the natural resource cure - diva portal

33
DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Uppsala University C-level Thesis Author: Anna Wiström 1 Supervisor: Niklas Bengtsson Spring 2013 The Natural Resource Cure Quality of institutions? Abstract This study explores the natural resource curse and its possible cure via good institutional quality. In theory countries that are resource abundant are said to have slower economic growth than countries that are resource scarce. Earlier studies have shown that resource abundant countries only suffer from the resource curse if the resources are highly appropriable and if the institutional quality is low. If resource abundant countries instead have resources that are highly appropriable and if the institutional quality is high they will benefit from their resources. If a country has resource with low technical appropriability no negative effect on growth is expected. In this study several time periods are studied and it can be concluded that for earlier time periods the resource curse theory in general holds but for later time periods no negative effects of resource abundance on economic growth can be detected. Keywords: Natural resource curse, economic growth, development, appropriability, institutional quality JEL classification: N50, O13, O40, O57, P17 1 E-mail: [email protected]

Upload: others

Post on 30-Apr-2022

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

DEPARTMENT OF ECONOMICS Uppsala University C-level Thesis Author: Anna Wiström1 Supervisor: Niklas Bengtsson Spring 2013

The Natural Resource Cure Quality of institutions?

Abstract

This study explores the natural resource curse and its possible cure via good institutional quality. In theory countries that are resource abundant are said to have slower economic growth than countries that are resource scarce. Earlier studies have shown that resource abundant countries only suffer from the resource curse if the resources are highly appropriable and if the institutional quality is low. If resource abundant countries instead have resources that are highly appropriable and if the institutional quality is high they will benefit from their resources. If a country has resource with low technical appropriability no negative effect on growth is expected. In this study several time periods are studied and it can be concluded that for earlier time periods the resource curse theory in general holds but for later time periods no negative effects of resource abundance on economic growth can be detected.

Keywords: Natural resource curse, economic growth, development, appropriability, institutional quality

JEL classification: N50, O13, O40, O57, P17

1 E-mail: [email protected]

Page 2: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

2

Table of Content

1 INTRODUCTION ......................................................................................................... 3  2 PREVIOUS RESEARCH ............................................................................................... 4  3 THEORY AND DATA ................................................................................................... 6  

3.1 THEORY ............................................................................................................ 7  3.2 DATA ................................................................................................................ 9  

4 RESULTS ............................................................................................................... 12  4.1 MAIN RESULTS ................................................................................................ 12  4.2 INSTRUMENTING FOR INSTITUTIONAL QUALITY .................................................... 16  4.3 WHY IS THERE NO RESOURCE CURSE BETWEEN 1990 AND 2010? ....................... 17  

5 ROBUSTNESS ......................................................................................................... 20  5.1 EXCLUDING OUTLIERS ...................................................................................... 20  5.2 EXCLUDING OR INCLUDING VARIABLES ............................................................... 21  5.3 EXCLUDING REGIONS ....................................................................................... 21  5.4 EXCLUDING RICH OR POOR COUNTRIES ............................................................. 22  

6 DISCUSSION ........................................................................................................... 22  7 CONCLUSION ......................................................................................................... 24  REFERENCES ............................................................................................................ 26  APPENDIX ................................................................................................................. 28  

 

Page 3: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

3

1 Introduction

Why have Chile and Liberia had such different rates of economic growth for the last

30 years? And Singapore and Iran? Chile had a growth rate of 3.2 % per year and

Liberia -3.2 % per year between 1980 and 2010.2 Singapore grew at a rate of 4.6 %

per year and Iran -1.2 % per year between 1970 and 2000. One thing these four

countries have in common is that they are abundant in fuel, ores or metals.3 About 64

% of Chiles and Liberia’s merchandise exports were ores and metals in 1980 and

about 25 % of Singapore’s and 90 % of Iran’s merchandise exports were fuels in 1970.

What makes these countries experience such different rates of economic growth? One

thing that is different between the countries is the institutional quality. The quality of

the institutions, governments and legal systems are in Chile and Singapore higher

than in Liberia and Iran, making it possible for the two first countries mentioned to

benefit from their resources while the two last cannot. To measure institutional

quality in this study the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) index is used. The

ICRG index is combined of three components scaled to an o-1 variable where values

close to 1 indicate good institutions and values close to 0 indicate bad institutions.

The components included in the measure are quality of the bureaucracy, corruption

in government and rule of law. The values for the countries mentioned above are 0.57

for Chile, 0.17 for Liberia, 0.89 for Singapore and 0.35 for Iran.

In the previous examples the resources in question had a high level of technical

appropriability. What happens with a country’s growth if the resources have a low

level of technical appropriability? In both Panama and Paraguay food export was

about 70 % of merchandise exports and the ICRG values were 0.22 and 0.14

respectively in 1970. Still both countries grew at a rate of 2.3 % and 2.6 % per year

between 1970 and 1990. Less appropriable resources do not always imply a resource

curse even if the institutional quality in a country is low.

2 For sources and descriptions of all data and variables used in the study see Table 14 in Appendix. 3 The level of resource abundance will in this study be approximated by exports as share of merchandise exports.

Page 4: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

4

The examples above demonstrate three aspects of the theory to be explored in this

study. Firstly, the phenomenon that resource abundant countries have slower

economic growth than resource scarce countries, known as the natural resource

curse. Secondly, the resource curse can only be detected if the resources have high

technical appropriability, for example fuel, ores and metals, and not if the resources

have low technical appropriability, like food and agricultural products. Thirdly, if a

country is abundant in highly appropriable resources it will only be cursed if the

institutions in the country have low quality. The theory of the resource curse with

these aspects has been explored in earlier research from for example Boschini et al

(2007 and 2013) and Isham et al (2005).

In this study different resources with different levels of appropriability will be

explored to see if a natural resource curse can be found and if it can be reversed, as it

has been in Chile and Singapore, by good institutional quality. Thus the main

questions to be answered can be stated as: do resource abundant countries,

depending on the level of appropriability of the resources, suffer from slower

economic growth than resource scarce countries? If they do, can the curse be

reversed via good institutions quality? This study will with some alterations follow

that of Boschini et al (2007 and 2013). The two studies will be explained in more

detail and the differences between this study and those of Boschini et al (2007 and

2013) will be stated in the following parts of the text.

The remaining part of this paper is divided into the following sections: section two

covers earlier research, section three explains the theory and data to be used, section

four will present the main results, section five checks the robustness of the results,

section six discuses the results and future questions to be answered and section seven

concludes.

2 Previous research

Some of the most cited works in the natural resource curse field are by Sachs and

Warner (1995, 1999 and 2001). Using primary exports as a proxy for natural

resources they found a negative relationship between exports and growth between

1970 and 1989. They did not however find that institutional quality could reverse the

Page 5: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

5

curse. They explained the negative relationship with what is known as the Dutch

Disease. The basic idea behind the Dutch Disease is that countries that gain a lot of

rents from natural resources will have a crowding-out effect in other economic

sectors. Sachs and Warner (1995) argued that positive externalities, for example

learning-by-doing, are only present in the manufacturing sector and thus countries

with a large natural resource sector and small manufacturing sector will not benefit

from these positive externalities. This theory does not explain why Chile and

Singapore can have such high growth rates even if they are natural resource

exporters.

More resent research has been trying to deal with the problem that the outcome of

natural resource abundance is ambiguous. Isham et al (2005) for example found, in

contrast with Sachs and Warner (1995, 1999 and 2001), that institutional quality do

play a role in determining if a country will be cursed or not. They also found that it is

only what they call point source resources, like fuel, ores, metals and plantation

crops, that lead to the resource curse and not diffuse resources, like food and

agricultural products.

Mehlum et al (2006) found in line with Isham et al (2005) that a country will be

cursed if the institutions are grabber friendly but not if the institutions are producer

friendly. Given that a country is abundant in point source resources it will only be

cursed if the institutions are grabber friendly, undermining the production sector in

the economy that lead to long term growth. When instrumenting for institutional

quality they found that natural resources only effect economic growth negatively via

institutional quality and not directly.

Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian (2003) used instrument variables as well when

estimating the effect resource abundance have on growth. As Mehlum et al (2006)

they found that resource abundance only effect growth via institutional quality.

Pineda and Rodríguez (2010) argued against the resource curse. Using the Human

Development Index (HDI, a measure that is calculated with components in three

main fields; health, education and economic standard of living) they found that

resource abundance, measured as net natural resource export per worker, have

positive effects on HDI and especially its non-economic components. When

Page 6: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

6

explaining why they use net exports instead of exports as the resource abundance

approximation they criticize Sachs and Warner (1995) for not being consistent in

their measuring. Two countries in the sample used by Sachs and Warner (1995) are

measured as net exports instead of exports. The reason Sachs and Warner give is that

the two countries, Singapore and Trinidad and Tobago, import a lot of resources and

directly export them again and thus these countries will appear to be more resource

abundant than they really are. In a study form Lederman and Maloney (2008), the

study that Pineda and Rodríguez (2010) is largely based on, the results from Sachs

and Warner (1995) were redone and is was show that the negative relationship goes

away when using natural resource exports, and not net exports, for all countries.

Pineda and Rodríguez (2010) and Lederman and Maloney (2008) therefore argue

that net export should be used as the natural resource proxy for all countries to

ensure that it is only the resources from within the country that are accounted for.

In the studies this paper is largely based on, Boschini et al (2007 and 2013), they

found that highly appropriable resources will lead to a resource curse and that good

institutions can reverse the curse. In one section in each study they instrumented for

institutional quality and found in contrast with Mehlum et al (2006) and Sala-i-

Martin and Subramanian (2003) that resource abundance do have a direct negative

effect on growth.

3 Theory and data

In this section theory behind the resource curse and the data to be used will be

explained. In the part explaining theory we will start with the basic resource curse

theory, move on to appropriability, institutional quality and lastly putting

appropriability and institutional quality together. After the theory has been described

the data to be used will be explained, starting with the model and then explaining the

variables included in the model.

Page 7: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

7

3.1 Theory

3.1.1 The basic resource curse theory

The basic theory of the resource curse is that countries that are resource abundant

have slower economic growth than countries that are resources scarce (Sachs and

Warner 1995, 1999 and 2001, Boschini et al 2007 and 2013 and Mehlum et al 2006).

This basic theory does not explain the ambiguous outcome of resource abundance.

3.1.2 Appropriability

It is not only to what degree a country is resource abundant that matters when it is

determined whether a country will be cursed or not, what type of resources a country

has plays an important role as well. If the resources in a country are point source

resources, like fuels and minerals, they will more likely cause slower economic growth

in a country than if the resource are diffuse, like food and agricultural products

(Isham et al 2005). Isham et al (2005, p. 3) describes point source resources as

resources that are “…extracted from a narrow geographic or economic base…”. These

point source resources will because of their narrow base be easier to control centrally

and will thus with high probability lead to rent-seeking, corruption and conflicts that

will harm the economic development while diffuse resources most likely will not lead

to such behavior (Boschini et al 2007). To use the terminology from Boschini et al

(2007 and 2013) point source resources are said to have high technical

appropriability and diffuse resources low technical appropriability.

3.1.3 Institutional quality

As mentioned above some researchers has pointed out the importance of institutional

quality in determining if a country will be suffering from the resource curse or not

(Boschini et al 2007 and 2013, Mehlum et al 2006). According to them a country that

has good institutions and is resource abundant will benefit from its resources but a

country that has poor institutions and is resource abundant will be cursed. Figure 1

below graphs ores and metals exports and growth between 1970 and 2010. Included

in the graph to the left is half of the sample with the lowest institutional quality and

included in the graph to the right is half of the sample with the highest institutional

quality. The data indicates a negative relationship for ores and metals exports when

Page 8: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

8

institutions are bad and a positive relationship when institutions are good. As can be

expected from the theory outlined in Boschini et al (2007 and 2013) and Mehlum et

al (2006) countries abundant resources will be cursed only if their institutional

quality is low.

Figure 1: Graphs showing growth and ores and metals exports

3.1.4 Appropriability and institutional quality combined

The two dimensions of the resource curse theory, appropriability and institutional

quality, can be depicted as in Figure 2. Along the vertical line are examples of

resources with different levels of technical appropriability. If the theory holds

countries in the two lower corners of the figure will not be affected by their high

amount of natural resources, countries in the upper right corner will benefit from

their natural resources and countries in the upper left corner will suffer from the

resource curse.

Page 9: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

9

Figure 2: Two dimensions: appropriability and institutional quality

3.2 Data

3.2.1 The model

The basic regression model for testing the effects of resource abundance on economic

growth used in this study follows that of Boschini et al (2007):

!"#$%ℎ! = !!! + !!!"! + !!!!"#! + !! !"!×!"#$! + !! (1)

The dependent variable, !"#$%ℎ!, represents the average yearly growth rate in GDP

per capita over the appropriate time period. !! is a vector including a constant and

initial GDP per capita level, period average of openness and investment and dummy

variables for regions (Africa, the Middle East, Latin America and Asia). !"! is the

proxy used for natural resource abundance, !"#$! stands for institutional quality and

Page 10: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

10

!"!×!"#$! is the interaction between natural resources and institutional quality. The

index ! represent the different countries included in the study.4

There are some differences between this study and those of Boschini et al (2007 and

2013). One difference is that the regional dummy variables used in Boschini et al

(2007) are Sub Saharan Africa and Latin America and in Boschini et al (2013) are Sub

Saharan Africa, Latin America, the Middle East and North Africa instead of Africa,

the Middle East, Latin America and Asia that are used in this study.5 Two other

differences between the studies are that more resent data will be used and that

different time periods will be considered. In the study of Boschini et al (2007) only

one time period is studied, 1975-1998, and in the study from 2013 different start

years for the time periods studied are used, 1965, 1975 and 1985, but only one end

year, 2005. The time periods to be studied in this paper are 1970-2010, 1970-2000,

1970-1990, 1980-2010, 1980-2000 and 1990-2010.6

The proxies for natural resource abundance and the variables in the vector are

measured in the beginning of each time period that is studied as to avoid reverse

causality, where growth is affecting the explanatory variables.

As in Boschini et al (2007 and 2013) the estimations are made using the Ordinary

Least Square (OLS) method. When the measures for natural resources used in the

regressions have high technical appropriability !!will be expected   to be negative,

indicating the resource curse, !!  to be positive, indicating that good institutions are

beneficial for growth, and finally !!  to be positive. If the curse is to be reversed !! has

to be larger in absolute value than !! . When the resources have low technical

appropriability we will not expect any significant results for !! or !!. We still might se

significant and positive results for !!, indicating that good institutions are good for

growth independently of the amount or type of resources a country has.

4 See Table 13 in Appendix for a list of all countries included in the study. 5 Boschini et al (2013) states that the results are not sensitive for extra variables, for example regions, being included in the model. 6 All variables are calculated as five year averages to ensure that no particular year will have a crucial effect on the results. The year 1980 is for example the average between 1978 and 1982.

Page 11: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

11

3.2.2 The variables

In this study a variation of five measures used in Boschini et al (2013) are used to

approximate resource abundance. The measures are taken from The World Bank

(2013) and are agricultural, food, fuel and ores and metals exports as share of

merchandise exports. Total exports are calculated as the sum of agricultural, food,

fuel and ores and metals exports. The data used in Boschini et al (2013) are exports as

share of GDP instead of as share of merchandise exports. Looking again at Figure 2

agricultural and food exports are located at the bottom half of the figure, indicating

low technical appropriability, while fuel and ores and metals exports are located at

the top half of the figure, indicating high technical appropriability. Total exports will

capture the whole range of appropriability levels. Table 14 in Appendix describes

what products are included in the different exports categories. In the results we will

expect to see the resource curse most strongly when using ores and metals exports,

some when using total or fuel exports. Agricultural products and food are less

technically appropriable so we will not expect the curse to appear when using these

two approximations.

Institutional quality in this study is measured by the ICRG index. The three

components of the ICRG that are used in this study are quality of the bureaucracy,

corruption in government and rule of law.7

• Quality of the bureaucracy: This component is given a high value if the

bureaucracy is somewhat independent of political pressure and change of

political rule.

• Corruption in government: A high value is given if corruption is not present.

Absence of corruption is essential if people or companies are to be willing to

invest within the country.

• Rule of law: This variable measures how well the legal system works and how

high the crime rate is in a country. If the legal system is efficient and the crime

rate is low the country will get a high value.

7 There are more components in the original ICRG index but they are not used in thus study due to limited data availability.

Page 12: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

12

The ICRG index is calculated as an average of these three components and is scaled to

a 0-1 variable (Teorell et al 2011a). High values indicate good institutional quality and

low vales indicate bad institutional quality.

There are problems when measuring institutional quality. First, institutional quality

is a question of subjectivity. Second, there has been suggested that institutional

quality can affect the amount of natural resources found and extracted in a country or

that the amount of natural resources can effect the institutional quality. Research has

shown that the most likely way institutions and natural resources are correlated is

that abundance in natural resources generate institutions with bad quality and that in

turn will affect economic growth negatively (Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian 2003

and Mehlum et al 2006). A country with bad institutions might not provide the

essential safety for natural resources to be found and extracted while a country with

good institutions will provide the framework for people and companies to extract and

use the resources efficiently. In this way good institutions will probably lead do more

resources being found and extracted while bad institutions will lead to less resources

being found and extracted (Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian 2003).

4 Results

In the first part of this section the main results are presented. In the second part

results are presented when instrumenting for institutional quality. In the main results

no resources curse can be detected in 1980-2000 or 1990-2010 when using ores and

metals exports, in the third part possible reasons for this absence are tested.

4.1 Main results

The main results are presented in Table 1. Staring with total exports, if the theory of

the resource curse is true we will expect to se some evidence of the curse when using

this proxy. Looking at the results in Table 1 we can see that this is the case for only

one time period, 1970 to 1990, where there is some indication of a negative

relationship between resources and growth.

According to theory abundance in agricultural exports should not be a source of a

resource curse. Looking at the results we can see that there is no evidence of any

Page 13: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

13

curse but rather the opposite, abundance in agricultural exports seem to be beneficial

for growth when looking at the first three time periods. The interaction term is also

significant for the first three time periods and is in absolute value larger than

agricultural exports. The results indicate that agricultural export is beneficial for

growth but if the institutions are good enough the positive effect of the exports will be

reversed and agricultural exports will be negative for growth. We can see that

institutional quality is beneficial for growth in all time periods except 1990-2010.

As with agricultural exports we do not expect any evidence for a resource curse for

food exports. In the results we can se that food exports do not have any influence over

growth for any of the time periods. Neither does the interaction term. The only

significant variable is institutional quality for all time periods but the last, 1990-2010.

When using fuel exports as the resource abundance proxy we will expect some

evidence of a resource curse. As with the results for food exports no evidence of a

curse can be found in the regressions. Growth appears not to be explained by either

fuel exports or the interaction between fuel exports and institutional quality. Good

institutions seem to be beneficial for economic growth in all time periods but the last.

For countries abundant in ores and metals exports we would expect evidence of a

resource curse. Looking at the results we can see that large amounts of exports of ores

and metals indeed have a negative effect on growth for the first four time periods. The

interaction term is significant for the same time periods and is larger in absolute

value. We can thus conclude that ores and metals exports have a negative effect on

growth but with good enough institutions the curse will be reversed and ores and

metals in combination with good institutions will be beneficial for economic growth.

Institutional quality explains some of the growth in the time periods 1970-2000,

1970-1990, 1980-2000 and 1990-2010. In these periods better institutions will lead

to faster economic growth.

Looking at the explanatory power, !!, in the regressions for each time period we can

see that for the first five periods the !! is around 50 % to 60 % while for the last time

period the explanatory power is only about 25 % to 30 %. This indicates that the data

in the first periods fit the model better than in the latest time period. In other words,

Page 14: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

14

there is something else explaining economic growth in the period from 1990 to 2010

other than the variables included in the model used in this study.

To summarize the results; evidence of the resource curse can only be detected in the

regressions using total exports in 1970-1990 and ores and metals exports in the first

four time periods. Looking at food and fuel exports no relationship between exports

and growth can be detected in any time period, either positive or negative. When

using agricultural exports there appears to exist a resource blessing rather than a

resource curse.

Since the curse is almost exclusively present in the regressions using ores and metals

exports as measure for natural resources the remaining part of the paper will present

results for ores and metals exports only and, without loosing generality and saving

space, the time periods 1970 to 1990 and 1990 to 2010.8

8 For results not presented in the text contact the author.

Page 15: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

15

Table 1: Main results

1970-2010 1970-2000 1970-1990 1980-2010 1980-2000 1990-2010

Total exports -2.148 (1.714)

-3.540 (2.125)

-4.206* (2.476)

-1.230 (1.309)

-2.130 (1.771)

-0.186 (1.413)

Institutional quality

-0.117 (1.510)

-0.694 (1.784)

-0.455 (1.965)

1.357 (1.188)

1.537 (1.566)

1.979 (1.376)

Interaction term 2.215 (1.963)

3.641 (2.356)

3.992 (2.759)

1.305 (1.686)

1.889 (2.140)

-0.213 (1.805)

N

!!

69 0.5415

69 0.5949

69 0.5899

68 0.4894

68 0.5166

67 0.2697

Agricultural exports

4.093* (2.169)

5.274** (2.384)

7.541** (3.013)

-0.574 (2.516)

-0.216 (2.420)

-4.100 (2.648)

Institutional quality

2.438*** (0.637)

3.342*** (0.728)

4.621*** (0.906)

2.139** (0.812)

3.103*** (0.973)

1.753 (1.429)

Interaction term -5.250** (2.309)

-6.988*** (2.494)

-11.152*** (3.282)

0.916 (3.936)

0.080 (4.530)

3.444 (5.119)

N

!!

69 0.5595

69 0.6019

69 0.6068

67 0.4706

67 0.4938

67 0.2854

Food exports 0.360 (1.372)

1.074 (1.496)

2.956 (1.776)

0.344 (1.610)

-0.185 (1.975)

-0.426 (1.935)

Institutional quality

2.235** (0.956)

3.186*** (1.036)

4.523*** (1.244)

2.586*** (0.890)

3.392*** (1.093)

1.924 (1.280)

Interaction term -1.152 (1.687)

-1.928 (1.842)

-3.905 (2.446)

-1.151 (1.943)

-0.866 (2.290)

-0.256 (2.015)

N !!

69 0.5304

69 0.5713

69 0.5831

67 0.4748

67 0.5005

67 0.2724

Fuel exports 0.604 (1.196)

-0.498 (1.496)

-1.148 (2.124)

1.121 (1.266)

1.878 (1.679)

0.532 (2.180)

Institutional quality

1.944*** (0.693)

2.473*** (0.752)

3.217*** (0.872)

2.562*** (0.938)

3.519*** (1.229)

1.490 (1.183)

Interaction term -0.916 (2.692)

0.202 (3.058)

0.683 (3.989)

-1.925 (2.424)

-3.696 (3.245)

-0.546 (3.458)

N !!

66 0.5236

66 0.5706

66 0.5921

65 0.4808

65 0.5060

65 0.2541

Ores and metals exports

-3.482** (1.519)

-3.960** (1.696)

-5.070*** (1.902)

-5.416* (3.053)

-5.695 (3.614)

1.614 (2.064)

Institutional quality

0.768 (0.612)

1.306* (0.669)

1.759* (0.953)

1.158 (0.741)

1.796* (0.904)

2.317* (1.181)

Interaction term 7.363** (2.985)

8.297** (3.403)

8.819** (3.601)

11.107* (5.897)

11.927 (7.324)

-4.262 (4.145)

N !!

69 0.5911

69 0.6223

69 0.6292

66 0.5479

66 0.5461

66 0.2753

Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown).

Page 16: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

16

4.2 Instrumenting for institutional quality

As suggested above the amount of natural resources in a country can depend on the

quality of institutions. Because of this correlation there might be a problem with

biased and inconsistent estimates. To deal with this problem we will use the two-

stage least square (2SLS) method, instrumenting for institutional quality and the

interaction term between the natural resource proxy and institutional quality with

variables that are correlated with institutions but not with the error term. The

variables used in Boschini et al (2007), and to be used in this study, are latitude, the

interaction between the natural resource proxy and latitude and the fraction of people

in the country that speaks a western European language.

The results from the first stage regressions are presented in Table 5 in Appendix. We

can see that the variables used as instruments are explaining some of the variation in

the institutional quality measure and the interaction term. All three instruments are

significant in at least one regression.

The results from the second stage regressions are presented in Table 2 below. The

main results from Table 1 for the corresponding time periods are also presented for

comparison. We see that the results in the first time period do resemble that of the

main results to some extent. The sings in front of the estimates are the same when

using the two methods but the effects of the variables are larger when using OLS.

Since the 2SLS method always gives larger standard errors than the OLS method the

variables are not significant when instrumenting for institutional quality and the

interaction term.

The results for the second time period do not resemble that of the main results. When

using the 2SLS method the estimates for ores and metals exports and the interaction

term have the opposite signs from the estimates when using the OLS method, they

are larger in absolute value and are not significant. Institutional quality is still

positive, larger in absolute value and not significant.

Since the estimates are not significant in either time period we can conclude that

there is no evidence of a resource curse when instrumenting for institutional quality

and the interaction term. The results are consistent with the findings of Sala-i-Martin

Page 17: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

17

and Subramanian (2003), resource abundance have negative effects on institutional

quality and through that on economic growth but abundance in natural resources do

not appear to have any direct effect on economic growth. The results are not

consistent with that of Boschini et al (2007 and 2013) where they find that the

estimates when using the two estimation methods give roughly the same results.

Table 2: Second stage regressions

1970-1990 (2SLS)

1970-1990 (OLS)

1990-2010 (2SLS)

1990-2010 (OLS)

Ores and metals exports -4.636 (3.183)

-5.070*** (1.902)

-15.703 (15.919)

1.614 (2.064)

Institutional quality 7.333 (5.391)

1.759* (0.953)

7.392 (4.876)

2.317* (1.181)

Interaction term 9.159 (7.840)

8.819** (3.601)

27.519 (30.250)

-4.262 (4.145)

N 69 69 66 66

Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown). The !! values are not shown since they do not have any clear statistical meaning when using the 2SLS method.

4.3 Why is there no resource curse between 1990 and 2010?

We have seen in the main results there is no resource curse to be found between 1980

and 2000 or 1990 and 2010. Focusing on the last time period this lack of relationship

is also evident in Figure 3 that shows graphs with growth and ores and metal exports

for the time periods 1970-1990 and 1990-2010. The fitted line in the graph to the left

slopes downwards, indicating the curse, while the fitted line in the graph to the right

is horizontal, indicating no relationship between ores and metals exports and growth.

Why is there a negative relationship between growth and ores and meals exports in

1970 to 1990 but not in 1990-2010? To see if there have been any drastic changes in

the data between these two time periods descriptive statistics for several variables in

the two time periods are shown in Table 3. There are some differences between the

time periods that can be the reason for the disappearance of the resource curse in the

later time period. Four of these will be more closely examined and, if possible, tested.

Page 18: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

18

Figure 3: Graphs showing ores and metals exports and growth

Firstly, looking at the variables growth and ores and metals exports we can see that

the minimum growth was much lower between 1970 and 1990 than between 1990

and 2010 and the maximum value of exports was much higher in 1970 than 1990.

What implications this can have will be discussed in section 6.

Secondly, focusing on the variable institutional quality we can see that the minimum

value of the ICRG index is larger in 1990 than 19709. The fact that the institutions in

the world have become better can be one reason for the disappearance of the resource

curse. But since the institutional measure was instrumented for in the previous

section we can conclude that better institutions are not the reason for the lack of the

resource curse in 1990-2010.

Thirdly, moving on to the variable initial GDP level we can see that the world in

general has become richer. Both the mean and the minimum value have become

higher since 1970. The results from running a regression for the time period between

1990 and 2010 but with the initial GDP level from 1970 instead of 1990 can be found

in column 1 in Table 4. We can see the there is still no resource curse present in the

time period and we can conclude that the fact that the world has become richer has

not played a crucial role in the disappearance of the resource curse.

9 The actual year is 1984 but to make it logical and easy to follow in the text the year is written as 1970.

Page 19: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

19

Fourthly, examine the variable average investment we see that the minimum value is

larger for the later time period. Highly appropriable resources like ores and metals

are dependent on investments and if the investments have become higher in the last

20 years this could be the reason for the absence of the curse. Running a regression

with the average investment from 1970 to 1990 instead of 1990-2010 tested this

hypothesis. The results are presented in column 2 in Table 4. Looking at the results

we see that average investment has not played a role in the disappearance of the

resource curse.

Finally there are some countries that only appear in the regression from 1990 to

2010.10 To see if there countries are the reason for the absence of the curse we run a

regression for the time period 1990-2010 and excluding these countries. The results

are presented in column 3 in Table 4 and we can see that there is no resource curse

present even if the countries listed are excluded.

Table 3: Descriptive statistics

Variable Time period Mean Standard deviation

Minimum value

Maximum value

Observations

Growth 1970-1990 1990-2010

1.025 1.909

1.905 1.198

-3.751 -0.230

6.417 6.494

69 66

Ores and metals exports

1970 1990

0.128 0.081

0.209 0.141

0.000 0.000

0.983 0.582

69 66

Institutional quality 1970 1990

0.568 0.606

0.288 0.262

0.087 0.111

1.000 1.000

69 66

Initial GDP level 1970 1990

9.104 13.575

9.547 11.211

0.600 1.335

56.581 48.285

69 66

Average openness 1970-1990 1990-2010

3.957 4.233

0.595 0.530

2.466 3.056

5.773 5.899

69 66

Average investments 1970-1990 1990-2010

23.341 24.332

8.669 6.816

2.358 11.042

49.102 50.811

69 66

10 The countries are China, Kuwait, Malta, Oman, Papua New Guinea, Poland, Saudi Arabia and Suriname.

Page 20: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

20

Table 4: Results testing why there is no curse between 1990 and 2010

(1) (2) (3)

Ores and metals exports 0.016 (0.020)

0.021 (0.020)

1.402 (1.972)

Institutional quality 2.134** (0.952)

2.678** (1.058)

2.943** (1.111)

Interaction term -0.029 (0.043)

-0.048 (0.042)

-0.448 (4.088)

N

!!

64 0.3104

64 0.3370

58 0.3102

Notes: Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown). All regressions are for the time period 1990-2010. Kuwait and Saudi Arabia are excluded from the regressions in column 1 and 2 due to missing data.

5 Robustness

The analysis of the main result shows that as a whole the theory about the resource

curse holds for ores and metals exports for earlier years but not in the later time

periods. When using the OLS method to estimate the equation some assumptions

have to be fulfilled. For example the data should not include observations with

extreme values or have omitted variables that explain the dependent variable. This

section tests if the data used are sensitive to these assumptions being fulfilled. If the

results do not change when for example excluding outliers or including new variables

we can conclude that the results are robust. If the results are robust they are more

reliable for further analysis and can be generalized to other time periods or to be

generalized for all the countries in the world and not only the ones included in the

regressions. This section largely follows that of Boschini et al (2007).

5.1 Excluding outliers

Excluding very influential observations, so called outliers, is a method that can be

used to make sure the observed results are true and not only dependent on a few

unusually influential observations. One way to detect outliers is to calculate the

DFITS index. An observation is normally counted as an outlier if the absolute value of

Page 21: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

21

the DFITS index is larger than 2 !/! where ! is the number of variables, including

the intercept, and ! is the number of observations in the regression. Table 6 in

Appendix presents the results when running the regressions without outliers.11 In

general the results follow that of the main results. Ores and metals exports and the

interaction term are as in the main results significant for 1970-1990 but not for 1990-

2010. For the last time period institutional quality is, as in the main results,

significant. The results seem to be robust when excluding outliers.

5.2 Excluding or including variables

The estimated coefficients in front of variables in a regression can alter if different

variables are excluded or included from the model. Table 7 and 8 in Appendix

presents results when initial GDP, average openness and average investment are

excluded from the model in different combinations. Ores and metals exports and the

interaction term are significant for 1970-1990 but not 1990-2010 and institutional

quality is significant for some of the regressions in both time periods. It seems that

the results are not very sensitive to excluding variables.

Collier and Hoeffler (2002) and Boschini et al (2007) suggest that if a country has

been in a conflict or civil war it can have had an effect on economic growth. The

results when including dummy variables for war or civil war are presented in Table 9

in Appendix. We can see that none of the variables are significantly effecting growth

in either time period. The estimates for ores and metals exports, the interaction term

and institutional quality are close to those in the main results and we can conclude

that the results are not sensitive to adding the variables war or civil war.

5.3 Excluding regions

In the main results countries from the whole world is included but to see if the

resource curse is general for the whole world or just a phenomenon located at some

11 The countries counted as outliers in 1970-1990 are Bolivia, Brunei, Egypt, Iran, South Korea, Nicaragua and Turkey and the countries counted as outliers in 1990-2010 are Brunei, Chile, China, Japan, Kuwait, Papua New Guinea, Suriname and Trinidad and Tobago.

Page 22: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

22

specific region regressions have been run excluding Africa, the Middle East, Latin

America and Asia respectively. The results are presented in Table 10 and 11 in

Appendix. Ores and metals exports are not significant in either time period when

Africa is excluded and but significant in both time periods when Latin America is

excluded. Excluding the Middle East or Asia does not seem to have any effect on the

main results. These results indicate that much of the curse is located in Africa.

5.4 Excluding rich or poor countries

As with excluding different regions it can be interesting to see if the resource curse is

mostly a problem for rich or poor countries. By excluding the richest or poorest 25 %

of the countries we can see if the rich countries or the poor countries are the ones

mostly cursed. Results can be found in Table 12 in Appendix. When excluding the

poorest 25 % of the sample ores and metals exports and the interaction term are not

significant in any time period but when excluding the richest 25 % of the sample ores

and metals exports and the interaction term are significant in all periods. The

interaction term is significant for both time periods when the rich countries are

excluded but not significant in either time period when the poor countries are

excluded. We can from this conclude that much of the resource curse originates from

the poor countries.

6 Discussion

The results from this study are to large extent in line with earlier studies. As in the

studies of Boschini et al (2007 and 2013) highly appropriable resources do cause a

resource curse while other resources do not. In contrast with these studies the

coefficients in this paper are smaller. This could be because the variables used are not

exactly the same.

Another difference in the results is that when instrumenting for institutional quality

the results in Boschini et al (2007 and 2013) are close to the OLS estimates while the

results in this study are not close to those obtained with the OLS method. The results

from this study are more in line with the results of Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian

(2003). The reason for the difference in results can be because Boschini et al (2007

Page 23: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

23

and 2013) did not include the resource abundance proxy in the first stage regression

when instrumenting for institutional quality while the proxy is included in the first

stage regression in the study of Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian (2003) and this

study.

In this study no resource curse could be detected in the regression using fuel exports

as a proxy for natural resources even if it is counted as a resource with quite high

technical appropriability (Boschini et al 2007 and Figure 2). In Boschini et al (2013)

fuel exports are significant for some time periods but not others. The alteration in

variables used as natural resource proxies for fuel can be the reason for this

difference in results.

While this study has answered some questions it has been the source of new

questions as well. A finding that is consistent throughout the study is that no resource

curse can be detected for the time period between 1990 and 2010. The tests complete

in section 4.3 rejects this lack of significance to be the consequence of better

institutions, higher initial GDP levels, larger average investments or the different

countries included in the regressions. It can be seen in Table 3 that both resource

abundance and growth in the world are less spread in 1990-2010 than 1970-1990 and

this lack of variation in the variables could be the reason for the absence of the curse.

The lowest growth rates in 1990-2010 are higher than that in 1970-1990 and the most

resource abundant country was not as resource abundant in 1990 as in 1970. This

means that there are no real resource losers left in the world. In the countries

included in this study the countries with the lowest growth in combination with high

exports of ores and metals between 1970 and 1990 were Zambia and Liberia with

growth rates of -3.1 % and -3.8 % and ores and metals exports of 98 % and 75 %

respectively. In 1990-2010 the countries were Bolivia and Papua New Guinea with

both having growth rates of 1.4 % and ores and metals exports of 46 % and 58 %

respectively. What is the reason for the disappearance of the resources losers? Why

are the growth rates higher now than 20 years ago? What happened to the countries

that almost exclusively exported natural resources? These are some of the questions

still to be answered.

One thing that could be done differently in future research is that net exports could

be used instead of exports as the natural resource proxy, as argued in Pineda and

Page 24: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

24

Rodríguez (2010) and Lederman and Maloney (2008). The values used in this study

could be misleading and not really show the resource abundance within a country but

rather the amount of resources handled at the ports of a country.

One other thing that could be done differently is that the same countries should be

used in all the regressions. This to make sure that the difference in results between

time periods or types of resources is not dependent on what countries are included in

the regressions. To be able to keep as many observations as possible this was not

done but as data for more countries gets available with time this might not be a

problem in the future.

7 Conclusion

The results from this study can be summarized in the following statements:

• Indications of a resource curse can be detected in 1970-2010, 1970-2000, 1970-

1990 and 1980-2010 when using ores and metals exports as an approximation of

natural resource abundance.

• No relationship between natural resources and growth can be found when

approximating natural resources with total, food or fuel exports.

• A positive relationship can be detected when using agricultural exports as a proxy.

Agricultural exports thus seem to bring a resource blessing rather than a resource

curse.

• In all regressions where the proxy for natural resources is significant the curse, or

blessing, can be reversed with good enough institutions.

• The results seem to be similar to those of Sala-i-martin and Subramanian (2003)

when instrumenting for institutional quality and the interaction term with latitude,

the interaction between the natural resource proxy and latitude and the fraction of

people in a country speaking a western European language. Resource abundance

appears to influence institutions negatively and that in turn will influence growth

negatively. Natural resources do not seem to have a direct negative effect on

growth.

• The lack of resource curse in 1990-2010 does not appear to be caused by the fact

that the lowest level of institutional quality has become higher, that the world has

Page 25: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

25

become richer, that the average investment has become higher or that some

countries only appear in the regressions for the time period 1990-2010.

• The results seem robust when exclude outliers and include or exclude different

variables.

• When excluding Africa or the poorest countries the resource curse disappears

indicating that much of the curse is located in Africa and the poorest countries in

the world.

The main questions to be answered in this study were: do resource abundant

countries, depending on the level of appropriability of the resources, suffer from

slower economic growth than resource scarce countries? If they do, can the curse be

reversed via good institutions quality? The answers found in the results of this study

are that resource abundant countries do suffer from slower economic growth than

resource scares countries in the earlier time periods studied but not in the later time

periods. This negative effect can only be detected if the resources are highly

appropriable and will only effect countries with low institutional quality. If the

institutions are good enough we can conclude that countries will benefit from their

resources.

Page 26: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

26

References

Boschini, A. D., Pettersson, J. and Roine, J. (2007). “Resource Curse or Not: A

Question of Appropriability”, The Scandinavian Journal of Economics

109(3): 593– 617.

Boschini, A. D., Pettersson, J. and Roine, J. (2013). “The resource curse and its

potential reversal”, World Development, 43: 19–41.

CIA (2013) - The World Factbook. Avaliable at: https://www.cia.gov/library/

publications/the-world-factbook/index.html (Accessed June 7, 2013).

Collier, P. and Hoeffler, A. (2002). “On the Incidence of Civil War in Africa”, Journal

of Conflict Resolution, 46(1): 13–28.

Themnér, L. and Wallensteen, P. (2012). ”UCDP/PRIO Armed Conflict Dataset”,

version 4-2012. Available at: http://www.prio.no/Data/Armed-

Conflict/UCDP-PRIO/Armed-Conflicts-Version-X-2009/ (Accessed

June 7, 2013).

Heston, A., Summers, R. and Aten, B. (2012). Penn World Table Version 7.1, Center

for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the

University of Pennsylvania. Available at: https://pwt.sas.upenn.edu/

php_site/pwt71/pwt71_form_test.php (Accessed June 7, 2013).

Isham, J., Woolcock, M., Pritchett, l. and Busby, G. (2005) “The varieties of resource

experience: Natural resource export structures and the political economy

of economic growth”, The World Bank Economic Review 19(2): 141–174.

Lederman, D. and Maloney, W. F. (2008). “In search of the Missing Resource Curse”,

Policy Research Working Paper 4766. Available at:

https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/6901/

WPS4766.pdf?sequence=1 (Accessed June 7, 2013).

Lewis, P. M., Simons, G. F., and Fennig, C. D. (2013). “Ethnologue: Languages of the

World”, Seventeenth edition, Dallas, Texas: SIL International. Available

at: http://www.ethnologue.com (Accessed June 7, 2013).

Page 27: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

27

Mehlum, H., Moene, K. and Torvik, R. (2006). “Institutions and the Resource Curse”,

The Economic Journal 116(508): 1–20.

Pineda, J. and Rodríguez, F. (2010). “Curse Or Blessing? Natural Resources and

Human Development”, United Nations Development Programme, New

York. Available at: http://hdr.undp.org/es/informes/mundial/idh2010/

trabajos/HDRP_2010_04.pdf (Accessed June 7, 2013).

Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (1995). “Natural resource abundance and economic

growth”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 5398.

Available at: http://www.nber.org/papers/w5398 (Accessed June 7,

2013).

Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (1999). “The big push, natural resource booms and

growth”, Journal of development economics 59(1): 43–76.

Sachs, J. D. and Warner, A. M. (2001). “The curse of natural resources”, European

economic review 45(4): 827–838.

Sala-i-Martin, X. and Subramanian, A. (2003). “Addressing the natural resource

curse: An illustration from Nigeria”, National Bureau of Economic

Research Working Paper 9804. Available at: http://www.nber.org/

papers/w9804 (Accessed June 7, 2013).

Teorell, J., Samanni, M., Holmberg, S. and Rothstein, B. (2011a). “The QoG

Codebook”, Version 6Apr11. University of Gothenburg: The Quality of

Government Institute. Available at: http://www.qog.pol.gu.se/data/

datadownloads/qogstandarddata/ (Accessed June 7, 2013).

Teorell, J., Samanni, M., Holmberg, S. and Rothstein, B. (2011b). “The QoG Standard

Dataset”, Version 6Apr11. University of Gothenburg: The Quality of

Government Institute. Available at: http://www.qog.pol.gu.se/data/

datadownloads/qogstandarddata/ (Accessed June 7, 2013).

The World Bank (2013) - World Development Indicators Online Database. Available

at: http://databank.worldbank.org/data/views/variableselection/

selectvariables.aspx?source=world-development-indicators (Accessed

June 7, 2013).

Page 28: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

28

Appendix

Table 5: First stage regressions

1970-1990 (1)

1990-2010 (2)

1970-1990 (3)

1990-2010 (4)

Latitude 0.490** (0.225)

0.441*** (0.136)

-0.107** (0.041)

-0.062 (0.038)

Interaction between latitude and ores and metals exports

-2.645** (1.294)

-1.476** (0.597)

1.321*** (0.170)

0.510 (0.371)

Fraction speaking European language 0.073 (0.048)

0.120*** (0.040)

0.002 (0.007)

-0.011 (0.009)

N !!

69 0.8033

66 0.8357

69 0.9097

66 0.9055

Notes: Dependent variable in column 1 and 2 is institutional quality and the dependent variable in column 3 and 4 is the interaction between ores and metals exports and institutional quality. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant, ores and metals exports and control variables listed in the text (not shown).

Table 6: Results without outliers

1970-1990 1990-2010

Ores and metals exports -6.529*** (1.126)

2.060 (2.029)

Institutional quality 1.313 (0.906)

1.933* (1.011)

Interaction term 11.887*** (2.272)

-3.619 (3.600)

N

!!

62 0.7677

58 0.3938

Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown).

Page 29: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

29

Table 7: Results when excluding different variables, 1970-1990

Ores and metals exports

-5.605*** (1.889)

-4.612** (1.767)

-5.810*** (1.951)

-5.320*** (1.883)

-5.028*** (1.900)

-5.413*** (1.941)

Institutional quality

-0.384 (1.047)

1.875** (0.909)

-0.510 (1.009)

-0.542 (1.045)

1.718* (0.884)

-0.585 (1.007)

Interaction term

11.037*** (3.818)

8.026** (3.402)

11.422*** (3.871)

10.363*** (3.650)

8.738** (3.639)

10.544*** (3.680)

Initial GDP level

-0.104*** (0.013)

-0.110*** (0.013)

Average Openness

0.167 (0.274)

0.387* (0.209)

0.066 (0.303)

Average Investment

0.029 (0.027)

0.028 (0.030)

N

!!

69 0.4942

69 0.6159

69 0.4967

69 0.5085

69 0.6291

69 0.5089

Notes: Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include control variables for Africa, The Middle East, Latin America and Asia (not shown).

Table 8: Results when excluding different variables, 1990-2010

Ores and metals exports

1.076 (2.056)

1.332 (1.944)

-1.161 (2.111)

1.297 (1.878)

1.544 (2.089)

1.317 (1.899)

Institutional quality

-0.006 (1.089)

2.235* (1.250)

0.021 (1.077)

-0.140 (1.081)

2.452* (1.228)

-0.125 (1.098)

Interaction term

-1.772 (4.208)

-3.541 (3.979)

-1.992 (4.340)

-2.232 (3.914)

-4.165 (4.237)

-2.287 (3.960)

Initial GDP level

-0.072*** (0.026)

-0.077*** (0.027)

Average Openness

0.137 (0.288)

0.311 (0.248)

0.047 (0.347)

Average Investment

0.025 (0.032)

0.024 (0.036)

N !!

66 0.1150

66 0.2540

66 0.1185

66 0.1328

66 0.2716

66 0.1332

Notes: Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include control variables for Africa, The Middle East, Latin America and Asia (not shown).

Page 30: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

30

Table 9: Results when including variables for war or civil war

1970-1990 1970-1990 1990-2010 1990-2010

Ores and metals exports -5.357*** (1.861)

-6.028*** (1.848)

1.836 (2.094)

1.452 (2.271)

Institutional quality 1.599 (0.964)

1.176 (0.991)

2.433* (1.330)

2.219 (1.327)

Interaction term 9.442*** (3.540)

11.050*** (3.471)

-4.648 (4.346)

-3.997 (4.432)

War -0.209 (0.382)

0.121 (0.446)

Civil War -0.695 (0.482)

-0.152 (0.496)

N

!!

69 0.6309

69 0.6473

66 0.2768

66 0.2774

Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown).

Table 10: Results when excluding different regions, 1970-1990

Excluding Africa

Excluding Middle East

Excluding Latin America

Excluding Asia

Ores and metals exports -2.899 (1.764)

-5.258*** (1.939)

-6.666*** (1.590)

-5.007** (1.922)

Institutional quality 1.963* (1.074)

0.977 (0.878)

2.454** (1.218)

1.953* (1.144)

Interaction term 5.313* (2.875)

9.194** (3.699)

11.319*** (3.706)

9.128** (3.644)

N !!

55 0.6459

64 0.6479

51 0.6997

59 0.5138

Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown).

Page 31: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

31

Table 11: Results when excluding different regions, 1990-2010

Excluding Africa

Excluding the Middle East

Excluding Latin America

Excluding Asia

Ores and metals exports 1.587 (2.055)

2.341 (2.031)

-15.320*** (4.336)

1.336 (2.613)

Institutional quality 2.328* (1.187)

2.972** (1.194)

1.052 (1.294)

1.417 (1.223)

Interaction term -4.325 (4.045)

-4.650 (5.735)

19.323*** (6.309)

-0.515 (5.214)

N !!

62 0.2883

59 0.3362

46 0.5380

54 0.1265

Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown).

Table 12: Results when excluding rich or poor countries

1970-1990 (1)

1990-2010 (2)

1970-1990 (3)

1990-2010 (4)

Ores and metals exports -4.919** (2.160)

3.754* (2.032)

-2.762 (1.913)

1.374 (2.854)

Institutional quality 2.558* (1.379)

3.169** (1.436)

1.981 (1.278)

1.146 (1.175)

Interaction term 8.187* (4.616)

8.452* (4.738)

5.113 (3.088)

-0.892 (5.404)

N

!!

52 0.6252

50 0.3298

52 0.6002

50 0.3516

Note: Notes: Dependent variable is Growth. Robust standard errors in parenthesis. * significant at 10 % level, ** significant at 5 % level and *** significant at 1 % level. All regressions include a constant and control variables listed in the text (not shown). Regressions in column 1 and 2 exclude rich countries and regressions in column 3 and 4 exclude poor countries.

Page 32: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

32

Table 13: Countries included in the study

Algeria Angola Argentina Australia Austria Bahrain Bangladesh Belgium Bolivia Brazil Brunei Cameroon Canada Chile China Colombia Costa Rica Denmark Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt El Salvador Finland France Gabon Ghana Greece Guatemala Guyana

Haiti Honduras Hungary Iceland India Indonesia Iran Ireland Israel Italy Ivory Coast Jamaica Japan Jordan Kenya Kuwait Liberia Malawi Malaysia Malta Mexico Morocco Netherlands New Zealand Nicaragua Nigeria Norway Oman Pakistan

Panama Papua New Guinea Paraguay Peru Philippines Poland Portugal Saudi Arabia Senegal Singapore South Africa South Korea Spain Sri Lanka Sudan Suriname Sweden Switzerland Syria Thailand Togo Trinidad & Tobago Tunisia Turkey United Kingdom United States Uruguay Venezuela Zambia

Note: All countries are not included in all regressions due to limited data availability.

Page 33: The Natural Resource Cure - DiVA portal

33

Table 14: Sources and definitions of variables

Variable Source and definition

Growth Source: Heston et al (2012). Growth is the average yearly growth rate of GDP in percent calculated as (ln  (!"#!/!"#!)/!)×100 where !"#! is the GDP level at the end year and !"#! is the GDP level at the start year. The variable is originally called rgdpch and is the PPP adjusted GDP per capita at 2005 constant prices.

Total exports Source: The World Bank (2013). Total exports are measured at the start year and is calculated as the sum of agricultural, food, fuel and ores and metals exports.

Agricultural exports Source: The World Bank (2013). Agricultural raw material exports are measured at the start year and include Standard International Trade Classification (SITC) section 2 excluding divisions 22, 27 and 28.

Food exports Source: The World Bank (2013). Food exports are measured at the start year and include SITC section 0, 1, 4 and division 22.

Fuel exports Source: The World Bank (2013). Fuels exports are measured at the start year and include SITC section 3.

Ores and metals exports Source: The World Bank (2013). Ores and metals exports are measured at the start year and include SITC division 27, 28 and 68.

Institutions Source: Teorell et al (2011b). The ICRG index includes measures on quality of the bureaucracy, corruption in government and rule of law.

Initial GDP level Source: Heston et al (2012). The variable is originally called rgdpch and is the PPP adjusted GDP per capita at 2005 constant prices. GDP is measured at the start year. Measured in thousands.

Average openness Source: Heston et al (2012). The variable openness is the sum of imports and exports as share of GDP and is originally called openc. Average openness is then calculated as the sum of openness from the start year to the end year divided by the number of years in the period.

Average investment Source: Heston et al (2012). Investment is the share investment to GDP and is originally called ki. Average investment is then calculated as the sum of investment from the start year to the end year divided by the number of years in the period.

Regions Source: CIA (2013). Regions used are Africa, the Middle East, Latin America and Asia. Dummy variables are used; they take the value 1 if a country is located in the region and 0 otherwise.

Latitude Source: CIA (2013). The absolute value of latitude converged to a 0-1 scale.

Fraction of people speaking a western European language

Source: Lewis et al (2013). The fraction of people in a country that speaks English, German, French, Spanish or Portuguese as first language.

War Source: Themnér and Wallensteen 2012. A country is said to be at war a specific year if there has been at lest 25 battle-related deaths during that year.

Civil War Source: Themnér and Wallensteen 2012. A country is said to be in a civil war a specific year if there has been at lest 25 battle-related deaths during that year and if the parts fighting belong to the same country.