technology, innovation and economic growth in britain

31
Copyright © 2012 by Tom Nicholas Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author. Technology, Innovation and Economic Growth in Britain Since 1870 Tom Nicholas Working Paper 13-032 September 19, 2012

Upload: others

Post on 04-Nov-2021

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Copyright © 2012 by Tom Nicholas

Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author.

Technology, Innovation and Economic Growth in Britain Since 1870 Tom Nicholas

Working Paper

13-032 September 19, 2012

Technology, Innovation and Economic Growth in Britain Since 1870

[Prepared for the Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain]

Tom Nicholas*

Harvard Business School

September, 2012

Abstract

This chapter examines technological change in Britain over the last 140 years. It analyzes the effects of patent laws and innovation prizes that were designed to promote technical progress. It explores the challenge associated with the changing organizational structure of innovation and the shift from independent invention to R&D activity taking place inside the boundaries of firms. And it also studies the development of British industrial science in universities and efforts to promote innovation through the formation of industry clusters. Overall, the evidence supports the traditional story of British failure in generating large payoffs from technological development. Although from the early 1970s Britain experienced a revival in the quality of innovation and improved productivity growth, structural weaknesses in the commercialization environment still remain.

* Soldiers Field Road, Boston, MA 02163, USA. [email protected]. I am very grateful to Steve Broadberry, David Chambers, Nick Crafts, Paul Johnson, Jonathan Michie, Avner Offer and conference participants at All Souls College, Oxford for many helpful comments and suggestions. I thank Teresa Amabile for providing funding via Harvard Business School’s Division of Research.

2

1. Introduction

Economic growth can be driven in the short run by factor accumulation or by utilizing factors

more efficiently, but permanent increases can only result from technological innovation. Given

Britain’s loss of industrial preeminence from the late nineteenth century, an absence in new

technology formation is as natural an explanation for British failure as cultural interpretations

that emphasize a weakness of the industrial spirit (Weiner, 1981). While Britain was the first

“workshop of the world” its lagging position behind the technology frontier during the drive to

industrial maturity is a topic of some debate in economic history. Accounts of technological

progress during industrialization emphasize that Britain’s rise was defined by capabilities in a

broad array of industries and by a culturally enlightened and technically competent stock of

human capital that could translate new ideas from home, or abroad, into commercially viable

innovations (Mokyr, 1999, 2002, 2010). What changed the trajectory of technological change in

Britain from this high-point of early economic development?

This chapter examines the hypothesis that Britain has failed technologically. It provides a

statistical portrait of innovation over the last 140 years and it then focuses on three main areas of

explanation for Britain’s historical innovation performance. First, it analyzes incentives for

technological development, specifically British patent law and efforts to induce innovators using

inducement prizes as an alternative or complementary mechanism. Second, it explores the

organizational structure of innovation in Britain and R&D performance. Finally, it examines

public policy efforts to promote industrial science and innovation clusters.

The data strongly support the argument that Britain has historically been lackluster

technologically as other industrial nations began to catch up during the late nineteenth and early

twentieth century. Some of this decline was inevitable given that advancing countries, especially

the United States, had larger markets which promoted demand-induced innovation, larger

populations leading to a greater supply of human capital for invention, or deeper capital markets

to promote investment. But other aspects of decline were related to structural factors such as the

lack of competition in product markets and the relative absence of creative destruction as

disciplinary mechanisms to promote the efficiency of firms.

The data also reveal that Britain has experienced a renaissance in the quality of technological

development from the early 1970s. This is consistent with the hypothesis that this period

witnessed a positive change in the growth rate of productivity and the end of Britain’s relative

3

economic decline (Crafts, 2012). However, recent advances in productivity did not lead to

performance gaps in the ability to manage innovation being fully overcome. In fact, managerial

failures in small and large firms still act as a barrier to the widespread adoption of best-practice

techniques (Bloom and Van Reenen, 2007; Bloom, Sadun and Van Reenen, 2012). Although

Britain has a long tradition of excellence in the production of scientific knowledge, factors like

weak management have stifled the rate at which new innovations have been commercialized.

2. Measuring Technological Change

A. Productivity Statistics

It is well-established in growth models that innovation is a main engine of economic

development, but despite a glut of research in the area, technological change is still difficult to

measure empirically. In growth accounting, the Solow residual is a measure of (among other

things) technological progress, but as Abramovitz (1956, p.11) famously put it, it is really a

“measure of our ignorance” and even more so if the inputs into TFP calculations are measured

with error, as they tend to be historically. Yet, with advances in data and methodology, it is

possible to make clear conclusions about Britain’s productivity performance. Britain was

outperformed by the United States and Germany during the early twentieth century; it fell behind

European countries during the “golden age” of economic growth between 1950 and 1973; but a

strong recovery occurred thereafter (Crafts, 2012). Because technology and productivity are

inextricably intertwined, this implies a strong recent innovation performance. Consequently it is

useful to analyze additional indicators to explore how productivity may be related to underlying

measures of technological change.

B. Patents and Patent Citations

Innovation surveys offer new insights into the boundaries between “technology” and

“innovation” and differences between product versus process innovation (e.g. Michie, 1998), but

they are only available systematically for recent years. Patent and R&D data, by contrast, are

more readily available over the long run and are commonly used as primary indicators of

technological change (Griliches, 1990). Figure 1 shows the number of patents per thousand of

population granted in Britain, the United States, Germany and France from the late nineteenth

century up to the present. Much of the change in British patenting, and indeed patenting in other

countries, can be explained by changes in patent laws. For example, the large drop in the number

4

of patents granted in the late 1970s reflects more stringent novelty tests that were applied by the

British Patent Office under the 1977 Patents Act, which represented a first step towards

harmonizing patent standards across Europe. While the United States appears to have witnessed

an increase in patents per capita in recent years, especially relative to European countries,

measurement of this effect on a per capita basis is confounded by the fact that this period was

also associated with a rise in the number of patents granted in the United States to inventors from

overseas (Nicholas, 2011, p.801). Separating out domestic from foreign inventor patents, Khan

(2011, p.774) finds that patent per capita for domestic inventors were far higher in the early

twentieth century compared to at the end.

Figure 2 provides a more informative set of comparisons because it focuses on patenting

activity by inventors in a single country – the United States – where the effects of patent laws

remained largely the same for inventors from different countries. U.S. patent law required that

the first true inventor be listed on the patent document. Accordingly, the data reflect the

addresses of inventors residing overseas who were granted patents by the United States Patent

and Trademark Office between 1870 and 2005. British inventors accounted for the highest share

of foreign patentees up to 1900, but thereafter the share dropped and hovered at between 2 and 4

percent for the rest of the time period, with Britain’s trajectory from the early 1980s up to the

end of the period being closely synchronized with that of France. Noticeably, the share of patents

accounted for by German inventors was severely disrupted by the First and the Second World

Wars, but an equally pronounced feature of the data is the rise in the proportion of German

inventors patenting in the United States from the 1950s up to the 1980s, which is consistent with

a superior growth performance in this country induced by structural change during the “golden

age” of European economic growth (Temin, 2002). From the 1980s all the countries shown in

Figure 2 lost share as foreign inventors from countries such as Israel, Japan and Taiwan

increasingly patented their inventions in the United States. Based on these comparisons, Britain’s

patenting performance over the long run appears weak. In 2004 the British share of foreign

patents in the U.S. was 60 percent lower than it was in 1900.

Figure 3 shows the industry distribution of patents by the major time periods for inventions

patented by British, German and French inventors in the United States, along with the

distribution of patents by U.S. domiciled inventors. During the late nineteenth and early

twentieth century British inventors patented disproportionately in mechanical-related areas,

5

perhaps reflecting expertise in equipment used in British industry as revealed in an important

study of the machine tools industry by Floud (1976). The relative dominance of patenting in

German chemicals stands out across all the time periods and mechanical patents are another area

of focus. France, like Britain, was heavily oriented towards mechanical patents prior to the First

World War and even more so during the interwar years. Interestingly, the shape distribution of

patents granted to British inventors is not dissimilar to that of patents granted to U.S. inventors

over time. In recent years much has been written about the significance of information and

communications technologies and the productivity benefits stemming from its interaction with

organizational capital. From 1974 to 2004 approximately 10 percent of patents granted to

inventors from the United States, Britain and France were in ICT.

But it is well-know that patents vary significantly by their quality and therefore insights

based on raw patent counts, or their industry distribution, can be misleading. Even if inventors

patented their best technologies in the United States, it is still possible that the quality of the

inventions in the data in Figures 2 and 3 varied. A solution to this problem is to use citations that

patents receive in subsequent patents granted as a measure of their technological significance

(Trajtenberg, 1990; Nicholas, 2005) and then compare patents by citation frequency across

inventors from different countries. U.S. patent law requires that all prior art (i.e., the knowledge

on which the invention builds) is disclosed and this has been systematically recorded on patent

documents in the form of patent citations going back to 1947. This method can be used to

determine how highly cited were the U.S. patents of British inventors relative to otherwise

equivalent patents granted in the U.S. to inventors from other countries.

Table 1 reports estimates of patent citation regressions, which take the following form where

i indexes an individual patent, j a inventor’s county, k a technology category and t a year:

.YEARTECHNOLOGYCOUNTRY)CITS1(log tkji

Given the skewed nature of citations, the dependent variable is the natural logarithm of a count

of patent citations to each patent granted in year t in all patents granted in the United States

between 1947 and 2008. One is added to the citation count to rescale zero values to facilitate the

log-transformation. This variable is regressed on a set of country dummies, with Britain as a

baseline category. Technology dummies based on the United States Patent Office classification

6

scheme, as developed by Hall, Jaffe and Trajtenberg (2002), are included because citations may

reflect industry or factor endowment driven biases in the distribution of patents or citations. Year

dummies control for time effects because earlier patents receive more citations ceteris paribus

than later patents. Regressions are run using data on inventors from all countries that patented

10,000 or more inventions in the United States between 1870 and 2004. The data consist of 1.74

million patents from inventors residing in 17 countries.

Because countries enter into the data over time, it makes the most sense to examine patent

citations during four separate sub-periods: up to the First World War (1870-1918); the interwar

years (1919-1945); the Second World War and post-war years (1946-1973); and the period

associated with the end of Britain’s relative economic decline (1974-2004). The regressions are

run in semi-logarithmic form so the coefficients measure the percentage change (exp[ BRj ]-

1×100) in citations to patent i granted in the United States to an inventor in country j relative to

citations to patents by British inventors who also patented there.

Results in Table 1 for the period between 1870 to 1918 show that patents by British inventors

tended to be, in relative terms, of a lower average quality. On a patent citations basis, inventors

from Britain underperformed inventors from most countries in Europe, although it is important to

note that in absolute terms the number of patents granted to British inventors was also much

higher (Figure 2). During the interwar years, however, the share of patents granted in the United

States to German inventors increased significantly (Figure 2) and the average quality of these

inventions was also higher. Furthermore, at this time, patents by French inventors had

approximately 4 percent higher citations than patents by British inventors. During the “golden

age” of European economic growth, citations to patents by British inventors still slightly lagged

average citations to patents by German inventors, but note that British inventors outperformed

inventors from 8 out of the 13 countries on a citations basis from 1946 to 1973. Between 1974

and 2004 British inventors outperformed inventors from 13 out of 16 countries, including

Germany, with only patents to inventors from Canada, Israel and Japan receiving significantly

higher citations.1 While this evidence suggests that from the early 1970s Britain experienced a

relative increase in the quality of innovation, it is also worth pointing out that this coincided with

1 Intellectual spillovers tend to be localized geographically. Hence it would be expected that the inventions of Canadian inventors would be highly cited by patents granted in the United States. The citation premium to inventors from Israel and Japan, on the other hand, is less likely to be confounded by the effect of geography and more likely to be consistent with their technological superiority.

7

a drop in the relative share of inventions by British inventors patented in the United States

(Figure 2). In other words, the data suggest that the quality, but not the quantity, of patents was

improving.

C. R&D Investment and Human Capital

Patents are an outcome measure of innovation whereas R&D is an input measure that informs

our understanding of the scale of the resources devoted to technological change. Historical

statistics on R&D are limited, but the scant data that are available suggest that at the turn of the

twentieth century Britain was spending about 0.03 percent of GDP on R&D (Edgerton, 1996,

p.32) and over time this share increased significantly as the complexity and capital requirements

for innovation increased. During the 1990s Britain was spending about 2 percent of GDP on

R&D and the share currently stands at approximately 1.8 percent.

Yet, the history of R&D investment in Britain is typically a story of underinvestment, or

underperformance (or both) relative to international standards. Figure 4 shows that during the

1930s R&D output was less than half the level in the United States and a large gap between the

two countries persists for all of the snapshot years, whether using net output or value added as

denominators. While Britain looks better when using Germany as a benchmark, it seems

reasonable to assume that Germany was far more productive per unit of R&D input, especially

between 1945 and 1970 when the output from Britain’s research effort was relatively weak

(Horrocks, 1999). Data on research employment in Figure 5 show Britain in a more favorable

light to Germany and the United States. But while the level and the quality of British human

capital in R&D has always been high, firms have traditionally been weak at translating this

knowledge into productivity performance (Nickell and Van Reenen, 2001).

It is clear from the statistics, and the historical evidence more generally, that over the long

run competing countries had a much stronger tradition of productive R&D than did Britain. In

Germany the exemplar case is knowledge and complementary capabilities in the chemicals

industry (Murmann, 2003). Firms such as Badische Anilinund-Soda-Fabrik (BASF) and Bayer

devoted large capital resources to R&D and to incentive mechanisms so that scientists developed

the most appropriate types of new technical knowledge (Burhop and Lübbers, 2009). In the

United States interactions between technology and organization led to the institutionalization of

R&D (Mowery and Rosenberg, 1989). During the interwar period, Britain lagged even further

behind Germany and the United States, as both countries heavily invested in industrial

8

development. In the United States in-house R&D developed extensively as firms like General

Electric, Eastman Kodak and Du Pont took basic and applied science seriously, leading to

numerous breakthrough innovations such as electrical appliances, motion picture cameras and

products like neoprene (Mowery and Rosenberg, 1989).

Although during the post-Second World War period, aggregate statistics suggest that Britain

was devoting a large share of GDP to R&D this was unobservable in the growth statistics. One

explanation would be scale effects, whereby higher levels of aggregate R&D investment in

countries like the United States had a larger impact because externalities, which magnify the

impact of innovation, grow with the size of the economy. Jones (1995), however, rejects the

hypothesis of scale effects given that the number of scientists and engineers engaged in R&D in

OECD countries increased substantially from the 1950s without a simultaneous boost to

economic growth rates. Moreover, since the 1970s it is reasonable to assume that the effect of

scale would not have shifted dramatically in Britain relative to other competing nations and yet

British R&D has been particularly productive (Crafts, 2012). This implies factors other than

scale may have been more influential determinants of British R&D performance.

3. Patent Laws, and Incentives

A. Patents

Among all the explanations for Britain’s lackluster performance in the technical sphere

patent laws should, on the face of it, be a good candidate. It is well-established that the

institutional environment in which inventors and firms operate can powerfully influence both the

rate and direction of technological change (Lerner and Stern, 2012). Patents provide a short run

monopoly over the right to use an invention in order to compensate inventors for the expense

incurred to develop the invention. Publication of the idea and codification of the underlying

knowledge in a patent document is meant to encourage the diffusion of new ideas across

inventors. British patent laws have traditionally been criticized for being expensive and

cumbersome. In 1875 it was 19 times more expensive to hold a patent to full term in Britain than

it was in the United States (Lerner, 2000).

According to one dominant theme in the literature, innovation in the United States flourished

during the process of industrialization because patent laws provided cheap democratic access to

intellectual property rights, whereas in Britain the high cost of obtaining a patent may have

curtailed technological progress (Khan, 2005). On one level this argument is compelling because

9

inventors in the United States were both able to access cheap patents and interact with

intermediaries who created a market for ideas (Lamoreaux and Sokoloff, 1999, 2002). A

challenge to the importance of patent laws in this account is that across countries the historical

evidence shows changes in patent laws do not predict changes in innovation. Using data on

patent reforms for 60 nations from 1850 to 1999, Lerner (2009) even finds a negative effect of

reforms on subsequent patenting. He concludes that “the impact of strengthened patent

protection may simply be far less on innovative activities than much of the economics and policy

literature assumes” (p. 348).

More detailed evidence from a major patent reform in Britain also questions the significance

of patent laws as a lever for innovation (Nicholas, 2011). The 1883 Patents Act represents one of

the most significant reforms in patent law history as filing fees were reduced by 84 percent. The

Act was passed against a long debate in European countries over the use of patents and whether

knowledge should even be patentable (Machlup and Penrose, 1950), and in the late nineteenth

century inventors in Britain protested that most governments in Europe and certainly the United

States charged far less for patent protection. The most significant change associated with 1883

Patents Act was the substantial reduction in fees, although other administrative changes were

also made such as the use of examiners to facilitate the patenting process. At the same time,

Britain also ratified the Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property, thereby

providing full patent rights to foreign inventors from the signatory countries.

Despite the significance of the 1883 reform there is little evidence that it led to a shift in

innovation. Although the number of patents granted increased by a factor of 2.5, there was not a

step jump in the quality of technological development. In fact, while the propensity to patent

increased as inventive activity migrated from outside to inside the patent system, the inventions

that were patented were more likely to be those in the lower end of the patent value distribution.

Moreover, for an event window around the 1883 reform, citations to patents by British inventors

patenting in the United States did not increase after the reform relative to before. This suggests a

limited role for British patent laws in inducing innovation.

After the 1883 Patents Act, British patent law grappled with the issue of how to balance the

tradeoff between providing inventors with temporary monopolies and the public desire to limit

the deadweight loss arising from inventors earning supernormal returns. In their influential

assessment of the patent system, Boehm and Silberston (1967) argued that the balance was only

10

partially resolved. They recommended replacing the fixed patent term (16 years when they were

writing) with a flexible term based on patent extension principles, and they also suggested

changing the scope of patent rights to take account of the relative merits of different inventions.

These types of ideas form the basis of a large literature on the economics of patents, but they

have not been implemented in policy, a problem that is often compounded by patent office

mismanagement (Jaffe and Lerner, 2004). Furthermore, while patents have typically done a good

job of protecting the rights of inventors (or at least those who are willing to defend their rights in

the courts), they have done much less to achieve their second goal of diffusing knowledge across

innovators. In the absence of strong incentives to share knowledge in a context where technology

diffusion is a critical driver of economic growth, it is perhaps no surprise that patent laws have

been largely indeterminate of the rate of technological change.

B. Prizes

Patents are a dominant mechanism for incentivizing inventors, but it is important to note that

throughout British history alternative mechanisms have also been used. Science has long had a

prominent place in British culture and the economy going back to the archetypal institutions that

promoted learning during industrialization. By 1850 there were 1,020 scientific societies or

associations in Britain with approximately 200,000 members (Mokyr, 2002, pp. 43-45, 66) and

these helped to create an “enlightened economy” that was conducive to rapid technological

progress. These institutions encouraged spillovers of technological knowledge in an environment

where technical and practical knowledge was not only highly valued but also enthusiastically

disseminated (Mokyr, 2010). To this end, scientific societies also used prizes in order to spur

innovation where inventors could also protect their inventions using patents.

The basic theory behind prizes is long-standing. Polanvyi (1943) suggests that “[i]n order

that inventions may be used freely by all, we must relieve inventors of the necessity of earning

their rewards commercially and must grant them instead the right to be rewarded from the public

purse.” In a more recent theoretical contribution, Kremer’s (1998) government funded patent-

buyout mechanism establishes a price for the invention using a sealed bid auction, where the

bidders have some small probability of winning the right to use the invention. If a bidder wins

then the inventor receives a “prize” payment equivalent to the bid price plus some markup to

reflect the social value of the invention. Otherwise the government pays the same amount to the

inventor and it then owns the invention and places it in the public domain. The attractive

11

property of the mechanism is that it avoids the deadweight loss associated with patents, but it

does not need to replace the patent system altogether. Rather, it can be used to provide prize-

based incentives in areas that have a particular appeal from the perspective of welfare. This type

of intuition was behind the famous 1714 prize offered by the British government for an

instrument measuring longitude (Sobel, 1996). It also applied in the acquisition of the

Daguerreotype photography patent by the French government from Louis Jacques Mande

Daguerre, and his partner. With public ownership of the patent, and therefore the underlying

knowledge behind the invention, Daguerreotype photography diffused rapidly (Kremer, 1998).

The fact that prizes have worked to simulate invention is evident from a study by Brunt,

Lerner and Nicholas (2010), which examines almost a century of data on prize competitions held

annually by the Royal Agricultural Society of England (RASE). The RASE used medals and

monetary prizes to spur technological development, sometimes in areas where British inventors

lagged behind foreign competition, such as harvesting technology. Prizes were offered and

awarded in these areas to promote innovation and medals in particular were effective at

increasing the number of entrants into competition and both the number and the quality of

patents. Furthermore, this boost to innovation did not come from substitution effects arising from

inventors reallocating from non-prize areas to prizes areas. Instead, the overall level of aggregate

innovation increased. This evidence shows the utility of British institutions of science in

establishing pioneering mechanisms for promoting innovation. Of course, technology must

interact with organization to create productivity improvements, and it is in the management and

commercialization of new ideas that the British economy has been historically lacking.

4. The Organization of Invention and Managing R&D

A. Independent Inventors

The tension between Britain’s capacity for developing new ideas, but its relative inability to

implement them successfully is evident from the careers of pivotal independent inventors. An

often overlooked fact, given the large literature on the rise of the corporation, is that a significant

share of innovative activity in Britain, and indeed other countries, during the late nineteenth and

early twentieth century occurred outside the boundaries of firms. By 1930, approximately half of

all patents in Britain, the United States and Japan were granted to independent inventors.

Moreover, the average quality of these inventions was high (Nicholas, 2011).

12

Macleod’s (2008) analysis of British culture from 1750 to 1914 shows that independents had

a particularly prominent profile in cultural discourse going back to individuals like the steam

engine pioneer, James Watt (1736-1819), who were celebrated for their creativity. Although their

popularity in society diminished after the First World War, there is every bit as much evidence to

suggest that they still mattered economically. In their extensive study of independents entitled

The Sources of Invention, Jewkes, Sawers and Stillerman’s (1958) conclude:

The evidence of the continued survival of the individual inventor is simply that many men who have lived this century – numbers of whom are still, or were until recently, alive – fall into this category and by their genius have added enormously to the stock of useful ideas and to standards of living. (p.84)

In order to explain why these types of inventors developed such path-breaking innovations

that changed everyday life, Jewkes, Sawers and Stillerman contend that “if invention ever

became the prerogative of full-time professional employees, there are grounds for believing that

it would be weakened in range, liveliness and fertility” (p.96). The purview of independent

inventors was the pursuit of the unorthodox and the search for new ideas derived from original

thinking. They could be more creative by being liberated from tradition, the boundaries of what

was already known, or from what Joseph Schumpeter (1950) described as “routinization”.

Jewkes, Sawers and Stillerman’s assessment is based on the role of individuals such as

Sidney G. Brown (1873-1948) who acquired 235 patents in his lifetime for inventions in the area

of electrical engineering, the first of which he filed in 1899. Brown’s career was typical of many

independents in that he was motivated by the psychic rewards from discovery and only then by

commercialization. Despite starting up a firm to facilitate commercialization of his inventions,

expensive patent litigation meant that he made virtually no money from his most celebrated

invention – the gyro-compass, a navigational device for determining geographical direction.

Frederick W. Lanchester (1868-1946) was granted almost twice as many patents as Brown, and

became a pioneer in aerodynamics and automotive engineering. Yet, although he acted as a

consultant to B.S.A. motors and Daimler, his financial payoffs from invention were limited.

In many instances independents could neither commercialize themselves nor sell on their

inventions to third parties and this has long been considered to be an inherently British problem.

New technologies, by their very nature, are disruptive and are subject to commercial uncertainty,

which may lead to technology trade working imperfectly (Arora and Gambardella, 2010). A

13

well-known case is Frank J. Whittle (1907-96) who applied to the British patent office for

protection on a turbo-jet engine in 1930, an invention which became one of the most significant

discoveries of the twentieth century (Whittle, 1945). But when Whittle notified officials at the

British Air Ministry of his idea and patent they rejected it as being infeasible and so did several

private corporate entities. Eleven years later a prototype aircraft using a Whittle-style engine

produced 800 pounds of thrust, reached 466 miles per hour and an elevation of 42,000 feet, far

beyond anything that had been achieved prior to this point in time. Because of technology

uncertainty and poor commercialization, the jet aircraft age was delayed.

On the other hand, payoffs could be achieved, both for inventors and society, by interactions

between independents as sources of new ideas and firms that were in a position to

commercialize. In the United States firms monitored the market for technology and there is

strong evidence to suggest that this led to a division of labor in invention as firms selected

complementary inventions from independents operating outside their formal R&D environments

(Nicholas, 2009). There is also some evidence of this type of exchange in Britain, in contrast to

the market failures mentioned above. For example, Cadbury, the confectionary manufacturer

maintained a register of outside inventions. More generally, there was scope for the coexistence

of independents and firms because they generally focused on different fields of technological

development. That complementarity, plus the presence of intermediaries who could facilitate the

sale of patents, meant that independents could play a crucially important role in the process of

technological change even as the corporate economy developed (Nicholas, 2011).

B. Industrial Research and Management Practices

As technological progress depended on larger capital requirements, R&D inside the

boundaries of firms became more important over time. The first corporate research laboratory is

conventionally traced to 1868 when BASF opened a facility in Ludwigshafen, Germany. This lab

was most prominently directed by Heinrich Caro, a leading chemist who synthesized the first

indigo dye. Despite being a disorganized, idiosyncratic figure with a reputation for being a

difficult collaborator, the in-house facility that Caro directed became a focal point of

technological development in the German synthetic dyestuffs industry. Caro’s path breaking

innovations acted as a catalyst to the industrialization of chemistry. By hiring academically

trained chemists and through links with noted professors in the field such as August Wilhelm

14

Hofmann from the University of Berlin and Adolf von Baeyer who won the Nobel Prize for

chemistry in 1905, BASF created an auspicious foundation for the commercialization of basic

scientific discoveries that became widely replicated in the industry (Murmann, 2003).

Mowery and Rosenberg (1989, pp.38-39) date the origins of industrial research in the U.S. to

an 1863 facility in Wyandotte, Michigan that investigated the chemistry of Bessemer steel

making, while prominent examples of corporate labs include those founded by Thomas Edison in

Menlo Park, and Alexander Graham Bell in Boston, both in 1876. However, it was not until the

early twentieth century that in-house R&D facilities assumed a prominence seen in the German

dyestuffs industry. By the early 1900s the corporate sector had developed on such a scale that

vertical integration and managerial hierarchies were necessary for the efficient functioning of

American business (Chandler, 1990). Innovation was brought increasingly within enterprises

because the market was no longer able to organize transactions to achieve efficient outcomes. By

1920 the National Research Council had noted a widespread demand for information on in-house

research, and it conducted regular surveys of industrial establishments. Data from these surveys

show that the number of scientists and engineers employed in industrial research laboratories

grew at a rapid rate. Numbers more than doubled between 1921 and 1927 from 2,775 per 1,000

production workers to 6,274 (Mowery and Rosenberg, 1998, pp.21-22).

In an important study, Edgerton and Horrocks (1994) document the early history of R&D in

Britain. They maintain that British firms invested quite heavily in in-house R&D, especially in

the chemicals industry. Networks of technical experts facilitated spillovers of technological

knowledge which were also promoted by inter-firm linkages. An early contributor to the British

R&D effort was United Alkali which had centralized R&D as early as 1892. Firms like ICI

(formed in 1926 as a merger of United Alkali and three other chemicals companies), GEC and

Metropolitan-Vickers were R&D pioneers, a point noted in Hannah’s (1976) work on the rise of

the corporate economy. Edgerton and Horrocks’ revisionist evidence represents a counter to

Mowery’s (1986) traditional argument that British R&D was weak and Chandler’s (1990)

implicit assertions that British firms also failed to generate large returns from R&D because they

underinvested in the complementary capabilities of production, distribution and management.

In line with the revisionist view, there is anecdotal evidence to show that British R&D could

be innovative and well-managed. Barker’s (1977) study shows how Pilkington developed the

Float Process after extensive R&D over a decade, which was facilitated by family ownership and

15

control of the company and a commitment by the company to harnessing applied science and

technology. Another prominent example of British success is the pharmaceuticals and biologics

industry, where Glaxo-Wellcome, Smithkline-Beecham (these two companies merged in 2000 to

form GlaxoSmithKline) and AstraZeneca have created a portfolio of some of the world’s best

known drug innovations such as Tagamet, Zantac and Nexium for the treatment of

gastrointestinal problems. Equally there is anecdotal evidence of British R&D failure. Notably

the British inventor Geoffrey Hounsfield, a scientist employed at the Central Research

Laboratories of EMI, developed the profoundly significant CT Scanner, but EMI did not have the

managerial capabilities to keep pace with demand. During the 1970s and 1980s it lost out to

organizationally efficient U.S. companies like Technicare and General Electric.

Beyond individual case studies, Broadberry and Crafts (1992) argue that a critical set of

drivers of firm performance are related to industry structure and the operating environment more

generally, and these in turn influence incentives and management capabilities. For example, the

British regulatory environment during the interwar years tolerated collusion between firms and

provided subsidies for incumbents, so competition was absent as a disciplinary device in product

markets. Furthermore, labor unions created an unproductive bargaining situation and constrained

the reallocation of resources from poorly to better performing firms, which had a strongly

depressing effect on productivity. It is well-known that if managers of incumbent firms do not

face the threat of replacement then their preferences can tend towards the Hicksian “quiet life”.

On the other hand, competition can encourage innovation especially if firms are already close to

the technological frontier. In this case, firms have more incentives to invest in R&D to capture

the incremental profits deriving from innovating (Bloom et. al., 2005).

The notion that such factors were influential in Britain’s more recent innovation performance

is evidenced by the uptick in productivity as a consequence of more favorable competitive

dynamics in British business. Deregulation, the liberalization of capital markets, better industrial

relations standards and the strengthening of legislation with respect to product market

competition all had positive effects (Crafts, 2012). At the same time, it is worth noting British

weaknesses in the management and diffusion of technology still persist. Insofar as the main

determinants of rapid TFP advance are the diffusion of innovations and the effectiveness of

factors that affect the efficiency with which new technologies are used (Comin and Hobijn,

2010), the evidence suggests a large gap exists between Britain and the United States. Bloom and

16

Van Reenen (2007) find that competition in recent years is still relatively milder in Britain than

in the United States and when combined with the preponderance of British family firms, this has

led to a prominent and persistent tail of badly managed medium-sized firms. Among larger firms,

Bloom, Sadun and Van Reenen (2011) find that U.S. multinationals operating in Europe were far

more able to benefit from technology diffusion as manifested in the implementation of ICT

advances compared to otherwise equivalent European firms. Weaker diffusion and inept

management practice capabilities help to explain performance defects, although in a Europe-

wide context, these are not uniquely British problems.

5. Efforts to Promote Science and Agglomeration

A. Science and Scientific Education

Another important set of influences on the determination of technological progress are public

policy towards the promotion of basic science and education in technical capabilities. Scientific

knowledge changed radically over time from the science of elementary mechanics during the

Industrial Revolution to breakthroughs like complex polymer science that set the foundations for

the Second Industrial Revolution. From electricity generation to nuclear power the growth of

knowledge has been a defining characteristic of the modern world (David, 1990; Mokyr, 2002).

Scientific and technical breakthroughs are critical inputs on the supply side. Where a

fundamental connection exists between science and the growth of technology and invention,

these inputs can be powerful drivers of the rate of economic development.

It has often been argued that Britain fostered high social status education institutions that

were inimical to technological progress, with the traditional “cultural critique” suggesting that

Britain did a good job of training gentlemen and not “practical men” (Wiener, 1981). By

contrast, technical education was prioritized under the French education system as exemplified

by the École Polytechnique in Paris, one of the most significant technical schools. It was also

said to have been a priority in Germany where the integration of science and practice led to a

productive type of knowledge. Summarizing this literature on Britain’s education shortcomings,

Edgerton (1996, p.19) quips “[s]cience is red-brick, not Oxbridge; it is Manchester not London;

it is Harold Wilson and not Harold Macmillan; it is, furthermore, politically radical rather than

conservative”. With respect to science, Britain has always been culturally antithetical.

The alleged weaknesses of British education has been challenged by Sanderson (1988) who

shows that scientific and technical instruction improved radically in Britain during the late

17

nineteenth century, even at the high-prestige institutions. At Oxford and Cambridge, the number

of students graduating annually in science and technical fields increased by more than one third

between 1900 and 1914 (Edgerton, 1996, p.20). Moreover, the London and civic universities had

never subordinated technical and scientific instruction to the classics. And, Berghoff and

Möller’s (1994) analysis prominently indicates that despite the alleged bias of the German

education system to practice, the majority of German businessmen between 1870 and 1914 had

actually received a classical education at a prestigious Gymnasium.

The data indicate a significant expansion over time in scientific education in Britain with

noticeable growth after the Second World War. By the late 1920s, 30 percent of university

students in Britain received a scientific or technical education rising to 52 percent during the late

1960s (Edgerton, 1996, p.22). The richness and importance of the science base has led to major

breakthroughs. The 1953 DNA discovery by Francis Crick and James Watson at the Cavendish

Laboratory at Cambridge University laid the foundation for the development of the bio-

technology industry and furthermore there is general evidence of a disproportionately positive

British influence on science. By the late twentieth century Britain produced 8 percent of the

world’s scientific research papers, yet it accounted for only about 1 percent of the world’s

population (Nickell and Van Reenen, 2001).

Britain’s capabilities in science are evidenced in the developments associated with the

Second World War and its geopolitical aftermath. Given that up to at least the 1960s

approximately a quarter of R&D investment came from government-financed defense

expenditure, the Cold War played an important role in the development of the British science

base. Aviation, electronics and nuclear capabilities all received heavy levels of investment. In

1954 the Atomic Energy Authority was established with a view to managing the R&D process

and creating collaborations and spillovers into private industry. And as Agar (2003, p. 352)

points out “[w]ithout the Second World War the history of computing would have been radically

different”. The need to process and decipher large amounts of data for reasons of national

security, led to an extensive research program. This culminated in the first programmable

computer – “Collosus” – built at the Post Office Research Laboratory in North London, which

was then used for code breaking at Bletchley Park.

Because Collosus was destroyed after the war, and the tacit knowledge cloaked in secrecy, it

was not until the 1950s that Britain developed a computer mainframe industry. Hendry (1990)

18

describes the formation of the National Research Development Corporation in 1949 as an

institutional mechanism for government funded support of R&D efforts and a number of new

computer manufacturers emerged such as International Computers and Tabulators, which later

became ICL. But as the industry migrated to personal computers, Britain’s main computer

manufacturers – Acorn, Amstrad and Sinclair – enjoyed a limited period of success. And on the

mainframe side the industry was soon surpassed by American manufacturers, specifically IBM.

Furthermore, a new wave of semiconductor and micro-processing startups in Silicon Valley

captured market share on the component manufacturing side. Britain’s inability to compete in

this area was an entrepreneurial problem that reflected a weakness at the intersection of science

and technology. It was also caused by a lack of competition and new entry and the absence of

creative destruction that was so dominant a force in the U.S. computer industry.

B. Clusters

Policy makers frequently cite Silicon Valley or clusters in Germany as optimal ecosystems

for generating sustainable competitive advantage. Clusters have institutions and culture,

industrial structure and corporate organizations that promote innovation and economic

development (Saxanian, 1996). The idea that agglomeration creates positive externalities is a

fundamental proposition in urban economics (Porter, 1990; Krugman, 1991), and the idea goes

back to Alfred Marshall’s famous quote in the Principles of Economics:

The mysteries of the trade become no mysteries; but are as it were in the air, and children learn many of them unconsciously. Good work is rightly appreciated, inventions and improvements in machinery, in processes and the general organization of the business have their merits promptly discussed: if one man starts a new idea, it is taken up by others and combined with suggestions of their own; and thus it becomes the source of further new ideas (1890), p.271.

Marshall’s insights have formed the basis of a large literature. Industry clustering it is

commonly observed and yet it typically cannot be explained by exogenously determined natural

advantages like resource endowments that would also lead to a close proximity between firms. In

addition to the “mysteries of the trade” argument, which is essentially about social interactions

spurring innovation spillovers, Marshall also recognized that clusters could be driven by a desire

to save on transport costs between input suppliers and manufacturers or by firms and workers

wanting to benefit from a pooled labor market.

19

Historical evidence provides a link between clusters and technology. Knowledge flows

through informal contacts play a role in Allen’s (1983) account of collective invention in the

Cleveland blast furnace industry during industrialization where producers established the best

height for the furnace through a process of information exchange. These mechanisms operated in

steam technology according to Nuvolari’s (2004) account of Cornish mining. Leunig’s (2003)

work shows that Lancashire cotton manufacturers were heavily clustered. In Blackburn, the

average spinning mill had 7 weaving mills within 300 yards, and 28 within half a mile. Leunig

contends that prior to 1914 Lancashire had high levels of human capital based on learning by

doing, and world leading productivity. This contrasts with the traditional story of British

backwardness and highlights how firms could efficiently operate in a vertically specialized

setting characterized by the kind of strong external economies envisaged by Marshall.

The location of inventive activity informs our understanding about regional comparative

advantage. Using patent data Cantwell and Spadavecchia (2011) investigate the regional

concentration of inventive activity during the interwar years based on the locations of British

inventors who patented over 8,000 inventions in the United States. They find a dominant spatial

role for the South East, especially Greater London, which alone accounted for over 40 percent of

all patents with the next largest regions in terms of patenting – the North West and the West

Midlands falling some way behind. But while the London area has been an important center of

inventive activity, it is not clear that innovation has been caused by cluster-based advantages. In

fact, using an extensive 1996 survey of London businesses and examining inter-firm linkages

and the geography of innovation, Gordon and McCann (2005) find “that the importance of

specifically local informal information spillovers for successful innovation is very much more

limited than has been suggested.”

The absence of strong and sustainable agglomeration effects on a scale witnessed in Silicon

Valley or in the industrial clusters in Germany can be illustrated with reference to Britain’s best

known cluster of Cambridge technology firms, or “Silicon Fen”. Drawing on a strong university

science base in scientific instruments, ICT and biotechnology, the number of firms there

increased from 50 during the mid-1960s to more than 1,200 firms that employed 36,000 workers

by the year 2000 (Garnsey and Heffernan, 2005). At the height of the ICT boom during the late

1990s, high tech firms in Cambridge had a combined turnover in excess of £3.5 billion, with a

large number of acquisitions fuelling investment in entrepreneurship and new technology

20

formation. Cambridge benefitted from government policy initiatives such as the 1998 University

Challenge Fund, which established seed funding for turning scientific knowledge into

commercial innovations. However, Drofiak and Garnsey (2009) show that the recent

performance of the Cambridge cluster is less favorable, as fewer enterprises have received

venture funding and firm survival rates have shortened. More generally, agglomeration effects

may be more limited under policies designed to generate new innovation clusters in places

characterized by old declining industries, especially if there is a mismatch between labor market

pools. Relative to Silicon Valley, Britain has not created global innovation giants through cluster

initiatives (perhaps with the exception of Silicon Fen’s ARM Holdings a leader in mobile phone

chip technology), which casts doubt on the long run success of British efforts designed to induce

positive agglomeration externalities.

6. Conclusion

This chapter has surveyed the literature on technological development in Britain over the last

140 years in an effort to highlight major trends in the data and main patterns of causation.

Technology is central to the growth process, and therefore the history of innovation should

provide insights into why Britain lost its nineteenth century position as the dominant industrial

nation and why Britain’s decline up to the early 1970s was so relentless. To the extent that

innovation and the diffusion of useful knowledge are main drivers of economic growth (Romer,

1990; Mokyr, 2002), an underlying hypothesis throughout this chapter has been that Britain’s

problem was fundamentally related to deficiencies in technology.

To be clear, Britain has not failed when considering the function of invention. Rather, Britain

has a long tradition of excellence in invention and in basic science. The pioneer inventors during

the era of industrialization were followed by path-breaking contributions to technological

progress by both independent inventors and by corporations that pushed out the frontier of

technological progress. The gyro-compass, jet engine, and the float glass process all stand out as

examples of British success. Lancashire was a preeminent source of technological knowledge in

cotton textile machinery, and the diffusion of this knowledge facilitated the growth of competing

industries in the United States and Japan (Jeremy, 1981; Singleton, 1997). British academics

discovered DNA, invented the CT Scanner and Tim Berners-Lee, a British computer scientist, is

credited with the idea for the World Wide Web.

21

Furthermore, institutional mechanisms to support invention have flourished in Britain.

Although the country’s patent laws have been criticized because they were expensive and

awkward to administer, this may not have represented a major drag on innovation, as historical

evidence suggests that British (and indeed American) inventors did not frequently use patents to

protect their intellectual property rights (Moser, 2005). Moreover, when patents did become

cheaper – as indicated by the large drop in fees following the 1883 Patents Act – the propensity

to patent increased, but very little else changed (Nicholas, 2011). Outside the patent system,

British scientific societies contributed to the diffusion of knowledge during industrialization and

they were frequently pioneers in using alternative or complementary mechanisms to incentivize

inventors. From the early nineteenth century, the Royal Agricultural Society of England used

inducement prizes to promote technological progress, and such exemplar historical cases are

particularly relevant as policy makers in recent years have focused attention on the optimal

design of public policies to promote innovation (Brunt, Lerner and Nicholas, 2012).

Despite these areas in which Britain displayed competence and distinctiveness, the

management of technology has typically been weak. Organizational economists have long

argued that a strong complementarity exists between technology, management practices and the

demand for skilled labor, which creates a much more complex nexus through which invention

contributes to productivity growth. Moreover, the economic environment in which firms operate

is also central, including competition in product markets and the ecosystem to support R&D and

a capacity to harness inventions developed domestically or diffused from abroad. In all areas

Britain has failed to match the standards existing in the United States. Since the early 1970s

constraints on growth, such as regulations that previously undermined competition and prevented

reallocation to more efficient firms, have been progressively removed and there is strong

evidence to suggest that the quality of innovation has improved, especially relative to other

European countries. But, while the relentless phase of Britain’s relative economic decline is now

an artifact of the past, creating a foundation where technology continues to be an impetus to the

acceleration in productivity growth is still a pressing issue of the present and the future.

22

References

Abramovitz, Moses. “Resource and Output Trends in the U.S. since 1870,” American

Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 46 no. 2, (1956): 5-23.

Agar, Jonathan “Science and Information Technology,” in Jonathan Hollowell (ed.) Britain

Since 1945. Oxford: Blackwell Press, 2003.

Allen, Robert C., “Collective Invention,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 4

(1983): 1-24.

Aghion, Philippe., Nicholas Bloom, Richard Blundell, Rachel Griffith, Peter Howitt

“Competition And Innovation: An Inverted-U Relationship,” Quarterly Journal of Economics,

2005, 120, no. 2 (2005): 701-728.

Arora, A. and A. Gambardella, “Ideas for Rent: An Overview of Markets for Technology”,.

Industrial and Corporate Change, 19, no. 3 (2010): 775-803.

Barker, T. C., The Glassmakers: Pilkington: The Rise of an International Company, 1826-

1976. London, 1977.

Berghoff, H. and Moller, R., “Tired Pioneers and Dynamic Newcomers? A Comparative

Essay on English and German Entrepreneurial History, 1870-1914,” Economic History Review

47, no.2, (1994).

Bloom, Nick and John Van Reenen., “Measuring and Explaining Management practices

Across Firms and Nations,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 122, no. 4 (2007): 1351–1408.

Bloom, Nick., Raffaella Sadun and John Van Reenen, “Americans do I.T. Better: US

Multinationals and the Productivity Miracle,” American Economic Review (2012).

Boehm, Klaus and Aubrey Silberston, The British Patent System: I. Administration,

Cambridge: Cambridge, 1967.

Broadberry, S. N., The Productivity Race: British Manufacturing in International Perspective,

1850-1990. Cambridge, 1997.

Broadberry, S. N., and Crafts, N. F. R., “Britain’s Productivity Gap in the 1930s: Some

Neglected Factors,” Journal of Economic History, 46, no.1, (1992).

Brunt, Liam., Josh Lerner and Tom Nicholas, “Inducement Prizes and Innovation”, Journal of

Industrial Economics (2012).

23

Burhop, C. and T. Lübbers, “Incentives and Innovation? R&D Management in Germany’s

Chemical and Electrical Engineering Industries Around 1900”, Explorations in Economic

History, 47, (2009): 100-111.

Cantwell, John and Anna Spadavecchia, “Innovation and British Regions in the Interwar

Period”, Reading University mimeo, 2011.

Chandler, Alfred. Scale and Scope: The Dynamics of Industrial Capitalism. Cambridge,

Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1990.

Comin, Diego, and Bart Hobijn. “An Exploration of Technology Diffusion,” American

Economic Review 100, no. 5 (2010): 2031-59.

Crafts, Nicholas., “British Relative Economic Decline Revisited: The Role of Competition,”

Explorations in Economic History 49, no. 1 (2012): 17-29.

David, Paul., “The Dynamo and the Computer: An Historical Perspective on the Modern

Productivity Paradox.” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 80, no. 2 (1990):

355–361.

Diebolt, Claude., and Karine Pellier, “La cliométrie du brevet, Rapport de recherche: Projet

Exploratoire / Premier Soutien (PEPS) du CNRS”, 2010.

Edgerton, David and Sally Horrocks., “British Industrial Research and Development Before

1945.” Economic History Review 47, no. 3 (1994): 213-38.

Edgerton, David., Science, Technology, and the British Industrial “Decline”, 1870-1970.

Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1996.

Floud, Roderick., The British Machine Tool Industry: 1850-1914 Cambridge, Cambridge

University Press, 1976.

Garnsey Elizabeth., and P. Heffernan, “High Tech Clustering through Spin Out and

Attraction; the Cambridge Case”, Regional Studies, 39, no.8 (2005).

Garnsey Elizabeth., and Alex Drofiak “The Cambridge High Tech Cluster: Resilience and

Response to Cyclical Trends”, Cambridge Centre for Technology Management (CTM) Working

Paper, 2009.

Gordon, Ian. R and Philip McCann “Innovation, Agglomeration, and Regional Development”,

Journal of Economic Geography, 5, no., 5 (2005): 523-543.

Griliches, Zvi., “Patent Statistics as Economic Indicators: A Survey.” Journal of Economic

Literature 28, no. 4 (1990): 1661-1707.

24

Hall, Bronwyn, Adam Jaffe, and Manuel Trajtenberg. “The NBER Patent-Citations Data File:

Lessons, Insights, and Methodological Tools.” In Patents, Citation, and Innovations: A Window

on the Knowledge Economy, edited by Adam Jaffe and Manuel Trajtenberg, 403–59. Cambridge,

MA: MIT Press, 2002.

Hannah, Leslie., The Rise of the Corporate Economy. London, Methuen, 1976.

Hendry, John., Innovating for Failure: Government Policy and the Early British Computer

Industry MIT Press, London, 1990.

Horrocks, Sally., The Nature and Extent of British Industrial Research and Development,

1945-1970 Refresh 29 (Autumn 1999).

Jaffe, Adam and Josh Lerner, Innovation and Its Discontents: How Our Broken Patent System

is Endangering Innovation and Progress, and What to Do About It Princeton, Princeton

University Press, 2004.

Jeremy, David., The Transfer of International Technology: Europe, Japan and the USA in the

Twentieth Century. London: Edward Elgar, 1992

Jewkes, John, David Sawers and Richard Stillerman, The Sources of Invention. New York:

Norton, 1968.

Jones, Chad “R&D-Based Models of Economic Growth,” Journal of Political Economy, 103,

no. 4 (1995):759-784.

Khan, B. Zorina., The Democratization of Invention: Patents and Copyrights in American

Economic Development, 1790-1920. Cambridge, Mass.: Cambridge University Press, 2005.

Khan, B. Zorina., “Antitrust and Innovation Before the Sherman Act”, Antitrust 77, no. 3

(2011): 757–786.

Kremer, Michael., “Patent Buyouts: A Mechanism for Encouraging Innovation.” Quarterly

Journal of Economics 113, no. 4 (1998):1137–1167.

Krugman, Paul., “Increasing Returns and Economic Geography,” Journal of Political

Economy, 99, vol. 3 (1990): 483-99.

Lerner, Josh. “150 Years of Patent Protection.” American Economic Review Papers and

Proceedings 92, no. 2 (2002): 221–225.

Lerner, Josh. “The Empirical Impact of Intellectual Property Rights on Innovation: Puzzles

and Clues.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 99, no. 2 (2009): 343–348.

25

Lerner Josh and Scott Stern (eds) The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited

Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 2012.

Leunig, Timothy., “A British Industrial Success: Productivity in the Lancashire and New

England Cotton Spinning Industries a Century Ago”, Economic History Review 56, no. 1 (2003):

90-117.

Machlup, Fritz and Edith Penrose, “The Patent Controversy in the Nineteenth Century,”

Journal of Economic History 24, no.1 (1950).

MacLeod, Christine., Heroes of Invention: Technology, Liberalism and British Identity, 1750-

1914. Cambridge. Cambridge University Press, 2007.

Maddison, Angus. Statistics on World Population, GDP and Per Capita GDP, 1-2006 AD

(2009 Edition).

Marshall, A., Principles of Economics. London, 1920.

Michie, Jonathan “The Internationalisation of the Innovation Process”, The International

Journal of the Economics of Business, 5, no. 4 (1998): 261-277.

Mokyr, Joel., The Lever of Riches. Oxford, 1990.

Mokyr, Joel., The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton:

Princeton University Press, 2002.

Mokyr, Joel., The Enlightened Economy: An Economic History of Britain, 1700-1850. Yale:

Yale University Press, 2010.

Moser, Petra. “How do Patent Laws Influence Innovation? Evidence from Nineteenth-Century

World’s Fairs.” American Economic Review 95, no. 4 (2005): 1214–1236.

Mowery, David., “Industrial Research in Britain, 1900-1950,” in B. Elbaum and W. Lazonick

(eds), The Decline of the British Economy, Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1986.

Mowery, David & Nathan Rosenberg. Technology and the Pursuit of Economic Growth.

Cambridge, Massachusetts: Cambridge University Press, 1989.

Mowery, David & Nathan Rosenberg. Paths of Innovation: Technological Change in

Twentieth Century America. Cambridge, Massachusetts: Cambridge University Press, 1998.

Murmann, Johann Peter, Knowledge and Competitive Advantage. The Coevolution of Firms,

Technology, and National Institutions. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 2003.

Nicholas, Tom. “Does Innovation Cause Stock Market Runups? Evidence from the Great

Crash,” American Economic Review, 98, no. 4 (2005): 1370–96.

26

Nicholas, Tom. “Spatial Diversity in Invention: Evidence from the Early R&D Labs.” Journal

of Economic Geography, 9, no. 1 (2009): 1–31.

Nicholas, Tom. “The Role of Independent Invention in US Technological Development,

1880-1930.” Journal of Economic History 70, no. 1 (2010): 59–84.

Nicholas, Tom. “Cheaper Patents” Research Policy 77, no. 20 (2011): 325–339.

Nicholas, Tom. “What Drives Innovation” Antitrust 77, no. 3 (2011): 787–809.

Nickell, S. J. and John Van Reenen, “Technological Innovation and Economic Performance in

the United Kingdom”, CEP Discussion Papers dp0488, 2001.

Nuvolari, Alessandro., “Collective Invention During the British Industrial Revolution: the

Case of the Cornish Pumping Engine’, Cambridge Journal of Economics, 28 (2004): 347-363.

Polanvyi, Michael., “Patent Reform.” Review of Economic Studies 11, no. 2 (1944):61–76.

Porter, Michael., The Competitive Advantage of Nations, Free Press, New York, 1990.

Romer, Paul M., “Endogenous Technological Change.” Journal of Political Economy 98 no. 5

(1990): 71-102.

Sanderson, M., “Education and Economic Decline 1890-1980,” Oxford Review of Economic

Policy (1988).

Saxenian, AnnaLee., Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and

Route 128 Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 1996.

Schumpeter, Joseph., Capitalism Socialism and Democracy. New York: Harper, 1950.

Scotchmer, Suzanne., Innovation and Incentives. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2004.

Singleton, John., The World Textile Industry London: Routledge, 1997.

Sobel, Dava., Longitude: The True Story of a Lone Genius Who Solved the Greatest Scientific

Problem of His Time, Penguin Press, 1996.

Temin, Peter., “The Golden Age of European Growth Reconsidered,” European Review of

Economic History, 6 (2002): 3-22.

Trajtenberg, Manuel, “A Penny for Your Quotes: Patent Citations and the Value of

Innovations,” Rand Journal of Economics 21 (1990): 172-187.

Whittle, Frank., “The Whittle Jet Propulsion Gas Turbine.” The Engineer. October 12th 1945.

Wiener, M., English Culture and the Decline of the Industrial Spirit 1850-1990. Cambridge,

1981.

27

Table 1. Estimates of Historical Patent Citations to Patents Granted to Foreign Inventors in the United States

Notes: Coefficients are from historical patent citation regressions described in the text. Coefficients in bold are statistically significant at the 5 percent level and measure the percentage change i.e. [exp(α)-1×100] in citations for patents to inventors from each country relative to the baseline category of citations to patents by British inventors. Citations counts are derived from patents granted in the United States from 1947 to 2008.

1870-1918 1919-1945 1946-1973 1974-2004

Austria 0.041 0.023 -0.019 -0.221Austrailia -0.006 0.027 0.063 -0.001Belgium 0.003 -0.075 -0.049 -0.060Canada -0.043 -0.040 0.054 0.117Switzerland 0.023 0.008 -0.013 -0.114Germany 0.024 0.030 0.010 -0.125Denmark 0.035 -0.016 0.002 -0.082Finland 0.103 -0.038 -0.040 -0.056France 0.039 0.042 -0.007 -0.129Israel 0.188Italy -0.013 -0.008 -0.057 -0.191Japan 0.026 -0.038 0.059 0.054Korea (South) -0.081Netherlands -0.031 0.025 -0.048 -0.110Sweden 0.030 -0.009 -0.082Taiwan -0.017

Base Category is British Patents

28

Figure 1. Patents Scaled by Population, 1870-2004

Notes: British and US patent data are from official statistics of each country’s Patent Office. German and French data provided courtesy of Diebolt and Pellier (2010). Population data are from Maddison (2009).

Figure 2. Percentage of United States Patents Granted to

British, German and French Inventors, 1870-2004

Notes: Data compiled by recording patent addresses of all patents granted in the United States from 1870 to 2004 and tabulating those British, German and French inventors.

0.0

0.2

0.4

0.6

0.8

1.0

1.2

187

018

75

188

018

85

189

018

95

190

019

05

191

019

15

192

019

25

193

019

35

194

019

45

195

019

55

196

019

65

197

019

75

198

019

85

199

019

95

200

0

Pat

ents

per

Tho

usan

d P

opul

atio

n

US BR DE FR

0%

2%

4%

6%

8%

10%

12%

187

018

75

188

018

85

189

018

95

190

019

05

191

019

15

192

019

25

193

019

35

194

019

45

195

019

55

196

019

65

197

019

75

198

019

85

199

019

95

200

0

Per

cent

age

BR DE FR

Figure 3. Technology Category Distribution of Patents Granted to Inventors Patenting in the United States

Notes: Data compiled by recording patent addresses of all patents granted in the United States from 1870 to 2004 and tabulating those British, German and French inventors. Patents were then categorized using the United States Patent Office scheme and then coded according to the categories used by Hall, Jaffe and Trajtenberg (2002). These are: 1=Chemicals; 2=Computers and Communications; 3=Drugs and Medical; 4=Electrical and Electronic; 5=Mechanical; 6=Miscellaneous.

01020304050

01020304050

01020304050

01020304050

1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6

1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6

1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6

1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6

DE, 1870-1918 DE, 1919-1945 DE, 1946-1973 DE, 1974-2004

FR, 1870-1918 FR, 1919-1945 FR, 1946-1973 FR, 1974-2004

GB, 1870-1918 GB, 1919-1945 GB, 1946-1973 GB, 1974-2004

US, 1870-1918 US, 1919-1945 US, 1946-1973 US, 1974-2004

Pe

rcen

tage

of P

ate

nts

Figure 4. Scaled R&D Expenditure in Manufacturing

Notes: Bars represent data for Britain and figures for comparison countries are given in the associated Table. Data are taken from Broadberry (2005), Table 8.14, p.122.

Figure 5. Scaled R&D Employment in Manufacturing

Notes: Percentage of manufacturing employment accounted for by “researchers”. Bars represent data for Britain and figures for comparison countries are given in the associated Table. Data are taken from Broadberry (2005), Table 8.15, p.124.

0.43 0.43

3.49

4.40

3.403.50

4.79 4.77

3.99

5.88 5.96

0.0

1.0

2.0

3.0

4.0

5.0

6.0

7.0

1934 1938 1959 1964 1968 1975 1983 1989

Per

cent

age

% Net Output % Value Added

% Net % ValueOutput Added

USA:

1937 0.98 1959 5.821981 5.96 7.681987 7.33 9.91

Germany:

1950 0.581959 1.401964 1.961969 3.081975 3.881983 5.72

0.03 0.05 0.07 0.07

0.57

2.69

2.42

3.663.55

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

4.0

1933 1935 1938 1945-46 1959 1968 1975 1983 1989

Per

cent

age

% ResearchersUSA:

1933 0.17 1940 0.291946 0.32 1959 1.31

Germany:

1964 1.291969 1.701975 1.921989 3.29