teachers unions and student performance: help or hindrance? · teachers unions and student...

26
Teachers Unions and Student Performance: Help or Hindrance? Randall W. Eberts Summary Randall Eberts explores the role of teachers unions in public education. He focuses particularly on how collective bargaining agreements shape the delivery of educational services, how unions affect both student achievement and the cost of providing quality education, and how they sup- port educational reform efforts. Eberts’s synthesis of the empirical research concludes that union bargaining raises teachers’ compensation, improves their working conditions, and enhances their employment security— while also raising the cost of providing public education by upwards of 15 percent. The effect of unions on student performance is mixed. Students of average ability who attend school in union districts perform better on standardized tests, whereas low-achieving and high-achieving students perform worse. However, the overall gain in achievement does not make up for the higher cost. Of late, unions have begun to be more supportive of school reform, moving from an adversarial bargaining model to a more collaborative one in which teachers and administrators share com- mon goals and hold joint responsibility. Yet unions’ desire to participate in reform does not match their fervor to organize in the 1960s and 1970s. While national union leadership has talked about reform, local affiliates have initiated most of the reform efforts, pioneering re- forms such as accountability and incentive pay. In Eberts’s view, one reason that unions have been slow to embrace reform efforts is the lack of consensus on their effectiveness. He argues that many reforms have been too narrowly focused; rather, effective schools result from well- designed systems and processes. In principle, adopting standards that help teachers focus on lessons they want students to learn, aligning their teaching to the lessons, and devising meas- urements that demonstrate that students are responding to these lessons can improve teaching as long as the public, policymakers, and school administrators acknowledge the complexity of the learning process and the broad outcomes that society desires. VOL. 17 / NO. 1 / SPRING 2007 175 www.futureofchildren.org Randall W. Eberts is executive director of the W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. He gratefully acknowledges his colleagues Joe Stone and Kevin Hollenbeck for their collaboration on work referenced and used in this chapter. He thanks Allan Hunt for helpful comments on earlier drafts and Phyllis Molhoek for her assistance in preparing the manuscript. The views and observations expressed in the chapter are the sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily represent positions of the W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.

Upload: vonhan

Post on 24-Apr-2018

224 views

Category:

Documents


5 download

TRANSCRIPT

Teachers Unions and Student Performance:Help or Hindrance?

Randall W. Eberts

SummaryRandall Eberts explores the role of teachers unions in public education. He focuses particularlyon how collective bargaining agreements shape the delivery of educational services, how unionsaffect both student achievement and the cost of providing quality education, and how they sup-port educational reform efforts.

Eberts’s synthesis of the empirical research concludes that union bargaining raises teachers’compensation, improves their working conditions, and enhances their employment security—while also raising the cost of providing public education by upwards of 15 percent. The effectof unions on student performance is mixed. Students of average ability who attend school inunion districts perform better on standardized tests, whereas low-achieving and high-achievingstudents perform worse. However, the overall gain in achievement does not make up for thehigher cost.

Of late, unions have begun to be more supportive of school reform, moving from an adversarialbargaining model to a more collaborative one in which teachers and administrators share com-mon goals and hold joint responsibility. Yet unions’ desire to participate in reform does notmatch their fervor to organize in the 1960s and 1970s. While national union leadership hastalked about reform, local affiliates have initiated most of the reform efforts, pioneering re-forms such as accountability and incentive pay. In Eberts’s view, one reason that unions havebeen slow to embrace reform efforts is the lack of consensus on their effectiveness. He arguesthat many reforms have been too narrowly focused; rather, effective schools result from well-designed systems and processes. In principle, adopting standards that help teachers focus onlessons they want students to learn, aligning their teaching to the lessons, and devising meas-urements that demonstrate that students are responding to these lessons can improve teachingas long as the public, policymakers, and school administrators acknowledge the complexity ofthe learning process and the broad outcomes that society desires.

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 175

www.futureofchildren.org

Randall W. Eberts is executive director of the W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research. He gratefully acknowledges his colleagues JoeStone and Kevin Hollenbeck for their collaboration on work referenced and used in this chapter. He thanks Allan Hunt for helpful commentson earlier drafts and Phyllis Molhoek for her assistance in preparing the manuscript. The views and observations expressed in the chapter arethe sole responsibility of the author and do not necessarily represent positions of the W. E. Upjohn Institute for Employment Research.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 175

America’s need to provide high-quality education to its chil-dren has never been greater. Intoday’s knowledge-based econ-omy, education—and public

education in particular—is at the center ofU.S. efforts to maintain a competitive inter-national edge. But many observers fear thatthose efforts are failing. In international tests,U.S. students rank only in the mid-range ofnations in the critical areas of math and sci-ence. Public surveys reveal grave concernabout the quality of public education—andalso about efforts to improve it. Over the pastseveral decades federal, state, and local poli-cymakers have adopted one education reformafter another, with little systemwide success.Some reforms focus on improving the exist-ing system—for example, by adopting incen-tive pay and encouraging accountability. Oth-ers aim to create new systems—for example,by promoting vouchers and charter schools.So far, the public appears to prefer reformingthe current system, not abandoning it.1

Some observers blame specific groups linkedwith public education for the slow pace ofimprovement. Some of the strongest attackshave been reserved for teachers unions,which are said to have captured schools toadvance their own interests, not those of thestudents. Many critics of unions believe thatcollective bargaining has created a tangledweb of rules that keep public schools frombeing able to respond to the changing needsof students and that the bargaining processhas influenced public education more thanany other factor.2 As a result, they say, publiceducation is both more costly and less effec-tive than it should be. Such criticisms are notnew. In 1983 the landmark study A Nation atRisk, by the congressionally mandated Na-tional Commission on Excellence in Educa-tion, alerted Americans to a crisis in educa-

tion.3 The study, which challenged educators,policymakers, and parents to rethink the waystudents are educated, set in motion a waveof educational reform that continues to thisday. Teachers, who had hitherto attracted lit-tle public notice, suddenly found themselvesat center stage in the controversy over schoolquality. The nation’s immediate response tothe report was to set up systems to improveteacher and school accountability. Becausethe new focus—on monitoring and assessingteacher practices and on tying compensationto teachers’ performance—was antithetical totwo decades of work by teachers unions todecouple salaries from performance and toincrease the autonomy of teachers in theclassroom, teachers came to be perceived asreluctant participants in reform. Meanwhile,reform efforts gained little traction andyielded few, if any, sustained attempts atmerit pay or systems of accountability. Todaythese same reforms remain under discussionand teachers unions continue to find them-selves in the fray.

Aware of charges that they are resistant tochange, teachers unions have voiced concernabout school quality and urged the need forreform. Robert Chase, past president of theNational Education Association (NEA), thenation’s largest teachers union, called for anew unionism based on collaborative bar-gaining with school districts to help improveschool performance. In an address at the Na-tional Press Club in 1997, he reminded hisnearly 2.7 million members of the need forunions to take an active role in planning andimplementing educational reforms.4

In this article I explore both the extent towhich teachers’ collective bargaining affectsthe quality of education and the role of bar-gaining in the educational reform movement.Beyond the rhetoric of union advocates and

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

176 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 176

opponents, what do researchers know abouthow unions affect student achievement andthe cost of providing quality education? Areunions a help or a hindrance? To what extentare they promoting constructive change toimprove public education and to what extentare they thwarting such efforts?

Collective Bargaining by TeachersCollective bargaining is the process by whichteachers and administrators agree on a set ofregulations that govern working conditionsand determine compensation and fringe ben-efits. Dubbed a “web of rules,” it can affectevery dimension of the workplace and cansubsequently influence educational out-comes.5 It defines the rights and duties ofteachers to particular assignments, guaran-tees teachers’ participation in school gover-nance and educational policymaking, estab-lishes grievance procedures, and at timescreates disciplinary sanctions for teachers’failure to achieve certain standards. It alsoprovides for teacher participation in restruc-turing the workplace. More specifically, thefar-reaching web of rules may include work-ing conditions, such as the length of theschool day, hours of instruction and prepara-tion time, and interaction time with parents;class size; the number and responsibility ofsupplemental classroom personnel, such asaides; employment protection; assignment toschools and grade levels; criteria for promo-tion; reductions in force; professional ser-vices; in-service and professional develop-ment; instructional policy committees;student grading and promotion; teacher eval-uation; performance indicators; grievanceprocedures; student discipline and teachersafety; and the exclusion of pupils from theclassroom. The list goes on. Suffice it to saythat collective bargaining agreements,through negotiated rules and regulations, es-tablish school policy and govern how teach-

ers, administrators, parents, and students in-teract in the delivery of educational services.As the Wall Street Journal noted nearly threedecades ago, “Teachers’ unions have becomecrucial forces in deciding how public educa-tion should be run in the U.S.” 6

Laws governing public sector collective bar-gaining have come almost exclusively from

state governments. Although the NationalLabor Relations Act (NLRA) of 1935, asamended in 1947, required employers tomeet and confer in good faith with respect towages, hours, and other terms and conditionsof employment, it did not include public sec-tor employers. Congress has considered leg-islation to govern negotiations of public em-ployees, but states have assumed leadership.

Meaningful state legislation giving publicemployees a voice in determining the condi-tions of their employment was first enactedin the 1960s. Before then, two states, Alaskaand New Hampshire, had allowed local gov-ernments to negotiate with groups represent-ing public employees, but neither state ex-tended to public employees the same rights

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 177

Suffice it to say that collectivebargaining agreements,through negotiated rules andregulations, establish schoolpolicy and govern howteachers, administrators,parents, and students interactin the delivery of educationalservices.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 177

as granted to private employees. Alaska’s law(in 1935) and New Hampshire’s law (in 1955)did not require or ensure bargaining; theyonly allowed local governments to negotiateunder specified conditions. Permitting publicemployees to bargain, nonetheless, was a bigstep in treating private and public employeesequally in the bargaining arena. Before pas-sage of the two state collective bargaining

laws, contracts between school boards andteachers unions were seen as an illegal dele-gation to school boards of local citizens’ sov-ereign constitutional powers. Granting teach-ers and other public employees the power tobargain collectively was believed to give themclout over and above their private sectorcounterparts because they were already able,through the political process, to elect thepublic officials who would govern and man-age the workplace.7

In 1962 Wisconsin became the first state topass legislation governing public employeebargaining that resembled the languagefound in the NLRA. The Wisconsin statuterequired local governments to bargain ingood faith with employee groups and alsocreated administrative enforcement meas-ures. It charged the Wisconsin Public Em-ployee Relations Board with determining ap-propriate bargaining units, enforcing theprevention of prohibited practices, fact find-

ing, and mediating disputes. The law alsomarked the beginning of widespread recogni-tion of the rights of public employees to bar-gain collectively. Within the next five years,New York and Michigan passed similar laws,and by 1974 thirty-seven states had passedlegislation permitting public employee bar-gaining—a number that remains unchangedto this day.

After public sector collective bargaining waslegally recognized, teacher representationgrew significantly. In 1974 roughly 22 percentof public school teachers were covered by col-lective bargaining. That share doubled in sixyears and grew to more than 60 percent bythe mid-1980s. Today unions represent 67percent of the nation’s 3 million active publicelementary and secondary school teachers.8

The coverage rate for teachers is much higherthan the average of 40 percent for all publicsector employees. Representation varies geo-graphically, with some teachers in all regionsand all states reporting that they belong to alabor union or a similar association or else arenevertheless covered under a collective bar-gaining contract. The highest proportion ofrepresentation is in the Middle Atlantic re-gion (88 percent), with the New England (82percent), East North Central (81 percent),and Pacific (82 percent) regions close behind.Coverage is lowest in the West South Centralregion, at 40 percent, and slightly higher inthe South Atlantic (47 percent) and EastSouth Central (52 percent) regions.

Teachers were not always anxious to be a partof organized labor. In the early years of theNEA, members saw its role as promoting theprofessional side of teaching. Although NEAmembers were sensitive to their financialneeds, the union’s official posture was one ofdiscourse, not collective action.9 The Ameri-can Federation of Teachers (AFT), by con-

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

178 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

Today unions represent 67 percent of the nation’s 3 million active publicelementary and secondaryschool teachers.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 178

trast, tried from its inception to bring teach-ers into the mainstream of organized labor.Unlike the larger and more powerful NEA,the AFT advocated collective action as thebest way to promote the interest of teachers.

Researchers generally cite four reasons forthe growth of collective bargaining for teach-ers.10 The first, as noted, was the passage ofstate laws protecting teachers’ rights to seekbargaining recognition. Second, declining en-rollment and skyrocketing inflation in the1970s eroded teachers’ financial well-being,and general discontent with access to and in-fluence over educational decisionmaking di-minished teachers’ sense of professionalism.Third, changing social conditions and work-force demographics and an increasing mili-tancy and social awareness provided fertileground for the union movement. Finally, asunionism in the private sector continually de-clined, union organizers came to see teachersand the public sector as ripe for organizing.And rivalry between the AFT and the NEAincreased their fervor.11

During their formative years of collectivebargaining, teachers unions patterned them-selves after their private sector counterparts,which followed what has been called an in-dustrial bargaining model.12 According to theNEA’s Chase, “When we reinvented our asso-ciation in the 1960s, we modeled it after tra-ditional, industrial unions. Likewise, we ac-cepted the industrial premise: Namely, thatlabor and management have distinct, con-flicting roles and interests . . . that we aredestined to clash . . . that the union-manage-ment relationship is inherently adversarial.”13

The industrial model is based on an adversar-ial, not collaborative role, with managementcontrolling the workplace and workers fillingnarrowly defined tasks. Such a model valuesstandardized practice and views similarly

skilled workers as interchangeable, each tobe treated alike. From the viewpoint ofteachers in the classroom, administrators uni-laterally set educational policy and teacherscomply. Instruction is delivered uniformly tolarge groups of students, and the teachingforce is undifferentiated. The primary role ofunions is to protect workers from unrealisticdemands of management, ensure a safeworking environment, and extract the maxi-mum compensation possible. Bargaining fo-cuses more on teachers’ interests and less ontheir performance and how that performanceaffects student outcomes. While perhapsmore applicable to private sector productionworkers, such a stance places teachers atodds with their desire to be treated as profes-sionals as they bargain in their self-interest.

The extent to which teachers unions affectschool quality and ultimately studentachievement depends on many factors. First,how successful are unions in negotiatinghigher salaries and fringe benefits? Second,how successful are they in negotiating provi-sions that affect workplace conditions, suchas class size and transfers, which in turn mayaffect students’ school-based learning envi-ronment? Third, how successful are unions innegotiating rules that govern teachers’ inter-action with students, parents, and otherteachers? Fourth, how successful are they inshielding teachers from accountability fortheir own performance? All these factors andothers must be considered to determine thebottom line of collective bargaining: what ef-fect, if any, it has on student achievement.

Outcomes of Collective Bargaining NegotiationsI begin by examining the ability of teachersunions to affect their compensation, workingconditions, employment security, and work-place governance through collective bargain-

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 179

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 179

ing and then look at the evidence of the over-all effect of union bargaining on studentachievement.14 I note at the outset that re-searchers at times draw a distinction betweenunionization and collective bargaining.Unionization is seen as the influence teachersexert on their school district through the bar-gaining power of their membership; collec-tive bargaining, by contrast, has more to dowith the establishment of rules governing theworkplace and compensation through negoti-ated collective bargaining agreements. It is asubtle distinction, because the effects of bar-gaining power are seen in the ability ofunions to negotiate higher compensation andto include key provisions in their contracts.Furthermore, bargaining power determinesthe strength with which contract provisionsinfluence administrative decisions.15

A necessary foundation for bargaining poweris the extent to which state laws permit andrequire collective bargaining. A recent re-view of state collective bargaining laws forthe public sector found that the presence orabsence of state laws governing union secu-rity and laws defining collective bargainingrights affects the wages of public sector em-ployees.16 For example, earnings of unionworkers are between 4 and 11 percent higherwhere an agency or union shop is either com-pulsory or negotiable than where it is not.Consequently, given the legal right to bargaincollectively, public sector unions are able toincrease the wages of their members, whichin turn affects the allocation of resources inthe public sector.

Teachers unions may wield power at the pollsand through the political process, as well asaround the bargaining table. As noted, oneargument against allowing public sector bar-gaining was that public employees have theability to elect the government officials who

would govern and manage the workplace andallocate resources that directly affect theteachers’ working conditions and compensa-tion.17 In addition to their individual votes, inmany local jurisdictions, teachers and otherpublic employees have the opportunity toform a strong voting bloc that can dispropor-tionately affect the outcomes of school boardelections, school bond elections, and otherreferendum ballots directly affecting publicschools. Teachers unions can, and have, comeout strongly against state referenda to allowcharter schools and voucher systems, whichthey believe could divert students away fromtraditional public schools and thus reducepublic school resources, their union ranks,and their bargaining and political power.18 Astate teachers union typically has a stronglobbying arm that finances media campaigns,supports political action committees, andcontributes to specific campaigns throughvoluntary contributions from its members.19

Contract ProvisionsBargaining power may be reflected simply inthe number of significant provisions found incontracts. One study of the collective bar-gaining contracts of New York State schooldistricts, which are represented by either theNEA or AFT, found that these agreementsare hierarchical, in that some provisions aremore easily negotiated, while others, presum-ably more restrictive to management, areharder to include.20 Thus contracts withmore restrictive provisions, such as no reduc-tion in the teacher workforce during thelength of the contract, would seem to indi-cate greater bargaining power on the part ofteachers unions. In fact, the study finds thatthe sheer number of contract provisions posi-tively affects the negotiation of teachersalaries. Teachers in districts with fifty con-tract provisions (of a possible fifty-three pre-determined categories) received $1,900

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

180 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 180

more, on average, than those in districts withthe minimum number of items. Budget allo-cations are also affected by the inclusion orremoval of specific contract provisionsthrough the negotiating process, providingfurther evidence of the link between bargain-ing power and contract provisions.

Teacher Pay and BenefitsTwo detailed studies, one by William Baughand Joe Stone and the other by CarolineHoxby, using different techniques and datasamples, find that teachers covered by collec-tive bargaining tend to earn 5 to 12 percentmore than those who are not covered.21 Thisis consistent with the typical range found forunion pay premiums in other sectors.22 Evi-dence on the fringe benefit premium is not asextensive. One study, based on contracts forNew York State public schools, finds that bar-gaining has a larger effect on fringe benefitsthan it does on pay.23 This finding corre-sponds to evidence from other sectors, wherethe effect of bargaining on fringe benefits istypically larger than the effect on pay. Asnoted, higher pay and fringe benefits, al-though they increase educational costs, mayalso increase the quality of education if theyattract better teachers.

Working ConditionsThe working conditions about which teach-ers appear to be most concerned are classsize, time for preparation and other activitiesaway from students, and autonomy in theclassroom.24 Three studies, each relying ondifferent data sets, find that student-teacherratios are 7–12 percent lower for unionteachers than for nonunion teachers.25

Teachers have also successfully negotiatedprovisions that regulate instructional andpreparation time and limit the time theymust devote to administrative duties andmeeting with parents. A study by Eberts and

Joe Stone found that elementary teachers inunion districts spend 4 percent more time inclass preparation and administrative dutiesbut 3 percent less time in instruction thantheir nonunion counterparts.

Another aspect of working conditions isteachers’ mode of instruction. The Ebertsand Stone study finds that teachers unionstend to “standardize” the workplace, by rely-ing more on traditional classroom organiza-tion than on other instructional methods. Innational data for fourth-grade students, italso finds that union schools are less likely torely on specialized, less standard instruc-tional methods in mathematics. Students inunion schools spend 42 percent less timewith a specialist, 62 percent less time with aspecialized aide, 26 percent less time with atutor, and 68 percent less time in indepen-dent, programmed study.26 Such standardiza-tion, common to unionized workplaces, mayaffect average and atypical students in differ-ent ways.

Employment SecurityUnions and their members also seek job pro-tection from temporary downturns in enroll-ment and from reductions in employment asthe costs of union pay and fringe benefitsrise. Many public school teachers, bothunion and nonunion, are granted tenureafter a few years of regular employment,which protects them from dismissal exceptfor specific causes, few of which are relatedto performance. But in addition, unions pro-tect employment by negotiating lower classsize and reduction-in-force provisions. Asnoted, student-teacher ratios tend to belower in union schools, even in the face ofhigher pay and fringe benefits. Reduction-in-force provisions are also prevalent inmany district contracts. Their effectivenessin protecting employment can be seen in

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 181

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 181

their positive effects on wages and their mit-igating effects on terminations in districtswith declining enrollments.27

Cost of InstructionIn other unionized sectors, the increased pay,better fringe benefits, improved workingconditions, more standardized and regulatedworkplace, and protections against job losscommon in union contracts typically come atthe expense of a higher cost of production.28

The same is true for public education. Al-though a few early studies found little or nodifference in the costs of operating unionizedschools, the two most detailed studies pro-vide consistent evidence of higher operatingcosts.29 One finds that the operating cost ofunionized elementary schools is about 15percent higher; of unionized high schools,about 8 percent higher.30 The other, relyingon different, more recent data, finds that thecosts of operating unionized high schools areabout 12 percent higher.31

By negotiating higher salaries and smallerclass size, teachers unions may influence theway schools allocate their resources. It is pos-sible that higher payroll costs could be cov-ered by raising taxes, leaving the same moneyavailable for other educational spending un-related to teacher compensation. But studiesshow that teachers unions distort the way ed-ucational spending is allocated because thehigher compensation typically reduces fundsavailable for other instructional purposes.

Administrative FlexibilityBy their very nature, contracts restrict thediscretion of administrators. They can dictateclass size and teacher assignments, imposerestrictions on teacher dismissal and reduc-tion in force, and determine the extent towhich teachers participate in key decisions.Codifying strict rules into a contract, which

may be in place for up to three years, couldbe problematic for administrators seeking toadapt to change. But although these provi-sions reduce the discretion of administrators,they need not completely impede their effec-tiveness. As one study reports, “truly effec-tive principals usually accept collective bar-gaining and use the contract both to managetheir building more systematically and to in-crease teacher participation in school deci-sionmaking. Less effective principals mayview the contract as an obstacle to a well-runschool and then use it as an excuse for poormanagement.”32 Superintendents may useunion rules to strengthen their control overprincipals and centralize decisionmakingwithin the district. Such efforts may lead tomore effective schools if they are alignedwith the desired outcomes and if teachersand principals share similar views. Whetherthis takes place is an empirical issue that fewanalysts have examined with any rigor. TheEberts and Stone study finds from a nationalsurvey that the gap in perceptions betweenelementary school teachers and principalsabout a principal’s active leadership is largerin union than in nonunion schools. The sameis true for perceptions about teachers andprincipals working well together. By contrast,it finds no difference in perceptions regard-ing staff being well informed or identifyingconflict. It also finds that time spent by prin-cipals in instructional leadership leads tohigher test scores in union districts but lowerscores in nonunion districts. These findingsare only suggestive of the differences in atti-tudes and their effect on student achieve-ment that stem from the greater structure in-troduced by collective bargaining contracts.33

Student AchievementThe question that causes the most publicconcern, of course, is whether teachersunions affect student achievement. Evidence

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

182 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 182

on “productivity” from other (nonteacher)unionized sectors is mixed. In some sectors,union workers appear to be more productive;in others, less. In most cases, though, the dif-ferences are small, especially in the most rig-orous studies.34 For teachers the critical find-ing seems to be not whether teachers unionsraise or lower student achievement, but howthey influence the effectiveness of schools.

What is the evidence on student achieve-ment? The evidence that is available is notideal. One would like to assign students ran-domly to schools that are also randomly as-signed to union or nonunion status and thenobserve student achievement over time. Thebest approximations to this ideal experimentuse extensive statistical controls for both stu-dent and school attributes, as well as for thenonrandom assignment of students andschools. But even good approximations tothe ideal have been difficult to achieve. An-other approach has been to look at the ef-fects of unions on schools’ ability to attractand retain more qualified teachers, throughhigher pay and fringe benefits, better work-ing conditions, and a greater voice in deci-sionmaking and teacher transfers. Onestudy, by Susanna Loeb and Marianne Page,finds that higher wages attract a better poolof teacher applicants.35 But another, bySusan Moore Johnson and Morgaen Donald-son, finds no consistent evidence that thequality of teachers has increased or de-creased as a result of collective bargaining.36

Although other studies have shown thatteachers contribute to student achievement,they have difficulty identifying whichteacher attributes are responsible.37 There-fore, I review studies that link collective bar-gaining directly to student achievement, in-stead of trying to piece together the effect ofunions on the various factors affecting stu-dent achievement.

Often, the most widely reported evidence isbased on state data for SAT or ACT scores.Three prominent state studies find roughlysimilar positive effects for teachers unions onaverage scores on either the SAT or theACT—between 4.5 and 8 percent.38 One ofthese also finds a similar positive effect (4.4percent) on high school graduation rates.39

These studies are problematic, however, be-

cause they have few controls for student anddistrict effects and aggregate the student out-comes of vastly different school districts intoone measure of student outcomes for eachstate.

A few studies have looked at student achieve-ment using individual student data with rela-tively detailed controls for both student andschool attributes.40 Across four different sam-ples of students (the Sustaining Effects Sur-vey, High School and Beyond, the NationalAssessment of Economic Education, and theNational Educational Longitudinal Survey)and three different grade levels (fourth,tenth, and twelfth), these studies yield re-markably consistent results. Collectively, theyfind that teachers unions raise average stu-dent scores on various standardized examsbetween 1 and 2 percent. Some also estimatethe effect of unions on gains in test scoresfrom the beginning to the end of the school

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 183

For teachers the criticalfinding seems to be notwhether teachers unions raiseor lower student achievement,but how they influence theeffectiveness of schools.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 183

year. Eberts and Stone, for example, find thatstudents in union districts have a 5 percenthigher gain in before and after testing thanstudents in nonunion schools. Given the dif-ferences among samples, grade levels, testmeasures, and empirical methodologies, thesimilarity of these findings cannot be ig-nored. Yet the effects are relatively small.Furthermore, they are positive only for aver-

age-achieving students. Low- and high-performing students fare worse in unionschools.41

Caroline Hoxby uses a different measure ofstudent outcomes: high school dropout rates.Using district-level data, she finds that teach-ers unions are associated with a 2.3 percentincrease in dropout rates and infers thatunionization reduces student achievement.42

Hoxby also finds that union effects ondropout rates are larger in areas with little in-terdistrict competition.

Hoxby’s findings raise the question of howteachers unions can raise average studentachievement on standardized exams (basedon the four studies mentioned), yet also in-crease high school dropout rates. Given thather analysis is based on district data, one an-swer might be that low-scoring students aremore likely to drop out, so that relativelyhigher-scoring students remain in the districtto take the tests. But that does not explain the

positive achievement found in early grades(in the case of Eberts and Stone, fourthgrade), where the dropout rates are muchlower and the achievement results are stillsimilar to those for high school.

Another explanation may lie in the method-ologies used and the ability to control for fac-tors affecting student achievement that areunrelated to unionization, as well as unobserv-able variables that may have caused teachersto unionize. A closer look at the two groups ofstudies—those based on individual studentdata and Hoxby’s, based on district data—shows more similarities than differences intheir methodologies.43 Without consideringthe problems inherent in using studentdropout rates to proxy student achievement, itis not apparent that one methodology is supe-rior to another, because each has its advantagein controlling for important factors related tostudent achievement.44

A more satisfactory answer may lie in the evi-dence on the effect of unions on the distribu-tion of student achievement, rather than onaverage student achievement. The finding byEberts and Stone and others of an inverted-U-shaped effect of teachers unions on stu-dent achievement may help to reconcile theevidence of positive effects on achievementfor average students with negative effects onhigh school dropout rates. Dropout rates arehighly correlated with student success inschools, and low-performing students aremuch more likely to drop out. If teachersunions tend to reduce the academic successof weak students, one would tend to expectthe dropout rate to increase, because it is theweakest students who are the most likely todrop out.

Disparities in the way unions affect studentsof varying ability can be explained in part by

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

184 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

Disparities in the way unionsaffect students of varyingability can be explained inpart by the standardizingeffect of unions on schools.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 184

the standardizing effect of unions on schools.As noted, unionized schools rely to a greaterextent on traditional classroom instructionand less on specialized modes of instruction.Because standard methods are likely to workbest for the average student and specializedmodes to work best for atypical students, onemight expect the effects to differ by studentability.45 This explanation is reinforced byArgys and Rees, who find that effects nolonger differ after they take into account thetype and size of the instructional setting andother related classroom factors.46

The evidence on how unions affect studentachievement leads to the general conclusionthat there is no simple answer and that gen-eralization is difficult. The average-achievingstudent does not appear to be harmed by at-tending union schools and may even fareslightly better, whereas low-achieving, at-riskstudents and high-achieving students tend todo better in nonunion schools. Even thoughsome threads of evidence are promising, re-searchers have much to learn about howunions affect student outcomes. What isknown with some certainty is that the pro-ductivity gains of unionization, if any, do notmatch the increase in cost, upward of 15 per-cent, that unions place on education throughhigher compensation and their influence onresource allocation within schools.

Reform InitiativesIn recent years, both the NEA and the AFThave advocated a new model for collective bar-gaining known as reform bargaining. Reformbargaining recognizes that management andlabor are not adversaries but share commoninterests, are jointly responsible for the out-comes of their organization, and should find ituseful to collaborate to pursue those commongoals. Instead of a standardized workplace inwhich duties are rigidly defined and compart-

mentalized, both management and labor strivefor flexibility, and workers participate in site-based decisionmaking. For teacher collectivebargaining, the new model calls for teachersand administrators to hold joint responsibilityfor schooling, share common goals, and collab-orate in determining governance, instruc-tional, and personnel issues.47

The first waves of reform initiatives,prompted in 1983 by A Nation at Risk, werenot widely embraced by teachers unions. Inmany respects, the reform movement col-lided head-on with the union movement,which by the early 1980s included nearlytwo-thirds of the nation’s public school teach-ers. As described by Lorraine McDonnelland Anthony Pascal in their study of the roleof unions in implementing reform, the bar-gaining process continued to place materialgain, such as higher salaries and benefits andbetter working conditions, over efforts to in-crease teacher professionalism and accounta-bility.48 Johnson and Kardos also concludethat many unions tried to stall reform in thebelief that the public would soon lose inter-est. But they discovered that far from losinginterest, the public instead began to call forsweeping changes, such as vouchers andcharter schools, which could threaten thevery existence of public schools and of theunions themselves.49

As in the race to organize teachers, the NEAand AFT have continued to jockey for positionin leading the reform effort. Sensing the na-tion’s concern about teacher complacency dur-ing the 1980s, the AFT began to soften itsstrong activist and militant stand in bargaining.Instead of pushing for hard-line positions onwage demands and bargaining provisions, theAFT has urged its affiliates to establish higherstandards—to police its ranks, hold teachersaccountable to union standards, and bargain

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 185

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 185

cooperatively rather than contentiously withmanagement.50 The NEA, most recently withthe public proclamations of President Chase,has echoed these sentiments while insisting onthe urgent need for action.

Charles Kerchner and Julia Koppich notethat union-sponsored reform does not havethe momentum that collective bargaining hadduring the 1960s and 1970s.51 They see three

internal challenges to union reform. The firstis a lack of clarity about goals. While unionleaders do not lack vision, say the authors, thecomplexity of the task of improving schoolquality makes it hard for them to discuss theissue without raising teachers’ fears of howreform will affect their work life and com-pensation. The second challenge is organiza-tional undercapacity, because union leadersand members have not embraced the ur-gency of reform. Many teachers do not be-lieve that public schools need to be re-formed. Third, without the vision andcommitment of teachers and leaders, it is dif-ficult to build a strong political coalition thatwould legitimate reform roles. Furthermore,the lack of agreement about the effectivenessof many reform initiatives makes it difficultto convince teachers to implement thechanges.

While national union organizations havetalked about reform, much of the effort hasbeen initiated by local affiliates, sometimeswith resistance from their parent organiza-tions. In 1996, a group of reform-mindedNEA and AFT local affiliates formed theTeachers Union Reform Network (TURN).The brainchild of two local union presidents,TURN is funded primarily by grants fromprivate foundations, not from the parent or-ganizations. Its twenty-plus members meetregularly to exchange ideas and promote re-form initiatives. Its goals include “improvingthe quality of teaching” and “seeking to ex-pand the scope of collective bargaining to in-clude instructional and professional issues.”52

Kerchner and Koppich have analyzed thecollective bargaining contracts of twenty-oneTURN members to see which types of provi-sions they find important for reform.53 Theprovisions include (with the number of con-tracts in parentheses): shared decisionmakingand budgeting (21), uses of time (19), profes-sional development (15), peer assistance andreview (14), school-based staff and budget(14), intervention strategy for low-perform-ing schools (10), alternative compensation,such as pay-for-performance (8), parent en-gagement (4), charter and pilot schools (4),and learning standards (2).

In many cases, success in including theseprovisions in collective bargaining agree-ments came about not from a broad accept-ance of the new unionism at the nationallevel, but from stances taken by local unionleaders and school administrators. Severallocal unions and their districts stand out forpioneering initiatives addressing accountabil-ity and incentive pay. Both initiatives havegained considerable support among policy-makers and have been implemented to vary-ing degrees across the country; performancestandards were most recently embodied in

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

186 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

While national unionorganizations have talkedabout reform, much of theeffort has been initiated bylocal affiliates, sometimeswith resistance from theirparent organizations.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 186

the No Child Left Behind Act (NCLB) of2001. After briefly describing these initia-tives, I will focus on evidence of their effec-tiveness in improving student outcomes, inparticular, test scores.

AccountabilityReforms to improve the accountability ofschools have sought either to improve or re-place the existing public education system.Improvements within the system involvechanges that directly affect the internal oper-ations of schools. Chief among these are stan-dards for student performance, measurementtools to track student progress, and pre-scribed consequences for students, teachers,and schools if standards are not met. Reformsthat go outside the system put competitivepressure on schools to improve, by enhancingparental choice. This latter wave of reformhas created a number of different voucherprograms that enable parents to use publicdollars to send their children to privateschools. It has also created publicly sup-ported “charter” schools, outside the directcontrol of local school boards, as alternativesto conventional public schools.

Both types of reforms were proposed andadopted by local teachers unions before theywere instituted as state or national policy.Toledo, Ohio, is generally credited withpaving the way among teachers unions inholding its members more accountable forperformance. Throughout the 1970s, theunion pressed to expand its role in evaluatingteachers. It finally codified a plan in its col-lective bargaining agreement in 1981. Knownas the Toledo Plan, it included two separateprograms—an intern program for first-yearteachers and an intervention program for ex-perienced teachers who need substantial re-mediation. Both use consulting teachers, whotake a three-year leave from the classroom to

serve as both mentor and evaluator. A nine-member Intern Board of Review, includingfive teachers, makes the final decision torenew or dismiss an intern. The board alsodetermines whether a tenured teacher who isseen by the principal or the union’s buildingcommittee as underperforming needs to un-dergo a performance review and get assis-tance. If performance does not improve suffi-ciently, the teacher may be let go.54

Incentive PayOther school districts adopted the peer eval-uation system initiated by Toledo and ex-panded it to link pay to performance. For ex-ample, the Columbus, Ohio, EducationAssociation adopted a peer evaluation systemin 1986 but later agreed to school-basedsalary incentives and limits on the impact ofseniority.55 The Cincinnati Federation ofTeachers recently expanded its peer reviewprocess and professional development acad-emy by implementing a compensation systembased on professional development instead ofseniority. Teachers are assessed on predeter-mined quality standards and paid accordinglywhen they have achieved them. Seattle hastaken pay for performance one step furtherby including student achievement as a qualitystandard.

Denver, probably more than any other schooldistrict to date, has pursued an ambitiouspay-for-performance experiment. Ironically,in 1921 Denver became the first school dis-trict to replace a merit pay approach with asingle salary schedule based on seniority. Sev-enty-eight years later the district administra-tion and teachers association agreed on atwo-year pilot that would base teachers’ payin part directly on the achievement of theirstudents. As described by Donald Gratz, whowas in charge of evaluating the Denver In-centive Program, the pilot provided small

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 187

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 187

bonuses for teachers who met either one ortwo student achievement objectives that theythemselves chose.56 These objectives had tobe approved by their principals. For each ob-jective met, teachers received $750. For aschool to join the pilot, 85 percent of its fac-ulty had to vote for participation. Thirteenschools signed up.

The Denver Teachers Association had op-posed the new compensation system as ini-tially proposed but, wishing to avoid contin-ued confrontation with the administration,agreed after winning three important conces-sions. One was that teachers’ performancewould be based on objectives of their ownchoice, with approval of their principals. An-other was that an outside, objective partywould evaluate the effectiveness of the pilot.The third was that the final plan would besubject to a general vote of the association’smembers. By the time the system wasbrought to a vote and approved in 2004, ithad been modified extensively. The approvedsystem included four components. Compen-sation was based on student growth objec-tives; on earned professional developmentunits, including advanced degrees; and ontwo bonuses, one for serving in hard-to-staffassignments and the other for serving inhard-to-serve schools.

At first blush, it would seem that teachersunions should find standards-based systemsattractive, because they promote standardiza-tion of the workplace. With clearly definedgoals and objectives and mandates to adhereto these standards, teachers understand whatis expected of them, are protected from capri-cious directives from administrators that maydistract them from these goals, and can relatenegotiated contract provisions, such as classsize reduction, to the achievement of thesestandards. But teachers believe that standards-

based accountability intrudes into their auton-omy in the classroom. It dictates curriculumand the tests that the teacher should adminis-ter, and it establishes the outcomes that are ex-pected. The first two items—curriculum andtesting—have normally been outside the im-mediate discretion of teachers, althoughteachers do participate in their design and im-plementation. The third—being held account-able for student outcomes—is the major pointof contention. Teachers believe that such ac-countability can expose them to arbitrarytreatment by administrators and make themresponsible for things outside their immediatecontrol. They also believe it can base compen-sation on ambiguous criteria.57 The few teach-ers associations that have adopted accountabil-ity systems linked to pay have opted tomaintain some control over determining ob-jectives and how outcomes are measured.

The Effectiveness of Accountability and Incentive PayBetween the mid-1990s, when Denver firstpursued a performance-based compensationsystem, and 2004, when it approved it, nearlyevery state implemented a school accounta-bility program with the help and encourage-ment of the federal government, althoughmost have not been linked directly to teach-ers’ pay. For the most part, then, the questionof whether teachers unions will agree to suchaccountability systems is moot, because theyare imposed by state and federal laws. Thequestion is how effective these programs are,particularly when they are imposed and notnecessarily agreed to by teachers.

According to a recent study by Julian Bettsand Anne Danenberg, these programs arebased on three elements: content standardsthat mandate what students should know andwhen they should know it; an assessment sys-tem that tracks the progress of students in

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

188 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 188

meeting the state standards; and a set of re-sponses by the state that may include finan-cial incentives, penalties, sanctions, or addi-tional resources.58 As the authors point out,supporters of such a system argue that mak-ing school performance more transparent tothe public, including parents, can put neededpressure on schools to perform better. Propo-nents claim that schools will be forced to im-prove their operations and that teachers willbe more productive when presented withwell-defined goals and held accountablethrough close scrutiny of their adherence tothese goals and a carefully designed system ofconsequences.

But critics point out that state standards maybe unfair both to affluent districts with highexpectations for their students and to low-income districts that lack adequate school-and home-based resources to meet studentneeds. For instance, they argue that imposingone standard on all students and penalizingdistricts that do not meet the standard whilerewarding districts that do may divert re-sources from poor districts, which need theadditional resources, to affluent districts,which do not. A related concern is that thestate will be slow in adjusting these standardsin response to changing times or the specificneeds of selected school districts.

Critics are also concerned about the assess-ment system. Measuring a teacher’s contribu-tion to a student’s progress is difficult be-cause classrooms are not, as Gratz puts it,“scientifically controlled environments,” butare subject to outside influences beyond thecontrol of teachers.59 Furthermore, criticsworry about adverse incentives such as teach-ing to the test and focusing instruction on thenarrower content covered by tests, ratherthan offering broader topics and more in-depth treatment of the material.

States have established standards-based ac-countability systems more on principle andtheir promise than on any evidence of theireffectiveness. Evidence of the success of ear-lier accountability and incentive systems—those implemented before the recent adop-tion of high-stakes testing and accompanyingincentive systems by states and the federalgovernment—does not offer strong support.Even though most observers agree that it is

human nature to respond to incentives, theremay be several other factors that work againstthe effectiveness of performance measures inindividual incentive-based compensationschemes—just as they often do in the privatesector.

Four characteristics of teaching and learningin schools may reduce the effectiveness ofincentive-based compensation: the relianceon subjectively measured outcomes; theneed to perform multiple tasks during theday; the use of team teaching, where morethan one teacher is responsible for the out-come of the student or the classroom; andthe existence of multiple stakeholders withdiverse objectives.60 In addition, most schooldistricts have little control over their rev-enue streams and cannot offer the sizable in-creases in compensation necessary to enticeteachers to put forth the extra effort and to

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 189

States have establishedstandards-based account-ability systems more onprinciple and their promisethan on any evidence of theireffectiveness.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 189

assume the added risk inherent in a meritpay system.

The net result of all these forces remains anempirical issue. Yet little empirical evidencehas been collected on the effects of merit payon student achievement. Most of the earlyexperiences with merit pay systems in schooldistricts were rather short-lived and usuallynegative. For example, one major studyfound that 75 percent of merit pay programsthat had been in existence in 1983 were nolonger operational in 1993. An interestingself-described limitation of this study is thatit did not examine student achievement. Itsauthors note: “We would especially haveliked to have performed an in-depth analysisof the impact of incentive programs on stu-dent achievement. However, very few of theparticipating districts had attempted any sys-tematic evaluation of the effects of their in-centive plans on student achievement, eventhough a basic assumption behind incentiveplans is that teachers can indeed significantlyaffect learning.”61

A study of a Pennsylvania district found nogains in student achievement from a bonussystem.62 An analysis of Dallas’s perform-ance-based system found an increase of 10 to12 percent in the pass rate on selectedstatewide tests.63

A recent evaluation of California’s school ac-countability program, carried out by Bettsand Danenberg, offers a more positive assess-ment of the effects of incentives.64 The pro-gram, enacted in 1999, was based on highlyspecific and comprehensive standards, a newnorm-referenced statewide test and highschool exit exam, and a complex series of re-wards and punishments for school staff andstudents. Betts and Danenberg analyze recenttrends in test scores and school resources and

find two particularly important trends: testscores have risen significantly since imple-mentation of the accountability program,whereas instructional resources have de-clined. Both trends are particularly evidentfor the lowest-performing schools. In theirview, the accountability reforms and publicscrutiny have spurred genuine growth inachievement. They recognize that the pat-terns are consistent with teaching to the testor a growing familiarity with the tests andtesting process, possibilities that detract fromthe success of the program. Nonetheless, theyfind that testing and related aspects of ac-countability have neither diluted the highschool curriculum nor widened inequality be-tween top- and bottom-performing schools.

Donald Gratz, the evaluator of the DenverIncentive Program, concludes that a “systemthat attempts to closely measure and regulateinstruction provides negative, rather thanpositive incentives,” and that a complex sys-tem that tries to capture results in a singletest score fails to meet its objective of im-proving education.65 Gratz does not dismissstandards. On the contrary, he contends thatclearly identified goals with which all partiesare familiar and lessons and assessments de-signed to achieve these goals are a major ad-vance over previous methods used by the dis-trict. Adopting standards that help teachersfocus on lessons they want students to learn,aligning their teaching to these lessons, anddevising measurements that demonstratethat students are responding to them can im-prove teaching. The message of the Denverexperiment, as echoed in the private sector, isthat a system of accountability needs to cap-ture the contribution of employees to the en-tire bottom line. For schools, such a systemmust acknowledge the complexity of thelearning process and the broad outcomes thatsociety desires.

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

190 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 190

Katharine Boudett, Elizabeth City, andRichard Murnane set out similar standardsfor effective schools. Effective schools have“a coherent instructional program well-aligned with strong standards,” and in theseschools “a community of adults committed toworking together to develop the skills andknowledge of all students . . . have figuredout how to find time to do this work and areacquiring the skills to do it well.”66

There is a clear consensus that public educa-tion must be reformed. What is less clear ishow to reform it. Evaluations of two reformefforts—accountability and incentive pay—show some signs of promise, but do not pro-vide sufficiently convincing evidence of theireffectiveness to elicit a groundswell of sup-port from either union or nonunion schooldistricts. In many instances, school reforminitiatives have merely nibbled at the edgesof the broader issues confronting improve-ments in school quality. The lessons learnedfrom several attempts at accountability warnagainst adopting the narrow approach of link-ing teacher incentive pay directly to studenttest scores. They point instead to the abilityto define and articulate the goals of educa-tion and align resources to accomplish thosegoals. Under current collective bargaininglaws, for teachers and administrators to movetoward more comprehensive reform, negotia-tions must allow for more shared responsibil-ities and greater flexibility in trying new ap-proaches and responding to the students’needs. Restrictive provisions, such as class as-signment based on a teacher’s seniority andthe rigid allocation of time among daily activ-ities, must be replaced with provisions thatallow for shared decisionmaking and budget-ing between teachers and administrators,flexibility in the use of time, professional de-velopment, and peer assistance and review.Some teachers unions—but only a few—have

negotiated these items into their contracts.Some states, however, do not allow certainitems, such as class size restrictions or classassignment based on seniority, to go unmen-tioned in the contract, and some do not allowteachers to evaluate their own peers andshare in decisions reserved for management.Therefore, state laws may also need to bechanged before teachers unions and adminis-trators can negotiate more reform-mindedcontracts.67

The Future of the New Unionismand School ReformReturning to the question posed in thetitle—have unions been a help or a hindranceto student achievement?—average studentsappear not to have been harmed by attendingunion schools. If anything, the performanceof average students on standardized tests isslightly higher, but below- and above-averagestudents fare worse. Still, the overall increasein productivity does not offset the highercosts of unionized districts. Furthermore,teachers unions reduce the discretion of ad-ministrators, impose rigid standards, and re-allocate school expenditures toward highercompensation and greater employment andaway from resources for specialized and en-hanced instruction.

A broader question is whether unions willhelp or hinder school reform. And to thatquestion, the answer remains unclear andspeculative. Ask the public, and the responseis divided evenly. The last time the Phi DeltaKappa/Gallup poll posed that question, 27percent responded that unions helped, 26percent said that they hurt, and 37 percentsaid they made no difference.68 Ask the ex-perts, and one receives strong arguments oneither side. Proponents argue that only bybringing teachers fully into the process canreform succeed; opponents claim that once

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 191

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 191

shared decisionmaking makes its way intocollective bargaining contracts, flexibility islost, reform initiatives are stifled, and atten-tion soon shifts from what is right for the stu-dents to whether school administrators haveadhered to the contract.69

Yet ask the teachers and administrators ofschool districts—union or not—who havepursued reform to improve the quality of ed-

ucation, and one finds stakeholders who un-derstand the complexity of the educationalprocess and recognize the need to build anorganization that can deliver high-quality ed-ucation. Too often school reform takes a sim-ple and naïve approach—if only teacherswere held accountable, if only teachers werepaid for their performance, if only studentsand parents were given a choice in schools, ifonly unions were disbanded, then the qualityof the educational system would vastly im-prove. Obviously, there are teachers who arenot accountable, not working to their full po-tential, and hiding behind the protection ofunions. There are unions that put teachersbefore students and stand in the way of im-proving the quality of education. The truth isthat we know little about what works andwhat does not in the current reform move-ment. What we do know, however, is that ed-ucation is a complex process that defies sim-

ple approaches. Effective schools are nothoneycombs of individual autonomous class-rooms, but rather well-designed and well-executed systems and processes.

Can unions fit into that type of environment?Can administrations and school boards? Toboth questions, the answer is that some canand have but many have not. The problemlies in the inability of many to identify theirpurpose, set goals and objectives, align re-sources and policies with them, and find theexpertise and leadership to carry them out.Attempts at reform have come and gone withlittle progress in school improvement. In re-cent years, the leadership of both majorteachers unions has shared the concern aboutthe deteriorating quality of education and hascalled for more teacher participation and col-laboration. But only a few local teachersunions have initiated true reforms—at timesin the face of resistance from their nationalparent organizations. Policymakers havecalled for more accountability from teachersand administrators but have enacted an ac-countability system that makes little, if any,connection between the actions of teachersand the outcomes of their students.

While there are no quick fixes for improvingschool quality, with respect to unions and col-lective bargaining a few steps could be takenthat focus on building a high-performanceorganization. First, school districts need or-ganizational role models, leadership, and re-sources. Second, union leadership and theteacher membership need to realign theirfocus and attitudes by assuming more re-sponsibility for the outcomes of their stu-dents. Third, administrators and schoolboards must affirm the importance of teach-ers as stakeholders in the educational processand recognize, as high-performance schooldistricts have, that a high-performing work-

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

192 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

Effective schools are nothoneycombs of individualautonomous classrooms, butrather well-designed andwell-executed systems andprocesses.

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 192

force requires a culture of teamwork and anunderstanding of what it takes to retain qual-ity teachers. Fourth, teachers and administra-tors must work together to determine goalsand objectives, and once established, alignresources and activities to achieve them.Fifth, once resources and activities arealigned, a set of measures must be devisedand used by the management team (whichwould include teachers and union leaders) tomeasure the performance of students and thelevel of satisfaction and professional growthof teachers and other staff. If properly imple-mented and followed, the goals and objec-tives and the monitoring system could serve

teachers much as collective bargaining provi-sions do now.

Finally, teachers unions must embrace thetenets of the new unionism and actively pur-sue them in their collaboration with districts.This means that teachers must be willing tomove away from the security of their con-tracts and assume, with the administration, ajoint responsibility for schooling. With em-powerment must come responsibility, andonly through systems of accountability inwhich risk is recognized and accepted canreal progress be made in improving the edu-cation of the nation’s children.

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 193

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 193

Notes

1. According to a Phi Delta Kappa/Gallup Poll (September 2003), 75 percent of respondents favored reform-

ing the existing system, whereas 23 percent favored promoting alternative systems.

2. Helen Raham, “Teacher Bargaining Today and Tomorrow,” School Business Affairs 65, no. 4 (1999): 24–27.

3. National Commission on Excellence in Education, A Nation at Risk: The Imperative for Educational Re-

form, A Report to the Nation and the Secretary of Education (U.S. Department of Education, 1983).

4. Robert Chase, “The New NEA: Reinventing Teachers Unions for a New Era,” remarks before the National

Press Club, Washington, February 5, 1997, www.nea.org/nr/sp970205.html (March 11, 2002).

5. John Dunlop, Industrial Relations System (New York: Holt, 1958).

6. Sewall Gilbert, “Teachers’ Unions and the Issue of Academic Standards,” Wall Street Journal, January 6,

1983.

7. Harry H. Wellington and Ralph K. Winter, “The Limits of Collective Bargaining in Public Employment,”

Yale Law Journal 77, no. 7 (1969).

8. To estimate union representation, I used the Outgoing Rotation Group of the Current Population Survey

(CPS) for the years 1996–2005. I included a decade of data to ensure a large enough sample. Teachers

were defined as local government employees who had occupation codes 155–59 for the period 1996–2002

and occupation codes 2300–40 in 2003–05. Following Barry T. Hirsch and David A. Macpherson, “Union

Membership and Coverage Files from the Current Population Surveys: Note,” Industrial and Labor Rela-

tions Review 46, no. 3 (April 1993): 574–78, I consider two questions from the CPS. One question relates

to membership: “On this job are you a member of a labor union or of an employee association similar to a

union?” Those who answered no to this question were asked: “On this job, are you covered by a union or

employees association contract?” Therefore, the inference from the first question is that those answering

yes are members of a union or employee association that negotiates a contract and are covered under that

collective bargaining contract. Nationally, 61 percent report that they are members of a union and another

6 percent report that they are not members but are covered under a collective bargaining agreement. In-

terestingly, the two regions with the lowest percentage of membership and coverage—East South Central

and West South Central—have the highest percentage of teachers who are covered but not members (11

percent and 10 percent, respectively). Of course, since this is self-reporting, there may be biases in the re-

sponses, as discussed by Edward C. Kokkelenberg and Donna R. Sockell, “Union Membership in the

United States, 1973–81,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 38, no. 4 (July 1985): 497–543.

9. Bruce S. Cooper, “Collective Bargaining, Strikes, and Financial Costs in Public Education: A Comparative

Review” (Clearinghouse on Educational Management, University of Oregon, 1982).

10. Ibid.; and Steve M. Goldschmidt, “An Overview of the Evolution of Collective Bargaining and Its Impact

on Education,” Proceedings of a Conference on the Effects of Collective Bargaining on School Administra-

tive Leadership (University of Oregon, Center for Educational Policy and Management, 1982).

11. The turning point may have been AFT’s major victory in organizing New York City teachers in 1961. M.O.

Donley Jr., Power to the Teacher: How America’s Educators Became Militant (Indiana University Press,

1976), describes it as probably the biggest single success in the history of teacher organizing in the United

States.

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

194 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 194

12. Susan Moore Johnson and Susan M. Kardos, “Reform Bargaining and Its Promise for School Improve-

ment,” in Conflicting Missions? Teachers Unions and Educational Reform, edited by Tom Loveless (Brook-

ings, 2000), pp. 7–46.

13. Chase, “The New NEA” (see note 4).

14. This section relies heavily on Randall W. Eberts and Joe A. Stone, Unions and Public Schools: The Effect of

Collective Bargaining on American Education (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1984). While this re-

search examines the effects of teacher collective bargaining during the late 1970s, its relevance to more

current times is supported by more recent research that follows similar methodology and finds similar re-

sults. Dan Goldhaber, “Are Teachers Unions Good for Students?” in Collective Bargaining in Education:

Negotiating Change in Today’s Schools, edited by Joan Hannaway and Andrew Rotherham (Cambridge,

Mass.: Harvard Education Press, 2006), pp. 141–57, in a recent review of the literature of the effects of

teacher collective bargaining on student achievement, states that “there is relatively little research that di-

rectly links unionization and student achievement” (p.142). Furthermore, there is even less research that

attempts to provide a comprehensive analysis of the various aspects of teachers unions and the multiple

ways in which collective bargaining may affect student achievement. A reasonable benchmark to determine

teachers’ success at the bargaining table is the private sector. Richard B. Freeman and James L. Medoff,

What Do Unions Do? (New York: Basic Books, 1984), offer a useful perspective from the effects of unions

in the private sector on pay and benefits, working conditions, cost of instruction, and productivity.

15. For instance, a provision on class size is found in many contracts and allowed by state laws. However,

whether class size is a district average or a cap on any specific class, and the action taken after the class size

limit has been exceeded, depends on the strength of the local union in negotiating those provisions. The

enforcement of class size restrictions varies across bargaining units. For example, Susan Moore Johnson

and Morgaen Donaldson, “The Effects of Collective Bargaining on Teacher Quality,” in Collective Bargain-

ing in Education: Negotiating Change in Today’s Schools, edited by Hannaway and Rotherham (see note

14), pp. 111–40, report that the collective bargaining agreement in Branford, Connecticut, requires a new

class after class size is exceeded by more than two students, whereas the teacher contract in Lowell, Mass-

achusetts, states that the administration will work in good faith to reduce class size when contracts become

available.

16. Henry Farber, “Union Membership in the United States: The Divergence between the Public and Private

Sectors,” in Collective Bargaining in Education: Negotiating Change in Today’s Schools, edited by Hann-

away and Rotherham (see note 14), pp. 27–51.

17. Heather Rose and Jon Sonstelie, “School Board Politics, School District Size, and the Bargaining Power of

Teachers Unions,” Working Paper (San Francisco: Public Policy Institute of California, May 2006), hypoth-

esize that teachers unions will be more powerful in large districts than in small ones. Their analysis of Cal-

ifornia school districts shows that the salaries of teachers, as a measure of a union’s success in collective bar-

gaining, are positively related to the number of eligible voters in the jurisdiction.

18. Paul Courant and others, “Public Employee Market Power and the Level of Government Spending,”

American Economic Review 69, no. 5 (1979): 806–17, show that in states where local school districts may

raise their own tax revenues by raising local taxes, teachers unions may also use their political power to en-

courage local voters to support tax increases. On the other hand, Daniel Hoskins and David Margolis, “The

Efficiency of Collective Bargaining in Public Schools,” Working Paper (U.S. Federal Trade Commission,

December 1997), find that teachers unions operating in areas where school boards must have their budget

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 195

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 195

approved by popular referendum tend to have significantly lower bargaining power than their counterparts

in which the budget is implemented without being subject to public approval.

19. As a labor organization, a teachers union is not permitted to use member dues for political actions. How-

ever, members can voluntarily contribute to a political action committee, which is typically set up by the

state affiliate of the local bargaining units for the purpose of political activism and fundraising to elect can-

didates who share the same goals as the teachers union. For example, the political action committee of the

Michigan Education Association, the NEA-affiliated teachers union in Michigan, collected $1 million from

25,000 of its 160,000 members during the first half of 2006, an election year.

20. Eberts and Stone, Unions and Public Schools (see note 14).

21. William H. Baugh and Joe A. Stone, “Teachers, Unions, and Wages in the 1970s: Unionism Now Pays,” In-

dustrial and Labor Relations Review 35 (1982): 368–6; and Caroline M. Hoxby, “How Teachers Unions Af-

fect Education Production,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111 (1996): 671–718. Morris Kleiner and D.

L. Petree, “Unionism and Licensing of Public School Teachers: Impact on Wages and Educational Out-

put,” in When Public Sector Workers Unionize, edited by Richard B. Freeman and Casey Ichniowski (Uni-

versity of Chicago Press, 1988), pp. 305–19, find only a small differential, but rely on aggregate data with

few controls.

22. Evidence in sectors other than education suggests that pay and fringe benefits for union workers typically

exceed those of nonunion workers. While the magnitude of the differential can vary from one sector to an-

other, Freeman and Medoff, What Do Unions Do? (see note 14), pp. 47, 67–68, find that the union pay dif-

ferential is typically 8 to 10 percent higher for “identical” workers and the differential for fringe benefits is

even higher.

23. Eberts and Stone, Unions and Public Schools (see note 14).

24. Ibid.

25. Ibid. Eberts and Stone, relying on national data from the Sustaining Effects Survey of elementary schools,

find that the student-teacher ratio is nearly 12 percent lower for union teachers. Kleiner and Petree,

“Unionism and Licensing of Public School Teachers” (see note 21), p. 316, using state-level data, also find

lower (7 percent) student-teacher ratios for union teachers. Similarly, Hoxby, “How Teachers Unions Affect

Education Production” (see note 21), p. 695, uses district-level data and finds a decline of about 9 percent

in her preferred specification.

26. Eberts and Stone, Unions and Public Schools (see note 14), p. 156.

27. Ibid., pp. 119–20, 143–44.

28. In some exceptional cases, total costs of unionized production are lower at very large scales of integrated

operations, as found, for example, by Steven G. Allen, “Unionization and Productivity in Office Building

and School Construction,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 39 (1986): 187–201, in construction; and

Wesley W. Wilson, Joe A. Stone, and M. C. Mitchell, “Product Selection and Costs in a Partially Unionized

Industry,” Journal of Labor Research 16 (1995): 81–95, in sawmills.

29. Jay G. Chambers, “The Impact of Collective Bargaining for Teachers on Resource Allocation in Public

School Districts,” Journal of Urban Economics 4 (1977): 324–39; and W. C. Hall and N. Carroll, “The Ef-

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

196 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 196

fect of Teachers’ Organizations on Salaries and Class Size,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 28

(1975): 834–41.

30. Randall W. Eberts and Joe A. Stone, “Teachers Unions and the Cost of Public Education,” Economic In-

quiry 24 (1986): 631–44.

31. Hoxby, “How Teachers Unions Affect Education Production” (see note 21).

32. Lorraine M. McDonnell and Anthony Pascal, Organized Teachers in American Schools (Santa Monica,

Calif.: RAND, 1979), p. 83.

33. Eberts and Stone, Unions and Public Schools (see note 14).

34. Studies of unions and productivity include John H. Pencavel, “The Distribution and Efficiency Effects of

Trade Unions in Britain,” British Journal of Industrial Relations 40 (1977): 137–56, for British coal fields;

Kim B. Clark, “Unionization and Productivity: Micro-Econometric Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Eco-

nomics 95 (1980): 613–39, for cement producers; and Ronald G. Ehrenberg and others, “Unions and Pro-

ductivity in the Public Sector: A Study of Municipal Libraries,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 36

(1983): 199–213.

35. Susanna Loeb and Marianne Page, “Examining the Link between Teacher Wages and Student Outcomes:

The Importance of Alternative Labor Market Opportunities and Non-Pecuniary Variation,” Review of Eco-

nomics and Statistics 82, no. 3 (2000): 393–408.

36. Johnson and Donaldson, “The Effects of Collective Bargaining” (see note 15).

37. See Daniel Aaronson, Lisa Barrow, and William Sander, “Teachers and Student Achievement in the

Chicago Public High Schools,” paper presented at the Labor Market Policy/Princeton Industrial Relations

Section Tenth Annual Policy Conference sponsored by the University of Chicago, DePaul University, the

University of Illinois, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 2003; and Steven Rivkin, Eric Hanushek,

and John Kain, “Teachers, Schools, and Academic Achievement,” Econometrica 73, no. 2 (2005): 417–58.

38. Kleiner and Petree, “Unionism and Licensing of Public School Teachers” (see note 21); F. H. Nelson and

M. Rosen, “Are Teachers Unions Hurting American Education? A State-by-State Analysis of the Impact of

Collective Bargaining among Teachers on Student Performance,” Technical Report (Milwaukee: Institute

for Wisconsin’s Future, 1996); Lala C. Steelman, Brian Powell, and Robert M. Carini, “Do Teachers

Unions Hinder Educational Performance?” Harvard Educational Review 70, no. 4 (2000): 437–66.

39. Kleiner and Petree, “Unionism and Licensing of Public School Teachers” (see note 21).

40. These studies include Randall W. Eberts and Joe A. Stone, “Teachers Unions and the Productivity of Pub-

lic Schools,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 40 (1987): 354–63; Martin I. Milkman, “Teachers

Unions, Productivity, and Minority Student Achievement,” Journal of Labor Research 18 (1997): 247–50; P.

W. Grimes and C. A. Register, “Teachers Unions and Student Achievement in High School Economics,”

Journal of Economic Education 21 (1990): 297–308; and L. M. Argys and D. I. Rees, “Unionization and

School Productivity: A Re-examination,” Research in Labor Economics 14, edited by S. Polachek (Green-

wich, Conn.: JAI Press, 1995): 49–68.

41. Sam Peltzman, “Political Economy of Public Education: Non-College-Bound Students,” Journal of Law

and Economics 39 (1996): 73–120, also found negative effects of unions on low-achieving students. He

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 197

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 197

used state-level data over several years, and his analysis may therefore be subject to the same estimation bi-

ases found in Kleiner and Petree and others using highly disaggregated data. It should also be mentioned

that the effects of unions on these students varied over the period.

42. Hoxby, “How Teachers Unions Affect Education Production” (see note 21). H. L. Zwerling and T. Thoma-

son, “The Effects of Teachers Unions on the Probability of Dropping Out of High School,” Journal of Col-

lective Negotiations 23 (1994): 239–50, also examined the effect of unions on dropout rates but found

mixed results. Male students in union districts had lower dropout rates than those in nonunion districts, but

female students did not. However, their controls for factors that could bias the estimates were not as exten-

sive as Hoxby’s.

43. Both groups use difference-in-differences techniques to control for unobservable time-invariant factors.

The student-level studies, such as Eberts and Stone and Milkman, use pre- and post-test score data, which

in essence controls for student, class, parental, and district factors that may affect student achievement but

do not vary over time. They also include a long list of explicit factors that affect student achievement.

Hoxby does not control for student characteristics through differencing, but does include an abbreviated

list of factors in her estimation. She uses a difference-in-differences and instrumental variables approach to

control for unobservable and steadily trending school and state characteristics that may affect both educa-

tional outcomes and the decision to unionize. Eberts and Stone also use instrumental variables to control

for underlying factors that may cause teachers to organize.

44. Lawrence Mishel and Joydeep Roy, Rethinking High School Graduation Rates and Trends (Washington:

EPI Press, April 2006), have compiled a list of issues regarding the measurement of high school dropout

rates and their use as a measure of student achievement.

45. One study, for example, finds that even within the traditional organization of classroom instruction, the use

of hourly tutors for selected students improves student performance, especially among disadvantaged stu-

dents. G. Farkas, “Structuring Tutoring for At Risk Children in the Early Years,” Applied Behavioral Sci-

ence Review 1 (1993): 69–2.

46. Argys and Rees, “Unionization and School Productivity” (see note 40). Studies have found differential ef-

fects of union schools on minorities. Both Milkman and Grimes and Register (see note 40) find that African

Americans do better in union than nonunion districts. Furthermore, Milkman finds that the union effect

on minorities depends on the level of racial diversity in the school.

47. Johnson and Kardos, “Reform Bargaining” (see note 12).

48. Lorraine McDonnell and Anthony Pascal, “Teachers Unions and Educational Reform,” Center for Policy

Research in Education (Santa Monica, Calif.: RAND, 1988).

49. Johnson and Kardos, “Reform Bargaining” (see note 12).

50. Al Shanker, the long-time president of the AFT, was regarded by many as a champion of educational re-

form among the union movement. Like his later counterpart in the NEA, Robert Chase, Shanker believed

that the future of public education and teacher collective bargaining depended on teachers unions taking

more of a leadership role. Shanker died in 1997, the year in which Chase made his National Press Club

speech. His successors, however, did not pursue the reform effort with the same fervor, according to Julia

Koppich, “The As-Yet-Unfulfilled Promise of Reform Bargaining: Forging a Better Match between the

Labor Relations System We Have and the Education System We Want,” in Collective Bargaining in Edu-

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

198 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 198

cation: Negotiating Change in Today’s Schools, edited by Hannaway and Rotherham (see note 14), pp.

203–27.

51. Charles Kerchner and Julia Koppich, “Organizing around Quality: The Struggle to Organize Mind Work-

ers,” in Teachers Unions and Education Policy: Retrenchment or Reform? edited by Ronald Henderson,

Wayne Urban, and Paul Wolman (London: Elsevier, 2004), pp. 187–221.

52. Koppich, “The As-Yet-Unfulfilled Promise of Reform Bargaining” (see note 50).

53. Kerchner and Koppich, “Organizing around Quality” (see note 51).

54. Christine Murray, “Innovative Local Teachers Unions: What Have They Accomplished?” in Teachers

Unions and Education Policy: Retrenchment or Reform? edited by Henderson, Urban, and Wolman (see

note 51), pp. 149–66.

55. J. Archer, “Districts Targeting Teacher Seniority in Union Contracts,” Education Week, April 12, 2000.

56. Donald Gratz, “Lessons from Denver: The Pay for Performance Pilot,” Phi Delta Kappan 86, no. 8 (April

2005).

57. Johnson and Kardos, “Reform Bargaining” (see note 12).

58. Julian Betts and Anne Danenberg, “School Accountability in California: An Early Evaluation,” Brookings

Papers on Education Policy (2002).

59. Gratz, “Lessons from Denver” (see note 56).

60. In this discussion I rely heavily on arguments presented in Richard J. Murnane and David K. Cohen,

“Merit Pay and the Evaluation Problem: Why Most Merit Pay Plans Fail and a Few Survive,” Harvard Ed-

ucational Review 56, no. 1 (1986): 1–17. The analysis by Avinash Dixit, “Incentives and Organizations in

the Public Sector: An Interpretative Review,” Journal of Human Resources 37, no. 4 (Fall 2002): 696–727,

of incentives in education also coincides closely with ours. Dixit suggests four complications that confound

the simple “principal-agent” model of implicit contracting in educational settings: multiple goals, multiple

principals, lack of competition in the product market, and agents motivated by intrinsic values.

61. Harry P. Hatry, John M. Greiner, and Brenda G. Ashford, Issues and Case Studies in Teacher Incentive

Plans, 2nd ed. (Washington: Urban Institute Press, 1994). Murnane and Cohen, “Merit Pay and the Evalu-

ation Problem” (see note 60), also emphasize the short-lived nature of merit pay systems.

62. Dennis J. Tulli, “An Assessment of Student Achievement before and during a Merit Pay Program for

Teachers of the Penn Manor School District,” Ed.D. diss. (Temple University, 1999).

63. Charles Clotfelter and Helen Ladd, “Recognizing and Rewarding Success in Public Schools,” in Holding

Schools Accountable, Performance-Based Reform in Education, edited by Helen F. Ladd (Brookings,

1996), pp. 23–63. Unfortunately, the study did not use a true control group and there was a similar rate of

improvement in the year prior to the implementation of the performance-based system. In contrast, Can-

dice Prendergast, “The Provision of Incentives in Firms,” Journal of Economic Literature 37 (1999): 7–63,

documents that private sector businesses reward workers more through promotions and group-based merit

systems, such as gain sharing or profit sharing, than through individual merit rewards.

64. Betts and Danenberg, “School Accountability in California” (see note 58).

Te a c h e r s U n i o n s a n d S t u d e n t P e r f o r m a n c e : H e l p o r H i n d r a n c e ?

V O L . 1 7 / N O. 1 / S P R I N G 2 0 0 7 199

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 199

65. Gratz, “Lessons from Denver” (see note 56).

66. Kathryn Parker Boudett, Elizabeth A. City, and Richard J. Murnane, eds, Data Wise: A Step-by-Step Guide

to Using Assessment Results to Improve Teaching and Learning (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Education

Press, 2005).

67. Courts have interpreted the National Labor Relations Act to reserve functions such as peer review, curricu-

lum development, resource allocation, and assessment as the sole prerogative of management, not labor.

The Yeshiva University case, which went before the U.S. Supreme Court, denied faculty collective bargain-

ing rights on the grounds that they exercise managerial decisions in their determination of tenure and the

promotion of other faculty members. Some states, such as California, have passed legislation to circumvent

this law and allow members of a bargaining unit to participate in decisions as listed above.

68. Phi Delta Kappa/Gallup Poll, September 1998.

69. Sandra Black, “Reforming the Unions,” American School Board Journal (February 2002), offers several of

these critical points.

R a n d a l l W. E b e r t s

200 T H E F U T U R E O F C H I L D R E N

09 5564-7 Eberts.qxp 1/15/2007 10:17 PM Page 200