the benefits and costs of environmental protection: measuring costs “roughly 2% of (u.s. gdp) is...

25
The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental regulation tend to focus on aggregate consequences” “Yet these consequences are not evenly distributed among all members of society” there is a distribution of costs which can be “broken down by household, sector, region, and generation.” (Pizer and Kopp, 2005)

Upload: lydia-anderson

Post on 25-Dec-2015

218 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs

• “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.”

• CBAs “of environmental regulation tend to focus on aggregate consequences” – “Yet these consequences are not evenly distributed

among all members of society” – there is a distribution of costs which can be “broken

down by household, sector, region, and generation.” (Pizer and Kopp, 2005)

Page 2: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Conceptualization of cost for environmental policy: (Revesz and Stavins, 2007, 511)

– “(T)he value of whatever must be sacrificed to prevent (or reduce the risk of) an environmental impact.

– (T)he forgone social benefits due to employing

scarce resources for environmental policy purposes, instead of putting those resources to their next best use.”

Page 3: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs

• The true economic costs of environmental protection are the opportunity costs

– (Social) opportunity costs: the highest-value alternative use to which inputs (resources) might have been put and that society has to forego when the inputs are used.

– What you give up by taking one action and not another• What’s the cost of attending UCD?

– “Sticker” price? The opportunity cost?

– NB of the best alternative opportunity foregone

Page 4: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Do environmental regulations cost jobs?

• Greenstone (2002): “The Impacts of Environmental Regulations on Industrial Activity: Evidence from the 1970 and 1977 Clean Air Act Amendments and the Census of Manufactures”

• “…first 15 years after the Amendments became law (1972- 1987):– nonattainment counties (relative to attainment ones) lost

approximately • 590,000 jobs, • $37B in capital stock, and • $75B (1987$) of output in pollution intensive industries”.

• “…undermine(s) the contention that environmental regulations are costless or even beneficial for the regulated.”

Page 5: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Taxonomy of costs: most obvious to most comprehensive

Abatement costs (see detail in add’l slides at end)

– out-of-pocket costs for abatement equipment (used to reduce pollution)

Compliance costs– the cost of all policy compliance actions (captures costs outside of

abatement, e.g. process change).– may be sufficient when “behavioral response, transitional costs and

indirect costs are small” (Revesz and Stavins, 2007, 512).

Partial equilibrium/behavioral response– Captures behavioral responses, but holds prices constant, limited to

burden on directly regulated entities (firms or households).

General equilibrium/Secondary effects– the net burden once all good and factor markets have equilibrated. (Pizer

and Kopp, 2005)

Page 6: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Accounting for behavioral response

Story: new regulation increases the MC of paper production from MC1 to MC2

1.What are the implications for consumer surplus given a flat demand curve?

2.What is the area D+E in plain English? A reasonable est. of cost?

3.What is the increase in total cost of producing r1 (the initial quantity) after the regulation? Why might it be misleading to use this as an estimate of compliance cost?

4.What are the social costs of the regulation? (Note: we’re not looking at the benefit side of the policy now, just costs.)

When we account for behavioral responses in the regulated sector (but no further) we are conducting a “partial equilibrium analysis” (vs. a multi-sector general equilibrium).

output

$

r1

A

B

r2

C

MC1

MC2

DemandD

E

F

Page 7: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

“General equilibrium” or“secondary” effects

• Secondary effects: (economic) outcomes of a policy that extend beyond the primary market being regulated

• When are secondary effects likely important?1. For regulations that affect highly integrated sectors of the

economy • Produce widely used intermediate products• E.g. energy

2. Regulations that generate large direct costs• If costs are passed to consumers their overall consumption might fall• Industry may contract (employees reduced)• Compliance consulting industry might grow

Material from RFF B-C primer

Page 8: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Example: (1) Clean Water Act, and (2) Clean Air Act.

Hazilla and Kopp, 1990. “Social Cost of Environmental Quality Regulations: A General Equilibrium Analysis”

• Effects in table are just the compliance costs.

Page 9: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

The secondary effect analysis (SEA) (CAA/CWA e.g. continued)

• SEA: A large mathematical model of consumers and producers in many industries– Parameters of the model (e.g. how do consumers value

consumption versus leisure?) are estimated from historical data– Model is “run” twice

• Without the proposed policy (“baseline”, “counterfactual”)• With the proposed policy

• What kinds of behavioral links does it capture?– Individual household choices:

Regulation increases prices Price of consumption (versus leisure) goes up

People work less (labor supply falls), savings rate falls (capital supply falls)

Individual (and therefore aggregate) economic growth is reduced– Analogous story for firm decisions

Page 10: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Secondary effect analysis results (e.g. continued)

• Compliance investments: required in 13 sectors – BUT, production costs increased and output and labor productivity fell in all

sectors.– E.g. finance sector: bore no compliance cost, BUT cost of

production is 2% higher (higher input costs)

Page 11: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Conclusions of the study

Hazilla and Kopp, 1990. “Social Cost of Environmental Quality Regulations: A General Equilibrium Analysis”. Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98, no. 4 (August), pp. 853-873.

• In other words, regulation causes prices to rise but then consumers adapt, substituting towards other goods. Ignoring consumer response leads to a overstatement of costs of the CAA & CWA and therefore an understatement of net benefits.

Page 12: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Overall record of cost estimation• Harrington et al. (2000): examined 28

environmental and occupational safety regulations– Half the cases: cost estimates > actual costs

• Per-unit abatement costs: over- and under-estimation error equally common

– BUT: When economic incentives instruments used, per-unit costs were consistently overestimated.

• Attributed to technological innovation stimulated by market-based instruments.

(via Revesz and Stavins, 2007, 513)

Page 13: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Other cost issues• Dynamic: technological progress• Enforcement: gov. admin., monitoring and

enforcement

• Environmental costs: e.g. S02 sludge from scrubbers (risk-risk)

• “Negative costs”: increases in productivity from cleaner environment, process improvements from innovation spurred by regulation.

Page 14: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Equity impacts of environmental policy

• Who appropriates the benefits?

• Who bears the cost?– The results of environmental policies are likely

to be regressive (if equity concerns ignored).• Regressive: greater relative impact on the poor.• Mechanism

Env. and energy policy may raise the prices of goods and services that make up a greater share of expenditures for poor people.

(Bento 2013)

Page 15: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Policy cost example: “Distributional and Efficiency Impacts of

Increased US Gasoline Taxes”Bento et al. (2009)

• What happens when we impose a $0.25 tax on gasoline?

• Econometrically based multimarket simulation model.

• Behavioral response: – fuel consumption,

– vehicle miles traveled (VMT)

– fleet composition (new and used)

Page 16: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Bento et al. (2009)• Distribution across 20,000 households

– Varying: income, region of residence, race, and employment status

– Random sample, National Household Travel Survey

• Utility maximization framework– theoretically sound welfare indexes of

distributional impacts

Page 17: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Bento et al. (2009)

• Revenue recycling scenarios—distribute gas tax revenue by:– “Flat”: equal amounts to every household.– “Income-based”: according to income share– “VMT-based”: according to VMT share (baseline)

• Results: 25 cent tax welfare loss of $30/yr (2001$, avg per household)– Cost-side only, excludes external benefits

Page 18: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Welfare impacts by race & income

EV: “equivalent variation” welfare measure based on compensated demand. WTP to avoid the price increase before it occurs.

For lowest income bracket: refund > taxes paid

Page 19: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Decomposition of welfare impacts

“pro

gres

sive

”“r

egre

ssiv

e”

slightly progressive for lowest bracketbut mostly even

Page 20: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

BCA capstone

United States Office of Management and Budget (executive branch), 2015http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/inforeg/regpol/RIA_Checklist.pdf

Page 21: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental
Page 22: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental
Page 23: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Additional slides

Page 24: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Direct costs: Abatement • Abatement expenditures: out-of-pocket costs for

abatement equipment (used to reduce pollution) – Most popular (but poor) concept of regulatory cost in

the analysis of environmental programs

Wood Products MACTPictured above is a Regenerative Catalytic Oxidizer designed to meet the EPA's MACT for plywood, particleboard, veneer, OSB, MDF and specialty wood products plants.

www.aircleantech.com

Page 25: The Benefits and Costs of Environmental Protection: Measuring Costs “Roughly 2% of (U.S. GDP) is spent on environmental protection.” CBAs “of environmental

Example: costs of policy to ban CFCs

•Response: develop CFC replacements like freon.

•Possible costs

1. Replacement: Increased costs of production for the replacement

2. R&D: The diverted resources necessary to develop the substitute

3. Obsolescence: The value of services of specialized capital and technology

4. Consumer welfare: Change retail price of replacement (lost surplus)

Kopp et al. 1997