the making of economic policy: a transaction-cost politics perspective

93
The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction- Cost Politics Perspective Avinash K. Dixit MIT Press, 1996

Upload: madge

Post on 12-Jan-2016

26 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

DESCRIPTION

The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective. Avinash K. Dixit MIT Press, 1996. Motivation. - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Avinash K. DixitMIT Press, 1996

Page 2: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Motivation

• The reality of most countries’ trade policies is so blatantly contrary to all the normative prescriptions of the economist that there is no way to understand it except by delving into the politics.

Page 3: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Transaction-Costs• In economics, it has come to mean a very general class of

information, negotiation, and enforcement problems that affect the internal organization of firms and the outcome of market and nonmarket relations among firms, workers and so on.

• A similar and even more severe class of transaction costs (which deals with principal-agent problems, commitment and credibility) pervades political relations and affect political outcomes.

• The policy process can be better understood and related to each other by thinking of them as the result of various transaction costs and of the strategies of the participants to cope with these costs.

Page 4: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Common Agency

• Within this general framework, a particularly important feature of the political process of making economic policy is the “common agency,” where several players in the political game try to influence the actions of one decision-maker.

• It leads to a severe diminution of the power of the incentives that can be offered to this decision-maker.

Page 5: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Market versus Government

• The tradition dichotomy of market versus government, and the question of which system perform better, largely lose its relevance. – Both of them are facts of the imperfect economic life,

and they unavoidable interact in complex ways. • The most we can do is to understand how the

combined economic-political system evolves mechanisms to cope with the variety of transaction costs it must face that precludes a fully ideal outcome.

Page 6: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Principal-Agent Model

Page 7: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Regulatory agency

Page 8: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and Investors

Regulatory agencies

Page 9: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and Investors

Regulatory agency

Consumers

Page 10: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and investors

Regulatory agency

Consumers

Executive

Congress and

Committees

Page 11: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and Investors

Regulatory agency

Consumers

Executive

Congress and

Committees

Page 12: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and investors

Regulatory agency

Consumers

Executive

Congress and

Committees

Voters

Page 13: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and Investors

Regulatory agencies

Consumers

Executive

Congress and

Committees

Voters

Bureaucracy and other agencies

Page 14: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and Investors

Regulatory Agency

Consumers

Executive

Congress and

Committees

Voters

Bureaucracy and other agencies

Courts

Page 15: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The players in the Regulatory Process andtheir inter-relations

Firms and Investors

Regulatory agency

Consumers

Executive

Congress and

Committees

Voters

Bureaucracy and other agencies

CourtsSupreme

Court

Page 16: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Regulatory Agencies

Supreme Court

Executive

CourtBureaucracy

and other agencies

Firms and Investors

ConsumersInterest Groups

Congress and Committees

Set of Principal – Agent Models

Voters

Page 17: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Principal-Agent model:

• It is relevant to analyze relationships with following conditions:– Delegation– Asymmetric information– Imperfect relation between the effort and its

results– High costs of monitoring– No alignment of preferences or objectives

Page 18: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Principal-Agent model:

• In general terms, there exist two solutions to the principal-agent relation:

1. Involves a structure of remuneration aiming at approaching the incentives of both parts involved (paying a tip).

2. Rules and institutions capable of avoiding opportunistic behavior of the agent.

Page 19: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive versus Normative Political Theory:

• To what extent those theories are excluding, complementary, or competitors?

• Both are based on the premise that agents are rational and look for the own interests.

• Dixit suggests a synthesis, labeled ‘transaction-cost politics’ that views policymaking as a process in real time.

Page 20: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Normative Political Theory:

• Market failure (i.e. natural monopoly)• Requires a criterion to fix with the “best” way this

failure aiming at maximizing the social welfare.• Pareto-optimality (efficiency criterion)• First-best and second-best solutions (overcome the

market imperfections)– Moral hazard (level of effort of the firm)– Adverse selection (the regulator has no complete

information about the costs of the firm)– The regulator is obliged to pay informational rents.

Page 21: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Normative Political Theory:

• As a consequence of asymmetric information Laffont and Tirole offer as a solution a menu of contract:– Price-caps– Repartition of profits

• Thus, the firm would have incentives to revel its true effort

Page 22: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Normative Political Theory• The normative solution is rarely observed in the real life• The normative solution requires a high level of discretion of

the regulator. This generates incentives for opportunistic behavior

• Dixit (1996) observes that the normative theory understand the formulation and implementation of policies as a technical or organizational problems. As if political failures could be avoided through good management, namely, giving power to make and implement economic policy to an economist…

• In other words, it does not take into account political and economic institutions.

• The benevolent, omnipotent, and omniscient dictator would maximize the social welfare.

Page 23: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive and Normative Political theory

• Dixit 1996

• Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-best literature

Page 24: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive and Normative Political theory

• Dixit 1996

• Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-bestliterature

Informational Economics literature

Page 25: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive and Normative Political theory

• Dixit 1996

• Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-bestliterature

Informational Economics literature

PPTR tries torelaxthis unrealisticpremises

Page 26: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive and Normative Political theory

• Dixit 1996

• Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-bestliterature

Informational Economics literature

Economic relationsUsually involves Multiple principals

Page 27: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive and Normative Political theory

• Dixit 1996

• Dictator benevolent, omnipotent and omniscient

second-bestliterature

Informational Economics literature

Economic agents, Including regulatory agencies,Bureaucracy, and governmentare made by people that try to Maximize their own interests

Page 28: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive Theory

• Also starts from a market failure• Regulation necessarily leads to a redistribution.

Rarely there are Pareto-optimum corrections or ways of implementing compensations (side-payments)

• Given the behavioral premises, individuals and groups would try to influence this redistribution.

• Their capacity to do so would depend on the institutions (i.e. property rights)

Page 29: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Positive Theory• Many situations apparently inefficient could be

understood as a consequence of restrictions imposed by transaction costs among agents. The great majority of the PPTR tries to explain why such inefficient situations are observed even when there are obvious and better ways to deal with that. This involves to identify the source of restriction which are generating transaction costs and to show how it affects the agent choices. Almost always it requires to take into account the political institutions.

Page 30: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Why does the regulation (government intervention) tend to be inefficient?

• Economic reasons:– Asymmetric information – Uncertainty about effects, costs, and benefits– It does not mean that the regulation is not

necessary; however, those problems should be taken into account

Page 31: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Why does the regulation (government intervention) tend to be inefficient?

• Political reasons:– Regulation necessarily means income redistribution – Quotas, licenses, subsides, establish a price, etc. transfer

rents and incomes– Interest-groups will demand this redistributions and

politicians offer– Generally, the regulation tends to be inefficient– Rent-seeking– Few beneficiaries and lots of opponents

Page 32: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

A Synthesis: A Policy Process in ‘Real Time’

• Constitutions are incomplete contracts:– The constitution never lays down the clear, firm,

and comprehensive set of rules that the contractarian approach depicts; so there is room for maneuver in individual acts.

– Inability to foresee all the possible contingencies and to adjust to them

– Last longer than most business relationships• Constitutions are not made behind a veil of

ignorance

Page 33: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Coase’s Theorem

• Once the property rights over a disputed resource (ex. Rents of a monopoly) have been established, and given that the transaction costs are equal to zero, the private negotiations between agents approaches to the efficient level of allocation. (Coase, Ronald, (1960) The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1-44).

Page 34: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Example:

• A firm pollutes a river which provides a cost of $500 to a farmer along the river.

Page 35: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Example:

• A firm pollutes a river which provides a cost of $500 to a farmer along the river.

• It costs $300 to the farmer to build a station to purify the water.

Page 36: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Example:

• A firm pollutes a river which provides a cost of $500 to a farmer along the river.

• If costs $300 to the farmer to build a station to purify the water.

• The firm can eliminate the harmful effect of pollution changing its production process at the cost of $100.

Page 37: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Questions:

• Should be allowed the firm to pollute the river?• Should the firm be obliged to change its production

process?• Who should pay for that?• What are the economic implications if the firm would

have the property rights of polluting and the farmer would have to compensate him in order to not pollute?

Page 38: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Example:

• And, if the property rights belong to the farmer?

Page 39: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The Coase’s Theorem:

• Coase argues that, for the economic efficiency point of view, the result would be the same regardless the of the property rights given that the transaction costs are null.

Page 40: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Numeric Example I:

• Cost of pollution over the farmer = $500• Cost of cleaning from the farmer = $300• Cost of cleaning from the firm = $100– Case I:

• The farmer has the property rights.• The firm will pay for the right to pollute, It pays $100 at maximum• The farmer would accept more than $300 only since he/she would

have to clean the water in order to avoid the cost of $500• Thus, the is no agreement and the firm purifies the water itself.

Page 41: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Numeric Example I:

• Cost of pollution over the farmer = $500• Cost of cleaning from the farmer = $300• Cost of cleaning from the firm = $100– Case II:

• The firm has the property rights.• The farmer will pay for the firm to not pollute. It pays $300 at

maximum• The farmer would accept to pay no more than $100 since he/she

could clean the water at this price.• Thus, the farmer pays between $100 and $300 and the firm

purifies the water itself.

Page 42: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The solution is the same in both cases

• The solution is economically efficient

Page 43: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Efficiency vs. Equity

• Although the reached solution are not affected by the property rights the distribution between the parts involved would be.

Page 44: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Efficiency vs. Equity

• When the property rights belong to the farmer, the firm has a cost of $100.

Page 45: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Efficiency vs. Equity

• However, when the property rights belong to the firm, the farmer pays at least $100 and part of the exceeding of $200. This “rent” of $200 will be allocated by negotiations between the parts.

Page 46: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

What is the fairest solution?

• Coase recommends that we should not conclude too fast.

• He calls our attention to the reciprocal nature of the problem.

Page 47: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Graphic Example.

1 23

MB for the firm to pollute

a

b d

c

MC of the pollution over the farmer

Page 48: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

If the firm has PR it pollutes until 3. The farmer can convince the firm to pollute until 2 offering more of ‘d’. The farmer would thus win c+d.

1 23

MC of the pollution over the farmer

MB for the firm to pollute

a

b d

c

Page 49: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

If the farmer has the PR he/she prefers If the farmer has the PR he/she prefers 1 1 (if there is no (if there is no negotiation). The firm can compensate the farmer to pollute at negotiation). The firm can compensate the farmer to pollute at 2 2 offering more of ‘b’. offering more of ‘b’.

1 23

MC of the pollution over the farmer

MB for the firm to pollute

a

b d

c

Page 50: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Necessary conditions to reach the negotiated result:

• Well defined property rights. It implies political and judicial institutions that work well.

• Low transaction costs• Information about all costs of each possible

result for each part involved.

Page 51: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Polemic Implications of the Coase’s Theorem

• In many cases there are no necessity of governmental interventions in order to solve problems of externalities since the private negotiations reach the economically efficient solution.

Page 52: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Limitations of the Coase’s Theorem:

• The transactional costs usually are not small, especially when several players are involved.

• There exist public and private externalities. In the public ones there are the free-ridding problem.

• There exist the problem of inter-temporal transactions with future generations.

• The initial distribution of the property rights can affect the capacity of negotiation of each part.

• Even when the theorem fits there are room for government role.

Page 53: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Role of the government is to help greasing the private negotiation

• Property rights have to be well defined and allocated clearly. • The government has to monitor the environment aiming at

identifying who are the polluters and who are victims of the pollution. This information has to be publicized for all parts that have been affected.

• The government must establish, quantify, and publicize the legal rules that regulates the environment in order to make it easier the private negotiations.

• Access to the judicial system has to be facilitated and cheap

Page 54: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Regulation and the Coase’s Theorem

• As in practical terms those conditions are rarely found, the coase’s solution is not viable (this is exactly what Coase claims!)

• Therefore, the regulation becomes necessary.• The transactions costs are the key. Whose are the

political property rights? What are the political transaction costs?

• The results usually are not efficient

Page 55: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Regulation and the Coase’e Theorem

• Reasons why it is difficult to make side payments:– Informational problems, uncertainty, difficulties of

measuring costs and benefits– Collective action problems– Inexistence of a market of political property rights

(political risks)

Page 56: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Delegating Powers

A Transaction Cost Politics Approach to Policy making under Separate

Powers

David Epstein & Sharyn O’Halloran

Page 57: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Average Discretion of the Executive in the EUA

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

Exec

utiv

e D

iscr

etio

n

Page 58: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Puzzle

• Why does Congress delegate broad authority to the executive in some policy areas but not in others?

• Can Congress perfectly control delegated authority through administrative procedures, oversight, and administrative law?

Page 59: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Question

• When does Congress specify the details of policy in legislation, and when does it leave these details to regulatory agencies?

• What are the implications of this institutional choice for policy outcomes?

Basic question of policy making in a separation of powers system.

Page 60: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Transaction Cost Politics

• Policy can be made (i) in Congress, (ii) through delegation authority to the executive agencies, or a (iii) mixture of these two.

• When deciding where policy will be made, Congress trades off the internal policy production costs of the committee system against the external costs of delegation

• (make-or-buy decision).

Page 61: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Theory:

• A policy will be made in the politically most efficient manner; that is, maximizing legislators’ political goal: reelection.

• Legislators will prefer to make policy themselves as long as the political benefits they derive from doing so outweighs the political costs; otherwise, they will delegate to the executive

Page 62: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Abdication versus delegation?• Implications:

– To what extent can Congress control unelected regulatory agencies when delegating authority?

• Lowi (1969)– Congress has surrendered their legislative authority to

bureaucrats• MCNOLGAST (1987, 1989)

– Legislators can control bureaucrats through oversight, administrative procedures and enfranchising third parties into the decision-making process.

Page 63: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Authors’ Claim:

• A theory of oversight divorced from a theory of delegation will overlook the fact that those issue areas in which the executive makes policy differ from those in which Congress makes policy itself.

Page 64: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Legislative organization and delegation

• Distributive versus informational theories– This is a false dichotomy (whether committee

serves pork barrel projects or legislators’ desire to avoid the consequences of ill-informed policies):• Some policy areas are more characterized by

informational concerns and other by distributive. The first ones tend to be delegated and the second tend to be made in Congress

Page 65: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Divided Government and Delegation

• To what extend will an opposing Congress delegate more powers to the executive?

• Mayhew (1991): the same number of legislation get passed under unified and divided government. It doesn't lead to gridlock.– However, the authors call our attention to the quality of bills

passed: • Congress delegate less and constrains more under divided

government: procedural gridlock, that is, producing executive branch agencies with less authority to make policy and increase oversight from congressional committees.

Page 66: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

What does Transaction Cost mean?

• Anything that makes reality deviate from this Coasian world:– “anything that impedes the specification,

monitoring, or enforcement of an economic transaction is a transaction cost” (Dixit 1966).

Page 67: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Common elements of the Transaction Costs analysis:

1. The contract is the unit of analysis2. The contracts are enforceable by some neutral third-

party3. Assumes the existence of multiple governance

structures4. Economic actors are assumed to be boundedly

rational (agents cannot eliminate transaction costs by simply contracting)

5. Holdup problems

Contracts are incomplete and ambiguous

Page 68: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Theory of Transaction Cost politics

• Delegation to a bureaucracy is subjected to the political equivalent of a holdup problem; so Congress will delegate to the executive when the external transaction costs of doing so are less than the internal transaction costs of making policy through the normal legislative process of the committees.

Page 69: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Reasons not to delegate

• With transaction costs equal to zero Congress might like to delegate broad discretionary authorities and agencies might like to receive such authority (please everyone). However,– Difficult to control and monitoring – Incomplete contracts– Uncertainty of future opportunistic behavior– Impossibility of binding the actions of agency successors

Page 70: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Reasons to delegate

• Save time/Reduce congress workload• Take advantage of agency expertise• Protect special interests• Blame-shifting (avoiding the inefficiencies of committee

system)– Delays, logrolling, informational inefficiencies, etc.

These do not explain why delegate in some policy areas rather than others.

Page 71: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Neither alternative is perfect…

• However, in some specific cases delegate or not (how mach delegate) would be relatively more attractive than from the median legislator’s preference.

Page 72: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Basic Assumptions

• Two alternative modes of policy making– Congress: • Committee System

– Regulatory Agencies: • Delegation to Executive

• Legislators decide where policy is made.• Legislators’ primary goal is reelection– Authority will be allocated across the branches

in a politically efficient manner

Page 73: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Division of Labor

• Each alternative mode of policy making has its own set of inefficiencies:– Legislative Policy Making (Committees)• Logrolling, delay, informational problems

– Agency Policy Making (Delegation) • Principal-agent problems of oversight

So when deciding where policy will be made, legislators trade off these internal and external inefficiencies.

Page 74: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Make-or-Buy

• Congress’s decision to delegate is like a firm’s make-or-buy decision.

– Legislators can either produce policy internally,

OR

– Legislators can subcontract out (delegate) to the executive.

Page 75: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Discretion Continuum

Legislative Policymaking

Agency Policymaking

Low Discretion High Discretion

D

Page 76: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Discretion Continuum

Trade Off:

Legislative Policymaking

Agency Policymaking

Low Discretion High Discretion

LegislativePolicymaking

AgencyPolicymaking

vs.

D

Page 77: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Discretion Continuum

Amount of discretion delegated to the executive balances these costs at the margin.

Trade Off:

Legislative Policymaking

Agency Policymaking

Low Discretion High Discretion

LegislativePolicymaking

AgencyPolicymaking

vs.

D

Page 78: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

The formal decision to delegate:

1. The legislation (bill) is the unit of analysis2. There exist enforceable mechanisms for inter-branch

contracts3. Multiple possible governance structures4. Bounded-rationality 5. Holdup problem6. Internal transaction cost of production7. A decision mechanisms predicting which governance

structure will be chosen

Page 79: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Model Elements

• Actors: Floor, Comm., Pres., Agency• Policy space: X = 1, status quo x0=0

• Preferences: –(x-xi)2 xF=0, xP>0– Implies that all actors will be risk averse

• Outcomes: x = p + , ~ U[-R,R]– Agencies have perfect information of – Committees only know sign of – Floor knows ex ante distribution of

Page 80: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Model:• Players:

– Median floor voter in Congress (F)– Congressional Committee (C)– President (P)– Agency (A)

• One-dimension policy; single-pick preferences, median voter (pivotal) • Each player has a most-preferable policy or ideal point and are risk-

averse (dislike uncertainty)• Policy outcomes are not necessarily the same as the policies that

emerged from the policymaking process. – That is, X = p +

Page 81: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Model:

• The players start the game with probabilistic beliefs about the value of .

• These beliefs are uniform in some interval [-R, R].

• During the game, players will try to gather more information (expertise) about the exact value of

Page 82: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Game Tree

N

Committee learns >0 or <0,

reports bill (b)

Don't Delegate

Delegate

Floor sets policy pF

x=pF+

Agency learns exact value of sets policy pA s.t.

|pA| d

x=SQ+pA+Floor sets

discretion (d), status quo (SQ)

C

AF

F

F

P

President sets Agency ideal

point xA

Institutional Choice Policy Making ProcessFinal

Outcomes

Page 83: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Sequential Signaling game:

1. Institutional choice– While the agency observes the exact value of , the

committee observes only whether lies in the interval range [-R, 0] or the range [0. R]; that is, the committee sees only the sign of .

2. Policy-making Process– Choice of buying or making the policy.

3. Final outcome– Committee: X = p + – Agency: X = SQ + pa +

Page 84: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Solving the Game

• Agency sets policy as close to its ideal point as possible, given limits on discretion.

• President sets Agency’s ideal point to equal her own: xA=xP.

• Congress sets status quo and discretion: – Set SQ to get its ideal point in expectation, given beliefs

about – Set discretion d=R-xP.

Page 85: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Theoretical Propositions

• In equilibrium, Congress will delegate more discretionary authority to the executive:1. The lower the level of congressional-

executive conflict;2. The higher the level of committee-floor

conflict; 3. The higher the level of uncertainty in the policy

environment.

Page 86: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Deliberate Discretion?

The Institutional Foundation of Bureaucratic Autonomy

John Huber & Charles ShipanJohn Huber & Charles Shipan

Page 87: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

What this book is about?

• How elected officials use the statutes to establish policy details in effort to achieve desired outcomes.

• Develop and test a theory of delegation that explains the choice of how to delegate aiming at understanding how institutional context affects delegation strategies.

Page 88: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Two types of designing statutes:

1. To write long statutes with extremely detailed languages in a effort to micromanage the policymaking process.

2. To write vague statutes that have many details unspecified, thereby delegating policymaking authority to other actors, usually bureaucrats.

Page 89: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Vague (Germany) versus specific (Ireland) statutes about sexual harassment:

• Why has the same policy issue been treated differently by politicians in distinct political systems?

• Why these choice matter?• Is the transferred discretion a deliberate

choice?

Page 90: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Delegation as double-edge sword

• “the central reason for granting policymaking autonomy to bureaucrats – their technical expertise – also creates a big problem, as bureaucrats can use their knowledge against politicians. Bureaucratic expertise is thus a double-edge sword, creating both the incentive for legislatures to give policymaking power to bureaucrats and the opportunity for these bureaucrats to act counter to legislative preferences” (Peters 1981)

Page 91: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Two prevalent views:

• Bureaucratic discretion (bureaucratic dominance)

versus• Deliberate discretion (politicians dominance.

That is, politicians would have capacity to control bureaucrats and achieve their goals by delegating)

Page 92: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

Alternative view:

• Rather than asking to what extent politicians control bureaucrats, the authors assume that in any political context there typically exists a politician who has greater opportunities than other political actors to influence bureaucratic behavior.

– In parliamentary democracy = Cabinet– In presidential system = president or governors

Page 93: The Making of Economic Policy: A Transaction-Cost Politics Perspective

4 factors that affect politician’s incentives to micromanage policymaking

1. Level of political conflict between politicians who adopt the statute and bureaucrats who implement them

2. The capacity of politicians to write detailed statutes3. The bargaining environment (e.g. the existence of

vetoes or bicameral conflicts) in which the statutes are adopted

4. The politicians’ expectation about non-statutory factors such as the role of courts or legislative oversight.