sustainable use humphrey 2009

Upload: maddianwar

Post on 10-Apr-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    1/36

    Sustainable Use and Depletion of NaturalResources: Lessons for the Energy System

    Stephen R. Humphrey - University of Florida

    All industrial activity depends on energy and material. Knowing the principles for their provision and use

    could determine whether industrial societies succeed or failan extraordinary imperative for the rising

    generation. My purpose is to clarify these principles for renewable and exhaustible resources,

    integrating biophysical dynamics and human behavior. Then Ill apply them to the energy system, for

    which adaptation over the next few decades is crucial. My intent is to arm students with some vital

    ideas and inspire you to a positive and constructive ambition to meet the challenges ahead.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    2/36

    What is an exhaustible natural resource? What about non-renewable resources?

    All NRR are exhaustible, only the depletion rate can be managed .

    Its important to answer some very basic questions, about which people are remarkably confused.

    What is an exhaustible natural resource? This economists term is helpful because the class is much

    larger than generally recognized. First, all non-renewable resources are exhaustible. These include

    crude oil, coal, copper, rock phosphate, uranium, and rubies (illustrated). The amount of stock is usually

    uncertain or unknowable, and its depletion is managed through the rate of extraction. Financial

    analysts call these depleting resources.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    3/36

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    4/36

    Key insight: distinguishing stock and flow The supply in supply and demand is not a resource stock!

    Supply is flow, or periodic production from stock

    Stock is the resource that may be used sustainably or exhausted

    Stock

    Flow

    The key to understanding these resources is to avoid confusing stock and flow. The graphics show

    examples of various stocks and flows.

    The supply in economic supply and demand models is the flow or periodic production of a resource,

    not its underlying stock. If you manufacture wooden toys and demand goes up, you would like to

    increase supply so you order more lumber, and the truck brings more black cherry boards. But the

    actual stock of the resource is the forest, not the supply truck. Someone else is managing the stock, not

    you.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    5/36

    Special Model 1: sustainable use of arenewable resource

    Roughly 5% harvest is the most biological systems can sustain.The sustainable model is simple but crucial to visualize.

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

    RelativeValues

    Time

    Stock

    Flow = Production

    Price in Constant $

    Price is dependable, like a utility, if

    Stock is renewed indefinitely, if

    If flow is constrained so as to not draw down stock

    Once stocks and flows are viewed explicitly, you can integrate biophysical dynamics and human

    behavior with this very simple conceptual model of sustainable use of a renewable resource. The

    physical stock (orange) can be renewed indefinitely, and the price (green) is dependable like a utility, if

    the flow (blue) is constrained so as to not draw down the stock. Notice that the proportion of flow to

    stock is drawn as a 5% harvest. This is the most any biological system can sustainexamples are sugar

    cane, cattails, or algae. More typically, sustainable harvest for most terrestrial systems is only 1/25th of

    5%, so fixation of solar energy into carbohydrates in most terrestrial systems is quite inefficient.Elaborating this simple model in more complex cases helps to visualize resource-use limits and

    opportunities for sustainability.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    6/36

    Corn: sustainable use, disruptive tech

    Applies to non-renewable and renewable resources

    Mass selection

    Mendelian hybrid trait selection

    Here is a variation on the simple sustainable-use model, showing previously limited U.S. production of

    corn per acre increasing with application of new technology. Under genetic mass selection of seed corn,

    flow was stable for many decades. When the disruptive technology of Mendelian hybrid trait selection

    began in the 1940s, and other inputs were managed differently, productivity rose five-fold.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    7/36

    Is modern corn agriculture sustainable?

    Depends whether the renewable inputs are used renewably.And whether the non-renewable inputs have substitutes.

    Viewed in this way, the controversy over laboratory management of trait selection pales next to the

    questions of whether the use of inputs is sustainable and how we can feed 50% more people by 2050. If

    we want modern corn agriculture to be sustainable, we should ensure that the renewable inputs are

    used renewably and the non-renewable inputs either have substitutes or are recycled.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    8/36

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    9/36

    Inferring stock is the most diff icult step.Ex: cumulative world oil & gas discoveries

    Backdating corrects errors in reporting date and reserve estimates

    Documenting resource stocks is very difficult, done mainly by inference. The best example is for crude

    oil, for which public companies are required to report reserve estimates (unfortunately, reserve

    estimates of national oil companies are notoriously unreliable). The gray data points show cumulative

    discoveries of world oil and gas, backdated from the black points of initial reports. Correcting the initial

    data is necessary because oil and gas discoveries often are found to be larger or smaller than initially

    assessed, and because some new fields turn out to be part of previously discovered fields. The

    asymptotic level of the stock is apparent only when new discoveries become vanishingly small, so formost resources the asymptote is unknown or underestimated. (Oil reserve estimates project forward

    only about 10 years, because distant projections are costly and inaccurate, but 10 years of visibility is

    very helpfulabout as good as the crystal ball gets.)

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    10/36

    Flow i s seen empirically, see Hubberts1956 data on US oil produced; reservesallow inferring US & world production

    Roughly a normal curve: goes parabolic, peaks, then declines with long tail

    We know a lot about flow of oil resources, but the picture was quite misleading 60 years ago. Hubberts

    seminal 1956 publication challenged the conventional wisdom. He looked at oil production in the lower

    48 U.S. states, the upper left graph. He inferred that this could not last forever because the physical

    resource would become depleted, so he projected a roughly normal cumulative production curve, and

    then he extrapolated the U.S. pattern to the world. His contribution was to anticipate the reversal of

    the parabolic curve through a peak and decline, and he speculated that the decline would be elongated

    relative to the increase.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    11/36

    Hubberts peak prediction: correct

    Shows 11-year lag from discovery to production, flow varies and skewsto the right via conservation & enhanced oil recovery tech

    Here is an update by Ivanhoe (1996) of Hubberts model. Hubbert predicted that US oil discoveries

    would peak in 1958 and production would peak in 1969. The actual peak of production occurred in

    1970, off by only one year. This update shows some variation in flow and a skew to the right due to

    conservation, as well as modest enlargement of production by enhanced oil recovery technologies.

    Enhanced oil recovery has historically achieved a 20-40% gain, but increasing this to 30-60% or even

    more may be possible if sufficient volumes of CO2 were to become available, at the times and places

    needed, from new carbon capture and storage technologies.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    12/36

    World price of oil (in constant dollars)

    This is the left half of the U-shaped price curve

    Kerosene light

    1st light bulbs

    1st Ford car

    Gasoline motive power

    Electric light

    Random

    geopolitical

    event

    Model T

    Here are data tracking the left half of the U-shaped price curve (green in the model). When oil was first

    drilled in 1859 in Titusville Pennsylvania, the initial price was very high price. It rapidly declined (with

    high volatility) to a relatively stable price for many decades, disturbed by a random geopolitical event in

    the 1970s. Oil was initially valued as kerosene to make light, when light otherwise came from plant and

    animal oils. Geological oil was a large new feedstock for making light.

    It was not until invention of the light bulb and distribution systems for electricity around 1880 that

    demand and access shifted use of fossil oil from kerosene to electric power generation.

    Not until the first Ford car came off the assembly line in 1898 and the first model T in 1908 did gasoline

    motive power become a major use for oil.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    13/36

    Phases of the resource development-depletion model for oil

    Prior to peak, price is robust to practices-policies-events, becausesupply is elastic; but when supply is constrained, look out!

    Innovation

    phase

    (Moores law,cheap revolution)

    Utility phase

    Excursion I: US oil

    production peaked;

    Arab oil embargo,

    Iranian revolution,

    Iran-Iraq War,

    stagflation

    Excursion II:

    Demand

    growth at

    supply

    plateau;price rises,

    then

    demand

    drops

    Competition, combination, monopo ly, anti-trust, depression, WW I, WW II,

    import tariffs & quotas, export controls, price controls, cartel, nationalization

    Here are price data for the first two model phases of the oil-resource lifecycle. The innovation phase

    was completed in 15 years. The utility phase has lasted 125 years. Its most remarkable attribute was

    relative price stability despite an enormous array of practices, policies, and events directly affecting oil

    prices. Because supply (flow) was elastic (due to ample stock) during the utility phase of the

    development/use/depletion curve, production and demand could equilibrate, keeping price volatility

    relatively muted at plus or minus 50%.

    Two quite interesting and potentially confusing price excursions have occurred during the utility phase,

    however. The first was triggered by a series of geopolitical events in 1973-82: the Arab oil embargo, the

    Iranian revolution, and the Iran-Iraq war. These shocks caused economic stagflation and deep recession

    in the U.S., where domestic oil production was declining after its 1970 peak. U.S. dependence on

    imported oil, whose stock was abundant but flow curtailed, caused a decade of very high prices. The

    eventual reduction of mid-1980s prices back down to the utility level showed that world oil stocks were

    still in excess of demand for flow. Thus this episode was situated in the left half of the model. More

    foreboding, this experience of price spiking due to constrained flow presages severe economic

    disruption that will accompany the process of global oil depletion.

    The second excursion (2004-09) has occurred as evidence mounts that world oil production is peaking,with flow no longer elastic half-way through the resource lifecycle. If demand cannot be met, prices

    would be increasingly vulnerable to geopolitical shocks, investment bubbles, and financial speculation.

    The right half of the model thus portends chaos from extremely high and volatile oil prices.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    14/36

    When w ill world oil production peak?

    Duncan and Youngquist:

    world oil production peaked in 2007 BP Statistical Review data:

    world oil production peaked in 2008

    National Petroleum Council 2007: Facing hard truths

    Dr. Sadad Al-Husseini: the oil boom is over

    (former Saudi Oil Minister)

    capacity outlook: 10-year production plateau

    Association for the Study of Peak Oil: 2010

    Former Shell CEO van der Veer: 2015

    International Energy Agency 2008: trends in energysupply and consumption are patently unsustainable

    Opinions vary about the timing, but not about the outcome!

    Ever since Hubberts work, people have debated when world oil production will peak. This peak has

    been declared each year since 2004. Global recession in 2009 will reinforce the 2008 claim, so we will

    have to await economic recovery to see if flow can rise further. People with various perspectives

    (geologists, oil companies, industry advocates, and government ministers) all agree on the outcome that

    rising oil production has ended or will soon end. They disagree only about the timing. So if you are less

    than 60 years old (and healthy), you are going to live in a post-petroleum world. Your question should

    be What is that going to mean and what will we do about it.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    15/36

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    16/36

    Adding plausible price volatility to thelifecycle of exhaustible oil

    Economic cycles (and ideology) mask the depletion trend.

    The left half was fun; the right half will be chaotic.

    0

    100

    200

    300

    400

    0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

    RelativeValues

    Time

    Stock/6

    Flow = Production

    Price in Constant $

    TechnologicalInnovationPhase

    Utility or Service Phase

    Depletion orExhaustionPhase

    Demand Destruction

    You Are Here

    Recent experience with price spikes shows that we also need to visualize the naturally cyclic behavior of

    commodity markets. Here is the model adding plausible price volatility into the lifecycle of exhaustible

    fossil oil. (Similar examples occur for renewable resources used unsustainably, shown next.) Feedback

    from these cost cycles would affect the stock and flow curves too, but it is sufficient to imagine those

    without graphing. More importantly, people who understand finance and investing but not geology

    view these excursions as conventional business cycles, after which everything returns to normal. But

    the cycles and worldviews mask the underlying trend. If the stock is at a plateau, the next phase isdecline towards exhaustion, and prices will trend upwards with huge volatility. Instability of this

    magnitude will destabilize the dependent economy, an outcome worth great costs to avoid.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    17/36

    Caspian sturgeon landings & caviar price

    High demand and unsustainable harvest easily can exhaust arenewable resource

    Lets digress to reflect on the generality of the two models. The case of Caspian sturgeon is easily

    understood in terms of model 2. The data show the peak and depletion phases of fish landings (flow or

    production) and caviar price. The three species in the Caspian sturgeon fishery provide the worlds

    luxury caviar, so demand is very high (substitutes exist but are less desirable and fetch lower process).

    Ongoing high demand led to commercial exhaustion of this renewable resource.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    18/36

    US/ global whale oil production & price

    Also renewable but used unsustainably, so follows model 2;note the demand destruction by kerosene after 1859

    Here is a similar graph for world whale oil production and price over a century. (The main whaling ports

    were in New England but the fishery was global.) Whale oil was a luxury good, because it burned

    cleanly, did not smell bad, and produced the whitest light. It sold to the wealthy for the equivalent in

    todays prices of several hundred dollars a barrel.

    On the left is a hint of the innovation phase, perhaps hidden by missing data. Production or flow of

    whale oil peaked and then declined. Then something really interesting happened. Price spikes during

    depletion were muted by demand destruction, which occurred because kerosene became commonly

    fabricated in workshops and then became inexpensive after oil wells were drilled in 1859. The price

    chart even shows a double top, well known among investors as signaling the end of a growth industry.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    19/36

    Northern Cod: sustainable use,disruptive tech, rapid depletion

    Shifted from Model 1 to Model 2; ecosystem no longersupports a large cod population or fishery

    Numerous, small technological advances in fishing gear

    1960 factory freezer-trawler, Fairtry III

    Earlier, we looked at model 1 for corn, with a disruptive technology leading to a new high level of

    production. Heres another complex case. To understand use and depletion of the (theoretically)

    renewable northern cod fishery, shift your understanding of the concept from static to dynamic: the

    resource-use system morphed from one model to the other and then progressed rapidly to depletion.

    Northern cod were fished sustainably (model 1) for a century, except that a consistent uptrend resulted

    from a long series of numerous small technological advances in fishing gear. Then in 1960 the British

    invented the factory freezer trawler that could go worldwide, stay out for months or even years, and fish

    until the freezers filled. This disruptive technology shifted the fishery to unsustainable use (model 2).

    Cod populations quickly crashed. Now the ecosystem cannot longer sustain a large cod population or

    fishery because of associated changes in the ecosystem.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    20/36

    Focus: transforming the energy system

    Reason #1: energy services from cheap naturalresources are the basis of our industrial economy

    I promised to focus on implications of this thinking for the energy system.

    Energy services from cheap natural resources are the basis of our industrial economy. Our experience

    with depleting resources calls the question: If the end of the current paradigm is appearing, shouldnt

    we transform the energy system before crisis develops?

    To visualize our energy sources, heres a graphic with renewables on the left and non-renewables on the

    right. The data on percent consumption are out of date; the 2008 sum of U.S. renewables was about10.6% (including hydro) and slowly growing.

    Well need all of these for a calm transition, but foresight on the prospects of each is imperative.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    21/36

    Focus: transforming the energy system

    Reason #2: greenhouse gases from fossil fuels arechanging climate--an existential threat to civilization.

    The second reason for transforming the energy system is that greenhouse gases from fossil fuels are

    warming the climate at a rate that is still seriously underestimated. Shifting to a climate unlike that in

    which agriculture developed and civilization prospered is an existential threat.

    Not until 2014 will the IPCC produce climate-change models including the destabilizing feedback loops

    of melting permafrost, glaciers, ice shelves, sea ice, and seabed methane, reduced albedo, and drought-

    and fire-induced loss of forests.

    Then the twin problems of energy and climate will be seen in their full significance. Remarkably, both

    problems might be solved by the same set of strategies and actions.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    22/36

    Constraints for the new energy system

    To avert the climate-change threat, we must halt and reversecarbon release from fossil fuels, forests, and sediments.

    So my argument is: Were going to be forced to transform the energy system by (1) insufficient oil flow

    and unaffordable prices and (2) the urgent need to preserve a human-friendly climate.

    This implies both constraint and restraint. Well need to replace oil with other energy carriers. And

    well need to reduce use of other carbon-intensive fuels (especially coal), or capture the CO2 and

    sequester it away from the atmosphere. This investment in survival, however, will not lower standards

    of living, because it will create profitable assets.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    23/36

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    24/36

    The substitution puzzle (Solow 1974)

    If we can easily substitute other factors fornatural resources, then we can get alongwithout natural resources, and exhaustion isjust an event, not a catastrophe.

    But, if no substitute is found, catastrophe isunavoidable.

    In between are many cases where the problemis real, interesting, and not foreclosed.

    So, substitution needs disciplined thinking,puzzling out Solows uncertain outcomes byfocusing on innovation.

    For guidance on the substitution process, lets turn to economist Robert Solow. On the one hand, he

    said that if we can easily substitute other factors for natural resources then we can get along without

    natural resources, so exhaustion is just an event, not a catastrophe. On the other, catastrophe is

    unavoidable if no substitute is found.

    Most interesting of all, he said that in between exhaustion and substitution are cases where the

    problem is real, interesting, and not foreclosed. Hes advising us to look at the substitution process in a

    disciplined way. We need to puzzle out Solos uncertain outcomes and focus on the innovation process.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    25/36

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    26/36

    Vinod Khoslas system for drivinginnovation/ adoption of energy tech Principles: promising technologies must be:

    Inexhaustible or truly renewable Affordable, low start-up cost, short innovation cycle

    Capable of scaling up to demand, w declining costs

    Competitive without subsidy in ~10 years

    Not energy intensive

    Policies: government must:

    Encourage capitalists to invest

    Subsidize next-least-cost tech

    See khoslaventures.com

    Heres one innovators stimulating, disciplined thinking for adaptive energy technology. Vinod Khosla

    co-founded Sun Microsystems and then devoted himself to investing in new energy technology

    companies to help them succeed. His website provides many idea papers and presentations articulating

    a set of principles for driving the process.

    Promising technologies should have a number of attributes: truly renewable (i.e., renewables used

    sustainably) or inexhaustible, affordable, scalable, profitable, and not energy intensive. On careful

    examination, many options lack some of these qualities and thus are likely to have limited prospects.

    He also favors government policies that encourage and assist capitalists as prime actors to move the

    innovation agenda. This requires a transformational vision of the future among our political leadership

    and decision-makers. It also implies a risk-support role for government with private people and firms

    doing the actual work.

    Khosla says What is amazing about this is the size of the markets. We are dealing with much harder

    science and technology, so we will see much higher rate of failure, but the wins will be bigger. More

    money will be made in cleantech than in traditional areas of Silicon Valleyby far.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    27/36

    Only a few good choices:Bio fue l ( ce l lu los i c e thano l , bu tano l , a lgae)

    Our knowledge of the dynamics of sustainable use and depletion is confirmed by the experience and

    judgment of Vinod Khosla: there are only a few good choices for the new energy system.

    All the conventional energy sources are dirty and/or dangerous, but theres a pragmatic argument for

    using them to bridge from here to where we need to be. Ultimately, however, limited stocks and rising

    costs will lead us away from these and toward those that are sustainable for the economy, the

    environment, and society.

    One strong group of choices is the biofuels, specifically cellulosic ethanol, biobutanol, and algae-

    generated biodiesel. Food-based ethanol is not justifiable on economic or humanitarian grounds, but it

    serves the temporarily useful role of proving biofuels valuable and developing some of essential

    infrastructure. Diffusion of the idea is paving the way for better biofuels, and food-based biofuels will

    be phased out rapidly as the others become accessible and cheap. A promising development is the

    recent partnering of integrated oil companies with biofuel start-ups. Watch this space.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    28/36

    Only a few good choices:W i n d

    Wind power is the most promising of the true renewables. Installed capacity of wind power accelerated

    earliest among the true renewables, and it has huge development prospects in many areas of the world.

    Wind power is still a very small part of the energy mix in most places (but 20% in Denmark and parts of

    Germany), so the growth trend for wind power should continue. Wind could generate 20% of U.S.

    electricity by 2030. To accommodate windless intervals, wind power needs to be paired with backup

    power from conventional sources, with natural gas making by far the most sense for now.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    29/36

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    30/36

    Only a few good choices:Ocean w ave / cu r r en t / t i d e/ t h e rma l

    Most hydropower sites have already been exploited, but the special case of ocean energy is an

    enormous unexploited opportunity. For example, tapping just 1/1000th of the Gulf Stream current could

    supply 35% of Floridas current energy use (all of south Floridas). A few of the illustrations are

    operational, but most of these are still in the laboratory-pilot-demonstration phases.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    31/36

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    32/36

    Pushing the learning curve:

    solar PV cheaper each year, grid parity soon

    Its crucial to see Moore's Law in operation, in this case for solar PV, so you can see the cheap

    revolution at work. Steady, incremental tech innovations push down the learning and cost curve. Solar

    photovoltaic gets cheaper each year and has already achieved grid parity where conventional power is

    expensive (for example, Hawaii and California). The 2008 industry outlook by Deutsche Bank projectedgeneral grid parity in 2013, or sooner if a disruptive technology appears.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    33/36

    Learning curves, electricity technologies

    Steep: biomass combined heat & power.Cheap: wind, fuel cells, gas combined cycle

    Here are learning curves for a wide variety of electricity technologies. The cheap revolution is occurring

    everywhere.

    Most interesting are (1) the steepest curves, particularly biomass combined heat and power (orange),

    where the cheap revolution is fastest, and (2) the lowest curves, which are inherently cheapest. In the

    latter set are wind, fuel cells (sourced from natural gas), and natural gas combined cycle.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    34/36

    Infrastructure needed for all the above,including a bigger, better pow er grid

    We need better transmission infrastructure for all the above. As usual, this is not just a matter of tech

    innovationwe also need vision, policy leadership, and investment. Acting on the 2002 U.S.

    Department of Energy recommendations for the national electricity transmission system would do the

    job. DOE has already assessed priorities for planning, siting, and development of existing and new

    transmission corridors, and appropriate use of the many existing advanced technologies now blocked by

    the business uncertainties of political indecision. These available technologies could enhance reliability

    and dramatically increase electricity flows through existing transmission corridors. Additional corridorsare needed to carry electricity from areas of high wind and solar resources to population centers.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    35/36

    To develop new electricity at 2008 prices, natural gas (#5) is cheapest

    Wind is cheaper than coal Nuclear is most costly

    To assess prospects for transforming the energy system, we need to calibrate the options by costs of

    developing new power generation, not costs of legacy generation. Most comparisons in the popular

    press are the latter and thus quite misleading. According to the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission,

    new natural gas power was cheapest in 2008, new wind next cheapest, and new nuclear most

    expensive. Solar thermal was competitive with coal and cheaper than nuclear. The report did not

    address other solar technologies. Keep in mind that cost structure changes with economic conditions

    from year to year.

    One lesson is to ignore or, better, to confront media reports, for example those comparing the legacy

    costs of 1960s nuclear power (heavily subsidized then and now) with costs of newly developed

    renewables. The comparison makes renewables look infeasible, which is incorrect.

  • 8/8/2019 Sustainable Use Humphrey 2009

    36/36