported by the Managerial Economics Research Center of the University of Rochester.

    Separation of Ownership and Control*

    Eugene F. Fama and Michael C. Jensen

    Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. XXVI, June 1983. Foundations of Organizational Strategy, Michael C. Jensen, Harvard University Press, 1998.

    I. Introduction

    Absent fiat, the form of organization that survives in an activity is the one that

    delivers the product demanded by customers at the lowest price while covering costs.1

    Our goal is to explain the survival of organizations characterized by separation of

    ownership and controla problem that has bothered students of corporations from

    Adam Smith to Berle and Means and Jensen and Meckling.2 In more precise language,

    we are concerned with the survival of organizations in which important decision agents

    do not bear a substantial share of the wealth effects of their decisions.

    We argue that the separation of decision and risk-bearing functions observed in

    large corporations is common to other organizations such as large professional

    partnerships, financial mutuals, and nonprofits. We contend that separation of decision

    and risk-bearing functions survives in these organizations in part because of the benefits

    1 Alchian (1950) is an early proponent of the use of natural selection in economic analysis. For a survey of general issues in the analysis of organization, see Jensen (1983).

    2 Smith (1776); Berle and Means (1932); and Jensen and Meckling (1976).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 2

    of specialization of management and risk bearing but also because of an effective

    common approach to controlling the agency problems caused by separation of decision

    and risk-bearing functions. In particular, our hypothesis is that the contract structures of

    all of these organizations separate the ratification and monitoring of decisions from

    initiation and implementation of the decisions.

    II. Residual Claims and Decision Processes

    An organization is the nexus of contracts, written and unwritten, among owners of

    factors of production and customers.3 These contracts or internal rules of the game

    specify the rights of each agent in the organization, performance criteria on which agents

    are evaluated, and the payoff functions they face. The contract structure combines with

    available production technologies and external legal constraints to determine the cost

    function for delivering an output with a particular form of organization.4 The form of

    organization that delivers the output demanded by customers at the lowest price, while

    covering costs, survives.

    The central contracts in any organization specify (1) the nature of residual claims

    and (2) the allocation of the steps of the decision process among agents. These contracts

    distinguish organizations from one another and explain why specific organizational forms

    survive. We first discuss the general characteristics of residual claims and decision

    processes. We then present the major hypotheses about the relations between efficient

    allocations of residual claims and decision functions. The analysis focuses on two broad

    types of organizationsthose in which risk-bearing and decision functions are separated

    and those in which they are combined in the same agents. We analyze only private

    organizations that depend on voluntary contracting and exchange.

    3 See Jensen and Meckling (1976).

    4 See Jensen and Meckling (1979).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 3

    A. Residual Claims

    The contract structures of most organizational forms limit the risks undertaken by

    most agents by specifying either fixed promised payoffs or incentive payoffs tied to

    specific measures of performance. The residual riskthe risk of the difference between

    stochastic inflows of resources and promised payments to agentsis borne by those who

    contract for the rights to net cash flows. We call these agents the residual claimants or

    residual risk bearers. Moreover, the contracts of most agents contain the implicit or

    explicit provision that, in exchange for the specified payoff, the agent agrees that the

    resources he provides can be used to satisfy the interests of residual claimants.

    Having most uncertainty borne by one group of agents, residual claimants, has

    survival value because it reduces the costs incurred to monitor contracts with other

    groups of agents and to adjust contracts for the changing risks borne by other agents.

    Contracts that direct decisions toward the interests of residual claimants also add to the

    survival value of organizations. Producing outputs at lower cost is in the interests of

    residual claimants because it increases net cash flows, but lower costs also contribute to

    survival by allowing products to be delivered at lower prices.

    The residual claims of different organizational forms contain different restrictions.

    For example, the least restricted residual claims in common use are the common stocks of

    large corporations. Stockholders are not required to have any other role in the

    organization; their residual claims are alienable without restriction; and, because of these

    provisions, the residual claims allow unrestricted risk sharing among stockholders. We

    call these organizations open corporations to distinguish them from closed corporations

    that are generally smaller and have residual claims that are largely restricted to internal

    decision agents.5

    5 The terms public corporation and close corporation, which are common in the legal literature, are not used here. Closed corporation seems more descriptive than close corporation. The term public

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 4

    B. The Decision Process

    By focusing on entrepreneurial firms in which all decision rights are concentrated

    in the entrepreneur, economists tend to ignore analysis of the steps of the decision

    process. However, the way organizations allocate the steps of the decision process across

    agents is important in explaining the survival of organizations.

    In broad terms, the decision process has four steps:

    initiationgeneration of proposals for resource utilization and structuring of

    contracts;

    ratificationchoice of the decision initiatives to be implemented;

    implementationexecution of ratified decisions; and

    monitoringmeasurement of the performance of decision agents and

    implementation of rewards.

    Because the initiation and implementation of decisions typically are allocated to

    the same agents, it is convenient to combine these two functions under the term decision

    management. Likewise, the term decision control includes the ratification and monitoring

    of decisions. Decision management and decision control are the components of the

    organizations decision process or decision system.

    III. Fundamental Relations Between Risk-Bearing and Decision Processes

    We first state and then elaborate the central complementary hypotheses about the

    relations between the risk-bearing and decision processes of organizations.

    Separation of residual risk bearing from decision management leads to decision

    systems that separate decision management from decision control.

    Combination of decision management and decision control in a few agents leads

    to residual claims that are largely restricted to these agents.

    corporation best describes government-owned corporations such as Amtrak and the TVA. In contrast, what we call open corporations are private organizations.

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 5

    A. The Problem

    Agency problems arise because contracts are not costlessly written and enforced.

    Agency costs include the costs of structuring, monitoring, and bonding a set of contracts

    among agents with conflicting interests. Agency costs also include the value of output

    lost because the costs of full enforcement of contracts exceed the benefits.6

    Control of agency problems in the decision process is important when the

    decision managers who initiate and implement important decisions are not the major

    residual claimants and therefore do not bear a major share of the wealth effects of their

    decisions. Without effective control procedures, such decision managers are more likely

    to take actions that deviate from the interests of residual claimants. An effective system

    for decision control implies, almost by definition, that the control (ratification and

    monitoring) of decisions is to some extent separate from the management (initiation and

    implementation) of decisions. Individual decision agents can be involved in the

    management of some decisions and the control of others, but separation means that an

    individual agent does not exercise exclusive management and control rights over the

    same decisions.

    The interesting problem is to determine when separation of decision management,

    decision control, and residual risk bearing is more efficient than combining these three

    functions in the same agents. We first analyze the factors that make combination of

    decision management, decision control, and residual risk bearing efficient. We then

    analyze the factors that make separation of these three functions efficient.

    B. Combination of Decision Management, Decision Control, and Residual Risk Bearing

    Suppose the balance of cost conditions, including both technology and the control

    of agency problems, implies that in a particular activity the optimal organization is

    6 This definition of agency costs comes from Jensen and Meckling (1976).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 6

    noncomplex. For our purposes, noncomplex means that specific information relevant to

    decisions is concentrated in one or a few agents. (Specific information is detailed

    information that is costly to transfer among agents.)7 Most small organizations tend to be

    noncomplex, and most large organizations tend to be complex, but the correspondence is

    not perfect. For example, research oriented universities, though often small in terms of

    assets or faculty size, are nevertheless complex in the sense that specific knowledge,

    which is costly to transfer, is diffused among both faculty and administrators. On the

    other hand, mutual funds are often large in terms of assets but noncomplex in the sense

    that information relevant to decisions is concentrated in one or a few agents. We take it as

    given that optimal organizations in some activities are noncomplex. Our more limited

    goal is to explain the implications of noncomplexity for control of agency problems in the

    decision process.

    If we ignore agency problems between decision managers and residual claimants,

    the theory of optimal risk bearing tells us that residual claims that allow unrestricted risk

    sharing have advantages in small as well as in large organizations.8 However, in a small

    noncomplex organization, specific knowledge important for decision management and

    control is concentrated in one or a few agents. As a consequence, it is efficient to allocate

    decision control as well as decision management to these agents. Without separation of

    decision management from decision control, residual claimants have little protection

    against opportunistic actions of decision agents, and this lowers the value of unrestricted

    residual claims.

    7 Specific information is closely related to the notions of information impactedness and bounded rationality discussed in Williamson (1975) and (1981). Hayek (1945) uses specific information to discuss the role of markets in complex economies. See also Sowell (1980). Our analysis of the relations between specific information and efficient decision processes owes much to ongoing work with William Meckling.

    8 See, for example, Arrow (1964); or Fama (1976, chs. 6 & 7).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 7

    A feasible solution to the agency problem that arises when the same agents

    manage and control important decisions is to restrict residual claims to the important

    decision agents. In effect, restriction of residual claims to decision agents substitutes for

    costly control devices to limit the discretion of decision agents. The common stocks of

    closed corporations are this type of restricted residual claim, as are the residual claims in

    proprietorships and partnerships. The residual claims of these organizations (especially

    closed corporations) are also held by other agents whose special relations with decision

    agents allow agency problems to be controlled without separation of the management and

    control of decisions. For example, family members have many dimensions of exchange

    with one another over a long horizon and therefore have advantages in monitoring and

    disciplining related decision agents. Business associates whose goodwill and advice are

    important to the organization are also potential candidates for holding minority residual

    claims of organizations that do not separate the management and control of decisions.9

    Restricting residual claims to decision makers controls agency problems between

    residual claimants and decision agents, but it sacrifices the benefits of unrestricted risk

    sharing and specialization of decision functions. The decision process suffers efficiency

    losses because decision agents must be chosen on the basis of wealth and willingness to

    bear risk as well as for decision skills. The residual claimants forgo optimal risk

    reduction through portfolio diversification so that residual claims and decision making

    can be combined in a small number of agents. Forgone diversification lowers the value of

    the residual claims and raises the cost of risk-bearing services.

    Moreover, when residual claims are restricted to decision agents, it is generally

    rational for the residual claimantdecision makers to assign lower values to uncertain

    9 In contrast, the analysis predicts that when venture equity capital is put into a small entrepreneurial organization by outsiders, mechanisms for separating the management and control of important decisions are instituted.

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 8

    cash flows than residual claimants would in organizations where residual claims are

    unrestricted and risk bearing can be freely diversified across organizations. As a

    consequence, restricting residual claims to agents in the decision process leads to

    decisions (for example, less investment in risky projects that lower the costs of outputs)

    that tend to penalize the organization in the competition for survival.10

    However, because contracts are not costlessly written and enforced, all decision

    systems and systems for allocating residual claims involve costs. Organizational survival

    involves a balance of the costs of alternative decision systems and systems for allocating

    residual risk against the benefits. Small noncomplex organizations do not have demands

    for a wide range of specialized decision agents; on the contrary, concentration of specific

    information relevant to decisions implies that there are efficiency gains when the rights to

    manage and control decisions are combined in one or a few agents. Moreover, the risk-

    sharing benefits forgone when residual claims are restricted to one or a few decision

    agents are less serious in a small noncomplex organization than in a large organization,

    because the total risk of net cash flows to be shared is generally smaller in small

    organizations. In addition, small organizations do not often have large demands for

    wealth from residual claimants to bond the payoffs promised to other agents and to

    purchase risky assets. As a consequence, small noncomplex organizations can efficiently

    control the agency problems caused by the combination of decision management and

    control in one or a few agents by restricting residual claims to these agents. Such a

    combining of decision and risk-bearing functions is efficient in small noncomplex

    organizations because the benefits of unrestricted risk sharing and specialization of

    decision functions are less than the costs that would be incurred to control the resulting

    agency problems.

    10 These propositions are developed in. Fama and Jensen (1983).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 9

    The proprietorships, partnerships, and closed corporations observed in small scale

    production and service activities are the best examples of classical entrepreneurial firms

    in which the major decision makers are also the major residual risk bearers. These

    organizations are evidence in favor of the hypothesis that combination of decision

    management and decision control in one or a few agents leads to residual claims that are

    largely restricted to these agents.

    We analyze next the forces that make separation of decision management,

    decision control, and residual risk bearing efficientin effect, the forces that cause the

    classical entrepreneurial firm to be dominated by organizational forms in which there are

    no decision makers in the classical entrepreneurial sense.

    C. Separation of Decision Management, Decision Control, and Residual Risk Bearing

    Our concern in this section is with the organizational forms characterized by

    separation of decision management from residual risk bearingwhat the literature on

    open corporations calls, somewhat imprecisely, separation of ownership and control. Our

    hypothesis is that all such organizations, including large open corporations, large

    professional partnerships, financial mutuals, and nonprofits, control the agency problems

    that result from separation of decision management from residual risk bearing by

    separating the management (initiation and implementation) and control (ratification and

    monitoring) of decisions. Documentation of this hypothesis takes up much of the rest of

    the paper.

    1. Specific Knowledge and Diffusion of Decision Functions. Most organizations

    characterized by separation of decision management from residual risk bearing are

    complex in the sense that specific knowledge relevant to different decisionsknowledge

    which is costly to transfer across agentsis diffused among agents at all levels of the

    organization. Again, we take it as given that the optimal organizations in some activities

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 10

    are complex. Our theory attempts to explain the implications of complexity for the nature

    of efficient decision processes and for control of agency problems in the decision process.

    Since specific knowledge in complex organizations is diffused among agents,

    diffusion of decision management can reduce costs by delegating the initiation and

    implementation of decisions to the agents with valuable relevant knowledge. The agency

    problems of diffuse decision management can then be reduced by separating the

    management (initiation and implementation) and control (ratification and monitoring) of

    decisions.

    In the unusual cases where residual claims are not held by important decision

    managers but are nevertheless concentrated in one or a few residual claimants, control of

    decision managers can in principle be direct and simple, with the residual claimants

    ratifying and monitoring important decisions and setting rewards.11 Such organizations

    conform to our hypothesis, because top-level decision control is separated from top-level

    decision managers and exercised directly by residual claimants.

    However, in complex organizations valuable specific knowledge relevant to

    decision control is diffused among many internal agents. This generally means that

    efficient decision control, like efficient decision management, involves delegation and

    diffusion of decision control as well as separation of decision management and control at

    different levels of the organization. We expect to observe such delegation, diffusion, and

    separation of decision management and control below the top level of complex

    organizations, even in those unusual complex organizations where residual claims are

    held primarily by top-level decision agents.

    2. Diffuse Residual Claims and Delegation of Decision Control. In the more

    common complex organizations, residual claims are diffused among many agents.

    11 See Alchian and Demsetz (1972).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 11

    Having many residual claimants has advantages in large complex organizations because

    the total risk of net cash flows to be shared is generally large and there are large demands

    for wealth from residual claimants to bond the payoffs promised to a wide range of

    agents and to purchase risky assets. When there are many residual claimants, it is costly

    for all of them to be involved in decision control and it is efficient for them to delegate

    decision control. For example, some delegation of decision control is observed even in

    the large professional partnerships in public accounting and law, where the residual

    claimants are expert internal decision agents. When there are many partners it is

    inefficient for each to participate in ratification and monitoring of all decisions.

    Nearly complete separation and specialization of decision control and residual

    risk bearing is common in large open corporations and financial mutuals where most of

    the diffuse residual claimants are not qualified for roles in the decision process and thus

    delegate their decision control rights to other agents. When residual claimants have no

    role in decision control, we expect to observe separation of the management and control

    of important decisions at all levels of the organization.

    Separation and diffusion of decision management and decision controlin effect,

    the absence of a classical entrepreneurial decision makerlimit the power of individual

    decision agents to expropriate the interests of residual claimants. The checks and

    balances of such decision systems have costs, but they also have important benefits.

    Diffusion and separation of decision management and control have benefits because they

    allow valuable knowledge to be used at the points in the decision process where it is most

    relevant and they help control the agency problems of diffuse residual claims. In complex

    organizations, the benefits of diffuse residual claims and the benefits of separation of

    decision functions from residual risk bearing are generally greater than the agency costs

    they generate, including the costs of mechanisms to separate the management and control

    of decisions.

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 12

    3. Decision Control in Nonprofits and Financial Mutuals. Most organizations

    characterized by separation of decision management from residual risk bearing are

    complex. However, separation of the management and control of decisions contributes to

    the survival of any organization where the important decision managers do not bear a

    substantial share of the wealth effects of their decisionsthat is, any organization where

    there are serious agency problems in the decision process. We argue below that

    separation of decision management and residual risk bearing is a characteristic of

    nonprofit organizations and financial mutuals, large and small, complex and noncomplex.

    Thus, we expect to observe separation of the management and control of important

    decisions even in small noncomplex nonprofits and financial mutuals where, ignoring

    agency problems in the decision process, concentrated and combined decision

    management and control would be more efficient.

    4. Common General Features of Decision Control Systems. Our hypothesis

    about the decision systems of organizations characterized by separation of decision

    management and residual risk bearing gets support from the fact that the major

    mechanisms for diffusing and separating the management and control of decisions are

    much the same across different organizations.

    Decision hierarchies. A common feature of the diffuse decision management

    and control systems of complex organizations (for example, large nonprofit universities

    as well as large open corporations) is a formal decision hierarchy with higher level agents

    ratifying and monitoring the decision initiatives of lower level agents and evaluating their

    performance.12 Such hierarchical partitioning of the decision process makes it more

    difficult for decision agents at all levels of the organization to take actions that benefit

    12 See Weber (1947); Blau (1956); Simon (1962); and the titles by Williamson (1975). The historical development of hierarchies in open corporations is analyzed in Chandler (1977); and Chandler and Daems (1980).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 13

    themselves at the expense of residual claimants. Decision hierarchies are buttressed by

    organizational rules of the game, for example, accounting and budgeting systems, that

    monitor and constrain the decision behavior of agents and specify the performance

    criteria that determine rewards.13

    Mutual monitoring systems. The formal hierarchies of complex organizations are

    also buttressed by information from less formal mutual monitoring among agents. When

    agents interact to produce outputs, they acquire low-cost information about colleagues,

    information not directly available to higher level agents. Mutual monitoring systems tap

    this information for use in the control process. Mutual monitoring systems derive their

    energy from the interests of agents to use the internal agent markets of organizations to

    enhance the value of human capital.14 Agents choose among organizations on the basis of

    rewards offered and potential for development of human capital. Agents value the

    competitive interaction that takes place within an organizations internal agent market

    because it enhances current marginal products and contributes to human capital

    development. Moreover, if agents perceive that evaluation of their performance is

    unbiased (that is, if they cannot systematically fool their evaluators) then they value the

    fine tuning of the reward system that results from mutual monitoring information,

    because it lowers the uncertainty of payoffs from effort and skill. Since the incentive

    structures and diffuse decision control systems that result from the interplay of formal

    hierarchies and less formal mutual monitoring systems are also in the interests of residual

    claimants, their survival value is evident.

    13 The separation of decision management from decision control that we emphasize is reflected in the auditing professions concern with allocating operating and accounting responsibility to different agents. For instance, it is recommended that an agent with responsibility for billing should not have a role in receiving or recording customer payments. See, for example, Horngren (1982, ch. 27); or Stettler (1977, ch. 4 & 8).

    14 See Fama (1980).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 14

    Boards of directors. The common apex of the decision control systems of

    organizations, large and small, in which decision agents do not bear a major share of the

    wealth effects of their decisions is some form of board of directors. Such boards always

    have the power to hire, fire, and compensate the top-level decision managers and to ratify

    and monitor important decisions. Exercise of these top-level decision control rights by a

    group (the board) helps to ensure separation of decision management and control (that is,

    the absence of an entrepreneurial decision maker) even at the top of the organization.15

    IV. The Spectrum of Organizations

    A. Introduction

    Organizations in which important decision agents do not bear a major share of the

    wealth effects of their decisions include open corporations, large professional

    partnerships, financial mutuals, and nonprofits. We are concerned now with analyzing the

    data each of these organizations provides to test the hypothesis that separation of decision

    management functions from residual risk bearing leads to decision systems that separate

    the management and control of decisions.

    To motivate the discussion of specific organizational forms, we also outline a set

    of more specialized propositions to explain the survival value of the special features of

    their residual claims. These more specialized hypotheses about the survival of specific

    organizational forms in specific activities are developed in our paper Agency Problems

    and Residual Claims.16

    15 Decision functions can be delegated in two general ways: (1) joint delegation to several agents (as in a committee), or (2) partitioning and delegation of the parts to different agents. Boards of directors are examples of the former approach; decision hierarchies are examples of the latter.

    16 Fama and Jensen (1983).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 15

    B. Open Corporations

    1. Unrestricted Common Stock Residual Claims. Most large nonfinancial

    organizations are open corporations. The common stock residual claims of such

    organizations are unrestricted in the sense that stockholders are not required to have any

    other role in the organization, and their residual claims are freely alienable. As a result of

    the unrestricted nature of the residual claims of open corporations, there is almost

    complete specialization of decision management and residual risk bearing. Even

    managers who own substantial blocs of stock, and thus are residual risk bearers, may

    elect to sell these shares.

    Unrestricted common stock is attractive in complicated risky activities where

    substantial wealth provided by residual claimants is needed to bond the large aggregate

    payoffs promised to many other agents. Unrestricted common stock, with its capacity for

    generating large amounts of wealth from residual claimants on a permanent basis, is also

    attractive in activities more efficiently carried out with large amounts of risky assets

    owned within the organization rather than rented. Moreover, since decision skills are not

    a necessary consequence of wealth or willingness to bear risk, the specialization of

    decision management and residual risk bearing allowed by unrestricted common stock

    enhances the adaptability of a complex organization to changes in the economic

    environment. The unrestricted risk sharing and diversification allowed by common stock

    also contributes to survival by lowering the cost of risk-bearing services.

    2. Control of the Agency Problems of Common Stock. Separation and

    specialization of decision management and residual risk bearing leads to agency

    problems between decision agents and residual claimants. This is the problem of

    separation of ownership and control that has long troubled students of corporations. For

    example, potential exploitation of residual claimants by opportunistic decision agents is

    reflected in the arguments leading to the establishment of the Securities and Exchange

    Commission and in the concerns of the modern corporate governance movement. Less

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 16

    well appreciated, however, is the fact that the unrestricted nature of common stock

    residual claims also allows special market and organizational mechanisms for controlling

    the agency problems of specialized risk bearing.

    The stock market. The unrestricted alienability of the residual claims of open

    corporations gives rise to an external monitoring device unique to these organizationsa

    stock market that specializes in pricing common stocks and transferring them at low cost.

    Stock prices are visible signals that summarize the implications of internal decisions for

    current and future net cash flows. This external monitoring exerts pressure to orient a

    corporations decision process toward the interests of residual claimants.

    The market for takeovers. External monitoring from a takeover market is also

    unique to the open corporation and is attributable to the unrestricted nature of its residual

    claims.17 Because the residual claims are freely alienable and separable from roles in the

    decision process, attacking managers can circumvent existing managers and the current

    board to gain control of the decision process, either by a direct offer to purchase stock (a

    tender offer) or by an appeal for stockholder votes for directors (a proxy fight).

    Expert boards. Internal control in the open corporation is delegated by residual

    claimants to a board of directors. Residual claimants generally retain approval rights (by

    vote) on such matters as board membership, auditor choice, mergers, and new stock

    issues. Other management and control functions are delegated by the residual claimants

    to the board. The board then delegates most decision management functions and many

    decision control functions to internal agents, but it retains ultimate control over internal

    agentsincluding the rights to ratify and monitor major policy initiatives and to hire,

    fire, and set the compensation of top level decision managers. Similar delegation of

    decision management and control functions, at the first step to a board and then from the

    17 Monitoring from the takeover market is emphasized in Manne (1965).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 17

    board to internal decision agents, is common to other organizations, such as financial

    mutuals, nonprofits, and large professional partnerships, in which important decision

    agents do not bear a major share of the wealth effects of their decisions.

    However, the existence of the stock market and the market for takeovers, both

    special to open corporations, explains some of the special features of corporate boards, in

    particular: (1) why inside manager board members are generally more influential than

    outside members, and (2) why outside board members are often decision agents in other

    complex organizations.18

    Since the takeover market provides an external court of last resort for protection

    of residual claimants, a corporate board can be in the hands of agents who are decision

    experts. Given that the board is to be composed of experts, it is natural that its most

    influential members are internal managers since they have valuable specific information

    about the organizations activities. It is also natural that when the internal decision

    control system works well, the outside members of the board are nominated by internal

    managers. Internal managers can use their knowledge of the organization to nominate

    outside board members with relevant complementary knowledge: for example, outsiders

    with expertise in capital markets, corporate law, or relevant technology who provide an

    important support function to the top managers in dealing with specialized decision

    problems.

    However, the board is not an effective device for decision control unless it limits

    the decision discretion of individual top managers. The board is the top-level court of

    appeals of the internal agent market,19 and as such it must be able to use information from

    the internal mutual monitoring system. To accomplish this and to achieve effective

    18 See Herman (1981, ch. 2), for data on the characteristics of corporate boards.

    19 See Fama (1980).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 18

    separation of top-level decision management and control, we expect the board of a large

    open corporation to include several of the organizations top managers. The board uses

    information from each of the top managers about his decision initiatives and the decision

    initiatives and performance of other managers. The board also seeks information from

    lower level managers about the decision initiatives and performance of top managers.20

    This information is used to set the rewards of the top managers, to rank them, and to

    choose among their decision initiatives. To protect information flows to the board, we

    expect that top managers, especially those who are members of the board, can effectively

    be fired only with consent of the board and thus are protected from reprisals from other

    top managers.

    The decision processes of some open corporations seem to be dominated by an

    individual manager, generally the chief executive officer. In some cases, this signals the

    absence of separation of decision management and decision control, and, in our theory,

    the organization suffers in the competition for survival. We expect, however, that the

    apparent dominance of some top managers is more often due to their ability to work with

    the decision control systems of their organizations than to their ability to suppress diffuse

    and separate decision control. In any case, the financial press regularly reports instances

    where apparently dominant executives are removed by their boards.

    Corporate boards generally include outside members, that is, members who are

    not internal managers, and they often hold a majority of seats.21 The outside board

    members act as arbiters in disagreements among internal managers and carry out tasks

    20 For example, Horngren (1982, at 911), describes the role of the audit committee of the board (generally composed of outside board members) as a collector and conduit of information from the internal mutual monitoring system: The objective of the audit committee is to oversee the accounting controls, financial statements, and financial affairs of the corporation. The committee represents the full board and provides personal contact and communication among the board, the external auditors, the internal auditors, the financial executives, and the operating executives.

    21 See Herman (1981, ch. 2).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 19

    that involve serious agency problems between internal managers and residual claimants,

    for example, setting executive compensation or searching for replacements for top

    managers.

    Effective separation of top-level decision management and control means that

    outside directors have incentives to carry out their tasks and do not collude with

    managers to expropriate residual claimants. Our hypothesis is that outside directors have

    incentives to develop reputations as experts in decision control. Most outside directors of

    open corporations are either managers of other corporations or important decision agents

    in other complex organizations.22 The value of their human capital depends primarily on

    their performance as internal decision managers in other organizations. They use their

    directorships to signal to internal and external markets for decision agents that (1) they

    are decision experts, (2) they understand the importance of diffuse and separate decision

    control, and (3) they can work with such decision control systems. The signals are

    credible when the direct payments to outside directors are small, but there is substantial

    devaluation of human capital when internal decision control breaks down and the costly

    last resort process of an outside takeover is activated.

    C. Professional Partnerships

    1. Mutual Monitoring, Specific Knowledge, and Restricted Residual Claims.

    The residual claims of professional partnerships in activities such as law, public

    accounting, medicine, and business consulting are restricted to the major professional

    agents who produce the organizations services. This restriction increases the incentives

    of agents to monitor each others actions and to consult with each other to improve the

    quality of services provided to customers. Such mutual monitoring and consulting are

    attractive to the professional agents in service activities where responsibility for variation

    22 See Herman (1981, ch. 2).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 20

    in the quality of services is easily assigned and the value of professional human capital is

    sensitive to performance. The monitoring and consulting are likely to be effective when

    professional agents with similar specialized skills agree to share liability for the actions

    of colleagues.

    In both large and small partnerships, individuals or small teams work on cases,

    audits, and so forth. Because of the importance of specific knowledge about particular

    clients and circumstances, it is efficient for the teams to make most decisions locally. At

    this level. however, decision management and decision control are not separate. To

    control the resulting agency problems, the residual claims in professional partnerships,

    large and small, are restricted to the professional agents who have the major decision-

    making roles. This is consistent with our hypothesis that combination of decision

    management and control functions leads to restriction of residual claims to the agents

    who both manage and control important decisions.

    2. Large Professional Partnerships. The partners in large professional

    partnerships are diffuse residual claimants whose welfare depends on the acts of agents

    they do not directly control. Thus, these organizations provide a test of our hypothesis

    that separation of residual risk bearing and decision management induces decision

    systems that separate the management and control of important decisions. The major

    decision control devices of large professional partnerships are similar to those of other

    organizations with diffuse residual claims. For example, residual claimants in large

    partnerships delegate to boards the ratification and monitoring of important decisions

    above the level of individual cases and audits. Moreover, the sharing of liability and

    residual cash flows among important decision agents (the partners) ensures that large

    partnerships have strong versions of the mutual monitoring systems that we contend are

    common to the decision control systems of complex organizations.

    The boards of large partnerships have special features that relate to the restriction

    of the residual claims to important internal agents. The residual claimants are experts in

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 21

    the organizations activities, and they observe directly the effects of actions taken by the

    board of managing partners. Thus, unlike the stockholders of open corporations, the

    residual claimants in large partnerships have little demand for outside experts to protect

    their interests, and their boards are composed entirely of partners.

    The board is involved in decisions with respect to the management of the

    partnership, for example, where new offices should be opened, who should be admitted to

    the partnership, and who should be dismissed. The board is also involved in renegotiating

    the shares of the partners. Here, as in other decisions, the boards of large partnerships

    combine the valuable specific knowledge available at the top level with information from

    partner-residual claimants. The role of the board is to develop acceptable consensus

    decisions from this information. Thus, the boards of large professional partnerships are

    generally called committees of managing partners rather than boards of directors. The

    idea is that such committees exist to manage agency problems among partners and to

    study and determine major policy issues in a manner that is less costly than when

    performed jointly by all partners.

    Since the residual claims in a large professional partnership are not alienable,

    unfriendly outside takeovers are not possible. Inside takeovers by dissident partners are

    possible, however, because the managing boards of these organizations are elected by the

    partner-residual claimants.

    D. Financial Mutuals

    A common form of organization in financial activities is the mutual. An unusual

    characteristic of mutuals is that the residual claimants are customers, for example, the

    policyholders of mutual insurance companies, the depositors of mutual savings banks,

    and the shareholders of mutual funds. Like the diffuse stockholders of large nonfinancial

    corporations, most of the diffuse depositors, policyholders, and mutual fund shareholders

    of financial mutuals do not participate in the internal decision process. Thus, financial

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 22

    mutuals provide another test of our hypothesis that substantial separation of decision

    management and residual risk bearing leads to decision systems that separate the

    management and control of decisions.

    1. The Control Function of Redeemable Claims. For the purpose of decision

    control, the unique characteristic of the residual claims of mutuals is that they are

    redeemable on demand. The policyholder, depositor, or shareholder can, on demand, turn

    in his claim at a price determined by a prespecified rule. For example, the shareholder of

    an open-end mutual fund can redeem his claim for the market value of his share of the

    funds assets, while the whole life or endowment insurance policyholder, like the

    shareholder of a mutual savings bank, can redeem his claim for its specified value plus

    accumulated dividends.

    The decision of the claim holder to withdraw resources is a form of partial

    takeover or liquidation which deprives management of control over assets. This control

    right can be exercised independently by each claim holder. It does not require a proxy

    fight, a tender offer, or any other concerted takeover bid. In contrast, customer decisions

    in open nonfinancial corporations and the repricing of the corporations securities in the

    capital market provide signals about the performance of its decision agents. Without

    further action, however, either internal or from the market for takeovers, the judgments of

    customers and of the capital market leave the assets of the open nonfinancial corporation

    under the control of the managers.

    2. The Board of Directors. Like other organizations characterized by substantial

    separation between decision management and residual risk bearing, the top-level decision

    control device in financial mutuals is a board of directors. Because of the strong form of

    diffuse decision control inherent in the redeemable residual claims of financial mutuals,

    however, their boards are less important in the control process than the boards of open

    nonfinancial corporations. The reduced role of the board is especially evident in mutual

    savings banks and mutual funds, which are not complex even though often large in terms

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 23

    of assets. Moreover, the residual claimants of mutuals show little interest in their boards

    and often do not have the right to vote for board members.23 Outside board members are

    generally chosen by internal managers. Unlike open corporations, the boards of financial

    mutuals do not often impose changes in managers. The role of the board, especially in the

    less complex mutuals, is largely limited to monitoring agency problems against which

    redemption of residual claims offers little protection, for example, fraud or outright theft

    of assets by internal agents.

    E. Nonprofit Organizations

    When an organizations activities are financed in part through donations, part of

    net cash flows is from resources provided by donors. Contracts that define the share of

    residual claimants in net cash flows are unlikely to assure donors that their resources are

    protected from expropriation by residual claimants. In a nonprofit organization, however,

    there are no agents with alienable rights in residual net cash flows and thus there are no

    residual claims. We argue in Agency Problems and Residual Claims that the absence

    of such residual claims in nonprofits avoids the donor-residual claimant agency problem

    and explains the dominance of nonprofits in donor-financed activities.24

    The absence of residual claims in nonprofits avoids agency problems between

    donors and residual claimants, but the incentives of other internal agents to expropriate

    donations remain. These agency problems between donors and decision agents in

    nonprofits are similar to those in other organizations where important decision managers

    do not bear a major share of the wealth effects of their decisions. Our hypothesis predicts

    that, like other organizations characterized by separation of decision management from

    23 See Herman (1969), for documentation of such lack of interest. For example, he describes situations where in more than a decade only four depositors in total attended the annual meetings of two savings and loan associations and other situations where management did not even bother to collect proxies.

    24 Fama and Jensen (1983). See Hansmann (1980) for a general discussion of nonprofits.

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 24

    residual risk bearing, nonprofits have decision systems that separate the management

    (initiation and implementation) and control (ratification and monitoring) of decisions.

    Such decision systems survive in donor nonprofits because of the assurances they provide

    that donations are used effectively and are not easily expropriated.

    1. Nonprofit Boards. In small nonprofits delegation of decision management to

    one or a few agents is generally efficient. For example, in nonprofit cultural performing

    groups, an artistic director usually chooses performers, does the primary monitoring of

    their outputs, and initiates and implements major decisions. Nevertheless, the important

    decision agents in these organizations are chosen, monitored, and evaluated by boards of

    directors. Boards with similar decision control rights are common to other small

    nonprofits characterized by concentrated decision management, such as charities, private

    museums, small private hospitals, and local Protestant and Jewish congregations. Boards

    are also observed at the top of the decision control systems of complex nonprofits, such

    as private universities, in which both decision management and decision control are

    diffuse.

    Although their functions are similar to those of other organizations, nonprofit

    boards have special features that are due to the absence of alienable residual claims. For

    example, because of the discipline from the outside takeover market, boards of open

    corporations can include internal decision agents, and outside board members can be

    chosen for expertise rather than because they are important residual claimants. In

    contrast, because a nonprofit lacks alienable residual claims, the decision agents are

    immune from ouster (via takeover) by outside agents. Without the takeover threat or the

    discipline imposed by residual claimants with the right to remove members of the board,

    nonprofit boards composed of internal agents and outside experts chosen by internal

    agents would provide little assurance against collusion and expropriation of donations.

    Thus, nonprofit boards generally include few if any internal agents as voting members,

    and nonprofit boards are often self-perpetuating, that is, new members are approved by

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 25

    existing members. Moreover, nonprofit board members are generally substantial donors

    who serve without pay. Willingness to provide continuing personal donations of wealth

    or time is generally an implicit condition for membership on nonprofit boards.

    Acceptance of this condition certifies to other donors that board members are motivated

    to take their decision control task seriously.

    2. The Roman Catholic Church. To our knowledge the only nonprofit

    organization that is financed with donations but lacks a board of important continuing

    donors with effective decision control rights is the Roman Catholic church. Parish

    councils exist in local Catholic churches, but unlike their Protestant and Jewish

    counterparts, they are only advisory. The clerical hierarchy controls the allocation of

    resources, and the papal system does not seem to limit the discretion of the Pope, the

    organizations most important decision agent.

    Other aspects of the contracts of the Catholic clergy in part substitute for the

    control of expropriation of donations that would be provided by more effective donor-

    customer constraints on decisions. For example, the vows of chastity and obedience

    incorporated into the contracts of the Catholic clergy help to bond against expropriation

    of donations by avoiding conflicts between the material interests of a family and the

    interests of donor-customers. In addition, the training of a Catholic priest is organization-

    specific. For example, it involves a heavy concentration on (Catholic) theology, whereas

    the training of Protestant ministers places more emphasis on social service skills. Once

    certified, the Catholic priest is placed by the hierarchy. He cannot offer his services on a

    competitive basis. In exchange for developing such organization-specific human capital,

    the Catholic priest, unlike his Protestant and Jewish counterparts, gets a lifetime contract

    that promises a real standard of living. The organization-specific nature of the human

    capital of the Catholic clergy and the terms of the contract under which it is employed act

    as a bond to donor-customers that the interests of the Catholic clergy are closely bound to

    the survival of the organization and thus to the interests of donor-customers.

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 26

    Although Protestantism arose over doctrinal issues, the control structures of

    Protestant sectsin particular, the evolution of lay councils with power to ratify and

    monitor resource allocation decisionscan be viewed as a response to breakdowns of the

    contract structure of Catholicism, that is, expropriation of Catholic donor-customers by

    the clergy. The evolution of Protestantism is therefore an example of competition among

    alternative contract structures to resolve an activitys major agency problemin this case

    monitoring important agents to limit expropriation of donations.

    There is currently pressure to allow Catholic priests to marry, that is, to drop the

    vow of chastity from their contracts. We predict that if this occurs, organizational

    survival will require other monitoring and bonding mechanisms, for example, control

    over allocation of resources by lay councils similar to those observed in Protestant and

    Jewish congregations.

    3. The Private University and Decision Systems in Complex Nonprofits. In

    complex nonprofits we observe mechanisms for diffuse decision control similar to those

    of other complex organizations. For example, large private universities, like large open

    corporations, have complicated decision hierarchies and active internal agent markets

    with mutual monitoring systems that generate information about the performance of

    agents. Again, however, the decision control structures of complex nonprofits have

    special features attributable to the absence of alienable residual claims.

    For example, a universitys trustees are primarily donors rather than experts in the

    details of education or research. In ratifying and monitoring decision initiatives presented

    by internal decision agents (presidents, chancellors, provosts, etc.), and in evaluating the

    agents themselves, boards rely on information from the internal diffuse decision

    systemfor example, reports from faculty senates and appointments committeesand

    on external peer reviews.

    Moreover, the structure of internal diffuse decision control systems is a more

    formal part of a universitys contract structure (its charter or by-laws) than in large for-

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 27

    profit organizations such as open corporations. For example, unlike corporate managers.

    university deans, department heads, provosts, and presidents are generally appointed for

    fixed terms. The end of a contract period activates a process of evaluation, with search

    committees chosen according to formal rules and with rules for passing their

    recommendations on to the board. A more formal structure of diffuse decision

    management and control is helpful to trustees who do not have specialized knowledge

    about a universitys activities. It also helps to assure donors that the absence of discipline

    from an outside takeover market is compensated by a strong system for internal decision

    control.

    V. Summary

    The theory developed in this paper views an organization as a nexus of contracts

    (written and unwritten). The theory focuses on the contracts that (1) allocate the steps in

    an organizations decision process, (2) define residual claims, and (3) set up devices for

    controlling agency problems in the decision process. We focus on the factors that give

    survival value to organizational forms that separate what the literature imprecisely calls

    ownership and control.

    A. The Central Hypotheses

    An organizations decision process consists of decision management (initiation

    and implementation) and decision control (ratification and monitoring). Our analysis

    produces two complementary hypotheses about the relations between decision systems

    and residual claims:

    Separation of residual risk bearing from decision management leads to decision

    systems that separate decision management from decision control.

    Combination of decision management and decision control in a few agents leads

    to residual claims that are largely restricted to these agents.

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 28

    B. Combination of Decision Management and Control

    When it is efficient to combine decision management and control functions in one

    or a few agents, it is efficient to control agency problems between residual claimants and

    decision makers by restricting residual claims to the decision makers. This proposition

    gets clear support from the proprietorships, small partnerships, and closed corporations

    observed in small-scale production and service activities. These organizations are all

    characterized by concentrated decision systems and residual claims that are restricted to

    decision agents.

    C. Separation of Residual Risk Bearing from Decision Management

    1. The Role of Specific Knowledge. In contrast, most of the organizations

    characterized by separation of residual risk bearing from decision management are

    complex in the sense that specific information valuable for decisions is diffused among

    many agents throughout the organization. Thus in a complex organization separation of

    residual risk bearing from decision management arises in part because efficient decision

    systems are diffuse. Benefits from better decisions can be achieved by delegating

    decision functions to agents at all levels of the organization who have relevant specific

    knowledge, rather than allocating all decision management and control to the residual

    claimants. Control of the agency problems of such diffuse decision systems is then

    achieved by separating the ratification and monitoring of decisions (decision control)

    from initiation and implementation (decision management). The efficiency of such

    decision systems is buttressed by incentive structures that reward agents both for

    initiating and implementing decisions and for ratifying and monitoring the decision

    management of other agents.

    2. The Role of Diffuse Residual Claims. In most complex organizations,

    residual claims are diffused among many agents. When there are many residual

    claimants, it is costly for all of them to be involved in decision control. As a consequence

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 29

    there is separation of residual risk bearing from decision control, and this creates agency

    problems between residual claimants and decision agents. Separation of decision

    management and decision control at all levels of the organization helps to control these

    agency problems by limiting the power of individual agents to expropriate the interests of

    residual claimants. Thus diffusion and separation of decision management and control

    have survival value in complex organizations both because they allow valuable specific

    knowledge to be used at the points in the decision process where it is most relevant and

    because they help control the agency problems of diffuse residual claims.

    3. Common Features of Decision Control Systems. What we call separation of

    residual risk bearing from decision management is the separation of ownership and

    control that has long bothered students of open corporations. We argue that separation of

    decision and risk bearing functions is also common to other organizations like large

    professional partnerships, financial mutuals, and nonprofits. Moreover, our central

    hypothesis about control of the agency problems caused by separation of residual risk

    bearing from decision management gets support from the fact that the major mechanisms

    for separating decision management and decision control are much the same across

    organizations.

    The common central building blocks of the diffuse decision control systems of

    complex organizations of all types are formal decision hierarchies in which the decision

    initiatives of lower level agents are passed on to higher level agents, first for ratification

    and then for monitoring. Such decision hierarchies are found in large open corporations,

    large professional partnerships, large financial mutuals, and large nonprofits. Formal

    decision hierarchies are buttressed by less formal mutual monitoring systems that are a

    by-product of interaction that takes place to produce outputs and develop human capital.

    The common apex of the decision control systems of organizations, large and

    small, in which decision agents do not bear a major share of the wealth effects of their

    decisions is a board of directors (trustees, managing partners, etc.) that ratifies and

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 30

    monitors important decisions and chooses, dismisses, and rewards important decision

    agents. Such multiple-member boards make collusion between top-level decision

    management and control agents more difficult, and they are the mechanism that allows

    separation of the management and control of the organizations most important decisions.

    References

    Alchian, Armen A. (1950). Uncertainty, Evolution and Economic Theory. Journal of Political Economy 58, no. 3 (June): 221-221.

    Alchian, Armen A. and Harold Demsetz (1972). Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization. American Economic Review LXII, no. 5 (December): 777-795.

    Arrow, Kenneth J. (1964). The Role of Securities in the Optimal Allocation of Risk Bearing. Review of Economic Studies 31, no. 86 (January): 91-96.

    Berle, Adolf A. and Gardiner C. Means (1932). The Modern Corporation and Private Property. New York, Macmillan Publishing Co.

    Blau, Peter M. (1956). Bureaucracy in Modern Society. New York, Random House.

    Chandler, Alfred D., Jr. (1977). The Visible Hand: The Managerial Revolution in American Business. Cambridge, Mass, Belknap Press

    Chandler, Alfred D., Jr. and Herman Daems (1980). Managerial Hierarchies: Comparative Perspectives on the Rise of the Modern Industrial Enterprise. Cambridge, MA, Harvard University Press.

    Fama, Eugene F. (1976). Foundations of Finance. New York, Basic Books.

    Fama, Eugene F. (1980). Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm. Journal of Political Economy 88, no. 2 (April): 288-307.

    Fama, Eugene F. and Michael C. Jensen (1983). Agency Problems and Residual Claims. Journal of Law and Economics 26, no. 2 : 327-349.

    Hansmann, Henry B. (1980). The Role of Nonprofit Enterprise. Yale Law Journal 89, no. 5 (April): 835-901.

    Hayek, F.A. (1945). The Use of Scientific Knowledge in Society. American Economic Review 35, no. 4 (September).

  • Fama and Jensen 1983 31

    Herman, Edward S. (1969). Conflict of Interest in the Savings and Loan Industry. A Study of of the Savings and Loan Industry. I. Friend. Washington, D.C., Federal Home Loan Board.

    Herman, Edward S. (1981). Corporate Control: Corporate Power. Twentieth Century Fund Study. New York, Cambridge University Press.

    Horngren, Charles (1982). Cost Accounting: A Managerial Emphasis. Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall.

    Jensen, Michael C. (1983). Organization Theory and Methodology. Accounting Review 50 (April).

    Jensen, Michael C. and William H. Meckling (1976). Theory of the Firm: Managerial Behavior, Agency Costs, and Ownership Structure. Journal of Financial Economics 3, no. 4 (October): 305-360.

    Jensen, Michael C. and William H. Meckling (1979). Rights and Production Functions: An Application to Labor-managed Firms and Codetermination. Journal of Business 52, no. 4 (October): 469-506.

    Manne, H.G. (1965). Mergers and the Market for Corporate Control. Journal of Political Economy (April): 110-120.

    Simon, Herbert A. (1962). The Architecture of Complexity. Proceedings of the, American Philosophical Society.

    Smith, Adam (1776). The Wealth of Nations. Edited by Edwin Cannan, 1904. Reprint edition 1937. New York, Modern Library.

    Sowell, Thomas (1980). Knowledge and Decisions. New York, Basic Books.

    Stettler, Howard P. (1977). Auditing Principles. Englewood Cliffs, NJ, Prentice-Hall.

    Weber, Max (1947). The Theory of Social and Economic Organization. Glencoe, IL, Free Press.

    Williamson, Oliver E. (1975). Markets and Hierarchies: Analysis and Antitrust Implications. New York, Free Press.

    Williamson, Oliver E. (1981). The Modern Corporation: Origins, Evolution, Attributes. Journal of Economic Literature 19 (December): 1537-1568.