the political business cycle and trade policy formation ... · the political business cycle and...

85
e College of Wooster Libraries Open Works Senior Independent Study eses 2015 e Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? Lincoln Plews e College of Wooster, [email protected] Follow this and additional works at: hp://openworks.wooster.edu/independentstudy is Senior Independent Study esis is brought to you by Open Works, a service of e College of Wooster Libraries. It has been accepted for inclusion in Senior Independent Study eses by an authorized administrator of Open Works. For more information, please contact [email protected]. © Copyright 2015 Lincoln Plews Recommended Citation Plews, Lincoln, "e Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy?" (2015). Senior Independent Study eses. Paper 6671. hp://openworks.wooster.edu/independentstudy/6671

Upload: danghanh

Post on 02-Apr-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

The College of Wooster LibrariesOpen Works

Senior Independent Study Theses

2015

The Political Business Cycle and Trade PolicyFormation: How Do Electoral Incentives ImpactTrade Policy?Lincoln PlewsThe College of Wooster, [email protected]

Follow this and additional works at: http://openworks.wooster.edu/independentstudy

This Senior Independent Study Thesis is brought to you by Open Works, a service of The College of Wooster Libraries. It has been accepted forinclusion in Senior Independent Study Theses by an authorized administrator of Open Works. For more information, please [email protected].

© Copyright 2015 Lincoln Plews

Recommended CitationPlews, Lincoln, "The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy?" (2015).Senior Independent Study Theses. Paper 6671.http://openworks.wooster.edu/independentstudy/6671

Page 2: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives

Impact Trade Policy?

By

Lincoln Plews

Submitted in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements of Senior

Independent Study for the Program in International Relations at The

College of Wooster

Advised by

Dr. Amyaz A. Moledina

Department of Economics

March 23, 2015

Page 3: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

i

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank my parents, George and Christine Plews, and my brothers,

Arthur, Matthew, and Noah for their unending love and support. I extend a special word

of thanks to my advisor, Dr. Amyaz A. Moledina, for his belief in my ideas, his drive to

make me reach higher, and his guidance throughout this entire process. Simon Doong

toiled through with me every step of the way, and gave valuable insight and comments.

Finally, I would like to thank Dr. Matthew Krain, who inspired my interest in political

economy and helped me formulate the idea for the topic of this Independent Study.

Page 4: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

ii

Abstract

In this paper, I adopt the framework of the political business cycle to derive a

model of politician decision making with regard to international trade policy. To test my

model, I estimate a probit regression using a unique data set of 18 U.S. Senate votes on

trade liberalization from 1993-2011. My regression measures the impact of impending

reelection on an incumbent politician’s trade policy choice, controlling for the capital-

labor distribution and employment make-up of the politician’s constituency, as well as

the politician's personal ideology. I find empirical support for my hypothesis that, all else

equal, a politician within two years of an election is less likely to vote in favor of trade

liberalization.

在本文中,我采用了政治经济周期的框架,以获得关于国际贸易政策的政治

家决策模型。为了测试我的模型,我用概率回归分析了一个包含从1993年至2011年

间,十八次美国参议院就贸易自由化的表决的独特数据集。我的概率回归测试了以

下几个方面:即将到来的再次选举对于现任政治家的贸易政策选择的影响,对于控

制资本劳动分配和选区内就业组成的影响,以及对于政治家个人的意识形态的影

响。我发现了实验证据来证明我这个假设:在一切平等的情况下,一位在两年内即

将参与再选举的政治家不太可能就贸易自由化投赞成票。

Page 5: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

iii

Table of Contents

1. Introduction .............................................................................................................................. 1

2. Theoretical Framework ............................................................................................................ 4

2.1 Introduction ...................................................................................................................... 4

2.2 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model of Trade ............................................................................. 5

2.3 Stolper-Samuelson ........................................................................................................... 7

2.4 The Impact of Trade ......................................................................................................... 9

2.5 Median Voter Theorem .................................................................................................. 11

2.6 Collective Action ........................................................................................................... 14

2.7 Political Science Models of Political Influence ............................................................. 16

2.7.1 The Alignment of Special Interest Groups and Voters .......................................... 16

2.7.2 The Impact of Interpretation .................................................................................. 17

2.8 Voting Costs and Mayer’s Endogenous Tariff Formation .............................................. 17

2.9 The Political Business Cycle: Modeling the Politician’s Decision ................................ 20

2.10 Conclusion ..................................................................................................................... 28

3. Review of Empirical Literature.............................................................................................. 28

3.1 Introduction .................................................................................................................... 28

3.2 Conconi et al. (2014) ...................................................................................................... 29

3.3 Dutt and Mitra (2002) .................................................................................................... 35

3.4 Goldberg and Maggi (1999) ........................................................................................... 38

3.5 Baldwin and Magee (2000) ............................................................................................ 41

3.6 Beaulieu (2002) .............................................................................................................. 44

3.7 Alesina, Cohen, and Roubini (1993) .............................................................................. 47

3.8 Conclusion ..................................................................................................................... 49

4. Methodology and Data ........................................................................................................... 50

4.1 Hypothesis ..................................................................................................................... 50

4.2 Empirical Model ............................................................................................................ 51

4.3 Data ................................................................................................................................ 54

5. Results .................................................................................................................................... 57

6. Conclusion ............................................................................................................................. 65

Page 6: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

iv

6.1 Literature Review Organizational Table ........................................................................ 67

7. Appendix ................................................................................................................................... I

8. Bibliography ........................................................................................................................... VI

Page 7: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

1

1. Introduction

The potential impact of an impending election on public policy formation is

intuitive. As an incumbent politician approaches reelection, campaign advertisements

and rhetoric highlight his recent accomplishments and policies. Although many

economic theories, such as the Heckscher-Ohlin model discussed in section 2.5 of this

paper, show that free trade leads to growth in the long run due to the exploitation of

comparative advantage, empirical research has shown that trade policies are nearly

everywhere biased against trade (Dutt & Mitra, 2002). This finding suggests that

protectionist trade policies may be politically popular, given that they survive despite

their ill-effects. It stands to reason, then, that trade policy formation may be impacted by

electoral incentives. In other words, a pro-trade politician may alter his position on free

trade near reelection to appeal to protectionist voters. I hypothesize that a politician will

vote in favor of the economically beneficial free trade when not faced with immediate

reelection, but will vote for more politically popular protectionist policies when nearing

an election, to maximize the number of votes gained and thereby his chances of

reelection.

From the firestorm surrounding NAFTA to the current debate over the Trans

Pacific Partnership (TPP), trade policy has always been a hotly divisive issue in

American politics. There is a massive campaign underway to garner support for the TPP,

but proponents are facing an uphill battle against those who say it will lead to more jobs

shipped overseas, reductions in environmental and labor standards, and a general

deterioration of the U.S.’s economic welfare (Davis, 2015). This political opposition

Page 8: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

2

coincides with public opinion on free trade. In October of 2010, 44% of Americans said

that free trade agreements such as NAFTA have harmed the U.S. economy, while only

33% believed that they were beneficial. In total contrast to this division, economists

almost unanimously agree on the benefits of free trade. In 2006, a survey of a random

sample of 210 Ph.D. economists from the American Economic Association found that

87.5% of these economists believed that it would benefit the U.S. to eliminate tariffs and

other barriers to trade (Whaples, 2006, p. 1). Given this huge division between economic

thought and political reality, it is clear that politicians are not merely considering the

economic benefits of free trade agreements, but also the potential electoral impacts of

such agreements. If your constituency does not want free trade (regardless of whether it

would be beneficial or not), then a politician is unlikely to vote in favor of trade

liberalization, especially if the vote occurs during the enhanced scrutiny of an election

cycle. In fact, public opinion surveys have shown that “swing” voters (undecided voters

who often provide the crucial turning vote in an election) more frequently favor

protectionism (Molyneux, 1994, p. 30).

My hypothesis, therefore, centers on the idea that electoral incentives drive the

gap between economic reality and political will when it comes to trade policy. Since the

health of the economy is consistently the most salient issue for the majority of voters, a

politician considering a free trade bill must balance the positive economic impacts of free

trade with the negative electoral impacts (Drazen, 2000, p. 82). I hypothesize that this

balance is struck by voting in favor of free trade when not faced with immediate

reelection (thereby encouraging healthy economic growth), and voting for the

economically harmful but crowd-pleasing protectionism when faced with the increased

Page 9: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

3

scrutiny of impending reelection. I test this hypothesis by building a theoretical model

based on the political business cycle work of Nordhaus (1975) and Drazen (2000), then

empirically testing this model by analyzing the voting patterns of U.S. Senators on 18

trade liberalization bills from 1993 to 2011.

Through my data analysis in chapter 4, I find that sitting U.S. Senators are less

likely to vote for a trade liberalization bill when the vote falls within two years of an

election. This result holds even when controlling for the make-up of Senators’

constituencies and their individual ideologies. This is consistent with the findings of

Conconi et al. (2014), who have published the only article currently available on the

connection between election proximity and trade policy. They find that Senators (who

have longer terms than House members) are generally less protectionist than their House

counterparts. However, in the final two years of their terms, Senators become less likely

to vote for trade liberalization and become just as protectionist as House members

(Conconi, Facchini, & Zanardi, 2014, p. 102).

In the next chapter, I will start by constructing a theoretical model, beginning on

the intermediate level with the welfare implications of free trade in the Hecksher-Ohlin

model and finishing with a modification of the political business cycle model of

Nordhaus (1975) and Drazen (2000) to account for the changes in a politician’s behavior

over the course of an elected term.

Page 10: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

4

2. Theoretical Framework

2.1 Introduction

The Hecksher-Ohlin (H-O) model of trade implies that a country should

specialize and export the good that uses its abundant factor intensively. This results in

gains from trade for all, but owners of the abundant factor will benefit relatively more

than the scarce factor. For example, the majority of voters in capital-abundant countries

(assuming that this capital-abundance also means that the majority of voters are capital

owners) should prefer trade liberalization, as it increases the relative returns to owners of

factors of production that are used in the exported capital-intensive good. However, as

pointed out by Dutt and Mitra (2002), empirical research has shown that trade policies

are nearly everywhere biased against trade (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 108).

Building upon the H-O, median voter, and political business cycle theorems, I

intend to construct a model of political decision making which accounts for the impact of

political time horizon1 and constituency factor endowment on politician trade policy

preferences. In this case, I am referring to “trade policy preferences” as a politician or

voter’s preference toward trade liberalization or protectionism. I hypothesize that, as a

politician approaches reelection, she2 will favor more protectionist policies (regardless of

the economic impact of such policies on her constituency), because the politician’s utility

is based on maximizing the number of votes and such policies are favored by voters in

her constituency who have a stronger incentive to vote based mainly on their trade policy

preferences. However, since these voters have a short memory regarding the politician’s

1 “Political time horizon” refers to the amount of time before an incumbent politician will face reelection.

2 For simplicity, an individual politician will herein be referred to using the pronoun “she”.

Page 11: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

5

past trade policy decisions, the politician will vote for the policy that is most

economically beneficial to her broader constituency when not faced with immediate

reelection. So, in sum, voter’s decisions are affected by two things: the health of the

overall economy and the health of their individual sector of employment. The impact of

trade policy on the health of the overall economy depends on the factor endowment of the

entire constituency. The impact of trade policy on individual sector of employment

depends on the factor of production used intensively in that sector. Those whose sector

of employment is greatly impacted by trade policy stand to benefit more from voting than

those who are not intensely affected. Therefore, in order to capture the votes of both the

trade-sensitive and the non-trade-sensitive, the politician will vote for the most

economically beneficial trade policy for all when not faced with imminent reelection, and

will vote for the preferred trade policy of the trade-sensitive when nearing reelection.

2.2 The Heckscher-Ohlin Model of Trade

This theoretical explanation of the actions that a politician will take regarding

trade policy as reelection approaches begins with an analysis of the Heckscher-Ohlin

model of international trade. The basic premise of the H-O model is that trade between

two countries will be based on the relative abundance of factors of production within

those countries, as well as the relative intensity with which the traded goods use these

factors of production (Krugman, Obstfeld, & Melitz, 2012, p. 84). To demonstrate this,

we will examine a two good (shoes and cars), two factor of production (capital and

labor), and two country (Home and Foreign) model. We will assume that 1) factors of

production are mobile between industries, 2) both countries have fixed amounts of labor

and capital to allocate to the production of shoes and cars, 3) Home is relatively capital

Page 12: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

6

abundant and Foreign is relatively labor abundant, 4) the production of shoes is labor

intensive and the production of cars is capital intensive, 5) each country will produce the

combination of goods that yields the maximum total value, which is dependent on the

relative prices of the goods.

The production of shoes (QS) is a function of the inputs labor (LS) and capital

(KS), formally stated: 𝑄𝑠 = 𝑓[𝐾𝑠, 𝐿𝑆]. The same is true of the production of cars: 𝑄𝑐 =

𝑓[𝐾𝑐, 𝐿𝑐]. Since the production of cars is capital intensive, and Home is relatively capital

abundant, its production possibilities frontier will be skewed towards the production of

more cars. This can be seen in Figure 1.1. Likewise, as we can see in Fig. 1.2, the

production possibilities frontier of Foreign is skewed towards the labor intensive good,

shoes.

In both graphs, we see that Home and Foreign produce at quantity Q1, where the

slope of the production possibilities frontier is equal to the slope of the highest possible

isovalue line, a line on which the value of output is constant. This point on both graphs,

Q1, is where the economy maximizes the value of production given the prices it faces

(Krugman et al., 2012, pp. 88–89). We also see (assuming the graphs are scaled

Page 13: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

7

identically) that the value-maximizing combination of shoes and cars is skewed towards

cars in Home and towards shoes in Foreign. Since the H-O model suggests complete

specialization, the value maximizing combinations shown in Figures 1.1-1.2 are those in

a state of autarky. In other words, they are what Home and Foreign would produce in the

absence of trade. This is important to examine because it allows us to then see how a

country’s production changes in the presence of trade.

The difference in the intensity of each factor of production is demonstrated in

Figure 1.3. We see that, at any given wage-rental ratio, shoe production (SP) uses a

higher labor-capital ratio than car production (CP), meaning that shoe production is labor

intensive while car production is capital intensive.

2.3 Stolper-Samuelson

The Stolper-Samuelson theorem explains the impact that a change in the price of

a good will have on the return to the owners of the factor of production that is used

intensively in the making of that good (Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz 2012, 92). For

Page 14: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

8

example, if the price of cars increases, the returns to the owners of the factor of

production that is used intensively in the production of cars (in this case, capital owners)

will also increase. In order to understand how the Stolper-Samuelson theorem comes to

this conclusion, we must first examine how the change in the price of a factor of

production impacts the price of the good that uses that factor of production intensively.

In Figure 1.4, we see that there is a one-to-one relationship between the ratio of

factor prices (w/r) and the relative price of shoes (Ps/Pc). This means that as the relative

price of the labor intensive shoes (Ps/Pc) increases, the relative price of labor (w/r) also

increases. This occurs because, in the state of perfect competition that this model

assumes, the wage rate will equal the marginal product of labor (and, likewise, the rental

rate will equal the marginal product of capital). The marginal product of labor increases

due to the increase in the price of the labor-intensive good, shoes. In other words, as the

price of labor increases, the price of the labor-intensive good must also increase

(Krugman et al., 2012, p. 91). This effect is demonstrated by the SS curve in Figure 1.4.

Page 15: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

9

Now that we have established the relationship between factor price and the price

of the good that uses that factor intensively, we can move on to see how an increase in

the price of a good affects the returns to the owners of the factor of production that is

used intensively in that good. As we can see in Figure 1.5, an increase in the relative

price of a good, (PS/PC)1 to (PS/PC)

2, causes an increase in the wage-rental ratio, (w/r)

1

to (w/r)2, which in turn causes the labor-capital ratio for the production of both goods to

decrease.

2.4 The Impact of Trade

Now that we have shown that a change in the price of a good will impact the

returns to the owners of the factor of production used intensively in the production of that

good, we can examine how trade between countries will impact the prices of goods (and

thereby the returns to the owners of factors of production within the trading countries).

Page 16: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

10

To examine this we will establish a few more assumptions: 1) Home and Foreign have

the same relative demands for shoes and cars, 2) the two countries have the same

technology, meaning that an amount of labor or capital will produce the same output of

shoes or cars in both countries. In other words, the only difference between the two

countries is that Home is relatively capital abundant and Foreign is relatively labor

abundant.

Figure 1.6 illustrates the impact of trade on the price of shoes in Foreign and

Home. Since we have established that Foreign will produce relatively more shoes than

Home, we see that the relative supply of shoes in Foreign (RS) is greater than that in

Home in the absence of trade (RS*). Since the supply of shoes is greater, the price of

shoes in Foreign (PS/PC)1, found where RS intersects RD (which is the demand curve for

both countries because their preferences are the same), is lower than that of Home

(PS/PC)2. When trade occurs, the relative prices of shoes converge to somewhere

Page 17: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

11

between (PS/PC)1 and (PS/PC)

2, in this case (PS/PC)

3. So, in the 2x2x2 model

established here, Foreign will export shoes and import cars, while Home will export cars

and import shoes. This is significant to the overall research question because it

establishes that trade will cause the relative price of shoes to decline in Home and the

relative price of cars to decline in Foreign, which means that the returns to the owners of

labor in Home and returns to the owners of capital in Foreign will be reduced by trade.

In other words, the owners of the abundant resource benefit from trade, while the owners

of the scarce resources lose (Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz 2012, 96). In the next

section, we will analyze how this decrease in returns impacts voters’ and politicians’

preferences toward free trade bills.

2.5 Median Voter Theorem

Since we have established that trade unevenly benefits owners of certain factors

of production, we can conclude that there will be groups within a country in favor of free

trade and groups opposing free trade. The median voter theorem is a model of political

influence which broadly states that politicians will base their policies on the view of the

median voter in order to maximize the number of votes that they will receive in an

election (Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz 2012, 247). This theorem carries with it several

assumptions: 1) there are two competing political parties in a representative democracy

(Party A and Party B), 2) the only goal of each party is to win the election, 3) policy can

be plotted along a single dimension (e.g. the size of an import tariff), 4) voters differ on

the policy they prefer (Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz 2012, 247). To see the prediction

of the median voter theorem in the case of trade policy, we will apply it to the same

Page 18: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

12

2x2x2 model that we have established in previous sections. Let’s say that there is an

election in Home, and the single issue is a free trade agreement with Foreign.

At present, both Home and Foreign have significant tariffs on imported goods.

Therefore, rather than the state of complete specialization that the H-O model suggests as

optimal, prices are such that both countries produce some combination of shoes and cars.

Both countries, then, have a group interested in trade liberalization (those producing the

export-competing good) and a group interested in protectionism (those producing the

import-competing good). This free trade agreement would reduce these tariffs. As we

have shown in the section on Stolper-Samuelson, the owners of the abundant factor in

Home (capital owners) will benefit from the increase in the relative price of the capital-

intensive good (cars) that would come from the passage of this free trade agreement.

Likewise, the owners of the scarce factor in Home (labor owners) will be against the free

trade agreement, as it would decrease the relative price of the good that uses their labor

intensively and therefore decrease their relative returns.

As we can see in Figure 1.7, if voters are lined up in the order of the tariff size

that they prefer ( represented by the upward sloping “political support” line), the policy

that will draw the most political support is that which is closest to the view of the median

voter. To demonstrate this, we will assume that the owners of capital outnumber owners

of labor and therefore the median voter prefers a low tariff (tM). If Party A proposes a

tariff of tA, while the other proposes the lower tB, Party B will receive the votes of all of

the voters that prefer tB and any smaller tariff, giving them the vast majority. Therefore,

both parties have an incentive to undercut the proposed tariff of the other and will bring

their policy as close to the view of the median voter as possible. So, in our example, the

Page 19: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

13

median voter model predicts that politicians in Home will promise to reduce tariffs

through the passage of the free trade bill, thereby bringing the tariff to tM and capturing

the most votes by satisfying the tariff rate proposed by the median voter.

In the case of this simple model, in which we have assumed that capital owners

outnumber labor owners and the only salient issue is trade policy, the median voter

theorem predicts that the politician in Home will vote in favor of the free trade agreement

in order to align himself with the median voter and capture the most votes. However, as

we will show later in this chapter, altering these assumptions drastically changes the

outcome of the theorem. For example, adding the overall health of the economy as a

salient issue for voters may change the politician’s decision. In addition, we will

examine how a small but politically influential group may be able to sway the politician

away from the view of the median voter, especially when the overall salience of trade

policy to the median voter is low.

Page 20: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

14

2.6 Collective Action

The median voter theorem can be a useful tool for analyzing how representative

politicians choose their policies, but in the case of trade policy its predictions are often

the complete opposite of the actual outcome. The median voter theorem predicts that

trade policy will be based on the number of people that it benefits. In real life, trade

policy often benefits a small but politically influential group (Krugman, Obstfeld, and

Melitz 2012, 248). For example, car makers in the United States benefit from import

quotas on Japanese cars (Crandall, 1984, p. 8). These quotas benefit the small group of

car manufacturers, but negatively impact the much larger group of car consumers by

raising prices.

The explanation for the failure of the median voter theorem to correctly predict

trade policy can be found in part in the theory of collective action as proposed by Mancur

Olson. Olson made the observation that political action is a public good, so the actions of

a single individual can benefit a much larger group of people if they result in a change in

policy. In other words, political action is based on the combined self-interested actions of

individuals (Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz 2012, 248–249).

The main implication of this observation for our model is that policies which

negatively affect a large group of people but impact each person in a relatively small

manner may not receive the political opposition that one would expect given the large

absolute value of the impact. On the other hand, a policy with a relatively small absolute

negative impact that is distributed among a small group of people, such that the impact on

each individual is large, will receive a great deal of opposition. If each individual’s

incentive to act is small, then they are not likely to summon the combined political action

Page 21: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

15

necessary to affect policy. On the other hand, a small but intensely impacted group

would consist of individuals with a great deal of incentive to attempt to influence policy,

giving them a greater chance of summoning the political influence necessary to affect

change (Krugman, Obstfeld, and Melitz 2012, 248–249).

If we apply Mancur Olson’s observations to trade policy formation, we see why

the predictions of the median voter theorem fall short. To demonstrate this, we will

consider the following example. There is a proposed trade agreement that will increase

the quota of cars allowed to be imported into Home. If enacted, it would slightly reduce

the price of cars in Home. We will make the following assumptions: 1) car

manufacturers in Home are much less numerous than the consumers of cars, 2) the

negative impact on each car manufacturer (the reduction in their returns caused by the

lowering in the price of cars) will be smaller in absolute terms than the positive impact of

the efficiency gains and price reduction for consumers, but will be much more intensely

felt by each car manufacturer than by each consumer.

The median voter theorem predicts that trade policy will follow the preferences of

the median voter (in this case, the more numerous consumers would favor the quota

increase). However, each individual consumer has a relatively small incentive to act in

favor the policy, whereas each car producer has a very strong incentive to oppose the

policy. As a result, the car producers may be able to better organize and exert pressure

on politicians to vote down the trade agreement. According to Mancur Olson’s theory,

the smaller but more intensely affected and well-organized car producers would likely

overpower the larger but less organized and less intensely impacted consumers, resulting

Page 22: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

16

in a trade policy that does not reflect the view of the median voter but rather that of the

smaller, well-organized interest group.

2.7 Political Science Models of Political Influence

Public choice theory is an interdisciplinary field of study which uses the tools of

economics to address questions typically considered only by political scientists (Tullock,

2008, p. abstract). Our model here clearly falls within the realm of public choice theory,

so in the spirit of interdisciplinary work, it is important to also consider relevant models

of political influence proposed by political scientists. Here we will examine the

implications of the models of Austen-Smith and Wright (1992) and Smith (1984).

2.7.1 The Alignment of Special Interest Groups and Voters

Austen-Smith and Wright build a model of lobbyist influence in which campaign

contributions from special interest groups buy access to legislators, and these lobbying

groups in turn help legislators to make better decisions by providing them with

information (research, analysis, etc.) that they might not otherwise have had (Austen-

Smith & Wright, 1992, p. 229). This model suggests that campaign contributions from

special interest groups are not necessarily harmful to the overall welfare of society (or, in

the case of our model, the average voter). Therefore, it is possible that special interest

groups and the average voter may be in favor of the same trade policies. The implication

of this on the model established here is that voter preferences and the preferences of

special interest groups may align. This is further evidence of the connection between

voter preferences and politician preferences, as we have assumed (based on the Olson’s

collective action theorem) that politician preferences are intensely affected by special

interest groups.

Page 23: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

17

2.7.2 The Impact of Interpretation

In contrast to the model of Austen-Smith and Wright (1992), Smith (1984) builds

a model of public policy formation in which it is not just the potential outcome of a

policy that determines how a politician will vote, but also the politician’s interpretation of

the consequences of the policy (Austen-Smith & Wright, 1992, p. 44). In other words, it

is not just the outcome of a policy that matters, but also how a politician interprets that

outcome. Smith’s model therefore implies that lobbyists may aim not to educate a

politician on the potential outcomes of a policy (as suggested by Austen-Smith and

Wright (1992)), but may rather seek to simply change a politician’s interpretation of this

outcome. In particular, Smith suggests that lobbyists may be able to change politician’s

decisions by changing their interpretation of a policy by emphasizing its impact on the

politician’s personal goals (such as reelection) (Smith, 1984, p. 44). The implication of

this for the model that I develop is that a politician’s preferences on trade policy may not

depend on only the direct outcome of the trade policy, but also on the politician’s

interpretation of that outcome in relationship to their personal goals (i.e. reelection).

2.8 Voting Costs and Mayer’s Endogenous Tariff Formation Now that we have theoretically established the impact of trade on owners of

factors of production, the role of collective action and the median voter, and the self-

interested goals of politicians, we can build a model of political influence in tariff

formation that accounts for the disproportionately large impact of a small and trade-

sensitive but politically powerful sub-group within a constituency. To do so, we will

adapt the framework of Mayer (1984), who derived a model of tariff formation that

illustrated the relationship between trade-sensitivity, factor endowment, and political

influence with regard to trade policy (Mayer, 1984, p. 970). So, the question we are

Page 24: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

18

answering in this section of the theory is not, “what is the action of the median voter?”,

but rather, “how do voting costs determine the identity of the median voter?”

We will begin modeling the voting cost-benefit analysis from the perspective of

individual utility maximization. First, we will adopt all of the assumptions of the 2x2x2

H-O model stated in sections 2.2-2.4 (perfect competition, etc.). However, rather than

assuming perfectly mobile factors, we will assume that factors are semi-mobile between

industries such that an individual’s trade policy preference can be based on both his

sector of employment and his relative capital endowment. This is consistent with the

empirical findings of Beaulieu (2002), discussed in section 3.6 of this paper.

We assume that voter i’s goal is utility maximization, and his3 utility (U

i) is a

function of his income (Yi) in terms of the relative price of shoes (Ps). Formally written:

𝑈𝑖 = 𝑈𝑖(𝑃𝑠, 𝑌𝑖). We assume that there are two sources of income: returns on capital

ownership (r) and returns on labor ownership (w). Mayer (1984) assumes a third source,

the redistribution of tariff revenues, but for our purposes we will omit this from our

analysis. We are concerned with the impacts of free trade on factor ownership, not

redistributive fiscal policy. Therefore, total income of voter i is: 𝑌𝑖 = 𝑤𝐿𝑖 + 𝑟𝐾𝑖. We

will assume that each voter is endowed with one unit of labor (L i= 1), but capital

endowment varies from voter to voter. Therefore, any given voter’s utility is based on

the relative price of capital vs. labor and their individual capital endowment. Since we

established in 2.1-2.4 that trade liberalization causes uneven changes in the relative

returns to factor owners (and, in the case of semi-mobile factors, specific industries), we

3 For the purposes of simplicity, and to differentiate from the politician, we will refer to the voter using

the pronoun “he”.

Page 25: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

19

can therefore reason that an individual voter’s trade policy preferences will be based on

their individual factor endowment and their sector of employment. We will also assume

that current tariff rates are such that countries are not completely specialized and there

remains an industry in Home which uses the scarce factor (labor) intensively. As we

established using Stolper-Samuelson in section 2.3, a person who is relatively well

endowed in the abundant factor of a country stands to benefit more from trade

liberalization than a person who is well endowed with the scarce factor. If, as in the case

of the relatively capital-abundant Home, a person is relatively well endowed with capital,

such that the increase in their income from a rise in r is greater than their decrease in

income from a drop in w, then they will favor trade liberalization. The opposite is true

for someone who is not relatively well endowed with capital.

It is well established in the theoretical and empirical literature that there are

significant costs associated with voting (opportunity cost of time, effort spent

campaigning, transportation to/from the polling location, etc.) (Mayer, 1984, p. 976). We

will formally express these voting costs as cv. We will assume that an individual’s

benefit from voting bv must be greater than the cost of voting for someone to cast a ballot

(bv>cv). Since we are interested in trade policy formation, as we have stated earlier in our

model, the benefit of voting is exclusively linked to trade policy’s impact on the voter’s

income. So, 𝑏𝑣 = 𝑌1𝑖 − 𝑌2

𝑖, where 𝑌1𝑖 is the voter’s income before voting and 𝑌2

𝑖 is the

voter’s income after voting. Therefore, if the voter’s income increases more than the cost

of voting, he will vote. Otherwise, he will stay home. Formally stated: if 𝑌1𝑖 − 𝑌2

𝑖 > 𝑐𝑣,

then the voter will go to the polls. The voter’s decision to vote, then, is directly linked to

Page 26: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

20

his individual factor endowments and the relative impact of trade on the returns to these

factor endowments.

To illustrate this, we will consider the following hypothetical on the individual

level of analysis. There is a voter in the capital-abundant home, vh, who is, on the

individual level, not relatively well endowed with capital. We will say that for vh, K=0.5,

whereas the median individual’s capital endowment in home is K=2. There is a proposed

tariff decrease. With the current tariff, w = 4 and r = 5. If the tariff decreases takes place,

the new returns will be w = 1 and r = 7. Recall that every individual has the same labor

endowment, L=1. So vh has a pre-liberalization income of 6.5, and a post-liberalization

income of 4.5. On the other hand, the median individual in Home has a pre-liberalization

income of 14, and a post-liberalization income of 15. If voting costs c are greater than or

equal to 1, then those who stand to benefit from the trade liberalization, despite their

majority status, will not vote, because their bv = 1. The less-capital endowed voters have

a bv of 2 and stand to lose more from trade liberalization. Despite that he is actually in

the minority, vh is the median voter that a politician must adopt the preferences of in

order to win an election. This model illustrates how a smaller, more intensely affected

group can decide the trade policy of a constituency because their benefits from voting

outweigh voting costs such that they will actually go the polls, while the larger, less

intensely affected group will not.

2.9 The Political Business Cycle: Modeling the Politician’s Decision

In order to model the decision making of a politician faced with a free trade

agreement, we will first make the following assumptions: 1) the politician may either

vote yes or no, 2) the politician is utility maximizing, and his/her utility is based entirely

Page 27: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

21

on the number of votes garnered in the next election by the decision on the free trade

agreement, 3) the politician has perfect information regarding the composition and trade

policy preferences of his constituents, 4) the constituents consider two issues salient: the

overall health of the economy, and their personal trade policy preferences based on their

sector of employment, 5) constituents have an imperfect memory when considering how

their trade policy preferences match up with those of the politician (in other words, more

recent trade policy decisions by the politician will weigh more heavily in their voting

decision than those in the distant past), 6) the salience of trade policy to voters varies

based on the factor intensity of their sector of employment.

Most importantly, we will assume, based on the model put forth in section 2.8,

that not all constituents will vote. For some, the costs of voting will outweigh the

potential benefits, and they will simply remain at home. The politician knows this, and

acts accordingly. Therefore, the trade policy preference of the median individual in the

entire constituency may vary from that of the median voter in the portion of the

constituency that will actually vote. Beyond the theoretical model justification of 2.8,

this assumption is realistic for several reasons. First, voter turnout in the United States

(the country which this paper focuses on) is historically very low. Turnout has averaged

55% of voting-age citizens over the last 35 years, including 48% in mid-term elections

and 63% in Presidential elections (US Census Bureau, 2012). Second, empirical and

theoretical work has shown support for Mancur Olson’s theory of collective action,

suggesting that geographically dense industries are more politically active in terms of

common trade policy preferences, campaign donations, and voter turnout, because their

physical proximity reduces the costs of organizing (Busch & Reinhardt, 2000, p. 703). In

Page 28: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

22

fact, by Busch & Reinhardt’s (2000) estimation, being in a geographically concentrated

industry increases voter turnout by up to 15.4% and donating money by up to 97.5%. If

an individual is employed in an industry that is import-competing and geographically

concentrated, the probability of that individual supporting protectionism increases by

67.2% (Busch & Reinhardt, 2000, pp. 712–713). Along with this empirical reality, the

idea of a voter cost-benefit analysis has received wide-spread theoretical support (Mayer,

1984, p. 976).

A multitude of literature has shown that, in representative governments, the most

salient issue for the majority of voters is the health of the economy (Drazen, 2000, p. 82).

Therefore, we would expect that a politician’s decision on a trade-related bill would be

based on the overall welfare impact of that bill on the majority of his constituents. That

is, the politician should choose the option that has the largest positive impact on the

economy of his constituency. This is the case for the majority of a politician’s trade

policy decisions, but, when approaching reelection, the politician’s incentives change.

To illustrate this, let us assume that there is a small sub-sector of the politician’s

constituency that cares deeply about trade policy because it heavily influences their sector

of employment. Let us also assume that the trade-sensitive constituency favor a trade

policy that is detrimental to the overall economic welfare of the constituency, but

positively benefits their sector of employment (a realistic assumption, given that we have

established that trade liberalization leads to an overall welfare gain using the H-O model).

We will also, in the method of Drazen (2000), Nordhaus (1975), and Macrae (1977),

assume a myopic constituency with regard to trade policy. Since the constituents have a

relatively short memory regarding trade policy, in non-election years the politician can

Page 29: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

23

vote for the trade policy that has the greatest positive welfare impact on his constituency.

However, when closer to reelection, an incumbent politician will vote for the policy

preferred by this small sub-sector, allowing him to capture the votes of both the larger

constituency concerned with the health of the economy and the smaller sub-sector

concerned with trade.

To demonstrate this, let us first formally construct the loss function of the median

voter that will determine whether he will vote for the incumbent or the upstart. This

model is based heavily upon the political business cycle models of Nordhaus (1975) and

Drazen (2000), who dealt with the political business cycle in the context of monetary and

fiscal policy, respectively (Drazen, 2000, pp. 78–80, 101–112). One key assumption of

this model, which we stated earlier, is that voters have a relatively short memory when it

comes to trade policy. This will be represented by a coefficient, 𝛿, which we will assume

is relatively small (meaning that voters heavily discount trade policy decisions by the

politician in the distant past, and rely mostly on recent decisions). The voter’s loss

function is as follows: 𝐿𝑡 = 𝛼(𝑥𝑡−𝑥′)

2

2+

(𝑦𝑡−𝑦′)2

2. t is the time period being considered,

while x’ is the expected economic output of the constituency and y’ is the expected

performance of the voter’s sector of employment (which determines his trade policy

preference). 𝑥𝑡 and 𝑦𝑡 are the actual economic output of the constituency and the

performance of the voter’s sector of employment. 𝛼 is the relative weight that the voter

puts on the health of the economy vs. the health of their sector of employment. From this

function we see that, depending on a voter’s 𝛼, they will vote based on either their

feelings on the overall health of the economy or their feelings on the overall health of

their sector of employment.

Page 30: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

24

Based on the loss function of the median voter, we can construct a model of the

election itself: 𝑁𝑡 = 𝑁(∑ 𝛿𝐿𝑡−𝑠𝑇𝑠=0 ) + ∈𝑡. 𝑁𝑡 is the number of votes captured by the

incumbent, which is a function of the voter’s past well-being (represented by the loss

function 𝐿𝑡−𝑠). We also see that the “forgetfulness coefficient” δ helps to account for the

differing in the politician’s decisions depending on the proximity to reelection.

To see how this will pan out in real life, let us examine the following

hypothetical. First, we will reinstate all of the assumptions outlined in the theory sections

above (H-O, Median Voter, mobile factors, etc.), but we will add a third sector: services.

We will assume that the production of services uses equal parts capital and labor, so

factor endowment (and therefore trade policy) has no impact on those employed in the

services industry (𝛼 = 1). This assumption is justified by the fact that many services

(such as healthcare, retail, and food service) can’t be imported or exported at this time.

There is a politician in Home who operates on a six year election cycle. Let us say that

75% of his constituency is employed in this services sector, but the other 25% is

employed in the capital-intensive car production industry. This assumption is justified by

the empirical reality that the United States is an extremely services-heavy economy, with

an average of 6 services jobs for every 1 goods-producing job in 2011 (Bureau of Labor

Statistics, 2011).

In our original H-O model, we said that home and foreign each produced entirely

either cars or shoes. In this model, we are assuming that import tariffs in both countries

are such that there is incomplete specialization and it is still feasible to produce some

shoes in Home, and some cars in Foreign. All of the constituents consume equal

amounts of services, shoes, and cars. The politician must vote “yes” or “no” on a free

Page 31: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

25

trade agreement with Foreign that will lower import tariffs on Foreign shoes. This

agreement would have a significant positive impact on all of Home’s consumers of shoes

(100% of the constituents) by reducing the price of shoes, but would harm Home’s shoe

production industry, and therefore the returns of those employed in it, by introducing

greater price competition. We will assume that this price competition represents an

existential threat to the shoe production industry in home, and therefore the votes of those

employed in shoe production are highly based on the politician’s decision on the free

trade agreement ( 𝛼 = .25).

For the purposes of this model, we will assume that the forgetfulness coefficient

operates such that voters will fully discount any trade policy decision that occurred more

than two years before an election. This is an arbitrary distinction, but it is necessary to

draw a line somewhere so that we may illustrate the conclusions of the theoretical model.

Since we have assumed that 75% of constituents are employed in the services

sector and stand to benefit from free trade, why wouldn’t the politician simply reflect the

preference of the median voter and vote for trade liberalization regardless of political

time horizon? Recall that an earlier assumption of our model was that less than 100% of

the constituents would vote in the election, only those whose benefits from voting

outweighed their voting costs would actually vote. This is where Olson’s theorem on

collective action and median voter theorem come into play. In this relatively simplistic

model, the only issues considered by a voter are the health of the economy and the health

of one’s industry of employment. As we showed in our analysis of H-O theorem, Olson,

and Mayer, those who are negatively impacted by trade liberalization may face a much

greater effect, per person, than those who benefit from trade liberalization. We can

Page 32: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

26

assume, then, that those employed in a trade-sensitive industry have a much greater

potential benefit from voting, given that their vote may influence the trade policy of the

politician. This assumption is consistent with the theoretical work of Mayer (1984) on

endogenous tariff formation. Mayer analyzed the voting costs and benefits of a

constituency with regard to tariff rates and came to the conclusion that tariffs will follow

the preferences of a small but intensely trade-sensitive sub-group of a constituency,

because this group’s voting benefits with regard to trade policy are much greater than

their voting costs, which is not the case for the larger, less trade sensitive groups (Mayer,

1984, p. 971).

It is important to remember that the politician is assumed to have perfect

information regarding his constituent’s trade policy preferences and their voting

likelihood. Therefore, despite their relative scarcity in the constituency, those opposed to

trade policy are more likely to vote and thereby the “actual” median voter is opposed to

trade policy during the period immediately before an election. For the purposes of this

model, we will say that the actual distribution of voters is 51% employed in shoe-

producing industry and 49% employed in the services industry.

Now let us say that the politician is outside of two years from an election.

Although it will harm the shoe production industry, the politician would vote “yes” on

the free trade bill, as it will be economically beneficial for all of his constituents, and the

politician knows those who are concerned with trade agreements (those employed in the

shoe industry, for whom said 𝛼 = .25) will forget by the next election cycle. It is

important to note that those employed in a trade-sensitive industry, despite their aversion

to trade liberalization, do not contain the “actual” median voter outside of two years of an

Page 33: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

27

election because the politician is aware that they will not remember her vote by election

time. In other words, the trade policy preferences of those employed in the import-

competing shoe industry effectively have no impact on the trade policy choices of the

politician outside of two years from an election. The only consideration that matters to

the politician outside of the election cycle is the health of the economy. Just as the

politician can’t ignore the politically powerful minority around election time, she also

can’t completely ignore the overall health of the economy. Both those in the services

sector and those in the shoes-producing industry base their vote partially on the health of

the economy. The solution, then, is that the politician will vote for the economically

beneficial trade liberalization outside of the election cycle and will vote for shoe-

industry-benefitting protectionism within the election cycle.

Therefore, faced with the same choice within two years of an election, the

politician will vote “no” on the trade bill, as this will have a minimized negative impact

on the overall economy (a small increase in the price of shoes), but will have a large

positive impact on the returns to the now-relevant 51% of actual voters employed in the

shoe industry, earning the politician the vote of the “actual” median voter and winning

her the election. It is important to note that winning the vote of the trade-sensitive

constituency does not necessarily preclude the politician from also winning the vote of

the non-trade-sensitive constituency. If the economy does well and the politician votes

against trade liberalization near an election, the politician has the potential to capture the

votes her entire constituency.

Page 34: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

28

2.10 Conclusion

In the model we have constructed here, we see that the deciding factor in the

politician’s vote on a free trade agreement changes when she moves within two years of

an election. When she is outside of the two year range, she votes for what is

economically most beneficial for all of her constituents (maximizing 𝑥𝑡 and thereby

increasing the votes garnered from being associated with a healthy economy). When she

is inside of two years, she must vote for what is slightly economically detrimental for all

of his constituents but very beneficial for the import-competing employment sector of a

portion of his constituents. In this manner, she is able to both maintain a healthy

economy and appease the demands of the small sub-section of politically influential

trade-opposed constituents, giving her the maximum number of votes.

The causal relationship proven by this theory is that a politician’s decision on a

free trade agreement will be affected by both the make-up of her constituency (capital vs.

labor abundant, industry of employment of constituents) and the distance from reelection

(inside or outside of two years). These are the causal factors that I will test through my

empirical work in sections 4 and 5.

3. Review of Empirical Literature

3.1 Introduction

In order to determine if there is a relationship between electoral incentives and

trade policy, we must first examine the relevant empirical literature on the determinants

of trade policy formation and other areas in which electoral incentives have been found to

impact government policy. There is only one empirical article which directly addresses

my research question. The work of Conconi et al. (2014) find a significant relationship

Page 35: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

29

between impending reelection and protectionist votes on trade liberalization measures in

the U.S. Congress. Aside from Conconi, recent literature on trade policy formation has

largely focused on the impact of special interest groups (Baldwin and Magee 2000,

Goldberg and Maggi 1999). Others have studied the impact of income inequality and the

application of median voter theorem to trade policy formation (Dutt and Mitra 2002), and

still others have examined the impact of factor endowments and industry of employment

on individual voter’s trade policy preferences (Beaulieu 2002). In the area of political

time horizon, empirical tests on the theory of political business cycles have found a

relationship between time to reelection and expansionary fiscal policy (Alesina et al

1993).

The literature varies widely in unit of analysis. They include individual

politicians (Conconi et al.), individual voters (Beaulieu), countries (Dutt and Mitra,

Alesina et al.), industries (Goldberg and Maggi) The literature examined here provides

valuable insight into the various determinants of trade policy preferences and the

potential impact of political time horizon on public policy, allowing us to gather a sense

of the potentially relevant variables that should be considered in the empirical testing of

our theory in section 4. It also provides insight into the different units of analysis and

empirical methods that have been used in the literature. A table summarizing the

findings, methods, and data of these articles can be found in section 6.1.

3.2 Conconi et al. (2014)

Conconi et al. (2014) have published the only article that directly addresses the

impact of election proximity on trade policy decisions. They hypothesize that the

protectionist leanings of U.S. trade policy are, at least in part, influenced by the electoral

Page 36: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

30

incentives of protectionist policies. To test their hypothesis, they conduct a variety of

empirical tests on a collection of 27 trade liberalization bills in the United States

Congress. To isolate the impact of election proximity, they control for other factors that

may impact trade policy decisions, including the make-up of constituencies, interest

group contributions, personal ideology, and whether the examined politician is retiring or

holds a relatively “safe seat.” Although our empirical methods and theoretical

explanations differ, the hypothesis of Conconi et al. is very similar to my own. The

article adds to the body of literature on the legislative impact of election proximity, which

until now has focused almost exclusively on monetary and fiscal policy (Drazen, 2000,

pp. 75–77).

Conconi et al. do not expressly construct a theoretical explanation for their

empirical results, although they do suggest some relevant theoretical literature. They

mention the relevance of the political business cycle, and hypothesize that the

protectionist impact of elections is due to a protectionist bias among voters and a

“recency bias” among voters that places more weight on recent trade decisions at the

ballot box (Conconi et al., 2014, pp. 104, 115–116).

The empirical methods of Conconi et al. are of particular interest to this paper, as

their central research question is identical to my own. Although we come to the same

result, that election proximity does have a protectionist impact on trade policy, our

methods differ in several key ways. Conconi et al. begin their analysis with a comparison

of the voting habits of Members of the U.S. House of Representatives and U.S. Senators.

They find that House Members are generally more protectionist than Senators, suggesting

that the shorter terms (2 years) of House members compared to Senators (6 years) may be

Page 37: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

31

responsible for this difference. To further support their hypothesis, they examine the

differences between Senators of different generations (the focus of this paper). They find

that, even when controlling for differences between these Senator’s constituencies,

political contributions, and ideology, the generation of Senators that are closest to

reelection (a full third of Senators for any given bill) are 10% less likely to support a

trade liberalization bill than their colleagues who are further from reelection (Conconi et

al., 2014, p. 109).

Conconi et al. run a number of empirical equations to test their hypothesis. They

begin with equation (1), a probit model, to determine if, all other factors equal, Senators

are more protectionist than House Members.

𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑏(𝑉𝑜𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑗𝑡) = 𝛷(𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝑆𝑒𝑛𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑗 + 𝛽2𝑿𝑖𝑡 + 𝛽3𝒁𝑗𝑡 + 𝜇𝑗 + 𝛿𝑡 + 𝜖𝑖𝑗𝑡)

(1)

The dummy variable Senate accounts for the difference between House and

Senate Members, the matrix X accounts for controls specific to the legislator

(party identification, age, gender), and the matrix Z contains variables that are

specific to the legislator’s constituency (population, export/import ratio, skill

level). 𝜇𝑗 and 𝛿𝑡 are fixed effects dummies, with 𝜇𝑗 accounting for state specific

variables not attached to time, while 𝛿𝑡 accounts for year-specific variables that

are not attached to a particular state (Conconi et al., 2014, p. 107). To measure

the export/import ratio of each constituency (both states and Congressional

districts), Conconi et al. use the number of workers in import competing

industries vs. the number of workers in export competing industries. To

calculate this, they use County Business Patterns census data on SIC/NAICS

Page 38: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

32

sector of employment and classify industries as import or export competing

based on whether the U.S. was a net importer or exporter of that good in a

particular year (Conconi et al., 2014, pp. 105–106). From this equation, they

find that, ceteris paribus, Senators support trade liberalization a statistically

significant amount (6%-8%) more than House Members. They also find that age

(older = more support), party identification (democrat = less support), export

ratio (more export oriented = more support), and constituency skill endowment

(more educated = more support) are statistically significant across all

specifications (Conconi et al., 2014, pp. 106–108).

To test the difference between House Members and different generations

of Senators (3 generations: furthest from election, closer to election, and closest

to election), Conconi et al. estimate the following probit equation (2):

𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑏(𝑉𝑜𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑗𝑡 = 1) = 𝛷(𝛾0 + 𝛾1𝑆𝑒𝑛𝑎𝑡𝑒1𝑖𝑡 + 𝛾2𝑆𝑒𝑛𝑎𝑡𝑒2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛾3𝑆𝑒𝑛𝑎𝑡𝑒3𝑖𝑡 +

𝛾4𝑿𝑖𝑡 + 𝛾5𝒁𝑗𝑡 + 𝜇𝑗 + 𝛿𝑡 + 𝜖𝑖𝑗𝑡)

(2)

The coefficients of Senate1 and Senate2 are positive and statistically significant

(between 13.2% and 17.7% more likely to support liberalization), while the

Senate3 variable is statistically insignificant. Since House members face

election at the same time as Senate3, Conconi et al. conclude that the last

generation of Senators is equally as protectionist as House members, while

Senators who are further from election are significantly more likely to favor

trade liberalization (Conconi et al., 2014, pp. 107–108).

Page 39: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

33

The linchpin of Conconi et al.’s analysis (and the focus of my paper) is

their final equation, which they use to compare differences in trade liberalization

voting patterns among Senators of different generations. The equation is as

follows:

𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑏(𝑉𝑜𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑗𝑡 = 1)

= 𝛷(𝛿0 + 𝛿1𝑆𝑒𝑛𝑎𝑡𝑒2𝑖𝑡 + 𝛿2𝑆𝑒𝑛𝑎𝑡𝑒3𝑖𝑡 + 𝛿3𝑿𝑖𝑡 + 𝛿4𝒁𝑗𝑡 + 𝜇𝑗 + 𝛿𝑡

+ 𝜖𝑖𝑗𝑡)

(3)

They find that, ceteris paribus, Senators are less 10% less likely to vote for trade

liberalization if they are in the last two years of their terms (Conconi et al., 2014,

p. 109). They also estimate a logit and linear regression model for comparing

the individual voting records of Senators who voted on multiple bills. They find

results in line with those of their probit model, indicating that even a Senator

who has voted for trade liberalization in the past is less likely to vote for it in the

last two years of their term (Conconi et al., 2014, pp. 110–111). To further test

their results for robustness, they interact their Senate3 variable with the variables

retiring and safe (dummies for if the Senator willfully chose not to run in the

following election of if they won their last election by a margin of 60% or

greater). They find that the interaction term is significant and positive in both

cases, indicating that planning to retire or holding a safe seat removes the

electoral incentive of opposing trade liberalization. Meanwhile, the coefficient

for Senate3 remains negative and significant, further indicating that votes against

trade liberalization are partly driven by electoral considerations (Conconi et al.,

2014, p. 111). With regard to campaign contributions, Conconi et al. find results

Page 40: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

34

in line with those of Baldwin and Magee (2000), indicating that contributions

from business groups are associated with votes for trade liberalization, while

votes for trade restriction are associated with greater labor contributions.

Additionally, the inclusion of this variable did not affect the sign or significance

of Senate3, indicating that it is not campaign funding cycles that cause the

protectionist impact of elections (Conconi et al., 2014, p. 110).

The principal finding of Conconi et al. is that election proximity has a

significant (as great as 10% in some specifications) protectionist impact on trade

policy. They find that Senators are more likely to vote for trade liberalization

than shorter-termed members of the House of Representatives, and Senators who

are in the last two years of their term are less likely than their colleagues to

support liberalization. These results are robust when including controls for

constituency make-up and legislator ideology, as well as when examining the

voting records of individual Senators over time.

Conconi et al.’s results are striking, but there are several opportunities for

expansion to their research that I will take advantage of here. First, their

approximation of the capital-labor ratio of constituencies was limited to the

education level of constituents. They made no attempt to examine a more exact

measurement of constituencies’ capital-labor ratios. Second, they did not check

if the protectionist impact of elections increases as elections draw closer (say,

within one year). Third, they did not include trade agreements after 2005,

including the Peru, Panama, Colombia, and Korea Free Trade Agreements. If

Page 41: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

35

the impact of election proximity on trade legislation is as great as Conconi et al.

theorize, then these three issues require further investigation.

3.3 Dutt and Mitra (2002)

Dutt and Mitra (2002) examine the relationship between differences in inequality

between countries and differences in the levels of trade barriers. They hypothesize that

an increase in inequality will raise trade barriers in relatively capital-abundant countries

and lower trade barriers in capital scarce countries (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 107). This

examination of the impact of inequality is relevant to our discussion here because they

define inequality as the difference between the mean and median capital-labor ratios of a

country. This means that, by examining inequality in this fashion, they are also

examining the impact of capital-labor endowments on trade policy determination. In

effect, this paper provides an empirical test (and, in its results, support) for the assertions

made in the Heckscher-Ohlin/median voter/Mayer portions of our theoretical model.

To theoretically examine their hypothesis, they construct a model of trade policy

determination similar to that of Mayer (1984) (which is covered briefly in section 2.8),

using median voter theorem within a two-factor, two-sector Heckscher-Ohlin framework

(Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 107). They note that the median voter theorem predicts that

labor-abundant countries should be pro-trade, while capital-abundant countries should be

anti-trade, but in reality nearly all countries are in some way biased against trade (Dutt &

Mitra, 2002, p. 108). Therefore, they choose to focus not on pro-trade vs. anti-trade, but

rather on variations in the magnitude4 of anti-trade policy between countries. Their

4 For example: a country with very high import tariffs is considered to have a high magnitude of trade

barriers, while a country with relatively low import tariffs is considered to have a low magnitude of trade barriers.

Page 42: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

36

theoretical model supports their hypothesis that, holding constant overall relative factor

endowments, higher inequality within a country increases the magnitude of trade barriers

in capital-abundant economies and lowers the magnitude of trade barriers in capital-

scarce economies. In other words, they find support for a modified version of the Mayer-

H-O/median voter model that considers the magnitude of trade barriers rather than the

pro-trade/anti-trade orientation of policies. This result is consistent with the theoretical

predictions of my model in section 2.

In order to empirically test their theoretical model, they run several OLS

regressions of cross-sectional country-level data from the 1980s with magnitude of trade

protection as the dependent variable. First, they seek to determine the point in the

capital-labor level at which inequality and trade go from being positively related

(considered a relatively high capital-labor ratio) to being negatively rated (when the

capital-labor ratio is relatively low). To do this, they estimate equation (1):

𝑇𝑅𝑖 = 𝛼0 + 𝛼1𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄 + 𝛼2𝐼𝑁𝐸𝑄 × (𝐾/𝐿)𝑖 + 𝛼3(𝐾/𝐿)𝑖 + 𝑿𝒊𝜷 + 𝜖𝑖

(1)

𝑇𝑅𝑖 is the magnitude of trade restrictions in country I, INEQ is the level of

inequality, (K/L) is the captial-labor ratio, and Xi is a row vector of control variables

(Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 115). To measure inequality, they use both the Gini-coefficient

and the share of the third quintile in national income. They acknowledge that these are

imperfect measurements, as they represent income inequality rather than inequality in

individual factor endowments. To calculate the capital-labor ratio, they use data from

Page 43: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

37

Nehru-Dhareshwar5 on average physical capital endowment in the 1980s and define labor

as the population between ages 15 and 64. For control variables that may impact trade

barriers, they include level of democracy defined by the Freedom House 1-7 scale of

democracy and schooling defined as the average number of schooling years of the total

population over age 25 (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 117). For their dependent variable, they

use several different measurements of the level of trade protection. These include: “total

import duties collected as a percentage of total imports, an average tariff rate calculated

by weighing each import category by the 15 fraction of world trade in that category, a

coverage ratio for non-tariff barriers to trade and an indirect measure of trade restrictions-

the magnitude of trade flows relative to GDP, defined as (X 1 M)/GDP” (Dutt & Mitra,

2002, p. 117). Their sample size ranges from 44-64.

Dutt and Mitra find empirical support for the prediction of their modified Mayer-

Heckscher-Ohlin/median voter model. Their results indicate that an increase in

inequality leads to an increase in trade barriers in capital-rich countries and a decrease in

trade barriers in capital-poor countries, holding relative factor endowments constant (Dutt

and Mitra 2002, 130). This result is robust for all of the different measures of trade

barriers considered except for the quota coverage ratio, the failure of which they attribute

to coding problems and weaknesses in the underlying data (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 119).

They identify the critical capital-labor ratio (the level at which a country is considered

captial abundant vs. capital scarce) as around 8.5. Below this level, the positive

relationship between inequality and trade protection turns to a negative relationship (Dutt

& Mitra, 2002, p. 122).

5 Nehru, V., & Dhareshwar, A. (1993). A new database on physical capital stock: sources, methodology

and results. Revista de análisis económico, 8(1), 37-59.

Page 44: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

38

Among their control variables, level of schooling is found to have a significant

negative impact on trade restrictions. They reason that this may be because it is a

measurement of overall development, or a more educated constituency may understand

the dead-weight costs of protectionist trade policy (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 124). Level of

democracy is found to have a significant, but weak, positive impact on trade restrictions,

which they attribute to a democratic government being more concerned with the

distribution of an economy than its overall size (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 123). They note

that this provides support for the idea that the median voter theorem is a more accurate

predictor of trade policy in the case of democracies (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 126). They

use a Hausman test to check for endogeneity, and find evidence of endogeneity in the

case of the tariffs dependent variable. They correct for this by modifying the standard

errors by a factor of 1.94 to obtain consistent IV standard error estimates, and all main

coefficients remained statistically significant (Dutt & Mitra, 2002, p. 125).

The findings of Dutt and Mitra (2002) suggest statistical support for the

predictions of the Mayer-Heckscher-Ohlin/median voter theorem model presented in this

paper. Dutt and Mitra have shown using a Heckscher-Ohlin model that inequality (by

their definition) can impact trade policy, increasing trade barriers in capital-abundant

countries and decreasing trade barriers in capital-scarce countries. Therefore, the level of

inequality in a country should be included in my empirical analysis.

3.4 Goldberg and Maggi (1999)

Goldberg and Maggi (1999) empirically examine Gene M. Grossman and Elhanan

Helpman (1994)’s theoretical model on the impact of special interest group contributions

on trade policy. The authors hypothesize that an analysis of cross-sectional data will

Page 45: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

39

confirm the predictions of the Grossman-Helpman model. The model predicts that trade

protection will be higher where industries are represented by a lobby and in industries

with lower import elasticity. Further, within organized industries, protection increases

with lower import penetration, and in non-organized industries protection increases with

higher import penetration (Goldberg & Maggi, 1999, p. 135). The analysis of Goldberg

and Maggi is fairly unique within the literature on the political economy of trade policy

in that they strictly adhere to the theoretical model in their empirical analysis, including

almost exclusively theoretically relevant variables (Goldberg & Maggi, 1999, pp. 1136–

1137). Their hypothesis is related to my own in that both account for the political

influence of organized groups, but mine does so through the analysis of voting costs and

collective action rather than the direct examination of campaign contributions.

The Grossman-Helpman model of the political impact of special interest group

contributions builds a theoretical model on the assumption that organized industries will

contribute more to politician’s campaigns, giving them more influence over political

trade policy decisions. It assumes that each good has an input of labor and one factor that

is specific to that sector. The model predicts that protection increases with domestic

output, because specific factor owners stand to gain more from protection. Likewise, if

the volume of imports is lower, the overall economy suffers less from protectionism. It

also predicts that sectors with higher import elasticity will be less protected, because the

deadweight loss from such protection is higher and the government will therefore be less

willing to grant protection (Goldberg & Maggi, 1999, pp. 1138–1139).

Goldberg and Maggi empirically test the predictions of this model using a

maximum-likelihood regression with level of trade barriers as the dependent variable and

Page 46: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

40

import-demand elasticities, the import-penetration ratio, and level of political

organization as the independent variables (Goldberg and Maggi 1999, 1144). They

estimate the following equation (1):

𝑦𝑖∗ =

𝑡𝑖∗𝑒𝑖

1 + 𝑡𝑖∗ = 𝛾

𝑋𝑖

𝑀𝑖+ 𝛿𝐼𝑖 + 𝜖𝑖

(1)

𝑡𝑖∗ is a measurement of the level of protection, 𝑒𝑖 is the import demand elasticity,

𝑋𝑖

𝑀𝑖 is

the inverse import penetration ratio, and 𝛿𝐼𝑖 is a dummy for political organization

(Goldberg & Maggi, 1999, pp. 1139–1144).

It is important to note that they examine exclusively non-tariff barriers as their

measurement of trade protection, whereas the Grossman-Helpman model is based on

tariff predictions. Their reasoning for this is that tariffs are often determined through

international cooperative agreements such as GATT, but the G-H model does not account

for cooperation between countries (Goldberg and Maggi 1999, 1137). To represent non-

tariff barriers, they use coverage ratios from 1983 (Goldberg and Maggi 1999, 1140).

They use a number of variables to account for political organization, including data on

campaign contributions comes from the 1982 and 1984 congressional elections,

unionization, industry employment size/unemployment rate, and industry growth

(Goldberg and Maggi 1999, 1145). They used demand elasticity estimates from Clinton

R. Shiells et al. (1986) (citing their relative reliability), but place them on the left-hand

side of the equation to combat the notorious unreliability of demand elasticity predictions

in general. Data on the import penetration ratio comes from the National Bureau of

Economic Research Trade and Immigration data file.

Page 47: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

41

Their empirical tests find support for all of the predictions of the G-H model,

asserting that trade protection will be higher where industries are represented by a lobby

and in industries with lower import elasticity. Also, within organized industries,

protection increases with lower import penetration, and in non-organized industries

protection increases with higher import penetration (Goldberg & Maggi, 1999, p. 1136).

Therefore, in sum, political organization does have an impact on protection, but it also

varies depending on the import penetration and import elasticity of the industry. Of

particular interest to this paper, their analysis suggests that the U.S. government places

much more importance on the overall welfare implications of trade policy, rather than the

influence of special interest groups. This difference between the two impacts is quite

large, with a weight of .98 for welfare considerations and a weight of only .02 for

campaign contributions (Goldberg and Maggi 1999, 1136). These results are relevant to

my research question in that they suggest that, while interest group contributions matter,

welfare considerations are far more important determinants of trade policy. Therefore,

when building an empirical model, it is important to consider the impact of special

interest groups, but the overall welfare implications of the trade policies must be given

even greater consideration.

3.5 Baldwin and Magee (2000)

Baldwin and Magee (2000) empirically examine how members of the U.S. House

of Representatives respond to campaign donations from business and labor groups when

they make decisions on trade policy. Rather than using one specific theoretical approach

to test this question, they draw from a wide variety of both economic and political science

theoretical work to hypothesize that legislators’ preferences toward trade policy are

Page 48: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

42

determined by both the impact of the policy on their constituents and the input of special

interest groups attained through major campaign contributions (Baldwin & Magee, 1998,

pp. 85–87). This hypothesis is consistent with my own, as I also consider the impact of

overall welfare and the influence special interest groups in my theoretical model.

In order to empirically test the impact of campaign donations on

politicians’ trade voting habits, Baldwin and Magee examine three separate independent

variables in the form of votes of members of the U.S. House of Representatives on three

high-profile trade bills from 1993-1994: the North American Free Trade Agreement, the

General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade Uruguay Round, and Most Favored Nation

status for China (Baldwin and Magee 2000, 80). They then compare these votes to

several independent variables using a full information maximum likelihood simultaneous

regression of three separate equations for each of the three votes (this is to control for

possible correlation between the politician’s votes on the three trade bills). The equations

(1), (2), and (3) are as follows:

Votenafta = F(A′X + AL∗ (Labor contributions) + AB

∗ (Business contributions) + En

(1)

Votegatt = F(B′X + BL∗(Labor contributions) + BB

∗ (Business contributions) + Eg

(2)

Votemfn = F(C′X + CL∗(Labor contributions) + CB

∗ (Business contributions) + Em

(3)

“F is the cumulative standard normal distribution, X is a vector of constituency variables

that influence members’ voting behavior” (Baldwin & Magee, 1998, p. 87). They run

Hausman tests to test for endogeneity in the campaign donation variables of each

Page 49: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

43

equation. The results of these tests are mixed, with endogeneity in NAFTA’s business,

but not labor, contributions, no evidence of endogeneity in the GATT equation, and

evidence only in the labor variable in the China MFN equation. As a result, the authors

elect to treat all campaign donations as endogenous (Baldwin and Magee 2000, 88). In

addition to the independent variables presented above, Baldwin and Magee include

control variables for the measurements of the ideology of a legislator based on party

affiliation and ratings from interest groups (Baldwin and Magee 2000, 87).

Despite the inherent endogeneity of campaign contributions, the authors conclude

that these donations have a significant impact on Congressional voting on trade policy

(Baldwin and Magee 2000, 79). They estimate that campaign contributions from labor

groups accounted for 67 extra votes against NAFTA and 57 extra votes against the GATT

bill. They also find that contributions from business groups accounted for 41 votes for

NAFTA and 35 for GATT. The cost-per-vote that they estimate for labor groups is

$352,000 for NAFTA and $313,000 for GATT (Baldwin and Magee 2000, 99). Other

factors that they found significantly impacted the votes were certain variables involving

the economic make-up of the Congressman’s district (import-based vs. export-based),

and the ideology of the Representative (by interest group rating) (Baldwin and Magee

2000, 99). As predicted by the HO model (assuming that the U.S. is a capital abundant

country and therefore exports capital-intensive goods), labor groups’ donations were

linked to votes against trade liberalization while business groups’ donations were linked

to votes for trade liberalization (with business groups representing a rough equivalent to

capital owners) (Baldwin and Magee 2000, 79).

Page 50: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

44

Baldwin and Magee’s article is an important step toward determining the impact

of campaign donations on politician’s voting habits, but there are also a number of issues

with the article. Although they attempted to account for the possible endogeneity of

campaign donations (meaning that donations will go to candidates who are known to vote

in a group’s interests rather than donations being a “bribe” for votes) by including all of

the other variables in the same regression equation, it is possible that this endogeneity is

too deep-rooted to be avoided (Baldwin and Magee 2000, 87). The findings of this

article are relevant to my work in that they show that special interest group may have an

impact on legislator trade policy preferences through campaign contributions.

3.6 Beaulieu (2002)

Beaulieu (2002) does an empirical investigation of two different hypotheses based

on the perfect factor mobility of Stolper-Samuelson Theorem and its opposite, a situation

of factor immobility (Beaulieu, 2002, p. 99). According to the predictions of the Stopler-

Samuelson Theorem, if factors of production are mobile then trade policy preferences

will form along factor lines because factor endowment determines the cost/benefit of

trade. In this case, industry of employment is irrelevant to distributions from trade (this

is known as the factor-industry detachment corollary) (Beaulieu, 2002, p. 103).

However, if factors aren’t mobile, then it follows that trade policy preferences will from

along industry lines because industry of employment determines the cost/benefit of trade

(Beaulieu 2002, 99). The empirical comparison of these two competing models is

relevant to my hypothesis because it reveals the possible importance of both individual

factor endowment and industry of employment, a situation of partial factor mobility that

my model assumes.

Page 51: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

45

To empirically test these two competing hypotheses, Beaulieu first separately

estimates an equation for each theory using maximum-likelihood logit models. Equation

(1) represents perfect factor mobility and therefore states that supporting trade

liberalization is a function of factor endowments (in this case, represented as skill type).

Pr(𝑠𝑢𝑝𝑝𝑜𝑟𝑡 = 1) = 𝐹(𝛽0 + ∑ 𝛽𝑗

𝐽

𝑗=1

𝑠𝑘𝑖𝑙𝑙𝑗 + 𝑋𝛾)

(1)

Equation (2) represents completely immobile factors, meaning that the probability

of supporting a free trade agreement is a function of industry affiliation.

Pr(𝑠𝑢𝑝𝑝𝑜𝑟𝑡 = 1) = 𝐹(𝛼0 + ∑ 𝛼𝑖

𝐼

𝑖=1

𝑖𝑛𝑑𝑖 + 𝑋𝛾)

(2)

In both equations, X is a matrix of control variables that may affect the probability of

supporting trade liberalization, including region, age, union membership, and party

affiliation (Beaulieu, 2002, pp. 106–107).

To test the performance of the two models in relationship to each other, a Cox test is

performed in which with the null hypothesis is equation (1), and the alternative

hypothesis is equation (2). In addition to using a Cox test to test the null/alternative

hypotheses above, he also tests a comprehensive FIML logit regression equation

containing both the skill level and industry affiliation as independent variables, this is

equation (3)

Page 52: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

46

Pr(𝑠𝑢𝑝𝑝𝑜𝑟𝑡 = 1) = 𝐹(𝛽0 + ∑ 𝛽𝑗

𝐽

𝑗=1

𝑠𝑘𝑖𝑙𝑙𝑗 + ∑ 𝛼𝑖

𝐼

𝑖=1

𝑖𝑛𝑑𝑖 + 𝑋𝛾

(3)

Beaulieu uses data from a 1988 Canadian National Election Survey, which was

taken immediately before and after the 1988 Canadian general election. He asserts that

the only major issue in the election was politicians’ position on the potential U.S.-Canada

Free Trade Agreement, making the election effectively a referendum on free trade

(Beaulieu 2002, 101). The survey data includes socioeconomic information as well as

past voting behavior and political attitudes. Beaulieu notes that the CNES does not

contain specific industry of employment, but does include occupation data. It is from this

occupation data that he groups the individuals into industries (Beaulieu 2002, 108). To

ensure the accuracy of this grouping, Beaulieu compares the distribution of individuals in

industries in the survey to data on the same subject from the Canadian Census (Beaulieu

2002, 109). He finds that the two distributions are extremely close to one another (with a

correlation of .92) (Beaulieu 2002, 109). Factor ownership is based on skill level, with

two different measures of skill level used: level of education (less than high school, full

high school, some technical/college, and some university) and skill level of the

occupation (unskilled, low skilled, semi-skilled, high skilled) (Beaulieu 2002, 112).

In his empirical test of the model in which factors are mobile, Beaulieu finds that

“those employed in industries that were predicted to be adversely affected by the

agreement were more likely to oppose the FTA than those employed in industries

predicted to gain,” which is directly in line with the theoretical prediction of the model of

factor immobility (Beaulieu 2002, 118). He also finds that factors of production (in this

Page 53: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

47

case, skill level) affected voter preference on the FTA in that skilled workers were more

likely to support the FTA (Beaulieu 2002, 124), which is in line with the predictions of

the model of factor mobility. Therefore, these results suggest that factors of production

are partially mobile between industries, and therefore trade policy preferences can form

along both factor endowment and industry lines (Beaulieu, 2002, pp. 125–128). These

results are relevant to my hypothesis in that they provide evidence that factor endowment

and industry of employment may both affect a voter’s preferences on trade policy, and

therefore both should be considered in any empirical analysis of my theoretical model.

3.7 Alesina, Cohen, and Roubini (1993)

Alesina et. al empirically investigate data from 18 industrial democracies in the

period of 1960-1987 to determine if there is evidence that governments manipulate fiscal

or monetary policy prior to elections to encourage short-term economic expansion and

thereby increase their chances of reelection. They also examine if governments will call

elections early during times of economic growth to take advantage of favorable electoral

conditions. Since I am examining a theoretical model in which elections are exogenously

fixed (which is the case in the United States, but not in many parliamentary democracies),

I will only discuss Alesina et. al’s findings in regards to the manipulation of economic

policy, not election timing (Alesina, Cohen, & Roubini, 1993, p. 4).

Alesina et. al run separate regressions to empirically test several different political

business cycle theorems from the roughly 18 years preceding their paper since the

beginning of the literature on the subject with Nordhaus (1975). Nordhaus’ theory states

that a politician will manipulate monetary policy prior to elections in order to create a

spike in employment and economic growth rate, which is seen favorably by myopic

Page 54: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

48

constituents and therefore increases the politician’s chances of reelection (Alesina et al.,

1993, pp. 4–5). They also examine the more recent theoretical literature on political

business cycles, which takes into account more rational assumptions about the voter

(assuming them to be less myopic), and assumes that the politician has little ability to

manipulate large-scale economic indicators such as GDP growth and unemployment

(Alesina et al., 1993, p. 5). These new rational political business cycle models predict

that politicians will still attempt to alter the economy before elections, but their ability to

succeed at this is greatly reduced and it will be mostly based on small, short term changes

in fiscal and monetary policy (Alesina et al., 1993, p. 7).

They observe that, in order to produce an increase in economic activity, a

manipulation of fiscal policy must result from either an increase in spending or a decrease

in taxes, resulting in a fiscal deficit before elections. Therefore, the dependent variable is

the fiscal deficit 𝑑(𝑖𝑡), which they measure as a change in the debt-GDP ratio. The

independent variables that they examine include the lagged deficit 𝑑(𝑏𝑖,𝑡−1), the change

in the unemployment rate 𝑑(𝑈𝑖𝑡), the change in the GDP growth rate 𝑑(𝑦𝑖𝑡), the change

in the real interest rate minus the growth rate multiplied by the lagged debt-GDP ratio

𝑏𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑑(𝑟𝑡 − 𝑛𝑡), political instability 𝑝𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑡, an electoral dummy 𝑒𝑙𝑒𝑖𝑡, a dummy to

identify left-wing governments 𝑙𝑒𝑓𝑡𝑖𝑡, and an interaction term between the electoral and

left-wing variables𝑙𝑒𝑓𝑡𝑖𝑡 ∗ 𝑒𝑙𝑒𝑖𝑡 (Alesina et al., 1993, p. 16). They employ a panel

regression to empirically test these variables. They estimate the following equation (1)

𝑑(𝑖𝑡) = 𝛿0 + 𝛿1 ∗ 𝑑(𝑏𝑖,𝑡−1) + 𝛿2 ∗ 𝑑(𝑈𝑖𝑡) + 𝛿3 ∗ 𝑑(𝑦𝑖𝑡) + 𝛿4 ∗ 𝑏𝑖𝑡−1 ∗ 𝑑(𝑟𝑡 − 𝑛𝑡) + 𝛿5

∗ 𝑝𝑜𝑙𝑖𝑡 + 𝛿6 ∗ 𝑒𝑙𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝛿7 ∗ 𝑙𝑒𝑓𝑡𝑖𝑡 + 𝛿8 ∗ 𝑙𝑒𝑓𝑡𝑖𝑡 ∗ 𝑒𝑙𝑒𝑖𝑡 + 𝑣𝑖𝑡

Page 55: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

49

(1)

They run this regression using quarterly economic data on 18 different

industrialized democracies (including the United States, U.K., and Canada) from 1958-

1987, obtained from the IMF International Financial Statistics library and the OECD.

Like most empirical research before them, Alesina et al. did not find support for

the political business cycle proposed by Nordhaus (1975), seeing no relationship between

electoral cycles and GDP or unemployment (the two variables that, according to

Nordhaus, can be manipulated by politicians through monetary policy) (Alesina et al.,

1993, pp. 20–21). However, they do find support for the rational political business cycles

model, finding a statistically significant relationship between electoral cycles and fiscal

policy instruments in the form of increased real fiscal deficits in the year before an

election (Alesina et al., 1993, p. 18). This suggests that politicians still adopt semi-

expansionary policies when closer to an election, even if they aren’t very effective at

raising the GDP growth rate or lowering the unemployment rate. These findings are

relevant to my thesis in that they suggest that there may be some electoral cycle to

government policy decisions, especially in the area of fiscal policy. Since I will be

empirically testing the relationship between trade policy decisions and electoral cycles, it

is relevant to note that a relationship between elections and government action has been

found in another area of policy.

3.8 Conclusion

Conconi et al. (2014), Dutt and Mitra (2002), Goldberg and Maggi (1999),

Baldwin and Magee (2000), and Beaulieu (2002) all focused on the political economy

determinants of trade policy. Alesina et. al (1993) showed that there is a relationship

Page 56: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

50

between public policy decision making and political time horizon. The articles took

several different approaches in their analyses, with the unit of analysis varying from the

country, to the industry, to the individual. This is relevant to the work of this paper in

that I analyzed the role of the individual voter and the constituency as a whole in my

theoretical model, and I will take a similarly broad-based approach in my empirical work.

Based on the results of these empirical articles, relevant variables for my

empirical model include: the inequality in factor endowment within the politician’s

constituency, the impact of special interest groups, the effect of factor endowments and

industry of employment on voter’s trade policy preferences, and the time relationship

between elections and trade policy decisions. I will not, however, include all of these in

my empirical results in the exact form that the above researchers used them. Rather, as I

explain in the next section, I will use a series of proxy variables to represent each of the

relevant concepts, focusing on the make-up of the politician’s constituency, the ideology

of the politician, and the time to reelection.

4. Methodology and Data

4.1 Hypothesis

Based on the causal relationships established in my theoretical analysis and the findings

of my literature review, I hypothesize that, as a politician approaches reelection, he will

favor more protectionist policies, because the politician’s utility is based on votes

garnered and such policies are favored by a group of voters in his constituency who have

a stronger incentive to vote based only on their trade policy preferences. However, since

voters have a short memory regarding the politician’s past trade policy decisions, when

Page 57: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

51

not faced with imminent reelection the politician will vote for the policy that is most

economically beneficial to their broader constituency.

4.2 Empirical Model

To test my hypothesis, I will estimate a model of the politician’s decision that

accounts for the impact of the makeup of his constituency (expressed by capital/labor

ratio and goods/services employment), his ideology (expressed by party identification),

and his electoral incentives (expressed by inside/outside of two years from an election

and also whether he is retiring). I will use a probit model, since the dependent variable is

a yes/no dummy, and it is therefore advantageous to have the outcomes of my regression

bounded within 0 and 1. The model is as follows:

𝑃𝑟𝑜𝑏(𝑉𝑜𝑡𝑒𝑖𝑠𝑡) = 𝛷(𝛽0 + 𝛽1𝐶𝑎𝑝𝑖𝑡𝑎𝑙𝐿𝑎𝑏𝑜𝑟𝑠𝑡 + 𝛽2𝐺𝑜𝑜𝑑𝑠𝑆𝑒𝑟𝑣𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑠𝑠𝑡 + 𝛽3𝐷𝑒𝑚𝑜𝑐𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑠𝑡

+ 𝛽4𝐸𝑙𝑒𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡 + 𝛽5𝑅𝑒𝑡𝑖𝑟𝑒𝑑𝑠𝑡 + 휀𝑠𝑡)

(1)

Voteist is a dummy variable representing the vote of senator s on bill i in year t (1

= yea, 0 = nay). CaptitalLaborst represents the capital/labor ratio of the state of senator s

in year t, while GoodsServices represents the ratio of goods producing to service

providing laborers of senator s in year t, Democrat represents the Party identification of

senator s in year t (a dummy variable where 1 = Democrat and 0 = Republican, with

independents classified by the party of their caucus), Election is a dummy variable (1 =

within two years of an election, 0 otherwise), and Retired is a control for if the senator

decided not to run in the following election (1 if did not run, 0 otherwise).

Page 58: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

52

Based on my theoretical analysis and literature review, it is possible to

hypothesize expected signs for each of these variables. These signs are in found in table

(1). Note that a positive sign means an increased likelihood of approving a free trade bill.

Table 1. Expected Signs

Variable Expected Sign

CapitalLabor (+)

GoodsServices (-)

Democrat (-)

Election (-)

Retired (+)

The expected sign of the first independent variable, CapitalLabor, is positive

because my empirical analysis takes place in the U.S., which is capital abundant relative

to labor (Rassekh & Thompson, 2002, p. 239). Therefore, according to the H-O theorem,

the U.S. is an exporter of capital-intensive goods and an importer of labor-intensive

goods. This means that the more capital-abundant a constituency, the more export-

oriented they will be, and therefore the more they will stand to benefit from free trade.

The expected sign of the second symbol, GoodsServices, is negative based on the

theoretical assumption that goods are more labor-intensive than services, and therefore, in

the capital abundant U.S., a constituency that is more employed in goods-producing

industries (such as manufacturing) will be against free trade to protect themselves from

import competition. The expected sign of the third variable, Democrat, is negative based

on the long-standing tradition of the Democratic party opposing trade agreements on the

argument that they will harm American import-competing industries (Conconi et al.,

Page 59: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

53

2014, p. 113). The expected sign of the fourth variable, Election, is negative based on the

theoretical conclusion established in Chapter 2, which states that a politician will vote

against the more economically efficient free trade agreement if they are within two years

of an election, because it would cost them the votes of the extremely trade averse (but

forgetful) portion of their population. The expected sign of the fifth variable, retired, is

positive based on the idea that a retiring politician no longer has an electoral incentive to

favor protectionism, and therefore may vote for the overall economically beneficial free

trade agreement.

Page 60: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

54

4.3 Data

To test my empirical model, I constructed a unique data set of 18 votes on trade-

related bills in the U.S. Senate from 1993 to 2013. These bills consist of the granting of

fast-track negotiation authority to the President, the approval of free trade agreements,

and the granting of most favored nation status to China. A complete list of the bills can

be found in table A1 in the appendix. For each bill, I used Congressional records6 to

record the vote (yea, nay, or abstain) and party of each senator, then looked at the

senator’s electoral history to determine if they were within two years (and one year) of an

election at the time of the vote. To create the capital/labor ratio for each state, I used

estimates of the capital stock of U.S. states from Yamarik (2013) for 1990, 2000, and

2013, and divided them by yearly Bureau of Labor Statistics data on the total labor force

size of each state.7 The goods/services ratio takes yearly BLS data on the total

employment in goods-producing industries of each state and divides it by the total

employment in services-providing industries of that state.8 For the retirement variable, I

counted retiring as willfully not running for reelection. Resignations and deaths were not

counted as retirement, because they did not represent willful departure from the office

and therefore would imply that the elected official was still considering electoral

incentives at the time of the vote.

There are several limitations to consider in my data set. First, the capital

estimates for each state are not exact figures and, depending on the bill, may be as many

as 5 years away from the estimate itself. Therefore, there is a chance that the actual

capital-labor ratio of the states I examined could be different than the numbers I have

6 Available from a number of sources, I drew mine from govtrack.us.

7 http://www.bls.gov/lau/staadata.txt

8 http://www.bls.gov/iag/home.htm

Page 61: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

55

used. Second, my justification for using the goods/services ratio is that the U.S. has been

a net importer of goods and a net exporter of services for the last 30 years, allowing

employment in a goods-producing industry to represent import-competing employment,

while working in a services-providing industry to represent export-competing

employment. This is likely an over-simplification, as there may be specific goods that

the U.S. exports, or services that the U.S. imports. Third, I have chosen not to include

interest group campaign donations in my empirical analysis, despite the findings of

Goldberg and Maggi (1999) and Baldwin and Magee (2000) that they have a significant

correlation with votes on trade bills. I chose to exclude campaign donations because I

feel that these may be endogenously determined, that the politician is given a donation

because they already support/oppose trade, not in exchange for supporting/exchanging

trade. This is supported by the work of Rocca and Gordon (2010), who suggest that

politicians signal potential donors with non-committal public speech (i.e. non-roll call

position taking), and thereby receive donations based on their signaled political beliefs,

not in exchange for a particular vote (Rocca & Gordon, 2010). Furthermore, I feel that

party identification does an adequate job of approximating the ideology that would lead

to a senator supporting/opposing free trade, and therefore accounts for the same factors

that would be represented by campaign donations.

An overall picture of the data can be seen in table (2), which shows the summary

statistics of the data set. As we can see, excluding abstentions, we have a total of 1,748

dependent variable data points to analyze, a more than adequate sample size. There are

many interesting observations to be made from the mean values. We see that the mean

vote is .74, indicating that the overwhelming majority of votes are in the “yea” category.

Page 62: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

56

In fact, all of the bills examined here passed (not by design, it just seems that the bills

likely enjoyed majority support even before they went to a vote). The mean

goods/services ratio is .21, and the max is .45, indicating that the overwhelming majority

of jobs in every state in America are in the services sector. We can also see that there is a

large disparity in the capital per laborer between states, with a minimum value of $18,000

and a maximum of $138,000. The data set appears to be reasonably distributed on all

counts, so we will begin our analysis of the empirical results.

Table 2. Summary Statistics

Variable Observations Mean Std. dev. Min. Max.

Vote

1748 .7397025 .4389224 0 1

Election

1748 .3323799 .4712011 0 1

ElectionYear

1748 .256865 .4370293 0 1

Democrat

1748 .4971396 .5001349 0 1

Capital

1748 2.18e+11 2.78e+11 1.66e+10 1.69e+12

Labor

1748 2,906,205 3,123,638 242,599 1.84e+07

CapitalLabor

1748 70,018.09 14,742.25 18,852.6 138,071.3

Goods

1748 449,259 449,681.5 30,300 2,698,100

Services

1748 2,122,683 2,258,849 170,700 1.30e+07

GoodsServices

1748 .2186391 .0657557 .076365 .4489149

Retired 1748 .0709382 .2567951 0 1

Page 63: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

57

5. Results

To test my hypothesis, I ran a probit regression based of the empirical model in

section 4. The results of this regression can be seen in table (3), with the marginal effects

in table (4).

Table 3. Probit Regression

(1)

Election -0.160*

(-2.09)

Democrat -1.056***

(-14.38)

CapitalLabor 0.00000976***

(3.50)

GoodsServices -0.101

(-0.19)

Retired 0.462**

(3.14)

Constant 0.627*

(2.32)

Observations 1748

Pseudo R2 0.123

z statistics in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

Table 4. Marginal Effects of Probit Regression

(1)

Election -0.049*

(0.02405)

Democrat -0.314***

(0.02013)

CapitalLabor 0.00000296***

(0.00000)

GoodsServices -0.031

(0.16514)

Retired 0.118**

(0.03073)

Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

The regression yields a number of interesting results. First, the ideology variable,

Democrat, is significant and in the expected direction, indicating that a Democratic

Page 64: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

58

senator, holding all other independent variables constant, is 31% less likely to vote for a

free trade agreement than a Republican senator. Second, the CapitalLabor variable is

significant and in the expected direction, showing that a one unit increase in the

capital/labor ratio is only associated with a .000003% increase in the likelihood that a

senator will vote in favor of a free trade agreement. This impact may seem small, but our

capital measurements were only in dollars, so this is the impact of just a $1 increase in

capital. Third, the variable Election is significant at the 5% level and in the expected

direction. This result indicates that, ceteris paribus, being within two years of an election

reduces the likelihood that a politician will vote for a free trade agreement by 5%. The

variable Retired is significant in the expected direction, indicating that a retiring

politician is, ceteris paribus, 12% more likely to vote for a free trade agreement. The

only insignificant variable, GoodsServices, is still theoretically relevant, so I will leave it

in the model. In addition, despite its statistical insignificance, its sign is still in the

expected negative direction.

To demonstrate a hypothesis test, we will examine the variable Election. The

probit model uses the normal curve for hypothesis testing, so we will perform a one-sided

z-test. First, let us construct our null and alternative hypotheses:

𝐻𝑜: 𝛽4 ≤ 0

𝐻𝑎: 𝛽4 > 0

Page 65: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

59

The calculated z-statistic is -2.09 (-.1600/.0765 = -2.09), while the p-value for this z-

statistic is .037. Since p < .05, we reject the null hypothesis and conclude that there is

support for our alternative hypothesis that 𝛽4 > 0.

To determine if the impact of time to reelection extended to the politician’s

consideration of the capital-labor ratio, I interacted Election with CapitalLabor and ran

an new probit regression including the interaction term. The coefficient of the interaction

term was insignificant, so I have relegated the results of this regression to the Appendix

in Table A2.

To test for multicollinearity, let us first look at a correlation matrix of the

variables in table (5). We see that none of the variables used here are significantly

correlated (except for Election and ElectionYear, which I do not regress together).

Table 5. Correlation Matrix

Election ElectionYear Democrat CapitalLabor GoodsServices Retired

Election 1

ElectionYear 0.8332 1

Democrat 0.0368 0.0256 1

CapitalLabor 0.0287 0.0649 0.0345 1

GoodsServices

-

0.0335 -0.0905 -0.1875 -0.3405 1

Retired 0.3443 0.2456 0.0729 0.0145 -0.0308 1

Page 66: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

60

Just to be safe, let’s also look at the Variance Inflation Factors of the model in Table (6).

We see that none of the VIF values are remotely close to the rule-of-thumb value of 5,

further suggesting a lack of multicollinearity.

Table 6. Variance Inflation Factors Election

Variable VIF 1/VIF

GoodsServices 1.17 0.852816

Retired 1.14 0.877751

Election 1.14 0.880568

CapitalLabor 1.13 0.882864

Democrat 1.04 0.959289

Mean VIF 1.12

Now, let us test for heteroskedasticity. First, we will examine plots of the

residuals and each independent variable. All of these plots can be found in the appendix,

but here we will more closely examine the variables CapitaLabor (capital/labor ratio) and

GoodsServices (goods/services jobs ratio), since they appear to show the highest

probability of a lack of constant variance in the distribution of the standard errors. These

plots can be seen in figures (7) and (8) below.

Page 67: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

61

Figure (7): Graph of Residuals and CapitalLabor

Figure (8): Graph of Residuals and GoodsServices

Both plots appear relatively homoscedastic, with a lack of any distinct funnel

shape to the residuals. If we are very sensitive, we may see a small indication of

Page 68: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

62

heteroskedasticity in the GoodsServices plot, showing non-constant variance in the

distribution of errors. There is some disagreement on the effectiveness of currently

available corrections for heteroskedasticity in the probit model. The most readily

available method is the hetprobit model in Stata, which uses a standard probit model with

robust standard errors. Since there is no well agreed upon way of testing for and

correcting heteroskedasticity in a probit model, I have chosen to assume

homoscedasticity and proceed with my analysis. For the sake of thoroughness, I have

included tables and discussion of the results of the hetprobit model in the appendix under

tables A7-A8.

The results found in the regression in tables (3) and (4) are all consistent with my

theory, except for the insignificance of the goods/services ratio. This insignificance may

be the result of the limitations of the variable itself, as it is an imperfect representation of

import/export competing industries. There are likely many goods-producing industries

that are net exporters, and some services-providing industries may be net importers.

Also, while the variables insignificance is inconsistent with my theory, its sign is in the

expected negative direction.

The piece of literature which most closely mirrors my own, Conconi et al. (2014),

found a number of comparable results. First, they also found that being within two years

of an election has a significant protectionist impact on the voting of senators, albeit the

magnitude of their observation was slightly larger (~7%) (Conconi et al., 2014, p. 112).

They also find that retirement and being in the Democratic party have a significant

positive impact on the likelihood that a politician will vote in favor of a free trade

agreement. Interestingly, despite a much more specific methodology for identifying the

Page 69: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

63

import/export composition of senator’s constituencies, they too found that this variable is

insignificant (Conconi et al., 2014, p. 112).

In contrast to the findings of Conconi, and the results of the regression detailed

above, I found that being even closer to an election (within one year instead of two), does

not increase the protectionist impact of the electoral incentives, but rather eliminates

them. It is interesting that the effect of electoral incentives seems to disappear within one

year of an election, seen by the insignificance of the variable ElectionYear9 in tables (9)

and (10). It should also be noted that 10 of the 18 bills analyzed were within one year of

an election, allowing for a significantly large sample.

Table 9. Probit Regression with ElectionYear

(1)

ElectionYear -0.0654

(-0.80)

Democrat -1.055***

(-14.38)

CapitalLabor 0.00000973***

(3.49)

GoodsServices -0.0978

(-0.18)

Retired 0.391**

(2.72)

Constant 0.595*

(2.20)

Observations 1748

Pseudo R2 0.121

z statistics in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

9 ElectionYear = 1 if a vote is within 12 months of an election. Election = 1 if a vote is within 24 months of

an election.

Page 70: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

64

Table 10. Marginal Effects of Probit Regression with ElectionYear

(1)

ElectionYear -0.020

(0.02534)

Democrat -.314***

(0.02013)

CapitalLabor 0.00000295***

(0.00000)

GoodsServices -0.0297

(0.166)

Retired 0.103**

(0.03207)

Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

The insignificance of the ElectionYear variable suggests that, while politicians

may oppose trade liberalization more within 1-2 years of an election, this effect my fade

when election draws even closer. It is possible that other considerations drown out the

salience of trade policy within one year of an election, eliminating the protectionist

impact of the increased scrutiny of an electoral cycle. It is also possible that I may be

experiencing omitted variable bias, as I have not included campaign donations in my

empirical model because I assumed they were endogenously determined.

The results of my empirical tests largely support the predictions of my theoretical

model, suggesting that time to reelection may have a significant impact on the trade

policy decisions of a politician. It is also notable that the variable CapitalLabor was

significant and in the expected direction in all specifications, indicating that the capital-

labor ratio of a constituency has a significant impact on trade policy formation. My

results are roughly in line with those of Conconi et al (2014) (aside from the

insignificance of the ElectionYear variable, which they did not consider), further

strengthening my theoretical model.

Page 71: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

65

6. Conclusion

I hypothesized that, as a politician approaches reelection, she will favor more

protectionist policies, because the politician’s utility is based on votes garnered and such

policies are favored by a group of voters in his constituency who have a stronger

incentive to vote based on their trade policy preferences. My empirical analysis supports

my hypothesis and the conclusions of my theoretical model, showing that a U.S. senator

is 5% less likely to vote for a free trade agreement if he is within two years of an election.

Furthermore, my findings suggest that planning to retire eliminates this negative bias

against free trade agreements when approaching election. Other variables that have a

significant impact on the likelihood of supporting free trade agreements include the party

of the senator and the capital/labor ratio of the politician’s constituency.

While my theoretical model is entirely unique, the empirical research of Conconi

et al. (2014) is very similar to my own. However, there are several important differences

between their empirical methods and my own. First, while there is some overlap, we

analyzed different sets of trade bills. I analyze 4 bills since 2005, where Conconi et al.’s

analysis stops. Second, my capital/labor ratio and goods/services variables are unique,

and were not analyzed by Conconi et al. Third, my finding that moving within one year

of an election eliminates the statistical significance of election proximity, suggesting that

further analysis of this issue, using other trade-related issues (e.g. subsidies), may be

necessary.

In terms of the overall literature, my analysis contributes to the substantial field

on the determinants of trade policy, but adds a new section to the much smaller amount

of literature on the impact of election proximity on legislative decision making. As

Page 72: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

66

suggested by Conconi et al. (2014), further research in this area may focus on the impact

of election proximity in more broadly salient legislative issues, such as spending on

national defense or social welfare programs (Conconi et al., 2014, p. 116).

The limitations of my work include the relatively narrow applications of my

theoretical conclusion, which is based on several difficult-to-prove assumptions (such as

a perfect 50-50 split between service workers and shoe producers). Further theoretical

work must be done to expand this theory to allow for more real-world application. My

empirical analysis is limited by its examination of only the U.S. Senate. Future research

within the field of political time horizon and trade policy formation may wish to focus on

other countries to see if the empirical results attained by Conconi et al. (2014) and myself

are robust to changes in electoral systems. It would also be useful to see if the impact of

elections on trade policy holds for other trade-related issues (e.g. subsidies).

The legislative impact of electoral incentives is often discussed but seldom

proved. Anecdotal examples abound, but there is little empirical research done to back

them up. This study is a step in that direction, seeking to theoretically and empirically

support the idea that elected politicians are not completely selfless, and that their desire

for reelection can lead to less than optimal outcomes for their constituents. If citizens in

a democracy want their representatives to vote in their constituents’ interests rather than

their own, it is important to first identify the causal relationship between election

proximity and legislative decision making, so that steps may be taken to alleviate its

negative impacts. This study is an attempt at such an identification, but to collect a

meaningful and noticeable body of literature in the area more work must be done.

Page 73: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

67

6.1 Literature Review Organizational Table

Authors Unit of

Analysis

Data Source Dependent

Variable

Independent

Variables

Empirical

Methodology

Conclusions

Conconi et

al. (2014)

Individual

politicians

(U.S.

Congress, both

House and

Senate)

Cross-sectional

data on U.S.

Congressional

trade votes since

1972

Vote yes/no

on a trade

liberalization

bill

1. Import/export

composition of

constituency, 2.

business/labor

group campaign

contributions, 3.

Ideology (party), 4.

Education level of

constituency, 5.

Time to reelection

(2 years/greater

than 2 years)

Probit. Also use

logit and linear

regressions to

test robustness

of Probit results.

Being within

two years of an

election has

significant

protectionist

impact on

elected

officials’ trade

policy

decisions.

Dutt and

Mitra

(2012)

Countries Cross-sectional

data on levels of

trade barriers,

physical capital

endowment

estimates from

Nehru-Dhareshwar

(1993), level of

democracy

estimates from

Freedom House,

all averaged across

the 1980s

Magnitude of

trade

protection

(various

measures, see

discussion in

section 3.3.

1. Inequality

(defined as Gini

coefficient or share

of third quintile in

national income) 2.

Capital–labor ratio

3. Level of

democracy

4. Educational

Attainment

OLS regressions

and Hausman

test for

endogeneity

An increase in

inequality,

holding

constant the

economy’s

overall relative

endowments,

raises trade

barriers in

capital-

abundant

economies and

lowers them in

capital-scarce

economies.

Page 74: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

68

Goldberg

and Maggi

(1999)

Industries 1. Political

organization data

includes campaign

contributions from

1982 and 1984

U.S. Congressional

elections,

unionization,

industry

employment

size/unemployment

rate, and industry

growth

2. Import demand

elasticity estimates

from Clinton R.

Shiells et al. (1986)

3. Import

penetration ratio

comes from the

National Bureau of

Economic

Research Trade

and Immigration

data file

Level of trade

protection

(represented

by non-tariff

barriers, i.e.

coverage

ratios from

1983)

1. Political

organization

2. Import demand

elasticity

3. Import

penetration ratio

Maximum

Likelihood

1. Trade

protection will

be higher

where

industries are

represented by

a lobby and in

industries with

lower import

elasticity.

2. In organized

industries,

protection

increases with

lower import

penetration

3. In non-

organized

industries,

protection

increases with

higher import

penetration

Page 75: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

69

Baldwin

and Magee

(2000)

Politicians 1. Data on

campaign

contributions from

1992 election,

taken from

Makinson and

Goldstein (1994)

2. Congressional

voting data on

NAFTA, GATT,

and MFN for

China taken from

Congressional

Quarterly Almanac

3. Congressional

district

characteristics

from Census and

County Business

Patterns, union

data from Box-

Steffenmeir,

Arnold, and Zorn

(1997)

4. Data on

representative’s

ideology from

AFL-CIO, ACU,

etc.

Trade Policy

Preference

(yes/no vote

on 3 trade

liberalization

bills)

1. Special interest

group contributions

2. District

characteristics

(education,

income, sector of

employment, etc.)

3. Representative’s

ideology

Full Information

Maximum

Likelihood,

(simultaneously

estimates 3

separate

equations)

Campaign

donations have

a significant

impact on

Congressional

voting on trade

policy.

Donations

from labor

(business)

groups are

correlated with

votes against

(for) trade

liberalization

Beaulieu

(2002)

Individual

constituents

1. Individual-level

data on occupation

from a survey

conducted during

Individual

trade policy

preference

(vote in 1988

1. Industry of

employment

2. Skill

Endowments

1. Maximum-

likelihood logit

models and Cox

test

Industry of

employment

and skill

endowment

Page 76: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

70

the 1988 Canadian

federal election

(Canadian National

Election Survey)

and cross-

referenced with

Canadian census

data to determine

industry affiliation

2. Skill endowment

taken from CNES

educational

attainment data and

implied skill level

of occupation

3. Other control

variables all from

CNES data

election that

was de facto

referendum

on free trade)

3. Other control

variables: region,

age, union

membership, party

affiliation

both have

expected

impact on trade

policy

preference,

suggestive of

partial factor

mobility

Alesina et

al. (1993)

Countries Panel Data on

elections and

economic

indicators on 18

industrialized

democracies form

1960-1987

Annual

budget deficit

(change in

debt-GDP

ratio)

1. Lagged deficit

2. Change in the

unemployment rate

3. Change in the

GDP growth rate

4. Change in the

real interest rate

minus the growth

rate, multiplied by

the lagged debt-

GDP ratio

4. Political

instability

5. An electoral

dummy

Panel

Regression

There is a

relationship

between an

imminent

election and an

increase in the

budget deficit.

This suggests

that politicians

may be subtly

trying to use

fiscal/monetary

policy to

expand the

economy pre-

Page 77: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

71

6. A dummy to

identify left-wing

governments

7. An interaction

term between the

electoral and left-

wing variables

election in

order to signal

their

competence to

voters. This

policy

manipulation

does not result

in positive

economic

indicators like

an increase in

GDP or drop in

unemployment,

but it occurs

nonetheless.

Page 78: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

I

7. Appendix

Table A1. List of Trade Liberalization Bills

Bill Name Date of Vote Result (Y-N-DNV)

1993 Fast Track Authority 6/30/1993 Passed (76-16-8)

NAFTA 11/20/1993 Passed (61-38-1)

WTO 12/1/1994 Passed (76-24)

AGOA Passage 11/3/1999 Passed (76-19-4)

AGOA Conference Report 5/11/2000 Passed (77-19-4)

China PNTR 9/19/2000 Passed (83-15-2)

Andean Trade Preference

Act and Fast Track

5/23/2002 Passed (66-30-4)

Fast Track Conference

Report and Andean TPA

8/1/2002 Passed (64-34-2)

Chile FTA 7/31/2003 Passed (65-32-3)

Singapore FTA 7/31/2003 Passed (66-32-2)

Australia FTA 7/15/2004 Passed (80-16-4)

Morocco FTA 7/21/2004 Passed (85-13-2)

CAFTA 7/28/2005 Passed (55-45)

Oman FTA 6/29/2006 Passed (60-34-6)

Peru FTA 12/4/2007 Passed (77-18-5)

Panama FTA 10/12/2011 Passed (77-22-1)

Colombia FTA 10/12/2011 Passed (66-33-1)

Korea FTA 10/12/2011 Passed (83-15-2)

Page 79: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

II

Table A2. Probit Regression with Interaction Term

(1)

Election -0.358

(-0.94)

Democrat -1.056***

(-14.38)

CapitalLabor 0.00000875**

(2.61)

GoodsServices -0.110

(-0.20)

Retired 0.463**

(3.14)

CapitalLabor x Election 0.00000287

(0.53)

Constant 0.698*

(2.32)

Observations 1748

Pseudo R2 0.123

z statistics in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

Table A3. Marginal Effects of Probit Regression with Interaction Term

(1)

Election -0.113

(0.12488)

Democrat -0.314***

(0.02013)

CapitalLabor 0.00000265**

(0.00000)

GoodsServices -0.033

(0.1652)

Retired 0.119**

(0.03074)

CapitalLabor x Election 0.000000868

(0.00000)

Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

Page 80: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

III

Figure A4: Plot of Residuals vs. Party

Figure A5: Plot of Residuals vs. Retired

Page 81: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

IV

Figure A6: Plot of Residuals vs. Election

Page 82: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

V

Table A7. HetProbit Regression with Robust Standard Errors

(1)

Election -0.258*

(-2.04)

Democrat -1.733***

(-4.60)

CapitalLabor 0.0000108**

(2.65)

Retired 0.722**

(2.58)

Constant 1.305**

(2.63)

lnsigma2

GoodsServices 2.032*

(2.41)

Observations 1748

z statistics in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

Table A8. Marginal Effects of HetProbit Regression with Robust Standard Errors

(1)

Election -0.051*

(0.02322)

Democrat -0.328***

(0.02064)

CapitalLabor 0.00000209**

(0.00000)

Retired 0.118**

(0.03077)

lnsigma2

GoodsServices -0.458*

(0.18975)

Standard errors in parentheses * p < 0.05,

** p < 0.01,

*** p < 0.001

We see that correcting for the potential heteroskedasticity of GoodsServices brings the variable to

statistical significance at the 5% level, while maintaining the significance of all other variables.

While this may seem ideal, I believe (based on the observation of the residuals plot) that

GoodsServices is homoscedastic and therefore correcting for heteroskedasticity with robust

standard errors is resulting in a type 1 error, wherein we are incorrectly rejecting a true null

hypothesis.

Page 83: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

VI

8. Bibliography

Alesina, A., Cohen, G. D., & Roubini, N. (1993). Electoral business cycle in industrial

democracies. European Journal of Political Economy, 9(1), 1–23.

http://doi.org/10.1016/0176-2680(93)90027-R

Austen-Smith, D., & Wright, J. R. (1992). Competitive lobbying for a legislator’s vote. Social

Choice and Welfare, 9(3), 229–257.

Baldwin, R. E., & Magee, C. S. (1998). Is Trade Policy for Sale? Congressional Voting on

Recent Trade Bills (Working Paper No. 6376). National Bureau of Economic Research.

Retrieved from http://www.nber.org/papers/w6376

Beaulieu, E. (2002). Factor or Industry Cleavages in Trade Policy? An Empirical Analysis of the

Stolper–Samuelson Theorem. Economics & Politics, 14(2), 99–131.

http://doi.org/10.1111/1468-0343.00102

Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2011). Industries at a Glance. Retrieved March 22, 2015, from

http://www.bls.gov/iag/

Bureau of Labor Statistics. (2014). Civilian Noninstitutional Population. Retrieved March 23,

2015, from http://www.bls.gov/lau/rdscnp16.htm

Busch, M. L., & Reinhardt, E. (2000). Geography, International Trade, and Political Mobilization

in U.S. Industries. American Journal of Political Science, 44(4), 703–719.

http://doi.org/10.2307/2669276

Conconi, P., Facchini, G., & Zanardi, M. (2014). Policymakers’ horizon and trade reforms: The

protectionist effect of elections. Journal of International Economics, 94(1), 102–118.

http://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.2014.06.006

Crandall, R. W. (1984). Import Quotas and the Automobile Industry: The Costs of Protectionism.

The Brookings Review, 2(4), 8–16.

Page 84: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

VII

Davis, J. H. (2015, February 26). Obama Promotes Benefits of Trade Deals to Workers and

Smaller Businesses. The New York Times. Retrieved from

http://www.nytimes.com/2015/02/27/business/obama-promotes-benefits-of-trade-deals-

to-workers-and-smaller-businesses.html

Drazen, A. (2000). The Political Business Cycle after 25 Years. NBER Macroeconomics Annual,

15, 75–117. http://doi.org/10.2307/3585387

Dutt, P., & Mitra, D. (2002). Endogenous Trade Policy through Majority Voting: an Empirical

Investigation. Journal of International Economics, 58(1), 107–133.

Goldberg, P. K., & Maggi, G. (1999). Protection for Sale: An Empirical Investigation. The

American Economic Review, 89(5), 1135–1155.

GovTrack.us. (n.d.). Retrieved March 23, 2015, from https://www.govtrack.us

Krugman, P. R., Obstfeld, M., & Melitz, M. J. (2012). International Economics: Theory and

Policy (9th ed.). Pearson.

Mayer, W. (1984). Endogenous Tariff Formation. The American Economic Review, 74(5), 970–

985.

Molyneux, G. (1994, February). Unified “Opinion Leaders” Best a Reluctant Public. The Public

Perspective, 28–30.

Rassekh, F., & Thompson, H. (2002). Measuring Factor Abundance Across Many Factors and

Countries. Open Economies Review, 13(3), 237–249.

Rocca, M. S., & Gordon, S. B. (2010). The Position-taking Value of Bill Sponsorship in

Congress. Political Research Quarterly, 63(2), 387–397.

http://doi.org/10.1177/1065912908330347

Smith, R. A. (1984). Advocacy, Interpretation, and Influence in the U.S. Congress. The American

Political Science Review, 78(1), 44–63. http://doi.org/10.2307/1961248

Page 85: The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation ... · The Political Business Cycle and Trade Policy Formation: How Do Electoral Incentives Impact Trade Policy? By Lincoln

VIII

Tullock, G. (2008). public choice. In S. N. Durlauf & L. E. Blume (Eds.), The New Palgrave

Dictionary of Economics (2nd ed., pp. 722–727). Basingstoke: Nature Publishing Group.

Retrieved from http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_P000240

US Census Bureau, D. I. D. (2012). Table A-1. Reported Voting and Registration by Race,

Hispanic Origin, Sex, and Age Groups: November 1964 to 2012. Retrieved March 22,

2015, from

http://www.census.gov/hhes/www/socdemo/voting/publications/historical/index.html

Whaples, R. (2006). Do Economists Agree on Anything? Yes! The Economists’ Voice, 3(9),

1156. Yamarik, S. (2013). State-Level Capital and Investment: Updates and

Implications. Contemporary Economic Policy, 31(1), 62–72.

http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-7287.2011.00282.x

Yamarik, S. (2013). State-Level Capital and Investment: Updates and Implications.

Contemporary Economic Policy, 31(1), 62–72. http://doi.org/10.1111/j.1465-

7287.2011.00282.x