thesis final copy-aisi wang

56
ART AS COLLATERAL: AN OVERVIEW OF THE PRACTICE AND THE MANAGEMENT OF ASSOCIATED RISKS by Aisi Wang Advisor: Prof. Tom McNulty Department of Art and Art Professions Steinhardt School of Culture, Education and Human Development New York University M.A. Final Project Visual Arts Administration Spring 2016

Upload: aisi-aissi-wang

Post on 08-Feb-2017

21 views

Category:

Documents


5 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

ART AS COLLATERAL: AN OVERVIEW OF THE PRACTICE AND THE MANAGEMENT

OF ASSOCIATED RISKS

by

Aisi Wang

Advisor: Prof. Tom McNulty

Department of Art and Art Professions

Steinhardt School of Culture, Education and Human Development

New York University

M.A. Final Project

Visual Arts Administration

Spring 2016

Page 2: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

2

Abstract

Art as Collateral: An Overview of the Practice and the Management of Associated Risks

Aisi Wang

Visual Arts Administration

Spring 2016

This thesis considers the evolution of the market for loans for which fine art serves as the

underlying asset (collateral). The study is justified by the observation that the current market

presents some optimal conditions for fine art loan collateralization. Over recent decades, lenders

and borrowers alike have become increasingly sophisticated in their understanding of the forces –

both positive and negative – that can impact the success of the loan transaction. The benefits of

art-secured financing for various types of lenders and borrowers are identified and described, as

are the various major product offerings. Finally, credit risks and title risks are examined in some

detail, reflecting their impact on the viability of the art-secured financial transaction.

Page 3: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

3

TABLE OF CONTENTS

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT ............................................................................................................ 5

LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS ....................................................................................................... 6

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................ 7

1.1 INTRODUCTION ....................................................................................................................... 7

1.2 LITERATURE REVIEW .............................................................................................................. 8

Art as an asset class .................................................................................................................. 8

Art Risks and Valuation Drivers .............................................................................................. 9

Art Price Indices ..................................................................................................................... 10

The Credit Default Risk ......................................................................................................... 11

Presale Estimates and Downside Risk. .................................................................................. 12

1.3 LIMITATIONS ........................................................................................................................ 13

CHAPTER 2: THE MARKET FOR ART AND FINANCE .................................................. 14

2.1 THE ART MARKET ................................................................................................................ 14

Art Market Performance......................................................................................................... 14

Significant Market Trends ...................................................................................................... 17

2.2 ART AND FINANCE ................................................................................................................ 19

Art Collecting as a Financial Tool ......................................................................................... 19

Major Sectors in Art and Finance .......................................................................................... 20

CHAPTER 3 ART-SECURED FINANCING .......................................................................... 22

3.1 PRODUCTS IN ART-SECURED FINANCING .............................................................................. 22

Art-secured Financing in the Credit Market .......................................................................... 23

Types of Art Loans ................................................................................................................. 26

Page 4: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

4

3.2 LENDING PRACTITIONERS ..................................................................................................... 29

Banks ...................................................................................................................................... 29

Auction Houses ...................................................................................................................... 31

Specialized Lenders................................................................................................................ 34

CHAPTER 4: RISKS AND RISK MANAGEMENT .............................................................. 36

4.1 CREDIT RISK ......................................................................................................................... 37

Collateralization and the Default Risk ................................................................................... 37

Downside Risk and Presale Estimates ................................................................................... 38

Measuring the Downside Risk with Buy-ins.......................................................................... 39

Art Credit Default Swaps ....................................................................................................... 42

4.2 THE TITLE RISK .................................................................................................................... 43

The Uniform Commercial Code ............................................................................................. 44

UCC Article 9 and Section 9-319 Consignment Provisions .................................................. 45

UCC Article 2 and the Applicability of Section 2-326 and 2-403 ......................................... 47

CHAPTER 5: CONCLUSION .................................................................................................. 49

BIBLIOGRAPHY ....................................................................................................................... 51

Page 5: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

5

ACKNOWLEDGEMENT

I would like to express my gratitude to my advisor, Tom McNulty, for his support,

patience, and encouragement throughout my thesis research. His technical and editorial advice

was essential to the completion of this research. He has taught me innumerable knowledge and

insights on the subjects of this study as well as the workings of academic research in general.

Page 6: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

6

LIST OF ILLUSTRATIONS

Figure 2.1 The Global Art Market: Value and Volume of Transactions

Figure 2.2 Global Auction Market 2005-2015

Figure 2.3 Market Share by Value of the Fine Art Auction Market: 2000-2015

Figure 2.4 Global Market Share of the US, UK and China 2006 to 2015

Figure 3.1 KPIs

Figure 3.2 Art Loan Lenders by Interest Rate

Figure 4.1 Hammer Ratio for French Impressionist Paintings

Figure 4.2 Hammer Spread and Fitted Lognormal, Recognizing Buy-ins

Table 3.1 Lenders and Borrowers for Different Types of Art Loans

Page 7: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

7

Chapter 1: Introduction

1.1 Introduction

Taking art as an asset class is no longer a hidden agenda in the art world. According to

Deloitte/ArtTactic’s 2014 report on the art and finance market, 76% of art collectors are buying

art with an investment view1. This number is up from 53% in 2012, implying that the asset aspect

of art is gaining legitimacy among collectors. As an increasing number of Ultra-High Net Worth

Individuals (UHNWIs) are buying and investing in art and collectibles, the financial market is

driven to offer wealthy clients new products. Prior studies on practices in taking art as an asset

class largely investigated art as investment and its performance associated with constantly

improving art indices. Nevertheless, global art buying trends demonstrate a continuous

accumulation of wealth in art, signaling the opportunity for practitioners in both art and finance to

provide a greater variety of art and wealth management services, such as wealth protection, estate

planning, leverage, and value enhancement.

Consequently, the need and demand for art secured lending has increased, because art

secured lending has two merits that other art financial services are unable to deliver: it is an

effective way of enabling art collectors to access equity value in their art collections without

having to sell them, and art lending makes it possible to restructure collectors’ capital into new art

acquisitions or attractive business opportunities, or to refinance existing loans. Market research

conducted in 2015 by Skate’s on the global art-loans market confirms the trend with a

conservative estimate a $100 billion addressable market size for art-secured lending2.

Banks and auction houses have previously been cautious when considering art collections as

collateral for loans. This has largely been because of risks and uncertainty associated with art,

such as liquidity, valuation risk, defective ownership, authenticity risk, and borrower default risk.

The risks could potentially upset the lender by minor issues such as net loss due to high

1 “Art & Finance Report,” accessed [April 4, 2016],

http://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/at/Documents/Tax/art-finance-report.pdf. 2 “Skate’s Report on Global Art-loan Market,” accessed [April 4, 2016],

http://www.skatepress.com/wp-content/uploads/2015/08/Skates_Global_Art-Loans_Report_July_2015.pdf

Page 8: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

8

transaction costs and high storage costs of art or critical issues such as leaving the lender with a

worthless asset or an asset to which it has no access.

In response to the ample space for art-loan growth, developments in the art insurance

industry have been introduced to protect lenders from these types of risks and to potentially open

up opportunities for a much larger art secured lending market in the future. On the other hand,

many specialized lenders have emerged in the past few years, providing alternatives for borrowers

who have limited access to traditional lenders.

This thesis identifies and analyzes various roles in art-secured financing, emphasizing two

critical risks from the lenders’ perspective by assessing risk levels and speculating risk

management approaches, relating the practice of art lending to a greater social context. In

addition, as applied research, this thesis also demonstrates forthcoming developments in the

practice of art collateralization.

This thesis is organized as follows: Chapter 1 features the literature review and

methodology statement; Chapter 2 provides a highlighted assessment of the art market and

addresses the current market for art and finance; Chapter 3 introduces art-secured financing in

detail, from product offerings to motivations and limitations of major types of lenders in the

market; Chapter 4 examines the risks associated with art-secured financing and analyzes

corresponding risk management approaches; and Chapter 5 summarizes the paper’s most

important points.

1.2 Literature Review

Art as an asset class

The perception of works of art is no longer limited to aesthetic consumption that returns

nonmonetary viewing benefits. Findlay3 explains that private banking clients worldwide try to

involve themselves in the art world to present as culturally literate and financially sophisticated.

3 Michael Findlay, The Value of Art: Money, Power, Beauty (Munich: Prestel, 2004), 22.

Page 9: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

9

Gerlis4 demonstrates that art is inevitably an asset class, as it had been the source of income for

several intermediaries such as dealers, auction houses, and the artists themselves. Indeed, Parks’5

study on the Medici Family fortune reveals that the nature of artworks as capital assets dates

back to the 15th

century. In addition, many studies show that works of art can yield a return from

their appreciation in value over time, like other financial assets, with a theoretical and empirical

standpoint beginning with Anderson6 and Stein

7. Anderson differentiates the commercial effects

from psychic effects of art collecting by comparing rate of return on art to that of stocks. Stein

constructs the first art index over the 1946-1948 period, signifying a systematic approach to

taking art as an asset class.

Art Risks and Valuation Drivers

Strategic asset allocation accompanies anything that promises returns, and the Modern

Portfolio Theory (MPT) developed by Markowitz8 suggests that any capitalized asset with

targeted returns should be expected to be associated with proportional risks. When evaluating risk

and uncertainty in the art world, Robertson9 considers the major factors to be liquidity, market

inefficiency due to unparalleled information disclosure, and the valuation risk of art. Robertson

indicates that the art market does not conform to the Efficient Market Hypothesis (EMH), as the

prices do not reflect all published and unpublished data. Coffman10

confirms that purchase

prices for art are rarely quoted when bargained artworks are resold on the organized market, and

intermediaries with more knowledge regularly gain higher profits with lower exposure to risk.

Additionally, as Shleifer11

and Hagstrom12

observe, the risks of an inefficient market are also

4 Melanie Gerlis, Art as an Investment? A Survey of Comparative Assets (London: Lund Humphries, 2014), 67. 5 Tim Parks, Medici Money: Banking, Metaphysics, and Art in Fifteenth-century Florence (New York: W.W. Norton, 2005), 23. 6 Robert C. Anderson, “Paintings as an Investment,” Economic Inquiry: 13-26. 7 John P. Stein, “The Monetary Appreciation of Paintings,” Journal of Political Economy: 1021. 8 H. Markowitz, “Portfolio Selection,” The Journal of Finance 7(1) (1952): 77-91. 9 Iain Robertson, “The Current and Future Value of Art,” in Understanding International Art Markets and Management, ed. Iain

Robertson (London: Routledge, 2005), 228. 10 Richard Coffman, “Art Investment and Asymmetrical Information,” Journal of Cultural Economics: 1-24. 11 Andrei Shleifer, “Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical

Economics, (1999): 369-374. 12 R.G. Hagstrom, “The Essential Buffett: Timeless Principles for the New Economy,” Choice Reviews Online, (2001).

Page 10: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

10

derived from the fact that prices in the art market instantaneously adjust to updated information

available when rational arbitrageurs in the market pursue information disclosure.

The valuation risk associated with art is a more complex issue. Robertson indicates that

unobservable price characteristics, supply and demand factors for different markets, and

institutional interventions result in art prices with greater uncertainty. Skaterschikov13

also

references unobservable price characteristics, such as artist name, size, and year of production, as

art valuation drivers, but these drivers are considered insignificant when determining accurate

price ranges for artwork valuation purposes. Skaterschikov argues that provenance and irrational

premiums are the ultimate factors involving a judgment call. Robertson agrees with

Skaterschikov, validating these factors as influences on the supply and demand sides of the art

market. Conclusions of Becker14

, Bongard15

, Moulin16

, and Bowness17

also reflect Robertson’s

and Skaterschikov’s concepts that the price of a work of art is determined by interactions between

art market participants with various goals.

Art Price Indices

Art price indices are constructed to track the financial performance of art as a

heterogeneous good. Goetzmann and Spiegel18

verify the heterogeneity of art by demonstrating

that art only sells occasionally; no two works of art are identical, there are only a small number of

buyers per work; and art pieces include a private value component. Most studies concerning the

development of price indices examine the risk-return relations between art investment, investment

in other financial assets, and the overall market. Mei and Moses19

, Goetzmann20

, and Pesando21

13 Sergei Skatershchikov. Skate's Art Investment Handbook: The Comprehensive Guide to Investing in the Global Art and Art

Services Market (New York: McGraw-Hill, 2006), 16. 14 H.S. Becker, Art Worlds (Berkley: University of California Press, 1982). 15 W. Bongard, “Kunst Kompass,” Capitol. 16 R. Moulin, The French Art Market: A Sociological View (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers, 1987). 17 A. Bowness, The Conditions of Success (London: Thames & Hudson, 1989). 18 W. Goetzmann and M. Spiegel, “Private Value Components and the Winner’s Curse in an Art Index,” European Economic

Review 39: 549-55. 19 Jianping Mei and Michael Moses, “Art as an Investment and the Underperformance of Masterpieces,” The American Economic

Review 92(5) (2002): 1656-68. 20 William N. Goetzmann, “Accounting for Taste: Art and the Financial Markets over Three Centuries,” The American Economic

Review 83(5) (1993): 1370-76.

Page 11: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

11

use the repeat sale methodology (RSM) to estimate returns in the art market. However, Collins et

al.22

criticize this approach, claiming it is biased for its limited selection of samples. They apply

the hedonic approach to regress the price of each art piece on its characteristics. Hodgson and

Vorkink23

, de la Barre et al.24

, Renneboog and Spaenjers25

, and Bocart and Hafner26

agree on

applying hedonic regression to control variations due to observable differences between

heterogeneous art pieces. They all debate, to some extent, whether RSM can only be viewed

as a nested case of hedonic regression, as it analyzes only identical goods sold through time.

McAndrew and Thompson27

accept both approaches, as the general conclusion has been that art

investment has a low correlation with broad markets and provides a more favorable average

risk-adjusted financial return. Robertson28

remains concerned about most art price indices,

because they often carry strong tertiary market results, although many developing market tertiary

activities are ignored and private sales remain unrecorded.

The Credit Default Risk

To qualify as loan collateral, it must be possible for banks and financiers to quantify the

credit risk involved with any asset. Beaver studies the correlation between financial ratios and

propensity to default in companies, inspiring the quantitative modeling of credit risk29

. Altman

formalizes Beaver’s model in a multivariate framework through classification30

. Merton

21 James E. Pesando, “Art as an Investment: The Market for Modern Prints,” American Economic Review 83(5) (1993):

1075-1089. 22 A. Collins, A.E. Scorcu, and R. Zanola. “Sample Selection Bias and Time Instability of Hedonic Art Price Indexes” (Quarderi –

Working Papers), DSE 610 (2007): 1-19. 23 D.J. Hodgson and K.P. Vorkink, “Asset Pricing Theory and the Valuation of Canadian Paintings,” Canadian Journal of

Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 37 (2004): 629–655. Accessed April 4, 2016.

doi: 10.1111/j.0008-4085.2003.00241.x 24 M. de la Barre, S Docclo, and V. Ginsburgh, “Returns of impressionist, modern and contemporary European paintings

1962-1991,” Annales d’economie et de Statistique, 35 (1994): 143-181. 25 Luc Renneboog and Christophe Spaenjers “Buying Beauty: On Prices and Returns in the Art Market,” Management Science

59(1) (2013): 36-53. Accessed April 4, 2016. doi:10.1287/mnsc.1120.1580. 26 Fabian Y.R.P. Bocart and Christian M. Hafner, “Volatility of Price Indices for Heterogeneous Goods with Applications to the

Fine Art Market,” Journal of Applied Econometrics 30(2) (2013): 291-312. Accessed April 4, 2016. doi:10.1002/jae.2355. 27 Clare McAndrew and Rex Thompson, “The Collateral Value of Fine Art,” Journal of Banking & Finance 31(3) (2007): 589-607.

Accessed April 4, 2016. doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.01.012. 28 Robertson, “Current and Future,” 228. 29 W. Beaver, “Financial Ratios as Predictors of Failure,” Journal of Accounting Research 5 (Suppl.) (1966): 71-111. 30 E. Altman, “Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate Bankruptcy,” Journal of Finance 23 (4),

589-609.

Page 12: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

12

introduces the credit risk associated with interest rates through his structured form model based on

option pricing31

. On the other hand, Frye argues that credit risk is driven by the state of the

economy32

. Kao provides an overview on the theory and approaches of the above credit risk

models33

. Crouhy et al. compare the models and suggest applications to predict risk level34

.

Presale Estimates and Downside Risk.

Ashenfelter explores the institutional details of art auction markets and notes that the daily

functioning of the auction sector plays an important role in price formation and price reporting

processes of art35

. He describes the format of “ascending price” auctions, in which bidding starts

low and keeps increasing until it meets the final “hammer price”. McAndrew and Thompson are

particularly interested in the “reserves” of auction process, recognizing them as selling prices

below which the consignor will not allow the work to be sold. As such, they indicate that reserve

prices act as a clearing mechanism in which works of art can only be bought in by the auctioneer

rather than sold if reserve prices are not met36

. Ashenfelter, Graddy, and Stevens examine sale

records and reserve prices across various auctions, indicating that the reserve price is a constant

proportion of its subjected estimated price37

. Ashenfelter et al. estimate the reserve price to be

near 75% of the low estimate using a random effects probability model38

. This result serves as a

parameter that enables downside risk analysis in relation to the bias between the auction presale

estimates of artwork and achieved market prices. Studies that contribute to this niche area of

31 R. Merton, “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rate,” Journal of Finance 29 (1974): 449-470. 32 Frye, J. “Collateral Damage,” in Credit Risk Modeling: The Cutting-edge Collection: Technical Papers Published in Risk

1999-2003, ed. M. Gordy. (London: Risk Books, 2003), 115-120. 33 D. Kao, “Estimating and Pricing Credit Risk: An Overview,” Financial Analysts Journal 56(4) (2000): 50-66. 34 M. Crouhy, D. Galai, and R. Mark, “A Comparative Analysis of Current Credit Risk Models,” Journal of Finance 24

(2000): 59-117. 35 Orley Ashenfelter, “How Auctions Work for Wine and Art,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(3) (Summer, 1989):

23-36. 36 Clare McAndrew and Rex Thompson, Pre-sale Estimates, Risk Analysis, and the Investment Quality of Fine Art, Unpublished

Manuscript (2003). 37 Orley Ashenfelter, K. Graddy, and M. Stevens, “A Study of Sales Rates and Prices in Impressionist and Contemporary Art

Auctions,” University of Oxford Working Paper (2003): 1-28. 38 Ashenfelter, Graddy, and Stevens, “Sales Rates and Prices,” 1-28.

Page 13: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

13

research include McAndrew and Thompson39

, Ashenfelter et al.40

, Ashenfelter and Graddy41

, and

Ekelund et al.42

.

Several studies question the accuracy and bias of presale estimates. Although mixed results

are observed across various sectors of art, the fine art sector shows an empirical upward bias.

Milgrom and Weber suggest that the “ascending price” auction model is “honest” for sellers43

.

Ashenfelter reiterates Milgrom and Weber’s conclusion by showing that presale estimates are

highly correlated with the price actually received44

. Beggs and Graddy challenge the above,

finding that while honesty may hold in general, there are systematic under and over predictions in

certain circumstances and genres45

. Mei and Moss investigate the “Masterpiece Effect,” where

expensive paintings tend to under-perform their art market anticipation46

. In their later study, Mei

and Moss further analyze art auction price estimates, indicating that there is an apparent upward

bias for ultra-high/high price paintings47

—the artwork discussed in this dissertation.

1.3 Limitations

This study was conducted between Fall 2015 and Spring 2016. All data are gathered from

market reports and materials released before April 2016. Due to the broadening of the practice and

ever-emerging innovations in the niche market of art-secured financing, this study highlights only

matured and representative roles in each layer of analysis. The practitioners are assessed based on

limited publicized information due to their status as privately owned companies.

39 Claire McAndrew and Rex Thompson, “Are Presale Art Auction Estimates Unbiased? Some Affirming Evidence,” Southern

Methodist University Working Paper (2004): 1-31. 40 Ashenfelter, Graddy, and Stevens, “Sales Rates and Prices,” 1-28. 41 Orley Ashenfelter and K. Graddy, “Auctions and the Price of Art,” Journal of Economic Literature 16 (2003): 763-786. 42 Robert B. Ekelund, Rand W. Ressler, and John Keith Watson, “Estimates, Bias and ‘No Sales’ in Latin-American Art Auctions,

1977-1996,” Journal of Cultural Economics 22(1) (1998): 33-42. 43 Paul R. Milgrom and Robert J. Weber, “A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding,” Econometrica 50(5) (1982): 1089–

1122. Accessed April 4, 2016. doi:10.2307/1911865. 44 Ashenfelter, “How Auctions Work,” 23-36. 45 Alan Beggs and Kathryn Graddy, “Declining Values and the Afternoon Effect: Evidence from Art Auctions,” The RAND

Journal of Economics 28(3) (1997): 544-65. 46 Mei and Moses, “Art as Investment,” 1656-68. 47 Jianping Mei and Michael Moses, Are Investors Credulous? Some Preliminary Evidence from Art Auction, Unpublished

Manuscript (2002).

Page 14: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

14

Chapter 2: The Market for Art and Finance

2.1 The Art Market

The term “art market” is often discussed but ambiguous in definition. At its most basic, an

art market is the physical or figurative venue in which art is dealt. Historically, art transactions

have taken place outside the framework of what is now referred to as an art market. Examples

include patronage from the Roman Catholic Church in the European Middle Ages48

and the

porcelain trade from East to West initiated by the English East India Company in the 17th

century49

. Over time, the art market has developed into a global economic infrastructure,

informed by sociopolitical relations and financial vehicles through which art is traded and

exchanged. Subsequently, classifications for today’s art market are conducted through various

lenses that penetrate enormous aspects of the art field. Therefore, this study does not intend to

work within a delineated spectrum of the art market, but will rather take as its subjects of

analysis the market performance and global trends of the current art market.

Art Market Performance

According to the most recent Art Market Report released by The European Fine Art

Foundation (TEFAF), the global art market reached a total of $63.8 billion in 201550

. Although

this number is slightly less than the $68.2 billion total in 201451

, it is important to remember that

2014 saw the market’s highest ever recorded level, and the sales volume in 2015 is still above the

years between the sharp fall in 2009 and the peak of 201452

. This result is observed by TEFAF

from a longitudinal analysis on the yearly total value and volume of transactions between 2005

and 2015 (Figure 2.1). Skate’s Annual Art Investment Report 2015 also confirms the positive

48 F.W. Kent et al., eds., Patronage, Art, and Society in Renaissance Italy (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1987). 49 Margaret Medley, The Chinese Potter: A Practical History of Chinese Ceramics (Oxford: Phaidon Press, 1976): 13, 101, 102. 50 Claire McAndrew, “Key Findings and Summary,” TEFAF Maastricht Art Market Report (2016): 15. European Fine Art

Foundation, Accessed April 4, 2016. 51 Claire McAndrew, “Summary of Key Findings,” TEFAF Maastricht Art Market Report (2015): 21. European Fine Art

Foundation, Accessed April 4, 2016. 52 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 22.

Page 15: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

15

trend of the art market. The Skate’s market research report notes that the value of the top 10,000

most expensive art pieces sold with public records increased by 10% in 201553

. The report

further indicates that the threshold price, which is the lowest price point in Skate’s top 10,000

rating, increased by 9.6% in 201554

. The above statistics suggest a continuous increase in art

prices, and affirm the stability of the global art market.

Figure 2.1 The Global Art Market: Value and Volume of Transactions

Source: Arts Economics (2016)

The driving force of art market performance is auction sales, partly because 47% of global

art market sales come from public auctions55

, but more importantly, dealers and other agents set

the price levels of the remaining 53% (private sales), and their values derive from data culled

from auction and previous retail sales values. After a half decade long recovery from the

trickle-down effect of the global financial crisis and economic recession, the global auction

market has reclaimed the prosperity of 2007 and remained steady and strong (Figure 2.2). Fine

art sales, which include sales of paintings, sculptures, works on paper, and new media arts, have

dominated the auction market in the past decade. In 2015, fine art accounted for an average of

53 “Skate’s Annual Art Investment Report 2015,” accessed [April 4, 2016]. 54 Skate’s, “Skate’s Annual 2015,” 2.. 55 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2016, 27.

Page 16: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

16

69%56

of the total value sold in top-tier auction houses57

. Within the fine art sector, Modern Art

(works by artists born between 1860 and 1920), Post-War Art (works by artists born between

1920 and 1945), and Contemporary Art (works by artists born after 1945) are the leading

categories over the last 15 years, with Post-War and Contemporary Art (combined) achieving the

greatest market share by value in the fine art auction market (Figure 2.3).

Figure 2.2 Global Auction Market 2005-2015

Source: Arts Economics (2016) with data from Auction Houses, Artnet and AMMA.

Figure 2.3 Market Share by Value of the Fine Art Auction Market: 2000-2015

Source: Arts Economics (2016) with data from Artnet

56 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 27. 57 A top-tier auction house is defined by The European Fine Art Foundation as being one with turnover in excess of €50 million

or more than 250 employees.

Page 17: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

17

Geographically, the global art market remains dominated by the three major art markets of

the United States, the United Kingdom, and China, which together account for 83% of total

sales58

. As shown in Figure 2.4, the United States is the largest market by value in the past

decade, a temporary challenge by China in 2011 notwithstanding. From 2012 to 2014, China has

replaced the United Kingdom as the second largest art market worldwide. In 2015, China lost 3%

market share due to a sales contraction in both value and volume; therefore, the United Kingdom

reclaimed second place in terms of global market share.

Figure 2.4 Global Market Share of the US, UK and China 2006 to 2015

Source: Arts Economics (2016)

Significant Market Trends

While private sales through dealers and public sales through auction houses remain the

principal channels for art transactions, the proliferation of art fairs in recent years has created a

more complex sales structure. Art fairs break the traditional art market structure by creating a

competitive environment for collectors. Dealers benefit by the sheer number of collectors who

travel to peruse the offerings of a great many world renowned galleries; their scaled down on-site

inventory, coupled with the large base of collectors present, sets the stage for a level of

commerce that is midway between the rapid-fire auction scenario and the slower, more deliberate

sales conducted in commercial galleries. There are reportedly at least 180 major art fairs with

international elements as of 201459

; minor fairs with national foci, media specialization

(photography, etc.), and/or sector specificity (e.g., Outsider Art) are blooming alongside. In

58 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 23. 59 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 157.

Page 18: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

18

2014, the top 22 fairs selected by TEFAF generated visitors in excess of $1 million, pushing

transactions at art fairs to the second largest revenue source (40% of total) after in-gallery sales

for private dealers60

. Moreover, the trend shows no sign of slowing according to Skate’s, a

leading art business intelligence group. Skate’s major art fairs reports show no year-on-year

decline in visitors in the second quarter of 201561

.

Online art businesses are another greatly visible and widely discussed trend in the current

art market. Largely driven by an expanding global base of buyers, participants in the commercial

art sector such as dealers, auction houses, and other agents have developed online presences and

engaged in e-commerce in recent years. Traditional offline ventures such as Sotheby’s Auction

House and Gagosian Gallery have extended their businesses into the online marketplace. New

companies that are standalone and online-only have also emerged to offer innovative art-related

services; examples of this business type include Artnet, Artsy, and Lofty. Moreover, many

companies have collaborated and partnered on online platforms, adding new layers of sellers and

intermediaries to the art market. In addition to a wider global reach, the online art market also

generates notable sales value. TEFAF conservatively estimates an online art sale of $4.7 billion

in 2015, which accounts for approximately 7% of global art sales62

. However, online art sales by

value are not predicted to see significant growth in the near future. This is mainly because in

2015, 97% of the sales made through online companies were for artworks worth less than

$50,00063

.

Noteworthily, trends in the aggregate size and distribution of the art market closely

correlate to patterns of global wealth, as High Net Worth Individuals (HNWIs)—i.e., individuals

with investable wealth greater than $1 million—represent the major buying force of the art

market in terms of value. Estimates of the distribution of wealth in 2015 from Credit Suisse show

that less than 1% of the world’s adult population owns 45% of global wealth64

. Furthermore,

60 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 157. 61 “Skate’s Art Fairs Report, Summer 2015,” accessed March 27, 2016,

http://www.skatepress.com/art-market-reports/skates-art-fairs-report-summer-2015. 62 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 45. 63 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 51. 64 McAndrew, TEFAF Maastricht Report 2015, 187.

Page 19: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

19

World Wealth Report 2015 from Gap Gemini and RBC Wealth Management suggests that

HNWIs allocates on average about 10% of their investment on arts and collectables65

. Therefore,

patterns of global wealth are strong indicators of art market trends due to HNWIs’ purchasing

power.

2.2 Art and Finance

While art market professionals study collecting patterns of HNWIs as major art collectors,

wealth managers and financiers also join the emergence of art as a financial asset class to provide

their expertise.

Art Collecting as a Financial Tool

Historically, acquiring arts and collectibles has been principally recognized as consumption

out of passion rather than as a means of financial planning. This is mainly because art pieces are

heterogeneous, each having unique aesthetics. Unsurprisingly, their high values make the most

valuable works subject to acts of fraud and/or forgery. Artwork is not highly liquid compared to

some other assets, and art assets are difficult to trade in the short-term due to high transaction

costs. However, the wealth management community considers art an attractive financial tool

over the long run, as it is a store of value and a hedge against inflation that generates positive real

returns66

fueled by an explosion of art prices. This viewpoint is proven by a study based on data

from over 1.2 million fine art auction sales, in which an 11.6% real return is observed from

2002-200767

. In addition to a potential profit, art provides benefits that qualify it as a preferable

financial tool. Foremost, as previously mentioned, art provides a hedge against currency

devaluation and inflation. Additionally, art is proven to have low correlation with other financial

65 Cap Gemini and RBC Wealth Management, “World Wealth Report 2015,” accessed March 28, 2016,

http://www.luxesf.com/wp-content/uploads/2015/08/World_Wealth_Report_2015_Web.pdf. 66 Real return is the annual percentage return realized on an investment that is adjusted for changes in prices due to inflation or

other external effects. 67 Renneboog and Spaenjers, “Buying Beauty,” 36-53.

Page 20: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

20

assets such as bonds, stocks, gold, and oil68

, making art a good investment for a diversified

portfolio. Furthermore, art assets enjoy favorable tax treatment either through direct tax

deductions or charitable donations (as discussed in Chapter 3). More importantly, art assets are

able to act as leverage for additional financial resources, which is referred to as taking art as

collateral for financing.

With a financial management viewpoint, Baird Asset Management, a leading international

firm in the financial service industry, observes that there are three types of collectible buyers,

differentiated by their motivations for art collecting: pure collectors, collector/investors, and pure

investors69

. To be more specific, collectors who aim to build a collection for enjoyment are

recognized as pure collectors; collector/investors have the same drive to collect as pure

collectors, but simultaneously seek monetary returns; and, investors in art collecting are solely

motivated by profit opportunities with no passion for the art. Under this division,

collector/investors and investors in art view collection in financial terms, viewing art collecting

as a financial tool. According to the Art & Finance Report 2014 conducted by Deloitte and

ArtTactic, 76% of art collectors buy art for collecting purposes but with an investment view70

.

This group matches what Baird defines as the collector/investor, which occupies the majority of

the collector population. The wealth management community subsequently responds to this new

demand on an appreciable level, with 88% of family offices and 64% of the private banks

surveyed placing financial planning around art as their strategic focus71

.

Major Sectors in Art and Finance

Although the phenomenon of art as a financial asset class seems is in its early stage, a tacit

relationship between art and finance has existed for centuries. The development of art wealth

management services among financial institutions and art specialists is available at a holistic

68 Gerlis, Art as an Investment, 22. 69 Christopher G. Didier, “Picasso, St. Guadens or Lafite: Does Passion Have a Place in Wealth Management?” Baird Wealth

Management (November 2009): 3, accessed April 4, 2016. 70 Deloitte and ArtTactic,” Art and Finance 2014,” 16. 71 Deloitte and ArtTactic,” Art and Finance 2014,” 12.

Page 21: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

21

scale. With each at a different level of maturity, the following three sectors conclude major

practices in this intersectional field.

1. The Art Advisory Sector

Complexity is a fundamental theme of the art market, which is characterized by the lack of

market transparency and regulation, deficiency in price valuation mechanisms, and the illiquid

nature of art. Art advisory services function as intermediaries to navigate the notoriously difficult

art market for a broad spectrum of practices combining art and finance.

A successful execution in this sector requires that art advisory services cover the whole

lifecycle of art wealth and form partnerships between companies specializing in different aspects

of the art and finance industries. Art advisors are concerned with collectors’ cultivation activities,

such as educational panel discussions and art sponsoring; art collection management, such as

consolidated reporting, philanthropy advice, and art-related inheritance and estate planning; and

sophisticated art and finance integration, such as art insurance, art investment fund, and art

financing.

2. The Art Investment Sector

Investors constantly seek assets that diversify their financial portfolios. Especially in an

economic downturn, assets that have low correlation to traditional investable assets are in

increasing demand. In 2008, when global equity markets fell sharply, the art market continued to

be strong with only a lagging downturn in certain sectors in 2009. Largely fuelled by this

outcome, art assets are now viewed as a viable and attractive alternative investment, and

investors are becoming more confident than ever about strategically allocating wealth in art

investment products.

Products in art investment services are encompassed in art investment funds (or art funds),

which are investment trusts that aim to generate financial returns through the acquisition and

disposition of works of art. Similar to equity funds that invest in stocks, art funds apply a diverse

array of strategies to seek arbitrage opportunities in the art market and maximize capital gains to

redistribute profit to investors.

Page 22: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

22

Other art investment services are offered to support art fund operations, some of the

examples include art fund monitoring, art fund selection, investment viability research, portfolio

management, art fund structuring, and art securitization.

3. The Art Financing Sector

The contemporary scope of art as a financial asset class has contributed to the soaring

value and volume of art trading, which subsequently provides significant impetus for the

development of art financing. Art financing (also referred to as art-secured lending/financing and

art as collateral) is the practice in which individuals, institutions, or business entities borrow

money against their works of art. This practice essentially liquidizes the traditionally illiquid art

asset by unlocking the value of the collateralized works of art without selling them.

By targeting at the liquidity risk of fine art, art-secured financing provides additional

stability to the art market. For instance, when financial urgencies present, art wealth owners have

the alternative to source money from borrowing against art based on its market value rather than

selling the art at an irrational price. For fine art buyers, the potential to finance a purchase

enables buyers to seize market opportunities at their best, increasing the accountability of art

prices in the market. As a result, successful practices in art-secured financing add depth to the art

market; therefore, subjects of this study analyze the practice and its involved risks to help explain

art-secured financing.

Chapter 3 Art-secured Financing

3.1 Products in Art-secured Financing

Today’s product offerings in art-secured financing have been largely shaped by lessons

learned in the past. Lenders in the booming art market in late 1980s, when art-secured financing

was initially formalized, endured tremendous difficulties following the market crash in the early

1990s. In recent years, with greater market transparency provided by online databases and a

Page 23: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

23

steadily strong art market performance, fine art financiers have returned to the market with

art-secured financing products that are better structured and more mature. Art-secured financing

products, or art loans, are essentially asset-based financial loans that take art as collateral. As an

instrument in the credit market, an art loan can be secured by either the art assets alone or by

adding extra recourse to the borrower’s full credit. In addition, a myriad of loan structures and

business models are available to address various needs for borrowers.

Art-secured Financing in the Credit Market

As previously mentioned, art-secured financing, or art loans, falls under the category of

asset-based lending in the credit market. The underlying asset (in our case, art) gives value to the

loan, and that value is subject to appreciation or depreciation (increase or decrease in market

price in the case of art assets) over time according to market forces. The underlying asset is also

the collateral that serves as a security to the lender. In another words, if the borrower defaults or

violates the promised repayment agreement, the lender can seize the collateral and attempt to

recoup their lending costs and losses. Because the borrower is in debt to the lender when

asset-based lending is active, the borrower is also called the debtor and the lender is called the

creditor in this discussion. Furthermore, due to its nature in the credit market, the art loan is often

interchangeably referred to in this study and many others as art-secured lending/financing,

art-backed lending/financing, art-secured/art-backed loan, or loan taking art as collateral.

The amount of capital available from an art loan, or the borrowing base, is determined by

the value of the collateralized art as well as the assigned advance rate. The advance rate, which is

referred to as the loan-to-value (LTV) ratio in loan risk assessment, reflects the maximum

portion of the collateral’s value that the lender can issue as loan capital. For example, if a

collateralized painting is appraised at $1 million of collateral value, and the loan risk assessment

derives an advance rate of 45%, then the maximum capital the borrower can receive is $450,000.

This is calculated as:

Advance Rate = 𝐴𝑑𝑣𝑎𝑛𝑐𝑒 𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡

𝐴𝑝𝑝𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑠𝑒𝑑 𝑉𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝐶𝑜𝑙𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑙𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑑 𝐴𝑟𝑡

Page 24: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

24

Borrowing Base = Appraised Value of Collateralized Art x Advance Rate

Loan-To-Value Ratio = 𝐿𝑜𝑎𝑛 𝐴𝑚𝑜𝑢𝑛𝑡

𝐴𝑝𝑝𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑠𝑒𝑑 𝑉𝑎𝑙𝑢𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑡ℎ𝑒 𝐶𝑜𝑙𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑙𝑖𝑧𝑒𝑑 𝐴𝑟𝑡

Borrowing Base = Appraised Value of Collateralized Art x Loan-To-Value Ratio

The advance rate and LTV is updated regularly to reflect changes in the value of the collateral.

Therefore, a periodic reevaluation is often employed to adjust the borrowing base.

In the case of taking art as collateral, LTVs and advance rates ranging from 25% to 60%

are observed from researchable lenders in the current market72

. Compared to LTVs clustered

within the range of 70%-80% from loans based on other assets73

, the much lower rates with

greater variation of LTVs in art loans reflect the risky nature of art assets, meaning the value of

art assets is relatively more likely to see greater fluctuations. In addition, conservative rates also

disclose the lenders’ discretion on the effectiveness and efficiency of liquidating the art collateral

upon default.

The uncertainty of art price fluctuation also induces an ongoing debate on approaches to

appraise the value of underlying art collateral. One trend is to apply Fair Market Value (FMV) to

art loans and address risk through LTV and advance rate. The Fair Market Value (FMV) is the

price that property sells for on an open market between a willing buyer and willing seller, with

neither being required to act and both having reasonable knowledge of the relevant facts74

. The

adoption of FMV is commonly seen in art loans from lenders who also possess selling divisions

in their businesses, such as auction houses, in which the FMV also serves as selling estimates

when the loan is terminated with sale of the collateralized art (as discussed in the following

sections). On the other hand, specialized lenders who only practice art financing oppose the

72 Skate’s, The Global Art Loans Market Report: Art Lenders Directory (New York: Skate’s Press, 2015): 2. 73 Nick Timiraos and Annamaria Androitis, “Mortgage Lenders Ease Rules for Home Buyers in Hunt for Business,” Wall Street

Journal, April 18, 2014, accessed April 8, 2016, http://www.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702304626304579509463522046346?mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsColle

ction. 74 IRS, “Determining the Value of Donated Property,” Publication 561, April 2007, accessed April 9, 2016,

https://www.irs.gov/publications/p561/ar02.html#d0e139.

Page 25: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

25

adoption of FMV, because fire sales upon borrowers’ defaults often have insufficient time on an

open market, reducing the assets’ exposure to potential buyers and hindering the opportunity to

realize the appraised fair market price. Therefore, specialized lenders adopt the liquidation value,

or fire sale value, which is much lower than FMV assuming that the liquidation is compelled and

executed in an exposure period less than market normal. As a result, either FMV or liquidation

value is reasonable depending on the type of lenders and the type of art loans. Additionally, the

issued loan capital (borrowing base) is determined on both collateral value and the associated

advance rate and LTV. The ultimate borrowing base should reflect all considerations of potential

risks, no matter which valuing approach is applied, when appraising the collateral value.

The term length, or tenor of art loans is generally expressed in months and days. Tenors on

asset-based lending are normally decided by the lifespan of the underlying asset. For example,

housing mortgages have tenors ranging from 15 years to 40 years, reflecting the fact that houses

are most likely to amortize at a dramatic level after 15 to 40 years from the loan issued. In the

case of art as collateral, tenors range from 1 to 60 months depending on the type of art loan

applied. The relatively short tenors on art loans do not respond to the lifespan of art, because art

does not amortize due to its esthetic value; rather, the short tenors are assigned due to the volatile

price of art.

Interest rates on art loans are largely influenced by the overall credit worthiness of the

borrower and the loan structure. In cases when borrowers have lower than expected credibility in

relation to the requested amount of loan capital, lenders often offer recourse loans to secure their

interests without a soaring interest rate. A recourse loan is guaranteed by the borrower’s full

credit in addition to the art collateral. It allows the lender to liquidate the borrower’s unpledged

assets with, or even prior to, the underlying asset in case of default. A nonrecourse loan, on the

other hand, is solely secured by the art collateral. Due to the illiquid nature of art assets, lenders

in a nonrecourse art loan undertake much higher risk than those in a recourse art loan in default

scenarios. Therefore, a higher interest spread is assigned to nonrecourse loans to protect the

lender’s interest. Although varying by client and loan size, recourse loans offered by Citi Private

Page 26: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

26

Banks carry interest rates at 2%-3%, whereas interest rates on nonrecourse loans from Tutela (a

specialized lender) start at 8%75

.

Types of Art Loans

Art loans are structured to support various transaction motives. Collectors may borrow

against art to finance new acquisitions. Art dealers may use business lending to expand working

capital. Speculators may constantly leverage art assets to fund other investments. While the most

common art loans are in the form of term loans, bridge loans, and lines of credit, innovative

lending practices such as sell-leaseback and other customized loan programs have emerged to

accommodate needs enabled by art assets.

1. Term Loan

A term loan is a regular loan for a specific amount of capital. It is repaid in regularly

scheduled payments over a set period of time. Each repayment amount is fixed and consists of both

principal and interest in order to retire the debt at the set maturity date. The interest rate can be

either fixed or variable, and is dissimilar to different types of lenders (as discussed in Chapter 3.2).

Art-secured term loans are commonly extended for a period between 1 to 5 years, whereas a few

lenders offer tenors up to 10 years. Term loans are widely used by art dealers to raise working

capital, as well as by art foundations and museums to fund operating expenses and long-term

projects. Individuals and corporate collectors can use term loans to fund new acquisitions and

other investments, re-finance existing debts, and generate supplement cash flows.

2. Line of Credit

A line of credit is a loan arrangement with a maximum loan balance for the borrower to

withdraw. The credit balance can be drawn down at any time as long as the borrower does not

exceed the maximum set in the agreement. The advantage of a line of credit over a regular loan

is that interest is charged only on the used amount, which represents cost savings for borrowers

who do not spend the loan amount all at once. Lines of credit are extended to businesses,

75 Skate’s, Art Lenders Directory, 2.

Page 27: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

27

individuals, and special purposes. Interest rates, tenors and repayment schedules are varied based

on the goals of borrowing. For example, a gallery may obtain a line of credit to fund its

participation in international art fairs. The line is to be withdrawn as the expenses occur on the

project, and the outstanding balance will be repaid when the business cycle of art fairs ends. A

general-purpose line of credit may have a more regular repayment schedule, but it all depends on

the use cycle of the loan. Thus, lines of credit may have irregular repayment schedules, and the

tenors may revolve. Interest rates range from 2% to 20% based on the type of lender and the

loan’s purpose.

3. Bridge Loan

A bridge loan is usually a short-term loan that provides temporary cash flow to “bridge the

gap” between times when financing is needed. It serves as interim financing for individuals and

businesses for many different situations. A popular type of bridge loan in art-secured lending is

in the form of an advance, which constitutes a settlement in advance of a transaction. For

example, a collector has consigned a work of art for an auction sale in the short-term future but is

in need of urgent liquidity. An advance is set up to provide him/her with money prior to the sale

of the art and is repaid by the proceeds of the eventual sale. The advance is essentially a bridge

loan and is often referred to by many lenders as bridge-to-sale. Bridge loans are also commonly

used in estate settlements. For example, people who have inherited an art collection often

encounter large estate and other inheritance taxes that are usually due within a short period of

time. Inheritors of modest means can raise money quickly through bridge loans, settling the

estate and then repaying the loan after the art is sold. Bridge loans are typically extended for 6 to

18 months with higher interest rates than other types of art loans.

4. Innovative Art Loans

Inspired by major forms of art loans and their features, many innovative practices in

art-secured financing are tailored to provide services to owners of art. Sale-leaseback is one of

the trendy forms that have emerged in recent years. A sale-leaseback is a transaction in which the

owner of an art collection sells the collection to a specialized financier and then simultaneously

Page 28: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

28

leases the collection back at a yearly rate. This kind of transaction can often finance up to 80% of

the appraised value of the art collection and offer the option to lessees to buy back the collection

at any time during the lease. This form of financial arrangement is best for corporate collectors

and real-estate types of borrowers, because it reduces investment and maintenance costs in

non-core business assets and liberates cash in exchange for executing a lease. Moreover, the

leasing feature favors corporate collectors in particular, because lease payments are subject to

qualify as a tax-deductible expense.

Many other products and services associated with art loans are developed to target various

cross-sectional areas. Some examples include insurance trusts borrowed against the trustee’s art

collection to pay for the trustee’s life insurance policy, and charitable contributions are arranged

through art loans, enabling donors to retain ownership of their art and receive possible tax

deductions. The following table provides a broad view of types of lenders and borrowers

associated with the major types of art loans. The three types of major lenders are discussed in

detail in the next section.

TYPE OF LOAN TYPE OF LENDER TYPE OF BORROWER

Term Loan Banks

Auction Houses

Specialized Lenders

Individuals

Art Dealers

Museums and Foundations

Line of Credit Banks

Specialized Lenders

Individuals

Art Dealers

Trust and Estates

Museums and Foundations

Bridge Loan Auction Houses

Specialized Lenders

Individuals

Art Dealers

Lease-back Agreement Specialized Lenders Corporate Collectors

Hotel/Real Estate Collector

Table 3.1 Lenders and Borrowers for Different Types of Art Loans

Page 29: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

29

3.2 Lending Practitioners

Art-secured financing integrated within banks and auction houses have dominated the

current market by value; however, specialized lenders that practice stand-alone art lending have

emerged rapidly over recent years to acquire market shares by offering diversified services.

Although each type of lender obtains competitiveness from its core function, limitations apply.

In addition, due to opaque finances and nuanced operations, limited information is accessible for

a more comprehensive analysis on lenders’ practices.

Banks

Private banks and wealth management divisions of commercial banks have long

approached art loans as additional commercial loan products for existing clients. Given the lack

of established players in this jointed segment, some private banks and wealth management

offices have employed the niche play to differentiate themselves from other banks and to create a

holistic view of their clients’ wealth. Art loans from private banks and wealth management

offices are normally extended to existing clients who have qualified as private banking clients

and who have placed significant assets under management with the bank. Therefore, art loans

from banks are typically offered as full recourse loans against the general credit of the client,

with a slight premium to the respective client’s interest margin for other secured loans76

. One

exception is Emigrant Savings Bank, a subsidiary of Emigrant Bank, which is a pioneer among

traditional bank lenders in that it offers art loans without requiring clients to have other assets

under the bank’s management. Emigrant Savings Bank also differs from other traditional bank

lenders in product offerings, minimum loan sizes, and loan terms.

Although terms vary between banks and clients, most well-established private banks and

wealth management offices issue loan sizes of $5 million or more77

. Some of the leading

practitioners in this group include Citi Private Bank, US Trust (the Bank of America Private

76 Skate’s, The Global Art Loans Market Report: Type of Art Loans and Other Market Practice (New York: Skate’s Press,

2015): 7. 77 Skate’s, Type of Art Loans, 7.

Page 30: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

30

Wealth Management), Deutsche Bank, J.P. Morgan Private Bank, and Royal Bank of Canada.

Moreover, a few banks such as Citi Private Bank, US Trust, and Privatbank Berlin require the

minimum value of collateralized collection to be $10 million, with each piece being valuable

works of fine art by a well-known artist78

. Because borrowers financing at this scale are most

likely to be the best clients of the banks, interest rates applied on their art loan transactions are

typically based on the London interbank offered rate (LIBOR)79

and the prime rate80,81

.

Renewable lines of credit and fixed term loans with LTV up to 50% are the most common art

loans issued by bank lenders.

It is noteworthy that UBS, a renowned Swiss global financial service, closed its art-lending

business a few years ago due to the complexity in effecting the pledge over art assets. This case

uncovers several obstacles for banks practicing art-secured lending, despite the fact that banks

generally enjoy unrestrained funding and the most credit-worthy borrowers. To be more specific,

banks tend to avoid employing an in-house art specialist team (with the exception of Citi Private

Bank, which established its Art Advisory and Finance Service in 1979), as maintaining an

in-house team is capital intensive and challenging from an expertise perspective. In other words,

the scope of expertise and experience of in-house art advisory services must be comparable in

quality to the financial offerings delivered by the banks, which may induce tremendous cost and

diminish the profitability of an art lending operation. Moreover, most traditional bank lenders

outsource required art-related services separately to support different stages of art-lending

practice while protecting the banks’ interests. Outsourcing further complicates art-lending

practice in private banks and wealth management offices, because risks in valuation and

management of the underlying art assets inevitably increase, whilst loan terms have to stay

favorable to maintain wealthy and credit-worthy clients.

78 Skate’s, Art Lenders Directory, 2. 79 LIBOR is the world’s most widely used benchmark rate that some of the leading banks charge each other for short-term loans.

It serves as the reference rate for debt instruments, including government and corporate bonds, mortgages, student loans, and

credit cards. LIBOR is usually lower than the prime rate in real-time. 80 The prime rate is the interest rate that commercial banks charge their most credit-worthy customers. It is the lowest interest

rate that banks offer commercially. 81 Clare McAndrew and Suzanne Gyorgy, Fine Art and High Finance: Expert Advice on the Economics of Ownership (New York:

Bloomberg Press, 2010): 124.

Page 31: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

31

Auction Houses

As of June 30, 2015, Sotheby’s financial segment is reportedly the world’s largest lender in

art-secured financing, according to accessible information82

. This achievement may come

alongside the overall strong performance of auction businesses in recent years, as auction houses

offer loans in the form of consignment-based advances to link transactions from the agency

segment and the finance segment. These art loans are ancillary to consigned works of art, where

the borrowers are contractually committed to sell the works through the agency segment of the

auction houses in the near future and to pay off the loan with proceeds upon the eventual sale.

The consigner advance loan may have emerged due to the seasonality of the auction market, in

which principal sales are held biannually in the second and fourth quarter of the year. Advance

loans, which lend money to prospective consignors prior to the sale of the art, benefit clients in

need of emergent liquidity83

and the auction houses who see more business for their agency

segment. Auction houses also issue term loans for general purposes as their art-secured financing

segment vertically integrates into their organization. As Sotheby’s self-identifies in its 2015

Annual Report, the auction house’s finance segment is a competitive niche lender in the

art-secured financing market, because “through a combination of its art expertise and skills in

international law and finance, it has the ability to tailor attractive financing packages for clients

who wish to obtain immediate access to liquidity from their art asset.”84

Although the client’s overall credit worthiness remains a factor in considering whether to

issue a loan to a client, the loan terms are determined by the value of the art itself. It is an

outcome of the vertical connection between the two segments within an auction house, where

values appraised by the finance segment for loan purposes are obliged to reflect the presale

estimates by the agency segment when consignor-advanced loans mature or term loans default.

82 Skate’s, The Global Art Loans Market Report: Existing Market Size and Segmentation (New York: Skate’s Press, 2015): 4. 83 This is commonly the case because the supply side of the auction market has mostly been driven by death, debt, and divorce.

See Richard M. Smith, “The Art of Auctions: Christie's CEO Edward Dolman,” Newsweek (February 11, 2010), accessed April 12,

2016, http://www.newsweek.com/art-auctions-christies-ceo-edward-dolman-74999. 84 Sotheby’s, Annual Report 2015 (New York: Sotheby’s, 2016), accessed April 12, 2016,

http://investor.shareholder.com/common/download/download.cfm?companyid=BID&fileid=881557&filekey=17B2C0B6-51EA-

42AF-AE18-6D2DD7C34ADB&filename=2015_annual_report.pdf.

Page 32: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

32

Christie’s and Sotheby’s generally offer an advance rate and LTV between 40% and 50% and

refer to the artwork’s average or low estimates for auction or private sale in deciding the

appraised base value85

. The interest rate charged by auction houses varies from loan to loan.

According to an interview with a senior executive at a major auction house in New York86

,

consignors’ advances are sometimes issued at a 0% interest rate during peak selling seasons to

anchor consignments for the agency segment, and revenues in these cases are only generated

from set-up and termination fees and the seller’s commission upon sale. Normally, art loans

issued by auction houses are priced at prime plus a 2% to 3% premium regardless of loan type87

.

In recent years, some auction houses, such as Sotheby’s, intend to carry a variable market rate of

interest to remain competitive with traditional bank lenders and non-bank specialized lenders

(this type of lender is analyzed in later sections)88

.

Compared to traditional bank lenders and specialized art loan providers, the principal

limitation of auction houses in operating art-secured financing may lie in their source of capital,

or funding facilities, for art loans. Prior to 2014, Sotheby’s predominately funded its finance

segment with operating cash flows from its agency segment. This business model is believed to

restrict the finance segment’s aggregate capability to underwrite art loans and affects the rate of

return of Sotheby’s overall operations. In order to expand financial services without costing

liabilities for its agency segment, Sotheby’s began to debt-finance its loan portfolio by

establishing a dedicated revolving credit89

facility in 201490

. The separate capital structure

allows the finance segment of Sotheby’s to borrow from a line of credit backed by a syndicate of

lenders led by General Electronic Capital, which has funded a substantial portion of pre-existing

loans and will fund further the growth of art lending activities91

. This debt-funding strategy has

85 McAndrew and Gyorgy, “Fine Art,” 123. 86 Angelo K.H. Chan, “Art as Collateral: Seeking Returns from Lending vs. Owning,” PhD Dissertation, New York: Sotheby’s

Institute of Art, accessed April 14, 2016,

http://ezproxy.library.nyu.edu:2048/login?url=http://search.proquest.com/docview/1728065256?accountid=12768. 87 McAndrew and Gyorgy, “Fine Art,” 123. 88 Sotheby’s Annual Report 2015, 6. 89 Revolving credit is a type of loan that allows a company to borrow, repay, and reborrow as needed over the life of the loan

facility or agreement. It is commonly structured without a scheduled repayment, and on an interest-only basis. 90 Sotheby’s Annual Report 2015, 7-8. 91 Katya Kazakina, “Sotheby's Boosts Art-Loan Financing With $1 Billion Line,” Bloomberg.com, June 23, 2015, accessed April

15, 2016, http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-06-23/sotheby-s-boosts-art-loan-financing-with-1-billion-line.

Page 33: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

33

proven effective according to Sotheby’s Financial Segment KPIs (Figure 3.1), in which the

Finance Revenue Margin92

increased from 8.1% in 2014 to 8.9% in 201593

. Although funding

structures of all other auction house lenders that are privately held remain inaccessible, it is

reasonable to conclude from Sotheby’s case that in-house funding capital may restrict the

expansion of art-secured lending for auction house lenders, and debt-financing may be a feasible

solution to this limitation.

Figure 3.1 KPIs

Source: Sotheby’s 2015 Annual Report

92 Represents the annualized margin of total client paid and intersegment finance revenues in relation to the Average Loan

Portfolio. 93 Sotheby’s Annual Report 2015, 33-34.

Page 34: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

34

Specialized Lenders

While banks and auction houses favor clients and loans within a very specific and narrow

range, specialized lenders in art-secured financing have emerged in recent years to target

borrowers who seek more diverse options in art loans. As nonbank entities, specialized lenders in

art-secured financing often provide non-recourse loans solely against the appraised value of the

art collateral rather than the credit worthiness of the borrowers. Moreover, loan sizes offered by

this group of lenders are relatively small (in the art market), which range from $100,000 to $5

million compared to thresholds of $1 million in major auction house lenders and $5 million in

leading traditional bank lenders94

. Additionally, since the specialized lenders most likely assess

only the marketability and ownership of the collateral, art loans from these entities are usually

issued in a timely manner. In this regard, specialized lenders are particularly attractive to

borrowers who are rich in valuable art assets but lack in certain requirements from banks and

auction houses, and/or fine art owners who are in need of urgent cash flow. Typical examples

include people who have inherited an art collection and who want to leverage the collection’s

value to settle estate and inheritance taxes, and gallery owners who need additional liens of

working capital to run their businesses.

Similar to other types of lenders, most specialized lenders likewise extend LTVs on art

loans to up to 50% of the appraised value of the collateral95

. However, interest rates offered by

these entities are considerably high compared to those of bank lenders and auction house lenders,

and are drastically diverse within the spectrum of the specialized lenders group. As observed in

Figure 3.2, with recent entrants to this niche market and art loans of similar types and tenors,

Borro charges interest rates at 12% to 30%, whereas Falcon Fine Art spreads the rate from 8% to

10%. Although other factors count, the drive of such high and dissimilar interest rates lies in the

funding structures of the lenders. Specialized lenders have varied sources of funding with

different levels of cost. For example, Falcon Fine Art, a subsidiary of the British Falcon Group,

94 Skate’s, Type of Art Loans, 7. 95 As previously mentioned, specialized lenders commonly use liquidation value rather that fair market value in appraising art

collateral.

Page 35: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

35

which has over 20 years of experience in structured finance and asset-based lending, is funded

directly by British Falcon Group’s balance sheet96

. This explains the up to 10% interest rate by

Falcon Fine Art, where in-house funding is relatively inexpensive. On the other hand, Borro is a

startup financial technology company that promises returns to its 10 venture capital investors

from six rounds of equity financing97

. Borro essentially establishes a leveraging facility that

passes down the high cost of funding to art loan borrowers through interest.

Figure 3.2 Art Loan Lenders by Interest Rate

Source: www.skatepress.com

Another often discussed but inconclusive cause of the exorbitant interest rates involves a

strategy called “loan-to-own”. The strategy is often observed among pawnbrokers, where loans

are structured to induce default in exchange for greater gain from selling the collateral. A study

on secured lending and default risk has proven that a combination of low collateral requirements

and high interest charges discourages the repayment of loans98

. Consequently, specialized

lenders may aim to employ usurious interest rates to encourage default, resulting in an ultimate

gain of at least 50% of the collateral’s value plus substantial interest revenue.

96 Alasdair Whyte, “Falcon Fine Art,” Private Art Investor, October 8, 2014, accessed April 17, 2016,

http://www.privateartinvestor.com/art-finance/falcon-fine-art-we-have-the-money-and-we-are-ambitious-789/. 97 CrunchBase, “Borro,” CrunchBase, April 8, 2016, accessed April 17, 2016,

https://www.crunchbase.com/organization/borro#/entity. 98 A.W.A. Boot, A.V. Thakor, and G.F. Udell, “Secured Lending and Default Risk: Equilibrium Analysis, Policy Implications

and Empirical Results,” The Economic Journal 101(406) (1991): 458.

Page 36: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

36

Chapter 4: Risks and Risk Management

Lenders holding art as collateral confront multifaceted risks from the nature of art and its

market, as well as from the essence of collateralization. As previously mentioned99

, works of art

are heterogeneous, illiquid, and intrinsically valuable. The art market is characterized by market

segmentation, information asymmetry, and behavioral anomalies. As an asset class, fine art poses

the same types of risk as those associated with other types of assets. Collateralization adds

another layer of complication by placing fine art in the credit market.

This paper addresses risks associated with art-secured financing in two classifications:

financial and non-financial. Financial risks include credit issues associated with taking art as

collateral and fluctuations of fine art prices caused by art market volatility. Non-financial risks

include various uncertainties, such as authenticity, storage quality, security, ownership, and the

character of the borrower, among others.

Financial risks associated with fluctuations of fine art prices have been frequently

discussed in studies of taking art as an asset class. Art indices have been constructed in the past

few decades to track and interpret fine art prices. Standard financial risk metrics have also been

applied to lead hedges against several anticipated market volatilities. Therefore, this paper

focuses on credit risk in the financial risk category, as credit risk in regard to art-secured lending

is a relatively underdeveloped area. For the non-financial risk category, this paper emphasizes

the title risk among all others, as the loss induced is financially devastated and physically

irreversible at the same time100

. For both focused risk analyses, this study takes the lender’s

perspective.

99 See 1.2 Literature Review, “Art Risks.” 100 Although any non-financial risk can cause unfavorable losses, sophisticated insurance products are available to either cover

the financial loss or transfer the risk. However, in the case of title risk, the time-consuming legal dispute generates extravagant

legal fees in addition to the loss of ownership of the property, even if the property loss is covered by title insurance.

Page 37: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

37

4.1 Credit Risk

When art assets underlie secured loans, the credit risk of collateralization spontaneously

embeds the risk of art. This section identifies the collateral shortfall caused by the downside risk

of art as one of the core credit risks for art secured lending. It further demonstrates customized

risk quantification models that incorporate “buy-in” records. Lastly, art credit default swaps

(ACDS) are introduced as risk management products for lenders holding art as collateral.

Collateralization and the Default Risk

The use of collateralization in the credit market is fundamentally a response to adverse

selection and moral hazard101

. In a market characterized by contracting parties’ inevitably having

asymmetric information, lenders regularly offer average-priced loan contracts to sort out

borrowers of different risk levels. Borrowers with low risk can more readily find cheaper

alternatives, and will therefore likely shun the offer, while those borrowers who agree to the

terms are evidently higher risk, thus, resulting in adverse selection. Moreover, moral hazard

holds that the borrower’s incentive to repay is tested through his/her willingness to pledge as

much collateral as the lender requires. As a result, collateralization carries inherent risks of

lending, as it secures the adversely chosen loan contracts and serves as an incentive mechanism

of repayment.

Correspondingly, a study on credit control in imperfect markets suggests that lenders ration

credit rather than raise the interest rate in order to incorporate negative adverse selection and

incentive effects102

. To approach the proposed rationing, lenders must quantify two essential

elements of credit risk: the probability of default (PD) and the loss given default (LGD). The PD

estimates the likelihood that a borrower fails to meet his/her/its loan obligations, whereas the

LGD calculates the fraction loss due to default. In the past four decades, these two credit

parameters have been frequently used in credit risk assessment models on collateralizable asset

101 J.E. Stiglitz and A. Weiss, “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information,” American Economic Review (1981). 102 J.E. Stiglitz and A. Weiss, “Incentive Effects of Terminations: Applications to the Credit and Labor Markets,” American

Economic Review (1983).

Page 38: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

38

classes103

. In other words, the risk management of collateralization relies on quantifying PD and

LGD associated with the underlying asset class.

A detailed analysis of the PD, which derives from the obligator’s capacity to repay the debt

in accordance with contractual terms104

, is beyond the scope of this paper. The focus of the

analysis of risk and risk management in taking art as collateral is in the assessment of LGD. In

other words, in the context in which borrowers pledge fine art as collateral on loans, credit

default risks occur when the borrowers sell the collateral105

to repay the loans as well as when

sale proceeds are insufficient to cover the loan balance once liquidation occurs. The latter issue,

which is generally referred to as collateral shortfall, drives the current discussion.

Downside Risk and Presale Estimates

Loans are extended as a portion of the appraised value of the collateral. The collateral

shortfall results from a decline in the appraisal-based value of the collateral to the price realized

at the point of sale. Thus, assessing the downside risk in association with the appraisal is crucial

in estimating the collateral shortfall.

The appraised value of an asset is usually achieved through transaction records of similar

assets. In the case of art assets, a method termed the “comparative-market-data-approach” is used

to determine appraised value. This method uses as data the prices realized by recent sales of

works that are similar to the subject property in as many facets (e.g., medium, scale, etc.) as

possible, to arrive at the subject work’s fair market value106

. Furthermore, to appraise the fair

market value for loan purposes, the method generally refers to recent auction prices107

. As such,

the downside risk of the price of art has often been discussed in relation to the functioning of

auction business, and therefore, the formation of presale estimates. Presale estimates are

evaluations of prices that will possibly be achieved at auction. Presale high and low estimates are

103 See 1.2 Literature Review, “The Credit Risk.” 104 Michael LaCour-Little and Yanan Zhang, “Default Probability and Loss Given Default for Home Equity Loans,” Office of the

Comptroller of the Currency, Economics Working Paper 2014-1 (June 2014). 105 Either voluntarily or by force. 106 See Chapter 3, 3.1, Products in Art-secured Financing, for the use and definition of fair market value. 107 Elizabeth von Habsburg, Rachel Goodman, and Claire McAndrew. Art Appraisal: Fine Art and High Finance (New York:

Bloomberg Press, 2010), 42.

Page 39: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

39

intended as ranges within which the winning bid is expected to fall. The low presale estimate is

of particular interest, because it encompasses the opinion of the auction house specialist (who is

the market expert) and, more importantly, the reserve set by the seller. Given the fact that sales

records are created only when the buyer’s offer exceeds the seller’s implicit reserve, McAndrew

and Thompson argue that the empirical sales data for art appraisal contains a positive bias

relative to market demand108

, which ultimately induces the downside risk of art prices. Several

other researchers have also investigated the correlation between the market price of artwork and

contemporaneous presale estimates. Overall, researchers have observed a consistent upward bias

between presale estimates and the long-term performance of artwork in the fine art sector109

,

confirming a systematic correlation between these two indicators of value. Consequently, given

the calculated reserve price at 75% of the presale low estimate110

, the proven correlation has set a

ground for quantification analysis of downside risk based on presale estimates.

Measuring the Downside Risk with Buy-ins

The conclusion from the above is that the quantification of downside risk can be achieved by

measuring systematic deviations of auction sale prices from presale estimates. McAndrew and

Thompson construct a hammer ratio distribution to analyze downside risk. The hammer ratio is

simply the hammer price (the winning bid) over the mean of high and low presale estimates.

The hammer ration is calculated as:

Hammer Ratio (HR) = 𝐻𝑎𝑚𝑚𝑒𝑟 𝑃𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 (𝑃)

𝑀𝑒𝑎𝑛 𝑜𝑓 𝐻𝑖𝑔ℎ 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝐿𝑜𝑤 𝐸𝑠𝑡𝑖𝑚𝑎𝑡𝑒 (𝑀)

This equation examines the proportion of the achieved market price to the average expected price.

The calculated value reveals whether a deviation (either upside or downside) exists, as well as the

size of the possible deviation. For example, a hammer price (P) of $1.5 million with a mean high

and low estimate (M) of $2 million will result a hammer ratio (HR) of 0.75. In this case, the 0.75

HR, which is less than 1.00, indicates a downside deviation of 0.25, meaning the hammer price is

108 McAndrew and Thompson, “Collareral Value,” 589-607. 109 See 1.2 Literature Review, “Presale Estimates and Downside Risk.” 110 See 1.2 Literature Review, “Presale Estimates and Downside Risk.”

Page 40: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

40

25% less than the expected price of the artwork. Therefore, a distribution can be constructed to

observe the tendency of the “price error” by incorporating the data from a selected group of

auction records and their corresponding presale estimates. Figure 4.1 shows an example of such a

distribution derived from a sample of French Impressionist paintings over the period of January

1985 to December 2001.

Figure 4.1 Hammer Ratio for French Impressionist Paintings

Source: McAndrew and Thompson (2007)

As shown, the downside deviation is captured in the range of 0.00 -1.00 on the horizontal axis (or

the left tail of the distribution), as it includes transactions in which prices realized are lower than

expected. As such, lenders holding art as collateral are able to develop downside risk metrics to

estimate the size of the collateral shortfall of the underlying art/art collection over a given period of

time.

For the purpose of art-secured lending, McAndrew, Smith, and Thompson further argue that

the analysis of hammer ratio distribution is insufficient in measuring downside risk. They suggest

that a more accurate distribution should consider the phenomenon of “buy-ins” at auction. The

buy-ins are works that fail to attain the seller’s reserve at auctions and are therefore bought in

house by the auctioneers. The inclusion of buy-ins is critical in evaluating downside risk, because

the foremost risk of an intended sale is the risk of failing to sell. In other words, an artwork, once

Page 41: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

41

purchased at/above reserve price, is not guaranteed to exceed the same reserve in a later sale.

Consequently, the data omitting buy-ins contains a selection bias, in which a time series of

hammer price, or successful sale price, understates the downside risk of lending against art.

Therefore, by incorporating buy-ins, a new distribution is constructed to observe the relationship

between presale estimates and potential sale price. Building on the previous example with the

buy-in rate of 28% of the sale volume and 16% of the sale value111

, the new distribution is

illustrated in Figure 4.2.

Figure 4.2 Hammer Spread and Fitted Lognormal, Recognizing Buy-ins

Source: McAndrew and Thompson (2007)

As observed, the new distribution is superimposed over the original distribution with a much larger

left tail. It suggests that in addition to artworks that achieve less than expected, artworks that do

not sell at auction also present downside risk. As a result, a greater overall downside risk is

revealed in the distribution.

As demonstrated above, the modified hammer ratio distribution with consideration of

buy-ins enables a more accurate assessment of downside risk. Lenders and financiers can therefore

integrate this tool into a fuller scale financial model, achieving anticipation and quantification of

the collateral shortfall. Furthermore, given the quantifiability of the credit risk, derivative products

are designed for lenders to practice risk management to a fuller extent.

111 These values are from the original study in McAndrew and Thompson, “Collareral Value,” 589-607.

Page 42: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

42

Art Credit Default Swaps

The present Basel Accords—agreements set by the Basel Committee on Bank Supervision

(BCBS)112

—require banks to adequately estimate and report all risks associated with changes in

asset price113

. Given the fact that monitoring the risk of art assets is challenging, bank lenders of

art loans are unwilling to hold the risk on their balance sheet and therefore use art credit default

swaps (ACDS) to transfer the risk to a third party. Other types of art loan lenders are also

involved in risk management practice depending on the details of the art loan.

An ACDS is a particular type of swap first proposed by Campbell and Wiehenkamp114

. In

the credit market, a swap is a contract between two or more parties that the buyer of the swap

makes payments to the seller until the contract is terminated by a credit event. In return, the

seller provides monetary protection on the par value115

of a specified reference asset if credit

events occur. Such protection may be a set termination price and/or all interest payments that

would have been made by the buyer. In an ACDS, the art loan lender is the protection buyer and

the protection seller is someone with an interest in buying the reference asset, where the

specified reference asset is the artwork or the art collection held as collateral on the loan. A

credit event in an ACDS is most likely to be that the borrower defaults on the art loan with a

collateral shortfall. Upon occurrence of the credit event, the swap contract is terminated and the

third party (the protection seller) is obliged to pay a settlement to the lender (the protection

buyer). The settlement in an ACDS contains at least an exchange of collateralized art assets for a

predetermined price specified in the contract plus the associated collateral shortfall.

For art loan lenders, ACDSs encourage art collateralization by fully transferring the

unwanted credit risk exposure. For the counterparties in ACDSs, the derivative contracts enable

112 The Basel Committee on Bank Supervision is the primary global standard-setter for the prudential regulation of banks and

provides a forum for cooperation on banking supervision.

Bank for International Settlements, “About the Basel Committee,” September 30, 2015, accessed April 29, 2016,

http://www.bis.org/bcbs/about.htm. 113 J.P. Morgan and National Association of Pension Funds Limited, Derivatives and Risk Management Made Simple (London:

National Association of Pension Funds Limited, 2013). 114 Rachel A.J. Campbell and Christian Wiehenkamp. “Chapter 4: Credit Default Swaps and an Application to the Art Market: A

Proposal,” Credit Risk: Models, Derivatives, and Management (Boca Raton: CRC Press, 2008): 53-66. 115 Par value means stated value or face value.

Page 43: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

43

the probability of acquiring valuable artwork at a fraction of the cost in exchange for a low

premium. Some of the counterparties include art investment funds, art museums, speculative

investors in art, and individual/corporate art collectors.

4.2 The Title Risk

Due to the lack of transactional standards and transparency in art dealing, ownership

defects have evolved in the art world and are transmitted to art collateralization. Both buyers and

sellers of art tend to conceal their information as a means of maximizing their own benefits116

.

Therefore, transaction records are often discrete and incomplete, which makes it nearly

impossible to demonstrate an unbroken chain of title to works of art in absolute terms.

Title insurers subsequently target market incompetence, providing insurance guarantees on the

fair market value of the object plus defense costs. However, such title insurance often functions

inefficiently for pervasive title dispute in art-secured lending that involves multiple agents on

one or both sides of a transaction. As a result, understanding the legal provisions that protect

lenders’ interests best help manages the title risk.

As Bloom117

explains and the Michal Cohen case118

suggests, the informality of art

transactions can cause uncertainty as to whether a seller or a dealer has sufficient rights to pledge

a work of art as collateral for a loan. Nicyper and Gipson119

and Medelyan120

have also

examined questions concerning lenders’ rights vis-à-vis works of art. The Uniform Commercial

Code (UCC), which is the legal provision most often applied to commercial transactions

(including art), assures that determinations of who, among lenders, buyers, sellers, and

116 Buyers may want to minimize the purchasing price through disclosing their purchasing power, whilst sellers may conceal

their reasons of deaccession, which are often distressed, to maximize the selling price. 117 Bloom, “Buyers Beware: Protecting Against The Risk of Purchasing Stolen Art,” Entertainment, Arts and Sports Law

Journal 13(2) (Summer 2002). 118 T. Robertson, “Theft Case Threatens the Art of the Handshake,” Boston Globe, May 22, 2003. 119 Nicyper and Gipson, “Rights of Lenders Accepting Works of Art as Collateral,” Entertainment, Arts and Sports Law Journal

17(1) (Spring 2006). 120 Valerie Medelyan, “The Art of a Loan: When the Loan Sharks Meet Damien Hirst’s ‘$12-Million Stuffed Shark,’” Pace Law

Review 35 (2014): 643.

Page 44: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

44

consignors, has superior rights in works of art will be processed with analysis of various

provisions.

This analysis considers situations in which “person A” (who might be the owner of a work

of art and who intends to sell it) transfers the property (or the work of art) to “person B” (who

might be a dealer or other intermediary who facilitates transactions of the work of art), and

“person B” transfers the work of art to “person C” (who might be a lender accepting the art as

collateral or a buyer who then pledges the art as collateral).

The Uniform Commercial Code

The UCC is a comprehensive collection of codified and standardized laws developed

through the joint efforts of legal scholars from the National Conference of Commissioners on

Uniform State Laws, the American Law Institute, and the American Bar Association. It

harmonizes the law of sales and other commercial transactions in all 50 states, the District of

Columbia, and the territories of the United States of America. More specifically, when there are

two consecutive transfers of a good, the UCC set rules determining the respective rights of the

parties.

In cases in which works of art are pledged as collateral for loans, UCC provisions elucidate

sales of goods, rights of secured lenders, and rights arising out of consignments to dealers. UCC

sections 9-319, 2-326, and 2-403 set out the rights of lenders who accept works of art as

collateral. Section 9-319 may apply when the transfer from the owner to the dealer is a

consignment, and sections 2-326 or 2-403 may apply when a transfer is confirmed to be a sale or

for an intended sale. If the works of art are delivered to a dealer for “sale or return121

”, or if the

transfer is an entrustment, ensuing resolutions will require careful analysis of multiple provisions

from UCC Article 9 and UCC Article 2.

121 Refers to a sale to a merchant where the merchant wishes to return the goods he/she cannot sell.

Page 45: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

45

UCC Article 9 and Section 9-319 Consignment Provisions

UCC Article 9 provides rules governing transactions, regardless of their form, that involve

a debt with a creditor’s interest (or the “security interest”) in the debtor’s personal property122

.

Under Article 9, the creditor may repossess and sell the property (generally referred to as

“collateral”) to fulfill the debt if the debtor defaults. To be more specific, provisions from section

9-319 particularly concern a secured creditor’s rights in relation to consigned goods.

UCC Section 9-319 applies exclusively to creditors of, and people who purchase from, a

consignee. As previously mentioned, the provisions address situations in which “person A” (who

might be the owner of a work of art and who intends to sell it) transfers the property (or the work

of art) to “person B” (who might be a dealer or other intermediary who facilitates transactions of

the work of art), and “person B” transfers the work of art subsequently to “person C” (who might

be a lender accepting the art as collateral or a buyer who then pledges the art as collateral). In the

analysis of section 9-319, the primary determination is whether the transfer from “person A” to

“person B” is a “consignment”. This situation is the premise upon which to apply section 9-319,

and three criteria need to be affirmed:

a. The Nature of the Transaction

UCC section 9-102(a)(20) defines that a “consignment” is most importantly a transaction in

which “person A” delivers property to “person B” “for the purpose of sale”123

. It indicates

that person B will obtain section 9-319 rights to the property only if the transfer is made to

person B with both person A and person B understanding that the property will be sold.

Additionally, the nature of the transaction must not “create a security interest that secures an

obligation.”124

This means that, in the situation of an art transaction, if the purpose of the

transfer from person A to person B is to pledge the work of art as security or collateral for a

loan, then the transaction is not considered a “consignment” under UCC Article 9.

b. “Merchant” Requirements

122 UCC§ 9-109(a)(1) (2010) 123 UCC§ 9-102(a)(20) (2010) 124 UCC§ 9-102(a)(20)(D) (2010)

Page 46: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

46

In order to establish a “consignment”, UCC section 9-102 also requires person B, who is

receiving the property (e.g., the work of art), to be a “merchant” who (i) deals in goods of the

kind being transferred under a different name from that of person A; (ii) is not an auctioneer;

and (iii) is not generally known by his/her creditors to be substantially engaged in selling the

goods of others125

. In the case of art transactions, the “merchant” might be someone who

buys, sells, or otherwise deals in works of art with the above conditions fulfilled.

c. Type of Goods Requirements

The establishment of “consignment” under Article 9 further requires that the transferred

property must not be “consumer goods” immediately before delivery126

, where “consumer

goods” is defined in Article 9 as “goods that are used or bought for use primarily for personal,

family, or household purposes.”127

In addition, the aggregate value of the transferred

property is required to be at least $1,000 at the time of delivery.128

If the above criteria are satisfied, the transfer from person A to person B is a qualified

“consignment” under UCC Article 9. The provisions of section 9-319 can be applied to

determine whether person A (e.g., a consignor) or person C (e.g., a creditor to consignee)

has a superior interest in the transferred property (e.g., a consigned property).

The determination under section 9-319 is dependent upon which party has perfected his

security interest. Perfection of a security interest is processed by either (i) possession of the

property or (ii) filing a UCC financing statement to notify the secured party’s interest in the

property. Between which, the second instrument is especially principal for consignors to protect

their interests in transferred property, because the overall plan of the UCC generally favors good

faith purchasers and encourages notice filing of security interests. Courts explain that a consignor

who has not been paid for the property he/she transferred to another for sale “could always have

availed itself of greater protection” by filing a UCC Financing Statement and thereby recording

125 UCC§ 9-102(a)(20)(A) (2010) 126 UCC§ 9-102(a)(20)(C) (2010) 127 UCC§ 9-102(a)(23) (2010) 128 UCC§ 9-102(a)(20)(B) (2010)

Page 47: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

47

its interest129

. Therefore, courts in general reject claims of ownership by consignors who have

failed to file a UCC financing statement due to a protection to the debtor’s creditors who may be

misled by the discrete reservation of title to the consigned property.

UCC Article 2 and the Applicability of Section 2-326 and 2-403

If the Article 9 consignment definition is not satisfied, sections 326 and 403 under UCC

Article 2 may provide alternative legal theories for creditors in transactions involving loans for

which works of art are accepted as collateral. Section 2-326 supplements Article 9’s definition of

“consignments” by applying it to “sale or return” transactions in which the goods are “delivered

primarily for resale” to another party and “may be returned by the buyer even though they

conform to the contract,”130

In other words, in a “sale or return” transaction, an owner (person A)

delivers his/her artwork to person B (i.e., the dealer) with a primary intent to let person B resell

the artwork to a third party. As such, a “sale or return” transaction is likely, but not necessary, to

qualify as a UCC Article 9 consignment. Furthermore, Section 2-326 rules in favor of the

creditor to person B (i.e., person C) when the transferred property is sold in a “sale or return”

transaction, while person B holds the property in possession. Therefore, when the “consignment”

criteria in UCC 9-102 and 9-319 cannot be met, section 2-326 can serve as an alternative for

upholding creditors’ rights in consigned artworks.

Like section 2-326, section 2-403 favors creditors over sellers when resolving competing

claims for title. However, not all subsections under section 2-403 apply to lenders who receive

works of art as collateral. Subsection (2) of section 2-403 provides some coverage for situations

in which the end recipient (person C) of the artwork is a code-defined “buyer in the ordinary

course of business.” A “buyer in the ordinary course of business” is defined in the UCC Code as

a person who buys goods from a person who is in the business of selling goods of that kind131

.

The Code also requires the buyer be in good faith without knowing that the sale violates the

129 Mitsubushi Consumer Elecs. AM., Inc. v. Steinberg’s, Inc. (In re Steinberg’s, Inc.) 266 B. R. 8, 11 (Bankr. S. D. Ohio 1998) 130 UCC§ 2-326(1)(b) (2002) 131 UCC§ 1-201(9)(2002)

Page 48: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

48

rights of another person in the goods. Additionally, the definition explicitly excludes buyers who

acquire the goods as a security for a financial debt132

. As a result, section 2-403(2) is not

applicable to lenders. Therefore, cases encompassing competing ownership claims when works

of art are taken as collateral generally consult UCC section 2-403(1).

Section 2-403(1) concerns two critical criteria when providing legal theories in discussion

of good title. The provision requires that (i) a seller (person A) delivers the work of art to a

dealer (person B), referred to as the “transaction of purchase,” and (ii) the dealer is able to

transfer a good title to a buyer or a lender (person C) who is qualified as a “good faith purchaser

for value.” Consequently, to determine whether a lender (person C) has superior rights in title

against an unpaid seller (person A), a two-phase analysis needs to be conducted.

a. The “Transaction of Purchase” Criterion

Under section 2-403(1), the seller-to-dealer transaction need not be a direct sale and

purchase to constitute a “transaction of purchase.” The UCC broadly includes any “taking by

sale, lease, discount, negotiation, mortgage, pledge, lien, security interest, issue or reissue,

gift, or any other voluntary transaction creating an interest in property” in the definition of

“purchase.”133

Moreover, the dealer (person B) receives the ability to transfer good title to a

good faith purchaser, even if the dealer acquired the art through a dishonored paycheck134

or

false or fraudulent pretenses.135

The determination of a “transaction of purchase” is based on i) whether the transfer from

person A to person B is voluntary and ii) if the artwork is delivered for the purpose of sale.

As a result, involuntary transfer such as theft is not a “transaction of purchase”, which

therefore does not grant person B legal rights to transfer the title of artworks. Similarly, if the

artwork is delivered to person B for storage, restoration, or framing, the transaction is not

considered a “transaction of purchase,” because the transfer is not associated with purchase

and sale.

132 UCC§ 1-201(9)(2002) 133 UCC§ 1-201(29)(2001) 134 UCC§ 2-403(1)(b)(2002) 135 UCC§ 2-403(1)(d)(2002)

Page 49: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

49

b. The “Good Faith Purchaser for Value” Criterion

UCC section 2-403(1) considers buyers who do not know of, or who are not knowingly

involved in, an improper scheme prior to acquiring the work of art from the seller, a good

faith purchaser. The UCC also indicates a “good faith136

” buyer or secured creditor should be

able to identify obvious red flags in transactions involving dishonesty, even if the buyer does

not have direct knowledge.

When both of the above criteria are satisfied, a resolution on competing ownership claims

that refers to UCC section 2-403(1) generally supports innocent purchasers over unpaid buyers.

Similar to disputes in UCC Article 9, the judgment “rests on the premise that it is cheaper for an

owner to take precautious against to a defrauder than it is for a purchaser to research the chain of

title of every good he purchases,”137

as one court explained.

Chapter 5: Conclusion

Art collateralization is becoming an inevitability given the current market climate. There

are many good reasons for considering art as a new asset class aside from its aesthetic returns.

Art is attractive from a financial point of view as a means to hedge currency inflation over the

long run. In addition, art offers diversification to the investment portfolio, as it shows low

correlation with other investable assets such as stocks and bonds.

The steadily strong art market has escalated the price of fine art and inspired art

financialization. Many external forces such as globalization, online databases, and the

accumulation of wealth contribute to the growth of the fine art market, and push forward the

emergence of many initiatives that seek to securitize artwork, including taking art as collateral.

As HNWIs show a growing interest in buying art with an investment view, private banks

and wealth managers incorporate the concept of collectible assets into the overall asset

136 UCC§ 1-201(20)(2001) (defining “good faith” as “honesty in fact and the observance of reasonable commercial standards of

fair dealing.”) 137 Welch v. Cayton, 183 W. Va. 252, 257, 395 S.E.2d 496, 501(1990).

Page 50: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

50

management strategy, realizing the liquidation of art assets, tax-saving, and sophisticated estate

planning. Auction houses take advantage of their agency sectors, integrating art collateralization

as part of the vertical business channel in which art loans and art sales are able to mutually

benefit each other. Lenders specializing in art loans are also evolving, penetrating the niche

market by providing loans with low barriers and introducing innovative loan products.

Rigorous financial disciplines with modifications for art assets enable the quantifiability

and management of the downside risk associated with art-secured lending. Financial engineering

creates derivative products to improve market efficiency by transferring the risk of lowering

interest paid for loans taking art as collateral. When title disputes present, the UCC favors

lenders in general. As a protection to lenders who may be misled by the discrete reservation of

title to the consigned property, the code theoretically rejects claims of ownership by consignors

who fail to file a UCC Financing Statement.

This paper explores the merits and hedgeable risks involved in art-secured financing,

demonstrating viability and encouraging the practice of art loans. However, the current trend of

financialization of the art market, which is characterized by a lack of transactional standards and

transparency, ultimately impacts the liability of all market participants, including art loan

lenders, collectors (borrowers), and advisory intermediaries. Therefore, it is imperative to

address more uncertainties in the niche market of art-secured financing. This paper leaves these

questions for future research.

Page 51: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

51

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Altman, E. “Financial Ratios, Discriminant Analysis and the Prediction of Corporate

Bankruptcy.” Journal of Finance 23 (4), 589-609.

Anderson, Robert C. “Paintings as an Investment.” Economic Inquiry: 13-26.

Ashenfelter, O. and Graddy, K. “Auctions and the Price of Art.” Journal of Economic Literature

16 (2003): 763-786.

Ashenfelter, O., Graddy, K., and Stevens, M. “A Study of Sales Rates and Prices in

Impressionist and Contemporary Art Auctions.” University of Oxford Working Paper

(2003): 1-28.

Ashenfelter, O. “How Auctions Work for Wine and Art.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives

3(3) (Summer, 1989): 23-36.

Bank for International Settlements. “About the Basel Committee.” September 30, 2015. Accessed

April 29, 2016. http://www.bis.org/bcbs/about.htm.

Becker, H.S. Art Worlds. Berkley: University of California Press, 1982.

Beaver, W. “Financial Ratios as Predictors of Failure.” Journal of Accounting Research 5

(Suppl.) (1966): 71-111.

Beggs, A. and Graddy, K. “Declining Values and the Afternoon Effect: Evidence from Art

Auctions.” The RAND Journal of Economics 28(3) (1997): 544-65.

Bloom, “Buyers Beware: Protecting Against The Risk of Purchasing Stolen Art.” Entertainment,

Arts and Sports Law Journal 13(2) (Summer 2002).

Bocart, Fabian Y. R. P. and Hafner, Christian M. “Volatility of Price Indices for Heterogeneous

Goods with Applications to the Fine Art Market.” Journal of Applied Econometrics 30(2)

(2013): 291-312. Accessed April 4, 2016. doi:10.1002/jae.2355.

Bongard, W. “Kunst Kompass.” Capitol.

Bowness, A. The Conditions of Success. London: Thames & Hudson, 1989.

Boot, A.W.A., Thakor, A.V., and Udell, G.F. “Secured Lending and Default Risk: Equilibrium

Analysis, Policy Implications and Empirical Results.” The Economic Journal 101(406)

(1991): 458.

Cap Gemini and RBC Wealth Management. “World Wealth Report 2015.” Accessed March 28,

2016.

Page 52: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

52

http://www.luxesf.com/wp-content/uploads/2015/08/World_Wealth_Report_2015_Web.pd

f.

Campbell, Rachel A.J. and Wiehenkamp, Christian. “Chapter 4: Credit Default Swaps and an

Application to the Art Market: A Proposal.” Credit Risk: Models, Derivatives, and

Management. Boca Raton: CRC Press, 2008: 53-66.

Chan, Angelo K.H. “Art as Collateral: Seeking Returns from Lending vs. Owning,” PhD

Dissertation. New York: Sotheby’s Institute of Art. Accessed April 14, 2016.

http://ezproxy.library.nyu.edu:2048/login?url=http://search.proquest.com/docview/172806

5256?accountid=12768.

Coffman, Richard. “Art Investment and Asymmetrical Information.” Journal of Cultural

Economics: 1-24.

Collins, A., Scorcu, A.E., and Zanola, R. “Sample Selection Bias and Time Instability of Hedonic

Art Price Indexes,” Quarderi – Working Papers, DSE 610 (2007): 1-19.

Crouhy, M. Galai, D., and Mark, R. “A Comparative Analysis of Current Credit Risk Models.”

Journal of Finance 24 (2000): 59-117.

CrunchBase. “Borro,” CrunchBase. April 8, 2016. Accessed April 17, 2016.

https://www.crunchbase.com/organization/borro#/entity.

Deloitte and ArtTactic. “Art & Finance Report.” Accessed April 4, 2016.

http://www2.deloitte.com/content/dam/Deloitte/at/Documents/Tax/art-finance-report.p

df.

de la barre, M., Docclo, S., and Ginsburgh, V. “Returns of impressionist, modern and

contemporary European paintings 1962-1991.” Annales d’economie et de Statistique, 35

(1994): 143-181.

Didier, Christopher G. “Picasso, St. Guadens or Lafite: Does Passion Have a Place in Wealth

Management?” Baird Wealth Management (November 2009): 3. Accessed April 4, 2016.

Ekelund, Robert B, Ressler, Rand W., and Watson, John Keith. ““Estimates, Bias and ‘No Sales’

in Latin-American Art Auctions, 1977-1996.” Journal of Cultural Economics 22(1) (1998):

33-42.

Findlay, Michael. The Value of Art: Money, Power, Beauty. Munich: Prestel, 2004.

Gerlis, Melanie. Art as an Investment? A Survey of Comparative Assets. London: Lund

Humphries, 2014.

Page 53: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

53

Goetzmann, William N. “Accounting for Taste: Art and the Financial Markets over Three

Centuries.” The American Economic Review 83(5) (1993): 1370-76.

Goetzmann, W. and Spiegel, M. “Private Value Components and the Winner’s Curse in an Art

Index.” European Economic Review 39: 549-55.

Hagstrom, R.G. “The Essential Buffett: Timeless Principles for the New Economy.” Choice

Reviews Online, (2001).

Hodgson, D. J. and Vorkink, K. P. “Asset Pricing Theory and the Valuation of Canadian Paintings.”

Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique, 37 (2004): 629–655.

Accessed April 4, 2016 doi: 10.1111/j.0008-4085.2003.00241.x

IRS. “Determining the Value of Donated Property.” Publication 561. April 2007. Accessed April

9, 2016. https://www.irs.gov/publications/p561/ar02.html#d0e139.

J. Frye, “Collateral Damage.” In Credit Risk Modeling: The Cutting-edge Collection: Technical

Papers Published in Risk 1999-2003, edited by M. Gordy, 115-120. London: Risk Books,

2003.

J. P. Morgan and National Association of Pension Funds Limited. Derivatives and Risk

Management Made Simple. London: National Association of Pension Funds Limited, 2013.

Kao, D. “Estimating and Pricing Credit Risk: An Overview.” Financial Analysts Journal 56(4)

(2000): 50-66.

Kazakina, K. “Sotheby's Boosts Art-Loan Financing With $1 Billion Line.” Bloomberg.com. June

23, 2015. Accessed April 15, 2016.

http://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2015-06-23/sotheby-s-boosts-art-loan-financing-

with-1-billion-line.

Kent, F.W. et al. eds. Patronage, Art, and Society in Renaissance Italy. Oxford: Oxford

University Press, 1987.

LaCour-Little, Michael and Zhang, Yanan. “Default Probability and Loss Given Default for Home

Equity Loans.” Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, Economics Working Paper

2014-1. (June 2014).

Markowitz, H. “Portfolio Selection.” The Journal of Finance 7(1) (1952): 77-91.

McAndrew, C. and Thompson, R. “The Collateral Value of Fine Art.” Journal of Banking &

Finance 31(3) (2007): 589-607. Accessed April 4, 2016.

doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2006.01.012.

McAndrew, C. and Thompson, R. Pre-sale Estimates, Risk Analysis, and the Investment Quality of

Fine Art. Unpublished Manuscript (2003).

Page 54: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

54

McAndrew, C. and Thompson, R. “Are Presale Art Auction Estimates Unbiased? Some

Affirming Evidence.” Southern Methodist University Working Paper (2004): 1-31.

McAndrew, C. “Key Findings and Summary.” TEFAF Maastricht Art Market Report (2016): 15.

European Fine Art Foundation, Accessed April 4, 2016.

McAndrew, C. “Summary of Key Findings.” TEFAF Maastricht Art Market Report (2015): 21.

European Fine Art Foundation, Accessed April 4, 2016.

McAndrew, C. and Gyorgy, S. Fine Art and High Finance: Expert Advice on the Economics of

Ownership. New York: Bloomberg Press, 2010.

Medelyan, V. “The Art of a Loan: When the Loan Sharks Meet Damien Hirst’s ‘$12-Million

Stuffed Shark.’” Pace Law Review 35 (2014): 643.

Mei, Jianping and Moses, Michael. “Art as an Investment and the Underperformance of

Masterpieces.” The American Economic Review 92 (5) (2002): 1656-68.

Mei, Jianping and Moses, Michael. Are Investors Credulous? Some Preliminary Evidence from

Art Auction. Unpublished Manuscript (2002).

Medley, Margaret. The Chinese Potter: A Practical History of Chinese Ceramics. Oxford:

Phaidon Press, 1976.

Merton, R. “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rate.” Journal of

Finance 29 (1974): 449-470.

Milgrom, Paul R. and Weber, Robert J. “A Theory of Auctions and Competitive Bidding.”

Econometrica 50(5) (1982): 1089–1122. Accessed April 4, 2016. doi:10.2307/1911865.

Mitsubishi Consumer Electrics. AM., Inc. v. Steinberg’s, Inc. (In re Steinberg’s, Inc.) 266 B. R.

8, 11 (Bankr. S. D. Ohio 1998)

Moulin, R. The French Art Market: A Sociological View. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers, 1987.

Nicyper, and Gipson, First name. “Rights of Lenders Accepting Works of Art as Collateral.”

Entertainment, Arts and Sports Law Journal 17(1) (Spring 2006).

Parks, Tim. Medici Money: Banking, Metaphysics, and Art in Fifteenth-century Florence. New

York: W.W. Norton, 2005.

Pesando, James E. “Art as an Investment: The Market for Modern Prints.” American Economic

Review 83(5) (1993): 1075-1089.

Page 55: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

55

Renneboog, L. and Spaenjers, C. “Buying Beauty: On Prices and Returns in the Art Market.”

Management Science 59(1) (2013): 36-53. Accessed April 4, 2016.

doi:10.1287/mnsc.1120.1580

Robertson, Iain. “The Current and Future Value of Art.” In Understanding International Art

Markets and Management, edited by Iain Robertson, 228. London: Routledge, 2005.

Robertson, T. “Theft Case Threatens the Art of the Handshake.” Boston Globe. May 22, 2003.

Shleifer, Andrei. “Inefficient Markets: An Introduction to Behavioral Finance.” Journal of

Institutional and Theoretical Economics, (1999): 369-374.

Skatershchikov, Sergei. Skate's Art Investment Handbook: The Comprehensive Guide to Investing

in the Global Art and Art Services Market. New York: McGraw-Hill, 2006.

Skate’s. “Skate’s Art Fairs Report, Summer 2015.” Accessed March 27, 2016.

http://www.skatepress.com/art-market-reports/skates-art-fairs-report-summer-2015.

Skate’s. The Global Art Loans Market Report: Art Lenders Directory. New York: Skate’s Press,

2015.

Skate’s. “Skate’s Annual Art Investment Report 2015.” Accessed April 4, 2016.

Skate’s. “Skate’s Report on Global Art-loan Market.” Accessed April 4, 2016.

http://www.skatepress.com/wp-content/uploads/2015/08/Skates_Global_Art-Loans_Re

port_July_2015.pdf.

Skate’s. The Global Art Loans Market Report: Type of Art Loans and Other Market Practice.

New York: Skate’s Press, 2015.

Skate’s. The Global Art Loans Market Report: Existing Market Size and Segmentation. New York:

Skate’s Press, 2015.

Smith, Richard M. “The Art of Auctions: Christie's CEO Edward Dolman.” Newsweek, February

11, 2010. Accessed April 12, 2016.

http://www.newsweek.com/art-auctions-christies-ceo-edward-dolman-74999.

Sotheby’s. Annual Report 2015. New York: Sotheby’s, 2016. Accessed April 12, 2016.

http://investor.shareholder.com/common/download/download.cfm?companyid=BID&fileid

=881557&filekey=17B2C0B6-51EA-42AF-AE18-6D2DD7C34ADB&filename=2015_ann

ual_report.pdf.

Stein, John P. “The Monetary Appreciation of Paintings.” Journal of Political Economy: 1021.

Stiglitz, J.E. and Weiss, A. “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information.” American

Economic Review (1981).

Page 56: Thesis Final Copy-Aisi Wang

Wang

56

Stiglitz, J.E. and Weiss, A. “Incentive Effects of Terminations: Applications to the Credit and

Labor Markets.” American Economic Review (1983)

Timiraos, Nick and Androitis, Annamaria. “Mortgage Lenders Ease Rules for Home Buyers in

Hunt for Business.” Wall Street Journal. April 18, 2014. Accessed April 8, 2016.

http://www.wsj.com/news/articles/SB10001424052702304626304579509463522046346?

mod=WSJ_hp_LEFTWhatsNewsCollection.

UCC§ 9-109 (2010)

UCC§ 9-102 (2010)

UCC§ 2-326 (2002)

UCC§ 1-201 (2002)

UCC§ 2-403 (2002)

von Habsburg, E., Goodman, R., and McAndrew, C. Art Appraisal: Fine Art and High Finance.

New York: Bloomberg Press, 2010.

Welch v. Cayton, 183 W. Va. 252, 257, 395 S.E.2d 496, 501(1990).

Whyte, Alasdair. “Falcon Fine Art,” Private Art Investor. October 8, 2014. Accessed April 17,

2016.

http://www.privateartinvestor.com/art-finance/falcon-fine-art-we-have-the-money-and-we-

are-ambitious-789/.