the economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production...

26
Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 1999.18 (2), 399-424 The economics of optimal health and productivity in smallholder livestock systems in developing countries J.J. McDermott, T.F. Randolph & S.J. Staal International Livestock Research Institute, P.O. Box 30709, Nairobi, Kenya Summary Livestock kept or produced in smallholder farming systems are an important component of the agricultural economy in the developing world. The role of livestock on smallholder farms varies widely, providing draught power for crop production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist to intensive, peri-urban feeder and dairy systems. A set of unique conditions and features characterise smallholder systems, and these need to be appreciated when assessing the strategies that have evolved for managing animal health in smallholder systems, and evaluating opportunities for improving disease control strategies. To provide a framework for discussing animal health issues and analytical methodogies, a typology of smallholder livestock and crop/livestock systems is developed. The typology considers livestock systems both in terms of the degree of intensification, as measured by market orientation and intensity of factor use, and in terms of importance within the household economy, as measured by contribution to household income. A number of characteristics are identified that distinguish smallholder systems from the commercialised systems of developed countries, including the multiple functions livestock serve, the integrated nature of livestock activities, multiple objectives of producers and lower capacity to bear risk at the household level, as well as poor infrastructure, markets, and access to information at the community level. Three representative smallholder livestock systems from Africa are described in detail, highlighting the relevant characteristics and the implications for analysing disease control strategies. Smallholder dairy systems in Kenya demonstrate the role of individual producer decision-making for animal health management in intensive, market-oriented systems, placing emphasis on farm-level risk and production management aspects of disease control. In extensive pastoralist systems where epidemic diseases are still important and infrastructure is poor, disease control primarily involves managing communal natural resources, requiring a different analytical approach. Finally, in crop farming systems using draught cattle, the livestock activity is an integrated component of crop production and this must be reflected in the approach used to evaluate draught animal health management. Continued development of analytical approaches and decision-support tools for disease control strategies adapted to the special characteristics of these systems will be needed as smallholder systems continue to intensify in areas with good market access, and those in marginal areas face increasing pressures to optimally manage the natural resource base. Keywords Africa - Animal health - Developing countries - Economics - Kenya - Productivity - Smallholders.

Upload: others

Post on 05-Jul-2020

0 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 1999.18 (2), 399-424

The economics of optimal health and productivity in smallholder livestock systems in developing countries

J . J . McDermott, T.F. Randolph & S . J . Staal

International Livestock Research Institute, P.O. Box 30709, Nairobi, Kenya

Summary Livestock kept or produced in smallholder farming s y s t e m s are an important c o m p o n e n t of the agricultural e c o n o m y in the developing w o r l d . T h e role of l ivestock on smallholder f a r m s v a r i e s widely , providing draught p o w e r for crop production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under s y s t e m s ranging f rom extensive pastoralist to intensive, peri-urban f e e d e r and dairy systems. A set of unique conditions and features character ise smallholder s y s t e m s , and these need to be appreciated w h e n assessing the strategies that have e v o l v e d for managing animal health in smallholder systems, and evaluating opportunities for improving disease control strategies. To provide a f r a m e w o r k for discussing animal health issues and analytical methodogies, a t y p o l o g y of smallholder l ivestock and crop/livestock systems is developed. T h e typology considers l ivestock s y s t e m s both in t e r m s of the d e g r e e of intensification, as m e a s u r e d by market orientation and intensity of factor use, and in t e r m s of importance within the household e c o n o m y , as m e a s u r e d by contribution to household income. A number of character ist ics are identified that distinguish smallholder s y s t e m s f rom the commercia l ised systems of developed countr ies, including the multiple funct ions l ivestock s e r v e , the integrated nature of l ivestock activities, multiple object ives of producers and l o w e r capacity to bear risk at the household level , as w e l l as poor infrastructure, markets, and a c c e s s to information at the community level. T h r e e representat ive smallholder l ivestock s y s t e m s f rom A f r i c a are descr ibed in detail, highlighting the relevant character ist ics and the implications for analysing disease control strategies. Smallholder dairy s y s t e m s in Kenya demonstrate the role of individual p r o d u c e r decision-making for animal health m a n a g e m e n t in intensive, market-or iented s y s t e m s , placing emphasis on farm-level risk and production m a n a g e m e n t aspects of disease control . In extensive pastoralist s y s t e m s w h e r e epidemic diseases are still important and infrastructure is poor, disease control primarily involves managing c o m m u n a l natural r e s o u r c e s , requiring a different analytical a p p r o a c h . Finally, in crop farming s y s t e m s using draught cattle, the l ivestock activity is an integrated c o m p o n e n t of crop production and this must be reflected in the approach used to evaluate draught animal health management. Continued development of analytical a p p r o a c h e s and decis ion-support tools for disease control strategies adapted to the special character ist ics of these s y s t e m s will be needed as smallholder systems continue to intensify in areas w i t h good market a c c e s s , and those in marginal areas f a c e increasing p r e s s u r e s to optimally manage the natural r e s o u r c e base.

Keywords Africa - Animal health - Developing countries - Economics - Kenya - Productivity -Smallholders.

Page 2: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

400 Rev. sci tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

Introduction In many developing countries, livestock and mixed crop/livestock production systems are of crucial importance to both household and national economies. For example in Laos, 5 0 % of the gross domestic product (GDP) was attributed to agriculture and 2 2 % to livestock production (47). Overall, livestock production is considered to account for approximately 2 0 % of agricultural output in Asia, 2 5 % in Africa and 4 0 % in Latin America (86). For Asia, where mixed crop/livestock smallholdings predominate, the estimate rises to 3 0 % when manure and draught contributions are included (86). In these continents, usually 6 0 % - 8 0 % of the population consists of farmers. This is in sharp contrast to developed countries. For example, in the United States of America, less than 3 % of the population are farmers and only 2 % of the GDP is attributable to agriculture (5).

Smallholder farming systems in developing countries are varied, depending on ecological, demographic and socio-economic influences. In this paper, smallholdings will be considered to be livestock or mixed crop/livestock production systems whose inputs are primarily derived from the household and whose outputs are meant to contribute to household needs. In many cases, this implies only meeting basic subsistence needs, but in some market-oriented smallholder systems, fanners are able to earn sufficient income to pay for other non-subsistence needs such as education and building livestock and other capital assets. In areas of high population density, particularly close to growing urban markets, a rapidly accelerating trend of both increased intensification and more pronounced market-orientation has been reported among smallholders, particularly dairy farmers (89). While traditional smallholder farmers have not had a strong demand for animal health and production services, both increasing demands and improved opportunities for delivering animal health and production services to farmers will arise in these rapidly intensifying, market-oriented systems.

To consider the economics of animal diseases and disease control in smallholder livestock systems, the unique conditions of these systems need to be well understood. These conditions are both biological and socio-economic. Because of the small size and complex household goals of smallholder systems, animal health and disease control programmes designed for livestock systems in developed countries are not directly transferable; the standard health, productivity and economic indicators used to assess herd health and productivity in larger-scale livestock holdings often need to be modified. In this paper, the key characteristics and dynamics of smallholder systems are reviewed and the influence of these factors on methods for conducting economic analysis of animal diseases and disease control in the developing world context are discussed.

To provide this overview, the paper will be structured as follows. Firstly, the main smallholder systems in developing countries will be described and characterised. Secondly, the unique characteristics that distinguish smallholder systems from highly commercialised, specialised production systems in developed countries will be discussed. Next, using case studies from the spectrum of smallholder systems, specific issues associated with animal health constraints, methods to assess the impacts of these constraints, and methods to assess optimal control strategies will be highlighted. Lastly, the future will be considered by proposing priorities and approaches for optimising animal health and productivity management in rapidly evolving smallholder production systems.

Smallholder livestock production systems in the developing world As stated above, a relatively broad definition of smallholding has been selected, emphasising the role of household inputs and income as the classification criteria. This differs from common definitions of smallholder livestock units that are often defined as having less than a certain number of livestock (e.g. < 10 TLU [tropical livestock unit, the equivalent of an animal of 250 kg live weight]) or a certain land size (< 5 ha) . This approach to defining smallholders has been adopted for two main reasons. Firstly, livestock numbers and land size of 'smallholdings' are dependent on agro-ecological potential, demographic and other socio-economic factors. Thus, if uniform livestock number and land size criteria were applied, units that would be classed as a smallholding in a semi-arid area of Africa would be a largeholding in a densely-populated area of South-East Asia. Secondly, a focus on household inputs and income provides a common, farmer-centred, economic indicator for understanding the decisions made in the diverse circumstances faced by farmers. This approach means that both the common and unique features can be highlighted, across the full range of pastoral, mixed crop/livestock, and landless livestock production systems. The authors believe that this is very important; both to learn lessons from, and make predictions about, specific smallholder systems found within the spectrum of market-orientation and intensification levels currently practised.

This comparative perspective, calls for a general typology of smallholder livestock systems that takes into account the gradients from extensive pastoral to landless, from subsistence to market-oriented, from livestock-dominated to crop-dominated and from mixed to specialised systems, using only a few, generic classification criteria. With respect to

Page 3: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 401

household income and livestock production practices, key characteristics would include the following:

a) type of inputs used (e.g. forages, concentrates, preventive medicines and supplements, cattle breeds and services [breeding, health])

b) source of inputs (purchased or gathered)

c) density of livestock units (land area per livestock unit)

d) market-orientation (percentage of livestock products or services sold)

e) relative contribution of livestock to agricultural and household income.

Many of these household characteristics are correlated with each other and are strongly influenced by factors such as markets, disease risk and livestock policies operating at regional, national and agro-ecological levels.

A number of potentially useful typologies, from different intervention perspectives, could be used (e.g. feeds [7]). From the perspective of the theme of this book 'The economics of animal disease control', disease risk and ability to provide and sustain disease control inputs need to be considered. Some important variables influencing disease risk are management practices, livestock density, livestock movement patterns, and level of production. With respect to providing disease control services, the potentially important variables are disease risk, livestock density, market-orientation and degree of specialisation in livestock. Given the focus here, on the economics of animal disease in smallholder systems and the correlation between many of the important household characteristics that influence this subject, a typology is proposed with two broad classification axes that encompass what the authors consider to be the most important factors.

Axis 1: degree of intensification of the livestock activity The first axis relates only to the livestock sub-sector of the household, regardless of the importance of this aspect within the household economy, and characterises the relative intensity of the livestock production activity. Numerous measures of intensification have been proposed which are often highly correlated. The authors consider the following particularly relevant:

a) use of purchased inputs (indicator: percentage of inputs used for livestock activities that are purchased)

b) land area per head of livestock used for the livestock activity or maintenance of livestock

c) market orientation for production (indicator: percentage of livestock production and services sold).

Axis 2: importance of livestock activities within the household economy The main indicator is the percentage of total household income generated by livestock activities. Household income includes both cash and non-cash income (e.g. milk consumed on-farm). As noted above, in integrated crop/livestock systems, an estimation of income indirectly derived from livestock activities, such as the additional crop production generated by use of manure and draught power, is also important.

The principal, generic smallholder systems can then be related in terms of these two axes, generating the classification shown in Figure 1.

As an example, this typology has been used to classify some important African smallholder livestock production systems (Fig. 2) .

A number of important economic characteristics of smallholder systems vary along the gradients of these two axes of intensification, and together with them, characteristics related to disease risk and animal health strategies. For example, epidemic diseases are of much greater importance in extensive systems, and production diseases only found in very intensive systems. With respect to the supply and demand of animal health and production services, as a general rule, the greater the degree of intensification, the greater the demand for specialised services and the lower the transaction costs. Another key attribute of households in intensive systems is the greater need for decision-making tools. Tools are required to optimise the allocation of resources to different livestock and crop enterprises on the farm and to manage risk. While households in intensive systems may have less absolute risk than those in extensive systems (particularly in extreme environments), these households have a greater ability to manage risk. Thus, in intensive systems, decision tools for risk management will be more relevant. This is particularly important for households in intensive systems that are highly dependent on livestock. The other important feature of the livestock dependency axis is that farmers dependent on livestock have and can develop more specialised animal health and production management skills. These general economic features will be further expanded in the individual smallholder system scenarios presented later.

Special considerations in smallholder systems in developing countries To set the stage for the discussion of the economics of optimal health and productivity in certain smallholder livestock systems, it is useful to highlight the unique features of

Page 4: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

402 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

Fig. 1 C l a s s i f i c a t i o n of d i f f e r e n t s m a l l h o l d e r f a r m i n g s y s t e m s by d e g r e e of i n t e n s i f i c a t i o n a n d r e l a t i v e i m p o r t a n c e of l i v e s t o c k a c t i v i t i e s w i t h i n t h e h o u s e h o l d

smallholder systems that influence animal health and production, and that differ from commercialised livestock production systems in developed countries. Highlighting these differences is important in guiding decisions concerning which economic decision-making techniques might be usefully applied in smallholder systems. The generic characteristics of smallholder systems that might limit the usefulness of techniques presented elsewhere in this issue will be identified below. This should also help to motivate subsequent discussion on the needs for economic decision-making techniques in smallholder systems, whether newly developed or adapted from other settings.

Household level Fundamental differences exist in structure, objectives and function between smallholder farms and large-scale commercial farms. Some important differences with respect to the economics of animal health and production programmes are listed below.

a) Small size, which is reflected in lack of market power for both inputs and outputs and relatively high transaction costs.

b) Low proportion of monetised transactions related to costs and returns, making allocation of values difficult in economic analyses.

c) Lower capacity to bear risk. Smallholder households are generally much closer to the survival threshold, and given that livestock often represent relatively large-value assets, loss of animals has particularly important implications for household welfare.

d) Different economic objectives of producers. Smallholder farmers are often not solely interested in simple profit maximisation, as can be safely assumed in economic decision-making tools for large-scale commercial producers. As noted in c), above, in many situations smallholders will be equally as anxious to minimise risk.

e) Multiple functions of livestock. On smallholder farms, livestock provide multiple primary products (meat, milk, and hides). In addition, livestock provide inputs for cropping and other farm activities (draught, manure and transport). Livestock also often serve two crucial banking functions: as a tool to build assets and as a source of regular cash and emergency funds during the year.

f) Livestock serve as a non-separable component of an integrated farming system. In integrated crop/livestock systems, livestock do not represent a classic, isolated input-output enterprise activity. Instead, livestock activities are seen to have many interactions, joint inputs and joint outputs associated with other farm activities (for example,

D e g r e e of intensi f icat ion of l i v e s t o c k act iv i ty Increasing market orientation —-

Decreasing land per head —

Deg

ree

of im

port

ance

of

lives

tock

Lo

w

in f

arm

hou

seho

ld e

cono

my

Hig

h Pe

rcen

tage

of h

ouse

hold

inco

me

Page 5: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 403

improvements in soil fertility and crop yields due to increased efficiency of nitrogen and phosphorus cycling through ruminant livestock).

g) Low or no economies of scale. In most smallholder systems the opportunity costs of labour are very low. With low opportunity cost of labour, there are few opportunities to achieve economies of scale, which in livestock technology are mainly associated with substituting capital for labour (milking machines, mechanised feeding, etc.). Thus, smallholders can often compete very well with large-scale animal production in such settings, resulting in the observed small proportion of successful large-scale production in many developing countries.

External factors In addition to inherent differences at the household level, because of the characteristics of small size and location in developing countries, smallholder farms are much more reliant on, and susceptible to, the external environment. The following external factors have important implications for animal health and production.

a) Inefficient livestock input and output markets. Market access is a crucial feature determining demand and prices for livestock products and costs and supply of inputs. In many countries, concentrated effective demand to support strong markets for inputs and livestock products is lacking, especially in poor rural areas. In other settings, the occurrence of epidemic diseases restricts access to export markets.

b) Poor infrastructure and public services. The lack of infrastructure and public services is an indirect constraint limiting input and output markets. This is also a direct animal disease constraint in many developing countries where state Veterinary Services can no longer supply the essential public goods of controlling epidemic and endemic diseases (especially those with externalities, such as vector-borne diseases).

c) Poor flow of information. Smallholder farmers make animal health management decisions based on very limited information. Constraints include limited opportunities to learn by direct observation of successes on other farms, poor extension and information systems and lack of training or practice in decision-making. Improved information flow can

D e g r e e of i n t e n s i f i c a t i o n of l i v e s t o c k a c t i v i t y Increasing market orientation

Decreasing land per head

Deg

ree

of im

port

ance

of

lives

tock

act

ivit

y in

farm

hou

seho

ld e

cono

my

Perc

enta

ge o

f hou

seho

ld in

com

e

Fig. 2 Typology of some important African smallholder systems including livestock

Page 6: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

404 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

be a powerful tool to support animal health decisions on smallholder farms.

d) Potential benefits of community action. Because of the small scale of production and lack of external infrastructure, smallholders are often more reliant on support from other community members for activities, such as vector control, and input supply (e.g. water or communal grazing). While community action is often necessary, problems in mobilising community support may be encountered, particularly when opportunities exist for individual livestock owners to benefit from the disease control activities of others. This is termed 'free-riding' and examples include benefiting from herd immunity due to vaccination programmes or reduced vector or parasite populations due to treatments by neighbours.

e) A range of dependence on communal resources. Smallholder systems vary greatly in this regard, from pastoral herders at one extreme to small private dairy farmers at the other. Most, however, do depend to some extent on communal resources for animal feed. Even small dairy farmers may cut and carry grass from roadsides. In many cases, therefore, the behaviour and decisions of the farmer are associated with 'externalities' which concern others in the community.

Case studies of economic impacts of animal diseases and disease control in different smallholder systems This section develops three examples from the range of smallholder systems across the typology spectrum developed above. These include:

a) the smallholder mixed dairy system in highland Kenya b) the pastoralist system in arid and semi-arid Africa c) the draught oxen/cotton system in West Africa.

For each case study, the unique considerations of the system will be explored, the major disease constraints will be outlined, methods found successful in constraint diagnosis in the system will be described, and strategies proposed or used to control disease and improve animal health and production will be highlighted. These would include both farm and extra-farm diagnostic techniques and issues.

The smallholder dairy farming system in Kenya D e s c r i p t i o n of t h e f a r m i n g s y s t e m The smallholder dairy systems of the Kenya highlands are an example of intensive small-scale production systems in which crops and livestock are very closely integrated and where market factors have been crucial to development. Characteristic of tropical regions with good market access, the development of smallholder dairy systems in the Kenya

highlands is marked by three elements: declining farm size, upgrading into dairy breeds and an increasing reliance on purchased feeds, both concentrates and forage (9). With high population growth and consequent reduction in land-holding sizes, farmers have developed a dairy enterprise which is closely integrated into a multi-objective farming system, also relying on cash crops (coffee, tea, and closer to the urban centres, market vegetables and fruit), maize and beans, and supported by off-farm income from towns. Central to the success of this intensive highland system has been a high demand for dairy products, particularly liquid milk.

Within this system, farms can be divided by level of intensification, based on land-holding size and use of grazing, and fall into two main zones. A marked increase in more intensive dairy production has occurred in the last ten years (1). The most intensive dairy producing areas are found within 150 km of the capital, Nairobi, at altitudes over 1,500 m. Two harvests of food crops per year are usually possible under the bimodal rainfall pattern. Farms are frequently 1-2 ha in size with one to two dairy cows (generally high percentage Holstein-Friesian or Ayrshire crossed with local Zebu) with about the same number of female calves and heifers. Feeding is mainly 'cut-and-carry' of planted Napier grass (Pennisetum purpureurti) and crop residues, especially from maize and bananas, as well as weeds ('cut-and-carry' refers to the practice in smallholder dairy farms of feeding stall-confined cows by daily harvesting of grasses or other feedstuffs from the nearby vicinity and by carrying these grasses to the stall). Fodder from roadsides and other common land sources forms an important contribution to the basal diet. Purchases of Napier grass, maize stover and roadside grass are common, and a complex market has developed to supply these. On some farms, grazing/tethering along roadsides is occasionally carried out, but very few farms devote land to pasture. In most cases, cattle rarely leave the homestead dairy enclosures. In addition, 2-3 kg of concentrate feed is given to milking cows each day, in the form of either compounded dairy meal, maize bran, cotton seed cake, or others. On average, total daily milk output is some 10 kg per farm, of which a quarter is for home consumption and the remainder sold (76) .

In more land-extensive areas of the highlands, further from urban areas, smallholder dairy production relies on grazing to a greater extent. Farms range from 1.5 to 5 ha in size, rotated between natural or planted pasture and maize, sorghum and potatoes, depending on altitude. Dairy animals thus rely mainly on grazing, although fodder maize or sorghum is commonly grown to provide for the dry season and concentrates are often fed to milking cows. The breeds are the same as those in the more intensive areas, although often with higher local Zebu content. Milk production per acre per year is less than 500 kg on these farms, compared to over 1,000 kg on intensive farms (75).

Page 7: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 405

Particularly in the intensive areas, cattle manure and/or manure mixed with urine are used to fertilise food and cash crops, market vegetables, and on planted fodder. In some cases, manure is sold to other farmers, and manure is also imported by truck from drier pastoral areas and marketed to farmers. The general nutrient deficits in soils under the intensive bimodal cropping result in a high value for manure, due to demand for both nitrogen and organic matter. As a result, the market value for manure is relatively high, and the value of manure produced is equivalent to some 2 8 % of the value of the annual milk production on small farms (41). This is indicative of the importance of manure for the farming system as a whole, and the importance of manure as a livestock product.

Marketing of milk is the crucial element of this system. Until the late 1980s, milk sales were mainly through local dairy cooperative societies, which then sold the milk to a large parastatal monopoly processor. However, significant amounts of milk were also sold directly by farmers to consumers or informally through raw milk vendors. Since economic reforms and liberalisation in the early 1990s, marketing channels have diversified (see Figure 3 for an example of evolving channels in an intensive dairy area bordering Nairobi), with a larger proportion of direct sales or informal sales (56) . These sales are considered 'informai', as they are generally of raw milk and are not sanctioned by the authorities. These more direct sales of milk provide higher sales prices to farmers and lower purchase prices to

consumers, but create increasing concerns about milk safety. Regardless of market outlet, smallholder farms are highly market-oriented, with milk sales as the primary production objective.

The liberalisation of the early 1990s also affected the provision of livestock services. Public support for artificial insemination (Al) and clinical veterinary services declined, with the private sector left to assume responsibility. Some cooperatives and private veterinarians have begun providing these services. However, the use of AI has declined and some farmers report difficulty in obtaining veterinary services. In the intensive areas, AI is used by some 4 0 % of farmers, but the proportion falls to 1 0 % in the more extensive zones (75) .

Income increases with intensification. Estimates from 1998 showed that intensive dairying offered the highest returns to labour per farm (returns to labour are profits after all variable and fixed costs have been deducted, with the exception of family labour costs), on average the equivalent of nearly US$1,000 per year (1). However, this does not recognise differences in the opportunity cost of family labour compared to the extensive production areas, where opportunity costs for labour are considerably lower. When the same returns to labour are calculated per litre of milk, the results are reversed. On average, intensive farms earn lower returns to labour per litre of milk than less intensified farms (about US$0.21 versus US$0.40, respectively). These results suggest that if real milk

KCC: Kenya Cooperative Creameries

Fig. 3 Sale and consumption of milk from dairy farms in Kiambu District, Kenya

Page 8: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

406 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

prices decrease over time, low intensity systems will remain competitive, while high intensity dairy production may not. These results also underline the importance to intensive farms of relatively high volumes of production, in order to cover higher fixed costs.

D i s e a s e c h a l l e n g e a n d o t h e r r i s k s Because of minimal movement of animals, directly transmissible infectious diseases, such as brucellosis, are uncommon (37). Endemic diseases, particularly, pneumonia and diarrhoea of calves are much more common, with calf mortality exceeding 2 0 % on average (19). Since calves are in direct competition with humans for milk, growth rates are low (0.2 kg-0.25 kg per day) and significant morbidity and mortality are associated with premature weaning (18) . Calf mortality, combined with long calving intervals associated with poor breeding decisions (54), limits the number of heifers available for selection to join the dairy herd.

East Coast fever (ECF) caused by Theileria parva, transmitted by the tick Rhipicephalus appendiculatus, has been an important problem in highland areas because of the high climatic suitability for the tick (59). Infections with other tick-borne pathogens, particularly Babesia bigemina and Anaplasma marginale, are relatively common but morbidity and mortality are uncommon (53). Until the late 1980s, the Government provided tick control in the form of weekly acaricide dipping. The risk of ECF varies according to agro-ecological zone and grazing system (20). In intensive areas where all cows are stall-fed (zero-grazing), ECF challenge is characterised by low intensity and infrequent challenge resulting in low risk of mortality. On grazing farms in more extensive areas, challenge is more frequent and of higher intensity. Significant mortality can result under such conditions if tick control (usually by hand-spraying) and other risk management strategies are not applied (53) . Treatment for clinical ECF is available, but requires rapid diagnosis and is expensive. Thus, although risk is low in intensive areas, case-fatality rates can be high. This can be an important worry for risk-averse smallholder farmers owning only one or two expensive cattle. An infection and treatment immunisation method, costing approximately US$18-US$20, has been developed but is not widely available due to requirements for a liquid nitrogen cold chain and careful veterinary follow-up for adverse reactors (49). Recombinant vaccines are under research but are not yet available.

Given the intensive and sometimes unhygienic conditions on dairy farms, the potential for the occurrence of mastitis and lameness is high. Infections with mastitis-causing organisms and high somatic cell counts are common. However, impacts of mammary infections on the relatively low levels of milk produced on most farms are inconsequential (55). Likewise for lameness: a high proportion of cows have abnormal hoof conformation or lesions but do not exhibit clinical lameness (21, 22) . It has been suggested that the incidence and impact of both mastitis and lameness (and perhaps other diseases

associated with intensive dairy farming in developed countries) will increase as milk production levels increase over time (55). This is also likely to be the case for nutritional disorders, especially as fanners have to manage a more complex set of feed inputs, often varying seasonally (75) to support better reproductive performance and increased milk production.

Risk to farmer income and welfare also occurs through the high degree of market exposure of the dairy enterprise, both in inputs and outputs. Research in the intensive dairy system has shown that extension recommendations towards higher use of concentrate feed and animal health inputs may not raise farmer welfare (38). Although incomes are raised by these interventions through higher milk yields and reduced mortality, the variability of income is also raised. This is due to climatic variability in fodder production, and fluctuations in milk prices. Increased expenditure on inputs increases the exposure of the farm to these risks, and stochastic dominance analysis indicates that under these circumstances, risk-averse farmers would suffer a greater loss in welfare than if the system remained at lower levels of input use, production and average income.

A s s e s s i n g t h e e c o n o m i c s of o p t i m a l d a i r y h e a l t h a n d p r o d u c t i o n Issues arising from specifics of the system The description of the smallholder dairy systems and the risks farmers in these systems face raises several issues which must be addressed in any analysis of the impact of diseases on cattle in these systems. These issues are as follows:

a) the high complementarities/interactions between livestock, crops and rest of the farm

b) a high degree of market orientation for both inputs and outputs

c) manure as an important product

d) risks due to variability in markets and production

e) the essentially private nature of the smallholder dairy enterprise.

The first issue affects the way in which the impact of livestock disease and its control is valued for smallholder dairy animals. Whereas in commercialised systems, livestock are analysed in isolation, the physical complementarities in smallholder systems require an examination of the contribution of livestock to other farm crops and activities, as well as the dependence of livestock on these activities (Fig. 4 ) . The lost value of the various livestock outputs, including manure, must be captured in the overall losses due to disease. Unlike in the crop/livestock systems of West Africa (described later), animal draught power is not an output, so the main livestock products are milk, culled and sold animals and manure. Methods for assessing the value of manure are discussed below. Livestock may also add value to some crops and planted fodder used by livestock as feed. Maize is both a food

Page 9: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 1812) 407

Forage and concentrate Marketing

impact)

Sales and purchases

Fig. 4

Complementarities and interactions between different enterprises on a typical mixed dairy smallholding in highland Kenya Courtesy of Dr Jon Tanner, International Livestock Research Institute

and fodder crop, with maize stover fed to dairy animals, as are maize thinning and leaf Strippings. The value of planted fodder, either Napier grass, or maize and sorghum planted as fodder, naturally depends entirely on the contribution of this fodder to livestock output. Generally, the returns to both crop residues and planted fodder are considered as a part of the revenues from livestock marketed outputs, so that a loss in milk and animal sales revenue is partially a loss in returns to crops and planted fodder. When evaluating disease losses, quantification of the share represented by the value of crops fed is of little use since the overall loss to the farm remains the same. What is important, however, is valuing cost savings in terms of the residual market value of those crop and fodder products otherwise not used when livestock are lost. In the smallholder dairy areas of Kenya, maize stover and planted fodder are readily marketed, and the market value can be easily measured. In an analysis of losses due to animal disease, those losses should then be reduced by the market value of crop residues and fodder that are made available to the market by the lower on-farm demand for fodder.

Aside from the physical crop/livestock interactions, economic complementarities between dairy and other farm/household activities may be important. Off-farm income, as well as seasonal income from cash crops, may be important sources

of working capital to pay for feeds and other purchased inputs and the role of this income needs to be considered in any analysis of a dairy enterprise.

The major risk elements mentioned above, climatic and market variability, may accelerate the decline in the marginal value product of purchased inputs as the level of use increases. The importance of risk here can be understood by comparison with other smallholder systems. In pastoral systems, the actual risks faced, of severe hunger due to loss of all livestock from drought, are substantially higher. However, pastoralists have few livelihood choices available beyond livestock keeping, and the risks are simply an unavoidable part of the cost of the system. In the highland dairy system, on the other hand, many choices are available to farmers through various cash crops, food crops or even employment off-farm. Risk management can greatly influence farmer choice of enterprise, the level of enterprise, and the mix of enterprises. For example, the complementary income flows from dairy and coffee (daily versus seasonally) may lead farmers to combine these two activities to maximise cash flow and savings objectives. Thus, although risks, and the costs of these risks, may be lower in the highland system, the effects on decision-making by the farmer are greater.

Page 10: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

408 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 1812)

The high degree of market orientation, combined with the private nature of land and cattle ownership, and the relatively low use of communal or public land, makes the smallholder dairy enterprise an essentially private one. Decision-making rests solely within the household, in this case, shared by husband and wife due to the strong traditional role of women in milking cattle. Costs and revenues are almost all privately captured, with few externalities through use of common property, in contrast to pastoral systems where much of the costs of grazing are borne by the community. The private nature of the enterprise has several effects as follows:

a) economic analysis can largely follow a standard enterprise analysis (although accounting for household objectives) with externalities playing a small role, if any

b) demand for inputs and services are enterprise-driven. This means that many farmers are willing to pay for livestock services, so that animal disease control measures may be privatised to a much greater extent. From an analytical point of view, this also means that expressed demand of farmers fairly values those inputs and services. Farmers may prefer technologies which they can manage individually. One example of this has been the switch from communal acaricide dips to spraying by farmers themselves. This technology allows farmers individual control of resource allocation for tick control, providing a control level suitable for each dairy enterprise.

A p p r o a c h e s to a n a l y s i n g f a r m / h o u s e h o l d e c o n o m i c l o s s e s d u e to d i s e a s e Two basic approaches can be used to assess the losses due to animal disease at the smallholder farm level, as follows:

a) partial budget or cost-benefit analysis (CBA)

b) mathematical modelling, either of the optimisation or simulation type. Extrapolating farm-level results to the regional level requires an adjustment of the results based on numbers of animals and probabilities of loss, in addition to other assumptions regarding changes in prices, etc.

Rushton et al. describe the essence of CBA in an accompanying paper in this issue (67) . The reader can find additional comprehensive presentations of the methodology elsewhere (15 , 23 , 63 , 64 ) . This technique can quite easily be applied to the market-oriented smallholder dairy setting in most cases. This type of analysis requires that unit values of all resource flows, inputs and outputs in the farm/household system be first estimated and then entered into the analysis. In the highly market-oriented system, this may be relatively straightforward, even for unconventional products, since manure, crop residues and fodder values can often be observed in the market place. However, the researcher must judge whether these market values reflect adequately the value of those resource contributions to inter-farm flows.

More difficult to value may be the opportunity cost of family labour, which often represents a substantial portion of production costs in intensive dairy systems. Some indication

of the value can be obtained from the observed rural daily wage rate, conditioned by the expectation of employment and the reservation wage (a reservation wage rate is that below which a person would rather not work at all, and reflects the value of leisure). Conversely, if the opportunity cost of land is known, the labour opportunity cost can be estimated through the returns to the main agricultural commodities in the region. The opportunity cost of labour is generally lower than the market rural wage rate. Similarly, an indication of the opportunity cost of land can be obtained by rural land rental rates.

More sophisticated analysis of the impacts of losses due to diseases often requires the use of a mathematical model. Simulation models can be thought of as more detailed benefit-cost models in that these models simply tabulate outcomes based on pre-estimated physical or economic relationships, and based on initial farm and market parameters. However, by adding estimates of the probability distributions of key variables (related to production and markets), risk assessment can also be incorporated. Van Schaik et al. use a Monte Carlo simulation model which includes risk to identify the key production and economic factors affecting economic perfonnance on smallholder dairy farms in Kenya (87). The same model applied to strategies for controlling ECF in smallholder dairy systems along the coast of Kenya, using the stochastic dominance-ranking criterion to assess risk, is found in Nyangito et al. (52).

Because disease control decisions affect resource allocation, methods and tools for optimising resource use will be of increasing utility in this system. Optimisation models (usually linear programming [LP] models; also discussed in the accompanying paper by Rushton et al. [67]) are set up much like simulation models, and describe the interactions and resource availability on a farm. However, the models then solve for the optimal level and direction of resource allocation based on some assumed farm objectives (usually some form of best net returns, conditioned by risk considerations, household food security, etc.). The particular value of such models in this sort of analysis is twofold. Firstly, the links and interrelationships between livestock and other farm activities are captured explicitly. Secondly, within this integrated context, the models are able to determine internally consistent imputed 'shadow' values for intermediate outputs and inputs such as manure, crop residues and planted fodder. In a situation where these values are not easily obtained from market observations, an LP model could be considered. Griffith and Zepeda describe one such model applied to a smallholder dairy (26). Several techniques are also available for incorporating risk assessment into LP models, depending on the perception of the researcher in regard to which factors (e.g. disease risk, price variability) create the most important risk and what the primary farm objectives are. The assumption that farmers seek to ensure a target minimum farm income, for example, may lead one to employ the target MOTAD (minimum of total absolute derivations) model.

Page 11: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. teck Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 409

Descriptions of different approaches to risk modelling can be found in Hazell and Norton (28) and Boisvert and McCarl (4). Again, if uncertainty exists regarding key parameters, sensitivity analysis should be used to assess changes in these values.

The smallholder dairy system in the highlands of Kenya has intensified rapidly in recent years and this trend is expected to accelerate. Markets for milk and farm inputs have changed even more rapidly. The epidemiology of animal diseases will also evolve, with an increasing importance of production-associated diseases, requiring husbandry and nutrition solutions, rather than therapy or vaccination. Because of these rapid changes and also the increasing competition between farms to improve the efficiency of dairy production, a real need (and an opportunity) exists to enhance farmer decision-making in resource allocation, financial management and risk management. Decision­making tools can be adapted from dairy health and production management programmes that have evolved over the past thirty years in the developed world.

Pastoralist extensive systems in semi-arid areas of Africa U n i q u e c o n s i d e r a t i o n s of t h e s y s t e m Pastoralism is the dominant livestock production system in areas of the developing world with uncertain rainfall or other natural constraints to crop production. It is an important production system in human welfare terms, supporting approximately 1 2 % of the population of the world (31) , but is relatively insignificant in marketed livestock production, accounting for less than 1 0 % of all marketed meat and milk (7). However, this limited market orientation greatly underestimates the importance of livestock in pastoralist systems. Livestock are crucial and are often the principal activity supporting livelihoods in harsh environments unsuited to any other form of agriculture. In these societies, livestock are the centrepiece of daily and ceremonial life and are the principle currency for social and commercial transactions.

In Africa, a number of traditional pastoralist societies have been under pressure to change, due to increased competition for land and other factors. Over time, with the expansion of settled crop/livestock farming, pastoralists have been pushed into more and more marginal areas. In some areas, traditional land use arrangements have been modified and new organisations, such as group ranches in Kenya, Mali and Botswana, have developed. Such areas also often have increased access to input and output markets. The emergence of new structures such as these is at a comparatively early stage. Other pastoralist societies have, to a large extent, been able to retain traditional land use, herding and other practices.

The primary characteristic of pastoralist systems is the movement of people and animals to exploit available food and

water. Distances travelled are usually a function of the harshness of the environment. In Africa, these systems are found almost exclusively in arid and semi-arid zones. This mobility of human and livestock populations has a number of practical livestock production, animal disease and economic implications. Due to movement and large distances to markets, high transaction costs are involved in the delivery of animal health goods and services and also in the marketing of livestock products (as evidenced by the low amounts of marketed meat and milk described above). High transaction costs contribute to the low sale value of individual animals in pastoralist areas. Transaction costs also dominate the planning and assessment of animal health service delivery in pastoralist systems, greatly influencing the approaches and methods used to assess delivery strategies.

D i s e a s e c o n s t r a i n t s An important consequence of the large, mobile, and mixing livestock populations of pastoralists is to enhance the probability of transmission of epidemic diseases. In Africa, rinderpest has been the most important of these (see, for example, the historical summary by Schwabe [71]), but the classical form of rinderpest has now been restricted to the southern Sudan by the activities of the Pan African Rinderpest Campaign (PARC) coordinated by the Organisation of African Unity. In recent years, contagious bovine pleuropneumonia has become a more serious threat in a number of countries, where it causes significant morbidity, mortality and production loss (93) . In small ruminants, contagious caprine pleuropneumonia is important in many countries. Foot and mouth disease (FMD) is also widespread in many pastoralist areas. Occurrence of FMD in pastoralist areas usually exhibits peaks at approximately three-year intervals, when a sufficient population of susceptible animals has formed to support transmission. The loss of production due to FMD infection is not particularly significant in pastoralist herds. However, the occurrence of the FMD, along with that of other epidemic diseases, restricts possible export of livestock and livestock products. Export restrictions due to diseases in pastoralist areas may impact on neighbouring non-pastoralist areas in the same or neighbouring countries.

In addition to epidemic diseases, which are the main focus of interest to national and international veterinary authorities, a number of endemic zoonotic diseases are also of significance. Zoonoses are both common and important in most pastoralist areas because of the close associations between humans and animals. Of particular importance is brucellosis, due to Brucella abortus and Brucella melitensis. In many pastoralist areas, the high prevalence of brucellosis in cattle and small ruminants is mirrored by a high prevalence in humans (17, 50) . The disease in humans can be extremely debilitating. Other zoonoses of importance to pastoralists include tuberculosis, echinococcosis and anthrax, among others (71) .

Endemic diseases, particularly bacterial and viral pneumonia and diarrhoea and parasitism in young stock are important

Page 12: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

410 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

(indeed, these diseases are important for all the smallholder production systems discussed in this paper). Morbidity and mortality rates are consistently high in young animals and can also be high in adults under adverse conditions. Reproductive performance, growth rates and milk production are low on average and also fluctuate markedly depending on environmental conditions (3, 91 , 92) . Inadequate animal nutrition is an important determinant and interacting factor for both poor health and productivity. Nutrition is based exclusively on access to, and exploitation of, natural pastures and browse.

A n a l y s i s of t h e i m p a c t of a n i m a l d i s e a s e s a n d d i s e a s e c o n t r o l

In the pastoralist sector, economic assessment tools have focused on decisions to invest in control programmes, particularly vaccination campaigns, for epidemic diseases. Initial analyses, based on simply estimating all direct and certain indirect losses from a disease and implying that all the losses are recoverable through disease control, have been discredited (45). In Africa, ex post CBAs of rinderpest vaccination, for both the JP15 programme in the 1970s (13) and the PARC programme since the 1980s (81) , have been conducted. Specific eradication campaigns are much more amenable to assessment by classic CBAs than the delivery of services that must be sustained over a much longer period. A number of methodological considerations are important to consider in conducting CBAs (15), particularly since estimates of livestock numbers and different direct and indirect losses may be difficult to obtain and of variable quality. Clearly, the assumption of how quickly eradication occurs is crucial to ex ante assessments. A number of strategies can help in decision-making, including sensitivity analysis across the range of important variables and integration with mathematical models of disease transmission under different scenarios.

For large-scale vaccination programmes that cover nations and regions, costs and benefits to different individual sectors need to be estimated. In some circumstances, specific sectors benefit much more from the control or eradication of epidemic diseases, particularly when trade restrictions are involved. This can have direct implications for the pastoralist sector, a recent example being a total ban on Somali livestock exports to the Middle East in 1998, subsequent to reports of Rift Valley fever outbreaks in Somalia and northern Kenya. More common is the situation in which it is economically justified for the government to subsidise pastoralists to help control or eradicate diseases that otherwise would limit trade by commercial livestock sectors; this permits part of the benefits from expanded exports captured by the commercial sector to be effectively transferred to pastoralists whose control measures allow the commercial trade opportunities. Such subsidies are used in southern Africa (88) for the above reason as well as for social equity reasons. Another example is found in the regional analysis of FMD in South-East Asia (60).

A key constraint to sustained delivery of animal health and production services to pastoralists is the extremely high transaction costs. Thus, analyses of potential delivery pathways and assessments of which parties benefit from, and which parties are willing to pay for control and clinical services are of crucial importance to determine the long-term viability and sustainability of these services. In these analyses, the type of animal health good or service should be distinguished as public, private or private with externalities (85). Such classifications are not always simple. For example, in the rinderpest eradication campaign in Africa, some programme elements, particularly the establishment of quarantine areas, clearly represent pure public goods whereas vaccination is a private good with certain public good externalities (the individual herder benefits from the protection of his/her animal and other herders benefit from decreased disease transmission due to enhanced population immunity). The degree to which pastoralists are willing to pay for vaccination will depend on perceptions of the associated risk and benefits. Samburu pastoralists in Kenya, for example, have been willing to pay for rinderpest vaccination, because individuals perceive both important risks and losses. However, the same individuals have been unwilling to pay for vaccination for FMD since losses incurred by FMD are considered to be inconsequential (29) .

Pastoralists are keen to receive other veterinary services beyond vaccination for epidemic diseases. These could be divided into strictly private goods (e.g. clinical services), private goods with moral hazards (e.g. drugs for which protection from sub-standard or fraudulent products is important), private goods with externalities (e.g. pour-on insecticide treatments), and public goods (e.g. quality control of drugs and control of zoonotic diseases). Economic issues related to the delivery of veterinary services in Africa have raised interest in recent years (8, 35 , 42 , 85) , particularly with the downsizing of state Veterinary Services and the increasing reliance on private services. Economic approaches such as the New Institutional Economics (43) and structure-conduct-performance analysis (69) can be applied to assess the suitability and performance of potential delivery pathways for different types of animal health and production services. Economic analysis usually indicates that veterinarians are too expensive and immobile to provide routine clinical and advisory services to pastoralists. Strategies for providing these services are discussed below.

The specific issues related to the economic assessment of zoonotic diseases deserve special mention because of the importance of zoonotic disease in pastoralist systems. Techniques of public health economics and poverty alleviation are most relevant in this context, with the assumption that the importance of human health precludes the use of standard CBAs, shifting the focus, therefore, to analyses of cost-effectiveness. This may be true in wealthy countries, but the huge scale of public health problems in most African countries with pastoralist areas, and the scarce

Page 13: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 411

resources available to tackle these, mean that prioritisation of public health problems is needed first. One useful technique is the standardisation of human health impact using disability adjusted life years (DALYS) (51) . For brucellosis, it would be useful to incorporate the additional animal health and productivity effects to prioritisation estimates, possibly justifying control programmes in animals.

Standard techniques to assess economic decision-making on farm 'enterprises', such as gross margins or partial budgets (11), have little utility for pastoralists now or in the near future. Economic values of inputs and outputs in these systems are difficult to estimate and not of particular interest in most pastoral settings.

A n i m a l h e a l t h a n d p r o d u c t i o n s e r v i c e s t r a t e g i e s As mentioned, a key necessity for providing veterinary services to pastoralists is to reduce transaction costs. Constraints and options for the delivery of different animal health and production services are presented in Table I. A number of schemes have been proposed (see for example, Majok [46]). Trained paraveterinarians or 'barefoot vets' (25, 27, 71) have been used, with some success. In livestock-based societies, many people have specialist knowledge and skills in obstetrics, surgery and other procedures (25) . The advances of modem veterinary research such as vaccines and drugs can be combined with well-documented traditional veterinary

expertise in most pastoralist cultures (72) , either by training traditional healers or by developing partnerships between them and trained paraveterinarians (71) .

Delivery of multiple services could also reduce transaction costs for delivery of services to pastoralists. One option proposed by Schwabe is to mix community and veterinary health services (71) . This is a particular option in pastoralist areas where veterinary services are often more readily available and in greater demand than medical services. Another option for reducing transaction costs is to schedule service provision to coincide with market days or other community events.

While paraveterinarians are likely to be, and to remain, the main cadre of animal health service providers for pastoralists, some graduate veterinary expertise will probably be required. The trend is for this to be provided by private veterinary practitioners (8). Again, special incentives and innovative arrangements will be required. In Kenya, private veterinary practice has flourished in areas of high human and livestock densities close to major cities over the last ten years, but almost no private veterinarians are based in the more remote pastoral areas (90) . This may be overcome by allowing the development of quasi-private or public-private practitioners with either public vets allowed to conduct some

Table I Delivery of animal health services for pastoralists: beneficiaries, constraints and options

A n i m a l h e a l t h g o o d / s e r v i c e C l a s s of e c o n o m i c g o o d

B e n e f i c i a r y ( w h o c a n or s h o u l d pay)

D e l i v e r y c o n s t r a i n t s Opt ions to i m p r o v e d e l i v e r y

C l i n i c a l s e r v i c e c u r a t i v e Private Herder High transaction costs Trained paraveterinarians d r u g s Public education

Trained personnel Poor markets

Combined veterinary and medical treatment Community education and participation

Parasi te/vector c o n t r o l Private with externalities Herder High transaction costs Public education Trained personnel Poor markets

Trained paraveterinarians Community education and participation Adaptive research

V a c c i n a t i o n ( c o m p u l s o r y Private with externalities Herder High transaction costs Community education and or v o l u n t a r y ) Government

Other beneficiaries Public education participation

Subsidies from beneficiaries Qual i ty c o n t r o l Public Herder Trained personnel Community education and d r u g s / v a c c i n e s Government Infrastructure

Public awareness of benefits participation

S u r v e i l l a n c e / m o v e m e n t Public Government Understanding of collective Community education and c o n t r o l Identified beneficiaries benefits participation

P u b l i c h e a l t h Public Government Public education Community education and Community Infrastructure participation NGOs Trained personnel Adaptive research

A d a p t i v e r e s e a r c h Public Government Community NGOs

Trained personnel Public education

Community participation

P o l i c y Public Community Weak public institutions Political activism Government Low political importance of

pastoralism Community education and participation

NGO: non-governmental organisation

Page 14: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

412 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

private practice, as has been the case in India (68), or to guarantee private veterinarians a basic level of public sector service contracts, a practice common in many developed countries.

Nutrition is a major constraint in pastoralist systems and is a major contributing factor in the occurrence of endemic diseases. Seasonal shortages of natural pastures is a perennial problem but has been exacerbated in many cases by partial or complete loss of grazing areas, particularly more favourable ones, to sedentary farmers. The need for information to guide policy decisions in this area is extremely important. While large-scale nutritional supplements to natural pastures are not feasible, targeted interventions can be useful. A good example is provided by Stem who reported on the assessment of vitamin A supplementation among the Tuareg in Niger (78).

For any animal health and productivity strategy, the importance of community participation and education cannot be overemphasised (29, 78) . Techniques need to be adapted for local circumstances (78). Pastoralist societies are quite heterogeneous in regard to traditions and exposure to, and acceptance of, outside influences. In some areas, pastoralist societies have retained a strong structure of traditional grazing management and animal health services. Ethnoveterinary approaches have shown considerable benefits in fostering community participation and improving understanding of how interventions can be adapted to local contexts (44).

I m p o r t a n t i s s u e s f o r t h e f u t u r e Pastoral systems are unique and require different approaches to animal health and productivity improvement. A number of policy issues are of crucial importance. These include land rights, optimal land use, enhancement of market-oriented trade, alleviation of poverty and prioritisation of investments. Better information and community participation and consensus will be the key ingredients in the process of developing optimal strategies for animal health and productivity in pastoral systems. Economic assessments can play an important role. At the micro-economic level, an ethnoveterinary approach to help better understand poverty issues and the impact of different interventions at household level is necessary. Interventions intended to benefit all households need to make a special effort to reach poorer groups (78). A particular advantage of the ethnoveterinary approach is that communities are involved in the research process so that results will have greater relevance and thus are more likely to be adopted and have impact. Methods being developed in environmental impact assessment can contribute to the many important questions about natural resource management relative to pastoralist livestock production and environmental sustainability as traditional pastoral strategies come under increasing pressure. An important task for researchers in this process is to develop better transdisciplinary approaches (involving, for example, biology, range and veterinary science, economics or sociology) to support decision-making by pastoralists and

policy makers (10). Pastoralists have adapted to harsh environments by understanding and adapting to the system. Such a broad perspective needs to be kept at the centre of strategies to improve animal health and productivity in pastoral systems.

Mixed farming system with draught oxen in West Africa T h e f a r m i n g s y s t e m Over the past three decades, the use of livestock for animal traction for crop production has expanded significantly across the sub-humid zones of West Africa. As a result, new farming systems have evolved that integrate draught livestock -particularly cattle - into sedentary, crop-based smallholder farms.

The areas where this has occurred lie mainly in the transition zone between the Sahara and the humid forests along the coast of West Africa. This transition zone, which from The Gambia and Senegal stretches east through northern Nigeria, consists of the semi-arid Sahelo-Sudanese and semi-humid Sudano-Guinean zones with flat plains or rolling hills of partially wooded savanna (24). Although the zone has generally good agricultural potential, development had long been constrained by health problems, especially onchocerciasis for humans and trypanosomosis for livestock. While onchocerciasis has been nearly eradicated from the region, trypanosomosis transmitted by the tsetse fly remains endemic throughout much of the zone.

The threat of trypanosomosis has been an important factor in shaping farming systems in the region. Cattle herding has generally been concentrated in pastoralist systems in the drier areas where fewer tsetse flies are found; the cattle are only moved southward to look for water and grazing during the dry season, or when being taken to markets on the coast. Farming systems in the semi-arid and sub-humid zones to the south are predominantly crop-based, with livestock playing a minor role, mainly as a savings mechanism. If cattle are kept, they are generally kept off the farm in transhumant, communal herds managed by pastoralist peoples (70, 83) .

To improve rural incomes in this zone, policy makers have long promoted the development of cash crop production: groundnuts and cotton in Senegal and The Gambia, and rice and cotton elsewhere. However, small farm sizes and low availability of labour limited the area that could be devoted to such crops and the capacity to intensify production, creating supply constraints for the agro-industrial sector that depended on this output. In response, the parastatals responsible for developing cash crop production promoted mechanisation technologies based on draught cattle (77) . Uptake was initially slow since most people had little or no tradition of keeping cattle on-farm, and losses were often high (65, 77) . In the 1970s and 1980s, however, cotton production in particular expanded rapidly in many areas, and

Page 15: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 413

accompanying this was a rapid expansion in the use of draught power. In Côte d'Ivoire, for example, the number of draught oxen in the country increased from 200 in 1965 to 6,500 in 1975, and reached 39 ,100 by 1985 (32) . By the mid-1980s, 2 5 % of all crop farms in the cotton zone of Boundiali in northern Côte d'Ivoire possessed draught oxen (70). It is interesting to note that Itty partially attributes the adoption of animal traction during this period to the droughts of the 1970s since the dryer weather apparently reduced the threat of trypanosomosis (32) .

The use of draught power is now well established throughout the zone. Teams of draught animals are often kept by larger farmers, who use the animals mainly for land preparation, as well as for transport. These farms usually practise rotational cropping on areas of two to ten hectares, devoting a significant portion of land to the cash crop (cotton, groundnuts) and the rest to food crops (rice, maize, millet) or fallow. Keeping draught animals also provides additional benefits in terms of manure to fertilise crops, although this practice is certainly not yet generalised in West Africa. Smaller farms often hire animal traction services for land preparation if they do not

keep their own. Cattle traction is also found on irrigated rice schemes such as the 45 ,000 ha Office du Niger scheme in Mali (36) .

D i s e a s e c o n s t r a i n t s The most important health constraint faced by farmers keeping draught animals in West Africa remains trypanosomosis (77) . The impact of the disease on draught animals is portrayed in Figure 5. Swallow makes a very useful distinction between the impact of trypanosomosis incidence versus trypanosomosis risk (79) . The main effects associated with incidence are often related to morbidity. A diseased animal will be less available for fieldwork, will provide less power if worked, and cows will produce less milk and have longer calving intervals and lower reproduction rates. A sick animal will also consume less, so weight gain will be reduced and manure output will also decline. In some cases, the animal may die. Initial mortality rates for draught animals of up to 1 0 % - 2 5 % have been recorded in several areas across West Africa (77), and even 4 0 % in Mali (65) . Bangura, for example, reported 2 0 % mortality for draught oxen in an oxen traction project in Sierra Leone in 1985, in this case mostly

Fig. 5 The impact of trypanosomosis risk and incidence on draught cattle-based farming systems Adapted from Swallow (79)

Page 16: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

414 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

attributed to Stomoxys flies (2). For farmers in West Africa who do not have a tradition of livestock keeping, it is the loss of draught power, especially during the period of critical crop operations, together with mortality that represent the most important losses (40). Based on a large farm survey in Ethiopia, Swallow estimates draught oxen in high trypanosomosis risk areas to be 3 3 % less efficient than those in low risk areas (79). Shaw estimated trypanosomosis to be responsible for five lost workdays of the annual total of forty draught power workdays in The Gambia for an infected animal, and with an incidence of 20%, this translates to an average two workdays lost for all draught cattle (73) . Lost workdays, in turn, translate into reduced crop production, either through reduced area that can be cultivated, or through lower yields due to late timing of operations (62) . Morbidity over the longer term also leads to lower weight gain, which can affect the efficiency and final resale value of draught animals (66). Nutrient cycling by using manure for crop production is still fairly limited, and milk is generally not important in farm household diets (except for settled pastoralists). Since farmers keep only a f e w heads o f cattle for traction, reproductive efficiency and the impact of this on herd dynamics are less of a concern.

Beyond the direct effects of incidence on productivity, trypanosomosis has dramatic risk impacts. Firstly, the disease is associated with lost potential since it continues to discourage adoption of animal traction in areas where trypanosomosis challenge remains high, especially in the southern portions of the sub-humid zone of West Africa. In Côte d'Ivoire, for example, the proportion of cotton farms with draught animals declines on a north to south gradient (32). Secondly, trypanosomosis risk is a major factor influencing the choice of breed (77) . Farmers prefer to keep smaller, less powerful N'Dama or Baoulé cattle in areas of high risk, to the south, because these indigenous breeds are known to be trypanotolerant. Travelling north, trypanosomosis risk decreases, and farmers rapidly switch to more powerful crossbreeds and the larger Zebu for animal traction (14). Choice of breed, therefore, represents another form of lost potential. Thirdly, the risk and incidence of trypanosomosis require other control measures, either to control the parasite using trypanocides prophylactically or curatively, or to control the vector through the use of pour-on treatments or tsetse traps. Control measures increase the cost to the farmer of maintaining draught animals, and so also contribute to economic losses.

Analysing the impact of diseases and their control Given the situation described above, methods typically used for assessing the impact of disease on production livestock are often not fully appropriate for draught animals. As explained in the accompanying paper in this issue, by Rushton et al. (67), economic analyses of disease and disease control usually consider livestock keeping as a production activity that uses capital (land, equipment) and consumes inputs, to produce outputs (milk, meat, more livestock) for sale or on-farm

consumption. This type of production activity can be represented as an enterprise budget, and thus is amenable to gross margin analysis and CBA techniques as described above for smallholder dairy systems. However, keeping draught animals is not the same type of production activity (58) . The animals are viewed instead as farm equipment or capital. What they produce - draught power - is an intermediate output that serves as an input for crop production activities. Many of the inputs used in maintaining the animals, as well as the output - the draught power produced - are frequently not subject to market transactions, and so should be valued in terms of their contribution to the principal activity: crop production. The value of draught power, as well as that of manure, if used, is therefore determined by the profitability of the crop production activity. Since draught animals are used on a number of different crops on a given farm, the valuation problem becomes even more complicated.

Two approaches are used to address this situation. Firstly, if a market for traction services and manure exists, then the current market price can be used to value the opportunity cost, and the standard analytical techniques then applied. The appropriate market price to apply may not be obvious; Itty, for example, notes that in The Gambia, farmers pay a fee to animal owners to have the animals tethered in the field to deposit manure, rather than pay for the manure itself (32) . Market prices for these types of unconventional products must be reviewed carefully; for example, local prices for traction services may be adjusted to account for reciprocal obligations (e.g. exchange labour, whereby a farmer works on the farm of a neighbour one day, and the neighbour comes to work on his farm the next). In addition, animal traction used on-farm would probably be more valuable since it would be reserved for the most timely use, and hired off-farm at other periods. To date, most analyses of trypanosomosis control for this farming system have resorted to this simplified approach of using some type of proxy market price for traction services and manure lost to disease, preferring to ignore the potential implications for the farm profitability of crop production.

To better capture the role of draught animals as an integrated component of the farming system, an alternative approach is to model the complete system, as described above for LP models in the case of smallholder dairy systems. An appropriately constructed LP model can provide, for example, the value in a draught animal farming system of a day lost of animal traction or a quantity lost of manure due to disease. In the case of animal traction, consideration of multiple time periods (which are easily developed in LP models) becomes useful to estimate how shadow prices of draught power vary over the year as a function of seasonal fluctuations in the opportunity cost of labour (77) . This type of analysis could provide, for example, an economic justification for strategic chemoprophylactic control of trypanosomosis as recommended by Connor (6) .

Page 17: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 415

To capture the dimension of draught animals as farm equipment, consideration of investment analysis techniques in extended, multiple-year time horizons is also useful. Panin, for example, describes a classic CBA for the acquisition of a pair of draught oxen on a farm in northern Ghana (57) . Benefits from animal traction are expressed in terms of increased crop yields over a ten-year period. One advantage of this approach is that it permits capturing costs and returns associated with the final resale of a draught animal, which is likely to be the single largest source of profitability (77) . The analysis by Panin does not incorporate any risk or costs associated with animal morbidity, although it does include the cost of insuring against mortality. It also fails to capture the other non-market costs and benefits associated with animal traction noted above. This shortcoming could be resolved by integrating single-period LP models, and thereby serves as a framework for analysing the longer-term impact of diseases and their control. In the case of trypanosomosis, this type of framework would be useful for quantifying the impact of the disease on reduced weight gain over the service life of draught animals, and the implication for the final resale value. Itty uses a ten-year herd model when conducting social CBA to compare the returns to the use of trypanocides and the introduction of trypanotolerant cattle across six sites in Africa, but due to lack of data on returns to animal traction and manure, does not consider the case of draught cattle (32) .

The quality of the models described above depends on the quality of the data used to construct the model. The data required, or technical coefficients, can often be derived partly from available literature, but as Starkey points out, technical data for animal traction are often from on-station trials, and so will probably require additional data collection on-farm (77) . Preliminary diagnostic surveys using farming systems research (FSR) techniques are useful to distinguish the role played by draught animals in the farm household and their interactions with crop production (74) . Data then need to be collected on all aspects of the economic activities and resource use of the farm, and so require fairly detailed, longitudinal farm household surveys. Also, specific data would need to be generated regarding the relationship between management practices, disease, and the productivity of draught animals. As Thome notes, such information is largely lacking at present, and so limits the accuracy of this type of modelling (84) . Rowlands et al. stress the difficulties involved in quantifying such parameters, even using longitudinal studies (66).

Two other issues related to analysing the impact of trypanosomosis merit mention. The first relates to the choice of breed by the fanner for draught animals. We expect farmers to consider several criteria when deciding which breed to use. The most obvious would relate to the productivity of the animal in its different functions, particularly traction power. Moreover, since a draught animal represents the equivalent of a long-term investment in farm equipment, the farmer would be likely to also give priority to insuring against the loss of his/her capital. In terms of animal health, the farmer in West

Africa may therefore give preference to the smaller trypanotolerant indigenous breeds over the larger trypanosusceptible ones. Several innovative approaches have been used recently to explore these issues. Jabbar et al. report a matrix-rating technique in which farmers in Nigeria scored criteria for different cattle breeds using beans on a game board (33) . The criteria included milk yield, disease resistance, size of animal, ease of handling, market value, marketability, ability to graze diverse species of grasses, need to move long distances for grazing, and overall desirability. The scores for the criteria were then compared to farmer breeding practices using regression analysis. One of the results confirmed that farmers who give preference to disease resistance are indeed more likely to keep trypanotolerant cattle. Tano et al. conducted a similar study in Burkina Faso and found that mixed crop/livestock farmers in that country preferred more powerful Zebu to the smaller trypanotolerant breeds, whereas subsistence farmers preferred the lower risk associated with trypanotolerant breeds (83) .

A similar approach that has been borrowed from the consumer marketing literature is referred to as conjoint analysis. Farmers are asked to rank different combinations of attributes in cattle. By using a carefully planned experimental design, the ranking of the combinations permits the analyst to quantify the relative contribution of each individual attribute in the selection decision. Tano et al. have applied this approach in southern Burkina Faso and found that all livestock keepers give high preference to disease resistance (82). Traits related to beef and milk production were consistently related below other factors such as fitness for traction and disease resistance. Of the different types of livestock keepers, mixed crop/livestock farmers in particular gave the highest preference to fitness for traction.

The second issue relates to vector control options that require collective action, such as tsetse traps and screens. Similar to natural resource management under pastoralist systems (discussed earlier), these strategies require a coordinated effort off the farm, which is increasingly the responsibility of the local community to manage. Unlike other control strategies (chemotherapy, breed choice, pour-on insecticide treatments) that are basically private goods, the use of traps is essentially a public good. The analysis of such strategies therefore requires an assessment of the willingness of individuals to actively contribute to the management of vector control rather than to act as 'free riders'. Pokou et al. (61) describe the use of contingent analysis, based on earlier work by Swallow and Mulatu (80) and Echessah et al. (12) in East Africa, to evaluate the willingness of livestock keepers in northern Côte d'Ivoire to contribute money or labour, or both, to tsetse control using traps. The results indicate that type of production system (sedentary versus transhumance), region, and breed kept, significantly influence the expressed willingness to contribute. Cotton growing, which could be considered a proxy for the use of cattle for traction, is not a significant determinant. Elsewhere, Mullins et al. assessed the willingness of both

Page 18: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

416 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

tourist industries as well as nearby farmers to participate in tsetse control near a natural preserve in Botswana (48). Some of the farmers were willing to provide days of animal traction as a contribution.

As the above examples demonstrate, several aspects of keeping draught animals on mixed crop/livestock farms in West Africa render unsuitable many of the standard approaches for evaluating the economic impact of trypanosomosis and other livestock diseases. To appreciate farmer decision-making in this context, a more comprehensive view of livestock is often necessary; livestock should be seen as an integrated, inseparable component of the whole-farm production system. Researchers will need to continue experimenting with new, innovative approaches to more accurately capture the multiple effects of animal disease and its control.

Current lessons and future trends Animal health strategies: a systems perspective The case studies presented have illustrated the utility of considering strategies for improving animal health and production in a systems context. In the typology framework presented, a number of characteristics useful in distinguishing different livestock production systems were summarised into two main axes. The most important of these is the degree of intensification. Intensified systems evolve in response to good markets and infrastructure. Under these circumstances, livestock activities are naturally more market- and profit-oriented and the focus is in optimising productivity on the individual farm. In this context, disease is simply one of many variables to manage. Usually, fanners have access to, and can choose from, a number of animal health and production options, thus management skills are required to choose between the options. The focus on animal health economics is to support decision-making at the farm level. Recalling that endemic and production, rather than epidemic, diseases are most important in intensive systems, the animal health goods and services and their delivery are almost exclusively private goods.

This is in sharp contrast to more extensive systems, where epidemic diseases are of greater importance and farmers rely on communal natural resources. Infrastructure and markets are undeveloped and animal health and production strategies are adaptive rather than managerial. Although animal health risks are higher in most extensive systems, the ability to manage risk at the farmer level is much more limited. The focus on animal health economics in these systems shifts to natural resource management and disease control at the community level and greater emphasis is placed on the public good aspects of animal health goods and services and their delivery.

The second axis, dependence of the household economy on livestock, is less useful in characterising differences in approaches to animal health and production management across systems. The only key distinction relates to the greater specialisation in livestock management and the greater awareness and demand for animal health and production information. This awareness and demand can be used to advantage in animal health programmes at community level in pastoralist systems.

Main future trends Intensification will remain the key future determinant of livestock development within smallholder systems in the developing world. Livestock development will follow two main paths, one for market-oriented systems and the other for subsistence-oriented systems.

On average, the demand for livestock products in the developing world is predicted to outpace population growth. Already, in smallholder farming areas with good market access, farmers have responded in innovative ways to increase livestock production and cash income. The smallholder dairy system in the highlands of Kenya is one example. The authors expect this trend to accelerate in areas with good market access, since many of the necessary components, such as more efficient input and output markets and private-sector service provision are present or developing. Poor provision of necessary public service may be a weakness in some countries. The scale of livestock enterprises in intensifying systems will vary, based on a number of factors. The authors expect smallholder systems to dominate in areas where labour inputs are relatively cheaper than capital, and larger-scale systems where capital is less expensive. Smallholdings are expected to maintain a more diversified portfolio of farm activities while large holdings will be increasingly specialised. For intensifying smallholder systems, livestock or livestock products will provide both non-marketed intermediate outputs and marketed final products. In some systems, such as the draught/cotton system described for West Africa, traction is the main livestock output, and livestock will remain the principal source of draught for smallholders. In highly integrated crop/livestock systems, intermediate livestock outputs will be less obvious but crucial, for example, the importance of manure in the market-oriented smallholder dairy system ( 2 8 % of the estimated value of livestock products).

For less market-oriented systems, different trends and economic influences will be important. In these systems, usually found in more marginal and arid areas, farmers and herders rely almost entirely on natural resources (pastures and shrubs) for survival. Adaptations to improve the management of these natural resources will be the key future challenge, a particularly difficult challenge in pastoral areas where the grazing range of herders is increasingly constrained by sedentary farmers. The role of community action in this process will be crucial, as will policy and other public inputs.

Page 19: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2| 417

Targeted policies for poverty alleviation will be an important social issue, and improvements in natural resource management in subsistence areas will be an important strategy for poverty alleviation (30) .

Priority issues and approaches In the intensifying market-oriented smallholder systems, priority issues in animal health and production will be improved farm-level decision-making, both for farm and financial management. The management of financial risk will become a key skill for market-oriented smallholders. The emphasis in animal health will shift from infectious diseases to production diseases.

Many of the economic decision-making approaches required will be adaptations of available methods. Farm management decision-making techniques and financial management techniques used on dairy and swine farms in developed countries will be applicable with some minor adaptation (11) . A new researchable aspect will be to understand more fully the joint production and economic effects of the complex of inputs and outputs of highly integrated crop/livestock smallholdings. Simulation models and other systems analysis techniques will be useful at a research level. Decision-support tools based on LP (34) , portfolio theory (16) and other decision-analysis techniques would be helpful in the hands of advisors to smallholder farmers.

In these intensified and commercialised smallholder settings, farmers will need to make many more decisions and will be under greater financial risk. An example of these new kinds of decision-making pressures is in the control of tick-borne diseases. In the past, smallholders in Kenya were mandated to dip cows at communal, government-subsidised plunge dips every week. Now farmers are responsible for all decision-making regarding tick-borne disease control, but with a greater number of control options. Farmers need to choose from a combination of acaricide products and modes of application, an infection and treatment vaccination method, drugs, and grazing management strategies. Choosing the optimal combination of these methods and deciding on the supplier and method of supply is a complicated task, requiring a good understanding of the actual disease risk in addition to the level of risk the farmer is willing to accept. This is not a trivial decision for farmers whose one or two cows may be worth approximately US$1 ,000 each.

While animal health and production decision-making in intensifying systems can largely rely on adapting available techniques, in subsistence settings, new methods and strategies will be required. Clearly, tools for natural resource

management decision-making under constraints are required that consider social, environmental and economic components. These techniques need to incorporate community as well as individual decision-making. Policy decisions - such as assessments of poverty, causes of poverty and targeted solutions - will be crucial. On account of high transaction costs and the relatively greater importance of public, relative to private, provision of services in the subsistence system, ex ante assessments should be undertaken regarding the potential adoption and impacts of animal health and production services (39) . To improve the effectiveness, feasibility and sustainability of delivery systems, competing delivery pathways need to be assessed using techniques such as the New Institutional Economics (43) and structure-conduct-performance (69) .

Conclusion Smallholder crop/livestock and livestock systems are crucial with respect to contributions to human welfare on a global basis. Large numbers of poor people currently depend, and will continue to depend on these systems for survival. Substantial changes and accelerating intensification of smallholder systems with good market access are being observed, and accompanying this trend, great opportunities for increasing incomes and welfare. For non-market-oriented systems, the challenge will be to ensure sustainability and adaptation in the face of increasing pressures that compromise traditional community and producer resource management strategies. Animal health economics can play an important role in both these situations, to support better farm level decision-making in more intensive systems and to improve understanding of the community and natural resource issues required for more effective animal health and production strategies in more extensive systems.

Acknowledgement This paper is referenced by the ILRI as ILRI Publication No. 99100 .

Page 20: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

418 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

Aspects économiques de l'optimisation de l'état sanitaire et de la productivité des systèmes d'élevage à petite échelle dans les pays en développement

J . J . McDermott, T.F. Randolph & S . J . Staal

Résumé L e s a n i m a u x qui s o n t g a r d é s o u s e m u l t i p l i e n t d a n s d e s s y s t è m e s d ' é l e v a g e à p e t i t e é c h e l l e c o n s t i t u e n t u n e p a r t i m p o r t a n t e de l ' é c o n o m i e a g r i c o l e d e s p a y s e n d é v e l o p p e m e n t . L e u r r ô l e v a r i e c o n s i d é r a b l e m e n t s e l o n l e s c a s : s o i t ils s e r v e n t d ' a n i m a u x de t r a i t p o u r l ' a g r i c u l t u r e , s o i t ils s o n t d e s t i n é s à la c o n s o m m a t i o n d o m e s t i q u e o u à la v e n t e d a n s le c a d r e d e s y s t è m e s a l l a n t d u p a s t o r a l i s m e à d e s é l e v a g e s l a i t i e r s et d ' e n g r a i s s e m e n t i n t e n s i f s s i t u é s e n p é r i p h é r i e d e s v i l l e s . L e s p e t i t e s e x p l o i t a t i o n s s e d i s t i n g u e n t p a r d e s c o n d i t i o n s e t c a r a c t é r i s t i q u e s q u i l e u r s o n t p r o p r e s , c e d o n t il f a u t t e n i r c o m p t e l o r s d e l ' é v a l u a t i o n d e la g e s t i o n d e la s a n t é a n i m a l e d a n s c e t y p e d ' é l e v a g e s a i n s i q u e l o r s d e l ' é v a l u a t i o n d e s m o y e n s qui p e u v e n t p e r m e t t r e à c e s é l e v a g e s d ' a m é l i o r e r l e u r s s t r a t é g i e s d e p r o p h y l a x i e . P o u r f o u r n i r u n c a d r e d e d i s c u s s i o n s u r l e s q u e s t i o n s d e s a n t é a n i m a l e e t l e s m é t h o d e s a n a l y t i q u e s , les a u t e u r s o n t é l a b o r é u n e t y p o l o g i e d e s p e t i t s s y s t è m e s d ' é l e v a g e e t de c u l t u r e / é l e v a g e . Ils c l a s s e n t a i n s i les d i f f é r e n t s s y s t è m e s s e l o n l e u r d e g r é d ' i n t e n s i f i c a t i o n , m e s u r é p a r l e u r a c c è s a u x m a r c h é s et p a r l' intensité d'ut i l isat ion d e s f a c t e u r s d e p r o d u c t i o n , m a i s a u s s i s e l o n l e u r i m p o r t a n c e a u s e i n d e l ' é c o n o m i e f a m i l i a l e , é v a l u é e d ' a p r è s l e u r c o n t r i b u t i o n a u r e v e n u d u f o y e r . L e s a u t e u r s d é f i n i s s e n t u n c e r t a i n n o m b r e d e c a r a c t é r i s t i q u e s q u i d i s t i n g u e n t c e s s y s t è m e s d e p e t i t e s e x p l o i t a t i o n s de c e l u i d e s é l e v a g e s i n d u s t r i e l s p r o p r e s a u x p a y s d é v e l o p p é s . C e t t e c l a s s i f i c a t i o n p r e n d n o t a m m e n t e n c o m p t e la p o l y v a l e n c e d e s a n i m a u x , l ' i n t é g r a t i o n d e s a c t i v i t é s d ' é l e v a g e , les o b j e c t i f s m u l t i p l e s d e s é l e v e u r s e t la c a p a c i t é r é d u i t e d u f o y e r à s u p p o r t e r les r i s q u e s , s a n s o u b l i e r la f a i b l e s s e d e s i n f r a s t r u c t u r e s , d e s m a r c h é s et d e l ' a c c è s à l ' i n f o r m a t i o n a u p l a n l o c a l .

L e s a u t e u r s d é c r i v e n t e n s u i t e e n d é t a i l t r o i s pet i ts s y s t è m e s d ' é l e v a g e a f r i c a i n s r e p r é s e n t a t i f s , f a i s a n t r e s s o r t i r l e s p r i n c i p a l e s c a r a c t é r i s t i q u e s e t l e s c o n s é q u e n c e s p o u r l ' a n a l y s e d e s s t r a t é g i e s d e p r o p h y l a x i e . L e s p e t i t s é l e v a g e s l a i t i e r s d u K e n y a i l l u s t r e n t l ' i m p o r t a n c e d u r ô l e d e l ' é l e v e u r d a n s la p r i s e d e d é c i s i o n e n m a t i è r e d e g e s t i o n d e la s a n t é a n i m a l e . C e t y p e d e s y s t è m e s i n t e n s i f s f a v o r i s e l e s m é c a n i s m e s d u m a r c h é et l'attention y e s t c o n c e n t r é e s u r l e s r i s q u e s a u n i v e a u d e l ' é l e v a g e e t s u r l e s a s p e c t s d e la p r o p h y l a x i e qui p e u v e n t ê t r e c o n t r ô l é s p a r la g e s t i o n d e la p r o d u c t i o n . D a n s les s y s t è m e s p a s t o r a u x , qui s o n t e n c o r e v i c t i m e s d ' é p i z o o t i e s m a j e u r e s e t o ù l ' i n f r a s t r u c t u r e e s t f a i b l e , la p r o p h y l a x i e r e p o s e p r i n c i p a l e m e n t s u r la g e s t i o n a u p l a n l o c a l d e s r e s s o u r c e s n a t u r e l l e s , c e qui i m p l i q u e u n e a p p r o c h e a n a l y t i q u e d i f f é r e n t e . E n f i n , d a n s l e s s y s t è m e s c é r é a l i e r s , o ù l e s a n i m a u x s o n t u t i l i s é s a u x t r a v a u x d e s c h a m p s , l ' é l e v a g e f a i t p a r t i e i n t é g r a n t e d u s y s t è m e d e p r o d u c t i o n a g r i c o l e , c e d o n t doi t t e n i r c o m p t e la m é t h o d e de g e s t i o n de la s a n t é d e c e s a n i m a u x d e t ra i t . Il c o n v i e n t d ' é l a b o r e r d e m a n i è r e s o u t e n u e d e s m é t h o d e s a n a l y t i q u e s et d e s o u t i l s d'aide à la d é c i s i o n a p p l i q u é s a u x s t r a t é g i e s d e p r o p h y l a x i e les m i e u x a d a p t é e s a u x c a r a c t é r i s t i q u e s p a r t i c u l i è r e s d e c e s s y s t è m e s , c a r c e u x - c i n e c e s s e n t d e s e d é v e l o p p e r d a n s l e s r é g i o n s b é n é f i c i a n t d e b o n s d é b o u c h é s ; d a n s l e s z o n e s m o i n s b i e n d e s s e r v i e s , c e s s y s t è m e s d o i v e n t s ' e f f o r c e r d ' o p t i m i s e r r a p i d e m e n t la g e s t i o n de l e u r s r e s s o u r c e s n a t u r e l l e s .

Mots-clés Afrique - Économie - Kenya - Pays en développement - Petits exploitants - Productivité -Santé animale.

Page 21: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2] 419

Optimización económica de la sanidad y la productividad en minifundios ganaderos de países en desarrollo

J . J . McDermott, T.F. Randolph & S . J . Staal

Resumen El ganado mantenido o cr iado en sistemas minifundistas es una pieza fundamental de la economía agraria de los países en desarrol lo. En esas pequeñas explotaciones el ganado cubre n e c e s i d a d e s muy var iables, desde la provisión de animales de tiro para la labranza o la p r o d u c c i ó n de subsistencia hasta su v e n t a en el m e r c a d o , con sistemas product ivos que v a n del pastoreo extensivo a las granjas periurbanas intensivas de engorde o p r o d u c c i ó n lechera. Los s istemas minifundistas se c a r a c t e r i z a n por una ser ie de r a s g o s y c o n d i c i o n e s singulares, que conv iene t e n e r en cuenta a la hora de estudiar las t é c n i c a s de gestión zoosanitaria que han ido progres ivamente implementando o de va lorar el m a r g e n existente para mejorar sus métodos de control sanitario. A fin de disponer de un sistema de referencia para abordar cuest iones de sanidad animal y elaborar métodos para su análisis, los autores c o n s t r u y e n una tipología de los sistemas minifundistas pecuar ios y a g r o p e c u a r i o s . Esa tipología clasifica las explotaciones g a n a d e r a s en f u n c i ó n de su nivel de intensif icación (indicado por la v o c a c i ó n comerc ia l y la intensidad del uso de los f a c t o r e s de producción) y de su importancia dentro de la e c o n o m í a domést ica (que se mide por la contr ibución a la renta familiar). Los autores apuntan un conjunto de caracter íst icas que distinguen al sistema minifundista de los s istemas industriales propios de los países desarrol lados: la atribución de f u n c i o n e s diversas al ganado, el c a r á c t e r integral de las activ idades pecuar ias, los objetivos múltiples de los g a n a d e r o s y la m e n o r capacidad de la unidad familiar para asumir r iesgos, junto a la e s c a s e z de inf raestructuras, m e r c a d o s e información a escala de la comunidad. D e s p u é s descr iben en detalle t res ejemplos representat ivos de los minifundios g a n a d e r o s afr icanos, d e s t a c a n d o los r a s g o s que les s o n propios y la m a n e r a e n que inciden en el análisis de sus estrategias de control sanitario. Los sistemas minifundistas de p r o d u c c i ó n lechera de Kenia dejan patente la influencia que t ienen las decis iones de cada ganadero sobre la gestión zoosanitaria de este tipo de sistemas intensivos con a c c e s o a m e r c a d o , decisiones que se c o n c e n t r a n en los r iesgos en la propia explotación y a determinados aspectos de control sanitario ligados a la gestión de la producción. En sistemas pastorales extensivos, con elevada incidencia de epidemias y notable e s c a s e z de inf raestructuras, el control sanitario está ligado básicamente a la gestión de r e c u r s o s naturales de propiedad comunitar ia, aspecto éste que impone un t ratamiento analítico distinto. En sistemas agrícolas donde se utilizan animales de tiro, por último, la actividad del ganado es un elemento más de los que integran la p r o d u c c i ó n agrar ia, h e c h o que debe i n c o r p o r a r s e al método utilizado para evaluar la gestión sanitaria de esos animales. En un momento en que los sistemas minifundistas de zonas con buena salida comerc ia l intensifican sus activ idades, y los de zonas más aisladas suf ren c r e c i e n t e s presiones para optimizar su gestión de los r e c u r s o s naturales, se hace n e c e s a r i a la c r e a c i ó n permanente de t é c n i c a s analíticas y herramientas de ayuda a la decisión en materia de control sanitario adaptadas a las especiales caracter ís t icas de tales s istemas product ivos.

Palabras clave Á f r i c a - Economía - Kenia - M i n i f u n d i o s - Países en desarrol lo - Productividad - Sanidad animal.

Page 22: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

420 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

References

1. Bakenweck I., Staal S.J., Owango M., Muriuki H., Lukuyu B., Gichungu G., Kenyanjui M., Njubi D., Tanner J . & Thorpe W. (1998). - Dairy systems characterisation of the greater Nairobi milk-shed: application of spatial and household analysis. Workshop on urban markets and dairy development in sub-Saharan Africa, 9-10 September, Montpellier. Centre de coopération internationale en recherche agronomique pour le développement (CIRAD)-Élevage et médecine vétérinaire (EMVT), Montpellier, 20 pp.

2. Bangura A.B. (1990). - Constraint to the extension of draft animal technology in the farming systems of Sierra Leone. In Animal traction for agricultural development (P.H. Starkey & A. Faye, eds). Proc. 3rd Workshop of the West Africa Animal Traction Network, 7-12 July 1988, Saly, Senegal. Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA), Wageningen, 324-331.

3. Bekure S., de Leeuw P.N., Grandin B.E. & Neate P.J. (eds). (1991). - Maasai herding: an analysis of the livestock production system of Maasai pastoralists in Eastern Kajiado District, Kenya. International Livestock Centre for Africa (ILCA). Systems Study 4. ILCA, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 155 pp.

4. Boisvert R.N. & McCarl B. (1990). - Agricultural risk modeling using mathematical programming. Southern Cooperative. Series, Bulletin No. 356. Department of Agricultural Economics, Cornell University, Ithaca, 103 pp.

5. Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) (1999). - CIA world factbook, 1998 (internet edition). Website: http://www.odci.gov/cia/publications/pubs.html (document accessed on 21 May 1999).

6. Connor R.J. (1994). - Improving draft animal management with strategic chemoprophylactic control of trypanosomiasis. In Improving animal traction technology (P.H. Starkey, E. Mwenya & J . Stares, eds). Proc. 1st Workshop of the Animal Traction Network for Eastern and Southern Africa (ATNESA), 18-23 January 1992, Lusaka, Zambia. Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA), Wageningen, 155-157.

7. De Haan C. (1996). - Livestock and the environment. Some basic issues. In Livestock production and diseases in the tropics: livestock production and human welfare. Proc. 8th International Conference of Institutions of Tropical Veterinary Medicine (K.H. Zessin, ed.), 25-29 September 1995, Berlin. German Foundation for International Development, Feldafing, 773 pp.

8. De Haan C. & Bekure S. (1991). - Animal health services in sub-Saharan Africa: initial experience with new approaches. World Bank Technical Report No. 134. World Bank, Washington, 48 pp.

9. De Jong R. (1996). - Dairy stock development and milk production with smallholders. PhD thesis, Wageningen Agricultural University, the Netherlands, 308 pp.

10. De Leeuw P.N., McDermott J.J. & Lebbie S.H.B. (1995). -Monitoring of livestock health and production in Africa. Prev. vet. Med., 25, 195-212.

11. Dijkhuizen A.A. & Morris R.S. (eds) (1997). - Animal health economics: principles and applications. Post Graduate Foundation in Veterinary Science, University of Sydney, 306 pp.

12. Echessah N.P., Swallow B.M., Kamara D.W. & Curry J.J. (1997). - Willingness to contribute labor and money to tsetse control: application of contingent valuation in Busia District, Kenya. World Dev., 25, 239-253.

13. Felton M.R. & Ellis P.R. (1978). - Studies on the control of rinderpest in Nigeria. Study No. 23. University of Reading, Department of Agriculture and Horticulture, Reading, 40 pp.

14. Ferguson W. (1988). - Factors influencing the production potential of trypanotolerant livestock. In Livestock production in tsetse affected areas of Africa. Proceedings of the African Trypanotolerant Livestock Network Meeting, 23-27 November 1987, Nairobi, Kenya. International Livestock Centre for Africa/International Laboratory for Research on Animal Diseases, Nairobi, 187-209.

15. Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) (1990). -Cost/benefit analysis for animal health programmes in developing countries. Report of an FAO expert consultation, 10-14 September. FAO, Rome, 51 pp.

16. Galligan D.T. & Marsh W.E. (1997). - Application of portfolio theory for the optimal choice of on-farm veterinary management programs. In Animal health economics: principles and applications (A.A. Dijkhuizen & R.S. Morris, eds). Post Graduate Foundation in Veterinary Science, University of Sydney, 149-159.

17. Gidel R., Albert J.P., LeMao G. & Ratif M. (1976). -Epidémiologie de la brucellose humaine et animale en Afrique de l'Ouest. Résultats de dix enquêtes effectuées en Côte d'Ivoire, Haute-Volta et Niger. In International Symposium on Brucellosis, II, Rabat. Dev. biol. Standard., 31, 187.

18. Gitau G.K., McDermott J.J., Adams J.E., Lissemore K.D. & Waltner-Toews D. (1994). - Factors influencing calf growth and daily weight gain on smallhorder dairy farms in Kiambu District of Kenya. Prev. vet. Med., 21, 179-190.

19. Gitau G.K., McDermott J.J., Waltner-Toews D. & Lissemore K.D. (1994). - Factors influencing calf morbidity and mortality in smallholder dairy farms in Kiambu District. Prev. vet. Med., 21 , 167-178.

Page 23: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2) 421

20. Gitau G.K., Perry B.D. & McDermott J.J. (1999). - A longitudinal observational study to estimate the incidence, calf morbidity and mortality due to Theileria parva infections in smallholder dairy farms in Murang'a District, Kenya. Prev. vet. Med., 39, 65-79.

21. Gitau T., McDermott J.J. & Mbuiki S.M. (1996). - Incidence, type and risk factors for lameness in dairy cattle on small-scale dairy farms in Kikuyu division, Kenya. Prev. vet. Med., 28, 101-116.

22. Gitau T., Mbuiki S.M. & McDermott J.J. (1997). -Assessment of bovine hoof conformation and its association with lameness, animal factors and management practices on small-scale dairy farms in Kiambu district, Kenya. Onderstepoort J. vet. Res., 64, 135-140.

23. Gittinger J.P. (1982). - Economic analysis of agricultural projects. EDI (Economic Development Institute of the World Bank) series in economic development. Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 505 pp.

24. Goe M.R. (1990). - Overcoming constraints to animal traction through a collaborative research network. In Animal traction for agricultural development (P.H. Starkey & A. Faye, eds). Proc. 3rd Workshop of the West Africa Animal Traction Network, 7-12 July 1988, Saly, Senegal. Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA), Wageningen, 136-143.

25. Grandin B.E. & Young J . (1996). - Collection and use of ethnoveterinary data in community-based animal health programmes. In Ethnoveterinary research and development (C.M. McCorkle, E. Mathias & T.W. Schillhorn van Veen, eds). Intermediate Technology Publications, London, 207-228.

26. Griffith K. & Zepeda L. (1994). - Farm level trade-offs of intensifying tropical milk production. Ecol. Econ., 9, 121-133.

27. Halpin B. (1981). - Vets: barefoot and otherwise. Pastoral Network Paper 11c. Overseas Development Institute, London, 7 pp.

28. Hazell P.B.R. & Norton R.D. (1986). - Mathematical programming for economic analysis in agriculture. Macmillan, New York, 400 pp.

29. Heffernan C., Heffeman E. & Stem C. (1996). - Aspects of healthcare among Samburu pastoralists. In Ethnoveterinary research and development (C.M. McCorkle, E. Mathias & T.W. Schillhorn van Veen, eds). Intermediate Technology Publications, London, 193-206.

30. Holden S., Bazely P. & Ashley S. (1998). - Strategies for improving DFlD's impact on poverty reduction: a review of best practices in the livestock sector. Livestock in Development, Crewkerne, Somerset, 17 pp.

31. Intermediate Technology Development Group (1TDG) (1996). - Dynamic diversity: farmers, herders and fisherfolk safeguarding biodiversity. Livestock keepers safeguarding domestic animal diversity through their animal husbandry. 1TDG, Rugby, 17 pp.

32. Itty P. (1992). - Economics of village cattle production in tsetse affected areas of Africa: a study of trypanosomiasis control using trypanotolerant cattle and chemotherapy in Ethiopia, Kenya, Côte d'Ivoire, The Gambia, Zaire and Togo. PhD thesis. Hartung-Gorre Verlag, Konstanz, 316 pp.

33. Jabbar M.A., Swallow B.M., d'Ieteren G.D.M. & Busari A.A. (1998). - Farmer preferences and market values of cattle breeds of West and Central Africa. J. sustainable Agric., 12, 21-47.

34. Jalvingh A.W., Dijkhuizen A.A. & Renkema J.A. (1997). -Linear programming to meet management targets and restrictions. In Animal health economics: principles and applications (A.A. Dijkhuizen & R.S. Morris, eds). Post Graduate Foundation in Veterinary Science, University of Sydney, 69-84.

35. James A.D. (1997). - How do we integrate economics into the policy development and implementation process? In Animal health economics: principles and applications (A.A. Dijkhuizen & R.S. Morris, eds). Post Graduate Foundation in Veterinary Science, University of Sydney, 219-231.

36. Jamin J.Y., Keita M. & Sow M. (1990). - Mécanisation en culture attelée dans l'intensification de la riziculture irriguée : le projet retail de l'Office du Niger. Cah. Rech. Dév., 28,53-64 .

37. Kadohira M., McDermott J.J., Shoukri M.M. & Kyule M.N. (1997). - Variations in the prevalence of antibody to brucella infection in cattle by farm, area and district in Kenya. Epidemiol. Infect., 118, 35-41.

38. Kaguongo W.N.W., Staal S. & Ackello-Ogutu C. (1997). -Risk with intensification of Kenyan smallholder dairying. Kenya Agricultural Research Institute/Ministry of Agriculture (Kenya)/International Livestock Research Institute (ILRI) Smallholder Dairy Project Working Paper. ILRI, Nairobi, 17 pp.

39. Kristjanson P.M., Swallow B.M., Rowlands G.J., Kruska R.L. & de Leeuw P.N. (1999). - Measuring the costs of African animal trypanosomosis, the potential benefits of control and returns to research. Agric. Syst., 59, 79-98.

40. Lawson L.T. (1990). - Les contraintes de la culture attelée observées par la Société Togolaise de Coton. In Animal traction for agricultural development (P.H. Starkey & A. Faye, eds). Proc. 3rd Workshop of the West Africa Animal Traction Network, 7-12 July 1988, Saly, Senegal. Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA), Wageningen, 348-349.

41 Lekasi J . & Tanner J . (1998). - Manure management in Kiambu and Muranga districts. Research report. Market-oriented smallholder dairy research unit. ILRI, Nairobi, Kenya, 33 pp.

42. Leonard D.K. (1993). - Structural reforms of the veterinary profession in Africa and the new institutional economics. Dev. Change, 24, 227-267.

Page 24: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

422 Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2)

43. Leonard D.K., Koma L.M.P.K., Ly C. & Woods P.S.A. (1999). - The new institutional economics of privatising veterinary services in Africa. In The economics of animal disease control (B.D. Perry, ed.). Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2), 544-561.

44. McCorkle C.M., Mathias E. & Schillhom van Veen T.W. (eds) (1996). - Ethnoveterinary research and development. Intermediate Technology Publications, London, 338 pp.

45. Mclnemey J.P., Howe K.S. & Schepers J.A. (1992). - A framework for the economic analysis of disease in farm livestock. Prev. vet. Med., 13, 137-154.

46. Majok A.A. (1999). - The challenges of pastoralism in the delivery of veterinary services in sub-Saharan Africa. In Proc. 9th International Conference of Association of Institutions of Tropical Veterinary Medicine (AITVM), 14-18 September 1998, Harare.

47. Mekhagnomdara S. (1996). - Report of the Second Meeting of the OIE Sub-Commission for foot and mouth disease in South-East Asia, 27 February-1 March, Vientiane, Laos. Office International des Epizooties, Representation for Asia and the Pacific, Tokyo, 3.

48. Mullins G., Nkhori P., Allsopp R., Kolanyane M. & Phillemon-Motsu T. (1997). - The economics of trypanosomiasis control in the Okavango Delta region of Botswana and the scope for public-private sector partnerships. In Proc. 8th International Symposium on Veterinary Epidemiology and Economics, 8-11 July, Paris. Epidémiol. Santé anim., 31-32, 02.20.1-3.

49. Muraguri G.R., Mbogo S.K., McHardy N. & Kariuki D.P. (1998). - Cost analysis of immunisation against East Coast fever on smallholder dairy farms in Kenya. Prev. vet. Med., 34, 307-316.

50. Muriuki S.M.K., Arimi S.M. & McDermott J.J. (1994). -Brucellosis as a cause of human illness in Narok District, Kenya. In Proc. 7th International Symposium on Veterinary Epidemiology and Economics, 15-19 August, Nairobi (G.J. Rowlands, M.N. Kyule & B.D. Perry, eds). Kenya Vet, 18, 537-539.

51. Murray C.J.L. & Lopez A.D. (1996). - Global burden of disease. Harvard University Press, Boston, 900 pp.

52. Nyangito H.O., Richardson J.W., Mukhebi A.W., Zimmel P., Namken J. & Perry B.D. (1996). - Whole farm simulation analysis of economic impacts of East Coast fever immunization strategies on mixed crop-livestock farms in Kenya. Agric. Syst., 51, 1-27.

53. O'Callaghan C.J. (1998). - A study of the epidemiology of theileriosis on smallholder dairy farms in Kiambu District, Kenya. PhD thesis. University of Guelph, 406 pp.

54. Odima P.A., McDermott J.J. & Mutiga E.R. (1994). -Reproductive performance of dairy cows on smallholder dairy farms in Kiambu District, Kenya: design, methodology and development considerations. In Proc. 7th International Symposium on Veterinary Epidemiology and Economics, 15-19 August, Nairobi (G.J.Rowlands, M.N. Kyule & B.D. Perry, eds). Kenya Vet, 18, 366-368.

55. Omore A.O., McDermott J.J., Arimi S.M. & Ouma D. (1996). - A longitudinal study of milk somatic cell counts and bacterial culture from cows on smallholder dairy farms in Kiambu District, Kenya. Prev. vet Med., 29, 77-89.

56. Owango M., Staal S., Kenyanjui M., Lukuyu B., Njubi D. & Thorpe W. (1998). - Dairy co-operatives and policy reform in Kenya: effects of livestock service and milk market liberalisation. Food Policy, 23, 173-185.

57. Panin A. (1990). - Profitability assessment of animal traction investment: the case of northeastern Ghana. In Animal traction for agricultural development (P.H. Starkey & A. Faye, eds). Proc. 3rd Workshop of the West Africa Animal Traction Network, 7-12 July 1988, Saly, Senegal. Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA), Wageningen, 201-209.

58. Panin A. & Ellis-Jones J . (1994). - Increasing the profitability of draft animal power. In Improving animal traction technology (P.H. Starkey, E. Mwenya & J . Stares, eds). Proc. 1st workshop of the Animal Traction Network for Eastern and Southern Africa (ATNESA), 18-23 January 1992, Lusaka, Zambia. Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA), Wageningen, 94-103.

59. Perry B.D. & Young A.S. (1995). - The past and future roles of epidemiology and economics in the control of tick-borne diseases of livestock in Africa: the case of theileriosis. Prev. vet Med., 25, 107-120.

60. Perry B.D., Kalpravidh W., Coleman P.G., Horst H.S., McDermott J.J., Randolph T.F. & Gleeson L.J. (1999). - The economic impact of foot and mouth disease and its control in South-East Asia: a preliminary assessment with special reference to Thailand. In The economics of animal disease control (B.D. Perry, ed.). Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2), 478-497.

61. Pokou K., Kamuanga M., Swallow B. & N'go A.G.M. (1999). - Application de l'analyse contingente à l'étude de la contribution des éleveurs à la lutte contre la trypanosomose animale en Afrique de l'Ouest. International Livestock Research Institute/Centre international de Recherche-Développement sur l'Élevage en zone subhumide (CIRDES) Working Paper. CIRDES, Bobo-Dioulasso, 34 pp.

62. Powell J.M., Pearson R.A. & Hopkins J.C. (1998). - Impact of livestock on crop production. In Food, lands and livelihoods: setting research agendas for animal science (M. Gill, T. Smith, G.E. Pollott, E. Owen & T.L.J. Lawrence, eds). Occ. Publ. Br. Soc. Anim. Sci., 21, 53-66.

63. Putt S.N.H., Shaw A.P.M., Woods A.J., Tyler L. & James A.D. (1987). - Veterinary epidemiology and economics in Africa: a manual for use in the design and appraisal of livestock health policy. International Livestock Centre for Africa, Addis Ababa and University of Reading, 130 pp.

64. Ray A. (1984). - Cost-benefit analysis: issues and methodologies. World Bank, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, 188 pp.

Page 25: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2| 423

65. Reddy S.K. (1988). - Use of animal power in West African farming systems: farm level problem and implications for research: perspectives from Mali. In Animal power in farming systems (P.H. Starkey & F. Ndiamé, eds). Proc. Workshop, 19-26 September 1986, Freetown, Sierra Leone. German Appropriate Technology Exchange, Deutsche Gesellschaft für Technische Zusammenarbeit, Eschborn, Germany, 182-190.

66. Rowlands G.J., d'Ieteren G.D.M., Coulibaly L., Hecker P.A., Leak S.G.A. & Nagda S.M. (1996). - Assessment of the effect of tsetse control on livestock productivity - a case study in northern Côte d'Ivoire. Prev. vet. Med., 28, 17-32.

67. Rushton J . , Thornton P.K. & Otte M.J. (1999). - Methods of economic impact assessment. In The economics of animal disease control (B.D. Perry, ed.). Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2), 315-342.

68. Sandford S. (1983). - Management of pastoral development in the third world. John Wiley and Sons, Chichester, 363 pp.

69. Sandiford F. & Rossmiller E. (1997). - Studying policy delivery systems. In Political economy of the common market in milk and dairy products in the European Union (R.E. Williams). Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) Economic and Social Development Paper No. 142, Annex I. FAO, Rome, 139-171.

70. Schuetterle A. & Coulibaly M. (1988). - The socio-economic aspects of livestock production in villages in northern Côte d'Ivoire. In Livestock production in tsetse affected areas of Africa. Proceedings of the African Trypanotolerant Livestock Network Meeting, 23-27 November 1987, Nairobi. International Livestock Centre for Africa/International Laboratory for Research on Animal Diseases, Nairobi, 389-398.

71. Schwabe C.W. (1984). - Veterinary medicine and human health, 3rd Ed. Williams and Wilkins, Baltimore, 680 pp.

72. Schwabe C.W. & Kuojok I.M. (1981). - Practices and beliefs of the traditional Dinka healer in relation to provision of modern medical and veterinary services for the southern Sudan. Hum. Organ., 40, 231-238.

73. Shaw A.P.M. (1992). - Development of a methodology for assessing the losses due to trypanosomiasis in cattle in Africa. Report to the socioeconomics programme. International Laboratory for Research on Animal Diseases, Nairobi, 29 pp.

74. Simpson J.R. (1988). - The economics of livestock systems in developing countries. Westview Press, Boulder, Colorado, 297 pp.

75. Smallholder Dairy Project (SDP) (1999). - Data from the Kenya Agricultural Research Institute/Ministry of Agriculture (Kenya)/International Livestock Research Institute, Nairobi.

76. Staal S., Chege L., Kenyanjui M., Kimari A., Lukuyu B., Njubi D., Owango M., Tanner J . , Thorpe W. & Wambugu M. (1997). - Characterisation of dairy systems supplying the Nairobi milk market: a pilot survey in Kiambu

district for the identification of target groups of producers. Kenya Agricultural Research Institute/Ministry of Agriculture (Kenya)/International Livestock Research Institute (ILRI) Collaborative Research Project Report. ILRI, Nairobi, 88 pp.

77. Starkey P.H. (1990). - Animal traction for agricultural development in West Africa: production, impact, profitability and constraints. In Animal traction for agricultural development (P.H. Starkey & A. Faye, eds). Third Workshop of the West Africa Animal Traction Network, 7-12 July 1988, Saly, Senegal. Technical Centre for Agricultural and Rural Cooperation (CTA), Wageningen, 90-114.

78. Stem C. (1996). - Ethnoveterinary R&D in production systems. In Ethnoveterinary research and development (CM. McCorkle, E. Mathias & T.W. Schillhorn van Veen, eds). Intermediate Technology Publications, London, 193-206.

79. Swallow B.M. (1997). - Impacts of trypanosomosis on African agriculture. In Proc. 24th International Scientific Council for Trypanosomiasis Research and Control Meeting, 29 September-4 October, Maputo. Organisation of African Unity, Scientific, Technical and Research Commission, Nairobi, 515-536.

80. Swallow B.M. & Mulatu W. (1994). - Evaluating willingness to contribute to a local public good: application of contingent valuation to tsetse control in Ethiopia. Ecol. Econ., 11, 153-161.

81. Tambi E.N., Maina O.W., Mukhebi A.W. & Randolph T.F. (1999). - Economic impact assessment of rinderpest control in Africa. In The economics of animal disease control (B.D. Perry, ed.). Rev. sci. tech. Off. int. Epiz., 18 (2), 458-477.

82. Tano K., Faminow M.D., Kamuanga M. & Swallow B. (1999). - Using conjoint analysis to estimate farmers' preferences for cattle traits in West Africa. International Livestock Research Institute (ILR1)/Centre international de Recherche-Développement sur l'Élevage en zone subhumide (CIRDES) Working Paper. CIRDES, Bobo-Dioulasso, 40 pp.

83. Tano K., Kamuanga M., Faminow M.D., Swallow B. & D'Ieteren G.D.M. (1999). - Adoption and demand for trypanotolerant cattle in the sub-humid zone of West Africa. International Livestock Research Institute (ILRI)/Centre international de Recherche-Développement sur l'Élevage en zone subhumide (CIRDES) Working Paper. CIRDES, Bobo-Dioulasso, 29 pp.

84. Thorne P.J. (1999). - Crop-livestock interactions: a review of opportunities for developing integrated models. In Report for the International Livestock Research Institute (ILRI) Systems Analysis and Impact Assessment Project. ILRI, Nairobi, 73 pp.

85. Umali D.L., Feder G. & de Haan C. (1992). - The balance between public and private sector activities in the delivery of livestock services. Discussion Paper 163. World Bank, Washington, DC, 114 pp.

86. Vandersmissen A. & Symoens C (1997). - The multifactorial contribution of livestock to development in Asia. European Commission, Brussels, 67 pp.

Page 26: The economics of optimal health and productivity in ...€¦ · production or as a production activity for subsistence needs or market sale under systems ranging from extensive pastoralist

424 Rev. sci. tech. Off. i n t . Epiz., 18 (2)

87. Van Schaik G., Perry B.D., Mukhebi A.W., Gitau G.K. & Dijkhuizen A.A. (1996). - An economic study of smallholder dairy farms in Murang'a District, Kenya. Prev. vet. Med., 29, 21-36.

88. Vogel S. (1997). - Heartwater in South Africa. In Proc. SADC heartwater workshop, 2-4 April, Gaborone. University of Florida, Gainesville, Florida, 53-57.

89. Walshe M.J., Grindle J . , Nell A. & Bachmann M. (1991). -Dairy development in sub-Saharan Africa: a study of issues and options. World Bank Technical Paper 135. World Bank, Washington, DC, 97 pp.

90. Wamukoya J.P.O., Gathuma J.M. & Mutiga E.R. (1995). -Spontaneous private veterinary practices evolved in Kenya since 1988. Food and Agriculture Organization, Rome, 76 pp.

91. Wilson R.T. (1986). - Livestock production in central Mali: long-term studies on cattle and small ruminants in the agropastoral system. International Livestock Research Institute Report, No. 14. International Livestock Centre for Africa, Addis Ababa, Ethiopia, 111 pp.

92. Wilson R.T. (1991). - Small ruminant production and the small ruminant resources in tropical Africa. Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) Animal Health and Production Paper No. 88. FAO, Rome, 231 pp.

93. Windsor R.S. & Wood A. (1998). - Contagious bovine pleuropneumonia - the costs of control in Central/Southern Africa. In Tropical veterinary medicine - molecular epidemiology, hemoparasites and their vectors and general topics (F. Jongejan, W. Goff & E. Camus, eds). Ann. N.Y. Acad. Sci., 849, 299-306.