stephen j. turnovsky university of washington, seattle

45
The Dynamics of Wealth and Income Distribution in a Neoclassical Growth Model * Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle Cecilia García-Peñalosa CNRS and GREQAM March 2006 Abstract: We examine the evolution of the distributions of wealth and income in a Ramsey model in which agents differ in their initial capital endowment and where the labor supply is endogenous. The assumption that the utility function is homogeneous in consumption and leisure implies that the macroeconomic equilibrium is independent of the distribution of wealth and allows us to fully characterize income and wealth dynamics. We find non-degenerate long-run distributions of wealth and income. The model shows that (i) the initial level of aggregate capital is an essential determinant of whether inequality increases or decreases during the transition to the steady state; (ii) temporary shocks to the stock of capital have long-run effects on the distribution of wealth even if they do not affect the stationary aggregate variables; (iii) income inequality need not move together with wealth inequality if factor shares change during the transition. JEL Classification Numbers: D31, O41 Key words: wealth distribution; income distribution; endogenous labor supply; transitional dynamics. * Turnovsky’s research was supported in part by the Castor endowment at the University of Washington. We are grateful to Carine Nourry for her comments.

Upload: others

Post on 30-Dec-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

The Dynamics of Wealth and Income Distribution in a Neoclassical Growth Model*

Stephen J. Turnovsky

University of Washington, Seattle

Cecilia García-Peñalosa

CNRS and GREQAM

March 2006

Abstract: We examine the evolution of the distributions of wealth and income in a Ramsey model in which agents differ in their initial capital endowment and where the labor supply is endogenous. The assumption that the utility function is homogeneous in consumption and leisure implies that the macroeconomic equilibrium is independent of the distribution of wealth and allows us to fully characterize income and wealth dynamics. We find non-degenerate long-run distributions of wealth and income. The model shows that (i) the initial level of aggregate capital is an essential determinant of whether inequality increases or decreases during the transition to the steady state; (ii) temporary shocks to the stock of capital have long-run effects on the distribution of wealth even if they do not affect the stationary aggregate variables; (iii) income inequality need not move together with wealth inequality if factor shares change during the transition.

JEL Classification Numbers: D31, O41

Key words: wealth distribution; income distribution; endogenous labor supply; transitional

dynamics.

* Turnovsky’s research was supported in part by the Castor endowment at the University of Washington. We are grateful to Carine Nourry for her comments.

Page 2: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

1

1. Introduction

Beginning with Stiglitz’s (1969) seminal contribution, the evolution of the distribution of

wealth in neoclassical growth models has been extensively studied. A central question to emerge

from this literature concerns the circumstances under which the neoclassical model with an unequal

distribution of wealth mimics the representative-agent model insofar as the macroeconomic

aggregates are concerned. Caselli and Ventura (2000) examine the Ramsey model with exogenous

labor supply and heterogeneous agents that differ in their initial wealth (capital) endowment. They

show that in this case, the macroeconomic equilibrium is independent of the distribution of wealth,

while the distribution of wealth depends on the evolution of the aggregate economy. They term this

a “representative consumer theory of distribution”. In this paper we determine the conditions under

which the Ramsey model with endogenous labor supply may also exhibits this feature.

A Ramsey model with endogenous labor and heterogeneous wealth endowments has been

studied by Sorger (2000). He shows that for his chosen specification of utility over consumption and

leisure, the evolution of aggregate variables depends on the entire distribution of wealth at each point

in time. A key feature of his specification is that the utility function is non-homogeneous in its two

arguments. In this paper we consider an alternative specification for the utility function, namely that

it is of the familiar constant elasticity for in consumption and leisure, making it s member of a more

general class of homogeneous utility functions. Indeed, homogeneity turns out to play a crucial role

in agents’ labor supply choices, making the individual supply of labor not only a function of the

agent’s wealth, as in Sorger, but a linear function. As a result, aggregate variables are independent

of the distribution of wealth, and we recover the independence of the macroeconomic equilibrium

from distribution of the Ramsey model without endogenous labor.

This result has two important implications. First, Sorger finds a correlation between per

capita income levels and the distribution of wealth, which depends on the elasticity of intertemporal

substitution. In contrast, with our chosen utility specification, a particular level of per capita output

is compatible with any distribution of wealth, depending on the initial distribution. Second, Sorger

focuses on the stationary state, as the interdependence of the macroeconomic equilibrium and

Page 3: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

2

distribution renders the analysis of the dynamics intractable. 1 Our formulation allows us to

represent the macroeconomic equilibrium in terms of a simple recursive structure. First the

dynamics of the aggregate stock of capital and labor supply are jointly determined, independently of

distribution. Then individual quantities are obtained as a function of the aggregate magnitudes,

implying that we are able to characterize the transitional dynamics of the distributions of wealth, and

ultimately, income.

We find that wealth holdings converge to a steady state distribution such that agents hold

different amounts of capital. Wealthier individuals remain wealthier, but the steady state distribution

depends both on parameters of the economy and on initial conditions. In fact, the dynamics of the

distribution of wealth depend on whether the economy converges to the steady state from below or

from above. If the initial stock of capital is below the steady state one, then wealth inequality will

decrease during the transition. This contrasts with the results obtained by Caselli and Ventura

(2000) in the Ramsey model with exogenous labor supply, where wealth inequality falls during the

transition from below for certain parameterizations, while it increases for others. We show that it is

labor supply responses that prevent wealth divergence. We also characterize the steady state

distribution of income. We find that the dynamics of the distribution of income can be complex, as

they depend both on the dynamics of individual wealth and on the evolution of factor rewards. If the

shares of labor and capital in aggregate output are not constant, it is possible for the distribution of

income to exhibit episodes of increasing and episodes of decreasing income inequality during the

transition to the steady state.

Two key elements drive our results. The first is the relationship we derive between agents’

relative wealth (capital) and their relative allocation of time between work and leisure. This

relationship is very basic and has a simple intuition. Wealthier agents have a lower marginal utility

of wealth. They therefore choose to increase consumption of all goods including leisure, and reduce

their labor supply. Indeed, the role played by labor supply in this model is analogous to its role in

other models of capital accumulation and growth, where it provides the crucial mechanism by which

1 In fact, Sorger also obtains a linear relationship between individual capital and labor supply for the particular parameter value for which his utility function is homogenous. However, since he is interested in how distribution affects output levels he does not focus on this case, and hence does not derive the dynamics of wealth.

Page 4: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

3

demand shocks influence the rate of capital accumulation. For example, in the standard Ramsey

model, government consumption expenditure will generate capital accumulation if and only if labor

is supplied elastically. With inelastic labor supply it will simply crowd out an equivalent amount of

private consumption. The key factor is the wealth effect and the impact this has on the labor-leisure

choice, as emphasized by both Ortigueira (2000) and Turnovsky (2000). This mechanism is also

central to empirical models of labor supply based on intertemporal optimization; see e.g. MaCurdy

(1981).

There is substantial empirical evidence documenting the negative relationship between

wealth and labor supply. Holtz-Eakin, Joulfaian, and Rosen (1993) find evidence to support the view

that large inheritances decrease labor participation. Cheng and French (2000) and Coronado and

Perozek (2003) use data from the stock market boom of the 1990s to study the effects of wealth on

labor supply and retirement, finding a substantial negative effect on labor participation. Algan,

Chéron, Hairault, and Langot (2003) use French data to analyze the effect of wealth on labor market

transitions, and find a significant wealth effect on the extensive margin of labor supply. Overall,

these studies and others provide compelling evidence in support of the wealth-leisure mechanism

being emphasized in this paper.

The other crucial element in our analysis is the assumption of that utility is homogeneous in

consumption and leisure. This type of utility function is common in many areas of macroeconomics,

most notably in business cycle theory but also in the endogenous growth literature.2 It is therefore

an important question to understand whether this type of preferences allow a representative-

consumer representation of societies with heterogeneous agents. Homogenous utility functions are

also commonly used by labor economists, and are generally consistent with empirical evidence on

labor supply responses; see Heckman (1976) and Zabalza (1983).

In our analysis we focus on a constant elasticity (Cobb-Douglas) specification for utility,

although the independence of the aggregate equilibrium from distribution would hold for any

homogenous utility function. This specification, which implies that utility is nonseparable in

2 See King and Rebelo (1999) for a survey on business cycle theory, and Rebelo (1991), Ladrón-de-Guevara et al. (1997, 1999), Turnovsky (2000) and García-Peñalosa and Turnovsky (2006a,b) for endogenous growth models.

Page 5: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

4

consumption, is frequently used in policy analyses of endogenous growth models.3 Although

empirical evidence on this aspect of preferences is scarce, two recent studies indicate that the

elasticity of substitution between leisure and consumption is different from zero. Laitner and

Silverman (2005) use changes in consumption over the life-cycle to estimate the substitutability

between leisure and consumption, and show that separable preferences are not consistent with the

observed drop in consumption taking place at retirement. Jacobs (2005) uses investment data to

estimate the various parameters in the utility function and cannot reject the assumption of

nonseparability. This evidence indicates that our choice of preferences is a natural setup in which to

study wealth and income dynamics.

Our paper provides a bridge between the representative consumer theory of distribution of

Caselli and Ventura (2000) and the model with endogenous labor of Sorger (2000). It is also related

to Ghiglino and Sorger (2002), who consider a Ramsey model with endogenous labor, but focus on

the impact of the distribution of wealth on the possibility of indeterminacy, and to Bliss (2004), who

generalizes the result of non-convergence of wealth in the basic Ramsey model to the case of non-

time separable preferences. Chatterjee (1994) has also examined the dynamics of the distribution of

wealth in the Ramsey model, and finds that under reasonable parameter specifications wealth

inequality increases during the process of development. The mechanism driving this result is,

however, very different from ours. He assumes the existence of a minimum consumption

requirement which tends to make the propensity to save increasing in individual wealth, and hence

exacerbates inequalities as the economy accumulates capital. Lastly, there is an extensive literature

focusing on the Ramsey model with agents that differ in their rate of time preferences. In this

framework, the most patient agent ends up holding all the capital in the long-run, although the

presence of progressive taxation or capital market imperfections can prevent a degenerate

distribution of wealth; see Becker (1980), Becker and Foias (1987), Sorger (2002).

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the economy and derives the

macroeconomic equilibrium. Section 3 characterizes the distributions of wealth and income and

3 See, for example, Rebelo (1999) and Turnovsky (2000).

Page 6: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

5

derives the main results of the paper. Comparative statics are established in section 4, and these are

then illustrated by a number of numerical examples. Section 6 concludes.

2. The Analytical framework

We begin by setting out the components of the model.

2.1 Technology and factor payments

We assume that there are a fixed number of firms, M say, indexed by j. Each representative

firm produces output using a standard neoclassical production function4

( ),j j jY F K L= (1a)

where jK and L j denote the individual firm’s capital stock, and employment of labor, respectively.

All firms face identical production conditions. Hence they all choose the same level of employment and capital stock. That is, K j = K , L j = L , and jY Y= for all j, where L , K, and Y denote the

corresponding economy-wide average quantities, per population. The economy-wide average

production function is therefore

( ),Y F K L= (1b)

The wage rate, w, and the return to capital, r, are determined by their respective marginal

physical products,

( , ) ( , )jL

j

Y Yw F K L w K LL L∂ ∂

= = = ≡∂ ∂

(2a)

( , ) ( , )jK

j

Y Yr F K L r K LK K∂ ∂

= = = ≡∂ ∂

(2b)

where 0; 0; 0; 0K KL L LL K KK L KLw F w F r F r F= > = < = < = > .5

4 That is both factors of production have positive, but diminishing, marginal physical products and the production function exhibits constant returns to scale (linear homogeneity). 5 The signs 0, 0LL KKF F< < are a consequence of diminishing marginal product, while 0KLF > is a consequence of the assumption of linear homogeneity, an implication of which is K LrK wL F K F L Y+ = + = .

Page 7: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

6

2.2 Consumers

At time 0, the economy is populated by 0N individuals, represented as a continuum, each

indexed by i and identical in all respects except for their initial endowments of capital, ,0iK . Each

individual defines a “family.” Population grows uniformly across all families at the exponential rate,

n, so that family i at time t has grown to nte and the total population of the economy has grown to

0( ) ntN t N e≡ . Each member of a given family has the same capital stock, although the distribution

of capital differs across families. From a distributional perspective we are interested in the share of

family i’s capital stock of the total capital stock in the economy. To this end we identify the

following quantities:

(i) Individual i holds ( )iK t units of capital at time t, so that the amount held by family i

is ( ) ntiK t e . This depends upon the capital of each representative member of the family plus the fact

that the size of the family is growing exponentially over time.

(ii) The total amount of capital in the economy at time t is the total capital stock owned by

the 0N families and can be expressed as

0

0( ) ( )

NT ntiK t K t e di= ∫

(iii) Total amount of capital per family is

0

00 0

( ) 1 ( )T N nt

iK t K t e di

N N= ∫

(iv) Average stock of capital per capita is thus

0 0

0 00 0

( ) 1 1( ) ( ) ( )T N Nnt

i int

K tK t K t e di K t diN N e N

≡ = =∫ ∫

which is also the average among the families.

Since the economy is growing we need to be careful in defining the distribution of the capital

stock. We shall define the share of capital owned by family i as

Page 8: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

7

0 0

00 0

0 0

( ) ( ) ( ) ( )( ) 1 1( ) ( )( ) ( )

nt nti i i i

i T N Nnti i

K t e K t e K t K tk tK t N K tK t e di K t di

N N

≡ = = =

∫ ∫

With all agents in the different families growing at the same rate, we can express the distribution in

terms of relative family shares, )(tki . Note that relative capital has mean 1. We denote its initial

distribution function by )(0 kH , the initial density function by )(0 kh , and the initial (given) standard

deviation of relative capital by ,0kσ .

We now focus on a particular agent. Each such agent is endowed with a unit of time that can

be allocated either to leisure, li or to work, 1− li ≡ Li . The agent maximizes lifetime utility, assumed

to be a function of both consumption and the amount of leisure time, in accordance with the

isoelastic utility function

( )0

1max ( ) , with 1, 0, 1 ti iC t l e dt

γη β γ η γηγ

∞ − −∞ < < > <∫ (3)

where 1 (1 )γ− equals the intertemporal elasticity of substitution.6 The preponderance of empirical

evidence suggests that this is relatively small, certainly well below unity, so that we shall restrict

γ < 0.7 The parameter η represents the elasticity of leisure in utility. This maximization is subject

to the agent’s capital accumulation constraint

)())(1)(()())(()( tCtltwtKntrtK iiii −−+−= (4)

and yields the corresponding first-order conditions 8

1i i iC lγ ηγ λ− = (5a)

1i i iC l wγ ηγη λ− = (5b)

i

inrλλβ −=− (5c)

6 This utility function is homogeneous of degree (1 )γ η+ in iC and il . The utility function in general employed by

Sorger (2000) is of the form 1 1/( 1) (1 1/ ) lni ic lθ θ β− − − + , which is non-homogeneous. 7 See e.g. the discussion of the empirical evidence summarized and reconciled by Guvenen (forthcoming). 8 Time dependence of variables will be omitted whenever it causes no confusion.

Page 9: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

8

where iλ is agent i’s shadow value of capital, together with the transversality condition

lim 0ti itK e βλ −

→∞= (5d)

These optimality conditions are standard and require no further comment. Taken together with the

individual’s accumulation equation and the corresponding conditions for the aggregate economy we

can derive the macroeconomic equilibrium and the dynamics of the aggregate economy. Having

determined these, we shall then obtain the dynamics of the distribution of capital and income.

2.3. Derivation of the macroeconomic equilibrium

In general, we shall define economy-wide aggregates (averages) as

0

00

1( ) ( )N

iZ t Z t diN

= ∫

Summing over firms and households, equilibrium in the capital and labor markets is described by9

0 0

0 00 0

1 1 1( ) ( )N Nnt

j i intjK K K t e di K t di

M N e N= = =∑ ∫ ∫ (6a)

0 0

0 00 0

1 1 11 (1 ) (1 )N Nnt

j i intjL L l l e di l di

M N e N= = − = − = −∑ ∫ ∫ (6b)

Equation (6b) gives the relationship between aggregate leisure and the aggregate labor supply. Note

that in equations (2) we have defined the wage and the interest rate, w, r, and expressed them as

functions of average employment, L . From (6b), we can equally well write them as functions of

aggregate leisure time, (1− l), namely, ( , )w w K l= and ( , )r r K l= .

In order to obtain the macroeconomic equilibrium we begin by dividing (5b) by (5a) to yield

( , )i

i

C w K ll

η = (7)

and using this expression we may write the individual’s accumulation equation, (4), in the form

9 As a small technical point we assume that the number of firms is represented by discrete units, while households are represented by a continuum.

Page 10: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

9

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ +−+−=

ηη11),(),( i

ii

i lK

lKwnlKrKK (8)

Taking the time derivative of (5a) and combining with (5c) implies

( 1) ( , )i i i

i i i

C l n r K lC l

λγ ηγ βλ

− + = = + − for each i (9)

This is the Euler equation modified to take into account the fact that leisure changes over time. The

important point about (9) is that each agent, irrespective of capital endowment, chooses the same

growth rate for the shadow value of capital. We can then show (see Appendix) that

; i k i k

i k i k

C C l lC C l l

= = for all i, k (10)

That is, all agents will choose the same growth rate for consumption and leisure.

Now turn to the aggregates. Summing (7) over all agents and noting that

0 0

0 00 0

( )1 1( ) 1( )

N N ii

K tk t di diN N K t

= =∫ ∫ , 0

00

1 N

il di lN

=∫ (11)

the aggregate economy-wide consumption-capital ratio is

),( lKwlC=η (7’)

while summing over (8) yields the aggregate accumulation equation

⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛ +−+−=

ηη11),(),( l

KlKwnlKr

KK (8’)

In addition, (10) implies that average consumption, C, and leisure, l, also grow at their respective

common individual growth rates, namely

; i i

i i

C lC lC C l l

= = for all i (10’)

2.4. Aggregate equilibrium dynamics

We can now derive the dynamics of aggregate capital and leisure, ( )K t and ( )l t as follows.

Page 11: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

10

First, substituting for the equilibrium rate of return on capital, ( , )r K l , and the wage rate, ( , )w K l ,

into (8’) and recalling the linear homogeneity of the production function, yields the aggregate goods

market clearing condition

( , )( , ) LF K L lK F K L nKη

= − − (12a)

Second, substituting (10’) into (9) and taking the time derivative of (7’) to substitute for CC / ,

yields the aggregate modified Euler equation

( , ) ( , )( 1) 1 ( 1) ( , )( , ) ( , )

l Kw K l l w K l Kl K n r K lw K l l w K l K

γ ηγ γ β⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞

− + + + − = + −⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

Finally, substituting (12a) into this equation, and recalling the expressions Lw etc. implies

( , ) ( , )( , ) (1 ) ( , )( , )

( )

KL LK

L

F K L F K L lF K L n F K L nKF K Ll

G l

β γη

⎡ ⎤− − − − − −⎢ ⎥

⎣ ⎦= (12b)

where

L

LL

FF

llG )1()1(1)( γηγ −

−+−

≡ (12c)

Equations (12a) and (12b) are autonomous equilibrium dynamic equations in the economy-

wide average quantities of capital and leisure (or employment). Assuming that the economy is

stable, these aggregate quantities converge to a steady state characterized by a constant average per

capita capital stock, labor supply, and leisure time, which we denote by K~ , L~ and l~ , respectively.

Setting 0K l= = in (12a) and (12b), we can then express the steady state as

nLKFK += β)~,~( (13a)

( , )( , ) LF K L lF K L nKη

− = (13b)

1L l+ = (13c)

Page 12: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

11

where the first two equations come from (12a) and (12b), and the third is simply the labor market

clearing condition. These equilibrium relationships are standard. Equation (13a) is the modified

golden rule, equating the marginal product of capital to the discount rate, adjusted for population

growth. The second is simply a reformulation of the first-order condition (7’) equating the marginal

rate of substitution of consumption and leisure to the price of leisure (the real wage), where the left-

hand side captures the fact that in steady state consumption is equal to output minus the amount

needed to keep per capita capital constant with a growing population.

Using (13a) and (13b), while recalling the homogeneity of the production function, we

immediately infer that:10

1

l ηη

>+

(14)

This inequality yields a lower bound on the steady-state time allocation to leisure that is consistent

with a feasible equilibrium. As we will see below, this condition plays a critical role in

characterizing the dynamics of distribution.

Linearizing equations (12a) - ( 12b) around steady state yields the local dynamics

11 12

21 22

K Ka aKa al l l

⎛ ⎞−⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞= ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟−⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠

(15)

where 21122211 ,,, aaaa are defined in the Appendix. There we show that 021122211 <− aaaa ,

implying that the steady state is a saddle point. The stable path for K and l can be expressed as

0( ) ( ) tK t K K K eµ= + − (16a)

( ) ( )KtKa

alKtKa

altl ~)(~~)(~)(12

11

22

21 −−

+=−−

+=µ

µ (16b)

where 0µ < is the stable eigenvalue. From the sign pattern established in the Appendix,

22( ) 0a µ− > , implying that the slope of stable arm depends inversely upon the sign of 21a . The sign

of this expression reflects two offsetting influences of the capital stock on the evolution of leisure. 10 We can combine (13a) and (13b) to yield: ( )( )(1 )LF K lη η η β+ − =

Page 13: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

12

On the one hand, an increase in capital lowers the return to capital and hence the return to

consumption, thereby reducing the growth rate of consumption and reducing the desire to increase

leisure. At the same time, a higher capital stock reduces its growth rate, and the growth rate of the

wage rate, thus reducing the growth of labor and increasing that of leisure. As we show in the

Appendix, which effect dominates depends upon the underlying parameters, and in particular upon

the elasticity of substitution in production. There we demonstrate that for plausible cases [including

the conventional case of Cobb-Douglas production and logarithmic utility ( 0,1 == γε )] 21 0a < , in

which case the stable locus is positively sloped; accumulating capital is therefore associated with

increasing leisure. However, if ε is sufficiently small, 21 0a > and the relationship between capital

and leisure implied by (16b) becomes negative11

As we will see below, the evolution of aggregate leisure over time is an essential determinant

of the time path of wealth and income inequality. For expositional convenience we shall restrict

ourselves to what we view as the more plausible case of a positive sloped stable locus, (16b). Since

this relationship holds at all times, we have

( ) ( )21 110 0

22 12

(0) a al l K K K Ka a

µµ

−− = − = −

− (16b’)

Thus consider a situation in which the economy is subject to a structural shock that results in an

increase in the steady-state average per capita capital stock relative to its initial level ( KK ~0 < ). The

shock will lead to an initial jump in average leisure, such that (0)l l< , so that, thereafter, leisure will

increase monotonically during the transition; an analogous relationship applies if 0K K> .

3. The distribution of income and wealth

3.1. The dynamics of the relative capital stock

To derive the dynamics of individual i’s relative capital stock, ( ) ( ) ( )i ik t K t K t≡ , we

combine (8’) and (8) to obtain

11 See (A.7) of the Appendix.

Page 14: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

13

( , )( ) 1 1ii i i

lw K l lk t l l kK η η

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞= − − − − −⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦ (17)

where ,K l evolve in accordance with (16a, b) and the initial relative capital ,0ik is given from the

initial endowment. Since i il l l l= we may write

i il lθ= where 0

00

1 1N

idiN

θ =∫

and iθ is constant for each i, and yet to be determined. Thus, we may write (17) as

( , ) 1 1( ) 1 1 1 1i i iw K lk t l l k

η η⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞

= − + − − +⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

(18)

To solve for the time path of the relative capital stock, we first note that agent i’s steady-state

share of capital satisfies

1 11 1 1 1 0i il l kθη η

⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞− + − − + =⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠ for each i (19)

or, equivalently

( 1)1i il l l kη

η⎛ ⎞

− = − −⎜ ⎟+⎝ ⎠ for each i (19’)

Recalling (14), this equation implies that the higher an agent’s steady-state relative capital stock

(wealth) increases, the more leisure he chooses and the less labor he supplies. This relationship is a

critical determinant of the distributions of wealth and income and explains why the evolution of the

aggregate quantities such as K and l are unaffected by distributional aspects. There are two key

factors contributing to this: (i) the linearity of the agent’s labor supply as a function of his relative

capital, and (ii) the fact that the sensitivity of labor supply to relative capital is common to all agents,

and depends upon the aggregate economy-wide leisure. As a consequence, aggregate labor supply is

independent of the distribution of capital. It is important to note here that this result holds for any

utility function that is homogenous of degree b in consumption and leisure, and in the Appendix we

show that this is indeed the case.

Page 15: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

14

To analyze the evolution of the relative capital stock, we linearize equation (18) around the

steady-state , , iK l k , in (19). This yields

( )( , ) 1 1( ) 1 ( )( ( ) ) 1 1 ( )i i i i iw K lk t k l t l l k t k

η η

⎡ ⎤⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞= + − − + + − −⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟

⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦⎣ ⎦ (20)

In the Appendix we show that the stable solution to this equation is

( ) 1 ( )( 1)i ik t t kδ− = − (21)

where

( , )1 ( )( ) 1 1LF K L l ttK l

δβ µ

⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞≡ + −⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟− ⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠, (22)

Setting 0t = in (21) and (22), we have

,0( , )1 (0)1 (0)( 1) 1 1 ( 1)L

i i iF K L lk k k

K lδ

β µ⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞− = − = + − −⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟− ⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠

(23)

where ,0ik is given from the initial distribution of capital endowments.

The evolution of agent i’s relative capital stock is determined as follows. First, given the

time path of the aggregate economy, and the distribution of initial capital endowments, (23)

determines the steady-state distribution of capital, ( 1)ik − , which together with (21) then yields the

entire time path for the distribution of capital. Using (21) – (23), and equations (16), describing the

evolution of the aggregate economy, we can express the time path for ( )ik t in the form

)~()~(~)0(

~)()~(1)0(1)(~)( 0,0,0, ii

tiiiiii kkekk

llltlkktktk −=−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

−−

=−⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−−

=− µ

δδ (24)

from which we see that ( )ik t also converges to its steady state value at the rate µ .

We can also determine the time path for the individual’s leisure (labor supply). First, having

determined ( 1)ik − , (19’) yields agent i’s steady-state leisure allocation, il , which, knowing the

economy-wide average, l , determines his constant relative leisure time iθ , namely

Page 16: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

15

,01 1 11 1 ( 1) 1 ( 1)

1 (0) 1i i ik kl l

η ηθη δ η

⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞− = − − = − −⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟+ +⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠

(25)

Thus, knowing the time path for the aggregate leisure allocation, ( )l t , the time path for ( ) ( )i il t l tθ≡

immediately follows. We see from (25), in conjunction with (14), that any agent whose steady-state

capital stock exceeds the economy-wide average will enjoy above average leisure time throughout

the transition.

Because of the linearity of (21), (23), and (24), we can immediately transform these

equations into corresponding results for the standard deviation of the distribution of capital, which

serves as a convenient measure of wealth inequality. Specifically, corresponding to these three

equations we obtain

( ) ( )k kt tσ δ σ= (21’)

,0 (0)k kσ δ σ= (23’)

,0 ,0 ,0( ) 1 ( ) 1( ) ( ) ( ) ( )(0) 1 (0) 1

tk k k k k k k k

t l tt el

µδσ σ σ σ σ σ σ σδ⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞− −

− = − = − = −⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟− −⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠ (24’)

The critical factors upon which we wish to focus are: (i) how agent i’s relative wealth

evolves over time and (ii) the consequences of this for the distribution of wealth. A critical

determinant of this is the magnitude of ( )tδ . From (22) this is seen to depend upon ( )l t l , which in

turn depends upon how the underlying shock affects the evolution of the aggregate capital stock,

( ( ) )K t K− . From (14), (16), and (22) we can deduce the following, where we restrict our focus to

what we have identified as the “normal” case of a positive adjustment between aggregate leisure and

capital; see (16b).

(i) If 0K K> then ( ) 1tδ > , for all t

(ii) If 0K K< , then ( ) 1tδ < . As long 0 2K K> , so that the decline in the capital

stock is less than 50%, we can show that ( ) 0tδ > , implying that 0 ( ) 1tδ< < ,

for all t.12

12 This is established in the Appendix.

Page 17: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

16

(iii) ( )0sgn ( ) sgnt K Kδ⎡ ⎤ = −⎣ ⎦

We can then state:

Proposition 1 (The long-run distribution of wealth): The allocation of wealth

converges to a long-run distribution in which (i) all agents hold positive amounts of

wealth, (ii) wealth is unequally distributed, (iii) the ranking of agents according to

wealth is the same as in the initial distribution.

Having established the existence of a long-run distribution of wealth, we can compare it to

the initial distribution. For the moment it is convenient to measure distribution by the standard

deviation of the capital stock (wealth), although in Section 3.4 below we express this in terms of more conventional Gini coefficients. From equations (21’) and (23’) we see that ,0( )k ktσ σ> if and

only if (0) ( )tδ δ< , i.e. if and only if )0()( ltl < and that ,0k kσ σ> if and only if (0) 1δ < . Together

with (16b’) and since leisure is monotonically increasing or decreasing along the transition path, this

implies the following

Proposition 2 (Wealth dynamics): The initial condition 0K affects the long-run

distribution of wealth. If the economy starts below (above) the steady state, i.e. 0K <

K~ ( 0K > K~ ), then wealth inequality will decrease (increase) during the transition,

and the long-run distribution of wealth will be less (more) unequal than is the initial

distribution.

The intuition for this result can be easily obtained by noting, from equation (A.10) in the

Appendix, that

( )( ),0sgn( ) sgn 1 (0)i i ik k k l l− = − −

Recall that if the economy converges to the steady state from below, then (0)l l< . Then for people

who end up above the mean level of wealth, their wealth will have decreased during the transition

,0i ik k> , while for people who end up below the mean level of wealth, their wealth will have

decreased, ,0i ik k> , implying a narrowing of the wealth distribution.

Page 18: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

17

To understand why the evolution of inequality depends on the initial condition consider two

individuals having different capital endowments. Homothetic preferences imply that they both

spend the same share of total wealth at each point in time and have the same rate of growth of total

wealth. Total wealth has two components, physical capital and the present value of all future labor

income. Since wages are growing at the same rate for both agents but represent a higher share of

total wealth for the poorer individual, then his capital must be changing more rapidly than that of the

wealthier agent. When the economy is accumulating capital, this means that his capital stock is

growing faster and inequality is diminishing. When the economy is converging from above, i.e.

when the stock of capital is falling, he will disave faster and inequality will increase.

This result contrasts with the evolution of the distribution of wealth in the Ramsey model

with inleastic labor supply. In this case, if the elasticity of substitution is greater or equal to one, i.e.

1≥ε , the distribution of wealth will become more equal during the transition from below.

However, for 1<ε , the distribution could widen. 13 The reason for this is that a low elasticity of

substitution implies fast wage growth as the economy accumulates capital. Consumers calculate

their total wealth and choose a constant consumption-to-total-wealth ratio. If wages are growing

slowly, poor consumers will need a high rate of capital accumulation to sustain their consumption

path. However, if wages are growing fast, a lower rate of capital accumulation is optimal. With

sufficiently high wage growth, poor consumers may choose to disave early in their life-times and

finance current consumption with their (high) future wages. As a result, the distribution of capital

becomes more unequal. With endogenous leisure, this effect is offset by labor supply responses.

Higher future wages have two effects, as they tend to increase both current consumption and future

leisure. The desire to increase leisure in the future prevents the reduction in the rate of capital

accumulation of capital-poor agents, and hence the wealth diverge, that occurs when individuals

cannot change work-hours. As a result, there is an unambiguous narrowing of the wealth distribution

during the transition from below.

Proposition 2 has a number of implications for the distribution of wealth that can be

summarized as follows:

13 See Caselli and Ventura (2000).

Page 19: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

18

Corollary 2:

(i) Consider two economies identical in all respects except for their initial capital

stock. They will have the same steady state macroeconomic equilibrium, but the

poorer country (the one with the lower initial 0K ) will have a more equal long-run

wealth distribution.

(ii) Temporary shocks to the stock of capital have long-run effects on the

distribution of wealth, with any temporary reduction in the stock of capital resulting

in a permanent reduction in wealth inequality.

(iii) Suppose an economy is subject to a policy shock or structural change that

generates a long-run increase in the capital stock, so that (0)l l< . Then in the long

run, the wealth distribution of that economy will be narrower.

3.2. Income Distribution

We turn now to the distribution of income. We define the income of individual i at time t as

))(1)(()()()( tltwtKtrtY iii −+= , average economy-wide income as ))(1)(()()()( tltwtKtrtY −+= ,

and we are interested in the evolution of relative income, defined as )(/)()( tYtYty ii ≡ . Letting

YKFts K /)( ≡ denote the share of output going to capital, and recalling that i il lθ= , relative income

may be expressed as

( )( ) 1 ( )( ( ) 1) (1 ( )) (1 )1 ( )i i i

l ty t s t k t s tl t

θ− = − + − −−

(26)

The relative income of agent i has two components, relative capital income, captured by the first

term in (26) and relative labor income, reflected in the second term. The capital share determines

the relative contribution of capital and labor to overall income, for given individual endowments.

Using equation (19) to substitute for iθ and (21), we may write (26) in the form

( ) 1 1( ) 1 ( ) (1 ( )) 1 ( ( ) 1)1 ( ) 1 ( )i i

l ty t s t s t k tl t tl

ηη δ

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞− = − − − −⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟− +⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

, (27)

which we can express more compactly as

Page 20: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

19

)1)()((1)( −=− tktty ii ϕ , (28)

where

( ) 1 1( ) 1 (1 ( )) 1 11 ( ) 1 ( )

l tt s tl t tl

ηϕη δ

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞≡ − − + −⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟− +⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

. (29)

Again, because of the linearity of (28) in )1)(( −tki we can express the relationship between relative

income and relative capital in terms of corresponding standard deviations of their respective

distributions, namely

( ) ( ) ( )y kt t tσ ϕ σ= (28’)

From inequality (14) the term in square brackets in equation (29) is positive and hence 1)( <tϕ ,

implying that income is more equally distributed than is capital.

Letting t →∞ , we can express the steady-state distribution of income as

y kσ ϕσ= (28”)

where

( , )1 1 1lim ( ) 1 11 1 ( , )1

L

t

F K LstF K Ll

ϕ ϕη η→∞

−⎛ ⎞= = − = −⎜ ⎟+ +−⎝ ⎠

In the Appendix we use the steady-state equilibrium conditions (13) in conjunction with (14)

to show that ϕ lies in the bounds

n s sn

ϕβ

⎛ ⎞< <⎜ ⎟+⎝ ⎠

(30)

implying in particular that the steady-state distribution of income is less unequal than that of capital.

From (28) we can compare the long-run distribution of income to the initial one, namely

( )( )( )( ),0 0 ,0 ,00 0 0 0

1 1 (1 ( ) ( )

1 1 (1 ( ) ( )Ly k k

y k kL

F K L F K L

F K L F K L

ησ σ σϕσ ϕ σ ση

⎛ ⎞− +⎜ ⎟= =⎜ ⎟− +⎝ ⎠

(31)

Page 21: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

20

where the subscript 0 identifies the initial distribution, from which we infer that in general ( ) ( ),0sgn 1 sgn 1i iy y− = − .

We may summarize these results in:

Proposition 3 (The long-run distribution of income): The distribution of income

converges to a long-run distribution such that:

(i) income is unequally distributed, and the relative ranking of agents according

to income is the same as that of capital, as well as that of the initial income

distribution.

(ii) The ratio of the standard deviation of the distribution of income to that of

capital is less than the share of capital in output.

Whether the long-run distribution, following a structural chang, is more or less unequal than

the initial distribution depends on the long-run change in the distribution of capital, as reflected in

,0k kσ σ and factor returns, as reflected in 0ϕ ϕ . As we will illustrate in Section 5 below, any shock

leads to an initial jump in the distribution of income, after which it evolves continuously, in response

to the evolution of the distribution of capital and factor returns. These dynamics can be seen most

conveniently by considering the time derivative of equation (26), namely

( )

( )2

( ) ( ) 1 ( ) ( ) ( )( ) (1 ( )) ( ) 1 11 ( )1 ( )

i i ii i

dy t dk t dl t l t ds ts t s t k tdt dt dt l t dtl t

θ θ⎛ ⎞−

= + − + − + −⎜ ⎟−− ⎝ ⎠ (32)

This equation indicates how the evolution of the relative income of agent i depends upon two

factors, the evolution of relative capital income, reflected in the first term in (32), and that of relative

labor income. The latter can be expressed as a function of the evolution of aggregate leisure, and of

the relative rewards to capital and labor, as reflected by the capital share, s(t).

It is useful to start by examining what happens for a Cobb-Douglas production function. In

this case the capital share remains constant, and whether income inequality increases or decreases

depends on whether the economy converges to the steady state from below or from above. Consider

an economy that starts below the steady state, so that KK ~0 < . Then (0)l l< and leisure is rising,

Page 22: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

21

/ 0dl dt > , while wealth inequality is decreasing. Consider an agent with above average wealth,

0)1( >−ik , then / 0idk dt < and ( 1) 0iθ − > , implying that the first two terms in (32) are negative

and that the relative income of the agent is decreasing during the transition. The opposite would be

true for an agent with wealth below average, 0)1( <−ik , and hence income inequality will decline

during the transition to the steady state from below. For an economy that starts above the steady

state, i.e. for KK ~0 > , then (0)l l> , and together with the fact that wealth inequality is increasing

(see proposition 2) income inequality will be rising during the transition.

The evolution of factor shares may reinforce or offset these effects. For an economy that

converges from below, a falling capital share, / 0ds dt < , would reinforce the impact of the

distribution of wealth and income inequality will decline over time. If the capital share rises over

time, / 0ds dt > , and this effect will be offsetting. If this latter effect dominates, the distribution of

income would become less equal over time. Moreover, at different stages one or the other effect may

dominate, implying episodes of rising or falling inequality.

Proposition 4 (Income dynamics): Consider an economy that converges to its steady

state from below, i.e. 0K < K~ . Then:

(i) if the share of capital in income is constant or decreases during the transition,

income inequality will decrease during the transition to the steady state,

(ii) if the share of capital in income increases during the transition, then the long-run

distribution of income may be more or less unequal than the initial one, and the

economy may experience episodes of increasing and episodes of decreasing

income inequality.

Consider an economy that converges to its steady state from above, i.e. 0K > K~ . Then:

(iii) if the share of capital in income is constant or increases during the transition,

income inequality will increase during the transition to the steady state,

(iv) if the share of capital in income decreases during the transition, then the long-run

distribution of income may be more or less unequal than the initial one, and the

economy may experience episodes of increasing and episodes of decreasing

income inequality.

Page 23: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

22

3.3 Relative consumption

Finally, we examine the distribution of consumption. From the individual’s first order

conditions we have i iC wl η= , which implies that relative consumption is given by

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( )i i i ic t C t C t l t l t θ≡ = = , that is

1 1 1( ) 1 11 1 (0)c k kt

l lη ησ σ ση η δ

⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞= − = −⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟+ +⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠

(33)

The distribution of consumption is then constant over time, and depends on the initial distribution of

capital, together with the parameters that impact on the leisure decision. It is straightforward to establish that c yσ σ< , so that consumption is more equally distributed than both steady-state income

and capital. The reason for this is that wealthier individuals choose to have both a higher level of

consumption and a higher level of leisure, so that only part of the difference in capital translates into

differences in consumption.

3.4 Gini Coefficients

The conventional measures of inequality are given by Gini coefficients and in this section we

briefly consider the Gini coefficients for wealth and income. Recall that )(0 kH denotes the initial

distribution function of relative capital. Then, the Gini coefficient of the initial distribution of wealth

is (see Cowell, 2000):

∫ ∫ −=k k

jijik kdHkdHkkG0 0

00000, )( )(21

Then at time t we have

∫ ∫ −=)(

)(

)(

)(

)( )()()(21)(

tk

tk

tk

tkjtitjik kdHkdHtktktG (34)

where )( it kH is the distribution function of relative capital at t, and )(tk and )(tk its upper and

lower bounds. Writing the first equation in (24) in the form

Page 24: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

23

0( ) ( )( ) 1(0) (0)i it tk t kδ δ

δ δ= + − ,

we can transform (34) to get

0 0 0 0 ,00 0

1 ( ) ( )( ) ( ) ( )2 (0) (0)

k k

k i j i j kt tG t k k dH k dH k Gδ δ

δ δ= − =∫ ∫ (34’)

Similarly, using the relationship (28), the Gini coefficient form income can be expressed as

,0( )( ) ( ) ( ) ( )(0)y k ktG t t G t t Gδϕ ϕ

δ= = (35)

The main point to observe is that both Gini cofficients evolve exactly as does the relative capital

stock, so that comparing the standard deviations of the relative capital stock and income, as we have

been doing, carries over to the Gini coefficients

4. Long-run adjustments of wealth and income inequality

To illustrate the dynamic adjustments of wealth and income distribution we analyze two

shocks that are of interest: (i) an increase in productivity, (ii) a decrease in the population growth

rate. In this section we derive the formal expressions for the steady-state responses, and will

simulate the dynamic adjustments in the next section.

We begin by recalling the steady state conditions for the aggregate economy, (13a) – (13c).

Because of the homogeneity of the production function it is convenient to work in terms of intensive

quantities, i.e.

( , ) ( )Y AF K L ALf z= =

where z K L≡ is the average stock of capital per man-hour and A denotes the level of

productivity.14 Using this notation, we can rewrite steady state conditions in intensive form

( )Af z nβ′ = + (13a’)

14 That is, Tz K L K NL≡ = and shall be referred to as the average capital-employment ratio.

Page 25: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

24

[ ] [ ] (1 )( ) ( ) ( ) LL Af z nz A f z zf zη−′− = − (13b’)

1L l+ = (13c)

Since the distributions of wealth and income depend upon the aggregate economy, we first derive the

steady-state responses as follows:

4.1 Aggregate and distributional effects of increase in productivity, A

From (13a’), (13b’) and (13c) we can derive the following expressions for the aggregate

steady-state effects of an increase in productivity

(i) 0~~~

>′′′

−=A

dAfzf

zzd (36a)

(ii) A

dAs

LLLd )1(~1

)1(~1~~

εη−

−+−

= (36b)

and hence

(iii) A

dAL

Ls

Lzzd

LLd

KKd

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

+−+

+−+−

=+=)1(~1

)1(~1~1

)1(~1~~

~~

~~

ηεηη (36c)

(iv) [ ]( )( ) A

dAnzAfs

nsLzs

LKKds

LLds

AdA

YYd

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡−−−+

+−+−

+=+−+= ~1)~1(~

~1)1(~11~

~~~

~)~1(~

~ βεη (36d)

where ε denotes the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor in production, s . An

increase in productivity raises the steady-state capital-employment ratio, while its effect on steady-

state labor supply depends upon the elasticity of substitution, ε , raising labor supply if 1<ε and

reducing it if 1>ε . Irrespective of the response of labor supply, an increase in productivity will

raise both the average per capita capital stock, K , as well as output, Y .

To consider the consequences of this for the long-run wealth distribution we recall

Proposition 2. Since an increase in productivity raises the long-run capital stock (wealth) it leads to

a decrease in the long-run inequality of wealth. To see what this implies for long-run income

inequality recall (31), namely

Page 26: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

25

( )( )( )( ),0 0 ,0 ,00 0 0 0

1 1 (1 ( ) ( )

1 1 (1 ( ) ( )Ly k k

y k kL

F K L F K L

F K L F K L

ησ σ σϕσ ϕ σ ση

⎛ ⎞− +⎜ ⎟= =⎜ ⎟− +⎝ ⎠

This breaks down the steady-state change in income inequality into: (i) effect due to the change in

wealth inequality (wealth effect), which we have just shown to be negative, and (ii) effect due to the

change in labor supply (labor supply effect). The latter depends upon what happens to:

( , ) 11( , ) 1

LF K LF K L

ϕη

⎛ ⎞≡ − ⎜ ⎟+⎝ ⎠

Differentiating this with respect to A we obtain15

[ ][ ]znAfLA

nsLzdAd

~)1(~)~1(~~

)1(~

−+−+

−=η

βεϕ (37)

so that

)1sgn(~

sgn −=⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ εϕ

dAd

Thus we can derive the following proposition:

Proposition 5: (i) An increase in productivity leads to a reduction in long-run wealth

inequality.

(ii) This will lead to a larger, equal, or smaller decline in long-run income inequality

according to whether the elasticity of substitution is smaller than, equal to, or larger

than, unity. For a sufficiently large elasticity of substitution long-run income

inequality may actually increase.

(iii) If the elasticity of substitution is less than one the decline in income inequality

will be associated with a higher per capita level of income. If ε is sufficiently large,

a higher per capita level of income may be associated with greater income inequality.

15 The derivations of a number of these expressions, such as , d dA d dnϕ ϕ involves a lot of detail, making extensive use of equilibrium conditions. They can be expressed in a number of equivalent ways, and we have chosen what we view as the most convenient form. Since these calculations do not have any intrinsic interest, we do not report them, but they are available from the authors on request.

Page 27: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

26

4.2 Aggregate and distributional effects of decrease in population growth rate

As a second example we consider a decrease in the growth rate of population, yielding the

effects

(i) 1 0dz dnz Af z= <

′′ (38a)

(ii) ( )dnsDL

Ld ~~~

−= εεβ (38b)

(iii) dK dL dzK L z

= + 0~)1(~

)1(~<⎥

⎤⎢⎣

⎡+

−++

−= dnslL

D ηηεη

εβ (38c)

(iv) YYd~~

dnl

ssD ⎥

⎤⎢⎣

−+−−=

ηηεε

εβ

)1(~~

)~( (38d)

where [ ])~1(

)~1('Lz

snzAfAfD−

−−≡ε

While a reduction in the growth rate of population raises the capital-employment ratio, its effect on

labor supply depends critically on the relative sizes of the elasticity of substitution and the share of

income going to capital. Despite the ambiguity of this response, the capital employment effect

dominates and thus the reduction in population growth rate increases the steady state stock of capital,

K , and hence reduces the inequality of wealth. The net effect on per capita income depends upon

the relative sizes of ε and s. Differentiating ϕ with respect to n yields

[ ]( ) ( ) ⎭

⎬⎫

⎩⎨⎧

−′−−

+−′

+−+′−+

=nzAff

fLsnzAff

LnsffKfLA

zdnd )~1)(~1()~)(~1(~)1(

)1(~~~ ββε

ηϕ (39)

implying that if 1≤ε , then 0d dnϕ > . Thus we can derive the following proposition:

Proposition 6: (i) A decrease in the population growth rate leads to a reduction in

long-run wealth inequality.

(ii) This will lead to a larger, equal, or smaller decline in long-run income inequality

depending on the elasticity of substitution. If 1≤ε this leads to a larger than

Page 28: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

27

proportionate decline in income inequality. For a sufficiently large elasticity of

substitution long-run income inequality may actually increase.

(iii) The decline in wealth inequality may be associated with either a rise or fall in

average per capita income.

5. Numerical Simulations

To obtain further insights into the dynamics of wealth and income distribution we simulate

the economy in response to these two shocks. The simulations are based on the following functional

forms and parameters, characterizing the benchmark economy.

Production function: 1( (1 ) )Y A K Lρ ρ ρα α− − −= + −

Utility function: ( )1U Clγη

γ=

Basic parameters: 1, 0.4A α= =

1/ 3, 0, 0.2 (elast of sub 0.75, 1, 1.25)ρ = − =

1.5, 0.015, 1.75nγ η= − = =

Preferences are specified by a constant elasticity utility function, with intertemporal elasticity

of substitution 1 (1 ) 0.4γ− = , while the elasticity of leisure in utility is 1.75. The production

function is of the CES form, where we allow the elasticity of substitution to assume the values 0.75,

1, and 1.25, while the distributional parameter is 0.4α = . Population grows at the rate of 1.5% per

annum, while 1A = scales the initial level of productivity. These parameter values are standard and

non-controversial.16

We assume that the economy is initially in a steady state in which aggregate fraction of time

devoted to leisure is 0l and the average stock of capital is 0K . We define the initial steady state

16 For example, the intertemporal elasticity of substitution 0.4 is well within the range of empirical estimates summarized by Guvenen (forthcoming), while the choice of 1.75η = is standard within the real business cycle literature; see Cooley (1995). Allowing the elasticity of substitution in production to vary between 0.75 and 1.25 covers the range of most of the empirical estimates, while 0.4α = implies that 40% of output goes to capital in a Cobb-Douglas world, also broadly consistent with empirical evidence.

Page 29: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

28

distributions of wealth (capital) and income (prior to any shock) by the quantities, ,0kσ , and

0 0,0 ,0

0 0

( , ) 11( , ) 1

Ly k

F K LF K L

σ ση

⎡ ⎤= −⎢ ⎥+⎣ ⎦

, respectively. Starting from this initial steady state, we shall be

concerned with investigating the time paths of the economy in response to two shocks:17

(i) An increase in the level of technology A from 1 to 1.5 (Fig. 1);

(ii) A decrease in the rate of population growth rate, n, from 1.5% to 0 (Fig. 2).

In the left hand panels of these figures we plot the time paths of the aggregate quantities,

capital, 0( ) /K t K , output, 0( )Y t Y , and labor supply, 0( )L t L , relative to their respective original

benchmark levels. Capital always evolves continuously in response to a given shock, while labor

supply and output will undergo endogenous jumps at the initial point. In the right hand panels, we

plot the time paths for the distribution of wealth and income, relative to their respective initial values, namely, ,0( )k ktσ σ and ,0( )y ytσ σ , where we further normalize ,0 1kσ = . The distribution of

capital evolves continuously, while the distribution of income jumps at time zero, due to a jump in A

and in L.18

Looking at Figures 1 and 2 two general features stand out. First, while the two shocks affect

the distribution of wealth in qualitatively comparable ways, there is a sharp contrast in their impacts

on the distribution of income. In particular, the time path for the distribution of income in response

to an increase in productivity is highly sensitive to relatively mild changes in the elasticity of

substitution in production. Second, there is a sharp contrast between the time path of wealth

distribution and that of income distribution, particularly in response to an increase in productivity;

sometimes they move together and sometimes in opposite directions, again depending upon the

flexibility of production.

5.1 Increase in A from 1 to 1.5

It is convenient to focus first on the case of the Cobb-Douglas production function, illustrated

by the middle pair of figures in Fig 1. As we showed in Section 5, for 1=ε , an increase in 17 For the Benchmark Cobb-Douglas economy 0.722l = , which is plausible and satisfies (14). 18 In effect we are graphing ( ) (0)tδ δ in the case of wealth and ( ) ( ) (0)t tϕ δ δ in the case of the distribution of income.

Page 30: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

29

productivity A will leave the long-run aggregate (average) employment unchanged, but will raise

aggregate capital. Steady-state aggregate output will therefore rise, in fact doing so in the same

proportion as the capital stock.19 In the short run, the capital stock remains unchanged. However,

the higher productivity of labor, and therefore the higher wage rate, will increase labor supply in the

short run, resulting in a corresponding decline in leisure. Output therefore rises by around 55%,

consisting of the 50% direct increase in productivity, plus the contribution of the additional labor

supply. Thereafter, as the aggregate stock of capital continues to be accumulated, the average

fraction of time devoted to leisure increases (slightly), in accordance with (16b), implying that the

average fraction of time devoted to labor declines correspondingly, converging back to its initial

value. While these two responses have opposing effects on the time path of output, the capital

accumulation effect clearly dominates and output continues to rise, although at a slower rate than

does capital.

The effect of the decline in the long-run capital stock is to cause the distribution of capital to

gradually become more equal over time. For this parameter set, wealth inequality as measured by

the standard deviation, decreases uniformly, declining by around 7%, asymptotically. Although the

long-run distribution of income declines by the same proportion [see Proposition 5], its transition is

very different. The short run decline in average leisure time [increase in labor supply] leads to an

increase in short-run income inequality. This can be seen most directly from equation (25). The

correctly anticipated decline in long-run wealth inequality, reduces (increases) the amount of leisure

time, iθ , chosen by people with above (below) average wealth. That is, wealthier people initially

increase their work time, while poorer people work less and income inequality increases. Over time,

as average leisure increases the relative income of agents having above-average wealth declines, for

reasons noted in Section 3.2 and income inequality declines over time, eventually catching up to the

decline in wealth inequality.

For a lower elasticity of substitution (ε =0.75), the behavior of the economy-wide aggregate

variables are qualitatively generally similar. The less flexible production function means that that

there is less long-run accumulation in the aggregate capital stock, while the higher productivity 19 For the Cobb-Douglas case we can show 1(1 )d Y Y dK K dA Aα −= = − , which in this case equals 83.3%.

Page 31: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

30

increases labor supply permanently, though still less so than on impact. The time path for the

distribution of wealth is relatively unaffected, but as shown in Proposition 5, for ε =0.75 in the long-

run, income inequality declines more than does wealth inequality. However, the decline in long-run

leisure, l , raises the sensitivity of iθ to the anticipated long-run decline in wealth inequality, so that

in the short-run wealthier people increase further the amount of their labor supply, while poorer

people decrease their labor supply correspondingly. As a result, the short-run income inequality

increases by 20%, rather than by 12% in the Cobb-Douglas case. Over time, income inequality

decreases more rapidly than does wealth inequality, with its decline overtaking that of the latter after

about 20 years.

The main difference in the case of the higher elasticity of substitution (ε =1.25) is that there

is now a long-run decline in labor supply. At the aggregate level this has the effect of reducing the

long-run proportionate increase in output to below that of capital, although the enhanced flexibility

leads to large proportionate increases in both. Again, the reduction in the long-run capital stock

implies a gradual decline in wealth inequality. In contrast, the fact that average labor supply

decreases rather than increases has profound effects on income distribution. In the short run, the

increase in l can offset the effect of the anticipated reduction in wealth inequality on the relative

labor supply, iθ , so that income inequality actually declines on impact. Over time, as average

leisure increases, this effect is offset and income inequality increases over time, to above its original

level, consistent with Proposition 5. Thus over time, income and wealth inequalities move in

opposite directions. One further point we see that income distribution exhibits some mild non-

montonicity during its transition. This can be understood by recalling (28’) and the fact that the

income distribution is responding to two offsetting factors; first the declining wealth inequality, and

second the relative employment effect, iθ , which in this case is moving in the opposite way.

Finally, Fig. 1 illustrates an interesting dynamic relationship between per capita income and

income inequality. For the two cases ε =0.75, ε =1, we see that on impact the increase in

productivity causes both per capita income and income inequality to increase together. However, as

the former continues to increase, while the latter declines, over the long run they move in opposite

directions. For a high elasticity of substitution the pattern is reversed. Per capita income and

Page 32: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

31

income inequality initially move in opposite directions, but over time move together as income

inequality gradually increases.

5.2 Decrease in the rate of population growth from 1.5% to 0

The effects of reducing the population growth rate from 1.5% to 0 are much less sensitive to

variations in the elasticity of substitution in production. The long-run ratio of capital to

employment, z , always increases, as does the average per capita stock of capital, while labor supply

declines as long as s~>ε , a restriction that holds in all three cases. In the short run, the decline in

labor supply means an initial mild decline in output, but over time this increases with the rising

capital stock. However, with the decline in labor supply, the eventual increase in output is always

less than that of the capital stock.

The long-run increase in the stock of capital, K , again implies that wealth inequality

declines gradually over time, consistent with Proposition 2. In this case the decline in labor supply

causes an initial decline in income inequality and the long run decline in ϕ means that income

inequality declines more than does wealth inequality. The reason for this is the behavior of factor

rewards. The increase in per capita capital and the reduction in time spent at work both tend to

reduce the return to capital and increase the wage. As a result, a greater share of income is devoted

to paying the factor that is more equally distributed, labor. This effect accentuates the impact of the

decline in wealth inequality, and hence the long-run income inequality declines by a greater amount.

Finally, in the short run, both income inequality and per capita income move together, both

declining, while over time as income and capital both rise, they eventually move in opposite

directions.

6. Concluding comments

In this paper we have studied the dynamics of the distributions of wealth and income in a

Ramsey model with endogenous labor supply. We have shown that when utility is homogenous in

consumption and leisure we can represent the macroeconomic equilibrium in terms of a simple

recursive structure. First the dynamics of the aggregate stock of capital and labor supply are jointly

Page 33: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

32

determined, independently of distribution. Then the cross-sections of individual income and wealth

and their dynamics are characterized as a function of the aggregate magnitudes. The aggregate

behavior of the model hence collapses to that of a representative-consumer setup, implying that

existing results of representative-agent growth models with the kind of preferences we have studied

are robust to the introduction of wealth heterogeneity.

A number of results emerge from our analysis of distributional dynamics. The first is the fact

that the accumulation of capital tends to reduce the degree of wealth inequality when no other

mechanisms, such as fixed costs or capital market imperfection, are present. Second, although

temporary shocks to the aggregate stock of capital have no long-run implications for the aggregate

output level, they have permanent effects on the distribution of income and wealth. We also show

that for high values of the elasticity of substitution wealth and income inequality need not move

together during the transition towards the steady states.

The comparative statics we establish provide two interesting results. Our analysis of the

effect of an increase in the level of productivity shows that a Hicks-neutral increase in productivity

would have an equalizing effect when wealth ownership is the source of distributional differences.

The second concerns the impact of a reduction in the rate of population growth, i.e of an aging

population. In this case, the reduction in the labor supply and the increase in the capital-labor ratio

reduce the relative reward to capital and increase that to labor, leading to a more equal distribution of

income.

Our analysis also highlights how sensitive existing results on distributional dynamics are to

the particular assumptions made on the form of the utility function and the technology. For example,

Sorger (2000) and Sorger and Ghiglino (2002) find that with endogenous labor but a non-

homogenous utility function, the distribution of wealth affects aggregate income dynamics and the

steady state output level. In García-Peñalosa and Turnovsky (2006a,b) we consider a model with the

same preference structure but a technological externality that results in an AK technology. In this

case, macroeconomic behavior is independent of distribution and the distribution of wealth (although

not that of income) is also unaffected by the aggregate stock of capital, implying that wealth

inequality remains constant over time. The first two papers hence imply the interdependence

Page 34: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

33

between aggregate magnitudes and distribution, while the last two describe an economy with

complete independence between the macroeconomic equilibrium and the distribution of wealth. In

this paper, we provide a framework where distribution is endogenous but yet tractable.

An important limitation of our approach is that we consider only one source of heterogeneity.

Unlike in Caselli and Ventura (2000) who have skill, taste, and wealth heterogeneity, this precludes

social mobility. The interplay between ability, labor supply, and wealth remains an important

question to be explored, especially in the light of recent evidence indicating that the increase in wage

inequality that started in the late 1970s has been accompanied by an increase in the difference

between the hours worked by high-wage and by low-wage individuals; see Gottschalk and Danziger

(2005).

Page 35: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

Fig 1: Increase in A from 1 to 1.5

Elast of Subs =1

Elast of Subs =0.75Aggregate quantities Distribution

Elast of Subs =1.25

capital income labor

20 40 60 80 100t

0.9

0.95

1.05

1.1

1.15

dist.

20 40 60 80 100t

1.2

1.4

1.6

1.8

2K,Y,L

20 40 60 80t

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

1.05

1.1

1.15

dist.

50 100 150 200 250 300t

0.5

1.5

2

2.5

3

3.5

4K,Y,L

20 40 60 80t

1.1

1.2

1.3

1.4

1.5

1.6

K,Y,L

50 100 150 200 250 300t

0.92

0.94

0.96

0.98

1.02

1.04

dist.

Page 36: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

Fig 2: Decrease in n from 0.015 to 0

Elast of Subs =1

Elast of Subs =0.75Aggregate quantities Distribution

Elast of Subs =1.25

capital income labor

20 40 60 80 100t

0.8

0.9

1.1

1.2

1.3

1.4

1.5K,Y,L

20 40 60 80 100t

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

dist.

20 40 60 80t

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

dist.

20 40 60 80t

1.1

1.2

1.3

K,Y,L

50 100 150 200 250 300t

0.65

0.7

0.75

0.8

0.85

0.9

0.95

dist.

50 100 150 200 250 300t

0.75

1.25

1.5

1.75

2

2.25

K,Y,L

Page 37: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

A1

Appendix

This Appendix is devoted to the derivation of several technical details

A.1 Derivation of the macroeconomic equilibrium

The first-order conditions (5a) - (5d) imply

( , )i

i

C w K ll

η = (A.1)

( 1) ( , )i i i

i i i

C l n r K lC l

λγ ηγ βλ

− + = = + − (A.2)

Taking the time derivative of (7) implies

( )( , )( , ) ( )

i i lK

i i

C l w l lw K l K K lC l w K l K w l l

− = + (A.3)

Now consider equations (9) and (A.3) for individuals i and k. We obtain

( 1) 0i k i k

i k i k

C C l lC C l l

γ ηγ⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞

− − + − =⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠

0i k i k

i k i k

C C l lC C l l

⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞− − − =⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠

from which we infer

; i k i k

i k i k

C C l lC C l l

= = for all i, k (A.4)

Now turn to the aggregates. Combining

0

0

0

0

( )( )( ) ( )

N

i

N

i

C t diC tC t C t di

= ∫∫

with (A.4) implies

Page 38: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

A2

; i i

i i

C lC lC C l l

= = for all i (A.5)

A.2 Labor supply with a homogeneous utility function

Suppose the utility function ),( ii lCU is homogenous of degree b, so that we can write

),( ii lCU )/()/,/( iibiiiii

bi lCvllllCUl ≡= . The first-order conditions for utility maximization with

respect to consumption and leisure are now iiic lCU λ=),( and iiil wlCU λ=),( , which can be

expressed as

)/()/)(/()/(

ii

iiiiii

lCvlClCvlCbvw

′′−

=

Since the right-hand side of this expression depends only on the consumption-leisure ratio, we can

invert it and express the consumption-leisure ratio as a function of the wage, )(/ wlC ii φ= . Note that

iiii KlwKC /)(/ φ= and substitute for the consumption-capital ratio in the individual budget

constraint to get

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+−= i

ii

i lww

Kwnr

KK )(1 φ ,

which yields the aggregate accumulation equation

⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ −+−= l

ww

Kwnr

KK )(1 φ .

To derive the dynamics of individual i’s relative capital stock, ( ) ( ) ( )i ik t K t K t≡ , we combine these

two equations to obtain

⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛⎟⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ +−−⎟

⎠⎞

⎜⎝⎛ +−= iii kl

wwl

ww

Kwk )(11)(11 φθφ

Imposing steady state to solve for iθ and substituting back into the above expression we can express

the relative labor supply as

)1~(/)(1

1~~~−⎟⎟

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛+

−=− ii kww

lllφ

Page 39: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

A3

which implies that the aggregate labor supply is independent of the distribution of capital. This

equation becomes (19’) in the text with the particular form we have assumed for the utility function.

A.3 Linearization of the aggregate dynamic system

Linearizing equations (12a) – (12b) around steady state yields

11 12

21 22

K Ka aKa al l l

⎛ ⎞−⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞= ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟−⎝ ⎠⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠

(A.6)

where

11 K KLla F F nη

= − − ; 1211 0L LL

la F Fη η

⎛ ⎞= − + + <⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠

21 111 (1 )( )

LKKK

L

Fa F aG l F

γ⎡ ⎤

= − −⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

; 22 121 (1 )( )

KLKL

L

Fa F aG l F

γ⎡ ⎤

= − − −⎢ ⎥⎣ ⎦

and L

LL

FF

llG )1()1(1)( γηγ −

−+−

≡ >0

By direct calculation we show that

11 22 12 2111 0KK L KLa a a a F F F βη

⎛ ⎞− = + − <⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠

implying that the steady state is a saddle point.

We immediately see that 12 0a < . In order to determine the likely signs of the other

elements, it is useful to express them in terms of dimensionless quantities such as the elasticity of

substitution in production, KLLK FFFF /≡ε and FKFs K /≡ , the share of output going to capital.

Thus, using the steady-state equilibrium conditions, we may write

[ ])1()1(111 −+−= εβ

εsna

⎭⎬⎫

⎩⎨⎧ −

−+⎥⎦

⎤⎢⎣

⎡⎥⎦⎤

⎢⎣⎡ −−+

−−=

εεγβ

εγβ 1)1()1(11)( 21

sns

sFFalG

L

KL

Page 40: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

A4

the signs of which involve tradeoffs between ε and the other parameters. From these two equations

we find that 11 210, 0a a< < if and only if ε lies in the range

[ ]β

βεγββγ +−

<<−+−+−− )1(

)1()1()1()1( sn

ssnsns (A.7)

which is certainly met in the case of Cobb-Douglas production and logarithmic utility ( 0,1 == γε )

More generally, assuming 0.015, 0.04, 0.33, 2n sβ γ= = = = − , as highly plausible parameters, we

see that (A.7) restricts ε to lie in the range 0.65<ε <1.25, which is consistent with virtually all

empirical evidence. Thus while we view 11 210, 0a a< < as most plausible, and 11 1a > as

improbable, we cannot dismiss 21 0a > , which will occur if ε is sufficiently small to violate the left

hand inequality in (A.7). Finally,

0)1()1(1)( 22 >⎟⎟⎠

⎞⎜⎜⎝

⎛−+++−−=

L

LLKL

FF

lF

alG γηγη

hence 022 >a .

A.4 The dynamics of the relative capital stock

To obtain the dynamics of individual capital we linearize equation (18) around the steady-

state , , iK l k . This is given by

( )( , ) 1 1( ) 1 ( )( ( ) ) 1 1 ( )i i i i iw K lk t k l t l l k t k

η η

⎡ ⎤⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞= + − − + + − −⎢ ⎥⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟

⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠⎢ ⎥⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦⎣ ⎦ (A.8)

Using the equilibrium condition, ( , ) ( , )Lw K l F K L= and combining the steady-state conditions

(13a) and (13b) to show

( , ) 11 1LF K L lK

βη

⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞+ − =⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

the stable solution to (A.8) can be written as

( )( , )1 1( ) (0) tLi i i i

F K lk t k k l l eK

µη θµ β η

⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞+ ⎡ ⎤= + − −⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ ⎣ ⎦−⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠ (A.9)

Page 41: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

A5

Setting 0t = in (A.9) and noting that .0ik is given, we obtain

( ),0( , )1 1 (0)L

i i i iF K Lk k k l l

Kη θ

µ β η⎛ ⎞ ⎛ ⎞+ ⎡ ⎤= + − −⎜ ⎟ ⎜ ⎟ ⎣ ⎦−⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠

(A.9’)

Thus, having determined ,K L , equations (25) and (A.’) jointly determine ,i ikθ . We can express

equation (25) as

(1 )1

ii i

k kl

θη

η

−= +

⎛ ⎞+⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

Thus enabling us to rewrite (A.9’) as

( ),0( , )1 (0)1L

i i iF K L l lk k k

K lβ µ⎛ ⎞⎛ ⎞ −

= + − ⎜ ⎟⎜ ⎟−⎝ ⎠ ⎝ ⎠ (A.10)

Given .0ik and the evolution of the aggregate economy, this equation determines the steady-state

distribution of capital. Substituting (A.10) into (A.9) the time path for relative capital is given by

( )( , )1 (0)( ) 1 tLi i i

F K L l lk t k k eK l

µ

β µ⎡ ⎤⎛ ⎞ −

= + − ⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟−⎝ ⎠ ⎣ ⎦ (A.11)

i.e. ( )( , )1 ( )( ) 1 1Li i i

F K L l tk t k kK lβ µ

⎛ ⎞ ⎡ ⎤= + − −⎜ ⎟ ⎢ ⎥− ⎣ ⎦⎝ ⎠ (A.12)

which we can re-express in the form of equation (21) in the text.

A.5 Derivation of Proposition 1

Recall the definition

( , )1 (0)(0) 1 1LF K L lK l

δβ µ

⎛ ⎞ ⎡ ⎤≡ + −⎜ ⎟ ⎢ ⎥− ⎣ ⎦⎝ ⎠

(i) If 0K K> , then (0)l l< and (0) 1δ > follows immediately.

(ii) If 0K K< , then (0)l l> and (0) 1δ < . To show that 0 2K K> is a sufficient condition for

Page 42: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

A6

(0) 0δ > , we first note that by using (16b) that (0) 0δ > if and only if

110

12

( , ) 1 ( ) 0LF K L a K KK a l

µβ µ⎛ ⎞−

− − − >⎜ ⎟⎝ ⎠

(A.13)

Given the plausible restriction 11 0a < a sufficient condition for (A.14) to be positive is that

0 12 1 LL

L L

K K a l Fl lK F F

ηη

⎡ ⎤− ⎛ ⎞+< − = −⎢ ⎥⎜ ⎟

⎝ ⎠⎣ ⎦

which will certainly be met if 0 1K KK−

< , i.e. if 0 2K K> .

A.6 Derivation of (30)

Using (14), we have

1 (1 )1 1 (1 )1

s s sL

ϕη

−= − < − − =

+

Also, using equation (13a) and (13b) we have

sn

nKFKnl

KFKF

KFKF LL ~

)~(

~~

)~()~(1

)~()~(

111~

+==−>

+−=

βηηϕ .

Page 43: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

R1

References

Algan, Y., A. Cheron, J-O Hairault, and F. Langot, 2003, “Wealth Effect on Labor Market

Transitions,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 6, 156-178.

Becker R.A. and C. Foias, (1987). “A Characterization of Ramsey Equilibrium”, J. Econ. theory 41,

173-84.

Becker, R.A. (1980) “On the Long-Run Steady State In A Simple Dynamic Model of Equilibrium

With Heterogeneous Households”, Quart. J. Econ. 95, 375–382.

Bliss, C., 2004, “Koopmans Recursive Preferences and Income Convergence,” Journal of Economic

Theory 117, 124-39.

Caselli, F., and J. Ventura, 2000, “A Representative Consumer Theory of Distribution,” American

Economic Review 90, 909-926.

Castañeda, A., Díaz-Giménez, J. and Ríos-Rull, J.-V. (2003), “Accounting For U.S. Earnings and

Wealth Inequality”, Journal of Political Economy 3 (4), 818–857.

Cooley, T. F. (1995). Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton, N. J.: Princeton University

Press.

Coronado, J.L. and M. Perozek, 2003, “Wealth Effects and the Consumption of Leisure: Retirement

Decisions During the Stock Market Boom of the 1990s,” Board of Governors of the Federal

Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 2003-20.

Cowell, F. A. (2000) "Measurement of Inequality" in Atkinson, A.B. and Bourguignon, F. (ed.)

Handbook of Income Distribution, Handbooks In Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier Science;

New York and Oxford: North-Holland.

García-Peñalosa, C. and S.J. Turnovsky, 2006a, “Growth and Income Inequality: A Canonical

Model,” Economic Theory 28, 25-49.

García-Peñalosa, C. and S.J. Turnovsky, 2006b, “Growth, Income Inequality and Fiscal Policy:

What are the Relevant Tradeoffs?,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking , forthcoming.

Ghiglino, C., 2005. “Wealth inequality and dynamic stability”, Journal of Economic Theory, 124

(1): 106-115.

Page 44: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

R2

Ghiglino,C. and G. Sorger, 2002, “Poverty Traps, Indeterminacy, and the Wealth Distribution,”

Journal of Economic Theory 105, 120-39.

Gottschalk, P. and S. Danziger, 2005. “Inequality of Wage Rates, Earnings and Family Income in

the United States, 1975-2002”, mimeo.

Guvenen, F., 2005, “Reconciling Conflicting Evidence on The Elasticity of Intertemporal

Substitution: A Macroeconomic Perspective”, mimeo.

Holtz-Eakin, D., D. Joulfaian, and H.S. Rosen, 1993, “The Carnegie Conjecture: Some Empirical

Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 413-435.

King R.G. and S. Rebelo, 1999, “Resuscitating real business cycles” in J.B. Taylor and M.

Woodford (eds.) Handbook of Macroeconomics 1B, North Holland, Amsterdam.

Ladron-de-Guevara, Antonio; Ortigueira, Salvador; Santos, Manuel S. 1997. “Equilibrium Dynamics

in Two-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth”, Journal of Economic Dynamics and

Control, January 1997, v. 21, iss. 1, pp. 115-43.

Ladron-de-Guevara, Antonio; Ortigueira, Salvador; Santos, Manuel S. 1999; “A Two-Sector Model

of Endogenous Growth with Leisure”, Review of Economic Studies, July 1999, v. 66, iss. 3,

pp. 609-31.

MaCurdy, T., 1981, “An Empirical Model of Labor Supply in a Life Cycle Setting,” Journal of

Political Economy 89, 1059-1085.

Rebelo, Sergio, 1991. “Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth”, Journal of Political

Economy, Vol. 99 Issue 3, p500-521.

Sorger, G. 2000, “Income and wealth distribution in a simple growth model,” Economic Theory 16,

23-42.

Sorger, G. 2002, “On the Long-Run Distribution of Capital in the Ramsey,” Journal of Economic

Theory 105, 226-43.

Stiglitz, J.E. 1969, “The Distribution of Income and Wealth Among Individuals,” Econometrica 37(3):

382-97.

Turnovsky, S.J., 2000, “Fiscal Policy, Elastic Labor Supply, and Endogenous Growth,” Journal of

Monetary Economics 45, 185-210.

Page 45: Stephen J. Turnovsky University of Washington, Seattle

R3

Zabalza, A. 1993. “The CES Utility function, non-linear budget constraints and labour supply:

Results on female participation and hours”, The Economic Journal, 93(370): 312-330.

Heckman , J. J. 1976. “A life-cycle model of earnings, learning and consumption”, Journal of

Political Economy 84(4): S11-S44.