time as a network good

Upload: ioannis-kanlis

Post on 07-Aug-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    1/18

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    2/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    icized as providing a “subsidy” for “leisure” by “paying people not to work” (e.g., Feldstein andAltman 2007:40; Levin and Wright 2001:375; seealso Keane 2011; Krueger and Meyer 2002; Blun-dell and MaCurdy 1999). Critics described theextended Unemployment Insurance benets dur-ing the Great Recession as turning “our socialsafety net into a hammock” (Weiner 2011:1).

    If time is simply a valuable commodity, thereis a clear upside to unemployment. The free timethat unemployment creates could be comparedto an extended weekend. For most people, theweekend represents “two days of freedom” (Ry-bczynski 1991:7) in which workers live by theirown schedules, do what they choose, and spendtime with whom they want—rather than livingby the demands of their jobs. It seems to follownaturally, then, that more days off offer more

    freedom, more happiness, and more personal ful-llment.From the perspective of a network good, how-

    ever, the essential characteristic of the weekendis not just the having of a day off but ratherthat other people have the day off. The standardworkweek serves as a coordinating mechanism,ensuring that time off work can be converted intosocial time. The opportunity cost of working de-pends on the hours that other people work. Thefreedom of the weekend stems in large part fromthe availability of others.

    This study addresses two interrelated ques-

    tions:

    1. To what extent is time a network good?How much does the availability of othersshape and determine the value of time?

    2. How much of the enjoyment of weekendsis due simply to having a day off work—reducing time pressure and avoiding thedisutility of paid labor? How much of theenjoyment of the weekend can be gained bynot working on weekdays?

    We use the unemployed as a strategic case toanswer these questions. We factor out the netcost/distress of unemployment and focus ondifference-in-difference comparisons of workersand the unemployed by day of week: the differ-ence in how each group experiences Monday toFriday compared to Saturday and Sunday.

    Drawing on half a million respondents fromthe Gallup Daily Poll, we show that there arestriking similarities in day-to-day patterns in theemotional well-being of workers and the unem-ployed. Both experience a clear spike in theirwell-being on weekends and a drop in well-beingduring the week. Specically, the unemployedexperience about 75 percent of the subjectivebenets of weekends: not going to work duringthe week gives the jobless roughly 25 percent of the weekend experience (in terms of day-of-weekwell-being). To much the same degree as workingpeople, the unemployed are “living for the week-end.” This suggests that what people value mostabout weekends is not the day off work per sebut the social opportunities that are possible onwidely shared days off.

    We calibrate this nding by testing for similar

    patterns in social time with family and friendsusing eight waves of the American Time Use Sur-vey (ATUS). Social time—for both workers andthe unemployed—increases notably on weekendsand drops during the week. These differencesin social time explain roughly half of the week-end effect in well-being. In other words, roughlyhalf of the reason why people enjoy weekends isthe opportunity to spend more hours with familyand friends, which is true for both workers andthe unemployed. The remaining, residual bene-t of the weekend is not empirically accountedfor but accrues similarly among the unemployedand workers and may be due to differences inthe quality, as well as quantity, of social time onweekends.

    The comparative dynamics of free time amongworkers and the unemployed sheds unique lighton underappreciated social facts: the networkproperties of time, the role that an institution-alized standard workweek serves in facilitatingsocial time, and the difficulties of resolving timepressure through private individual action with-out broader social coordination.

    Scheduling Constraints and theMarginal Value of Time

    Time, as Winship (2009) observed, comes withtwo basic kinds of limitations: the budget con-straint and the scheduling constraint. The chal-

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 11 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    3/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    lenge of the budget constraint is simple: thereare only 24 hours in a day. In this simple model,time is a homogeneous quantity: an hour is anhour, and the main problem is that there are notenough hours in a day.

    The scheduling constraint, however, shapeswhat individuals can do with their endowment of time. It reects an individual’s ability to coordi-nate time and place with the people with whomthe individual wants to interact and limits howan individual can transform free time into valuedsocial time. Budget constraints are obviously im-portant, but often people’s real frustrations withtime are due to the scheduling constraint—thechallenge of aligning available time with that of others.

    Often, people’s desire for more time is reallya desire for better temporal scheduling that al-

    lows more joint activity with other people (andtheir schedules). Increasing one’s budget of freetime (say, by working less) is at best a partialsolution because working less does not changeother people’s schedules.

    In this sense, time is not like money but morelike goods in a barter economy. Barter requireswhat Jevons (1890) called a “double coincidenceof wants” (pp. 3–4): for exchange to occur, eachparty needs to have specic goods that the otherparty specically wants (cf. Stovel and Fountain2009). If a farmer wishes to build a house, thefarmer must nd someone who both (1) wants

    the farmer’s produce and (2) has lumber or build-ing supplies to exchange. Without a generalizedcurrency, it is difficult to nd exchange partners,and the farmer’s produce has limited value.

    Time suffers from a similar lack of fungibility(Winship 2009:502; Leclerc, Schmitt, and Dube1995). Time cannot be traded or exchanged di-rectly. A surplus of time cannot be stored awayand used later; it can only be consumed in themoment, whether it is particularly wanted ornot. 1 In contrast to money, time is a perishablegood.2

    This means that unexpected time savings,

    rather than being a windfall gain, often leads tousing time in ways that have low marginal value1 In this sense, a surplus of free time is rather like

    being paid in hamburgers: its value depends on how manyhamburgers you can enjoyably eat in one sitting.

    2 In a hyperination economy, money and time becomemuch more similar currencies.

    to individuals.3 Time slots increase in value whenthey can be shared with more people. For timeto have a high marginal value, it often requires adouble coincidence of wants —one or more socialothers (spouse, friend, family member) who havethe same schedule of free time. Otherwise, freetime becomes spare time, and individuals facethe prospect of “bowling alone” (Putnam 2000).

    Time as a Network GoodNetwork goods are things that increase in value asmore and more people have them: whenever some-one new acquires the good, it creates a positiveexternality for others. The telephone is a classicexample. In 1910, few people had telephones intheir homes. As a result, there was little rea-son for a person to own a phone: there was noone to call. As the network of phone ownershipexpanded, there was more and more reason toinvest in one. Every new household and businessthat had a phone created an incremental benetto telephone ownership in general, as the technol-ogy increased in utility. Virtually all informationtechnologies have these kinds of network effects:the value of e-mail, Facebook, Craigslist, Pay-Pal, and text messaging all depend on how manyother users there are (and often on how manyusers a person knows) (DiMaggio and Garip 2012;DiMaggio and Cohen 2005; Shapiro and Varian1999). Things like dating or carpooling likewisedepend on how many other people want to dothem; neither activity is possible without otheravailable participants. When one person becomessingle again, it creates a positive externality forother single people (Åberg 2009).

    Time is a quintessential network good. Fewthings are best done alone. Most activities areeither more enjoyable or more productive whendone with others. The efficacy of things like fac-tory production, political protests, church gather-ings, Christmas parties, family dinners, and foot-ball games depends on how many people show

    up for them. When an additional person goesto church, that person creates a positive exter-3 The idea of “saving time” suggests a continuous sched-

    ule of activities, so that when one task is completed morequickly, an individual can start the next task ahead of schedule. The opposite of this is the “hurry up and wait”problem: the next task requires input from others whoare not ready ahead of schedule.

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 12 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    4/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    nality for other churchgoers, who can enjoy amore vibrant religious experience. The more fam-ily members show up for Thanksgiving dinner,the more a sense of family is created. Of course,network goods can run into diminishing returnsand congestion problems. Production-line fac-tory systems cannot run if only a few workersshow up, but there can also be too many workers.Likewise, dinner parties can be too big, and therecan be too many cooks in the kitchen. Innitelyincreasing returns to a population are not neededfor network effects to be important. For manyleisure activities, a handful of people make thedifference between isolation and rich interaction.In any event, coordinating multiple participantsto be engaged in the same social event is a basicprecondition for successful “interaction rituals” that generate the emotional energy, mutual en-

    trainment, collective effervescence, and feelingsof solidarity and belonging that make up themicrofoundations of society (Collins 2004).

    The Standard Workweek as aCoordinating MechanismThe standard workweek is one of the most im-portant (and taken-for-granted) institutions toprovide social coordination of time and participa-tion. By coordinating people to work much thesame hours and take the same days off, the stan-

    dard workweek makes both work and leisure moreattractive (so long as they happen at the righttimes). First, a standardized workweek meansthat when a person has a day off work, so domost other people that individual knows. Thismaximizes shared time available for social inter-action on days off (weekends and holidays) andraises the value of leisure time for most people.Second, when the individual has to go to work, sodoes most everyone else. The standard workweekreduces the opportunity cost of going to work;there are few important events that people aremissing during usual working hours. This limitsthe desire to take extra time off and encouragesfull-time work.

    In contrast to a standardized workweek, imag-ine a system in which there are no xed weekends;all days are potential workdays (Hornstein 2002).People choose which two days they want to takeoff. People work ve out of seven days, and each

    day, roughly ve-sevenths of the labor force comesinto work. Factories and office buildings run witha mostly full (70 percent) staff seven days a week.Because people would have greater choice overtheir working days, the system offers a net in-crease in freedom. It is analogous to ending thecustom of church on Sundays and letting church-goers of each congregation sort out for themselveswhich day would really work best for worship.

    A rotating, seven-day workweek is not just athought experiment. It was implemented on amass scale in the Soviet Union in 1929, in an ef-fort to maximize industrial production (Zerubavel1985; Foss 2004). The central goal was to keep thefactories running every day, transforming the 52Sunday shutdowns per year into full productiondays. The new “Red Calendar” was a complexcreation that divided the months into ve-day,

    rather than seven-day, weeks. Factories wouldoperate every day, with 80 percent of staff onduty. Each day, one-fth of workers would havethe day off. The new calendar allowed for the con-tinuous operation of factories and also increasedthe number of leisure days workers had. Sovietworkers now rested one out of every ve days (73days a year) rather than the previous one out of seven (52 days a year) (as was the norm in theWest at that time). In effect, the new systemincreased the workweek of capital, while reducingthe workweek of labor. Nonetheless, the Red Cal-endar survived only two years and suffered manypractical problems of implementation. Most im-portantly, as Foss (2004) notes, “workers hatedit” (p. 47).

    The Red Calendar gave people more free timebut made it exceedingly difficult to coordinatethat time with anyone else. Many families sawtheir shared rest day—the old Sunday—disappear.They now had more days off, but many never hadthe same day off as their spouse. “Authoritiesessentially divided the entire society into ve sepa-rate working populations, staggered vis-a-vis oneanother” (Zerubavel 1985:38). If spouses wereassigned different workdays, they would almost

    never have a shared day of rest. Only 20 percentof the workforce would share a common rest day,so the odds of connecting with family and friendswere low. “In address books, people would addto the names of friends and acquaintances . . .the day of the week on which [those people] wereoff duty” (Zerubavel 1985:37). The official Soviet

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 13 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    5/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    newspaper Pravda gave voice to the complaint: “What is there for us to do at home if our wivesare in the factory, our children at school, andnobody can visit us . . . ? It is no holiday if you have to have it alone ” (quoted in Zerubavel1985:38; emphasis added).

    The central lesson from this experiment inreengineering time is the primacy of schedulingconstraints and the network properties of freetime. Even large increases in the budget of freetime matter little when those hours are discon-nected from the lives of our social others. We donot just want time away from work; we want freetime when our family and friends have free time.

    A modest formalization helps to drive thispoint home. In a society without a standardworkweek, the chance that a rest day, r, can be jointly shared with n people is proportional to

    rn

    . The coordination challenge increases exponen-tially with the number of people involved. Withtwo rest days per seven-day week, each personhas an r = 0 .28 chance of being off work on agiven day. What are the chances that their daysoff by coincidence align with others? For twofriends (i.e., 0 .282 ), the daily chance that theywill have the same day off is only 8 percent (onceevery 12 days), for three friends the chances area mere 2 percent (once every 45 days), and forfour friends the chances are roughly one-half of 1percent (once every 162 days). The occasion of four specic people having the same day off work

    purely by chance would happen only twice a year.Without the coordination of a standardized work-week, friends and family members would rarelyhave the same day off work.

    Weekend Effects

    What is a weekend? Is it just two days whenone does not have to go to work? Is the week-end primarily about avoiding the disutility orunpleasantness of work? If so, workers could pri-vately re-create their experience of the weekend

    anytime they choose by taking extra days off. Weargue that the essence of the weekend is not theavoidance of work per se but rather the socialpossibilities that arise with coordinated time off.

    In the standard workweek, “days off work” and “social days” perfectly overlap as weekends.It is not possible to distinguish the value of a

    day off as apart from the value of greater socialtime with family and friends. A day off means aweekend, which means broadly shared time awayfrom work.

    The unemployed are an interesting case in thisrespect. In the world of time, the unemployedface a conundrum: they experience a large in-crease in their budget of free, unstructured timebut simultaneously face a tangible schedulingconstraint—other people still have to go to work.

    The unemployed allow us to unbundle twoaspects of the weekend. For the unemployed, alldays are “days off”—they may keep busy, butthey do not go to work for an employer. How-ever, they are still limited by the same number of Saturdays and Sundays as everyone else. From apure time budget perspective, weekends for theunemployed should not matter: there is just an

    undifferentiated sequence of days with plenty of unstructured time. What makes weekends spe-cial for the unemployed is that other people alsohave time off —two days per week when schedul-ing constraints are relaxed and nonworkdays canbecome social days.

    Our difference-in-difference strategy for un-bundling the weekend is laid out in Figure 1.We do not compare workers and the unemployeddirectly. Rather, we compare the “weekend ef-fects” of these two groups. How much does anunemployed person’s well-being increase on theweekend compared to the increase experienced

    by workers? This factors out the average dif-ference in well-being between workers and theunemployed, focusing purely on differences intheir day-of-week patterns. Do weekends ceaseto have meaning for the unemployed? How muchof the weekend buzz can be sustained by notworking during the week?

    This research strategy coheres well with stud-ies on the costs of working nonstandard hours.Nonstandard employment arrangements such asworking nights and rotating shifts have beencalled “unsociable work” (Strazdins et al. 2006:394;Lesnard 2008). A considerable body of literaturedocuments the negative effect of unsociable workhours on families: declines in marital satisfac-tion, problems with children, and greater riskof divorce (Presser 2003; White and Keith 1990;Strazdins et al. 2006). From a time schedul-ing perspective, nonstandard work hours are theinverse of unemployment: working when other

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 14 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    6/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    Monday-Friday Saturday/Sunday Di ff erence Diff erence-in-Diff erence

    Worker Work ( W w ) Non-Work andSocial (NW S w )

    Weekend E ff ect(NW S w − W w ) Weekend Eff ect w −

    Unemployed Non-Work

    (N W u )

    Non-Work and

    Social (NW S u )

    Weekend E ff ect

    (NW S u − NW u )

    Weekend E ff ect u

    Figure 1: Time use by day of week for workers and the unemployed.

    people have free time is the inverse of having freetime when other people are working. Both are abreakdown in the temporal coordination of workand nonwork schedules, defecting from the stan-dard workweek; they are different problems, butthey represent two sides of the same coin in thescheduling constraint problem. This study helps

    to generalize the scholarship on unsociable work,viewing the problem from a broader theoreticallens, identifying parallel problems with nonworkhours, and specically measuring the value of time using subjective well-being.

    Data SetsWe use two independent data sets to test ourhypotheses: the Gallup Daily Poll and the ATUS.First, we use the Gallup Daily Poll to examinesubjective well-being by day of week for workersand the unemployed. Second, we use both Gallupand the ATUS to examine the amount of socialtime enjoyed by both groups each day of theweek.

    Since 2008, Gallup has interviewed at least1,000 American adults each day and, by 2011,had sampled almost 1.3 million respondents. TheDaily Poll includes questions on emotional well-being and labor force status and offers a uniqueopportunity to study small populations. For ex-ample, a key estimate of interest in this study isthe well-being of unemployed people on weekends.However, less than 5 percent of the total sample

    is jobless,4

    and only one in four of those respon-dents were sampled on weekends. Despite thissmall baseline population, that leaves us with asample of “unemployed people on the weekend” of

    4 This corresponds to an unemployment rate in thesample of 7.5 percent, which is not far from the officialunemployment rate during this sampling time frame.

    nearly 9,000 respondents—larger than what mostsocial surveys collect for their entire samples.

    In this study, we focus on the data collectedbetween January 2009 and December 2011. Priorto 2009, the Gallup data do not allow us to iden-tify the unemployed. Even without the 2008data, the Daily Poll includes more than 970,000

    respondents. Some 54 percent of them were ei-ther employed or self-employed at the time of survey. About 4.5 percent of all respondents,or 43,112 respondents, were unemployed: notworking but “actively looking for employment” and able to start working if they were offered a job. Respondents are distributed approximatelyequally across the seven days of the week.

    We focus on seven questions in the Daily Pollon positive and negative emotional well-being(Diener et al. 2010; Diener 1994; Kahneman et al.2004). For positive well-being, the questions arewhether respondents “smiled or laughed,” experi-

    enced “enjoyment,” and experienced “happiness” alot on the previous day. Respondents answer yesor no to these questions. We consider this some-what unfortunate, as a wider range of possibleresponses would capture more variation in well-being. Averaging the three responses, the variablefor positive emotions ranges from 0 for peoplewho experienced no positive emotions to 1 forpeople who experienced all of them. For negativewell-being, four questions asked whether respon-dents experienced “worry,” “sadness,” “stress,” or

    “anger” a lot on the previous day. These scores arelikewise averaged to range from 0 for respondentswho did not experience any negative emotion to 1for respondents who experienced all four negativeemotions (see the supplement for more details).

    In addition to these measures of emotionalwell-being, the Daily Poll asks a simple questionof how many hours respondents spent sociallywith friends or family the day before (including

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 15 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    7/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    telephone, e-mail, or other online communica-tions). With this question, we can examine howthe amount of social time uctuates from weekdayto weekend.

    To augment these data, and obtain a morerobust measure of social time, we examine eightwaves of the ATUS, from 2003 to 2011. TheATUS is collected by the Bureau of Labor Statis-tics and is an offshoot of the Current PopulationSurvey (CPS), administered two to ve monthsafter a respondent has completed a CPS rotation.Respondents are asked to recount the activitiesof one single day, beginning at 4:00 a.m. “yes-terday” and ending at 4:00 a.m. on the morningof the interview. From these records, we usethe aggregate time spent with family and timespent with friends. The categories are not com-pletely exclusive, as people can spend time with

    both friends and family simultaneously. However,this provides a more detailed, reliable, and com-prehensive measurement of social time than theGallup Poll, allowing us both to calibrate and toenrich that evidence.5

    The 2003 to 2011 waves of the ATUS give apooled sample of 6,212 unemployed respondentsand 78,661 working people. The unemploymentrate in the study (unemployed/labor force) is 7.3percent. The survey substantially oversamplesweekends. Half the sample is selected to reporton a weekday (Monday to Friday) and half toreport on a weekend (Saturday or Sunday). We

    treat the seven holidays included in the sample asweekend days (New Year’s Day, Easter, MemorialDay, Fourth of July, Labor Day, Thanksgiving,and Christmas), as we do with the Gallup data.Missing data, primarily due to nonresponse onfamily income, reduces the nal sample of laborforce participants to 61,684. The supplementshows the descriptive statistics for the ATUSdata.

    Respondents to both surveys are randomlyselected to report on either weekdays or weekends.This simplies the analysis of weekend effects, asindividual characteristics should be exogenous tothe day-of-week reporting. In the supplement,we show that for both data sets, those reportingon the weekend are more or less demographi-cally identical to those reporting on weekdays.

    5 Note that the ATUS social time measures are basedon copresence and do not include time spent on electroniccommunication.

    There are small differences that achieve statisti-cal signicance owing to our very large samplesizes but that are substantively unimportant. Inthe ATUS data, the average age of both groupsrounds down to 41 years, though the one-thirdof a year difference achieves statistical signi-cance. The largest demographic difference is inthe Gallup data, where the weekend respondentshave a higher unemployment rate (8.8 percent)than weekday respondents (8.1 percent). Our fullregression models adjust for these differences, butfor the most part, a simple analysis of the rawdata will be just as informative as, and perhapsmore intuitive than, regression analysis.

    Model SpecicationThere are ve outcome variables in this study:rst we focus on (1) positive emotions and (2)negative emotions, and next we focus on (3) so-cial hours, (4) time spent with family, and (5)time spent with friends. The key treatment vari-able is the day of week (simplied as weekdayvs. weekend), with employment status serving asa context variable for the treatment effect. Tosimplify the exposition, this article excludes per-sons out of the labor force.6 The basic well-beingand time use model, without control variables, iswritten as

    Y i = α + β 1 Worker Weekend i + β 2 Unemployed i

    + β 3 Unemp Weekend i + εi . (1)The parameters of this model give the simpleaverage outcome (either well-being or social time)for four conditions:

    1. Working people on weekdays (Monday toFriday): α

    2. Working people on weekends (Saturday, Sun-day, and holidays): α + β 1

    3. Unemployed people on weekdays: α + β 24. Unemployed people on weekends: α + β 2 +

    β 36 Data on people out of the labor force (OLF) are not

    relevant to computing coefficients listed in equation 1.Analyses of OLF are available on request. The estimatesare broadly similar to those for unemployed people.

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 16 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    8/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    This approach is equivalent to—and gives identi-cal results as—computing well-being and socialtime averages for each of the four groups. Thecomparison of weekend effects is simpler. Theincrease in well-being/social time on weekendsfor workers is given by β 1 , whereas the weekendincrease for the unemployed is given by β 3 .

    We extend this basic model in the usual wayby adding in control variables for age, gender,race/ethnicity, children in the home, education,and family income. 7 Because this study alreadyprovides random assignment to weekends, weexpect that our raw weekend effects will be unaf-fected by the inclusion of control variables. How-ever, the controls are likely to allow a more accu-rate estimate of β 2 , the difference between work-ers and the unemployed during the week. Thismodel is specied as

    Y i = α + β 1 Worker Weekend i + β 2 Unemployed i

    + β 3 Unemp Weekend i + X k δ k + εi , (2)in whichX k is the k × 1 vector of control variablesand δ k is the 1 × k vector of coefficients.

    Descriptive Evidence:Emotional Well-Being on Week-ends versus WeekdaysWe begin with a descriptive analysis of the rawdata, looking at weekend effects for workers andthe unemployed. After giving an intuitive eyeballanalysis, we check the robustness of this usingregression adjustment for a host of sociodemo-graphic covariates.

    As a starting point, we plot the average pos-itive and negative emotions of workers and theunemployed by day of week. In Figure 2, westart the graphs midweek to give a clear view of the beginning and ending of weekends (which oc-curs at the midpoint of our gures). This reveals

    three basic ndings. First, weekend effects areclear, with a rise in positive feelings and a dropin negative emotions on weekends. Second, theunemployed have notably lower well-being every

    7 The list of control variables is calibrated as closely aspossible across our two data sets. The only difference isthat ATUS includes a measure of annual family income,whereas Gallup uses monthly family income.

    Figure 2: (A ) Positive and ( B ) negative emotionsby day of week. From Gallup Daily Poll, 2009–11.

    day of the week (less happiness, more stress andworry) compared to workers. This is consistentwith previous work on the experience of unem-ployment (e.g., Young 2012; Burgard, Brand,

    and House 2007). Third, the weekend effects forworkers are strikingly similar to those of the un-employed. Though the unemployed do not goto work, they seem to be looking forward to theweekend in much the same way as workers.

    To get another perspective on these data, inTable 1, we simplify the day-of-week comparisonto weekends and weekdays and look at each emo-tion variable separately. For employed people, allthree positive emotions increase on weekends byabout 5 percent. Among the unemployed, theweekend boost is essentially the same. This isshown in the ratio of the weekend effects of the

    unemployed to the weekend effects for workers,which is 93 percent.On weekends, workers see their negative emo-

    tions drop by about 24 percent on average (rang-ing from 10 percent to 35 percent, depending onthe variable). Worry, stress, and anger show thelargest drops, whereas sadness has the smallest

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 17 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    9/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    Table 1: Average Number of Emotions Experienced, by Variable

    Positive Emotions Negative EmotionsHappy Smile Enjoy Worry Stress Anger Sad

    Employed

    Monday–Friday 0.89 0.83 0.85 0.31 0.45 0.13 0.14Weekend 0.92 0.87 0.91 0.23 0.29 0.10 0.12% Difference 4% 4% 7% -26% -35% -27% -10%

    UnemployedMonday–Friday 0.82 0.75 0.78 0.49 0.51 0.19 0.28Weekend 0.84 0.79 0.83 0.42 0.44 0.17 0.26

    % Difference 3% 5% 6% -14% -14% -12% -7%

    Ratio of Weekend Effects(Unemployed / Employed) 74% 122% 84% 54% 39% 43% 75%

    Average Ratio 93% 53%

    Note: Source: Gallup Daily Poll, 2009-11

    decline. The jobless experience a drop in theseemotions on weekends of about 12 percent. Theaverage ratio indicates that the unemployed expe-rience about 53 percent of the weekend reductionin negative emotions as workers.8

    Weekends have greater effects on negativeemotions, we suspect, for two reasons. First,there is simply a lower rate of reporting nega-tive emotions. People are much more likely toreport being happy than being angry, at leastpartly due to social acceptability bias. This lowbaseline rate of negative emotions makes the per-centage changes look larger. Second, as we showin the regression results, the coefficients on al-most all variables are larger in the analysis of negative well-being than in positive well-being.Reports of negative well-being seem more elasticto circumstances than reports of positive well-being. Positive and negative emotions are not

    8 The differences in this table can be thought of assemielasticities: the percentage difference in well-beingowing to the difference in employment status. Using themarginal effects (unit differences in well-being) producessimilar results. To exactly replicate our baseline regres-sion model, the positive and negative groups would eachbe averaged (i.e., average positive and average negativeemotions) before calculating the ratio of weekend effects.Doing so with marginal effects gives an average ratio of 84 percent and 63 percent for positive and negative well-being, respectively. That leads to a very similar overallconclusion. Table 1 gives a more intuitive representa-tion of the data and gives very similar average ratios asreported in our full regression models later in the article.

    simple reections of one another but seem to cap-ture some uniquely different aspects of emotionalexperience.

    In any event, taken across both positive andnegative measures of well-being, the jobless takein nearly three-quarters as much of the weekendeffect that working people enjoy. However, thereis a clear difference in that negative emotionsdecline more for workers than for the unemployedon weekends. A visible portion of the relief fromstress, worry, and anger on the weekend is uniqueto working people. Weekends are a decompressiontime—a relief from negative feelings—for workersmore than they are for the unemployed. Althoughthe unemployed have more negative emotionsduring the week on every measure, the negativesdo not drop on the weekend as much as they dofor workers.

    Regression ResultsHow robust are these conclusions to the additionof control variables for sociodemographic differ-ences, including age, sex, race, family status, in-come, and education? In Table 2, we report thefull details of our regression results for positiveand negative emotions. Model 1 shows regres-sion results for positive well-being by employmentand weekend status. The weekend effect for theunemployed ( + 0.038) is very similar to that for

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 18 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    10/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    workers (+ 0.043), both of which are highly signif-icant. The difference in coefficients between thetwo groups (0.005) is small and nonsignicant.

    Adding in controls (model 2) does not changethe weekend effect estimates, as we expected,because both workers and the unemployed arerandomly assigned to report on weekends. Thechange in the estimated weekend effects frommodel 1 to model 2 is barely visible, changingonly slightly for the unemployed, and the dif-ference is far from statistical signicance .9 Thecontrols do mute the negative baseline effect of unemployment, reducing it from –0.075 to –0.061,indicating that some of the raw effect of unem-ployment is due to demographic differences .10

    The point estimates indicate that the unemployedexperience about 90 percent of the weekend effectthat workers do.

    It is worth noting that weekend effects arelarge relative to almost all other inuences on well-being. The sociological signicance of weekendsfor well-being is greater than sociodemographicfactors such as marriage, race, and education butlesser than unemployment.

    Model 3 looks at the determinants of nega-tive well-being, and model 4 adds demographiccontrols. Weekends reduce negative feelings suchas stress and worry for both groups, but morefor workers (–0.071) than for the unemployed(–0.039). Again, these point estimates do notchange when control variables are included (model4). And the baseline effect of unemployment issignicantly smaller in model 2 than in model 1 (t-statistic = 4.94). Although there is selection intounemployment based on observed covariates, thisevidence continues to support the effectiveness of random assignment into weekends.

    The point estimates indicate that the joblessexperience 53 percent of the weekend effect thatworkers enjoy in lower negative emotions. Thenull hypothesis that the two groups have equalweekend effects is easily rejected, with a t-statisticof approximately 60. There is clearly reliable

    9 The t -statistic is simply the difference in coefficientsdivided by the square root of the sum of the squaredstandard errors (Paternoster et al. 1998; Gelman andStern 2006). For the difference in weekend effects for theunemployed from model 1 to model 2, this is (0.039 −0.038) / 0.005 2 + 0 .005 2 = 0.14.

    10 This difference is statistically signicant with a t -statistic of –3.29.

    empirical support for weekends having unique,additional value for workers.

    Finally, as seen with positive well-being, week-end effects rank among the most important in-uences on negative well-being. Even for theunemployed, weekend effects equal or outweighfactors such as education, gender, marriage, andparental status. Only unemployment itself has aclearly larger effect on well-being than do week-ends. Averaging across positive and negativeemotions, the unemployed experience about 73percent of the weekend rise in well-being thatworkers enjoy.

    Does Social Time Explain Week-end Effects in Well-Being?

    Something about the standard workweek leads tohigher well-being on weekends, even among the jobless. Going back to work on Monday provideslimited explanation for the drop in well-being seenduring the week. To what extent is this becausesocial time declines during the week for bothworkers and the unemployed? Are the weekdaypatterns of social time similar to the patterns inwell-being?

    First, we plot social time use by day of week,using the raw data. Figure 3A, time spent withfriends in the ATUS, shows large spikes aroundthe weekends for both workers and the unem-

    ployed. Saturday is clearly the peak day for timewith friends. The unemployed, compared to work-ers, spend more time with friends every day of the week. There is also some difference in theweekend effects for workers and the unemployed.For workers, time with friends is elevated on Fri-day, Saturday, and Sunday. For the unemployed,there is more noise in the day-to-day estimates,but their time with friends appears elevated onFriday and Saturday only; by Sunday, time withfriends has returned to their weekday average.

    Figure 3B, time with family, also shows clearweekend effects, with Saturday and Sunday beingroughly equal peak days of family time. Theunemployed spend more time with family Mondayto Friday, and their weekend increase is abouthalf of what workers experience.

    It is not the case that the unemployed have noone with whom to spend time on weekdays. Theirsocial time is certainly lower than on weekends

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 19 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    11/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    Table 2: Determinants of Positive Emotions, Negative Emotions, and Social Hours

    Positive Emotions Negative Emotions Social Hours(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

    Unemployed − 0.075∗ − 0.061∗ 0.122∗ 0.101∗ 0.910∗ 0.919∗(0 .003) (0 .003) (0 .003) (0 .003) (0 .040) (0 .039)

    Unemployed × Weekend 0.038∗ 0.039∗ − 0.039∗ − 0.039∗ 0.888∗ 0.908∗(0 .005) (0 .005) (0 .005) (0 .005) (0 .072) (0 .069)

    Worker × Weekend 0.043∗ 0.043∗ − 0.071∗ − 0.071∗ 2.080∗ 2.083∗(0 .001) (0 .001) (0 .001) (0 .001) (0 .019) (0 .018)

    Age − 0.001∗ − 0.001∗ − 0.044∗(0 .000) (0 .000) (0 .001)

    Female 0.007∗ 0.033∗ 0.236∗(0 .001) (0 .001) (0 .016)

    One or more children − 0.010∗ 0.032∗ 0.454∗

    (0.001) (0

    .001) (0

    .018)Married 0.026∗ − 0.023∗ 0.491∗

    (0 .001) (0 .001) (0 .019)Monthly income 0.004∗ − 0.006∗ 0.032∗

    (0 .000) (0 .000) (0 .002)Education a

    Less than high school − 0.022∗ 0.034∗ − 0.403∗(0 .003) (0 .003) (0 .045)

    Some college 0.005∗ 0.017∗ 0.042(0 .001) (0 .002) (0 .023)

    College degree 0.006∗ 0.011∗ − 0.448∗(0 .001) (0 .002) (0 .024)

    Post graduate education 0.003 0.021∗ − 0.483∗(0 .002) (0 .002) (0 .026)

    Race/ethnicityb

    Black 0.005∗ − 0.062∗ 0.219∗(0 .002) (0 .002) (0 .031)

    Asian − 0.023∗ − 0.018∗ − 0.844∗(0 .004) (0 .004) (0 .058)

    Hispanic 0.005∗ − 0.008∗ − 1.257∗(0 .002) (0 .002) (0 .030)

    Other − 0.010∗ 0.010∗ 0.202∗(0 .003) (0 .003) (0 .045)

    Constant 0.856∗ 0.858∗ 0.277∗ 0.326∗ 4.986∗ 6.367∗(0 .001) (0 .002) (0 .001) (0 .003) (0 .010) (0 .040)

    Observations 503,284 503,284 503,284 503,284 333,354 333,354R 2 0.011 0.019 0.026 0.045 0.060 0.105

    Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Gallup Daily Poll Data, 2009–11. a Reference category: high schooldiploma. b Reference category: white.∗ p < 0.01

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 20 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    12/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    Figure 3: Time with (A ) friends and (B ) family byday of week. From American Time Use Survey,2003–11.

    but remains higher than the amount of socialtime that working people have Monday to Friday.A full assessment of the evidence clearly needs totake this fact into account. However, in supple-

    mentary analyses not reported here, the amountof time the unemployed spend alone is also higherMonday to Friday (+ 1.8 hours per day) than onweekends.

    In summary, there are strong weekend effectsin social time for both workers and the unem-ployed. This provides a promising account of why both groups have similar weekend effects intheir well-being.

    Table 3 shows the full regression results for so-cial time in the ATUS. Model 7 shows the resultsfor time spent with friends including unemploy-ment and weekend status without controls. Forthe unemployed, time with friends increases by18.5 minutes, compared to 36.7 minutes for work-ers. With the full set of controls in model 8, theweekend effect for the unemployed rises slightlyto 20.2 minutes and is unchanged for workers at36.6 minutes. The difference in weekend effectsis statistically signicant (t-statistic = 3.69).

    Model 9 shows estimated weekend effects fortime spent with family. Working people increasethe amount of time spent with family on weekendsby 189 minutes—more than three hours. For theunemployed, the increase is 103 minutes—roughlyan hour and a half. Adding in demographic con-trols in model 10 changes the estimate for theunemployed weekend effect slightly, which dropsto 97 minutes. Time spent with family increasesby half as much for the unemployed as it doesfor workers. The difference is due to the greaterability of the unemployed to spend more hourswith family during the week. Nonetheless, a clearlimitation on social time with family during theweek remains.

    As a reference point, we also consider house-hold labor. Chores around the house are notsubject to social network constraints in the way

    that social time is. People do not need to coordi-nate with social others to productively engage inhousehold labor: cleaning, cooking, yard main-tenance, household repairs, and the like. Mosthousehold labor, we argue, is about as produc-tively done alone as with others, and we expect tosee no weekend effect in household work amongthe unemployed. Figure 4 shows that this isindeed the case.

    Whereas workers increase their household workon weekends, the unemployed have a stable, highlevel of housework. Workers, in effect, coordinatetheir household labor not to conict with their

    market work times. The jobless spend about 2hours and 15 minutes per day on household work—equivalent to what workers do on weekends. Witha “day off,” workers and the unemployed spend

    Figure 4: Time on housework by day of week. FromAmerican Time Use Survey, 2003–11.

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 21 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    13/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    Table 3: Determinants of Time Use: Friends, Family and Housework

    Time with Friends Time with Family Household Work(7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12)

    Unemployed 54.8∗ 36.4∗ 96.2∗ 132.1∗ 57.2∗ 75.3∗

    (3.3) (3

    .2) (6

    .2) (5

    .4) (3

    .0) (3

    .0)Unemployed × Weekend 18.5∗ 20.2∗ 103.2∗ 96.9∗ − 1.6 − 3.7

    (4 .4) (4 .3) (8 .4) (7 .2) (4 .1) (3 .9)Worker × Weekend 36.7∗ 36.6∗ 189.2∗ 187.4∗ 58.4∗ 58.7∗

    (1 .2) (1 .1) (2 .2) (1 .9) (1 .1) (1 .1)Constant 33.6∗ 143.1∗ 211.9∗ 1.2 77.6∗ − 25.1∗

    (0 .8) (2 .8) (1 .6) (4 .6) (0 .8) (2 .5)

    Demographic controls No Yes No Yes No Yes

    Observations 61,684 61,684 61,684 61,684 61,684 61,684Adjusted R 2 0.022 0.087 0.107 0.349 0.047 0.111

    Note: Standard errors in parentheses. American Time Use Data 2003-11. The dependent variable in theATUS is in minutes, while the Gallup data in Table 2 are reported in hours. To maintain comparableprecision, estimates here are reported to the rst decimal place.∗ p < 0.01

    equal amounts of time on household work. It is just that the unemployed have ve more daysoff per week. If social time were not subject tonetwork constraints, this is what we would expectpatterns of time with friends and family to looklike.

    In Table 3, models 11 and 12 show that al-though there are clear weekend effects in house-hold labor for workers, there is no weekend effectat all for the unemployed.

    The Gallup data also provide evidence of howtime use varies by day of week. Figure 5 shows

    Figure 5: Social hours by day of week. From GallupDaily Poll, 2009–11.

    a general measure of “social hours” for weekendsand weekdays from the Daily Poll. The resultsare similar to the ATUS data. In Table 2, mod-els 5 and 6 show that workers see an increase insocial time of 2.1 hours (125 minutes) per dayon weekends, whereas the unemployed see an in-crease of 0.9 hours (55 minutes). Thus, in theGallup data, the unemployed experience 43 per-cent of the weekend effect in social time. Duringthe week, the unemployed spend nearly an extraone social hour per day more than workers.

    In summary, the unemployed experience 55percent of the weekend effect in time spent withfriends that the employed experience, 52 percentof the weekend effect in time with family, and 43percent of the social hours effect in the Gallupdata. Overall, this suggests that weekends shouldbe about half as important for the unemployedas they are for workers. This does not seem toprovide a complete explanation of why the unem-ployed enjoy three-quarters of the weekend effectin well-being. But the commonality of the pat-terns in well-being and social time suggest thisis a prominent explanation. The next step is totest the underlying assumption that social hoursincrease well-being, and if so, do they increasewell-being by enough to explain the weekend ef-fects?

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 22 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    14/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    In Table 4, we incorporate the Gallup socialhours variable into the initial well-being regres-sions. For roughly one-third of our observations,questions about social hours were not asked. Thisreduces the sample size to about 333,000. Model13, the determinants of positive emotions, repli-cates model 2 with the smaller sample. None of the estimates of interest are meaningfully affectedby the sample size reduction. However, includingsocial hours (model 14) does have a clear effect.The weekend effect for the unemployed drops by38 percent, from 0.040 to 0.025, and drops forworkers by 77 percent (from 0.044 to 0.010). Thenumber of social hours explains about 57 percentof the increase in positive emotions on weekends.This is about what the simple day-of-week analy-ses suggested.

    For negative emotions, models 15 and 16 show

    that when social hours are included, the weekendeffects fall by 28 percent for the unemployed and31 percent for workers. Thus, social hours explainabout 29 percent of the reduction in negativefeelings on weekends. This is somewhat less thanexpected from the simple day-of-week patterns.The reason is that the number of social hourspeople spend has less of an effect on negativeemotions like stress and sadness (0.011 in absolutevalue) than it does on positive emotions (0.016in absolute value).

    Overall, averaging across positive and nega-tive emotions for both workers and the unem-

    ployed, the number of social hours people enjoyexplains 43 percent of the weekend well-beingeffects. 11 There remain weekend effects in well-being that are both statistically and sociologicallysignicant for both workers and the unemployed,that cannot be explained by social hours alone.

    Another important result from Table 4 is thatsocial hours do not explain the baseline effect of unemployment. This sheds light on why the un-employed have lower well-being, even though theyhave more social time than workers. Social timeduring the week does partly compensate for thedistress of unemployment. Without it, the unem-ployed would be even more distressed. However,the negative effect of unemployment is very largecompared to the gain in social hours. For positivewell-being, the effect of unemployment is –0.080,

    11 This is the average reduction in the four weekendcoefficients as a result of including social hours in theregression models.

    which is roughly ve times as large as the effect of a social hour. For negative well-being, the effectof unemployment is 0.118, which is 10 times theeffect of a social hour. In other words, it wouldtake ve extra hours of social time each day tocompensate for the drop in happiness among theunemployed and 10 social hours to compensatefor the increase in stress and sadness. But, inthe Gallup data, unemployment gives people anextra one hour of social time. Unemployment isa very costly way to leverage extra social time.

    Discussion and ConclusionWhat is it about time off work that people mostvalue: avoiding the disutility of labor or the op-portunity for greater social contact? To whatextent does extra free time give a valued benetthat can offset the socioeconomic and psychologi-cal costs of unemployment? Both these questionsfeed into a basic understanding of time. Is timebest understood as analogous to money, in whichthe primary concern is one’s budget of free time?Or is time better understood as a network good,in which the marginal value of extra time canvary widely and depends on the schedules of oth-ers (Winship 2009; DiMaggio and Garip 2012;Bittman 2005)?

    The analyses here present a series of new andimportant social facts. First, weekends have aneffect on well-being that is clear and large relativeto other determinants of well-being: weekendeffects are sociologically important (Helliwell andWang 2011). However, the benets of weekendsare not primarily due to having time off fromwork: the jobless experience about three-quartersof the benet of weekends. Only one-quarterof the weekend rise in well-being can be readilyattributed to rest from work.

    Second, the amount of social time that peo-ple have increases substantially on weekends, forboth workers and the unemployed. Increases insocial time explain nearly half of the weekend rise

    in well-being. A large part of why weekends arebetter than weekdays is that friends and familiesare able spend more time together. Free timeduring the week does not easily translate intogreater social time. Absent the social coordina-tion of the standard workweek, workers would see

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 23 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    15/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    Table 4: Determinants of Well-Being, Including Social Hours

    Positive Emotions Negative Emotions(13) (14) (15) (16)

    Unemployed − 0.062∗ − 0.080∗ 0.107∗ 0.118∗(0.003) (0 .003) (0 .003) (0 .003)Unemployed × Weekend 0.040∗ 0.025∗ − 0.036∗ − 0.026∗(0.006) (0 .005) (0 .006) (0 .006)

    Worker × Weekend 0.044∗ 0.010∗ − 0.072∗ − 0.050∗(0.001) (0 .001) (0 .001) (0 .001)

    Social hours 0.016∗ − 0.011∗(0.000) (0 .000)

    Constant 0.858∗ 0.756∗ 0.323∗ 0.389∗(0.003) (0 .003) (0 .003) (0 .003)

    Demographic controls Yes Yes Yes Yes

    Observations 333,354 333,354 333,354 333,354R 2 0.020 0.065 0.047 0.063Note: Standard errors in parentheses. Gallup Daily Poll, 2009-11.∗ p < 0.01

    much smaller gains in sociability and well-beingon their days off.

    Third, a signicant part of weekend well-beingremains unexplained by either time off work orextra social hours. There is something in addition to social hours that makes weekends better thanweekdays for both workers and the unemployed.

    Social multipliers stemming from having alarge portion of the workforce with a shared dayoff may explain the residual weekend effects. Forexample, those with a day off may interact withthe world in a more positive way—they are lessbusy, are less tired, and have more emotionalenergy to share with others. This increases thequality of their social interactions and creates apositive externality for the individuals who in-teract with them (Fowler and Christakis 2008).When a large portion of the population does notgo into work on a given day, not only the quantitybut also the quality of social interaction increases.

    This, in turn, suggests that the value of socialhours is greater on weekends than during theweek. From a different perspective, when themajority of the workforce has a day off, it maychange social expectations and normalize “notworking.” This allows everyone to relax moreand creates a sense that the day is meant to be

    enjoyed, increasing the value of nonwork timefor everyone, whether that time is spent withcompany or alone. The unemployed may partic-ularly appreciate days when the rest of societybecomes more similar to them, making their non-work status less salient and unusual. From thisperspective, weekend well-being depends on a

    general expectation of leisure but not on the spe-cic availability of one’s own family and friends.12Both of these factors likely help explain why thequantity of social hours explains only half of theweekend effect on well-being.

    The ndings of this study also speak directlyto the experience of unemployment. In a timefamine age, the unemployed are people who havegained large amounts of free time. This has comeat a steep cost: a loss of income and great anxietyabout their status as productive members of so-ciety (Young 2012; Burgard et al. 2007; Newman1999). Nevertheless, the jobless may see their

    circumstance as a mixture of costs and benets(Feldstein and Altman 2007; Krueger and Meyer2002), resenting joblessness but simultaneouslyvaluing extra time. We nd supporting evidence,

    12 This is a question of whether other people’s workschedules create “global” or “local” externalities (DiMaggioand Garip 2012).

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 24 February 2014 | Volume 1

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    16/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    but only weakly so. The jobless spend more socialtime with people than working people do (at leastan extra hour per day during the week), showinga tangible benet of unemployment. However,the social-psychological costs of unemploymentare very large relative to the extra social timethat is available during unemployment. Socialtime does moderate the distress of unemployment,but the jobless would need 5 to 10 times morehours of social contact than they actually get tofully alleviate the social-psychological distress of job loss.

    The dilemma of the unemployed is that, al-though they have additional free time during theweek, other people still have to go to work. Equiv-alently, working people may think of their jobsas “a drag” because they compare their workinglives to their lives on the weekend—not to the

    achievable alternative of staying home during theweek. The opportunity cost of working and thebenets of free time both depend on the schedulesand availability of others.

    The standard workweek coordinates work lifein a way that maximizes social time and well-being on weekends and creates a strong perceivedrelationship between workdays and unhappiness.Yet it also means that individuals cannot easilyavoid the unhappiness of the workweek by notgoing to work. Individual days off during theweek seem to fall very far short of the experienceof shared weekends. This emphasizes that the

    standard workweek is an institutional structurethat both enables and constrains (e.g., Brintonand Nee 1998; Ingram and Clay 2000).

    Because time is a network good, it is hardto nd individual solutions to problems of timepressure. Weekend well-being is a collectivelyproduced social good; time famine is in part a col-lectively produced coordination failure. In recentyears, there has been much focus on achievinggreater individual exibility in work schedules.Such exibility no doubt has many benets, butthe downside of time exibility is that it movesus toward the privatization of personal schedulesand ever further from coordinated social time.Privatized personal schedules generate individ-ual convenience but make unplanned social timeincreasingly difficult to nd: they set up the

    “bowling alone” problem. Ultimately, the moresuccessful solution may be to nd freedom in con-

    straint: greater standardization of the times forwork and the times for life.

    References

    Åberg, Yvonne. 2009. “The Contagiousness of Di-vorce.” Pp. 342–64 in The Oxford Handbook of Analytical Sociology, edited by Peter Hed-strom and Peter Bearman. Oxford: OxfordUniversity Press.

    Bianchi, S. M., J. P. Robinson, and M. A. Milkie.2007. Changing Rhythms of American Family Life. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Bittman, Michael. 2005. “Sunday Workingand Family Time.” Labour and Industry 16: 59–83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10301763.2005.10722031

    Blundell, Richard and Thomas MaCurdy. 1999. “Labor Supply: A Review of Alternative Ap-proaches.” Pp. 1559–1695 in Handbook of Labor Economics, Vol. 3, edited by Or-ley Ashenfelter and David Card. Amster-dam: North-Holland. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)03008-4

    Brinton, Mary and Victor Nee, eds. 1998. The New Institutionalism in Sociology . New York:Russell Sage Foundation.

    Burgard, Sarah A., Jennie E. Brand, andJames S. House. 2007. “Toward a BetterEstimation of the Effect of Job Loss onHealth.” Journal of Health and Social Be-havior 48:369–84. http://dx.doi.org/10 .1177/002214650704800403

    Collins, Randall. 2004. Interaction Ritual Chains. Princeton, NJ: Princeton UniversityPress.

    Diener, Ed. 1994. “Assessing Subjective Well-Being: Progress and Opportunities.” Social Indicators Research 31:103–57. http://dx .doi.org/10.1007/BF01207052

    Diener, Ed, Daniel Kahneman, William Tov, andRaksha Arora. 2010. “Income’s Associationwith Judgments of Life Versus Feeling.” Pp. 3–15 in International Differences in Well-Being,edited by E. Diener, J. F. Helliwell, and D.Kahneman. New York: Oxford UniversityPress.

    DiMaggio, Paul and Joseph Cohen. 2005. “Infor-mation Inequality and Network Externalities:

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 25 February 2014 | Volume 1

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10301763.2005.10722031http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10301763.2005.10722031http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)03008-4http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)03008-4http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/002214650704800403http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/002214650704800403http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF01207052http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF01207052http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF01207052http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF01207052http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/002214650704800403http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/002214650704800403http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)03008-4http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4463(99)03008-4http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10301763.2005.10722031http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/10301763.2005.10722031

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    17/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    A Comparative Study of the Diffusion of Tele-vision and the Internet.” Pp. 227–67 in The Economic Sociology of Capitalism, edited byVictor Nee and Richard Swedberg. Princeton,NJ: Princeton University Press.

    DiMaggio, Paul and Filiz Garip. 2011. “HowNetwork Externalities Can Exacerbate Inter-group Inequality.” American Journal of So-ciology 116:1887–1933. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/659653

    DiMaggio, Paul and Filiz Garip. 2012. “NetworkEffects and Social Inequality.” Annual Review of Sociology 38:93–118. http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102545

    Evans, James, Gideon Kunda and Stephen Bar-ley. 2004. “Beach Time, Bridge Time and Bil-lable Hours: The Temporal Structure of Tech-nical Contracting.” Administrative Science Quarterly 49:1–38. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/4131454

    Feldstein, Martin and Daniel Altman. 2007. “Unemployment Insurance Savings Accounts.”Tax Policy and the Economy 21:35–64.

    Foss, Clive. 2004. “Stalin’s Topsy-Turvy WorkWeek.” History Today, September, 46–47.

    Fowler, James and Nicholas Christakis. 2008. “Dynamic Spread of Happiness in a LargeSocial Network: Longitudinal Analysis over20 Years in the Framingham Heart Study.” British Medical Journal 337:a2338. http://dx.doi.org/10.1136/bmj.a2338

    Gelman, Andrew and Hal Stern. 2006. “TheDifference between ‘Signicant’ and ‘Not Sig-nicant’ Is Not Itself Statistically Signicant.”American Statistician 60:328–31. http://dx.doi.org/10.1198/000313006X152649

    Helliwell, John and Shun Wang. 2011. “Weekendsand Subjective Well-Being.” NBER WorkingPaper 17180.

    Hochschild, A. R. 1997. The Time Bind: When Work Becomes Home and Home Becomes Work. New York: Metropolitan Books.

    Hornstein, Andreas. 2002. “Towards a Theoryof Capacity Utilization: Shiftwork and theWorkweek of Capital.” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly 88: 65–86.

    Ingram, Paul and Karen Clay. 2000. “The Choice-within-Constraints New Institutionalism and

    Implications for Sociology.” Annual Review of Sociology 26:525–46. http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.26.1.525

    Jacobs, Jerry and Kathleen Gerson. 2004. The Time Divide: Work, Family, and Gender In-

    equality. Cambridge, MA: Harvard UniversityPress.Jevons, Stanley. 1890. Money and the Mecha-

    nism of Exchange. New York: D. Appleton.Kahneman, Daniel, Alan Krueger, David Schkade,

    Norbert Schwarz, and Arthur Stone. 2004. “A Survey Method for Characterizing DailyLife Experience: The Day ReconstructionMethod.” Science 306:1776–80.

    Keane, Michael. 2011. “Labor Supply and Taxes:A Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 49:961–1075.

    Krueger, Alan and Bruce Meyer. 2002. “La-bor Supply Effects of Social Insurance.” Pp. 2327–92 in Handbook of Public Eco-nomics, Vol. 4, edited by Alan Auer-bach and Martin Feldstein. Amsterdam:North-Holland. http://dx.doi.org/10 .1016/S1573-4420(02)80012-X

    Leclerc, France, Bernd Schmitt, and LauretteDube. 1995. “Waiting Time and DecisionMaking: Is Time Like Money?” Journal of Consumer Research 22:110–19. http://dx .doi.org/10.1086/209439

    Lesnard, Laurent. 2008. “Off-Scheduling withinDual-Earner Couples: An Unequal and Neg-ative Externality for Family Time.” Ameri-can Journal of Sociology 114:447–90. http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/590648

    Levin, Eric and Robert Wright. 2001. “Un-employment Insurance, Moral Hazard, andEconomic Growth.” International Advances in Economic Research 7:373–84. http://dx .doi.org/10.1007/BF02295767

    Lyness, Karen, Janet Gornick, Pamela Stone,and Angela Grottoa. 2012. “It’s All aboutControl: Worker Control over Schedule andHours in Cross-National Context.” American Sociological Review 77:1023–49. http://dx .doi.org/10.1177/0003122412465331

    Newman, Katherine S. 1999. Falling from Grace:Downward Mobility in the Age of Affluence.Berkeley: University of California Press.

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 26 February 2014 | Volume 1

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/659653http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/659653http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102545http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102545http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/4131454http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/4131454http://dx.doi.org/10.1136/bmj.a2338http://dx.doi.org/10.1136/bmj.a2338http://dx.doi.org/10.1198/000313006X152649http://dx.doi.org/10.1198/000313006X152649http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.26.1.525http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.26.1.525http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4420(02)80012-Xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4420(02)80012-Xhttp://%20http//dx.doi.org/10.1086/209439http://%20http//dx.doi.org/10.1086/209439http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/590648http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/590648http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02295767http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02295767http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0003122412465331http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0003122412465331http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0003122412465331http://dx.doi.org/10.1177/0003122412465331http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02295767http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/BF02295767http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/590648http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/590648http://%20http//dx.doi.org/10.1086/209439http://%20http//dx.doi.org/10.1086/209439http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4420(02)80012-Xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S1573-4420(02)80012-Xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.26.1.525http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.26.1.525http://dx.doi.org/10.1198/000313006X152649http://dx.doi.org/10.1198/000313006X152649http://dx.doi.org/10.1136/bmj.a2338http://dx.doi.org/10.1136/bmj.a2338http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/4131454http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/4131454http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102545http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.soc.012809.102545http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/659653http://dx.doi.org/10.1086/659653

  • 8/20/2019 Time as a Network Good

    18/18

    Young and Lim Time as a Network Good

    Paternoster, Raymond, Robert Brame, PaulMazerolle, and Alex Piquero. 1998. “Usingthe Correct Statistical Test for the Equal-ity of Regression Coefficients.” Criminology 36:859–66. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-9125.1998.tb01268.x

    Presser, Harriet B. 2003. Working in a 24/7 Economy: Challenges for American Families.New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Putnam, Robert. 2000. Bowling Alone: The Collapse and Revival of American Community.New York: Simon and Schuster.

    Robinson, John P. and Geoffrey Godbey. 2000.Time for Life: The Surprising Ways Amer-icans Use Their Time. 2nd ed. UniversityPark: Pennsylvania State University Press.

    Rybczynski, Witold. 1991. Waiting for the Week-end

    . New York: Viking Press.Schor, Juliet B. 1991. The Overworked American.New York: Basic Books.

    Shapiro, Carl and Hal Varian. 1999. Informa-tion Rules: A Strategic Guide to the Network Economy. Boston: Harvard Business SchoolPress.

    Stovel, Katherine and Christine Fountain. 2009. “Matching.” Pp. 365–90 in The Handbook of Analytic Sociology , edited by Peter Hed-strom and Peter Bearman. Oxford: OxfordUniversity Press.

    Strazdins, Lyndall, Mark S. Clements, Rose-mary J. Korda, Dorothy H. Broom, andRennie M. D’Souza. 2006. “Unsocia-ble Work? Nonstandard Work Schedule,Family Relationships, and Children’s Well-Being.” Journal of Marriage and Family 68:394–410. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1741-3737.2006.00260.x

    Verbakel, Ellen and Thomas DiPrete. 2008. “TheValue of Non-Work Time in Cross-NationalQuality of Life Comparisons: The Case of theUnited States vs. the Netherlands.” Social Forces 87:679–712. http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/sof.0.0125

    Weiner, Rachel. 2011. “State of the Union 2011:Paul Ryan Responds That Government Spend-ing Needs to Stop.” Washington Post, January25. Retrieved September 23, 2012, http://voices.washingtonpost.com/44/2011/01/paul-ryans-response-government.html.

    White, Lynn and Bruce Keith. 1990. “The Effectof Shift Work on the Quality and Stabilityof Marital Relations.” Journal of Marriage and Family 52:453–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/353039

    Williams, Joan. 2010. Re-shaping the Work Fam-ily Debate: Why Men and Class Matter. Cam-bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Winship, Christopher. 2009. “Time and Schedul-ing.” Pp. 499–520 in Oxford Handbook of An-alytical Sociology, edited by Peter Hedströmand Peter Bearman. Oxford: Oxford Univer-sity Press.

    Young, Cristobal. 2012. “Losing a Job: TheNon-pecuniary Cost of Unemployment in theUnited States.” Social Forces 91:609–34.http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/sf/sos071

    Zerubavel, Eviatar. 1981. Hidden Rhythms:Schedules and Calendars in Social Life. Berke-ley: University of California Press.

    Zerubavel, Eviatar. 1985. The Seven Day Cir-cle: The History and Meaning of the Week.Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Acknowledgements: The authors thank TomásJiménez, Corey Fields, Lindsay Owens, EzraZuckerman, Paul DiMaggio, Martin Ruef, SaraMcLanahan, Suzanne Bianchi, Danny Schnei-der, Paolo Parigi, Patricia Young, and Sociolog-ical Science editor Stephen Morgan for valuablesuggestions and constructive criticism. C.L.would like to thank Gallup for granting accessto the Gallup Daily Poll data.

    Cristobal Young: Department of Sociology,Stanford University. E-mail: [email protected].

    Chaeyoon Lim: Department of Sociology, Uni-versity of Wisconsin-Madison. E-mail:[email protected].

    sociological science | www.sociologicalscience.com 27 February 2014 | Volume 1

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-9125.1998.tb01268.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-9125.1998.tb01268.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1741-3737.2006.00260.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1741-3737.2006.00260.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1353/sof.0.0125http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/sof.0.0125http://voices.washingtonpost.com/44/2011/01/paul-ryans-response-government.html.http://voices.washingtonpost.com/44/2011/01/paul-ryans-response-government.html.http://voices.washingtonpost.com/44/2011/01/paul-ryans-response-government.html.http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/353039http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/353039http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/sf/sos071http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/sf/sos071http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/353039http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/353039http://voices.washingtonpost.com/44/2011/01/paul-ryans-response-government.html.http://voices.washingtonpost.com/44/2011/01/paul-ryans-response-government.html.http://voices.washingtonpost.com/44/2011/01/paul-ryans-response-government.html.http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/sof.0.0125http://dx.doi.org/10.1353/sof.0.0125http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1741-3737.2006.00260.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1741-3737.2006.00260.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-9125.1998.tb01268.xhttp://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1745-9125.1998.tb01268.x