thrill of victory and agony of defeat: · web viewhow does the optimal design of sales...

61
Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: Emotional Rewards and Sales Force Compensation Ying Yang Department of Marketing and Entrepreneurship University of Houston Houston, TX 77204 Email: [email protected] Phone: 713-743-4586 Niladri B. Syam Department of Marketing and Entrepreneurship University of Houston Houston, TX 77204 Email: [email protected] Phone: 713-743-4568 James D. Hess* Department of Marketing and Entrepreneurship University of Houston Houston, TX 77204 Email: [email protected] Phone: 713-743-4175

Upload: ngoquynh

Post on 16-Mar-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


4 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat:Emotional Rewards and Sales Force Compensation

Ying YangDepartment of Marketing and Entrepreneurship

University of HoustonHouston, TX 77204

Email: [email protected]: 713-743-4586

Niladri B. SyamDepartment of Marketing and Entrepreneurship

University of HoustonHouston, TX 77204

Email: [email protected]: 713-743-4568

James D. Hess*Department of Marketing and Entrepreneurship

University of HoustonHouston, TX 77204

Email: [email protected]: 713-743-4175

July 10, 2012

* Corresponding Author

Page 2: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat:Emotional Rewards and Sales Force Compensation

Abstract

How does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when

sales territories are imbalanced but you account for intrinsic agents’ emotions of pride and

disappointment in goal-attainment? First, more intensely felt pride by an underdog and

disappointment by a favorite improves the firm’s profit for either a quota or a contest. Second,

pride and disappointment have different, but specific, effects on the advantage of quota over

contest. Third, if the more personal nature of the contest that pits one person against a known

rival generates a thrill of victory and agony of defeat that is missing with quotas, contests may be

more profitable than quotas even with independent random sales. Fourth, if the strength of the

territory is the source of deep potential disappointment and the weakness of the territory is the

source of great pride, then handicapping the compensation system is unprofitable.

1

Page 3: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

1.1 Introduction

Sales contests and bonus-quota plans are frequently used to motivate salespeople,

especially for achieving short-term sales goals (Murphy and Dacin 1998). In both the contest and

the quota systems, salespeople win a prize if they surpass a sales threshold. The compensation

systems differ in how the threshold is determined: in the contest, the threshold is the sales level

of other salespeople, and in the quota, the threshold is a predetermined sales quota.

The economic aspects of quotas and contests have a long history. The theoretical

literature on contests began with the pioneering work of Lazear and Rosen (1981), Nalebuff and

Stiglitz (1983), and Green and Stokey (1983) in economics, and was continued in marketing by

Kalra and Shi (2001). The theory of bonus-quota plans (a special case of piece-rate schemes) has

been analyzed by Kim (1997) and Oyer (2000) in economics, and in marketing by scholars like

Mantrala, Raman and Desiraju (1997), Mantrala, Sinha and Zoltners (1994) and Raju and

Srinivasan (1996) etc. Some authors, notably Lazear and Rosen (1981) and Green and Stokey

(1983) have also compared relative compensation schemes like contests with individual schemes

like piece rates.

A recent stream of research has pointed out the importance of incorporating emotions to

better understand the behavior of economic agents (Rabin 1983; Holt and Sherman 1994; Elster

1998; Loewenstein 2000). Selling is a human activity and a complete investigation of the

behavior of sales agents requires us to understand how they take into account their emotions like

pride, disappointment, envy, compassion etc., when evaluating the consequences of their actions.

The extant literature comparing a relative scheme (contest) with an individual scheme

(quota) has ignored sales agents’ emotions, and our goal in this paper is to compare these

schemes when agents’ emotions are taken into account. There is a small literature dealing with

2

Page 4: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

emotions in contests (Kräkel 2008a; Grund and Sliwka 2005; Chen, Ham and Lim 2011).

However, making the comparison of contests with quotas requires us to also analyze a quota

scheme when agent emotions are incorporated. This is novel to the economics literature and is a

major contribution of our research. Like a contest, a quota scheme also has a natural target such

that an agent’s performance with respect to the target may give rise to emotions of pride and

disappointment. Just as in the contest the agent can feel pride or disappointment depending on

whether his sales exceeds or falls short of his rival’s, so too in a quota scheme the agent can feel

pride or disappointment if his sales exceeds the predetermined quota or not (Deci and Ryan,

1985, p.218-220; Latham, 2003).

The setting for our research is a situation where a firm is trying to design its

compensation scheme when faced with sales territories that are imbalanced. Though managers

try as best they can to balance the territories so that all have equivalent sales potential, as a

practical matter this is not always feasible and maybe too costly. Many practitioners have

commented on how unequal sales territories are in actual practice: “We have observed that sales

managers are frequently surprised to learn how unequal their sales territories are,” (Zoltners and

Lorimer 2000, p.139). There have been some attempts at incorporating territory potential in sales

response functions (Lucas et al. 1975), but the problem of properly accounting for territory

potential in designing compensation persists. Moreover, the problem of determining and aligning

territory potential is likely to endure (see Zoltners et al. 2006). Territory imbalance has the same

effect as asymmetry among agents (different experience, costs, skill levels, etc.) and agent

asymmetry is an important consideration in incentive design. Clearly any compensation scheme

must take into account territory imbalance or agent asymmetry.

3

Page 5: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

We have two research questions. First, when territories are imbalanced, how does a

relative plan like the contest compare with an individual plan like the quota scheme when agents’

emotions of pride and disappointment are taken into account? Second, since there is imbalance

between the territories, a natural question to ask is how handicapping the contest and quota

scheme compare with the un-handicapped ones when agents have feelings of pride and

disappointment.

1.2 Overview of Results

A major finding is that when territories are imbalanced, pride in winning/making quota

increases profits from both the quota and the contest but it benefits the contest more. As a

contrast note than when emotions are ignored territory imbalance decreases profits from both

quota and the contest but it hurts the contest more (Syam, Hess and Yang 2011). In fact a major

insight we provide is when and how emotions can counter the effects of territory imbalance.

If the intensity of emotions is the same for both contests and quotas a quota system is

more profitable. However, there is ample evidence that the mano-a-mano character of a contest,

pitting one salesperson against a known, personal rival, creates more intense feelings of pride

and disappointment than the impersonal benchmark of the quota system. In that case the contest

is more profitable. This result is new to the literature comparing compensation schemes, and also

contrasts starkly with the case when agent’s emotions are ignored. The extant literature

comparing relative and individual scheme finds that when emotions are ignored, the quota

scheme is more profitable for the firm with both balanced and imbalanced territories (Lazear and

Rosen 1981; Green and Stokey 1983; Syam, Hess and Yang 2011).

The primary reason why contests may be desirable was provided by Green and Stokey

(1983), who show that relative plans (contest) can dominate individual plans (quotas) when there

4

Page 6: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

are sizeable common shocks. We have uncovered a new rationale for contests to dominate quotas

even in the absence of common shocks. Since emotions play an important role in the behavior of

economic actors, our results can help explain the enormous popularity of contests, especially in

the sales setting.

Another salient finding in the current paper is that, when agents’ emotions are

incorporated the firm may find it better not to handicap the contest and quota scheme. When

agents’ emotions are ignored, then it is optimal to handicap the contest and quota scheme since

handicapping can overcome the deleterious effects of territory imbalance (or agent asymmetry),

and the contest and quota become as profitable as in the case with balanced territories. The

reason for our novel finding about the sub-optimality of handicapping when emotions are

accounted for is that handicapping has two contrasting effects. On the one hand, it removes the

negative effect of territory imbalance, but it also removes the impetus for agents’ emotions to

take effect. Since it is precisely the imbalance between territories that opens the door for pride

and disappointment, negating the imbalance also removes the source of these emotions. Since the

firm’s profit increases in these emotions, this is a negative effect of handicapping. We show that

when the emotions are intense enough, the firm is better off without handicapping.

Incidentally, our results provide one rationale why we see so few handicapped contests in

practice, even though they have been theoretically investigated and have been shown to increase

firm profits from a purely economic standpoint (Lazear and Rosen 1981). It has been argued that

from a practical standpoint a firm may eschew handicapping since it may not be able to handicap

properly and this would give rise to concerns of fairness, equity etc. We show that handicapping

may be undesirable even if the firm were able to handicap optimally to avoid the deleterious

effects of territory imbalance.

5

Page 7: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Because the contest involves interpersonal comparisons with other active participants it is

likely to generate stronger emotions than quotas, which are impersonal accounting standards. In

that case the firm will prefer not to handicap the contest even in situations where it chooses to

handicap the quota by setting territory-specific quota schemes. This may explain why

handicapped contests are much rarer than handicapped quotas.

1.3 Literature Review

As already mentioned, the extant work incorporating emotions in compensation schemes

involves contests. First, Kräkel (2008a) has investigated the emotions that come into play when

agents compare their own performance with the performance of other agents. Such interpersonal

comparisons engender feelings of pride (positive emotion) if one wins the contest, and feelings

of disappointment (negative emotion) if one loses. With heterogeneous agents who differ in their

innate abilities, the author finds that given exogenously defined prizes the agents’ efforts are

increasing in both pride and disappointment. This result rationalizes the empirical fact that agents

are found to overexert themselves compared to the predictions of standard tournament theory. He

has also endogenized the prize structure. Kräkel (2008b) carried out a similar analysis of salary

and commission. Though known asymmetry among agents could induce the firm to offer

handicapped contests as an optimal mechanism (a la Lazear and Rosen 1981), unlike us Kräkel

does not investigate handicapping.

Second, Grund and Sliwka (2005) investigate envy and compassion in contests.

Compassion is felt by the winner of the contest and envy is felt by the loser. Both emotions come

into play because of the agents’ aversion to inequity, which is felt because a contest always has a

winner and a loser. Indeed, the amount of inequity is operationalized via the difference between

6

Page 8: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

the winning and losing prizes. They find that, in the partial equilibrium where prizes are

exogenously defined, the optimal efforts are higher in a contest with inequity-averse agents

compared to a standard contest where agents only have self-regarding preferences. However, in

the full equilibrium with endogenous prizes chosen by the principal, the effort in a contest with

inequity-averse agents is smaller compared to a standard contests. Moreover, the principal’s

profit is smaller in tournaments with inequity-averse agents than in tournaments where agents

have self-regarding preferences.

Third, Gill and Stone (2010) study tournaments where agents like to receive ‘just deserts’

for their efforts. If an agent exerts more effort than his rival, then he feels that he deserves more,

and an agent’s utility is the sum of his monetary payoff and a comparison of this payoff with an

endogenous reference point that depends on both agents’ efforts. The authors’ main goal is to

demonstrate that when agents care about receiving just deserts, then a tournament with

symmetric agents can give rise to asymmetric efforts in equilibrium, contrary to standard

tournament theory.

Fourth, Chen, Ham and Lim (2011) experimentally investigate agent emotions in a multi-

person tournament with asymmetric agents. Like Kräkel (2008a) they too find that incorporating

emotions in tournaments allows researchers to rationalize the over-exertion of effort in the

laboratory compared to the prediction of standard tournament theory. They also investigate how

changing the number of prizes in a multi-person tournament changes the efforts exerted by the

agents. However, they do not derive nor use optimal prizes in their experiments and their results

are derived using exogenously given prizes.

We assume some salespeople have advantages owing to working in the better territory.

Thus there are feelings of pride when the agent in the weaker territory wins the contest and

7

Page 9: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

feelings of disappointment when the agent in the stronger territory loses the contest. Similarly,

there are feelings of pride when the agent in the weaker territory makes quota and feelings of

disappointment when the agent in the stronger territory fails to make quota.

Our contributions to the literature are, first, to analyze the effect of emotions on both

quota and contest and to contrast the resulting differences in the profits of the two compensation

systems (see Table 1). Second, we also contribute by investigating the effects of handicapping

the contest and quota when agents are asymmetric and their emotions are taken into account.

Homogeneous Sales Response Heterogeneous Sales ResponseOptimal Payment

Based Upon:Only

Financial RewardsEmotional and

Financial RewardsOnly

Financial RewardsEmotional and

Financial Rewards

Contest

Lazear & Rosen (1981)Green & Stokey (1983)Nalebuff & Stiglitz (1983)Kalra and Shi (2001)Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)

Grund & Sliwka (2005)Gill & Stone (2010)

This paper

Lazear & Rosen (1981)Meyer (1992)Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)

Kräkel (2008a)Gill & Stone (2010)

This paper

Handicapped Contest Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)

Thispaper

Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011) Thispaper

Quota or Commission

Lazear & Rosen (1981)Green & Stokey (1983)Nalebuff & Stiglitz (1983)Kim (1997)Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)

Kräkel (2008b)This paper

Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011) Thispaper

Handicapped Quota Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)

Thispaper

Thispaper

Comparisons

Contest vs. Quota Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)This

paper Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)This

paper

Contest vs. Commission

Lazear & Rosen (1981)Green & Stokey (1983)Nalebuff & Stiglitz (1983)Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)

Syam, Hess, & Yang (2011)

Table 1. Models of Multi-Agent Payment Systems:Asymmetric Sales Reponses and Emotional Rewards

2. Sales Quota and Sales Contest

Suppose a risk-neutral firm employs two risk-neutral salespersons who will exert efforts to

sell the firm’s goods. Each salesperson is assigned to a separate territory, i=1, 2. The firm cannot

observe the levels of salespersons’ effort, ei, but can observe dollar sales, si. The sales in a

8

Page 10: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

territory depend not only on the salesperson’s level of effort but also on the territory potential.

Without loss of generality, we assume territory 1 is the stronger territory. In particular, the sales

in territory 1 is s1=k+e1+ε1 , and the sales in territory 2 is s2=−k+e2+ε2 , where 0<k<½ is

the advantage of territory 1 over territory 2, ei is the effort level of salesperson in territory i, and

a random component of sales, i, is uniformly distributed on the interval [- ½ , ½ ]. Sales in

territory 1 are shifted up by k and the sales in territory 2 are shifted down by the same amount;

we limit the imbalance k to ½ so that sales are never negative with certainty. The functional

forms of the sales response functions are exactly as in Kräkel (2008a) who interprets the

exogenous constant as agents’ ability, whereas we interpret it as territory imbalance. The reader

could think of an average level of sales across the two territories with one territory enjoying an

advantage over the other.

The random variable, i, independent and identically distributed across different territories,

reflects the sales influenced by territory-specific environmental shocks outside the salespersons’

control. The assumption of independence is chosen to level the playing field to focus just on

territory imbalance. If there were common shocks, they would cancel in a comparison of sales in

a contest but would not disappear in a quota system.

2.1 Bonus-Quota

Consider a quota payment system.1 In a quota system the salesperson is entitled to a

bonus only if sales exceeds a prespecified quota, Q, and not otherwise:

Pay (si;Q , B)=¿ {0 if si<Q ,¿ ¿¿¿ (

1 In this section we assume that the principal sets the same bonus and quota for both territories. Thus both the contest and the quota have the same number of decision variables: S and B for the contest and B and Q for the quota. A situation wherein the principal sets territory specific quotas is called ‘handicapped’ quotas just as a contest which accounts for territory imbalance is called a ‘handicapped’ contest. A major result of our paper is to point out the sub-optimality of handicapping quotas when agents’ emotions are taken into account. This is done in Section 4.

9

Page 11: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

The quota system has two facets to control, B and Q, the same number as in the sales contest; for

analytic convenience we push baseline salary into the background.

We now incorporate agents’ emotions in the analysis. The salesperson derives benefits

from the pay received for working, but also has intrinsic utility from a job well-done.

Specifically, if the salesperson is able to achieve the bonus there is pride, a positive emotion felt

when a sales goal is accomplished. On the other hand, if the salesperson fails to earn a sales

bonus there is disappointment, a negative emotion felt when there is failure to achieve a goal.

This operationalization of emotions is the same as in Kräkel (2008a) who investigated only

emotions in contests whereas we analyze emotions in both a contest and a quota scheme.

Throughout this paper we will denote the utility associated with pride by the symbol and the

utility associated with disappointment as . The salesperson in the stronger territory 1 may have

different emotions than the salesperson in the weaker territory 2, so we will include a subscript in

pride and disappointment to indicate the territory. Finally, it is possible that the emotions depend

on whether the goal is to achieve a firm given quota or to outsell a fellow salesperson, so we will

add a superscript to indicated whether the goal is quota or sales contest.

The combination of extrinsic financial reward and intrinsic emotional reward leads to

utility in a quota:

U i=¿ {0 - δ iQ , if si<Q ¿ ¿¿¿ (

Efforts are costly to the salespeople and rise quadratically with effort in our model, ½ ei2.

Achieving quota is never certain. The probability that the salesperson assigned the

stronger territory 1 can make the sales quota is P1=½ + k - Q + e1, while the probability in

territory 2 is smaller, P2=½ - k - Q + e2. The expected net utility of the salesperson assigned to

10

Page 12: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

territory i is EUi=(B+iQ)Pi+(0-i

Q)(1-Pi)– ½ei2. Notice that in the expected utility the agent fully

anticipates the emotions that will be felt in the future depending upon success or failure in the

achieving quota. Such affective forecasts have been studied in other contexts (Gilbert and Wilson

2000, Patrick, Chun, MacInnis 2009).

The efforts that maximize these expected net utilities are

e1=B+π1Q+δ1

Q and e2=B+π2

Q+δ2Q

. (

Notice that while these partial equilibrium efforts increase with emotional rewards (obtaining

pride or avoiding disappointment), they do not depended on the quota or degree that the

territories are imbalanced. This is because added effort moves sales the same amount whether

the current sales are near or far from the quota.

With the efforts of (, the probability of making quota is higher in the strong territory 1 if

and only if

{ k+π1Q+δ1

Q }−{−k+π2Q+δ 2

Q }≥0 . (

Recall that territory 1 has a sales advantage of +k and territory 2 has a sales disadvantage –k.

Emotions associated with the job tend to increase the advantage in the strong territory and reduce

the disadvantage in the weak territory. That is, intrinsic emotions in the strong territory

implicitly increase imbalance while emotions in the weak territory implicitly reduce imbalance.

Inequality ( states that intrinsic emotional rewards are not so intense as to reverse the basic

territorial imbalance.

Chen et al. (2011) say, “For favorites, we assume that they expect themselves

11

Page 13: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

and other favorites to win. Hence, receiving a prize does not provide favorites any additional

psychological utility gains… Underdogs, on the other hand, are assumed to expect to lose

because they compete with an initial disadvantage. Hence, losing in the tournament

does not bring any psychological disutility.” (p.872). Kräkel (2008a) agrees with this when he

says, “If, for example, agents do not feel strong emotions when losing (winning) against more

(less)able opponents as this outcome is the most likely one, then the only emotions that matter

arise when strong contestants lose against less able ones and when low able agents win against

predominant opponents.” (p. 209). As a consequence, we will reduce the mathematical notation

from this point forward by assuming that in the stronger territory 1 the salesperson feels no pride

from making quota and that in the weaker territory 2 the salesperson feels no disappointment:

thus, 1Q =2

Q =0.

The maximum utility in the weaker territory 2 is

EU 2=(B+π 2Q)( 1

2−k−Q)+ 12 (B+π2

Q )2 . (

Set this to zero, solve this for the quota that motivates participation in the weaker territory,

Q= 12−k+ 1

2 (B+π2Q ). Because it is more difficult to motivate participation in the weaker

territory, the quota depends upon pride, specific to the weaker territory. Greater emotions in the

other, stronger territory have no direct effect on quota. The probability that both salespeople

make quota is P1+P2=( 1

2+k−Q+B+δ 1Q )+( 1

2−k−Q+B+π2Q ) , which after substituting the

quota reduces to P1+P2=B+δ 1Q+2 k . Because the quota applies to both territories, an

increase pride 2Q has no net effect on the probability that both territories make quota.

We can write profit only as a function of the bonus:

12

Page 14: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

EΠ Q=e1+e2−B (Pr (1 makes Quota)+Pr (2 makes Quota))=2B+δ1

Q+π2Q−B (B+δ1

Q+2 k ) .(

The optimal bonus is

B∗¿1−k− 12 δ1

Q . (

The bonus is reduced if there is greater disappointment in the strong territory because this leads

to greater effort in that territory and thus more frequent payouts of the bonus. On the other hand

greater pride in the weaker territory is neutralized by an increase in quota, so the bonus is

independent of 2C.

Back substitution gives profits, efforts and quotas in the full equilibrium:

EΠQ∗¿=δ 1

Q+ π2Q+(1−k−

δ1Q

2 )2

¿(

e1∗¿1−k+ 12 δ1

Q , (

e2∗¿1−k+π2Q−1

2 δ1Q , (

Q∗¿ 32 (

23−k )− 1

4 δ1Q+ 1

2 π2Q . (

The envelope theorem says that emotions have a direct effect on profits,

∂ EΠ Q

∂Emotion , and

an indirect effect,

∂EΠ Q

∂B∂B

∂Emotion , but this indirect effect vanishes because the bonus is

optimally chosen to have zero marginal effect. As a result it is easy to see from ( that the direct

effect of pride is 1 and the direct effect of disappointment is 1-B, both of which must be positive.

This follows because effort rises directly with emotions in ( and the probability of paying the

bonus rises with disappointment. Finally, suppose that overall emotional intensity rises in both

territories so that π2Q=π20

Q +μ and δ 1Q=δ10

Q +μ . By the envelope theorem, the direct effect of

13

Page 15: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

increases in emotional intensity is 2-B and this will be greater than 1. Proofs are found in the

Appendix.

Proposition 1: In the full equilibrium, after accounting for optimization of the bonus and quota by the firm, the profits of a quota system rise with a ceteris paribus increase in either pride in the weaker territory or disappointment in the stronger territory and if emotional intensity increases an equal amount in both territories, profits rise by a multiple that exceeds 1.

2.2 Sales Contest

Now consider a sales contest between two salespersons with a bonus paid to the one with

the higher sales:

Pay (si; s j ; S , B )=S+¿ {0 if si<s j ,¿ ¿¿¿ (

The contest has two prizes, S and S+B, with S given to the contest loser and S+B given to the

contest winner.

The combination of extrinsic reward and intrinsic emotional reward leads to utility in a

contest of

U i=¿ {S - δ iC , if si<s j , ¿¿¿¿ (

Winning the sales contest is not certain because of the random components of sales. The

probability that the salesperson in territory 1 wins the sales contest is Prob(s1≥s2) = P1= 1-

½(1+e2-e1-2k)2, given e1-(1-2k) ≤e2≤e1+2k. As a result the expected net utility of the salesperson

assigned to territory 1 is

EU1=S-1C+(B+1

C+1C)P1- ½ e1

2. (

14

Page 16: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

The expected net utility in territory 2 is

EU2=S-2+(B+2C+2

C)(1-P1)- ½ e22. (

Nash equilibrium efforts by the two rival salespeople are found by simultaneously setting

the derivatives of the expected utility with respect to the appropriate effort equal to zero and

solving the two equations to get

[e1

e2 ]= 2(1/2−k )2(1/2−k )+{k+π 1

C+δ1C }−{−k+π2

C+δ2C }[B+π1

C+δ1C

B+π 2C+δ2

C ] (

Notice two things in this formula. First, both extrinsic and intrinsic emotional rewards

drive effort to win the contest. Second, effort is also dependent on total imbalance of the

territories correcting for intrinsic emotions. Specifically, the term {k+1C+1

C} - {-k+2C+2

C} is

a measure of the emotion-adjusted territorial imbalance, as opposed to k – [-k] = 2k, the ‘real’

territorial imbalance. One can show that both efforts decrease as territories become more

imbalanced. The salesperson in the weaker territory is discouraged by greater imbalance; the

salesperson in the stronger territory mimics the other’s effort and depends on the sales advantage

to win the contest.

The full equilibrium efforts must take into account the optimal bonus, B, which remains

to be solved for. As we did in the analysis of the quota, we will now assume that in the stronger

territory the salesperson feels no pride from winning a contest because it is the favorite and that

in the weaker territory the salesperson feels no disappointment in losing because it is the

underdog.

The resulting probability that territory 1 wins the contest is

15

Page 17: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

P1=1−2( 1/2−k1+δ 1

C−π2C )

2

.(

This is independent of the bonus because extrinsic rewards drive both salespeople equivalently.

Given this and the efforts (, the expected utility of the salesperson in the weaker territory 2 is

EU 2=S+2( 1 /2−k1+δ1

C−π2C )

2

(B+π 2C−(B+π 2

C )2) . (

The participation of this salesperson requires that this be at least zero. Solving for the salary that

is just sufficient for participation gives:

S=−12 ( 2(1/2−k )

1+δ1C−π2

C )2

(B+π 2C−(B+π2

C )2) . (

The expected profit consists to the total expected efforts (terms k and –k cancel and the

expected value of i is zero) minus two salaries and one bonus (only one salesperson wins the

contest). This permits us to write profit as a function of the bonus for winning the contest:

EΠ C=e1+e2−2 S−B

¿2(1/2−k )1+δ 1

C−π2C (2 B+π 2

C+δ1C ) +(2(1/2−k )

1+δ 1C−π2

C )2

(B+π2C−(B+π2

C )2 )−B . (

The expected profit maximizing bonus is therefore

B∗¿1−π 2C−1

2 ( δ1C−π2

C+2 k2(1/2−k ) )

2

. (

If disappointment in the strong territory is more intense, this implicitly increases

imbalance and, as seen above, discourages effort. The firm has less incentive to pay a bonus in

this less effective contest. If pride in the weaker territory is more intense, there are two effects: a

direct reward effect and a territory balancing effect. Because the intrinsic reward (pride) is

16

Page 18: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

greater in territory 2, the firm can reduce its extrinsic reward B without fear of losing the

employee. On the other hand, more intense emotions in the weaker territory implicitly makes the

territories more balanced and as discussed above, this tends to encourage effort and hence give

the firm an incentive to pay a larger bonus. The net effect on the bonus is indeterminate.

Back substitution from the optimal bonus in ( gives the full equibrium efforts:

e1∗¿1+2( 12−k )−

12−k

1+δ1C−π2

C−14

1+δ1C−π 2

C

12−k ,

(

e2∗¿1+12−k

1+δ 1C−π2

C−14

1+δ1C−π2

C

12−k ,

(

Substituting the efforts, the optimal maximized profits with a contest equals,

EΠ C∗¿ π2C+2( 1

2−k )+ 1

4 ( 2( 12−k )

1+δ1C−π2

C+2−

1+δ1C−π2

C

2( 12−k ) )

2

−2 ( 1

2−k )1+δ1

C−π2C

. (

Consider the equilibrium efforts in ( and (. Notice that they depend upon the difference

between the disappointment in the strong territory and the pride in the weak territory. Hence,

once the firm has adjusted the financial compensation, a uniform increase in the emotional

intensity of salespeople will have no effect on their effort choices. What about independent

changes of the emotions in the two territories? If disappointment in the strong territory increases,

the motivation to avoid the loss of the contest tends to increase effort in territory 1 but more

imbalanced territories tend to reduce effort (recall that emotions in the strong territory increase

effective imbalance). One can show that so long as the implicit imbalance remains (see

inequality (), the latter dominates and effort decreases in territory 1. It is also clear that the

increased implicit imbalance discourages effort in the weaker territory 2. Thus, greater

disappointment in the strong territory decreases effort in both territories. If pride in the weak

17

Page 19: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

territory increases, then effort goes up in that territory as the salesperson seeks the more intense

emotional rewards in a more implicitly balanced contest (emotions in the weak territory reduce

effective imbalance). The salesperson in the stronger territory must mark his rival, counting on

territorial imbalance to win the contest. That is, greater pride in the weak territory stokes effort in

both territories. 

Turning to profits, notice that the first term in the profit formula ( is 2C. This appears

because the firm needs to convince the salesperson in the weak territory 2 to participate. If this

salesperson has intrinsic desires to win the contest (that is, 2C), the firm need not provide as

large a financial reward to maintain participation and this cost reduction increases profits. We

can show that an increase in pride in territory 2 increases profits in the contest. Disappointment

in the strong territory only indirectly influences profits by implicitly increasing the imbalance of

the territories: k+1C –{-k+2

C} increases with disappointment. In a model with imbalance but

no emotions, Syam, Hess and Yang (2011) show that profits in a contest fall with imbalance

because this discourages sales effort. This carries over for disappointment in the strong territory

and an increase in 1C reduces profits when k is not too large. If both disappointment and pride

intensify equally, this has no effect on implicit territory imbalance, but the firm can reduce the

bonus without losing the salesperson in the weak territory; this improves the firm’s profits. Thus

we have the following.

Proposition 2: In the full equilibrium, after accounting for optimization of the compensation by the firm, the profits of a contest increases in pride in the weaker territory and decreases in disappointment in the stronger territory (if imbalance is not too large). If emotional intensity increases by an equal amount in both territories, profits rise by a multiple of 1.

18

Page 20: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

It is important to point out two significant differences between our results and those in

the extant literature which incorporates emotions in contests. First, Chen, Ham and Lim (2011)

find that the agents’ efforts depend on emotions. However, they have only focused on the agent’s

efforts given exogenous prizes and have not endogenized the prizes offered by the principal. In

other words, they have looked at the equivalent of the partial equilibrium equation ( rather than

full equilibrium equations (-(. In the full equilibrium, after accounting for optimization of the

prizes by the firm, the efforts of both salespeople increase in the pride in the weaker territory and

decrease in the disappointment in the stronger territory. However, an equal change in emotional

intensity in both territories has no effect on the efforts expended.

Second, Kräkel (2008a) has endogenized tournament prizes, but all he says is that pride

and disappointment may or may not improve the firm’s profits (Proposition 2, p.210). Essentially

his result says that anything can happen and so is very non-specific. Improving on Kräkel’s

result, we can provide sharper predictions regarding the effect of emotions on profits from the

contest: increase in pride in territory 2 increases profits in the contest whereas increase in

disappointment in territory 1 decreases profits.

3. Profits of Contest versus Quota with Pride and Disappointment

The expected profits for quota and contest have been expressed in equations ( and (,

respectively, as functions of territory imbalance, k, disappointment in the strong territory and

pride in the weak territory. To simplify exposition we will begin the comparison by assuming

that pride of winning the contest is equally intense as pride in making quota, π2Q=π2

C≡π2 and

similarly for disappointment, δ 1Q=δ1

C=δ1 . It is very plausible that emotions are more intense in

a contest, where a salesperson is trying to outsell someone that they know personally, than in a

19

Page 21: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

quota system where a salesperson is just trying to achieve a sales target set by the firm. Later we

will address the more reasonable situation where pride and disappointment are larger in a contest

than in a quota.

Not all values of the parameters k, 2, 1 are practical. We would like to ensure that the

probabilities of making quota are positive fractions. Specifically, for the quota system we would

like emotional intensity to be small enough that the strong territory is not one hundred percent

certain to make quota: P1=12+

32 k+ 3

4 δ 1−12 π2≤1 . Also, all efforts must be positive. These

restrictions on the parameters essentially ensure that the interior solutions are valid and they

imply that neither emotions nor imbalance should be too large, as seen in Figure 1.

Figure 1: Limits on Emotional Intensity

Let us begin by assuming there are no intrinsic emotional motivations. The simplified

profits of quota and contest are EΠ Q∗¿=( 1−k )2 ¿ and

EΠ C∗¿(1−k− k2( 1

2−k ))2

. Clearly,

20

A

2

0

Pride, 2

Disappointment, 12/3-2k 2(1-k)

2k

Page 22: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

when there is no thrill of victory or agony of defeat with imbalanced territories, the quota is more

profitable than the contest. This was previously reported in Syam, Hess and Yang (2011). Their

basic logic was that with imbalanced territories, the salesperson in the stronger territory cannot

see how he could lose and the salesperson in the weaker territory cannot imagine how it can win

a sales contest. All the salesperson in the stronger territory needs to do is to mimic the effort

exerted by the agent in the weaker territory and simply allow the territorial advantage to win the

contest. On the other hand, such imitation plays no role if the bonus is rewarded for

independently achieving a predetermined quota.

What happens to these profits if the emotions associated with winning or avoiding losing

are more intense? As seen in Propositions 1 and 2, if the salesperson in the strong territory is

more intensely disappointed in not achieving their goal, the profit of the quota goes up and the

profit of the contest goes down. The basic intuition for this is that increasing disappointment in

the strong territory implicitly makes the two territories more imbalanced and this has a greater

negative impact when one territory’s sales are contrasted to the other (contest), rather than to a

predetermined standard (quota). Because the quota system begins with an imbalance-induced

advantage, an increase in intensity of disappointment makes the advantage even greater.

One the other hand, if the salesperson in the weak territory is more intensely proud profits

rise in both the quota and the contest. In the contest there are two complementary driving forces:

increased intrinsic rewards and improved balance of the territories (recall that pride reduces

implicit imbalance). These two positive forces amplify each other and so increased pride has a

larger effect in a contest compared to a quota. As a result, as 2 increases, the advantage of the

quota due to territory imbalance shrinks. However, for all practical levels of pride, the quota’s

imbalance-generated advantage is not completely overcome by emotional rewards.

21

Page 23: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Finally, what happens to quota’s advantage if pride and disappointment intensify in equal

amounts? This gives a differential benefit to the quota, enlarging its imbalance-based advantage.

The reason is that an equal increase in 2 and 1 has no effect on the implicit territorial

imbalance, k+1-{-k+2}. This reduces the impact of pride in the contest and thus the gap

between contest and quota widens.

Proposition 3: If emotional levels are independent of the payment system and territories are imbalanced then,a. The profit advantage of the quota over the contest decreases with a ceteris paribus

increase in pride in the weaker territoryb. The profit advantage of the quota over the contest increases with a ceteris paribus

increase in disappointment in the stronger territory (if imbalance is not too large). c. If emotional intensity increases an equal amount in both territories, the gap between

quota and contest profits widens.

The result in Proposition 3 is new since the extant literature comparing different schemes

has ignored emotions. Part (a) says that pride in the weaker territory increases profits for both the

contest and the quota but it benefits the contest more. In contrast Syam, Hess and Yang (2011)

find that when emotions are ignored, territory imbalance decreases profits for the contest and the

quota but it hurts the contest more.

One might expect that emotions are more intense in a contest than quota, because the

contest can get personal: “I really want to win the contest to show Tom who is the better

salesperson!” Can the advantage of the quota due to imbalanced territories be overcome by these

intrinsic motivations? The answer is, “Yes.” Suppose we begin without emotions at point 0 in

Figure 1, and allow pride and disappointment to intensify only in the contest.2 That is, suppose

that emotions for the contest enlarge along the dashed 45o line until they reach the level

corresponding to point A. At this point, the emotions are δ1C=π2

C=2(1−3 k ) . It is 2 The emotions in the quota are set to zero only for analytical simplicity. Clearly our result will hold as long as the contest engenders sufficiently stronger emotions compared to the quota.

22

Page 24: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

straightforward to show that the profits of the contest at this point A exceed the profits of the

quota without emotions, so long as imbalance is not too large (k≤0.2).

Proposition 4: Suppose that the quota system does not engender pride and disappointment, but that the mano-a-mano character of the contest creates feelings of pride and disappointment. Even though the quota system has a natural advantage with imbalanced territories, the emotional motivations of the contest can make it the more profitable compensation system.

This result is also new to the literature. In the absence of emotions, the extant literature

comparing relative and absolute schemes finds that the quota is either equivalent to the contest or

dominates it (Lazear and Rosen 1981; Green and Stokey 1983; Syam, Hess and Yang 2011),

unless there are sizeable common shocks. We have shown that when agents’ emotions are

properly accounted for in compensation plans, the contest can dominate the quota even in the

absence of common shocks. Of course, if there are common shocks this advantage of the contest

will be even more pronounced.

4. Handicapping the Territories

Suppose that the territories can be handicapped so that the imbalance is contractually

eliminated. Handicapping of the contest can be done if the firm compares the sales from the two

territories, explicitly accounting for the fact that territory 2 is disadvantaged, a la Lazear and

Rosen (1981). Handicapping of the quota can be done simply by setting territory-specific quotas.

As shown in the Appendix, optimally handicapping the contest and quota neutralizes the effect

of imbalance, and the agents’ efforts and firm’s profits are those that would obtain if territories

were balanced.

However, this may have an unintended consequence of eliminating the strong emotions

associated with the job, since it is the imbalanced nature of the territories that engenders the

23

Page 25: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

strong emotions as alluded to in Section 4. Imbalance in territories creates an underdog versus

favorite situation and gives rise to the strong emotions associated with winning or losing (see

also Kräkel 2008a). Without imbalance there can still be emotions but at the minimal level which

can be normalized to zero. Suppose that the firm can set k=0 at the consequence of also setting a

common emotional intensity δ1C=π2

C=μC equal to zero. The profits in a contest would change

from μC+(1−k−2/ (1−2 k ))2 to 1, a drop in profits if the pride were large. This is true if

μC≥1−(1−k− k1−2 k )

2. (

As seen in Figure 2a, for large emotional intensity, it does not pay to handicap a sales contest.

Figure 2: Region of Unprofitable Handicapping of Contest and Quota as a Function of Emotional Intensity and Territory Imbalance

24

b.a.

TerritoryImbalance, k

Unprofitable to Handicap Quota

0.20

0.8

Emotional Intensity, Q

Unprofitable to Handicap Contest

0.20

0.8

Emotional Intensity, C

TerritoryImbalance, k

Page 26: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

The profits in the quota system would change from 2μQ+(1−k−μQ

2 )2

to 1 if the

territories were balanced by a handicapped quota system. This would be a drop in profits if the

emotions were large:

μQ≥2√1+4 k−2 (1+k ) . (

As seen in Figure 2b, for large emotional intensity, it does not pay to handicap quotas.

We have assumed in this section until now that the emotions in a contest are just as

intense as those in a quota. Contrary to the classic line from the movies, “It’s not personal; it’s

strictly business,” a sales contest can be very personal. Beating a notable colleague in a sales

contest is likely to give rise to stronger emotions than merely exceeding an impersonal sales

quota. If so, it is possible that the firm would want to handicap a quota system, but not a contest.

Proposition 5: If emotional intensity is large but would vanish if territories are balanced, handicapping the territories is unprofitable for either contest or quota. If, in addition, the mano-a-mano character of the contest makes the intensity of pride and disappointment much greater in contests than with quotas, the firm profits from handicapping a quota but not from handicapping a contest.

Thus, by incorporating agents’ emotions into contests and quotas, our theory provides a

rationale for each of two commonly observed anecdotal practices regarding handicapping of

compensation systems: first, we often do not see handicapped contests and second, it is much

more common to see handicapped quotas rather than handicapped contests. Of course, if the

emotional intensity is small, the firm will still find it optimal to handicap the territories.

25

Page 27: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

5. Conclusions

In this research we introduced the emotions of pride and disappointment in the

comparison of sales contests and quotas when sales territories are imbalance. Specifically, since

an agent in the stronger territory was expected to win, she feels disappointment if she loses the

contest or fails to make quota. Similarly, an agent in the weaker territory feels pride if she wins

the contest or makes quota since she was expected to lose. Though there has been some work in

incorporating emotions in contests, the incorporating of emotions in quotas is new to the

literature.

One major result is that when emotions in a contest are intense enough the contest can be

more profitable than the quota. This result is novel since extant work finds that, in the absence of

common shocks, the quota dominates the contest on purely economic grounds when agents’

emotions are not accounted for. Thus, we provide a new rationale for the popularity of contests

even when there are no common shocks in the environment.

Another result is that when emotions are intense enough, the firm will not want to

handicap the contest and quota system. This result too runs counter to the literature which finds

that handicapping is always beneficial on economic grounds since it can overcome the negative

effects of territory imbalance which always reduces agents’ efforts. The reason is that territory

imbalance paves the way for agents’ emotions to take effect, and by handicapping the

compensation schemes to negate the effect of imbalance the firm also marginalizes the role of

emotions. Since profits increase in emotions, the result follows. If the emotions for contests are

more intense than for quotas, as they could be due to their interpersonal nature, then the firm will

handicap a quota even when it chooses not to handicap the contest. This provides a rationale for

why we see many handicapped quotas but very few handicapped contests.

26

Page 28: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

References

Chen, Hua, Sung H. Ham and Noah Lim (2011), "Designing Asymmetric Multi-Person Tournaments: An Experimental Study," Management Science, 57(5), 864-883.

Deci, E.L. and R.M. Ryan (1985), Intrinsic Motivation and Self-Determination in Human Behavior, New York: Plenum Press.

Elster, Jon (1998), “Emotions and Economic Theory,” J. of Economic Literature 36(1), 47-74.

Gilbert, Daniel and Timothy Wilson (2000), “Miswanting: Some Problems in the Forecasting of Future Affective States,” In J. Forgas (Ed.), Thinking and Feeling: The Role of Affect in Social Cognition. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Gill, David and Rebecca Stone (2010), “Fairness and Desert in Tournaments,” Games and Economic Behavior, 69, 346-364.

Green, Jerry and Nancy Stokey (1983), “A Comparison of Tournaments and Contracts,” Journal of Political Economy, 91(3), 349-364.

Grund, Christian and Dirk Sliwka (2005), “Envy and Compassion in Tournaments,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 14(1), 187-207.

Holt, Charles A. and Roger Sherman (1994), “The Loser's Curse.” The American Economic Review 84(3): 642-652.

Kalra, Ajay and Mengze Shi (2001), “Designing Optimal Sales Contests: A Theoretical Perspective,” Marketing Science, 20(2), 170-193.

Kim, Son Ku (1997), “Limited Liability and Bonus Contracts,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 6(4), 899-913.

Kräkel, Matthias (2008a), “Emotions in Tournaments,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 67, 204-214.

Kräkel, Matthias (2008b), “Emotions and Compensation,” Schmalenbach Business Review 60(April), 145-159.

Latham, Gary P (2003), “Motivate Employee Performance through Goal-setting," The Blackwell Handbook of Principles of Organizational Behaviour. Locke, Edwin A. Blackwell Publishing, 107-119.

Lazear, Edward and Sherwin Rosen (1981), “Rank-Order Tournaments as Optimum Labor Contracts,” Journal of Political Economy, 89(5), 841-864.

Loewenstein, G (2000), “Emotions in Economic Theory and Economic Behavior,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings, 90, 426-432.

27

Page 29: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Lucas, Henry, Charles Weinberg and Kenneth Clowes (1975), “Sales Response as a Function of Territorial Potential and Sales Representative Workload,” Journal of Marketing Research, 12(3), 298-305.

Mantrala, Murali, Kalyan Raman and Ramarao Desiraju (1997), “Sales Quota Plans: Mechanisms for Adaptive Learning,” Marketing Letters, 8(4), 393-405.

Mantrala, Murali, Prabhakant Sinha and Andris Zoltners (1994), “Structuring a Multiproduct Sales Quota-Bonus Plan for a Heterogeneous Sales Force: A Practical Model-Based Approach,” Marketing Science, 13 (2), 121-144.

Murphy, William H., and Peter A. Dacin (1998), "Sales Contests: A Research Agenda,” Journal of Personal Selling & Sales Management, 18(1), 1-16.

Nalebuff, Barry and Joseph Stiglitz (1983), “Prizes and Incentives: Towards a General Theory of Compensation and Competition,” Bell Journal of Economics, 14(1), 21-43.

Oyer, Paul (2000), “A Theory of Sales Quotas with Limited Liability and Rent Sharing,” Journal of Labor Economics, 18(3), 405-426.

Patrick, Vanessa M., HaeEun Helen Chun, and Deborah J. MacInnis (2009), “Affective Forecasting and Self-Control: Why Anticipating Pride Wins Over Anticipating Shame in a Self-Regulation Context,” Journal of Consumer Psychology, 19 (3), 537–45.

Rabin, Matthew (1983), “Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics,” American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281-1302.

Raju, Jagmohan and V. Srinivasan (1996), “Quota-Based Compensation Plans for Multiterritory Heterogeneous Salesforces,” Management Science, 42(10), 1454-1462.

Syam, Niladri, James D. Hess and Ying Yang (2011), “Sales Contests versus Quotas with Imbalanced Territories,” Working Paper, University of Houston.

Zoltners, Andris A., Sally E. Lorimer (2000), “Sales Territory Alignment: An Overlooked Productivity Tool,” J. Personal Selling Sales Management 20(3), 139–150.

Zoltners, Anders, Prabhakant Sinha and Sally Lorimer (2006), The Complete Guide to Sales Force Incentive Compensation, AMACOM Publishers, New York.

28

Page 30: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Appendix

Quota

Achieving quota is never certain. The probability that the salesperson assigned the stronger

territory 1 can make the sales quota is P1=½ + k - Q + e1, while the probability in territory 2 is

smaller, P2=½ - k - Q + e2. The expected net utility of the salesperson assigned to territory i is

EUi=(B+i)Pi+(0-i)(1-Pi)– ½ei2. Specifically, EU1=(B)P1+(0-1)(1-P1)– ½e1

2 =-1+(B+1)(½ + k

- Q + e1) – ½ei2. Take the derivative and set to zero,

∂EU 1

∂e1=B+δ1−e1=0

, to get the optimal

effort e1=B+1. Similarly for territory 2, EU2=(B+2)P2+0(1-P2)– ½e22=(B+2)( ½ - k - Q + e2)–

½e22 and the first order condition is

∂EU 2

∂ e2=B+π2−e2=0

and the resulting effort is e2=B+2.

Back substituting in territory 2 give EU 2=(B+π 2)(12−k−Q )+ 1

2 (B+π2)2=0 .

Solve for Q: Q=12−k+ 1

2 (B+π2 ) . Substituting Q gives the expected profit is

EΠ Q=e1+e2−B Pr (1 makes Quota)−B Pr (2 makes Quota )=2 B+δ 1+π2−B (1

2 +k−Q+B+δ 1+12−k−Q+B+π 2)

=2 B+δ 1+π2−B (1−2 Q+2B+δ1+π2 )

=δ1+π 2−B(−2+1−2( 12−k+ 1

2 (B+π2 ))+2B+δ1+π2 )

=δ1+π 2−B(−1−2( 12−k )+B+δ 1)

=δ 1+π2+B (2(1−k )−B−δ 1) .

The first order condition

∂EΠ Q

∂B=2(1−k )−2 B−δ1=0

, yields the bonus B=1-k -½ , and

back substituting gives

EΠ Q=δ1+π2+(1−k−δ1 /2 )(2(1−k )−(1−k )+δ1 /2−δ1)=δ 1+π2+(1−k−δ 1/2)

2 ,

29

Page 31: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

e1∗¿1−k+ 12 δ1>0 ,

e2∗¿1−k+π2−12 δ1>0 ,

Q∗¿1−32 k− 1

4 δ 1+12 π2>0 ,

0<P1=12+

32 k+ 3

4 δ1−12 π2<1 ,

0<P2=12−

12 k− 1

4 δ1+12 π2<1 .

Note that we have to restrict k, 1, and 2 so that efforts, bonus, quota, probability of making

quota are all sensible. First, we need P1<1 or π2>−1+3 k+ 32 δ 1 . We also need P2<1 or

π2<1+k+ 12 δ 1 . Finally we need π2<2 k+δ1 for territory 1 to be stronger. Note that the

first two inequalities cross at 1=2(1-k). But the first and third inequalities also cross at this

point. Since the third inequality is stricter than the second, we can ignore the second.

Contest

Expected utilities are of the form EU2=S+(B+2)(1-P1)- ½ e22 while probability of winning the

contest are Prob(s1≥s2) = P1= 1-½(1+e2-e1-2k)2. The utility maximizing efforts of both

salespeople are [e1

e2 ]=2(1/2−k )1+δ1−π2 [B+δ1

B+π2 ] .Back substituting gives

EU 2=S+(B+π2 )12 (1−2 k+e 2−e1 )2−1

2 e22

¿ S+2(B+π2 )(12−k+

12−k1+δ1−π2

(π 2−δ1 ))2−1

2e

22

¿ S+2(12−k1+δ1−π2

)2

[(B+π2 )− (B+π 2)2 ]

30

Page 32: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Solve this for salary and substitute into the expected profits

EΠ C=e1+e2−2 S−B=212−k1+δ 1−π2

(2B+π2+δ1 )

+4 (12−k1+δ 1−π 2

)2

(B+π2−(B+π2 )2)−B

The first order condition for the bonus is

∂EΠ C

∂B=4

12−k

1+δ 1−π2+4(

12−k

1+δ1−π2)2

(1−2(B+π 2))−1=0

1+δ1−π212−k

+1−2(B+π2 )−14 (1+δ1−π2

12−k )

2

=0

21+δ1−π2

1−2 k+1−(1+δ1−π2

1−2 k )2

=2(B+π 2)

¿−1+21+δ1−π 2

1−2 k−(1+δ1−π 2

1−2 k )2

+2=2(B+π2 )

Hence the optimal bonus is

B∗¿1−π 2−12 (1+δ1−π2

1−2 k−1)

2

=1−π2−18 ( δ1−π 2+2 k

1/2−k )2

.

Maximized profit is

EΠ C=212−k1+δ1−π2

(2(1−18 (δ1−π2+2 k

1/2−k )2

)+δ1−π 2) +

4 (12−k1+δ1−π 2

)2

(1−18 (δ 1−π2+2k

1/2−k )2

−(1−18 (δ1−π2+2k

1/2−k )2

)2)−1+1

8 (δ1−π2+2k1 /2−k )

2

+π2 ,

31

Page 33: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

which can be simplified to

EΠ C=2( 12−k )−

2( 12−k )

1+δ1−π2+ 1

4 ( 2 ( 12−k )

1+δ1−π2+2−

1+δ1−π2

2( 12−k ) )

2

+π 2 ,

e1∗¿1+2( 12−k )−

12−k

1+δ1−π2−

14

1+δ1−π 212−k ,

e2∗¿1+12−k

1+δ1−π 2−

14

1+δ1−π212−k .

Proof of Proposition 1.

EΠ Q=δ1+π2+(1−k−δ1 /2 )2 . Taking derivatives gives

∂EΠ Q

∂ π2=1>0

and

∂EΠ Q

∂ δ1=1−δ1(1−k−δ1 /2)=1−δ 1(1−k )+δ

12 /2=(δ12−2(1−k )δ1+2)/2=((δ1−1+k )2+2−(1−k )2 )/2 .

Since 0≤k≤1/2, 1-k<1, so this derivative with respect to δ 1 is positive.

Suppose that π2=π

2o+μ , and δ1=δ1o+μ

. Then

∂EΠQ

∂ μ=2−δ1 (1−k−δ1 /2)=2−δ1(1−k )+δ

12 /2=1+(δ12−2(1−k )δ1+2)/2=1+((δ1−1+k )2+2−(1−k )2) /2 >1 .

Proof of Proposition 2.

Proof that EC increases with 2 : The expected profit is

EΠ C=π2+2( 12−k )−

2 ( 12−k )

1+δ 1−π2+ 1

4 ( 2( 12−k )

1+δ1−π 2+2−

1+δ1−π2

2( 12−k ) )

2

,which can be simplified by

32

Page 34: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

writing Z≡

1+δ1−π2

2( 12−k )

=1+δ1−π2+2k

2( 12−k )

>1. Thus, expected profit is

EΠ C=π2+2( 12−k )− 1

Z+ 1

4 ( 1Z+2−Z)

2

. The total derivative with respect to 2 can be thought

of as having a direct and indirect part:

dE ΠC

dπ 2=1+ ∂ EΠC

∂Z ( −11−2 k ) . The partial derivative with

respect to Z is

∂EΠC

∂Z=Z4−2 Z3−1

2Z3, which can be factored as

∂EΠ C

∂Z=(Z−2 .11)(Z+ .717 )((Z−. 305)2+. 569 )

2 Z3. The requirements that δ 1−π2+2k≥0 and

that P1Q≤1 (or ≥-(1-3k)+3/2 1 means that pride and disappointment must be in the shaded

region in Figure 3. We also assume that e2C>0 when there are no emotions, which implies that

k< 12+√2

≃0 .2929. For the purpose of the proof we also consider values where 1=0 and 2 is

below zero but above –(2/3-2k).

33

Page 35: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Figure 3

Suppose that 1=0 and 2=-(2/3-2k). This implies that Z=1+ 2/3

2 ( 12−k ) . Given the factorization

of the total derivative given above, if Z<2.11, then the derivative is greater than 1. But this

inequality is equivalent to k< 1

2− 1

3×2.11≃0 .34 .

Because we assume that k cannot exceed

0.2929, this implies that

dE ΠC

dπ 2>1 .

The second derivative of the profit function with respect to

2 is

d2 EΠ C

dπ22=∂

2 EΠC

∂Z2 ( 11−2 k )

2

. The second partial derivative with respect to Z is

∂2 EΠ C

∂Z2 =12 (1+ 3

Z4 )>0 . This implies that the derivative

dE ΠC

dπ 2 starts above 1 and gets larger

as 2 increases in the interval [-(2/3-2k), 2k].

34

0

2

1

32

1

-(1-3k)

-(2/3-2k)2/3-2k 2(1-k)

2k

Page 36: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Suppose that we begin at a disappointment and pride (0,20) and then increase each value

by an equal amount to that we reach a new value (,20+). The value of Z does not change, but

2 becomes progressively larger. Each point in the shaded region could be increased by a small

amount holding 1 constant. That is, we move from (1,2) to (1,2+d2). This could be thought

of as decomposed into (1,2) = (,20) +(,) and (1,2+d2) = (,2

0+d)+(,). The upward

change improves profits and the equal displacement in emotional intensity leaves this

improvement unaffected. Hence, when the only change is an increase in pride in the weaker

territory 2, the profits must increase, as was to be shown.

Proof that EC decreases with 1. As above the total derivative with respect to 1 is

dE ΠC

dδ1=∂ EΠC

∂Z ( 11−2 k ) . As above,

∂EΠ C

∂Z=(Z−2 . 11)(Z+ .717 )((Z−. 305)2+. 569 )

2 Z3. Let us

limit ourselves to 2=0 and start at 1=0, where Z=1/(1-2k). The term Z-2.11 is negative if

k<(2.11-1)/2×2.11=.26. Suppose that you go to 1=2/3-2k. Then Z-2.11 is negative if k<1/2 –

1/(3×(2.11-1))=.20. Since Z is linear in 1, if k<.20,

dE ΠC

dδ1<0

for all 1[0,2/3-2k]. By

expanding each such point by (,), this shows that for k<0, the negative effect occurs in the

cross hatched region in Figure 4. To get the remainder of the region, we would have to start with

negative 1. Let 1=-2k, so that Z=1. Then clearly Z-2.11<0. Again because Z is linear in 1, this

implies that for k<.20,

dE ΠC

dδ1<0

for all 1[-2k,2/3-2k]. Hence, for k<.20, this implies that

profit decreases in disappoint for all legitimate emotion levels.

35

Page 37: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Figure 4

Proof of Proposition 3. Start with 1=0, so profits are EΠ Q=π2+ (1−k )2 and

EΠ C=π2+2( 12−k )− 1

Z+ 1

4 ( 1Z+2−Z)

2

where Z≡

1−π2

2 ( 12−k )

=1+2 k−π2

2 ( 12−k )

>1.

When 2=2k, Z=1 and EΠ Q=1+k2 > EΠ C=1 . At 2=0, Z=1/(1-2k) and

EΠ Q=(1−k )2 > EΠ C=(1−k )2− 8k

(1−2 k )2((1−k )2− 1

2).

36

 

-2k 0

2

1

 32

1

 

 

-(1-3k)

-(2/3-2k)2/3-2k 2(1-k)

2k

 

 

 

 

 

 

Page 38: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Figure 5

At 2=-(2/3-2k), this implies that Z=1+ 2/3

2 ( 12−k ) .

As seen above the derivative of EC is

dE ΠC

dπ 2=1+ ∂ EΠC

∂Z ( −11−2 k ) where

∂EΠ C

∂Z=Z4−2 Z3−1

2 Z3. At 2k, this gives

dE ΠC

dπ 2=1+ 1

1−2 k>1

. The second derivative is

∂2 EΠ C

∂ π22=1

2 ( 3Z4+1) 1

(1−2 k )2>0

. Hence, the profit curve lies below the chord connecting the

profits at 0 and 2k, and hence EQEC for all reasonable 2 when 1=0 as seen in Figure 5

37

1

0

1

(1-k)2-8k((1-k)2-1/2)/(1-2k)2

EC

EQ

1+k2

(1-k)2

2k

E

2

Page 39: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

When 1=0, the gap between EQ and EC is maximized when 2 is the value where

dE ΠC

dπ 2=1+∂ EΠC

∂Z ( −11−2 k )=dE ΠQ

dπ2=1

. This occurs when Z=2.11. At 2=-2/3+2k, this

requires k<0.20. Hence if this is true of k and 1=0, as 2 increases the gap between contest and

quota shrinks. Now free 1 to be positive. Any location can be reached by starting at (0,2) and

adding (,) to it. As we have seen this causes the gap to widen, but if you fix 1 and increase 2

the effect on the gap is driven by the effect at (0,2). For any 1, increase in 2 shrinks the gap.

Contest with Handicapping:

Because of the known advantage of territory 1 over territory 2, it seems unfair for the contest to

compare sales that are in part beyond the control of the salespeople. Suppose instead that the

weaker territory 2 is given an accounting head start in an amount h. That is, for the purposes of

the contest, sales are treated as though they were are s1-h and s2+h. Let the handicapped

imbalance be denoted Kk-h. The equilibrium effort levels that result are

e1¿=e2¿=12−K− K /2

12−K . The maximum efforts are achieved at K=0. By deducting this implied

handicap h=k from territory 1 and adding it to territory 2, the problem reduces to the balanced

case. For the handicapped contest the efforts are, e

1HC∗¿=e2HC∗¿

=1

¿¿

, and the profit isEπ HC∗¿=1 ¿.

Quota with Handicapping (Dual Quota Plans):

Consider territory-specific quotas. The quota territory 1, Q1, is greater than the quota for territory

2, Q2, due to the territory imbalance. The sales of territory 1 are s1=k+e1+ε1 and the sales of

territory 2 are s2=−k+e2+ε2 . The probabilities of making quotas respectively

Pr (1 makes Q1 )=12+k−Q1+e1 ,

Pr (2 makes Q2 )=

12−k−Q2+e2 .

The efforts in terms of

38

Page 40: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

bonus are e1=e2=B . Binding at both participation constraints, quotas in terms of bonus are

Q1=12+k+ B

2 and Q2=

12−k+B

2 . So we rewrite the expected profit in terms of B only,

EΠ Q=2 B−B2 . This gives B=1 and the equilibrium, quotas, effort levels, and firm’s profit are

easily obtained. The equilibrium effort levels are e

1DQ∗¿=e2DQ∗¿

=1

¿¿

, and the firm’s profit for the

dual quota are given asEΠ DQ∗¿=1 ¿.

Thus handicapping of the contest and quota correct for territory imbalance and the

agents’ efforts and firm’s profit are those that would be obtained if territories were balanced.

Proof of Proposition 4.

Point A of Figure 1 is where δ1=−(1−3 k )+ 32 δ1 , or δ 1=2(1−3k )=π2 At point A, the contest

profits are

EΠ C=2(1−3k )+(1−k− k2( 1

2−k ))2

.

This exceeds the quota profits at 0, (1-k)2 if and

only if −(k−.25 )(k−.773 )(k−.369 )

(1−2k )2≥0

. Since we are assuming that k≤0.2<.25, this will be

true.

Proof of Proposition 5.

39

Page 41: Thrill of Victory and Agony of Defeat: · Web viewHow does the optimal design of sales contests compare with sales quota systems when sales territories are imbalanced but you account

Suppose that k≤0.2 and that intensity of emotions are at point A where C=2(1-3k). This

satisfies μC≥1−(1−k− k

1−2 k )2

if 2(1−3 k )≥−(1−k− k

1−2k )2

. The roots of this inequality

are 0.202 and above, so for all assumed k, this inequality holds and handicapping the contest

reduces the expected profits. In the context of quotas, for any value of k all one needs to start

with emotions near zero and handicapping will help balance the territories with only a small

reduction in emotional motivation.

40