the collective model of the householddenardim/teaching/collective... · 2020. 11. 6. · voena...

38
The Collective Model of the Household Mart´ ın Garc´ ıa V´ azquez University of Minnesota Presented by: Mart´ ın Garc´ ıa V´ azquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 1 / 38

Upload: others

Post on 08-Feb-2021

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • The Collective Model of the Household

    Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez

    University of Minnesota

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 1 / 38

  • Plan for today

    1 Static models of the household

    2 Static models of the household

    3 Mazzocco (2007)

    4 Some interesting applications of the collective model

    5 Voena (2015)

    6 Summary

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 2 / 38

  • Static models of the household

    Unitary model

    Most used model of the household.

    Household behaves as a single rational agent.

    Pros:1 Simplicity

    Cons:1 Assumes an aggregation result.2 Often rejected by the data (more on this later).

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 3 / 38

  • Static models of the household

    Static Unitary model

    max(X ,x ,l1,l2,d1,D1,d2,D2)

    UH(Q, q, l1, l2)

    s.t (BC) pX + p(x1 + x2) +2∑

    i=1

    ωi (l i + D i + d i ) = Y

    (HP) Q = F (X ,D) , q1 + q2 = f (x , d)

    q , (Q): Consumption of the private or public good.

    l : leisure.

    x , (X ): expenditures in private or public good.

    d , (D): time devoted to production of private or public good.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 4 / 38

  • Static models of the household

    Testable predictions

    Model predicts that only total household non-labor income, ratherindividual non-labor incomes, matters for allocations: IncomePooling.

    Standard consumer theory applies. The Slutsky matrix has to besymmetric and negative semi-definite.

    The i , j term of the Slutsky matrix is given by:

    sij =∂ξi∂pj

    +∂ξi∂Y

    ξi

    ξ: Marshallian demand (solution to the Utility Maximization Problem)

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 5 / 38

  • Static models of the household

    Collective Model

    Acknowledges that a household is formed by many individuals.

    Does not assume a particular protocol for how decisions within thehousehold are made.

    Assumes that allocations are Pareto efficient.

    Allows each spouse’s position on the Pareto Frontier to depend ondistribution factors.

    These are variables that do not affect preferences or the budget set,but rather ”bargaining power”.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 6 / 38

  • Static models of the household

    Collective Model

    max(X ,x ,l1,l2,d1,D1,d2,D2)

    µ1(Z )U1(Q, q1, l1) + µ2(Z )U

    2(Q, q2, l2)

    s.t (BC) pX + p(x1 + x2) +2∑

    i=1

    ωi (l i + D i + d i ) = Y

    (HP) Q = F (X ,D) , q1 + q2 = f (x , d)

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 7 / 38

  • Static models of the household

    Browning and Chiappori (1998)

    Income pooling and the properties of the Slutsky matrix predicted bythe unitary model are rejected in a sample of married households.

    The properties of the Slutsky matrix are neither rejected in a sampleof single women, nor in a sample of single men.

    A collective model generates a set of testable restrictions onMarshallian demands and the Slutsky matrix that are not rejected bythe data.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 8 / 38

  • Static models of the household

    Why should we care?

    The collective model is more empirically supported than the unitarymodel.

    Why does this matter?

    Some policy recommendations are different for the unitary and thecollective model.

    Example: Cash-transfer program to poor households, like BolsaFamilia in Brazil or Progresa in Mexico.

    Unitary model: It doesn’t matter whether the wife or the husbandreceives the transfer.

    Collective model: This may matter. Moreover, since the objective ofthis program is to improve outcomes of children, it is very likely thatgiving the money to mothers will be more effective.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 9 / 38

  • Mazzocco (2007)

    Mazzocco (2007)

    Extends the collective model to a dynamic setting.

    At least two ways of doing that:1 Upon household formation, individuals can commit to any

    budget-feasible contingent plan: Dynamic Collective Model with FullCommitment.

    2 Individuals cannot commit to allocations that violate a ParticipationConstraint: Dynamic Collective Model with Limited Commitment.

    Mazzocco (2007) shows how to empirically distinguish one modelfrom the other using household-level consumption data (as opposedto individual-level consumption data).

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 10 / 38

  • Mazzocco (2007)

    Dynamic Unitary Model

    max{Ct ,Qt ,st}t∈T ,ω∈Ω

    E0

    [T∑t=0

    βtU (Ct ,Qt)

    ]

    s.t Ct + PtQt + st ≤2∑

    i=1

    y it + Rtst−1, ∀ t, ω

    sT ≥ 0,∀ ω

    where:

    Ct Total HH consumption of the private good.

    Qt Total HH consumption of the public good.

    st Savings in riskless asset.

    Rt Gross return of the riskless asset at t.

    y it Income of spouse i (exogenous labor supply).

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 11 / 38

  • Mazzocco (2007)

    Full Commitment Collective Model

    max{c1t ,c2t ,Qt ,st}t∈T,ω∈Ω

    µ1(Z )E0

    [T∑t=0

    βt1u1(c1t ,Qt)

    ]+ µ2(Z )E0

    [T∑t=0

    βt2u2(c2t ,Qt)

    ]

    s.t2∑

    i=1

    c it + PtQt + st ≤2∑

    i=1

    y it + Rtst−1, ∀ t, ω

    sT ≥ 0,∀ ω

    where:

    µi is the Pareto weight of individual i .

    Z contains variables that affect the ”bargaining power” of individualswithin the HH, these are called distribution factors.

    Examples of distribution factors can be the relative income of eachhousehold member or the local sex ratio.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 12 / 38

  • Mazzocco (2007)

    Limited Commitment Collective Model

    max{c1t ,c2t ,Qt ,st}t∈T,ω∈Ω

    µ1(Z )E0

    [T∑t=0

    βt1u1(c1t ,Qt)

    ]+ µ2(Z )E0

    [T∑t=0

    βt2u2(c2t ,Qt)

    ]

    s.t Eτ

    [T−τ∑t=0

    βti ui (c it+τ ,Q

    it+τ )

    ]≥ ui ,τ (Z ), ∀ω, τ > 0, i = 1, 2

    2∑i=1

    y it + PtQt + st ≤2∑

    i=1

    y it + Rtst−1, ∀ t, ω

    sT ≥ 0,∀ ω

    New: Participation Constraint.

    Each household member can decide to leave the Household at anypoint in time.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 13 / 38

  • Mazzocco (2007)

    Testing

    Mazzocco (2007) tests:1 Dynamic collective model with and without commitment.2 Dynamic unitary vs dynamic collective.

    To perform this test:1 Derives the EE for aggregate private and public consumption for each

    model.2 Takes a second order log-linear approximation and shows that Z enters

    differently in EE.3 More concretely:

    The approximate EE for the collective model nests the one for theunitary modelThe approximate EE for LC nests the one for FC model

    4 This implies:

    Testing for commitment can be done with a simple parametric test.Same can be said for unitary vs collective.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 14 / 38

  • Mazzocco (2007)

    Comment on the test

    Note that the test:

    Uses consumption at the household level.Doesn’t track individuals over time.

    An easier to interpret test could be achieved if we could observe howindividual shares of consumption respond to wage shocks.

    This kind of test requires:1 Household-level panel data.2 Detailed information on individual consumption.

    This test is performed in Lise and Yamada (2018).

    They conclude that:

    Pareto weights respond to large wage shocks...... but not to small wage shocks.

    This can be interpreted as a rejection of Full Commitment.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 15 / 38

  • Some interesting applications of the collective model

    Some interesting applications of the Collective Model

    Lundberg, Startz and Stillman 2003: Marital Bargaining canrationalize the Consumption-Retirement puzzle if intra-householdbargaining power depends on relative incomes and wives expect tolive longer.

    Lise and Seitz 2011: Adult-equivalent measures of consumption getthe level and the trend of consumption inequality wrong.

    1 The level of consumption inequality is higher than measured by usingequivalence scales because of intra-household inequality.

    2 The trend is flatter because decreasing intra-household inequalityoffsets increasing within-household inequality.

    Voena 2015: Examines how divorce laws affect intertemporal choicesof couples and welfare.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 16 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Voena 2015

    Divorce laws likely to affect the risk-sharing ability of households andbargaining power within the household. This matters for the level andthe intra-household distribution of welfare.

    1 Unilateral divorce introduces the possibility of walking away frommarriage. This reduces the ability of couples to commit and thereforeto share risks.

    2 How property is divided upon divorce is likely to affect the bargainingpower of household members. This effect on bargaining power is likelyto depend on whether or not unilateral divorce is possible.

    Given this, they also matter for household choices

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 17 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Institutional Framework

    Divorce grounds:1 Mutual consent: Divorce takes place if both partners agree to it.2 Unilateral Divorce: Any partner can end the marriage at any point in

    time.

    Property Division:1 Title-based regimes: Assets are allocated after divorce according to

    ownership.2 Community property: Assets are divided equally upon divorce.3 Equitable distribution: Courts decide the division of assets upon

    divorce.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 18 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelEnvironment

    Husband and Wife live for T periods and retire exogenously at age R.

    Each period, choose how much to save, how to allocate consumptionand whether or not to stay together. Before retirement they alsochoose labor force participation for the wife.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 19 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelPreferences

    Husband and wife derive utility from consumption c jt , participation Pjt

    and a subjective taste for marriage shock ξjt

    Period utilities:

    ujmarried = u(cjt ,P

    jt ) + ξ

    jt u

    jdivorced = u(c

    jt ,P

    jt )

    ξjt evolves according to:

    ξjt = ξjt−1 + �

    jt , , ξ

    j1 = �1, �

    jt ∼ N(0, σ2)

    u(c ,P) = c1−γ

    1−γ − ψP , with γ ≥ 0 ψ ≥ 0

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 20 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelEconomies of scale and children

    Childbirth is exogenous and happens at predetermined ages.

    Let x be the level of consumption expenditures. The inverseproduction function of consumption is given by:

    x = F (cHt , cWt )e(k) =

    [(cHt )

    ρ + (cWt )ρ] 1ρe(k)

    where e(k) is an equivalence scale that depends on the number ofchildren.

    This function tries to capture economies of scale in consumption.

    Key to include this if economies of scale are a big advantage ofmarriage.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 21 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelIncome over the Life-Cycle

    Labor income of spouse j (y jt ) depends on her human capital hjt and

    her permanent component of income (z jt ):

    ln y jt = ln hjt + z

    jt

    where:z jt = z

    jt−1 + ζ

    jt and z

    j1 = ζ

    j1, ζ

    jt ∼ N(0, σζ j )

    with ζ jt iid across time and correlated across spouses.

    Human capital evolves according to:

    ln hjt = ln hjt−1 − δ(1− P

    jt−1) + (λ

    j0 + λ

    j1t)P

    jt−1

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 22 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelBudget Constraints

    Married couple:

    At+1 − (1 + r)At + xt = yHt + (yWt − dWt )PWtwhere At = A

    Ht + A

    Wt

    Keeping track of individual asset holdings matters only in title-basedregimes.dkt captures child-care costs that the household has to incur if bothparents work.

    Divorcee:

    Ajt+1 − (1 + r)Ajt + c

    jte(kt) =

    (y jt −

    dkt2

    )P jt j = H,W

    Division of assets upon divorce:In a title-based regime, each spouse keeps Ajt after divorce.In a community property regime, assets are divided equally.In an equitable distribution regime, assets are divided randomly.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 23 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelProblem of the divorcee

    ωHt = {Ajt , y

    jt ,Ωt} : State for the divorced husband.

    Ωt : Divorce laws.

    qjt = (cjt ,A

    jt+1) be the control.

    For the wife hWt is added as a state and PWt is added as a control.

    In each period, divorcees remarry with an exogenous probability πjΩt .

    Problem of the divorcee:

    V jDt (ωt) = maxqjt

    u(c jDt ,PjDt ) + β

    {πjDt+1E

    [V jRt+1(ωt+1|ωt)

    ]+(1− πjΩt+1)E

    [V jDt+1(ωt+1|ωt)

    ]}subject to Divorcee B.C for j = H,W

    Let V jDR = πjΩt VjRt (ω) + (1− π

    jΩt )V

    jDt (ω) be the expected value of

    entering t as a divorcee.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 24 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelProblem of the married couple under Mutual Consent

    State: ωt = (AHt ,A

    Wt , y

    Ht , y

    Wt , ξ

    Ht , ξ

    Wt , h

    Wt ,Ωt)

    Choice vector: qt = {cHt , cWt ,PWt ,AHt+1,AWt+1,Dt}Value function:

    Vt(ωt) = maxqt

    (1− Dt){θu(cHt ,P

    Ht ; ξ

    Ht ) + (1− θ)u(cWt ,PWt ; ξWt )

    +βE [Vt+1(ωt+1|ωt)]}

    +Dt{θ[u(cHt ,P

    Ht ) + βE [V

    HDRt+1 (ωT+1|ωT )]

    ]+(1− θ)

    [u(cWt ,P

    Wt ) + βE [V

    WDRt+1 (ωt+1|ωt)]

    ]}s.t B.C in marriage holds if Dt = 0

    s.t B.C in divorce holds if Dt = 1

    u(c jt ,Pjt ) + βE [V

    jDRt+1 (ωT+1|ωT )] > V

    jMt for j = H,W if Dt = 1

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 25 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    ModelProblem of the married couple under Unilateral Divorce

    ωt now includes the within-period Pareto weights, θ̃jt , which change

    over time to ensure that the participation constraint is satisfied.

    These evolve according to:

    θ̃jt+1 = θ̃jt + µ

    jt for j = H,W

    Other difference with respect to the Mutual Consent Regime is thatnow the Participation Constraints say that the value of marriage nowhas to be higher than the value of divorce for both partners.

    Upon divorce, assets are divided according to the division rule in place.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 26 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Divorce Laws and Household Outcomes

    Mutual Consent:uc(c

    Ht ,P

    Ht )

    uc(cWt ,PWt )

    =1− θθ

    Unilateral Divorce:

    uc(cHt ,P

    Ht )

    uc(cWt ,PWt )

    =θ̃Wt + µ

    Wt

    θ̃Ht + µHt

    Mutual consent: allocations in marriage are not affected by thedivision rule upon divorce.

    Unilateral divorce: This is no longer the case. Allocations in marriagedepend on division rule through the Lagrange multipliers.

    Finally, note that this is partial equilibrium (θ is fixed acrossinstitutional arrangements).

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 27 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Data and Estimation

    Data:1 Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID)2 National Longitudinal Survey of Young Women and National

    Longitudinal Survey of Mature Women (NLS-YW and NLS-MW)

    Three groups of model parameters:1 Some parameters are taken from external sources.2 Earnings processes: Estimated without solving the model.These are

    estimated using Non-linear least squares and using a correctionprocedure to account for selection of women into the labor force.

    3 (θ, ψ, σ) estimated via indirect inference.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 28 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Preset parameters

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 29 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Parameters of Income Processes

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 30 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Parameters estimated by indirect inference

    1 σ: The standard deviation of the marriage quality shock.2 ψ: The utility cost of participation.3 θ: The Pareto weight of the husband.

    Auxiliary models (estimated on the sub-sample of couples living incommunity property states):

    assetsi ,s,t = βUnilaterals,t + γ′Zi ,t + δt + fi + v1,i ,s,t

    φ1 =β

    average assets

    employmenti ,s,t = φ2Unilaterals,t + γ′Zi ,t + δt + fi + v2,i ,s,t

    employmenti ,s,t = φ3 + v3,i ,s,t

    ever divorced = φ4 + v4,i ,s

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 31 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Identification

    φ2 is informative of θ.

    When θ is high, wife is more likely to be better off when divorced.When unilateral divorce is introduced, her Pareto weight shifts. Sinceshe values leisure, her labor supply goes down.When θ is low, wife is better off in marriage. When unilateral divorce isintroduced, divorce and the associated drop in consumption are morelikely. This increases wife’s labor supply due to aconsumption-smoothing motive.

    φ3 is informative of ψ and θ.

    ψ The higher the disutility of working, the lower the participation rate.θ The higher the Pareto weight of the wife, the larger her consumptionof leisure and the lower her participation rate.

    φ4, (share of women ever divorced) is informative of σ. The higher σ,the larger the probability of a very negative marriage quality shock,and the more likely divorce is.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 32 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Identification

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 33 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Estimated Parameters

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 34 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Welfare analysis of divorce laws reform

    Use model to evaluate how introduction of unilateral divorce affecteddistribution of resources within marriage and upon divorce.

    At the estimated value of θ = 0.7, the average share of resources thatgoes to the wife increases from 39% to 41%.

    This is driven by the 19% of couples for whose Pareto weights aremodified after the introduction of unilateral divorce.

    The distribution of assets upon divorce also changes. In a title-basedregime, the average share of assets upon divorce is 40%, while thisshare is 42% under equitable distribution and 50% under communityproperty by construction.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 35 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Divorce laws and consumption insurance

    From the risk-sharing with limited commitment literature we knowthat the possibility of walking out of the marriage reduces the abilityto share risk.

    In this models the introduction of unilateral divorce worsens thecommitment technology.

    If we had individual consumption data we could just run BPPregressions on individual consumption under mutual consent andunilateral divorce and see how those coefficients change.

    We do not have data on individual consumption, but we can usesimulations from the model.

    The paper also examines how individual consumption responds todivorce in both regimes.

    ∆ log(c jit) = κj + µj∆ log(y jit) + ν

    j ′X jit + �jit

    log(c jit) = χj + ηjDivorcedit + ψ

    j ′X jit + ρji + v

    jit

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 36 / 38

  • Voena (2015)

    Divorce laws and consumption insurance

    Consumption is more responsive to the husband’s income underunilateral divorce for all property division regimes.

    This is not true for the wife’s income, because under unilateraldivorce wives work less.

    Moreover, divorce is associated with a drop in consumption in allinstitutional arrangements for both wife and husband.

    Husbands suffer the least from divorce under unilateral divorce and atitle-based regime.

    Wives suffer the least under mutual consent and a communityproperty regime.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 37 / 38

  • Summary

    Summary

    Introduced the static unitary and collective models of the household,and revised some literature that suggests that the collective modelhas more empirical support.

    Use an influential paper to see how these static models can beextended to a dynamic context.

    When dynamics are introduced, commitment becomes an issue.Revised how to empirically distinguish a model with commitmentfrom a model without commitment.

    Revised an interesting application of the dynamic collective model.

    From this application, we learned that divorce laws affectintertemporal choices of married couples and their welfare by changingtheir ability to commit and the distribution of resources upon divorce.

    Presented by: Mart́ın Garćıa Vázquez Dynamic models of the Household. . . 38 / 38

    Static models of the householdStatic models of the householdMazzocco (2007)Some interesting applications of the collective modelVoena (2015)Summary